private and public sector expenditures on social …social welfare and government expenditures on...

48
PRIVATE AND PUBLIC SECTOR EXPENDITURES ON SOCIAL WELFARE: AN EMPIRICAL ANALYSIS OF SIMPLE CROWD-OUT Steven S. Cuellar Department of Economics Sonoma State University Phone (707) 664-2305 E-Mail: [email protected] Web: http://www.sonoma.edu/users/c/cuellar/home.shtml Preliminary Version February 22, 2004 Introduction This paper examines the interaction between private voluntary contributions to social welfare and government expenditures on social welfare for the years 1929-1991. In particular, I examine the extent to which government social welfare expenditures to the poor affect the level of voluntary private donations to the poor. The present research has important implications for both the theory of private and public expenditures and the much debated public policy ramifications of this theory. For example, if government expenditures affect the level of private charitable contributions, then increases in government expenditures may either increase or decrease the total level of funds transferred to the poor. Thus, the extent to which government contributions affect private contributions becomes a central concern. Consider first the case in which government involvement in helping the poor is counter productive. This will occur if a one dollar increase in government contributions reduces private contributions by more than a dollar. In this instance the total level of contributions to the poor falls as a result of government involvement. Thus, reducing government expenditures on social welfare by one dollar will induce the private sector to increase

Upload: others

Post on 21-Sep-2020

5 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: PRIVATE AND PUBLIC SECTOR EXPENDITURES ON SOCIAL …social welfare and government expenditures on social welfare for the years 1929-1991. In particular, I examine the extent to which

PRIVATE AND PUBLIC SECTOR EXPENDITURES ON SOCIAL WELFARE:

AN EMPIRICAL ANALYSIS OF SIMPLE CROWD-OUT

Steven S. CuellarDepartment of EconomicsSonoma State UniversityPhone (707) 664-2305

E-Mail: [email protected]: http://www.sonoma.edu/users/c/cuellar/home.shtml

Preliminary VersionFebruary 22, 2004

Introduction

This paper examines the interaction between private voluntary contributions to

social welfare and government expenditures on social welfare for the years 1929-1991.

In particular, I examine the extent to which government social welfare expenditures to

the poor affect the level of voluntary private donations to the poor. The present research

has important implications for both the theory of private and public expenditures and the

much debated public policy ramifications of this theory.

For example, if government expenditures affect the level of private charitable

contributions, then increases in government expenditures may either increase or decrease

the total level of funds transferred to the poor. Thus, the extent to which government

contributions affect private contributions becomes a central concern. Consider first the

case in which government involvement in helping the poor is counter productive. This

will occur if a one dollar increase in government contributions reduces private

contributions by more than a dollar. In this instance the total level of contributions to the

poor falls as a result of government involvement. Thus, reducing government

expenditures on social welfare by one dollar will induce the private sector to increase

Page 2: PRIVATE AND PUBLIC SECTOR EXPENDITURES ON SOCIAL …social welfare and government expenditures on social welfare for the years 1929-1991. In particular, I examine the extent to which

1 This analysis ignores efficiency issues regarding transfer programs.

2

contributions by more than one dollar thereby increasing the total level of expenditures

on the poor.

Consider next the case in which government expenditures to social welfare

increase the total level of contributions to the poor. This will occur if a one dollar

increase in government contributions to the poor, reduces private contributions by less

than one dollar. In this case the total level of contributions to the poor increases as a

result of government involvement. Conversely, in this case reducing government

contributions by one dollar will induce private contributions to rise by less than a dollar

thereby reducing total expenditures on the poor. Government tax and transfer programs

are thus effective in increasing the well being of the poor.1

Methodology

The paper follow the general methodology of Roberts (1984) who examines the

simple crowd-out hypothesis for the period 1929-1935. I begin first with a presentation

of a more generalized micro-theoretical model of private charitable contributions than

that presented by Roberts. A model of government spending is then introduced which is

eventually combined with the voluntary contributions model to determine the political-

equilibrium level of government spending. A review of the Roberts analysis of

depression era spending is next, followed by a graphical analysis of the present data.

Econometric analysis of the data is then presented. Finally, results of the study are

examined along with the subsequent policy implications.

Page 3: PRIVATE AND PUBLIC SECTOR EXPENDITURES ON SOCIAL …social welfare and government expenditures on social welfare for the years 1929-1991. In particular, I examine the extent to which

3

A Model of Private Philanthropy

Consider first an impure public goods model of private philanthropy as examined

by Steinberg (1986) and Andreoni (1989). The economy consists of n consumers, with

well defined inter-dependent utility functions in which the level of consumption by the

poor enters the utility function of the non-poor. That is, it is assumed that consumption

by the poor is seen as a public good by the non-poor. Like the pure public goods model,

the impure public good model initially consists of only two goods, a private consumption

good x and the total level public good G. However, unlike the pure public goods model,

in addition to deriving utility from the two goods x and G, the individual contributors

may also derive utility from the act of contributing to the public good. That is, the act of

contributing essentially becomes a third good. Thus, if gi is individual i�s voluntary

contribution to the public good, then individual i's utility can then be represented by the

following three good well behaved utility function:

(7) . Ui ' Ui (xi , G, gi )

Assume consumers are endowed with an exogenous endowment ωi , which is

allocated, after taxes, between the two goods xi and gi . Endowments are taxed at the

rate t with tax revenues costlessly transferred to the public good. Total government

transfers to the public good are then denoted Tg =Gtωi for all i. The sum of voluntary

contributions by those other than I are denoted by G-I =Ggj for j…i. The total level of the

public good is then G = gi + G-i + Tg . The individual budget constraint can then be

written as:

(8) G ' Pg [ ωi(1 & t) & xi ] % jj…i

Pg[ωj (1 & t) & x] % PT jn

i ' 1ωit

Page 4: PRIVATE AND PUBLIC SECTOR EXPENDITURES ON SOCIAL …social welfare and government expenditures on social welfare for the years 1929-1991. In particular, I examine the extent to which

2 For a detailed exposition of the comparative statics, see Chapter I.

3 Note that the model of impure altruism will result in a lower level of crowdingout then the pure public goods model used by Roberts. See Chapter I for a morecomplete discussion of this issue.

4

Where gi = ωi (1-t) - xi , G-I = ωj (1-t) - xj and Tg = 3ωi t . Pg and PT are the cost of

transferring voluntary and government contributions respectively. Set Pg and PT equal to

one (i.e., assume both private and public contributions are made costlessly). Assuming

non-cooperative Nash-Cournot behavior, individual economic agents will maximize the

following inter-dependant utility function:

(9) Maxxi , G , gi

Ui ( Xi , G , gi )

subject to the budget constraint:

(10) G' [ ωi (1 & t) & xi ] % jj…i

[ ωj (1& t) & xj ] % jn

i ' 1ωi

Recall from chapter one that optimization of (9) subject to (10) gives us the conditional

demand for charitable contributions of the form:2

(11) .gi ' gi (ωi (1&t), G& i , TG )

Assume initially that government transfers are zero (i.e., TG =0). In this case,

Nash behavior of economic agents and non-excludability of the public good results in

under provision of the public good.3

A Model of Government Expenditures

Consider now a model of government redistribution. Assume that the

equilibrium amount of government redistribution is determined by a process of

competing political groups. Suppose the government maximizes the following political

function:

Page 5: PRIVATE AND PUBLIC SECTOR EXPENDITURES ON SOCIAL …social welfare and government expenditures on social welfare for the years 1929-1991. In particular, I examine the extent to which

4 This model, used by Roberts, was developed by Becker (1983).

5 Inter-dependant utility functions are not a sufficient condition for an upwardsloping utilities possibilities frontier. Charitable contributions will increase the utility ofboth economic agents, only when the marginal benefit of contributing is greater than the

5

Figure 7Political-Economic Equilibrium

(12) P=P(Ui ,Up) where MPMUi

, MPMUP

> 0

The function P depends on the level of utility of its poor and non-poor constituents.

Political competition among the poor and non-poor ensures that P gets maximized. The

function P then produces convex iso-support curves in utility space. The iso-support

curves show a measure of utility among the poor and non-poor that keeps political

support constant.4

We can now combine the model of private philanthropy with the model of

government redistribution. Inter-dependent utility functions create an upward sloping

portion of the utilities possibilities frontier such as that shown in Figure 7.5 A convex

Page 6: PRIVATE AND PUBLIC SECTOR EXPENDITURES ON SOCIAL …social welfare and government expenditures on social welfare for the years 1929-1991. In particular, I examine the extent to which

marginal cost. That is, when a one dollar contribution to the poor provides more thanone dollars worth of benefit.

6 Note that if the poor have no political power (i.e. if MG/MUP <_ 0).

6

iso-support curve, such as that indicated by the curve I0 , is also illustrated in Figure 7.

Consider first a Nash-Cournot solution such as that represented by the point E1 in

Figure 7. Point E1 represents an equilibrium point in the absence of government. The

non-poor's most preferred point E*, an efficient allocation, is also shown. Note first that

all points on the increasing portion of the utilities possibilities frontier, that is all points

to the left of E*, are inefficient (i.e., all points to the right Pareto dominate points to the

left). That is both the non-poor and the poor can be made better off by further

contributions increasing the consumption of the poor. Points beyond E* however are

all Pareto-efficient. In order to increase the utility of the poor you must decrease the

utility of the non-poor.

A political equilibrium occurs where the highest attainable iso-support curve is

tangent to the utilities possibilities frontier, at a point such as EP . Note that the political

equilibrium Ep is beyond the non-poor's most preferred point E*. To see why, assume

first that the poor have no political power.6 In this case the iso-support curves will be

horizontal and the non-poor's most preferred point will be E*. Because of the public

good aspect of the poor's consumption, even in the case where the non-poor outnumber

the poor or similarly where the non-poor have more political power than the poor, the

non-poor would still choose a policy of redistribution. If the poor have any political

power, the iso-support curves will be convex to the origin, and will thus be tangent to the

Page 7: PRIVATE AND PUBLIC SECTOR EXPENDITURES ON SOCIAL …social welfare and government expenditures on social welfare for the years 1929-1991. In particular, I examine the extent to which

7 The term �over-provision� used by Robert's may be misleading. Recall that allprovisions beyond E* are Pareto optimal. Thus, although points beyond E* are beyondthe non-poor's most preferred point, they are still efficient.

7

utilities possibilities frontier at a point to the right of E*, resulting in �over-provision.�7

Suppose now, however, that the non-poor have no political power (i.e. MG/MUi <_

0). In this case the iso-support curves will be vertical. Because the poor are only

concerned with their own consumption, they would choose to maximize their own

utility. That is the iso-support curves would intersect at a corner point along the

horizontal axis, for example at point E2 in Figure 7, where the utility of the non-poor is

zero.

Political-Economic Equilibrium

In the simple crowd-out model the political economic equilibrium results in a

level of government expenditures beyond the non-poor's most preferred point. What are

the implications of this result for the level of private contributions? In the simple pure

public goods model of Roberts, in which government expenditures crowd-out dollar for

dollar private contributions, private charitable contributions go to zero. That is, in order

to increase the total level of spending on the public good beyond the Nash equilibrium

level, the government must completely crowd-out private sector contributions. These

results, however, are due to the restrictive assumptions used to arrive at dollar for dollar

crowding out.

In the model of impure altruism, government contributions only partially crowd-

out private contributions. Thus, at the margin government transfers will increase the

total level of expenditures to the public good beyond the Nash level. However,

Page 8: PRIVATE AND PUBLIC SECTOR EXPENDITURES ON SOCIAL …social welfare and government expenditures on social welfare for the years 1929-1991. In particular, I examine the extent to which

8

depending on the Nash equilibrium level of private contributions, the political

equilibrium may result in a considerable increase in the total level expenditures to the

public good. For example, suppose the political equilibrium results in a total level of

expenditures of EP shown in Figure 7. This would still be significantly beyond the initial

Nash equilibrium level of private contributions of E1 or the non-poor�s most preferred

point of E*. Consequently, although positive private donations may exist at levels of

spending just beyond the Nash equilibrium, for large discrete expenditures by the

government considerably beyond the Nash level, the total level of private contributions

may approach the complete crowding out results obtained by Roberts.

The implications of the political equilibrium arrived by Roberts from the simple

form of the pure public goods model are thus applicable, with some qualifications, to this

analysis using the model of impure altruism. Specifically, Roberts concludes that:

(a) at the political equilibrium, private contributions are [or will be near] zero.

(b) private contributions first became negligible when the government first

intervened in a �significant� way in the charity market.

(c) at the political equilibrium, the government �over-provides� for the poor.

(d) once an efficient allocation is reached, marginal reductions in social welfare

spending will be ineffective in inducing a crowding in of private charitable

contributions.

The Roberts Paper

Roberts (1984) provides an examination of the crowding out of private charitable

giving and public expenditures in 120 urban areas in the United States for the

Page 9: PRIVATE AND PUBLIC SECTOR EXPENDITURES ON SOCIAL …social welfare and government expenditures on social welfare for the years 1929-1991. In particular, I examine the extent to which

9

period 1929-1935. This period is especially important in that it presents a picture of the

private sector prior to the significant government intervention of the depression era.

Figure 8 shows a graphical representation of the Roberts data.

Figure 8 provides a clear picture of the crowding out theorem predicted by the

model. Note that initially, private contributions increase as government expenditures

increase. This could be a response by the private sector to the growing despair of the

Great Depression, and as such would be consistent with the assumption of inter-

Page 10: PRIVATE AND PUBLIC SECTOR EXPENDITURES ON SOCIAL …social welfare and government expenditures on social welfare for the years 1929-1991. In particular, I examine the extent to which

10

Figure 8Private vs Public Expenditures for 120 Urban Areas 1929-1935

(Thousands of 1920 dollars)Source: Roberts (1984).

dependent utility functions. An alternative explanation may be the so called

�demonstration effect.� The demonstration effect occurs if government expenditures

demonstrate to the private sector a need for giving. The crowding out effect, however,

soon dominates any other effects as government expenditures increase significantly. As

government expenditures increase by nearly 3000% from 1929-1935, private

Page 11: PRIVATE AND PUBLIC SECTOR EXPENDITURES ON SOCIAL …social welfare and government expenditures on social welfare for the years 1929-1991. In particular, I examine the extent to which

8 See F. G. Dickinson, The Changing Position of Philanthropy in the AmericanEconomy (1970).

9 Recall that the Roberts data is for 120 urban areas in the U.S.

contributions fall drastically (i.e., are crowded-out). Note, however, that private

contributions do not go completely to zero as the pure public good model predicts.

Roberts argues that this is due to the aggregate nature of the data. Because aggregate

data on private charity does not accurately distinguish between contributions directed to

social welfare uses and those directed toward more amenity oriented uses, it is difficult

to examine how private charitable contributions directed toward strictly social

redistributive purposes react to increases or decreases in government expenditures. The

aggregate nature of the data thus hides the changing structure of private philanthropy

towards more amenity oriented uses and away from redistributive purposes.8

Consequently, Roberts argues that the portion of private charitable contributions actually

reaching the poor is effectively zero. Positive levels of private contributions in the face

of massive government expenditures is also consistent with the impurely altruistic model

of philanthropy: Individuals will continue to give for purely self-interested motives.

Figure 9 provides an alternative view of the Roberts data which further illustrate

the reduction in private contributions. Figure 9 shows private charitable contributions as

a percent of total (private and public) expenditures on social welfare programs for the

Roberts data.9 As can be seen in Figure 9, private contributions as a percentage of total

expenditures initially increase following the onset of the Great Depression. However,

large increases in government expenditure (147.29% and 126.87% in 1931 and 1932

respectively) along with reduced private contributions eventually reduce the relative

Page 12: PRIVATE AND PUBLIC SECTOR EXPENDITURES ON SOCIAL …social welfare and government expenditures on social welfare for the years 1929-1991. In particular, I examine the extent to which

10 Note that Roberts' analysis ignores any changes in the tax rate or deductibilityof charitable contributions (i.e. the cost of contributing) and changes in aggregateeconomic variables.

Figure 9Ratio of Private to Total Contributions 1929-1935

Source: Roberts (1984)

share

of private contributions to near zero. Thus, Roberts concludes, the private sector has

been effectively crowded-out of the market for charity.10

This chapter, in addition to using a more generalized model of private charity,

extends the period of analysis from 1929-1991. In doing so, I am able to examine the

period immediately before and after the Great Depression to see how the private sector

Page 13: PRIVATE AND PUBLIC SECTOR EXPENDITURES ON SOCIAL …social welfare and government expenditures on social welfare for the years 1929-1991. In particular, I examine the extent to which

11 For a description of how estimates of charitable contributions are made seeGiving USA, or for a more detailed explanation see Nelson (1993).

12 The private data is initially only available in five year intervals for the years1930, 1935,1940,1945,1950 and 1955.

3

reacts to both increases and decreases in government spending. In addition, I examine

two other periods in which large discrete changes in government expenditures occur: The

Kennedy-Johnson �Great Society� programs of the late sixties and early seventies, and

the �Reagan cuts� of the 1980's.

The Data

The data used in this research to analyze the interaction between private

charitable contributions to social welfare and government expenditures on social welfare

comes from two separate sources. The data on private charitable contributions comes

from the American Association of Fund-raising Counsel's annual, Giving USA. The

American Association of Fund-raising Counsel was established in 1935 and has

maintained statistics on private philanthropy starting in 1930 to the present.11 It should

be noted, however, that the data on private philanthropy is incomplete for the period

1929-1955.12 Giving USA classifies data on private charitable contributions into eight

broad categories. These include: religion, education, health, human services, arts &

culture, public/society benefit, environment/wildlife, international affairs and

unclassified. Table 3 shows the human services segment while Table 4 shows the

remaining categories. Along with each category, the corresponding National Taxonomy

of Exempt Entities codes is shown.

The human services segment appears to represent the sort of charitable

Page 14: PRIVATE AND PUBLIC SECTOR EXPENDITURES ON SOCIAL …social welfare and government expenditures on social welfare for the years 1929-1991. In particular, I examine the extent to which

13 Roberts uses the human services data from AAFRC in his paper.

14 Note that the Arts and Public/Society begin in 1955 rather than 1930. This iswhen Giving USA began keeping data for these categories. Also, because Giving USAonly began keeping data on the Environment/Wildlife and International categories in1987, both of these categories are aggregated into the category �Other.� Since theseareas are not of concern for this study, this does not pose any problem.

57

contributions that are the most related to the current research .13 That is, the human

services portion provides the best measure of private charitable contributions aimed at

social welfare programs and is thus shown separately in Table 3. As can be seen from

Table 3, human services includes a large number of programs aimed at aiding the poor

including nutrition, housing employment and homeless programs. In its breadth,

however, the human services section also includes charitable contributions to programs

that may benefit the non-poor. Specifically, contributions to human services include

those contributions going to organizations that fall under categories I (public protection),

J (employment/jobs), K (food, nutrition & agriculture), L (housing/shelter), M (public

safety/disaster preparedness & relief), N (recreation, leisure, sports & athletics), O (youth

development) and P (other human services) of the National Taxonomy of Exempt

Entities. If those categories not aimed directly to the poor could be eliminated, a more

accurate measure of charity could be obtained. Unfortunately, contributions to each

subcategory are not readily available, thus precluding any further refinement of the data.

From the data that does exist, a clear picture of the structure of giving in America

can be examined. Figure 10 shows a graph of each category, along with total giving to

all categories in constant 1991 dollars.14 The last panel in Figure 10 shows a graph of

total giving. From Figure 10, it can be seen that total giving has been rising steadily over

Page 15: PRIVATE AND PUBLIC SECTOR EXPENDITURES ON SOCIAL …social welfare and government expenditures on social welfare for the years 1929-1991. In particular, I examine the extent to which

58

the entire period 1930-1993. Note also that contributions to the arts, education, health

and religion rose fairly steadily over this period, with religious contributions having the

least variability. The same cannot be said of human services. Although contributions to

human services follow a general upward trend, Figure 10 shows that they tend to vary

more drastically than any of the other categories. Determining why this variation occurs

is the central purpose of this research.

Figure 11 shows each category of charitable contributions as a percent of total

private charitable contributions. Figure 11 shows how the structure of giving has

changed over time. For example, although contributions to the arts consists of less than

ten percent of total contributions, their share of total contributions has been increasing.

Contributions to education which have been steadily increasing over the entire period

have experienced drastic increases and decreases in their share of total contributions.

Contributions to health, while increasing steadily over the entire period, have remained a

relatively constant share of total contributions. Religion, the largest category of

charitable contributions in both dollars and as a percent of total contributions, although

rising relatively constantly over the entire period, exhibits relatively large fluctuations in

its share of total contributions. Human services, while following an upward trend in

giving shown in Figure 10, has been falling as a percent of total giving. In addition,

human services has exhibited large fluctuations in its share of total giving. Contributions

to public/society which have been increasing since 1955, have also been increasing as a

share of total contributions. Figures 10 and 11 provides some insight into how the

structure of private charity has changed over time. The implications of these structural

Page 16: PRIVATE AND PUBLIC SECTOR EXPENDITURES ON SOCIAL …social welfare and government expenditures on social welfare for the years 1929-1991. In particular, I examine the extent to which

15 Data in one issue of the Statistical Abstract of the United States did notalways coincide with data recorded in other issues. For example, data for 1960 in the1970 SAUS may be different from data recorded for 1960 in the 1971 issue of theSAUS. The Historical Statistics of the United States provided a partial solution to thisproblem for the years up to 1970. However, for years after 1970, when discrepanciesdid occur, the most recent data was used with the assumption that the most recent data isthe most accurate.

16 This conforms closely to Browning and Browning�s (1994) measure of welfarewhich includes, AFDC, SSI, the earned income tax credit, medicaid, food stamps andhousing assistance.

60

changes for the current research and whether the model of crowding out can explain

some of these changes will be examined more closely below.

The data on public or government expenditures to the poor since 1970 are taken

from various issues of the Statistical Abstract of the United States. Prior to 1970 the

data is taken from the Historical Statistics of the United States.15 The Social Insurance

and Human Services chapter of the Statistical Abstract provides data on Social Welfare

Expenditures. The Public Aid portion of the Social Welfare Expenditures section is the

measure of public expenditures used in this study. The Public Aid section includes many

of those expenditures commonly referred to as �welfare.�16 Table 5 provides a

description of the programs included in the Public Aid section of the social welfare

programs used in this research. These include, Public Assistance including aid to

families with dependant children (AFDC), Medicaid, Social Services, Supplemental

Security Income, the Food Stamps and other public aid expenditures.

This category of public expenditures appears to be the most comparable to the

private contributions data. For the simple crowd out model of Chapter II, the data for

federal, state and local public aid expenditures are aggregated together. In Chapter III,

Page 17: PRIVATE AND PUBLIC SECTOR EXPENDITURES ON SOCIAL …social welfare and government expenditures on social welfare for the years 1929-1991. In particular, I examine the extent to which

17 Kingma (1989) provides a discussion of some of the potential problemsassociated with examining crowding out data. This paper also presents a brief descriptionof alternative models of private philanthropy.

61

when the joint crowd out model is introduced, federal expenditures are separated from

state and local expenditures.

Additional data on income, poverty, age, population and education was taken

from various sources of the Statistical Abstract of the United States and the Economic

Report of the President. Data on the distribution of income was taken from various

reports of the Current Population Survey.

Data Limitations

In examining the interaction between private voluntary contributions and public

expenditures to social welfare there are certain problems arising from data limitations.17

To begin with, there is a problem of disaggregating the data. That is, we must first

distinguish between those social welfare contributions/expenditures that are directed

toward increasing the well being of the poor and others that may be more amenity

oriented. For example, charitable contributions to help the homeless are considered as

increasing the well being of the poor while charitable contributions to the local opera are

not. This problem is most evident in the data on private charitable contributions. As

noted above, the Human Services segment includes not only charitable contributions to

the poor, but also contributions that go to programs like disaster prevention and relief,

recreation and athletics, many of which may benefit the non-poor. Consequently, the

data on private charity may not only overstate private charity to the poor, but may also

Page 18: PRIVATE AND PUBLIC SECTOR EXPENDITURES ON SOCIAL …social welfare and government expenditures on social welfare for the years 1929-1991. In particular, I examine the extent to which

18 This has been well documented in for example, Dickinson's, The Changing Position of Philanthropy, op. cit.

19 For example the National Survey of Philanthropy, used by Schiff (1985),provides data on reported charitable giving by type for 2,500 households for 1973.

62

dampen the response of charitable giving to changes in government spending.

In addition to finding an appropriate measure of charitable contributions to the

poor, the data on private charity must also be comparable to the data used for public

expenditures. That is, dollars spent on public sector social welfare programs must be

used comparably to dollars used in private sector social welfare programs. Accurately

matching private and public expenditures is perhaps the most difficult problem to

overcome. Compounding the comparability of data at any point in time, matching public

and private expenditures becomes increasingly difficult as the nature of philanthropy

changes over time.18 Inter-temporal comparisons increase the difficulty of comparability

since, as Roberts notes, �A dollar contributed to charity in 1929 bought a very different

bundle of services than it did in 1939.� As a result of the problems associated with the

data, one must be cautious in drawing implications from an analysis using aggregate

data.

The problems of using aggregate data notwithstanding, the benefits of using

aggregate data for the present analysis outweigh the costs. To begin with, dis-aggregated

data covering the present period of analysis 1929-1991 has not yet been found by this

researcher and may not exist. Thus, an analysis with a more comparable data set may not

be feasible. The few studies that use more closely matched data sets do not cover

extended periods of time and are thus not amenable to time series analysis.19 The present

Page 19: PRIVATE AND PUBLIC SECTOR EXPENDITURES ON SOCIAL …social welfare and government expenditures on social welfare for the years 1929-1991. In particular, I examine the extent to which

63

Figure 12Private vs Public Expenditures 1929-1955

(Billions of 1991 dollars)

data set, however, provides a unique opportunity to examine critical periods in

government redistribution to the poor and their subsequent affect, if any, on private

charity. Thus, in spite of the limitations of using aggregate data, further economic

analysis may lead to some insight into the inter-dependence between private and public

expenditures towards social welfare.

Graphical Analysis

In this section, I provide a graphical illustration of public expenditures as

measured by the Public Aid segment of governments social welfare expenditures and

private contributions as measured by the Human Services segment of the AAFRC�s

annual Giving USA. Consider first, the period before and after the Great Depression,

Page 20: PRIVATE AND PUBLIC SECTOR EXPENDITURES ON SOCIAL …social welfare and government expenditures on social welfare for the years 1929-1991. In particular, I examine the extent to which

20 If we allow for an initial increase in private sector contributions between 1930and 1935, after which private contributions fall to the 1935 level shown in Figure 12then we obtain results similar to Roberts.

64

1929-1955. Examination of this interval allows for a direct comparison with the Roberts

data. As noted earlier, prior to 1955 the private expenditures data is incomplete and thus

precludes any direct replication of Roberts' results. However, since the data does exist in

five year intervals between 1930 and 1955, tracing out the direction of contributions over

this period is easily accomplished. Figure 12 shows private and public social welfare

expenditures for the period 1929-1955 in billions of constant 1991 dollars. The heavy

dots in Figure 12 indicate the actual levels of private contributions while the straight line

connecting the dots represents a linear estimate of contributions between intervals.

At first glance increased government expenditures do not appear to affect the

level of private contributions. However, recall that the private contributions data is in

five year intervals. In the Roberts data, shown in Figure 8, private contributions initially

rise as government expenditures rise. That is, both private and public sector

expenditures rose at the onset of the Great Depression. Thus, the critical period in

examining the initial crowd-out of private expenditures occurs between 1930 and 1935,

for which the data is incomplete.20 Figure 12 does however show a clear picture of

private contributions �crowding back into� the market. Assuming that government

expenditures initially crowded out private contributions, Figure 12 illustrates the private

sectors

response to a significant reduction in public expenditures. That is, beginning in 1941

private charitable contributions increased sharply (i.e., crowded-back-in) as government

Page 21: PRIVATE AND PUBLIC SECTOR EXPENDITURES ON SOCIAL …social welfare and government expenditures on social welfare for the years 1929-1991. In particular, I examine the extent to which

65

Figure 13Private vs Public Expenditures 1955-1980

(Billions of 1991 dollars)

spending fell precipitously in 1939.

Figure 13 includes the second period of interest, The Kennedy-Johnson �Great

Society� era of social spending and the �War on Poverty� beginning in 1964. As can be

seen from Figure 13, government spending on the poor remained relatively flat from

1955-1964. Over the same period private charitable contributions remained fairly flat,

albeit less stable than public spending. With the onset of the War on Poverty, however,

government spending on the poor increased drastically. Note again, as occurred in the

Roberts data, private contributions initially follow public spending. As with the onset of

the Great Depression, the initial increase in private charity could be explained by the so-

called demonstration effect. That is, government spending demonstrates to the private

sector a need to give to the poor. As with the Roberts data again, the demonstration

Page 22: PRIVATE AND PUBLIC SECTOR EXPENDITURES ON SOCIAL …social welfare and government expenditures on social welfare for the years 1929-1991. In particular, I examine the extent to which

66

Figure 14Private vs Public Expenditures 1980-1991

(Billions of 1991 dollars)

effect is soon overwhelmed by the crowding out effect. Private contributions begin to

fall

in 1970 and continue to fall through to the mid 1970's. From 1970-1976, there is a clear

picture of crowding out. Additionally, as was illustrated in the post depression

reductions in social spending, as the growth rate of government spending significantly

reduced in 1976, private contributions again begin to crowd back in.

The final era of interest is the so called �Reagan cuts� of the 1980's. Figure 14

shows public and private spending for the period 1980-1991. Note first that the �Reagan

cuts� amounted to only a single reduction from 1981-1982. The reduction in 1982

amounted to approximately 13 billion dollars or a reduction of a little over 9% from the

Page 23: PRIVATE AND PUBLIC SECTOR EXPENDITURES ON SOCIAL …social welfare and government expenditures on social welfare for the years 1929-1991. In particular, I examine the extent to which

67

Figure 15Private vs Public Expenditures 1929-1991

(Billions of 1991 dollars)

1981 level. Secondly, following the initial cut in 1982, the level of government social

welfare spending remained relatively flat. The average annual growth rate over the

period 1980-1989 was less than one-half of one percent. Over this same period, private

charity grew at an average annual rate of 3.9% per year. Initially, it appears that the data

over this period does not conform to the model very well. However, recall that one of

the conclusions by Roberts of the model of crowding-out is that the private sector will

respond to large discrete changes in public spending.

Although the Reagan cut of 1982 amounted to large dollar amount, they

amounted to only a 9% reduction. Furthermore, the cut of 1982 is considerably smaller

Page 24: PRIVATE AND PUBLIC SECTOR EXPENDITURES ON SOCIAL …social welfare and government expenditures on social welfare for the years 1929-1991. In particular, I examine the extent to which

21 Chapter II, page 7, part (d).

68

than the reductions in spending that occurred in 1939 following the Great Depression

and in 1970 following the War on Poverty , both of which induced increases in private

sector giving. Thus, upon further inspection, Figure 14 can be explained by the model of

crowding out. As the model predicts, the marginal cuts of 1982's did not induce a

crowding in of private charity. However, beginning in 1989, as public spending

increased sharply, a clear picture of crowding out is again evident.

Figure 15 shows a graph for the entire period examined, 1929-1991. From the

graph you can easily identify the three periods of concern: The New Deal era following

the Great Depression, the Great Society spending of the late 1960's and early 1970's, and

the Reagan cuts of the 1980's. From Figure 15 and the previous graphs, several

preliminary inferences can be made. First, as Roberts argues, private charity does not

appear to respond to marginal changes in public expenditures.21 The relatively small

Reagan cuts the 1980's did not appear elicit a response from the private sector. Second,

large changes in public spending did appear to elicit changes in private charity. The

sharp reductions in spending following the Great Depression show clear signs of private

charity crowding back in. Similarly, the large increases in spending of the Great Society

and the sharp increase in spending of the late 1980's both show clear signs of crowding

out. As the data becomes available, it will be interesting to see if this most recent pattern

of crowding out continues.

Figure 16 shows private contributions as a percent of total contributions for the

entire period 1930-1991. In 1930, private contributions constituted just under 70% of

Page 25: PRIVATE AND PUBLIC SECTOR EXPENDITURES ON SOCIAL …social welfare and government expenditures on social welfare for the years 1929-1991. In particular, I examine the extent to which

69

Figure 16Private Contributions as a Percent of Total Contributions 1930-1991

total contributions. However, as government expenditures increase during the Great

Depression, private contributions fell to just under 4% of total contributions by 1935.

These results are similar to those obtained by Roberts shown in Figure 9. Figure 2.8,

also

shows how private contributions crowded back in to the market for charity as

government expenditures decreased following the Great Depression. Private

contributions rose to 40% of total contributions following the reductions in the New

Deal

social welfare spending. However, the percentage of private contributions begins to fall

again in the mid 1950's and continues until the late 1970's, where the ratio has remained

under 10%. Note that there are two effects working to reduce private contributions share

Page 26: PRIVATE AND PUBLIC SECTOR EXPENDITURES ON SOCIAL …social welfare and government expenditures on social welfare for the years 1929-1991. In particular, I examine the extent to which

70

of total contributions. First there is the decrease in private charitable contributions.

Second, there is the increase in government expenditures. The theory hypothesized here

is that increased government expenditures act to reduce private contributions. It should

be noted however, that the magnitude of the government expenditures tends to be of

much greater size than those of the private sector.

Regressions

This section provides an econometric analysis of the theoretical model developed

earlier and shown graphically above. Specifically, in this section, I examine the model

of simple crowd-out using ordinary least squares regressions. In the simple crowd out

model, I examine the interaction between total government expenditures on social

welfare, denoted TG and private voluntary contributions. Recall that TG is defined as the

sum of state, local and federal expenditures. In the next chapter, the model of joint

crowd-out is examined which separates the effects of state and local expenditures TS and

federal expenditures TF on private charitable contributions and the subsequent feed back

effects.

Dependent Variables

The dependent variable in the simple crowd-out model is the aggregate amount of

private charitable contributions directed toward social welfare purposes. This is

measured using the human services segment of charitable contributions from Giving

USA.

Independent Variables

Page 27: PRIVATE AND PUBLIC SECTOR EXPENDITURES ON SOCIAL …social welfare and government expenditures on social welfare for the years 1929-1991. In particular, I examine the extent to which

22 Median family income produces both a higher t-statistic and adjusted R2 thanmeasures of aggregate income.

23 The assertion by Bergstrom et. al. that greater income inequality leads to moreprivate charitable contributions will be examined in more detail below.

71

The independent variable of foremost concern in the simple crowd-out model is

public expenditures on social welfare. This is measured by the Public Aid expenditures

by state, local and the federal government. In addition to public expenditures, there are

other factors that are hypothesized to affect the level of charitable contributions.

If charitable contributions to the poor are a normal good, than the greater the

income, the more will be given. Thus, income is expected to have a positive effect on

charitable contributions. The measure of income used in this study is median family

income. Median family income appears to capture the changes in average giving better

than aggregate measures of income.22

Because the simple crowd-out model is a model of inter-dependent utility, it

requires some measure of �need� or well being of the poor. Three measures of well

being are used in the regression equations The first is the percentage of the population

below the poverty level (PBPL). It is expected that the higher the percentage of the

population below the poverty level, the greater the giving. The next two variables used

attempt to capture some measure of wage inequality. Bergstrom, Blume and Varian

(1986) show that greater inequality of wages should lead to more charitable

contributions.23 Thus, to test this hypothesis I use the standard deviation of wages of as

an alternative measure of well being. The standard deviation of wages is used to

measure the spread or inequality of wages. The third measure used, again attempts to

Page 28: PRIVATE AND PUBLIC SECTOR EXPENDITURES ON SOCIAL …social welfare and government expenditures on social welfare for the years 1929-1991. In particular, I examine the extent to which

24 A reduction in income will cause a reduction in charitable contributions ifcharitable contributions are viewed as a normal good by contributing agents.

25 See Clotfelter (1985) p.56 for a discussion on the merits of a price variable.

72

capture the inequality of wages. In this case, the difference in weekly earnings between

those at the ninetieth and those at the tenth percentile is used.

The price of giving is also expected to affect the level of giving. Because

charitable contributions are tax deductible, the cost of giving is usually measured using

tax rates. However, there are opposing effects. Higher marginal tax rates reduce the cost

of giving, thereby inducing more giving. But higher marginal tax rates also reduce

disposable income, thereby reducing giving.24 For the study at hand, the aggregate nature

of the data precludes the use of an accurate measure of the cost of giving. Additionally,

Clotfelter (1985) has shown that in previous empirical studies, �[charitable]

contributions are generally insensitive to variations in tax rates� and �that any price

effect of giving was bound to be small.� Thus, the absence of a price variable, is not

expected to create any problems.25

Finally, a vector X of other general population characteristics is also expected to

exert an influence on charitable giving. These include median age, age squared, median

education and the percentage of the population over the age of sixty-five. A population

variable is also included to extract any affects of an upward time trend.

The regression equation for the simple crowd-out model is specified as follows:

(13) PVTt ' β0 % β1PUBt % β2Incomet % β3PBPLt % β4Xt % ut

The regression results for the above model are shown in Table 3.

Page 29: PRIVATE AND PUBLIC SECTOR EXPENDITURES ON SOCIAL …social welfare and government expenditures on social welfare for the years 1929-1991. In particular, I examine the extent to which

73

Regression Results (Simple Crowd-Out Model)

Table 6 shows the estimated coefficients resulting from ordinary least squares

regression of equation 13. The equation is estimated using the double log form, thus

allowing the estimated coefficients to be interpreted as elasticities. T-statistics are shown

in parentheses. Three variants of equation 13 are run using the three measures of need

mentioned above. From Table 6, it is clear that most of the variables have the predicted

sign and are generally statistically significant.

Consider first the primary variable of concern, public expenditures on social

welfare. For the first equation, the coefficient on public expenditures is negative and

statistically significant at the .05% level. Converting the estimated elasticity to a dollar

crowd-out parameter allows for a more direct comparison with previous studies. The

estimated elasticity is converted at mean expenditures to yield a crowd-out parameter of

$.045. That is, a one dollar increase in public expenditures reduces or crowds out private

charitable contributions by almost 5 cents. Note however that the two equations using

measures of inequality both produce higher coefficients. Converting these to crowd-out

parameters yields $.093 and $.06 for the equations using the standard deviation of wages

and the 90-10 differential respectively.

Table 6

Simple Crowd-Out Model Regression Coefficients

Constant Public Income Pov/Ineq. Over 65 Pop. Age R2

-299.017(-6.166)

-.426(-4.31)

2.548(3.274)

.865(2.282)

-15.289(-5.526)

15.363(5.605)

3.199(4.348)

.869

Page 30: PRIVATE AND PUBLIC SECTOR EXPENDITURES ON SOCIAL …social welfare and government expenditures on social welfare for the years 1929-1991. In particular, I examine the extent to which

26 See Chapter I, Table 2 for a description of the source and type of data used therespective studies.

74

-467.535(-5.94)

-.885(-5.981)

1.288(3.758)

-2.42(-2.479)

-22.652(-5.87)

26.013(6.164)

5.516(4.918)

.85

-299.639(-4.792)

-.566(-5.218)

.837(2.444)

.290(.546)

-15.451(-4.492)

17.062(5.105)

3.216(3.358)

.81

The results shown in Table 6 are similar to those obtained by others using similar

aggregate data, including Reece (1979), Amos (1982), and Lindsey and Steinberg (1990).

For example, both Reece and Amos use measures of public expenditures nearly identical

to those used in this study. While Reece�s measure of private charity is more refined,

Amos uses an aggregate measure similar to that used in this paper. Although the results

obtained here are similar to the studies mentioned above, they are however considerably

less than those obtained by Abrams and Schmitz (1978, 1984), Pacque (1982), and

Schiff (1985, 1990) all of whom obtain results in the 30 cent range. The differences in

the resulting crowd-out parameters may be due to the differences in data sets used

between the two sets of studies. Both pairs of studies by Abrams and Schmitz and Schiff

analyze expenditures to social welfare using more refined measures of private and

public expenditures broken down by state and income.26

Another study of note is Kingma (1984) who obtains a crowd-out measure of

approximately fifteen cents. These results are for contributions to public radio which, it

could be argued, may not be motivated by the same factors that motivate contributions to

social welfare. In addition, Kingma uses a unique data set in which public and private

Page 31: PRIVATE AND PUBLIC SECTOR EXPENDITURES ON SOCIAL …social welfare and government expenditures on social welfare for the years 1929-1991. In particular, I examine the extent to which

27 An income elasticity of one generally separates income inelastic necessitiesfrom income elastic luxury goods. The further from one the income elasticities gets, themore a good is considered a luxury good.

75

expenditures are nearly perfect substitutes, with private expenditures measured on an

individual level. Thus, the results of this study would be expected to differ from those of

Kingma.

The next estimated elasticity of concern is income. While all three regression

equations produced positive income elasticities, the equation using the percent of the

population below the poverty level produced the highest elasticity of 2.584, whereas the

equations using the standard deviation and the 90-10 differential produce elasticities of

1.288 and .837 respectively. Recall that a positive income elasticity indicates that

charitable contributions are a normal good, while an income elasticity greater than one

indicates that charitable contributions are fairly sensitive to changes in income

suggesting that they considered are a luxury good.27

The demand or need for charity is examined next. The coefficient of regression

one using the percent of the population below the poverty level produced a positive and

statistically significant coefficient, which is consistent with the inter-dependant utility

model and with most previous empirical studies. The regression using the standard

deviation of wages produced a negative coefficient which is the opposite of what you

would expect with the inter-dependent utility model. While the regression using the 90th

- 10th percentile wage differential produces a positive coefficient which is consistent

with the theory of inter-dependent utility and with the empirical analysis of Hochman

and Rodgers (1973), the estimated coefficient is statistically insignificant.

Page 32: PRIVATE AND PUBLIC SECTOR EXPENDITURES ON SOCIAL …social welfare and government expenditures on social welfare for the years 1929-1991. In particular, I examine the extent to which

76

The remaining variables produced the expected coefficients and are all

statistically significant. Charitable contributions are expected to increase with age up to

the critical age of retirement of 65, after which charitable contributions are expected to

decline. As expected, age and age squared produced positive and negative coefficients

respectively. Likewise, the coefficient for the variable measuring the affect of the

percent of the population over the age of 65 was negative. Finally, the estimated

coefficient for total population was effective in extracting the positive time trend.

Page 33: PRIVATE AND PUBLIC SECTOR EXPENDITURES ON SOCIAL …social welfare and government expenditures on social welfare for the years 1929-1991. In particular, I examine the extent to which

77

Figure 17Indexed Weekly Wages 1963-1991

(1964=1)

Giving and the Distribution of Income

In this section, I examine an issue concerning charitable contributions and the

distribution of income. Specifically, I examine how giving changed as the distribution of

income has changed. This analysis is a direct extension of Bergstrom, Blume and

Varian�s seminal 1986 paper on public goods. More precisely, I examine Theorem Five

Page 34: PRIVATE AND PUBLIC SECTOR EXPENDITURES ON SOCIAL …social welfare and government expenditures on social welfare for the years 1929-1991. In particular, I examine the extent to which

28 Bergstrom, Blume and Varian (1986) pg. 43.

78

Figure 19Charitable Giving and Wage Inequality 1963-1991

of Bergstrom et al which hypothesizes that, �as an economy evolves towards a more

equal distribution of income, we can expect the amount of public goods that would be

provided voluntarily to diminish.�28 The policy implications of this hypothesis are clear.

As voluntary contributions to the poor diminish, government contributions to the poor

becomes more important to increasing the well being of the poor. Conversely, if the

inverse of the above hypothesis is true, then one can conclude �that as an economy

Page 35: PRIVATE AND PUBLIC SECTOR EXPENDITURES ON SOCIAL …social welfare and government expenditures on social welfare for the years 1929-1991. In particular, I examine the extent to which

79

moves toward a more unequal distribution of income, public good provision provided

voluntarily should increase.�

I begin first with an examination of income inequality in the U.S. and then

investigate the relationship between income inequality and private sector charitable

giving. Income inequality is examined using Current Population Survey data for the

years 1963-1992. In particular, I examine income for those earning at the ninetieth,

fiftieth (i.e., median) and tenth percentiles. The CPS income data used in this study

consists of men who worked full time (at least thirty five hours a week for at least forty

weeks per year) who were not self employed, in the military or in group quarters.

Figure 17 shows the natural log of weekly wages indexed to one for the years

1963-1964. As can be seen from Figure 17, wages rose for all three groups from 1963

until the early seventies. Wage earners at the 10th percentile began to fall precipitously,

while wages for those at the 90th percentile rose and those earning at the median

remained flat.

The rising inequality of wages has been and remains the subject of a considerable

Page 36: PRIVATE AND PUBLIC SECTOR EXPENDITURES ON SOCIAL …social welfare and government expenditures on social welfare for the years 1929-1991. In particular, I examine the extent to which

29 See for example Juhn, Murphy and Pierce (1993) and Finis Welch (1993a,1993b).

30 Herrnstein and Murray provide an interesting albeit controversialinterpretation of the ramifications of rising inequality in their 1994 best seller The BellCurve.

80

Figure 18Measures of Wage Inequality 1963-1991

amount of research.29 In addition, the rising inequality of wages has also provoked a

great deal of concern over the socio-political ramifications of the rising inequality.30

What has not been examined is the effect of wage inequality on private charitable

Page 37: PRIVATE AND PUBLIC SECTOR EXPENDITURES ON SOCIAL …social welfare and government expenditures on social welfare for the years 1929-1991. In particular, I examine the extent to which

31 The pattern of giving among different income groups also has significanttheoretical as well as policy implications, but is not examined in the present research.This issue has been examined by among others Boskin and Feldstein (1977), Reece andZieschang (1985), Schiff (1985), Brown (1987), Feenberg (1988), and Choe and Jeong(1993).

81

contributions.

Figure 18 shows two measures of wage inequality in the U.S., the standard

deviation of wages and the difference between the wages at the 90th and 10th percentiles.

Figure 18 clearly shows a rising inequality in weekly wage over the last thirty years.

From Figure 18 you can also see that both these measure of inequality over the period

from 1963-1992 are highly correlated.

Figures 17 and 18 indicate that wages have become more disparate over the last

thirty years. From the proposition in Theorem Five by Bergstrom et al, it follows that

charitable contributions should be increasing as wage inequality increases.31

To examine this proposition, Figure 19 shows private charitable contributions to

social welfare and the standard deviation of weekly wages for the years 1963-1991. As

can be seen, private charitable contributions to social welfare appear to be highly

correlated with the rising inequality of wages. That is, charitable contributions appear to

be increasing and decreasing as inequality has increased and decreased, thus conforming

to Bergstrom Blume and Varian�s Theorem Five.

Table 7 provides a summary of the relationship between wage inequality and

charitable contributions using several different measures of correlation including

Page 38: PRIVATE AND PUBLIC SECTOR EXPENDITURES ON SOCIAL …social welfare and government expenditures on social welfare for the years 1929-1991. In particular, I examine the extent to which

32 Pearson�s product moment is the measure most commonly used whencalculating correlation coefficients. Pearson�s product reflects the closeness of fitbetween an ordinary least squares regression line and the data. In the simple twovariable case, the R2 coefficient of determination of OLS regression is the square of thePearson coefficient. The Pearson Product Moment for two variables x and y iscalculated as follows: r' j (xi&x)(yi&y)

j (xi&x)2 j (yi&y)2

33 Spearman�s rank provides a measure of correlation less resistant to outliersthan Pearson�s measure. The Spearman correlation is calculated in the same way as thePearson correlation except that the variables are converted to ranks from lowest tohighest.

34 Kendall�s tau like Spearman�s is a rank correlation used for small samples. For a discussion of the calculations used to derive Kendall�s tau and references see theSTATA reference manual volume Three page 173.

83

Pearson�s Product Moment32, Spearman�s Rank33 and Kendall�s Tau.34

Inspection of Table 7, shows that Pearson�s Product Moment, the most commonly used

measure of correlation, shows the highest degree of correlation, while Kendall�s Tau,

which is used for small samples, produces the lowest correlation coefficient.

Spearman�s rank correlation falls between the Pearson and Kendall measure of

correlation.

Interestingly, although there is a clear positive correlation between wage

inequality and charitable contributions, including the standard deviation of wages in

equation (13), the equation used to estimate charitable contributions, produces a negative

Table 7

The Correlation Between Wage Inequality and Charitable Contributions

Pearson�s Product Moment Spearman�s Rank Kendall�s Tau (τ)

.69 .5488 .4023

Page 39: PRIVATE AND PUBLIC SECTOR EXPENDITURES ON SOCIAL …social welfare and government expenditures on social welfare for the years 1929-1991. In particular, I examine the extent to which

35 Recall from the discussion of section XIII showing the regression results andTable 3, that including the standard deviation of wages produced a negative coefficientwhile including the difference between the 90th and 10th percentile of wage earnersproduces a positive, but statistically insignificant, coefficient.

85

p=.0017 p=.009

coefficient, indicating that greater inequality reduces private charitable contributions.35

Testing the Model

Examining the link between private voluntary contributions and public

expenditures to social welfare naturally raises the question of causality. That is, does

government spending �cause� a reduction in private contributions? The theoretical

specification of the public goods model postulates the direction of causality as going

from public expenditures to private expenditures. The regression results (i.e., the

statistical specification of the model) thus far support the negative relationship between

these two variables. Further statistical analysis provides an opportunity to derive

additional measures of causality. These measures, however, are not without their

limitations. To begin with, determining whether one event causes another is difficult

from a theoretical perspective. That is, how does one determine what causes a person to

act in a specific manner (e.g., contributing to the poor). In addition, when testing

causality one must keep in mind the Latin dictum, �post hoc, ergo proctor hoc.� That is,

the fact that X precedes Y does not mean that X causes Y. Statistical analysis of

variables examines the correlation and precedence of one variable relative to another.

Page 40: PRIVATE AND PUBLIC SECTOR EXPENDITURES ON SOCIAL …social welfare and government expenditures on social welfare for the years 1929-1991. In particular, I examine the extent to which

36 C.W.J. Granger (1969).

37 G.S. Maddala (1988) and J. Kmenta (1986).

38 G.G. Judge et al.(1985).

88

Thus, what can only be tested and subsequently ascertained is the precedence of X to Y

rather than the actual causality as it is normally understood. Although the term

�causality� is often seen as misleading, it has nevertheless remained a fixture in the

econometric literature and is used throughout this study with the proviso that its more

accurate definition is understood.

The first test for causality used is that developed by Granger.36 Specifically,

given two time series Y and X, Granger examines whether current values of Y can be

better explained by current and past values of X and Y, than by past values of Y alone.

In effect, what Granger attempts to distinguish between is the time trend effect of Y and

the relation between Y and X. Hence, it is maintained the series Xt fails to Granger

Cause Yt if, in a regression of Yt on lagged Y�s and lagged X�s, the coefficients of the

lagged X�s are zero. The length of the lag is not determined according to statistical

doctrine but rather is determined according to the theoretical specification of the model.37

In the context of public and private expenditures to social welfare, the regression

equation is specified as follows:

(14) lnPVTt'jk

i'1αilnPVTt&i%j

k

i'1βilnPUBt&i%Ui

Thus, if past and present public expenditures help to improve the forecast of private

expenditures, then public expenditures are said to cause in, the Granger sense, private

expenditures.38

Page 41: PRIVATE AND PUBLIC SECTOR EXPENDITURES ON SOCIAL …social welfare and government expenditures on social welfare for the years 1929-1991. In particular, I examine the extent to which

89

The regression results of the direct Granger causality test are shown in Table 8.

A number of interesting observations can be made from the results in Table 8. To begin

with, the coefficients on the lagged public expenditures are generally very small and

statistically insignificant. More interestingly, although the lagged public expenditures

generally exert little influence, the coefficients on the one period lagged public

expenditures exerts the smallest effect on private expenditures, while the fifth period

lagged public expenditures exert the largest effect. Thus, expectations of future

government expenditures based on past expenditures do not appear to affect the level of

private contributions.

Although lagged public expenditures do not exert a significant effect on private

contributions, lagged private contributions appear to exert an even smaller effect. Again,

the coefficients are generally small and not statistically significant. Thus, past private

contributions do not appear to be a good predictor of present private contributions. The

overall results of the direct Granger causality test indicate that public expenditures fail to

Granger cause private expenditures.

While the public goods model used in this research postulates the direction of

causality as going from public expenditures to private contributions, examining the

causality running in the opposite direction ensures that the model is not mis-specified.

That is, do changes in private contributions �cause� changes in public expenditures?

The Granger equation for the reverse regression equation is specified as follows:

(15) lnPUBt'jk

i'1αilnPUBt&i%j

k

i'1βilnPVTt&i%Ui

The results of the reverse Granger regressions are shown in Table 9. Again, the

Page 42: PRIVATE AND PUBLIC SECTOR EXPENDITURES ON SOCIAL …social welfare and government expenditures on social welfare for the years 1929-1991. In particular, I examine the extent to which

39 C.A. Sims (1972).

40 Maddala (1988).

90

regression coefficients are generally not statistically significant. That is, neither past

public expenditures nor past private contributions are accurate predictors current public

expenditures. Thus, the results of the reverse Granger causality indicate that private

expenditures do not �cause� changes in public expenditures in a Granger sense.

An alternative test used to examine causality is that developed by Sims.39 For the

Sims test of causality, you begin by examining the parameter coefficients on a regression

of private contributions on lagged, current and future values of public expenditures.

Based on the regression results, it is said that public expenditures fail to �cause� private

contributions if in a regression of private contributions on lagged, current and future

public expenditures, the latter coefficients are zero.40 What the Sims causality test

attempts to evaluate is whether predictions of private contributions from current and past

values of public contributions would be improved if future values of public expenditures

were included. The direct Sims regression equation is specified as follows:

(16) lnPVT'α0%jn

j'&kβjlnPUBt&j%ut

The results of the direct Sims causality test, shown in Table 10, are significantly more

favorable to the public goods model than the Granger test results. The coefficients on

the third, fourth and fifth period future public expenditures are all negative, and

statistically significant. That is, knowledge of future government expenditures improves

predictions of future private charitable contributions. Additionally, the inclusion of

future public expenditures increased the significance of past public expenditures. The

Page 43: PRIVATE AND PUBLIC SECTOR EXPENDITURES ON SOCIAL …social welfare and government expenditures on social welfare for the years 1929-1991. In particular, I examine the extent to which

91

Sims Causality test appear to conform with the theory of rational expectations, which

assumes individuals use all available information in forming expectations. That is,

rational agent will not be solely backward looking in forming expectations, but will also

base expectations on current policies that may affect future government expenditures.

Thus, from the results of the Sims test, one can conclude that public expenditures do not

fail to cause private contributions.

Again, the reverse regression is run to test the direction of causality. The reverse

regression equation is specified as follows:

(17) lnPUB'α0%jn

j'&kβjlnPVTt&j%ut

The results of the reverse Sims causality test are shown in Table 11. As can be seen in

Table 11, the results of the reverse Sims test are generally not statistically significant.

Again, as with the reverse Granger test, we can conclude that private contributions do

not cause public expenditures on social welfare.

The results of the Granger and Sims causality tests are mixed. Although the

Granger test did not indicate a causal link between public expenditures and private

contributions, the Sims test did show that changes in future public expenditures

improved the predictions of private contributions.

Again, however, because of the data limitations the results of the regression

analysis should be taken with caution. The aggregate nature of the data and the

considerable difference in magnitude between the two sources of data create difficulties

in measuring the relationship and the causality between public expenditures and private

voluntary contributions to social welfare.

Page 44: PRIVATE AND PUBLIC SECTOR EXPENDITURES ON SOCIAL …social welfare and government expenditures on social welfare for the years 1929-1991. In particular, I examine the extent to which

92

A Comparison of Altruism and Egoism

Recall that in the impure public goods model, there are both altruistic and

egoistic motivates that lead the non-poor toward philanthropy. However, it is altruism

that is generally considered the primary motivating factor in giving to the poor. In this

section I examine the relationship between private charitable contributions and

government expenditures when the benefits are more direct to the benefactor. That is

when egoism dominates altruism. In particular, I examine the relationship between

private charitable contributions to the arts and government expenditures in the form of

expenditures on the National Endowment for the Arts. The source of the data for private

charitable contributions to the arts were obtained from Giving USA, while the data on

public expenditures was obtained from the National Endowment for the Arts. Figure 20

shows a graph of public versus private expenditures on the arts (in billions of 1991

dollars) since funding began for the NEA in 1966.

Page 45: PRIVATE AND PUBLIC SECTOR EXPENDITURES ON SOCIAL …social welfare and government expenditures on social welfare for the years 1929-1991. In particular, I examine the extent to which

93

Figure 20Private Contributions vs NEA Expenditures 1966-1993

As can be seen from Figure 20, public and private expenditures rose together

until 1979. In 1979 and 1980 NEA expenditures began a precipitous fall, while private

contributions continued to rise. Subsequently, in what may have been a response by the

private sector to the initial decrease in funding by the NEA , private contributions

increased dramatically in 1982 than fell back to their 1981 level in 1983. From 1984

onward private contributions continued to rise as NEA expenditures continued to fall.

As noted above, the model of impure altruism predicts that the more charitable giving

takes on an element of a private good, the less crowding out will occur. Thus, if

Page 46: PRIVATE AND PUBLIC SECTOR EXPENDITURES ON SOCIAL …social welfare and government expenditures on social welfare for the years 1929-1991. In particular, I examine the extent to which

94

charitable contributions to the arts are motivated by egoism, then we should not observe

a significant amount of crowding out.

From Figure 20 you cannot discern any clear relationship between private and

public expenditures to the arts. From 1966 to 1979 public and private expenditures

appear to move complementary, as both increase. Then, from 1980 to 1983, private

contributions fall, while public expenditures continue to rise until 1982, then fall 1983

and

then begin to rise again. From 1983 on, private contributions fall while public

expenditures rise. Private and public expenditures appear to behave as substitutes over

this period. Note however that although private contributions maintained an upward

trend throughout the entire period, the rate of growth increased after 1982.

Private and public expenditures to the arts can be examined closer using the same

regression equation that was used to examine private and public expenditures to social

welfare. Substituting private contributions to the arts into the left hand side of Equation

7 and NEA expenditures on the right hand side produces the following equation:

(18) PVTt ' β0 % β1NEAt % β2Incomet % β3PBPLt % β4Xt % ut

The estimated coefficients for equation 2.9 are shown in Table 12. All equations are run

in log-log form. The results of the regressions shown in Table 12 are shown for three

income levels. Note first that the regression coefficient on NEA expenditures is positive

for all three income levels. In addition, none of the estimated coefficients are

statistically significant. The income coefficient is positive for wage earners at the

ninetieth and fiftieth income percentile, but negative for those at the tenth percentile.

Page 47: PRIVATE AND PUBLIC SECTOR EXPENDITURES ON SOCIAL …social welfare and government expenditures on social welfare for the years 1929-1991. In particular, I examine the extent to which

95

Furthermore, only one of the income coefficients is statistically significant. The

coefficient on the percent of the population below the poverty level is positive for wage

earners at the ninetieth and fiftieth income percentile, but negative for those at the tenth

percentile. Again none of the coefficients are statistically significant. In general then,

there does not appear to be a discernable relationship between private contributions to

the arts and NEA expenditures for the period examined.

Table 12

Private vs Public Expenditures to the Arts Regression Coefficients

Constant NEA Income Poverty Over 65 Pop Age R2

-198.613(1.729)

.165(1.456)

1.174(1.279)

.293(.77)

16.341(2.409)

-8.237(-1.214)

-4.451(-2.109)

.96

172.425(1.343)

.098(1.02)

1.126(.721)

.233(.498)

17.01(2.167)

-5.53(-.774)

-4.656(-1.764)

.957

95.735(1.02)

.041(.483)

-.751(-.92)

-.192(-.565)

14.375(2.149)

.691(.142)

-3.604(-1.804)

.958

The preceding analysis demonstrates that giving to the poor is more amenable to

empirical analysis using the public goods model than giving to the arts. This does not

however imply that giving to the arts does not fit the model theoretically, but rather that

the confounding affects of altruism and egoism may be less evident in giving to the poor

than giving to the arts. That is, the egoistic nature of private contributions to the arts

results in contributions to the arts occurring independently of public expenditures.

Consequently, the correlation between private voluntary contributions to the arts and

public expenditures appears to be quite low and not statistically significant.

Page 48: PRIVATE AND PUBLIC SECTOR EXPENDITURES ON SOCIAL …social welfare and government expenditures on social welfare for the years 1929-1991. In particular, I examine the extent to which

41 Recall that the dollar for dollar crowding out model of Warr and Roberts is aspecial case of the public goods model.

42 See for example Charles Murray (1984), Herrnstein and Murray (1994) andMarvin Olasky (1992) for a discussion of this point.

96

Conclusion

The simple crowd-out model using aggregate data appears to refute the results of

previous empirical analysis of crowding out. That is, the current research indicates that a

one dollar increase in government social welfare expenditures appear to result in a

reduction of approximately 5¢ in private charitable donations to social welfare rather

than the 30¢ that has been found in other studies. Thus, although the present analysis is

consistent with the partial crowd-out models, including the pure public goods model of

Bergstrom, Blume and Varian, the results of this study also fit impurely altruistic models

of Andreoni and Steinberg. The weak result of the poverty variable is especially

consistent with the impurely altruistic model. Conversely, the results of this study do not

lend support to the dollar for dollar crowd-out model of Warr and Roberts.41

Ignoring the efficiency issues, (i.e., whether the private sector is more efficient

than the public sector in allocating funds to the poor or vice versa) the policy

implications are quite clear. Cuts in government expenditures on social welfare reduce

the total (i.e., private and public) level of expenditures on social welfare programs. The

assumption, by those calling for reduced expenditures on social welfare42, that the

private sector will adequately compensate for government reductions is not borne out by

this research.