portuese (2009)

Upload: rtoes

Post on 14-Apr-2018

215 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 7/30/2019 Portuese (2009)

    1/61Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1517424

    1

    Law and Economics of the

    European Multilingualism

    Aurlien Portuese

  • 7/30/2019 Portuese (2009)

    2/61Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1517424

    2

    Content

    Abstract...p.5

    Introduction........p.6

    I. Law of Languages in The European Union......p.6

    II. Economics of Languages in The European Union............p.7

    Part A: Cost-Benefits Analysis of the European Multilingualism......p.8

    I. Institutional and Policy Cost.........p.9a. Linguistic Cost in TheEU Institutions......p.9b. Language Teaching Cost........p.10

    II. Production Cost.....p.11a. Overview of the EU Language Law on Labeling...p.11b. Economic Analysis of the EU Language Law on Labeling.p.12c. Cost of the EU Language Law on Labeling.....p.14

    III.Competitive Cost...p.14a. Language Barriers to Entry...p.14b. Cross-linguistic Market Entry Decision...p.17

    . The Linguistic-based Bias.......p.17. Language Distance as Psychic Distance.....p.17

    c. Cost-Benefits Analysis for Cross-linguistic Market Entry DecisionIn a Nutshell...p.20

    IV.Contractual Cost....p.21a. The Multiplying Effect of Language Barriers on Transaction Costs...p.21b. Language Barriers as The Major Impediment to EU Cross-border Contracts................p.22c. An Economic Analysis of Multilingual Contracts..p.22

    V. Innovative Cost......p.23

    VI.Immobility Cost.p.26a. Language Barriers to EU Mobility.....p.26b. Languages in The Workplace.....p.27c. Discrimination Economics and Language Economics......p.28d. The Cost of The Non-EU Labour Market..p.28

    VII. Criminal Costp.29

  • 7/30/2019 Portuese (2009)

    3/61Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1517424

    3

    VIII. Political Cost.p.30

    IX.Benefits.....p.31

    X. Preliminary Conclusions...p.32

    Part B: Linguistic Coase Theorem.p.33

    I. From Coase Theorem to Linguistic Coase Theorem.......p.34a. Overview of The Coase Theorem......p.35b. Overview of The Political Coase Theorem......p.36c.

    Linguistic Coase Theorem......p.36

    II. Normativity of The Linguistic Coase Theorem..p.37

    III.Predictive Power of the Linguistic Coase Theorem ....p.39a. The Externalities of theCurrent Multilingualism..p.39b. Pareto-Optimality Applied to a Lingua Francap.39c. The OptimalLingua Franca in The Real World...p.40d. Literature Concerning The Choice of EU Lingua Franca...p.42e. The Reciprocal Nature of The Lingua Franca Problem...p.44

    . Initial Entitlement of Rights on The UK.....p.45

    . Initial Entitlement of Rights on The Continental Europe....p.45

    IV.The Challenges of The XXIst Century Europe: Competitiveness And Democracy....p.48

    Table of Cases..p.49

    Bibliography.....p.50

  • 7/30/2019 Portuese (2009)

    4/61

    4

    July, The 28th of 2009

    Hamburg.

  • 7/30/2019 Portuese (2009)

    5/61

    5

    Abstract

    The economics of language applied to multilingualism in the European Union (EU) has

    only recently come to the fore. Languages economics and Law and Economics disciplines both

    emerged in the 1960s. However, no study has, hitherto, linked these disciplines. This paper

    intends to fill that void.

    Language barriers are the last major remaining barriers for the EUs 'single' market. The

    lack of coordination of multilingualism in the EU stems from a taboo crystallized by a dilemma

    between economic efficiency and linguistic diversityi.e., the maximization of wealth versus the

    maximization of utility. The EU Member States (MSs) do not hasten to coordinate their language

    policies at the EU level inasmuch as they overestimate the benefits of the current EU

    multilingualism while drastically underestimating its costs. Coordination shall will only occur

    when MSs evaluate the costs and benefits of the current EU multilingualism. This will uncover

    the aforementioned dilemma, that will only be resolved when both Law and Economics are

    applied. In pursuing this objective a Linguistic Coase Theorem adapted from the work of

    Parisi and the Nobel Prize winner, Ronald Coase is elaborated .

    Having outlined the basic notions deriving from the EU Law of Languages and the

    Economics of Languages (Introduction), the paper scrutinizes the costs and benefits incurred by

    the current non-coordinated EU multilingualism (Part I). Subsequently, a 'Linguistic Coase

    Theorem' is elaborated in order to reach a Pareto-optimal outcome, thereby solving the dilemma

    both economic efficiency and the linguistic diversity being enhanced (Part II).

  • 7/30/2019 Portuese (2009)

    6/61

    6

    Introduction

    I. Law of Languages in the European Union

    The EU law of languages is governed unanimously1. The official languages of the EU

    institutions are the official languages of the MSs, each linguistic version of EU law being "equally

    authentic"2. Linguistic rights are enshrined for correspondence with the European Institutions and

    its Bodies3. Cultural/linguistic diversity4 is promoted through the actions of the MSs.

    In secondary EU law, Article 1 of the Council Regulation 1/58 of 1958 5 lays down the

    principle of equal treatment of all official languages of the MS. Correlating the Article 314 in

    primary law, Regulation 1/58 has established linguistic equality between the official languages of

    the MS, although "a principle of general linguistic equality is not explicit"(Creech 2005:14). Recently, the

    Council recognized that the Council is "attached to the fundamental principle of equality of the official

    languages of the EU as enshrined in the Council Regulation N16. The European Court of Justice (ECJ),

    ambiguously, expressed its commitment to the linguistic equality principle, when giving

    approvals to the unequal treatment of some languages8 (Creech 2005:32-38)7. In reality, despite a

    formal principle of equal treatment, the EU law of languages de facto hierarchizes languages

    (Creech 2005:44) as follows:

    1. English

    2. French

    3. German

    4. Spanish, Italian

    5. Bulgarian, Czech, Danish, Dutch, Estonian, Finnish Greek, Hungarian, Latvian,

    Lithuanian, Polish, Portuguese, Rumanian, Slovak, Slovenian and Swedish

    6. Maltese

    7. Irish

    8. Turkish and Luxemburgish

    9. Regional and Minority Languages (RM languages)

    II. Economics of Languages in the European Union

    1Article 217 of the Rome Treaty, Article 290 of the Nice Treaty2

    Article 248 of the Rome Treaty, Article 314 of the Nice Treaty.3

    Article 8d of the Amsterdam Treaty, Article 21 of the Nice Treaty4

    Article 149 of the Nice Treaty5

    Regulation 1/58, O.J. (1958) 017/385.6

    Reply to Written Question E4099/00 (2001) C23E/687 Case T-120/99 (2001) "Kik v. OHMI"with a dismissed appeal in the Case C-361/01 P (2003) "Kik v.OHMI"; Case C-42/97 (1999) "Parliament v. Council".

  • 7/30/2019 Portuese (2009)

    7/61

    7

    Through the embodiment of knowledge (Astley and Zammuto 1992:445; Hocevar 1975;

    Breton 1978), language is the prerequisite medium for the transmission of information. Any

    language is tied to information, and is priced by the market according to its actual/potential

    information value determined by the importance of its network of speakers, this determining its

    usefulness(Grin 2005:61).

    A language's objective value (price) is manifested by higher earnings for multilingual

    workers (Vaillancourt 1980; Grenier 1985; Vaillancourt 1991; Ginsburgh and Prieto-Rodriguez

    2006). Language is understood as a "hyper-collective"good (De Swaan 1993) being neither a rival

    nor an excludable good, its value increasing with its use. This flows from the existence of

    network externalities in languages. An individuals utility is an increasing function of the number of

    people with whom one can communicate(Church and King 1993:338) creating a positive externality

    towards a language, and inversely, a negative externality towards other languages, with the

    extreme consequence of a "linguicide"(Crystal 2000; Phillipson and Skutnabb-Kangas 1995).

    Languages are capitalized as human capital (Becker 1964; Grin and Vaillancourt 1997) since they

    encapsulate its three features i.e. "that is productive, costly to produce, and embodied in the person"

    (Chiswick 2008:4). Language skills reduce transaction costs by reducing informational costs.

    Although a speaker of a language has communicative interests in having a large linguistic

    community (Selten and Pool 1991:67), the inclusion of a new member in that community might

    reduce its human capital by the reduction of comparative advantage in the labour market.

    Speaking a lingua franca gives less 'monetary benefits' compared to its communicative benefits

    (Selten and Pool 1991:67) and becomes merely a requirement (Grin 2005:44; Ginsburgh and

    Prieto-Rodriguez 2006:13).

    Although not all languages have a market value, every language encapsulates an

    economic subjective value, since the use of each language delivers to its speakers a utility. The

    total value of a languages is constituted by "marketable" (objective) and "non marketable"

    (subjective) values (Grin 2005). Since economics is concerned with the maximization of utility as

    much as with the maximization of wealth, linguistic diversity and economic efficiency are sought

    whilst being mutually antagonistic.

    An optimal level of linguistic diversity has to be reached given its cost (Grin 2005:28;

    Grin 2002:28). The optimal level of linguistic diversity can encompass full linguistic diversity

    maximization of utilitiesif the transaction costs within a multilingual environment are reduced

    minimization of costs. Therefore, the reduction of transaction costs (costs of language barriers)

    within the EU multilingual economy is the cornerstone for solving the aforementioned dilemma

    involving linguistic diversity/economic efficiency.

    The "language game" theory elaborated by Wittgenstein (1953) emphasizes the utmost

    importance of reciprocity in the game played. Linguistic conventions must be reciprocally known.

    The payoffs of players are inter-dependent across linguistic communities while being

  • 7/30/2019 Portuese (2009)

    8/61

    8

    independent within a linguistic community (Selten and Pool 1991:68). The best strategy for a

    rational player in response to another players move to learn a specific language is to learn this

    same language, thereby maximizing her communicative benefits (Selten and Pool 1991:67) while

    minimizing the actual and probable information costs. Finally, a lingua francaemerges.

    Carr (1985) explains the rise of a lingua franca by comparing common language to a

    common currency, considering language as an information-carrier. However, the multiple

    purposes of languages, the language-specific investments, and the subjective value attached to

    linguistic diversity make the correlation hazardous (Grin 1994:32).

    Languages have a lock-in effect because language-acquisition requires language-specific

    investments as an additional knowledge. Because linguistic amnesia is unimaginable,

    "multilingualism is a viable strategy"(Laitin 1993:235). A rational actor will learn a new language if the

    expected returns of her current linguistic competence are smaller than the additional net

    communicative benefits expected from a new language additional communicative benefits

    minus learning costs (Selten and Pool 1991). The more the linguistic competences are constituted

    by 'important' languages (e.g. English), the more one is locked into her linguistic repertoire, and

    the more this equilibrium is stabilised (Gabszewicz et al. 2008:3). In the domain of Behavioural

    Law and Economics of Language, "stubborn beliefs" about language policies (Pool quoted by

    Grin,2004:192) and status quo bias regarding language choices are made in the context of bounded

    rationality(Luo and Shenkar,2006).

    If there are two-players in a non-coordinated linguistic game, each player being fluent

    only in the other players language, the equilibrium involves each player speaking her native

    language in a receptive bilingualism (Pool 1986:165). The outcome is efficient (integral inter-

    communications) but sub-optimal (Mackaay 2000:7; Pool 1986) with respect to the

    overinvestment of both players in becoming bilinguals (Church and King 2003:340). Where

    more than three official languages are involved, with the assumption of each player learning and

    becoming fluent in one foreign language, non-coordination upon language choices brings about

    non-integral intercommunication hence inefficiencies. A fortiori in the EU context, with 23

    official languages and non-10 coordinated linguistic games between rational players, inefficient

    outcomes are highly probable without a lingua franca.

    Part A: Cost-Benefits Analysis of the European Multilingualism

    Current EU multilingualism has never been subject to an analysis of the costs and

    benefits incurred in the EU economy. Language-planning can no longer "eschew this core issue"of

    cost-benefits analysis (Grin 1994:36) if rational decision making is sought. Obviously, the

    presence of languages in the EU is not a variable, but the (absence of) a EU lingua franca is a

    variable (a choice).

  • 7/30/2019 Portuese (2009)

    9/61

    9

    I. Institutional and Policy Cost

    a. Linguistic Cost in The EU institutions

    The EU started in 1958 with 4 official languages, and nowadays has 23 such languages.

    The institutional costs of managing the EU multilingualism represents "approximately 1.1 billion

    per year", tantamount to "2.5 per citizen peryear"8. New languages bring small benefits in terms of

    disafranchisment10. The number of pages translated increased 910 The addition of Irish costs

    13,000 per minute of debate in the European Parliament although none of the 6 Irish MEPs

    debated in Irish9.

    from 1700 pages in 1958 to 1,700,000 pages in 200710. EU multilingualism represents at least

    40% of the EU administrative cost (Haarman 1991:114).

    If the EU law is inconceivable without translation11and since translating means choosing

    (Caill 1967) EU multilingual law is in strictly legal terms [] inconceivable with it (Correia

    2003:38). Non-monetary costs delay and error costs have to be taken into consideration,

    although hard-data can hardly be gathered12. The problem of error cost is double: (i) error cost

    occurs by the process of translation due to the trade-off between transparency and faithful

    translation techniques which lead to the probability of errors; (ii)error cost occur due to the use

    in order to reduce translation costs of intermediary languages. The more 'pivot' languages are

    used for decreasing translation costs, the more error costs increase.

    EU multilingual law incurs litigation costs over its interpretation, with a difficult task

    delegated to the ECJ, which has adopted a supranational interpretative approach13. The ECJ

    must interpret contradictory linguistic versions, thereby creating uncertainty costs for EU

    citizens and enterprises.

    b. Language Teaching Cost

    8 Leonard Orban, Commissioner for Multilingualism, Interview of the 12th November 2008 forEurActiv.9

    Source: http://archives.tcm.ie/irishexaminer/2008/01/21/story53174.asp 11

    10DG Translations (2008). The hyperinflation in the number of translations creates necessarily

    problems of uniqueness of meanings (Koutsivitis 1988).11

    Hence the problems of the binding force of non-translated law (Bobek,2007)12

    The delay cost can include the loss of lives. See The Guardian, July the 28th of 2004, Available at :

    http://www.guardian.co.uk/business/2004/jul/28/politics.europeanunion13

    Case 80/76 (1997) "North Kerry Milk Products Ltd. V. Minister for Agriculture and Fisheries"; Case

    30/77 (1977) "Rgina v. Pierre Bouchereau"; Case 100/84 (1985) "Commission of the European

    Communities v. United Kingdom of Great Britain and Northern Ireland"; Case C-449/93 (1995)"Rockfon A/S v. Specialarbejderforbudet"; Case C-72/95 (1996) "Aannemersbedrijf P.K. Kraaijeveld

    BV e.a. v. gedeputeerde Staten van Zuid-Holland".

  • 7/30/2019 Portuese (2009)

    10/61

    10

    Overcoming language barriers within the EU 'single' market has led to the3 elaboration

    of EU programmes14 such as the Lifelong Learning Programme in 200615. Other educational

    programmes, not especially designed for language purposes, undoubtedly contribute to language

    learning and teachingsuch as the Erasmus programme.

    We found that the average number of hours of foreign language teaching in the EU-27

    is about 823 hours per year for primary and secondary educations16. The overall cost of language

    teaching was roughly 60 billions in 2005 (Lukacs 2007:8). In comparison, the US has no

    compulsory class for foreign languages. Only 8.6% of the students enrolled have followed

    foreign language courses (Furman et al. 2007). Not only does the US spends much less public

    money on language education, but the language education that is given delivers to the US a

    comparative advantage compared to the EU, since the foreign languages taught open markets

    located outside the American internal market, whilst language teaching in Europe is necessary in

    providing access to its own internal market.

    Regional and Minority (RM) languages have been denied EU legal status. This

    political/legal choice reinforced the attrition process and endangerment of the more than 600

    indigenous and non-indigenous languages spoken in the EU (Broeder et al. 2007:26-27). The EU

    intends to promote RM languages through public intervention encouraging the supply of goods

    and infrastructures in these languages, with a questionable low cost-effectiveness a policy-to-

    outcome path (Grin 2002b:79). Grin and Vaillancourt (1999), although recognizing that private

    demand is theprima conditio for the revitalization of RM languages, consider State intervention as

    necessary for reducing the negative network externalities created by the major languages. An

    alternative approach would be in focusing in enhancing the demand for RM languages a

    'market-to-outcome path'. This alternative approach is proposed thanks to the overcoming of the

    languages network externalities, causing the concentration of language-acquisition on a few

    'important' languages. Motivation for a RM language (condition for its survival: Grin 1992) will

    arise out if the subjective value attached to a specific RM language is taken into consideration.

    When deciding to learn a language, the traditional trade-off between its communicative benefits

    the positive network externalities and its subjective value must be halted in order to have an

    enhanced demand for RM languages: individuals will maximize their utility by freely choosing to

    learn an ethnic language. The perspective suggested shall avoid inefficiencies (i.e. oversupply)

    14Article 126-1 EC Treaty.

    15Decision 1720/2006, November the 15th of 2006. The "Lifelong Learning" Programme's2nde

    Activity concerns "Languages and Language Learning" and has received in 2008 for two years

    9,685,633. Hence, the cost of EU language programmes is approximately 4,842,826 per year.

    Source: http://eacea.ec.europa.eu/llp/ka2/key_activity_2_en.htm

    16European Commission, Eurydice, (2008)Key Data on TeachingLanguages at School in Europe,

    p.93, Available at: http://eacea.ec.europa.eu/ressources/eurydice/pdf/0_integral/095EN.pdf

  • 7/30/2019 Portuese (2009)

    11/61

    11

    since supply shall equate with the enhanced demand for a particular RM language.

    In conclusion, all these institutional costs are illegitimate since their purporse the

    equality of languages and the promotion of the European linguistic diversityare de facto either

    violated (with respect to the illusion of language equalityTosi,2003:129) or merely ineffective (with

    respect to the promotion of RM languages).

    II. Production Cost

    a. Overview of the EU Language Law on Labeling

    The existence of EU multilingualism impedes the free movement of goods17. The

    requirement of labeling products in the language of the MS where the product is purchased is an

    obstacle to intra-EU trade. Goods have to be modified when crossing linguistic borders.

    However, "the need to modify goods is itself a substantial barrier to market access18. Therefore, language

    barriers constitutes barriers "having an effect equivalent to quantitative restrictions"19hence impeding

    the free movement of goods by fragmenting the EU 'single' market into linguistic markets (in

    most cases tantamount to the national markets). Nevertheless, this restriction is a lawful barrier,

    justified by an imperative requirement20: the defense of the consumer demands that a product is

    labeled in the national language of the MS in order to have full intelligibility of the product by

    consumersmeaning, full information. The complex EU language law on labeling is characterized

    by the lack of any systematic coherent view21: different directives regulate the labeling of different sorts

    of products without rational justifications for these distinctions.

    In the absence of a specific directive, EU language law on labeling does not require the

    use of a particular language and allows labeling only through "designs, symbols, or

    pictograms"22(Creech 2005:82). Despite such theoretical possibility, because of the complexity of

    products and the intelligibility requirement in preparing products for consumer protection

    purposes, it seems to us that it is only the recourse of a written language (viz. the national

    language) that renders the protection of the consumers effective.

    A 'migrant consumer' who purchases a widget tied-in a MS's language without her speaking this

    language, is obviously not protected inasmuch as the product is labeled in a foreign language she

    17Articles 28, 29 and 30 of EC-Treaty.

    18Opinion of Advocate General Jacobs, 44 for C-412/93 (1995) "Leclerc-Siplec".

    19C-8/74 (1974) "Procureur du Roi v. Dassonville" where the ECJ stated that "all trading rules

    enacted by Member States which are capable of hindering, directly or indirectly, actually or

    potentially, intra-Community trade are to be considered as measures having an effect equivalent to

    quantitative restrictions".20

    C-120/78 (1979), "Rewe Zentrale v. Bundesmonopolverwaltung fr Branntwein".21

    Opinion of Advocate General Cosmas 56 for C-385/96, (1998) "Goerres".22 C-33/97 (1999) "Colim NV v. Bigg's Continent Noord NV".

  • 7/30/2019 Portuese (2009)

    12/61

    12

    does not understand. Consumer protection requirement does not insist on having the product

    labeled in the mother tongue of the consumer. The free movement of consumers is thereof

    obstructed.

    b. Economic Analysis of the EU Language Law on Labeling

    The legal requirement of different labeling incurs two direct costs for producers:

    Translation Costs: when the linguistic market targeted is important enough so that the expected

    benefits outweigh the translation costs, producers shall decide to bear the translation costs.

    Contrariwise, in the case of a small linguistic market, producers will refrain from translating. A

    detrimental threshold for intra-EU trade is settled; The opportunity costs of missed scale

    economies: the unlawfulness to produce and sell a particular product throughout the EU 'single'

    market all at once disallows economies of scale. The fragmentation of the EU market into

    linguistic markets concedes a comparative advantage to US producers who enjoy a unilingual

    continental market. Therefore, after a lowering of their products marginal costs, US producers

    can subsequently export their widgets abroad in so far as their costs are competitive.

    Labeling in the national language of the MS where the product is purchased cuts the

    'receiving informational costs' for consumers uncertainty and risk costs and/or translation

    costs while creating 'emitting informational costs' for the producers translation costs. The

    efficient solution is reached with the aforementioned requirement when the reduction in the

    producers translation costs is greater than the reduction in consumers costs. Current EU

    language law on labeling is efficient only when producers constitute the cheapest-cost avoider

    (Calabresi 1970). Producers can avoid the damage (opportunity costs of non-trade) at the lowest

    cost by pooling translation costs. Nevertheless, the current legal solution becomes inefficient

    when either:

    The damage is reduced/absent. Translation does not enfranchise moreconsumers. The less the disenfranchisement costs, the less the opportunity costs

    from missed trade without translation; or,

    The consumers' costs are reduced. Translation costs can be reduced, forexample, by the intervention of the State, whereas the uncertainty and risk costs

    are reduced when consumers shift from being risk-averse to being risk-

    neutral/favouring. This shift is either the result of the personalities of the

    consumers, or the result of a pooling of risks.

    The most probable cause of inefficiency of the current legal situation has to be found

    whereby there is no consumer disenfranchisement despite the absence of translation. This

  • 7/30/2019 Portuese (2009)

    13/61

    13

    situation is characteristic of multilingual States where consumers are fluent in the other

    language(s) of the State. In these cases, the translation costs are greater than their expected

    benefits reduction in consumers' costs because the translation does not bring about a

    decrease in disenfranchisement costs. Multilingual consumers bear very small uncertainty and

    risks costs compared to the producers translation costs. In these situations, consumers are the

    cheapest-cost avoider.

    As a result, the ECJ rulings "Piageme I"23and "Piageme II24 on the notion of "language

    easily understood by the purchaser" derived from Directive 79/112, have to be considered from an

    efficiency viewpoint. These decisions should not be extrapolated to monolingual MSs26

    according to the efficiency rationale explained above.

    Paradoxically, after having affirmed that "the fact that consumers in a Member State in which the

    products are marketed are to be informed in the language or languages of that country is therefore an appropriate

    means of protection", the ECJ judged in the "Crystal Glass" case25 concerning the validity of the

    Crystal Directive26 that the requirement of labeling only in the language of the country in which

    goods are marketed is "necessary". Here, the impediment to the free movement of goods is the

    maximized since bilingual labeling in order to simultaneously sell products in different MSs is

    prohibited. This judgment appears to overemphasize the need for consumer protection beyond

    a point where the additional precaution costs more than its inverse additional benefit, and thus

    leads to an inefficient solution. This wrongly judged decision might be explained on the grounds

    that the ECJ was protecting a EU law, whereas in other cases national laws were the bone of

    contention.

    23C-369/89 (1991) "Piageme v. BVBA Peeters": the ECJ judged 16 that "the obligation exclusively to

    use the language of the linguistic region constitutes a measure having equivalent effect to a

    quantitative restriction on imports, prohibited by Article 30 of the Treaty". A producer in Belgian is

    allowed to label its products only in French (or only in Flemish) and sell them throughout Belgium dueto the absence of consumers' disenfranchisement.24

    C-85/94, (1995) "VZM v. Peeters NV": the ECJ affirmed that the Directive 79/112, within which the

    notion of "language easily understood by the purchaser" is promoted, aims to ensure that the

    consumer is provided with information rather than to impose the use of a specific language. The

    preoccupation is the information, not the language which is seen as only an information tool. An

    easily understood language is determined with respect of the similarity of words in differentlanguages, the widespread knowledge amongst the population concerned of more tha n one

    language, the existence of special circumstances such as a wide-ranging advertising campaign or

    wide-spread distribution of the product. On this latter criterion, concern can be expressed from the

    viewpoint of competition policy. Indeed, detrimental effects are created since outsiders without well-

    known products have to bear relatively high costs of translation and/or advertising, whereas theinsiders can afford to avoid these costs hence strengthening the comparative advantages of insiders.

    For us, this criterion should not be contemplated by the ECJ. Accordingly, it is necessary to criticise

    the ECJ ruling C-366/98 "Geoffroy v. Casino France"whereby Coca-Cola (the incumbent) labeling in

    English (the linguistic hegemon) in France has been authorized not to translate the bottles in French

    because they are "well-known"products.A contrario, outsiders will have to translate and/or advertise

    because of their unknown products. 26 Opinion Advocate Generale Cosmas 50 for C- 385/96 (1998)"Goerres".25 C-51/93 (1994) "Meyhui v. Schott Zwiesel Glaswerke".26

    Directive (1969) 69/493.

  • 7/30/2019 Portuese (2009)

    14/61

  • 7/30/2019 Portuese (2009)

    15/61

    15

    Empirical researches regarding the organizational culture of firms have established the

    importance of the language factor in the cultural barriers that firms encounter (Cremer 1993;

    Schall 1983; Barley 1983; Lazear 1999). Concisely, and by syllogism, we shall say that cultural

    differences are barriers to entry across MSs (Madsen 1994); language differences are the main

    feature of cultural differences amongst Europeans; therefore, language differences are entry

    barriers across MSs.

    Linguistic costs are the costs of entry in a linguistically different market that fall upon

    the foreign entrant, but not upon the local incumbent. Language barriers to entry are a specific

    type of cultural barriers. The social cost of entry barrier is welfare detrimental. Entry barriers

    have been defined by Stigler (1983) as the "cost of producing (at some or every rate of output) which must be

    borne by a firm which seeks to enter an industry but is not borne by firms already in the industry"2830.

    Language barriers are structural barriers which do not need the actions of the local incumbent in

    order to deter or postpone the entry. These barriers are faced by potential foreign entrants who

    do not speak the language of the target market. Inefficient outcomes arise when the least-cost

    firm is blocked from entering the market.

    Motta (2004:115) illustrates situations whereby language barriers are discernible, referring

    to the media market where relevant markets are defined by linguistic boundaries29. The relevant

    geographic market, independently of the transportation costs, will be the area sharing a common

    language30. Translation costs and search costs (for interpreters and business contacts) can be

    assumed to be similar, independently of language. Subsequently, the size and maturity of the

    market matter. A producer located in a MS will compare the expected payoffs between entry in a

    MS such as Denmark, and a non-EU market such as Russia. Ceteris paribus, if the payoff in terms

    of linguistic costs/expected profits is higher for the Russian market than for the Danish market,

    the producer will enter the Russian market rather than the Danish market. Not only is the EU

    market fragmented, but also, EU producers neglect one or several markets within the EU when

    a better payoff is attainable outside the EU.

    Let us assume two firms aand b incorporated respectively in countries A and B, both

    countries being monolingual with different languages. Producer aproduces its widget written in

    A's language at the cost of 100 per unit. Producer bproduces the 'same' widget but written in

    B's language, also at the cost of 100 per unit. Both producers' selling prices are 110 per unit.

    effect of cultural barriers as non-tariff barriers within the EU market, and not focusing on oneparticular type of productnamely, foodstuffs products.28

    We shall adopt this definition although Stiglers definition differs from the Bains wider definition.

    See: Bain, J. (1956). Also, Demsetz (1982) and Von Weizsacker (1980).29

    E.g. Decision IV/M.993 (1998) Bertelsmann/Kirch/Premiere where the relevant geographic

    market was defined as being the German-speaking area; Decision COMP/JV.37 (2000) BSkyB/Kirch

    PayTV".30

    E.g. Decision COMP/M.2724 (2002) Royal Bank Private Equity/Cinven/Ambion Brick where the

    relevant market as been defined as the UK and Ireland together.

  • 7/30/2019 Portuese (2009)

    16/61

  • 7/30/2019 Portuese (2009)

    17/61

  • 7/30/2019 Portuese (2009)

    18/61

    18

    preventing or disturbing firms learning about and understanding a foreign environment", emphasizing the need

    of acquiring information about the market and above all understanding them. Understanding is

    evidently inconceivable if languages differences render the information unintelligible. Barkema et

    al. (1996) emphasize the role of learning process in the internationalization of the firms.

    Obviously, the learning process is facilitated (learning costs lubricated) when a common

    language is shared (Melitz 2007). Psychic distance is an umbrella notion encapsulating different

    elements, viz. "business practices, institutions, economic environment, industry structure and national culture"

    (Evans et al. 2002). Due to the European integration, "national culture"as has become the major

    feature of the psychic distance between MSs.

    We shall understand "language distance" (West and Graham 2004) to wit, the

    unintelligibility because of a mere language difference as a sub-category of cultural distance,

    being itself a category of psychic distance33. Language distance is "bundled into the psychic distance

    package"(Welch et al. 2001:194). We include the requirement of linguistic competence into what

    Johnson et al. (2006:536) call the "cognitive cultural intelligence"of the targeted market, which plays

    "an important role"in the concept of cultural distance. There could be no cultural intelligence of a

    market without linguistic competence. Intelligence presupposes the mastering of knowledge after

    a process of learning, a process that postulates a free flow of information. Psychic distance incurs

    'psychic costs', consisting in the overestimation of risk costs. An illustration of psychic costs as

    risk costs exaggerating factor is witnessed with banks offeringsmaller loans at a higher interest rate to

    more culturally distant borrowers (Giannetti and Yafeh 2009). Perceivably, costs are dramatically

    increased altogether with an expected benefits' decrease (Bartlett and Ghoshal 1989; Palich and

    Gomez-Mejia 1999). Language distance incurs some "liabilities of foreignness"(Zaheer 1995) which

    are "impediments to effective negotiations and alliance evolution" (Luo and Shenkar 2006:322). Whereas

    languages are viewed as "keys to market understanding"(Williams and Chaston 2004:477), there is an

    under-investment in learning foreign languages, leading to an inefficient equilibrium (Konya

    2002).

    Language distance has an influence on both the performance of firms34 and on the

    equity entry mode choice. There is a conflicting literature in this domain. Researches have found

    a positive relationship between psychic distance and companies performances the psychic

    33Nordstrm and Vahlne (1992:10) concluded that psychic distance comprises "cultural [...],

    structural (such as legal and administrative systems) and language differences". They classify

    language distance as a category per se, not as a sub-category of cultural distance as we adopt. This

    divergence is not significant for our purpose since cultural differences within the EU are limited for

    market entry decision.

    34Furthermore, language is a key determinant of the performance of a country in general. The more

    prominent a country's language is, the greater the country's economic performance (Hall and Jones

    1996).

  • 7/30/2019 Portuese (2009)

    19/61

  • 7/30/2019 Portuese (2009)

    20/61

  • 7/30/2019 Portuese (2009)

    21/61

    21

    one common knowledge language for the parties and the court (Battigalli and Maggi 2008). In the EU

    context, language differences raise the problem of translation costs. Translation costs are the

    informational costs borne by contracting parties for overcoming language barriers.

    a. The Multiplying Effect of Language Barriers on Transaction Costs

    The language barriers have the effect of multiplying the transaction costs in each stage of

    the contractual process. Because information is not lubricated between parties, the burden of

    language differences will be endured throughout the process, from searching to litigation steps.

    Mackaay (1982) argues that informational costs can be reduced by a tradeoff consisting of either

    pooling risks or incurring searching cost up to point where the marginal cost of searching equals

    the marginal benefit of reduction of risk cost.

    From Posner s equation (2004), we can say that language barriers have the effect of

    multiplying the transaction costs. Posner determines transaction costs in a contract as:

    C = x + p(x) (y + z + e(x,y,z))

    Where Cstands for transaction costs, xrepresents the negotiation and drafting costs,yis

    the parties litigation costs, z standsfor judiciary costs, and erepresents the error costs. Linguistic

    costs incurred for a multilingual contract multiply the overall transactional costs (where L is > 0

    and represents the multiplicative coefficient of linguistic costs):

    C = [x + p(x) (y + z + e(x,y,z))] (1 + L)

    b. Language Barriers as the Major Impediment to EU Cross-border Contracts

    Cross-border legal uncertainty about European contract laws incurs transaction costs.

    This leads the literature to promote harmonization of the European contracts laws in order to

    reduce informational costs. But harmonization of legal systems in Europe is only a tool for

    lubricating cross-border information (Smith 2005). If divergence of laws creates uncertainty costs

    (Ribstein 1996), legal uncertainty can only be reduced by the decrease of the informational costs

    notably incurred by language barriers. The necessary informationthe foreign contract lawis

    non decipherable due to the unintelligibility (lack of mutual intelligibility??) of the language.

    Smith (2005) states that uniform contract law has not proved to be an efficient tool for increasing

    cross-border contracts. The harmonization of contract law as such is not as important for the

    enhancement of trade as governments or academics sometimes think(Smith 2005).

    In the absence of a "language game", multilingual contracts are difficult to form.

  • 7/30/2019 Portuese (2009)

    22/61

    22

    Wittgenstein (1953) explains that there are an infinite numbers of language games played between

    actors. The promise game constitutes a particular family of language game. A contract game is

    played, which is an institutionalized reciprocal promising game (analogized from Wittgenstein's

    example of the marriage contract). No valid promise might be made when contracting parties do

    not share a common language. Misunderstandings occurring when a common language is learned

    might have sufficient weight so that risk-averse parties will decide not to enter into this language

    game, notwithstanding a third language in commonwith both text and context (Van Dijk 1977)

    being of importance. Lacking equal proficiency in a common language, inefficiencies due to the

    "signing-without-understanding" problem arise (variant of the "signing-without-reading" problem, De

    Geest 2002; De Geest et al. 2002).

    c. An Economics Analysis of Multilingual Contracts

    Multilingual contracts are particular sources of incompleteness since the three causes of

    incompleteness (Tirole 1999) are emphasized in this context. Unforeseen contingencies, writings

    costs, and enforcing costs are appreciably augmented. Contract incompleteness befalls mainly on

    the basis of avoidance of the inflation of writing costs (Battigalli and Maggi 2001). Language

    barriers substantially increase the probability of contract incompleteness, since drafting costs are

    necessarily higher in multilingual contexts. But because of the reluctance to bear greater drafting

    costs, parties shall either not enter into a multilingual contract or will accept greater contract

    incompleteness with "interpretative mistakes"(Eisenberg 2003:1611).

    As soon as one negotiator is "not truly fluent in a foreign language, [one] should not negotiate in

    that language"(Craver 2005:440): the additional translation cost is smaller than the additional cost

    of ex postmisunderstandings. Yet, overconfidence and "false consensus"biases (Solan et al. 2007)

    hamper the recourse of interpreters, and misunderstandings will only be brought into the open at

    the time of implementing the contract.

    More frequently opportunistic behaviours will crop up since a party has invested in

    language learning (or interpreters), whilst the other party did not. Information, as a "capital asset",

    shares the characteristics of any"investment problem" (Mackaay 1982). Language investments are

    language-specific investments (if not party-specific), as such being subject to opportunistic

    behaviours from the other contracting party (all the more if party-specific investments are aimed

    at understanding only this party). The non-investing party has gained bargaining power with a

    credible threat to stop the pre-contractual negotiations. In order to have other possible

    opportunities (risk-pooling), and to avoid sunk costs, only major languages will be learned. The

    bargaining power of the non-investing party renders an unbalanced contract possible. The more

    unilateral pre-contractual language investments are made, the more the investing party is subject

    to an unbalanced contract at her disadvantage. Rational actors will anticipate this damageable

  • 7/30/2019 Portuese (2009)

    23/61

    23

    outcome by under-investing in language skills, impeding the formation of multilingual contracts.

    When the supplier has invested in learning the language of potential consumers, the supplier is

    incentivized to distort information in her favour in the shadow of the consumer protection laws

    (Mackaay 1982) the high verification costs disincentivize consumers to go through the

    information supplied. With the assumption of risk-averse parties and aversion to contractual

    exploitation, consumers are deterred from dealing across linguistic borders. Consequently,

    language barriers impede cross-border contracts in the EU. Eleven percent of European SMEs

    lost contracts because of lack of language skills (ELAN Report 2006). A European business is

    estimated to lose 325,000 in contract value over three years due to lack of language skills. Often,

    businesses are unaware of contract loss caused by under-investments in language skills. For

    SMEs and for those aware of contract losses because of language barriers, the cost of lost

    contracts is estimated for the EU economy to be at least 100 billion per year (ELAN Report

    2006).

    V. Innovative Cost

    We shall here emphasize the cost of EU multilingualism for patenting in Europe.

    Language issue is the main obstacle for the emergence of a Community Patent35. Nowadays,

    patenting in Europe is a jigsaw puzzle36. The European Patent system is the most expensive

    patent system in the world. Prohibitive patenting costs necessarily bring about a lower demand

    for patents (De Rassenfosse and Van Pottelsberghe de la Potterie 2008; Mejer and Van

    Pottelsberghe de la Potterie 2008). Despite the presence of high judiciary and renewable costs,

    we shall concentrate on the existence of translation costs in the European Patent System.

    These costs derive from Article 65 of the European Patent Convention (EPC) which

    has been in force since 1977. Article 65 allows each MS to demand an exhaustive translation of a

    patent into its own official language(s) by the proprietor. The EPC is a mere bundle of national

    patent laws within a European institutional umbrella. The entry into force the first of May 2008

    of the London Agreement (LA)part of the EPCcut the translation costs since a patent must

    no longer be translated when written in one of the official languages of the EPC English,

    French, and German. However, the LA does not answer the aforementioned dilemma involving

    economic efficiency and linguistic diversity. Indeed, linguistic equality is denied in the LA due to

    a legalized hierarchization (free-riding) of languages English, French and German being

    privileged. This linguistic hierarchization may explain the small number of LA ratifications

    amongst MSs having neither English nor French nor German as their own official language(s).

    35The absence of a Community Patent damage 90% of the European businesses. Source: The

    European Parliament of Entreprises, http://www.cebre.cz/en/news/new-147/3336 Commissioner Jan Figel to EUobserver, 18.12.2008: http://euobserver.com/879/27308

  • 7/30/2019 Portuese (2009)

    24/61

    24

    The breach of the principle of equality of languages might be acceptable if the loss in subjective

    value were compensated by greater gains in economic efficiency in order to outweigh this breach.

    Yet, this is unfortunately not the case as we shall briefly explain.

    For an innovator to patent in all the MS of the EU, the LA only partly reduced

    translation costs. Indeed, only the filing (Article 1-3 a contrario) of a patent, and only between the

    contracting parties (only ten EU Member States) was involved (Mejer and Van Pottelsberghe de

    la Potterie 2008). The geographical limitation of the LA ratifications increases patent validations

    by 29%, instead of the more than 59% that were LA ratified by all parties at the EPC (Harhoffet

    al. 2009). To translate a patent into the 23 official languages of the EU cost more than 30,000

    (Karoutchi,2001) since on average translating costs 1,700 per language (Van Pottelsberghe de la

    Potterie and Francois 2006).

    When the LA regime is applicable, the economic gains are totally insufficient in order

    for the European Patent System to compete with other world patent systems. Under the LA

    regime, and only for 13 European countries, a validation of a patent in Europe is still thirteen

    times more costly than a validation in the US (Mejer and Van Pottelsberghe de la Potterie 2008).

    If a patent is filed in only 13 European countries, the reduction in translation costs resulting from

    the ratification of the LA amounts to 4,864 (Mejer and Van Pottelsberghe 2008). Hence, the

    translation costs alone went from 13,600 to 8,736, whilst the overall cost for filing a US patent

    and to protect it for 10 years is 12,125 (Van Pottelsberghe de la Potterie and Francois 2006). As

    shown below, only the translations costs, and only for 13 European MSs, are greater than the

    entire patenting costs in the US for a ten years protection, not to mention all other patent

    systems in the world:

  • 7/30/2019 Portuese (2009)

    25/61

  • 7/30/2019 Portuese (2009)

    26/61

    26

    require proficiency in the national language, but instead in a third language (e.g. English).

    Nevertheless, such a faculty is infrequently exploited (except perhaps for academic positions).

    The language requirement generates the non-appearance of a EU labour market, but rather, the

    perpetuating of small national labour markets a EU labour market being absolutely

    imperceptible (Zimmermann 2009).

    Language barriers are the foremost hindrance to labour mobility in the EU, since

    language barriers are perceived as difficult to overcome (Bonin et al.,2008:81) and they are seen

    as the prime barrier to EU labour mobility (Fertig and Schmidt 2002:Table7). Language barriers

    astronomically increase migration costs, hence hampering intra-European mobility (European

    Foundation for the Improvement of Living and Working Conditions 2006). Legal and

    administrative barriers to intra-EU mobility are very low, an illustration being the important

    mobility across regions sharing a common language such as Netherlands-Flanders, Germany-

    Austria, France-Wallonia, Ireland-UK, etc

    Four percent of EU citizens have lived outside their native MS in another MS (European

    Foundation for the Improvement of Living and Working Conditions 2006) whereas 32% of US

    citizens live in a State different from the one in which they were born (US Census Bureau 2000).

    These 4% have to be compared with the proportion of EU citizens who ever lived in a country

    outside the EU: 3%. Therefore, the EU political and economic integration (and geographic

    proximity) only counts for 1% of enhanced mobility. Indubitably, the removal of the legal and

    administrative barriers to intra-EU mobility does not count for much since this rate is almost

    equal to the mobility with non-EU countries where legal and administrative barriers are

    prominent. This confirms what Srivastava and Green (1986:624) state when stating "cultural

    similarity appears to have a more pronounced effect on relative trade flows than does shared membership in an

    economic union". Moreover, these 3% have to be compared to the 18% rate of migration across

    regions within a MS, despite the progresses of the EU law on free movement of workers on

    equal treatment. Thence, a constant impediment shared by both non-EU countries and other

    MSs seemingly hinders cross-border mobility but not intra-national mobility. Naturally, language

    barriers are the distinguishable factor explaining both high intra-national mobility and low cross-

    border mobility, independently of the country of destination, be it inside or outside the EU.

    b. Languages in the Workplace

    Individuals make language-specific investments for expected returns deriving from

    language skills. With respect to mobility, to become proficient in a foreign language naturally

    opens up the relevant labour market related to that language. Because learning costs are assumed

    to be similar, regardless of the language learned, individuals seek accessibility to the most

    sizeable national labour markets possible, conducing to focus language-acquisition on the

  • 7/30/2019 Portuese (2009)

    27/61

  • 7/30/2019 Portuese (2009)

    28/61

  • 7/30/2019 Portuese (2009)

    29/61

  • 7/30/2019 Portuese (2009)

    30/61

    30

    'democratic deficit'. Practical obstacles occlude the emergence of a pan-EU democratic society.

    As regards these practical obstacles, EU multilingualism is comprehensibly of major importance

    in the obstruction of the rise of a supranational democracy.

    Language is tied into political life because it naturally constitutes its medium(Longman 2007:89;

    Karisson 1999). The democratic deficit is caused by an absence of European ffentlichkeit

    (public sphere, Habermas 1989; 1990; 1992a; 1992b; 1992c), which posits a community of

    communication" embedded with a common language (Risse 2003; Kielmansegg 1996). Wright

    (2000) argues that democracy is inextricably bound with language, and one wonders how it can be managed

    without a community of communication.

    Democracy presupposes participation assuming interpersonal communication, which

    implies exchanges of information postulating a common mediuma common language being at

    the cornerstone of this socio-political chain. The society may well be multilingual; political

    debates can only be unilingual.

    The tie of language is perhaps the strongest and most durable that can unite mankind(Tocqueville

    1961:23). With 66% of the EU citizens being monolingual (Karisson 1999), the absence of a

    common language impedes the emergence of "postnational" Europeans (Habermas 2001).

    Linguistic diversity clearly prevents the rise of a European 'nation' (Braga and Monti 1982). The

    origin of this impediment is a demos deficit (Kraus 2008:21), and the impossibility of multilingual

    campaigning in order to avoid the "multilingual election problem"(Pool 1992). There is what we call a

    'receptive democratic deficit' EU leaders cannot receive messages from EU citizens, and an

    'explicative democratic deficit'EU leaders cannot explain their policies to EU citizens without

    either incurring prohibitive monetary and delay costs if discourses are translated into all official

    languages, or contribute to the linguistic imperialismwhen EU leaders use English as a lingua franca

    (Phillipson,1992) thereby contributing to a language disenfranchisement of at least 45% of EU

    citizens (Ginsburg and Weber,2005;Ginsburg et al.,2006;Fidrmuc et al.,2007). Dismissals of EU

    texts because of the lacking of a EU political arena incur two costs.

    First, delay costs are incurred: the EU integration is postponed, whereas the economic

    and political integration is supposedly welfare beneficial. Second, transaction costs are increased

    since the rejections of texts lead to renegotiations costs for ersatz of the defeated Treaties.

    The EU is more than a convivial order, but is neither a (linguistic) community order, nor

    (yet) a social order (Van Dun 2004). The Babelian EU is a multilingual political order within

    which political debates by the population are impractical. The notable void(De Swaan,2004) of

    dialogue/democracy/debate as the reason for the rejection of EU texts was evident in the

    European Constitution referenda when the Plan-D: Democracy, Dialogue and Debate40, costing 9

    40COM(2005) 494 The Commissions Contribution to the Period of Reflection : Plan-D for

    Democracy, Dialogue and Debate, 13.10.2005; COM(2008) 158/4 Debate Europe Building onExperience of Plan D for Democracy, Dialogue and Debate, 12.03.2008.

  • 7/30/2019 Portuese (2009)

    31/61

  • 7/30/2019 Portuese (2009)

    32/61

  • 7/30/2019 Portuese (2009)

    33/61

  • 7/30/2019 Portuese (2009)

    34/61

    34

    If a cooperative game is played amongst MSs by reference to their EU linguistic rights, there is

    no coordination game. A coordination game applied to the EU language policy would mean that

    MSs choose a common standardfor our purpose a common language in order to maximize

    MSs' payoffs. Integral inter-communications with 23 official languages require coordination

    involving one common language.

    I. From Coase Theorem to Linguistic Coase Theorem

    Coordination cannot take place since linguistic rights are granted to MSs without a

    possible bargain between them. Linguistic rights are governed unanimously according to Article

    290 of the EC Treaty. A consensus over EU language policy has to be reached. A question

    about why we need a Linguistic Coase Theorem?

    We necessitate a Linguistic Coase Theorem inasmuch as Article 290 of the EC Treaty

    requires unanimity in order to change the EU language law. The current law must be reformed

    since it is economically inefficient and linguistically damaging. In order to have unanimity, all

    MSs have to be better off following the agreement, without any MS being worse off. Hence,

    Pareto-optimality is required. The Coase Theoremand the Political Coase Theoremleads to

    optimality. Therefore, in order to exchange the EU law of languages for an optimal one, we need

    to apply the Coase Theorem to languages. Consequently, the Linguistic Coase Theorem is not

    only justified on economic grounds, but is also required from a legal viewpoint. We shall now

    review the precedents of the Linguistic Coase Theorem, that is the Coase Theorem and the

    Political Coase Theorem.

    a. Overview of the Coase Theorem

    The seminal article of Ronald Coase (1960) revolutionized the way we consider

    externalities. The Coase Theorem has been summarized in a clear and simple way as:

    "When transaction costs are zero, an efficient use of resources results from private bargaining,

    regardless of the legal assignment of property rights"48.

    In the absence of transaction costs, actors involved in an externality will bargain over

    their rights, and will attain an efficient allocation of resources, independently of their initial

    entitlement of rights. As a consequence, bargaining has to be lubricated through the reduction of

    transaction costs. Therefore, the normativity of the Coase Theorem is:

    48Restatement made by Cooter and Ulen (2007).

  • 7/30/2019 Portuese (2009)

    35/61

  • 7/30/2019 Portuese (2009)

    36/61

  • 7/30/2019 Portuese (2009)

    37/61

  • 7/30/2019 Portuese (2009)

    38/61

  • 7/30/2019 Portuese (2009)

    39/61

  • 7/30/2019 Portuese (2009)

    40/61

  • 7/30/2019 Portuese (2009)

    41/61

    41

    mastered in 500 hours and English in 1,500 hours57. Wells affirms that "opposition to Esperanto is

    often more emotional than rational"(Wells 2003; Piron 1994b).Esperanto does not create any

    externality since it is the national or official language of no country in the world. Esperanto is

    fitted to be the language of supranational democracy (Archibugi 2005) and concretizes the notion

    of"linguistic democracy"especially for the EU (Fettes and Bolduc 1998:101-129). Esperanto would

    be stable because the rise and fall of national powers will have no effect on Esperanto.

    In conclusion, Esperanto appears to have the characteristics of optimality should MSs

    engage in Coasian bargaining. Although Esperanto manifestly reveals its optimality, this outcome

    seems very improbable, especially when one reviews the current relevant literature.

    d. Literature Concerning The Choice of a EU Lingua Franca

    The academic debate presented here is stagnant, principally owing to the neglect of the

    reciprocal nature of the problem.

    Abram de Swaan promotes the adoption of English as the EU lingua francabecause it is

    already the "supercentral language"in the "galaxy of languages"(De Swaan 1993b:220). Yet, De Swaan

    acknowledges that the hierarchization of languages is "contested", and that "language groups are

    struggling to defend or impose their idiom as the central medium, or to prevent another language from achieving a

    57Even with this highly prudent assumption, the efficiency of Esperanto is great enough not to create a

    lock-in effect with English and to overcome the switching costs, something proven with a simple

    calculus. If we optimistically assume that half of the EU citizens speak 'very good' English (250

    millions EU citizens), then it costs: 250 millions x 1,500 h = 375 billions of hours of teaching for the

    entire EU citizenry to speak a 'very good' English. The cost of Esperanto is: 500 millions x 500 h = 250billions of hours. It costs 1.5 times (375/250=1.5) more to have half of the EU citizens speaking 'very

    good' English than for every EU citizens to become fluent in Esperanto.

  • 7/30/2019 Portuese (2009)

    42/61

  • 7/30/2019 Portuese (2009)

    43/61

    43

    Europe. Esperanto cannot become the EU lingua franca, not only because the current EU law on

    languages states that the languages of the EU can only be chosen from among the languages of

    the MSs (Regulation 1/58), but also and above all because the UK would not accept to abandon

    its free-ride. The scenario 'all-Esperanto' without accompanying measures is unrealistic given the

    current situation.

    e. The Reciprocal Nature of The Lingua Franca Problem

    We have reviewed the current literature related to the choice of a EU lingua franca, and

    we have seen that it is at a dead-end. Either the efficient solution ('all-Esperanto') seems

    unrealistic because of the lack of coordination and consensus, or the more probable solution

    ('all-English') incapable of implementation on account of the "linguistic tax".

    We argue that none of these propositions are realistic, and are flawed because they

    ignore the reciprocal nature of the problem. Either the linguistic hegemony of English requires a

    "linguistic tax" on every English-speaking country in the world (Van Parijs 2000; 2002; 2004a;

    2004b), or this linguistic hegemony justifies the adoption of Esperanto as the EU lingua francain

    order to cease the free-riding of the English-speaking countries (Grin; 2005). In both cases, UK

    is condemned as the 'generator' of a 'linguistic harm' whilst Continental Europe becomes the

    'victim'. This is in line with the Pigouvian tradition, involving a one-sided causality view of

    externalities.

    The true nature of the problem is not to say that the UK generates the externality and

    thus begging the question "how should we restrain [the UK]?" (Coase1960). To avoid Continental

    Europe being 'linguistically harmed' would inflict a harm to the UK; to allow the UK to free-ride

    would inflict harm on Continental Europe.

    In Coasian language, the fundamental question to ask is: should Continental Europe ("the

    surrounding woods"in Coase's example) be entitled to be free from 'linguistic harm' ("the sparks"), or

    should the UK be entitled to impose English ("to run additional train")?

    The reciprocal nature of the present problem flows from a (double) scarcity. Indeed, there is a

    scarcity of space hence the proximity of UK and Continental Europe makes the 'linguistic

    pollution' possibleand there is a scarcity of knowledgehence the need for one, and only one,

    lingua franca.

    Had Latin continued to be the European lingua franca, English could not have become

    the de facto EU lingua franca. Due to the disappearance of Latin, and due to the lack of

    coordination concerning the choice of a new European lingua franca, Continental Europe created

    the circumstances favourable for the rise of English as the de facto EU lingua franca. Pigouvian

    reasoning of causality concerning the determination of a 'generator' and a 'victim' of the damage

    is therefore proven to be flawedthereby rejecting the conspiracy theories re English (Phillipson

  • 7/30/2019 Portuese (2009)

    44/61

  • 7/30/2019 Portuese (2009)

    45/61

  • 7/30/2019 Portuese (2009)

    46/61

  • 7/30/2019 Portuese (2009)

    47/61

  • 7/30/2019 Portuese (2009)

    48/61

  • 7/30/2019 Portuese (2009)

    49/61

  • 7/30/2019 Portuese (2009)

    50/61

  • 7/30/2019 Portuese (2009)

    51/61

  • 7/30/2019 Portuese (2009)

    52/61

  • 7/30/2019 Portuese (2009)

    53/61

  • 7/30/2019 Portuese (2009)

    54/61

  • 7/30/2019 Portuese (2009)

    55/61

  • 7/30/2019 Portuese (2009)

    56/61

  • 7/30/2019 Portuese (2009)

    57/61

    57

    Chapter 5, pp.84-114,Lang K., (1986) "A Language Theory of Discrimination", The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol.101

    N2, pp.363-382.Lazear E.P., (1999) "Culture and language", Journal of Political Economy, Vol.107b N6, pp.95126.Leslie D., Lindley J., (2001) "The Impact of Language Ability on Employment and Earnings of Britain's

    Ethnic Communities", Economica, Vol.68, pp.587-606.

    Levi M., (1993) "Development in business crime control in Europe" in "Crime in Europe", Farell M.,Heidensohn F. (Eds), Routledge.Li C.S.D., (2003) "Between English and Esperanto: what does it take to be a world language?",

    International Journal of the Sociology of Language, N164, pp.33-63.Longman C., (2007) "The European Convention as Communicative Environment: The Challenge of

    Multilingual Deliberation", in "Public Sphere and Civil Society? Transformations of the EuropeanUnion", Fossum J.E., Schlesinger P., Kvaerk G.O. (Eds), ARENA Report N2/07.

    Lukacs A., (2007) "Aspetti economici della disuguaglianza linguistica", Available at:http://www.corrierecaraibi.com/Athena/Aspetti_economici_della_disuguaglianza_linguistica.pdf

    Luo Y., Peng M.W. (1999) "Learning to Compete in a Transition Economy: Experience, Environment,and Performance", Journal of International Business Studies, Vol.30, pp.269-296.

    Luo Y., Shenkar O., (2006) "The Multinational Corporation as a Multilingual Community: Language andOrganization in a Global Context", Journal of International Business Studies, N37, pp.321-339

    Machin S., Pelkonen P., Salvanes K.G., (2008) "Education and Mobility", IZA Discussion PaperN3845.

    Mackaay E., (1982) "Economics of Information and Law", Doctoral Thesis, Kluwer-Nijhoff Pub,Boston.

    Mackaay E., (2000) "Lanalyse Economique du Droit" in "Fondements", Vol.1, Edition Themis etBruylant, Bruxelles.

    Madsen P.T., (1994), "Is Culture a ma jor Barrier to a Singl e European Market? The Case of Pu blicPurchasing" in "National Cultures and Europea n Integrat ion - Explor atory Essay s on Cult uralDiversity and Common Policies", Zetterholm S. (Ed), Berg Publisher, Providence.

    Mamadouh V., (2002) "Dealing with Multiculturalism in the European Union: Cultural TheoryRationalities and Language Policies", Journal of Comparative Policy Analysis: Research and Practice,Vo l.4 , pp. 32 7-345.

    Manev I.M., Stevenson W.B., (2001) "Nationality, Cultural Distance, and Expatriate Status: Effects onManagerial Network in a Multinational Entreprise", Journal of International Business Studies, Vol.32N2, pp.285-303.

    Marschak, J. , (1965) Economics of Language, Behavioral Science, Vol.10 N2, pp.135 -140.Marschan R., Welch D., Welch L., (1997) "Language: The Forgotten Factor in Multinational

    Management", European Management Journal, Vol.15 N5, pp.591-598.Mejer M., Van Pottelsberghe de la Potterie B., (2008) "The London Agreement and the Cost of

    Patenting in Europe", Bruegel Working Paper N2008/05.Melitz J., (2007) "Language and Foreign Trade", European Economic Review, Vol.52, pp.667-699.Ministre de l instruction publique / Ministero della Pubblica Istruzione, (1995) "tude de la

    Commission sur la langue internationale", Bolletino ufficiale del Ministero della Pubblica Istruzione,N21-22-25, pp.7-43, Available at: http://www.internacialingvo.org/public/etude.pdf

    Mller H.M., (2006)"Barrier to European Union Counterterrorism Efforts", Intern Publication of theMemorial Institute for the Prevention of Terrorism (MIPT), Oklahoma City, Available at:http://www.mipt.org/Websites/mipt/Blog/478982/Barriers-European-Union-Counterterrorism-

    Efforts.pdfMorosini P. , Shane S. , Singh H., (1998) "National Cultural Distance and Cross-Border Acquisition

    Performance", Journal of International Business Studies, Vol.29, pp.137-158.Motta M., (2004) "Competition Policy. Theory and Practice", Cambridge University Press, New York.Newman P., (1998) "The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics and the Law", MacMillan Publisher

    Limited, England.Noguer M., Siscart M., (2003) "Language as a Barrier to International Trade? An Empirical

    Investigation", Universit Columbia, Second-Job Market Paper Nov.2003.Nordstrm K., Vahlne J.E., (1992) "Is the Globe Shrinking? Psychic Distance and the Establishment of

    Swedish Sales Subsidiaries During the Last 100 Years", Paper Presented at the International Tradeand Finance Association's Annual Conference, April 22-25, Laredo, US.

    Noss R., (1967) "Language policy and higher education", UNESCO/International Association ofUniversities, Paris, Vol.III Part 2, p.216.

    Ochs E., Schieffelin B., (1989) "Language has a Heart" in "The Pragmatics of affect", Special issueVo l.9 N 1, pp . 7-2 5.

    http://www.corrierecaraibi.com/Athena/Aspetti_economici_della_disuguaglianza_linguistica.pdfhttp://www.internacialingvo.org/public/etude.pdfhttp://www.mipt.org/Websites/mipt/Blog/478982/Barriers-European-Union-Counterterrorism-Efforts.pdfhttp://www.mipt.org/Websites/mipt/Blog/478982/Barriers-European-Union-Counterterrorism-Efforts.pdfhttp://www.mipt.org/Websites/mipt/Blog/478982/Barriers-European-Union-Counterterrorism-Efforts.pdfhttp://www.mipt.org/Websites/mipt/Blog/478982/Barriers-European-Union-Counterterrorism-Efforts.pdfhttp://www.internacialingvo.org/public/etude.pdfhttp://www.corrierecaraibi.com/Athena/Aspetti_economici_della_disuguaglianza_linguistica.pdf
  • 7/30/2019 Portuese (2009)

    58/61

  • 7/30/2019 Portuese (2009)

    59/61

    59

    John M. Ol in La w and Ec on om ic s Worki ng Pa pe r N1 46 .Posner R. A., (2004) "The Law and Economics of Contract Interpretation", John M. Olin Law &

    Economics Working Paper N.229.Reinert K. A., Rajan R. S., Glass A.J., Davis L.S. (Eds), (2008) "The Princeton Encyclopedia of the

    Wo rl d Ec on om y" , Princ et on Uni ve rsi ty Pr ess .Ribstein L.E, Kobayashi B.H., (1996)"An Economic Analysis of Uniform State Laws", Journal of Legal

    Studies, N 25 pp.131-199Rigby J.M., (1987) "The Challenge of Multinational Team Development", Journal of ManagementDevelopment, Vol.6 N3, pp.65-72.

    Risse T., (2000) ''Let's Argue! Communicative Action in International Relations", InternationalOrganization Vol.54 N1 pp.1-39.

    Risse T., (2003) "An Emerging European Public Sphere? Theoretical Clarifications and EmpiricalIndicators", Available at : http://userpage.fu-berlin.de/~atasp/texte/030322_europe_public.pdf

    Ronen S., Shenkar O., (1985) "Clustering Countries on Attitudinal Dimensions: A Review andSynthesis", Academy of Management Review, Vol.10 N3, pp.435-456.

    Ryan B., (2007) "The European Union and Labour Migration: Regulating Admission or Treatment?" in"Whose Freedom, Security and Justice? EU Immigration and Asylum Law and Policy", Baldaccini A.,Guild E., Toner H. (Eds), Hart Publishing, Chapter 16,, Oregon.

    Salk J., Shenkar O., (2001) "Social Identities in an International Joint Venture: An Exploratory CaseStudy", Organization Science, Vol.12 N2, pp.161-178.

    Samuels W.J., Medema S.G., (1998) "Ronald Coase on Economic Policy Analysis: Framework andImplications" in "Coasean Economics: Law and Economics and the New Institutional Economics",Medema S.G. (Ed), Kluwer Acdemic Publishers, Chapter 8.

    Sandler T., Enders W., (2004) "An Economic Perspective on Transnational Terrorism", EuropeanJou rna l of Pol itica l Ec on om y, Vo l.2 0, pp. 30 1 -3 16 .

    Sapir E., (1949) "The se l ec ted writ ings o f Edward Sapir in language, cul ture, and personal ity", University ofCalifornia Press, Berkeley.

    Saint-Paul G., (2004) "The Brain Drain: Some Evidence From European Expatriates in the UnitedStates", IZA Discussion Paper N1310.

    Schall M. S., (1983) "A communication-rules approach to organizational culture", AdministrativeScience Quarterly, Vol.28 N4, pp.557581.

    Schlesinger P. (1999) "Changing Spaces of Political Communication: The Case of the European Union",Political Communication, Vol.16, pp.263-79.

    Schlesinger P. , (1994) "Europes contradictory communicative space", Daedalus, Vol.123 N2 pp. 25-52.Schlesinger P., (2003) "The Babel of Europe? An Essay on Networks and Communicative Spaces",

    Ar ena Worki ng Pa pe r Se ries N22 /2003, Avail abl e at: ww w.arena .u io. no /p ubl ica ti ons /wor kin g-papers2003/papers/03_22.xml

    Schweiger D.M., Atamer T., Calori R., (2003) "Transnational Project Teams and Networks: Making theMultinational Organization More Effective", Journal of World Business, Vol.38 N2, pp.127-140.

    Selten R. Pool J., (1997) "Is it worth it to learn Esperanto? Introduction to game theory", in "The Costsof European Linguistic Non Communication", Selten R. (Ed), Esperanto Radikala Asocio, Rome,pp.114-149.

    Selten R., Pool J., (1981) " u Mi Lernu Esperanton? Enkonduko en la Teorion de Lingvaj Ludoj",in "Interlingvistikaj Kontribuaoj/Beitrge zur Interlinguistik", Sakaguchi A. (Ed), Esperanto -CentroAb te i lun g Ve rla g, Pa de rbor n, pp . 62 -1 17 . En gl ish abs tr ac t :" Sy mm et ric Eq uili br ia in Lin gu ist icGames", Available at: http://www.ais-sanmarino.org/publik/ludoj.html

    Selten R., Pool J., (1991) "The Distribution of Foreign Language Skills as a Game Equilibrium", in"Game Equilibrium Model IV: Social and Political Interaction", Selten R. (Ed), Springer-Verlag,Heidelberg, pp.64-87.

    Shenkar O., (2001) "Cultural Distance Revisited: Towards a More Rigorous Conceptualization andMeasurement of Cultural Differences", Journal of International Business Studies, Vol.32 N3,pp.519-535.

    Shenkar O., Zeira Y., (1992) "Role Conflict and Role Ambiguity of Chief Executive Officers inInternational Joint Ventures", Journal of International Business Studies, Vol.23 N1, pp. 55-75.

    Shoham A., Albaum G.S., (1995) "Reducing the Impact of Barriers to Exporting: A ManagerialPerspetive", Journal of International Marketing, Vol.3 N4, pp.85-105.

    Shore C. (2000) "Building Europe: The Cultural Politics of European Integration", Routledge.Siebert H., (1997) "Labor market rigidities: at the root of unemployment in Europe", The Journal of

    Economic Perspectives, Vol.11 N3, pp.37-54.

    Skutnabb-Kangas T., (2002) "Language Policies and Education: The Role of Education in Destroying orSupporting the World's Linguistic Diversity", Keynote Address at the World Congress on Language

    http://userpage.fu-berlin.de/~atasp/texte/030322_europe_public.pdfhttp://www.arena.uio.no/publications/working-papers2003/papers/03_22.xmlhttp://www.arena.uio.no/publications/working-papers2003/papers/03_22.xmlhttp://www.ais-sanmarino.org/publik/ludoj.htmlhttp://www.ais-sanmarino.org/publik/ludoj.htmlhttp://www.arena.uio.no/publications/working-papers2003/papers/03_22.xmlhttp://www.arena.uio.no/publications/working-papers2003/papers/03_22.xmlhttp://userpage.fu-berlin.de/~atasp/texte/030322_europe_public.pdf
  • 7/30/2019 Portuese (2009)

    60/61

    60

    Policies, 2002.Smith A. D., (1992) "National identity and the idea of European unity", International Affairs, Vol.68

    N1 pp.55-76.Smith D., Wright S. (Eds), (2000) "Whose Europe? The Turn Towards Democracy", Wiley-Blackwell,

    New York.Smith G.R., (1983) "Polities in Western Europe: A Comparative Analysis", Heinemann Educational,

    London.Smits J., (2005) "The Need for a European Contract Law", Europa Law Publishing, Groningen.Solan L., Rosenblatt T., Osherson D., (2007) "False Consensus Bias in Contract Interpretation",

    Columbia Law Review, Vol.108 N5, pp.1268-1300.Srivastava R.K., Green R.T., (1986) "Determinants of Bilateral Trade Flows", The Journal of Business,

    Vo l.5 9 N 4, pp. 62 3- 640 .Stigler G., (1983) "The Organization of Industry", University of Chicago Press, Chaicago.Stttinger B., Schlegelmilch B.B., (2000) "Psychic Distance: A Concept Past Its Due Date?",

    International Marketing Review, Vol.17 N2, pp.169-173.Swift J., (1991) "Foreign Language Ability and International Marketing", European Journal of

    Marketing, Vol.25 N12, pp.36-49.Ti ha ny i L., Gr iff ith D. A. , Ru sse ll C.T. , (2 005 ) "T he Ef fe ct of Cu ltu ral Di st anc e on En tr y Mo de Cho ic e,

    International Diversification, and MNE Performance: A Meta-Analysis", Journal of InternationalBusiness Studies, Vol.36 N3, pp.270-283.

    Ti rol e J ., (1 99 9) "I nc om plete Con tr ac ts: Wher e Do We Sta nd ?" , Ec on ome tr ic a , Vo l.6 7, pp .7 41 -78 1.To lli son R. D. , Co ng let on R. D. (Ed s) , (19 95 ) "T he Eco n om ic Analys is of Re nt Se ek ing ", Ed ward El gar

    Publishing.To ml ins on J. (1 99 1) "C ultur al Im pe ria lism ", Pint er Pu bl ish er s, Lon don .To si A. , (2 003 ) "C ros si ng Ba rrier s and Br idg ing Cu ltur es ", Mu lti li ng ual Ma tte rs Lt d., Fr an kf ur t.Tr ia nd is H.C ., (19 82) "Di me ns ions of Cul tural Va riat ions as Pa ram ete rs of Or ga ni za ti on al The or ies" ,

    International Studies of Organization and Management, Vol.12, pp.139-169Tr uc hot C., (2 00 2) "K ey As pects of the Use of En gl ish in Eu rop e" , La ng ua ge Po li cy Di vi si on of the

    Directorate of School, Out-of-School and Higher Education DGIV, Council of Europe.Tu rnbu ll P.W. We lha m G.F., (1 985) "The Cha ract er ist ic s of Eu ropea n Ex po rt Ma rke ti ng St aff ",

    European Journal of Marketing, Vol.19 N2, pp.31-41.US Census Bureau, (2000), Report Available at: http://www.census.gov/main/www/cen2000.html

    Va il la nc ou rt F. , (1 980) "D if ferenc es in Ea rni ng s by Languag e Gr ou p in Qu be c", Pr ess es de l Uni versit Laval, Qubec.

    Va il la ncou rt F., (1 982 ) "The Ec on om ics of La ngu age an d La ng uage Plan ni ng ", La ng uage Pr ob lem s andLanguage Planning, Vol.7 N2, pp.162-178.

    Va il la ncou rt F., (19 91 ) "T he Ec on om ic s of La ngu ag e: Theor y, Em pi rici sm and Ap pl ica tion to the As ianPacific", Journal of Asian Pacific Communication, Vol.2 N1, pp.29-44.

    Va n den Be rgh R. , Cam esa sc a P.D ., (2 006 ) "Eu rope an Competi ti on La w and Ec ono mi cs. A Com pa rat ivePerspective", 2nd Edition, Sweet & Maxwell,.

    Va n Di jk T.A. , (1 977 ) "T ex t an d co nt ext . Ex pl or ation s in the se ma nt ics and pr agm a ti cs of disc our se ",Longman, London.

    Va n Du n F., (2 00 4) "The Pu re Theor y of Na tu ral La w" , Dr af t, Unpu bl ished , Availa bl e at:http://users.ugent.be/~frvandun/Texts/Articles/Natural%20Law%20-%20part%20I.pdf

    Va n El s T. , (20 05) "Mul ti li ngualism in the Eu rop ea n Uni on ", Interna ti on al Jou rna l of Ap pl ie dLinguistics, Vol.15 N3, pp.263-281.

    Va n Par ij s P. , (2 003 ) "E urop es Thr ee Lan gu age Pr obl ems" in "The Cha ll enge s of Mu lt i l ingualism inLaw and Politics", Bellamy, R., Castiglione D., Longman C. (Eds), Hart Publishers: forthcoming,Availabl e at: http://www1.law.nyu.edu/clppt/program2003/readings/vanparijs.pdf

    Va n Par ij s P., (2 000 ) "The Gr ou nd Fl oo r of the World. On the soc io -e co no mi c con sequenc es oflinguistic globalization" , International Political Science Review, Vol.21 N2, pp.217-233,

    Va n Pa rijs P., (2 00 1) "L ingu ist ic Jus ti ce ", Pol iti cs, Phi los op hy and Ec on om ic s, Vol .1 , pp. 59 -74 .Va n Pa rijs P. , (20 02) "Ne ithe r Ba be l no r Pen te cos t" in "Pe rspec ti ve s on Gl ob al isa tion" , Ancka er t L. ,

    Cassimon D., Opdebeeck H. (Eds), Peeters, Leuven, pp.257-64.Va n Pa rijs P., (2 002) "L E urop e, Rpu bli que Mul ti culturelle? Trois Dfis", in "La Rpublique ou

    l Europe?", Savidan, P. (Ed), Le Livre de Poche, Available at:https://www.uclouvain.be/cps/ucl/doc/etes/documents/DOCH_090__PVP_.pdf

    Va n Pa rijs P. , (2 004) "Eu rop es Ling uist ic Cha l lenge", Eu rope an Jou rna l of Soc iol og y, Vol. 45 N1 ,pp.113-154.

    Va n Pa rijs P., (20 04 b) "L 'ang lai s lingua fr anc a de l 'Un ion Eu ropenne : im p rati f de so lida ri t , inj usti cedistributive, facteur de dclin?", Economie Publique, Vol.15 N4, pp.13-32.

    http://www.census.gov/main/www/cen2000.htmlhttp://users.ugent.be/~frvandun/Texts/Articles/Natural%20Law%20-%20part%20I.pdfhttp://www1.law.nyu.edu/clppt/program2003/readings/vanparijs.pdfhttps://www.uclouvain.be/cps/ucl/doc/etes/documents/DOCH_090__PVP_.pdfhttps://www.uclouvain.be/cps/ucl/doc/etes/documents/DOCH_090__PVP_.pdfhttp://www1.law.nyu.edu/clppt/program2003/readings/vanparijs.pdfhttp://users.ugent.be/~frvandun/Texts/Articles/Natural%20Law%20-%20part%20I.pdfhttp://www.census.gov/main/www/cen2000.html
  • 7/30/2019 Portuese (2009)

    61/61