political economy on indonesia's negative investment list 2014

Upload: nurman-hidayat-hartono

Post on 13-Apr-2018

219 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 7/26/2019 Political Economy on Indonesia's Negative Investment List 2014

    1/16

    The Political Economy of the Indonesias

    Negative Investment List (NIL) 2014

    Nurman Hidayat / G1502523BSanti H. Paramitha / G1500382E

    IP 6025Comparative Political EconomyTrimester 2 AY 2015/2016

  • 7/26/2019 Political Economy on Indonesia's Negative Investment List 2014

    2/16

    1

    Introduction

    In the globalization era, the removal of investment barriers between states

    consequences one state to invest in other states through relatively easy process without

    significant problems. Aside from the economic opportunity that arises, globalization signals

    higher challenge in terms of competition between states. Since FDI is believed to contribute to

    economic growth, states are gearing up to create a business friendly environment with the

    purpose to attract more FDI. With regard to that condition, in October 2012, Indonesia

    formulated a policy package containing four initatives to boost the investment activities.1This

    policy package was concentrated to address the issues which hinder the investments activities,

    through: (1) the deregulation of investment licenses; (2) the acceleration of agriculture and

    mining based investment programs by providing tax incentives; (3) the improvement of the

    ease of doing business;2and (4) the formation of more open investment policy through the

    new Negative Investment List.3

    Noting that Indonesia possesses abundant natural resources, working years' surplus,

    growing middle class, as well as huge potential markets, these initiatives are expected to

    enhance Indonesia competitiveness in the eyes of foreign investors. In addition to that,

    Indonesia has been acknowledged as the 3rd top prospective host economies by UNCTAD

    World Investment Report in 2014, in which Indonesia was ranked at the 4thposition in 2013.4

    This explains the big chunk of investment which contributes 32,57% of Indonesias GDP.5

    However, this favorable investment opportunity seems to be challenged as the NIL

    2014 released. The NIL 2014 is considered to be contradictory with the governments promise

    to give more spaces for investment as mentioned in October 2012 policy package, as it presents

    more restriction towards specific sectors such as agriculture and logistic distribution. In some

    cases, the sectors which become limitedly opened or sealed for FDI are the sectors which

    actually require more foreign investment for the reason of: (1) the lack of national capability

    1 Indonesia Economic Quarterly Report December 2013, accessed in February 1st 2016, through

    http://www.worldbank.org/content/dam/Worldbank/document/EAP/Indonesia/IEQ-Dec13-ENGLISH.pdf2Ease of doing business refers to the components of doing business index, such as the level of easiness for

    setting up new businesses, getting electricity connection, paying taxes, etc. It is released by International Finance

    Corporation World Bank Group, please find the detail throughhttp://www.doingbusiness.org/3Negative Investment List is a government instrument which regulates limitation of the sectors for investment.

    Before the introduction of this policy package, the latest NIL was regulated under Presidential Regulation

    number 36 of 2010, called as NIL 2010.4 UNCTAD World Investment Report 2014, accessed in February 1st 2016, through

    http://unctad.org/en/PublicationsLibrary/wir2014_en.pdf5 Source Ministry of Finance Website, February 5 th 2015, http://www.kemenkeu.go.id/Berita/pdb-2014-

    mencapai-rp105427-triliun

    http://www.worldbank.org/content/dam/Worldbank/document/EAP/Indonesia/IEQ-Dec13-ENGLISH.pdfhttp://www.worldbank.org/content/dam/Worldbank/document/EAP/Indonesia/IEQ-Dec13-ENGLISH.pdfhttp://www.doingbusiness.org/http://www.doingbusiness.org/http://www.doingbusiness.org/http://unctad.org/en/PublicationsLibrary/wir2014_en.pdfhttp://unctad.org/en/PublicationsLibrary/wir2014_en.pdfhttp://www.kemenkeu.go.id/Berita/pdb-2014-mencapai-rp105427-triliunhttp://www.kemenkeu.go.id/Berita/pdb-2014-mencapai-rp105427-triliunhttp://www.kemenkeu.go.id/Berita/pdb-2014-mencapai-rp105427-triliunhttp://www.kemenkeu.go.id/Berita/pdb-2014-mencapai-rp105427-triliunhttp://www.kemenkeu.go.id/Berita/pdb-2014-mencapai-rp105427-triliunhttp://unctad.org/en/PublicationsLibrary/wir2014_en.pdfhttp://www.doingbusiness.org/http://www.worldbank.org/content/dam/Worldbank/document/EAP/Indonesia/IEQ-Dec13-ENGLISH.pdf
  • 7/26/2019 Political Economy on Indonesia's Negative Investment List 2014

    3/16

    2

    to develop the sectors, (2) the huge national demand upon the sectors outcome, and (3) the

    economic potency of creating wider employment through opening new business activity.

    Embarking from that particular case, this paper intends to examine the relevant

    dimensions to understand the case of NIL 2014, such as the formulation mechanism of NIL;

    the political economy of NIL 2014 by observing the motives of each actor involved in the

    making of NIL 2014 and constructing its interaction model; and the NIL 2014 policy

    implications, to answer the following questions:

    1. Why does the government of Indonesia applymore restrictive treatment to specific

    sectors through the Negative Investment List (NIL) 2014, under the favorable

    investment opportunity? Is there any possibility of business players interests being

    granted by the government through the implementation of NIL 2014 upon certain

    sectors?

    2. What are the implications for Indonesias economy by applying NIL2014?

    This paper assumes that NIL 2014 is not merely formulated based on the national

    interest of supporting domestic economy. There are other reasons incorporated in the

    consideration of deciding the sectors to be put on the list. This is rooted on the factual

    mechanism that NIL is periodically adjusted based on the government preferences and dialogue

    with the existing business players to regulate the sectors which are fully opened, limitedly

    opened, or even sealed for the foreign investment.

    Literature Review

    Foreign Direct Investment (FDI) can be understood as a cross-border investments flow

    made by a firm which located in one country to expand its business by opening a new factory

    or purchasing an existing one in another country.6Previous researches have mentioned that

    beyond the possession of natural resources, competitive factor production costs, and larger

    market opportunity, the host countrys type of regime is central to explain the countrys

    attractiveness and attitude towards FDI.

    In terms of countrys attractiveness, the conventional wisdom says that authoritarian

    regime provides more promising deals for foreign investors, due to the lack of constraints and

    low pressure of labor union on political leaders. The better deals offered by authoritarian

    regimes, are mostly related to the cheaper labor wages and dictators protection for the foreign

    companies run their business. While authoritarian regimes provide better deals, the democratic

    6Thomas Oatley, International Political Economy, (US: Pearson Education, Inc, 2012), 161.

  • 7/26/2019 Political Economy on Indonesia's Negative Investment List 2014

    4/16

    3

    regime, on the other hand, offers different appealing consideration for the foreign investors to

    plant their money. Democratic regime provides credibility and political stability as the pull

    factors. Noting that the democratic regime consists of large veto players, its tendency to violate

    its own regulation and promises will be small. Also, as mentioned by Olson, the well-

    established democracy, will ensure the future of the FDI in the host country.

    Research upon the countrys attitude towards FDI was conducted by Li and Resnick in

    2003. Li and Resnick argue, although the democratic regime owns more likeable factors for

    foreign investors, it does not necessarily suggest that democratic country will be more open to

    the FDI.7Their empirical result proves that higher the level of democracy will create better

    judicial systems and rule of law as well as multiple avenue for the domestic groups to deliver

    their concern. These conditions sometimes may drive the government of democratic countries

    to put necessary constraints to the FDI, for the consideration of protecting their domestic

    market players from serious foreign competitors.

    In addition to that, previous research also finds that individual preferences may also

    influence the states attitude towards FDI. As mentioned on Mayda and Rodrik research, they

    find that there is a positive relationship between national pride and protectionist preferences

    towards FDI. It indicates that the higher the individual national pride within a state, the state

    will be less likely to widely open its door for FDI. 8With quite similar view, Sornarajah states

    that nationalistic sentiments would hinder the prospect of FDI, particularly when the host

    country economy is in the downturn and the prosperous foreign investors are seen as

    controlling the economy.9

    Besides national pride, Scheve and Slaughter mention that perceived job insecurity also

    induces the individual preference for FDI. It is rooted in the assumption that FDI increases the

    elasticity of labor demand in the host country, which therefore results in individual perception

    to relate FDI to the future of their jobs. Their findings suggest that individuals which perceive

    their jobs will be more vulnerable as the FDI flows in, will demonstrate less favorable

    preference towards the FDI.10 Furthermore, Pandya research in 2010, confirms that the

    individual level of education and is also found to be significant in shaping the preferences. The

    7 Quan Li and Adam Resnick, Reversal of Fortunes: Democratic Institutions and Foreign Direct Investment

    Inflows to Developing CountriesInternational Organization 57 No. 1 (2003), 196.8Anna Maria Mayda and Dani Rodrik, Why Are Some People (and Countries) More Protectionist Than Others?

    European Economic Review49 No. 6 (2005), 1416.9

    M. Sornarajah, The International Law on Foreign investment, (UK: Cambridge University Press, 2004), 78-79.10Kenneth F. Scheve and Matthew J. Slaughter, Labor Market Competition and Individual Preferences over

    Immigration Policy Review of Economics and Statistics83 No. 1 (2001), 141-142.

  • 7/26/2019 Political Economy on Indonesia's Negative Investment List 2014

    5/16

    4

    support for FDI inflows within a state will decrease in a condition where the educational

    background is low, and increase as the educational background is high.11

    Aside from the regime effects and individual preferences, Goodman, Spar, and Yoffie

    explain another factor contributes to the countrys attitude towards FDI, which is the relations

    of FDI to imports. Their results show that in the situation when FDI is considered as import

    complementary, there will be a split in the domestic industry, with the domestic business player

    of the host country will request for more protectionist measure from the government for FDI.12

    On the other hand, when the FDI is taken as substitute to import, the demand of domestic

    business players of host country for protection declines, as the protection benefits are becoming

    irrelevant.13

    However, apart from the sole reliance on the power of the government, the growing

    economic conditions in developing countries support the birth of local companies and

    entrepreneurs to play in the domestic markets. Given the considerable number of the local

    business players, it then becomes imperative to note the role of business players in shaping the

    governments decision. In regard to that, slightly different from the existing approach which

    considers the regime type, individual preferences, and FDI relations to import as the influential

    factors to the states attractiveness and attitude towards FDI, this paper seeks to examine the

    case of the Negative Investment List (NIL) year of 2014 in Indonesia. The research will be

    developed by scrutinizing the interaction between business players and government in making

    restrictive policies towards FDI. This still dovetails with the previous research findings, which

    shows that more democratic country will provide more spaces for the domestic groups to

    vocalize their concern to the government, in which, when the domestic group pressure and

    lobby are strong, the governments are urged to accommodate their requests.

    Discussions

    Negative Investment List

    Formulation Mechanism

    All of direct investment activities in Indonesia are regulated under the Law Number 25

    of 2007 on Investment. According to this law, all business fields in Indonesia are open for

    11Sonal S. Pandya, Labor Market and the Demand for Foreign Direct Investment International Organization 64

    No. 3(2010), 406.12

    John B. Goodman, Debora Spar, and David B. Yoffie, Foreign Direct Investment and the Demand of theProtection in the US, International Organization 50 No. 4 (1996), 569.13Ibid., 587

  • 7/26/2019 Political Economy on Indonesia's Negative Investment List 2014

    6/16

    5

    investment, unless those which are stated as close or open with a certain condition14on the NIL

    or have been regulated by other law. Noting that NIL is an instrument of investment restriction

    that is codified in the form of Presidential Regulation, thus the agenda setting in NIL is more

    flexible compared to the restriction which is regulated through legislation, because it only

    involves the executive element as the policy makers. However, any setting on investment

    restriction through NIL has its own level of complexity since each drafting process attracts a

    lot of attention from business and political circles.

    NIL is evaluated periodically. Those adjustments are done by taking into account the

    economic development and national interest. The adjustment process of NIL is coordinated by

    the Investment Coordinating Board (BKPM) to involve the related Ministries and the business

    players representative. The related ministries and business players may submit their proposal

    accompanied by supporting reasons during the evaluation process of NIL. The proposals

    subsequently are discussed bilaterally with BKPM and multilaterally in a coordination meeting

    with the Coordinating Ministry for Economic Affairs. This suggests that the evaluation of the

    previous NIL and the formulation of the new NIL, involve not only the governments branches

    but also the business players as the major actors in NIL policy-making.

    Grounding to the assumption that the business players are basically profit maximizers

    while the government and politicians are survival maximizers, this paper views that the above

    mentioned mechanism, opens the opportunity for lobbying process between the business

    players and government in every formulation of NIL. A particular business players may ask

    for protection to maximize their profits. To successfully get protection, they create a

    collectively powerful lobbying power to the government by using the business association. In

    the name of business association, they actively lobby the government for their collective

    interests. In accordance with this realm, this paper explores the motivation of each actor above

    on the latest investment restriction policy-making codified in NIL 2014 as replacement of NIL

    2010.

    Negative Investment List (NIL) 2014

    NIL 2014 was enacted on 23 April 2014, on the same month with the general elections

    and only three months to the presidential election on July 2014. Its formulation process had

    14Fully open means all business player are allowed to conduct a business in those area, close means none of

    private sector are allowed, while open with condition means that those business sectors are allowed but subject

    to certain requirement, such as only open for small-medium enterprise, only open for domestic investment, orcould be open for foreign investment with certain ceiling equity.

  • 7/26/2019 Political Economy on Indonesia's Negative Investment List 2014

    7/16

    6

    been started from the end of 2012 and was originally scheduled for completion at the end of

    2013. At first, according to the government, the new NIL aimed to encourage more investment

    activities by introducing a more liberal policy measures. The Government was also reaffirmed

    to further loosen the restrictions for foreign investment by opening up a greater investment

    opportunities in infrastructure through Public-Private Partnership (PPP) schemes. In addition,

    the government also said that it would be a more open investment policy in a number of sectors

    such as pharmaceutical industry, transportation, and specialty hospitals.

    Later, this announcement got a lot of negative responses in the media.15Towards these

    initiatives, many parties accused the government for failing to protect the national interest. A

    similar sentiment was expressed by domestic business players that calling for a number of

    protection from competition with foreign investors. Upon this situation, the government tried

    to soften the debate stating that the discussions were still unfinished and turned to express its

    commitment to balance the national interest.16It took a quite long time for the NIL to be fully

    released in April 2014, showing that there was a tough negotiation between government and

    the business players to accommodate those kind of national interest.

    In NIL 2014, there are several business field provisions that change from NIL 2010 as

    presented in Tabel 1. Some sectors are more relaxed and some other are more restrictive

    towards foreign investment. NIL 2014 relaxes the limitations on foreign ownership in sectors

    such as in infrastructures including electricity generation, transmission and power distribution,

    port facilities, pharmaceutical industry, and transportation. On the other side, NIL 2014 also

    introduces new restrictions in business retail, trade services including distribution,

    warehousing and cold storage, onshore oil production services, as well as horticulture sectors.

    In comparison, many perceive that NIL 2014 is becoming more protectionist towards FDI

    rather than NIL 2010.17

    15Erlangga Djumena, Asing Semakin Mendominasi Ekonomi Indonesia, KOMPAS, November 7th2013,

    http://bisniskeuangan.kompas.com/read/2013/11/07/0756260/Asing.Semakin.Mendominasi.Ekonomi.Indone

    sia16Ibid.17

    Michael Taylor and Randy Faby, Foreign Investor Unhappy With Some Indonesias New Investment Rules,Reuters, May 14th 2014, http://www.reuters.com/article/indonesia-economy-investment-

    idUSL3N0NV3L920140514

    http://bisniskeuangan.kompas.com/read/2013/11/07/0756260/Asing.Semakin.Mendominasi.Ekonomi.Indonesiahttp://bisniskeuangan.kompas.com/read/2013/11/07/0756260/Asing.Semakin.Mendominasi.Ekonomi.Indonesiahttp://bisniskeuangan.kompas.com/read/2013/11/07/0756260/Asing.Semakin.Mendominasi.Ekonomi.Indonesiahttp://www.reuters.com/article/indonesia-economy-investment-idUSL3N0NV3L920140514http://www.reuters.com/article/indonesia-economy-investment-idUSL3N0NV3L920140514http://www.reuters.com/article/indonesia-economy-investment-idUSL3N0NV3L920140514http://www.reuters.com/article/indonesia-economy-investment-idUSL3N0NV3L920140514http://www.reuters.com/article/indonesia-economy-investment-idUSL3N0NV3L920140514http://bisniskeuangan.kompas.com/read/2013/11/07/0756260/Asing.Semakin.Mendominasi.Ekonomi.Indonesiahttp://bisniskeuangan.kompas.com/read/2013/11/07/0756260/Asing.Semakin.Mendominasi.Ekonomi.Indonesia
  • 7/26/2019 Political Economy on Indonesia's Negative Investment List 2014

    8/16

    7

    Table 1Investment Policy Changes from NIL 2010 to NIL 201418

    Political Economy of NIL 2014

    To understand the dynamics of political economy in the process of formation

    investment policy in Indonesia, this paper identifies at least two major actors involved in NIL

    formation, namely government and business players. From the government side, it consists of

    the president and the ministries of the related sectors, where the president and all the ministers

    stand as politicians. Therefore, it is essential to analyze what kind of political incentives the

    government possess by imposing NIL. Two polar groups are identified within the business

    18Compiled from the Presidential Regulation No. 36 of 2010 and Presidential Regulation No. 39 of 2014.

  • 7/26/2019 Political Economy on Indonesia's Negative Investment List 2014

    9/16

    8

    players. The first group is domestic business players that generally demands for protection

    while the second group is foreign business players that prefer investment liberalization to

    protection. In the following section, this paper will explain those actors profile and their

    motivations in NIL policy-making, then finally draw the interaction model among those.

    Actor 1: Business Players

    First, we start to identify the profiles and motivations of business players that involve

    in policy formation of NIL. At the stage of collecting inputs, the government opens a wide

    opportunity for the business players, whether they are domestic or foreign players and whether

    as an individual firm or through a business association, to provide input for the evaluation of

    previous NIL and produce the new version of NIL. The foreign groups are more likely to

    support liberalization in contrary with the domestic groups which generally demand for more

    protective policies.

    However, on the next stage of NIL policy discussion, the government engage Apindo

    (The Employers' Association of Indonesia) as the only party to represent business players.19

    The Apindos membersconsist of both domestic and multinational companies in Indonesia, in

    which its MNC members are concentrated in the manufacturing sector. Noting that the board

    of Apindo is dominated by domestic business players, its policy preferences on the formation

    of NIL tends to bring along the nationalistic concern.

    During the development of NIL, Apindo expresses its support for the government's

    plans to liberalize investment in infrastructure, electricity, and manufacturing industry.

    However, Apindo also demands the government to maintain the protection in retail trade20and

    impose new restriction on logistic distribution sectors, including distribution, warehousing, and

    cold storage.21According to Apindo chairman, Sofjan Wanandi, such protection is necessary

    to provide business opportunities for domestic entrepreneurs. He argues that domestic

    employers have been unable to compete with foreign investors in manufacturing due to lack of

    capital and technology, hence the retail and distribution sector need to be protected so not all

    sectors can be controlled by foreigners.

    19Apindo is the largest business association in Indonesia that covers all business sectors running in Indonesia.20At that time, the government responded this request by keeping the closed investment status for the retail

    trade business and further providing more details in regard to what kind of retail trade business being listed as

    closed (which had not been mentioned in the prior NIL 2010).21Linda Yusman, Retail, Distribution should be Put on Negative List: Apindo, The Jakarta Post, May 11th2013,

    accessed throughhttp://www.thejakartapost.com/news/2013/05/11/retail-distribution-should-be-put-negative-list-

    apindo.html

    http://www.thejakartapost.com/news/2013/05/11/retail-distribution-should-be-put-negative-list-apindo.htmlhttp://www.thejakartapost.com/news/2013/05/11/retail-distribution-should-be-put-negative-list-apindo.htmlhttp://www.thejakartapost.com/news/2013/05/11/retail-distribution-should-be-put-negative-list-apindo.htmlhttp://www.thejakartapost.com/news/2013/05/11/retail-distribution-should-be-put-negative-list-apindo.htmlhttp://www.thejakartapost.com/news/2013/05/11/retail-distribution-should-be-put-negative-list-apindo.html
  • 7/26/2019 Political Economy on Indonesia's Negative Investment List 2014

    10/16

    9

    From those explanations, this paper assumes that Apindo would likely to demand for

    protection with certain ceiling foreign equities limitation rather than full restriction to FDI. In

    this case, foreign investors would be required to set up a joint venture company with domestic

    players, showing that the presence of foreign investors must bring benefits for local

    entrepreneurs, became partners and not competitors.22The second preference would be full

    protection from foreign investment in retail trade and distribution sectors. While the last

    preference would be to let government in maintaining a liberal policy in those sectors. In order

    to maximize its probability for success in this lobbying, business players may offer any kind

    of political support to the incumbent (government) to win the upcoming elections, given that

    2014 general election and the presidential election were coming soon.

    Actor 2: Governments

    To examine the motivation of the government, this paper employs electoral cycles

    (office-seeking policy makers) model to test whether the government has an office-seeking

    motivation in NIL policy making. This paper is engrained on the assumption that politicians,

    including incumbent governments are basically survival maximizers. Voters will be an

    important consideration for them to decide what policies will be taken. Government tends to

    target specific policies that can satisfy the median voter (Downs 1975).23 In Indonesia, the

    median voters are dominated by workers or lower and middle classes. This class will tend to

    favor pro-employment policies rather than low inflation. As in general, people easily forget the

    old policy outcomes, voters have a tendency to assess the government performance through the

    latest policy outcomes. On this premise, the government has a political incentive to pursue

    specific measures that can spur growth and combat unemployment mainly on the time leading

    up to elections. (Nordhaus 1975).24The purpose is none other to lure voters at the next election.

    In relation to those premises, NIL formulation that began in late 2012 (1.5 years ahead

    of elections) initially aims to reverse the economic downturn by opening up to attract more

    FDI in attempt to reduce unemployment and boost economic growth. Nevertheless, in

    November 2013, apparently that liberal policy was reaping a lot of negative responses in the

    media. Many put the commitment of the government of securing national interest into question.

    22Satria Sambijantoro, Door Widens for Foreign Investors, The Jakarta Post, November 7th2013, accessed

    throughhttp://www.thejakartapost.com/news/2013/11/07/door-widens-foreign-investors.html 23Antony Downs, An Economic Theory of Political Action in DemocracyJournal of Political Economy, Vol. 65,

    No 2 (April 1957), 135-150.24William D. Nordhaus, The Political Business Cycle The Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 42, No. 2 (Apr.,

    1975), 169-190.

    http://www.thejakartapost.com/news/2013/11/07/door-widens-foreign-investors.htmlhttp://www.thejakartapost.com/news/2013/11/07/door-widens-foreign-investors.htmlhttp://www.thejakartapost.com/news/2013/11/07/door-widens-foreign-investors.htmlhttp://www.thejakartapost.com/news/2013/11/07/door-widens-foreign-investors.html
  • 7/26/2019 Political Economy on Indonesia's Negative Investment List 2014

    11/16

    10

    This momentum is also captured by the domestic business players to reinforce their

    lobbying power in asking for investment protection through NIL. The rising of nationalist and

    protectionist sentiment in closer to the elections, makes the government to delay the enactment

    of NIL and continue to negotiate in balancing the national (domestic players) interest. Due to

    the tight time to the election, an investment policy would likely to become ineffective

    instrument to stimulate investment, employment, and growth in a short time.

    Pragmatically, signalling pro nationalist by accommodating a little protectionist policy,

    may give more political incentives for the incumbent government to reap political support in a

    short time. First, to lure voters. Second, to open up the possibility of cooperation with business

    players in an effort to win the election. From the situation, the government tends to

    accommodate protectionist policy as demanded by domestic business players. This policy can

    become a popular policy with a fashionable jargon of for the sake of national interest.

    Interaction Model between Government and Business Players Representative (Apindo)

    This section explains the interaction model in NIL policy-making between the

    Government and Apindo as the representative from business players. The model is constructed

    based on the profile and the possible incentives for both players as been descripted in the

    previous section. By considering its possible incentives, this paper predicts the order of each

    players preferences from the highest to the lowest as follows. Apindo prefers a moderate

    protection with certain ceiling limitation for foreign equities; over full protection; over no

    protection. Apindo gets its most preferred outcome, suppose payoff of 3, if it demands for

    ceiling limitation and the government complies. Apindo locks its next best outcome, payoff of

    2, if it seeks a full protection and the government agrees. Lastly, Apindo acquires the lowest

    outcome, payoff of 0, if it does not pursue any protection or if the government rejects its

    demands.

    The government favors investment liberalization over all other alternatives; slightly

    dislikes foreign investment limitation with a certain maximum amount of shares; and detests

    full restriction on foreign investment, but also wants to meet its constituents expectation to

    balance the national interest. Accordingly, the government prefers no investment restrictions

    if none protection is demanded. It yields the best outcome for government, suppose payoff of

    3. In turn, if Apindo demands for protection policy, the government prefers granting a mild

    protection with a particular foreign equity limitation (payoff of 2) over rejecting its

    constituents voices (payoff of 1), but prefers to repudiate a constituent (payoff of 1) rather

  • 7/26/2019 Political Economy on Indonesia's Negative Investment List 2014

    12/16

    11

    than grants a full investment protection (payoff of 0). The possible payoff and interaction

    model between the Government and Apindo are illustrated in Figure 1.

    Figure 1Interaction between Government and Apindo during the Formulation of NIL 201425

    Based on these preferences and game settings, the Apindos best strategy is to lobby

    government for imposing ceiling limitation on foreign equities. If Apindo is doing so, the

    government would likely allow its demand and Apindo will attain its best possible payoff (3).

    In contrast, if Apindo asks for full protection or does not lobby at all, it will not receive any

    protection and will be left with the lowest payoff of 0. This lobbying game will meet its

    equilibrium condition when Apindo asks for ceiling limitation and government yields its

    lobbying efforts.

    Policy Implications

    The aforementioned section has elaborated the circumstance which influences why NIL

    2014 is formulated the way it is. Morevover, this section will further explain how the NIL 2014

    25

    Adapted from Frieden, Jeffrey A. Actor and Preferences in International Relations in Strategic Choice inInternational Relations ed. David A. Lake and Robert Powell. New Jersey: Princeton University Press, 1999, 43.

    Government

    (G)

    Government

    (G)

    Apindo

    (A)

    Lobby for

    full protection

    Lobby forceiling limitation

    Do not lobby

    for protection

    Reject

    Reject

    Accept

    Accept

    (2,0)

    (0,3)

    (0,1)

    (0,1)

    (3,2)

    Government and Apindo:

    Strategic Interaction over Investment Policy

  • 7/26/2019 Political Economy on Indonesia's Negative Investment List 2014

    13/16

    12

    affects the Indonesian economy. The implications of the execution of NIL 2014 can be divided

    into two aspects, which are (1) the implications towards the domestic business players and (2)

    implications towards the future of investment activities in Indonesia.

    First, this paper argues that in some sectors, the regulation of NIL 2014 is too focused

    on accommodating the demand of the specific business players in the name of the national

    interest without really paying attention to the national capability and demand. It later results to

    the imbalance of the national supply and demand.

    As mentioned on the previous section, the restriction on retail trade creates incentive

    for the domestic business players while disadvantage the foreign investor because of the entry

    barrier. In addition, in the case of restriction on the logistic distribution, the World Bank Report

    in 2013 states that Indonesias logistic cost reached to 24% of Indonesia GDP, higher than

    other countries in the region.26This high cost and long logistic distribution process are mainly

    caused by the high demands which are not met by the limited number and the poor capacities

    of logistic distribution providers in Indonesia, which actually can be altered by opening the

    sectors for the foreign companies to operate.

    However, what the government decided through NIL 2014 is paradoxical. Instead of

    opening the sectors for the foreign companies, it decides to limit the sectors for the reason of

    protecting the national interest. This decision champions the domestic players which run their

    business in the logistic distribution since it is a strategic sector which demand will be relatively

    stable or even higher. Oppositely, it generates difficulty for the other domestic business players

    which business requires logistic distribution to market their commodities, as evident on the

    hiking logistic distribution cost to become 26,4% of Indonesias GDPin 2015.27

    Secondly, the introduction of the more protective NIL in 2014 triggers the perception

    towards the Indonesias investment climate to go south, as shown on the UNCTAD World

    Investment Report 2015. While the prior report suggests Indonesia will be number 3 among

    the worlds top prospective host economies, Indonesia falls down to rank 14 in the period of

    26World Bank Website, High Logistics Costs Impede Higher Economic Growth For Indonesia, Says Joint Report,

    September 6th2016, accessed through

    http://www.worldbank.org/en/news/press-release/2013/09/06/high-logistics-costs-impede-higher-

    economic-growth-for-indonesia27

    Reiy Schreiben, Tingginya Biaya Logistik Dan Solusi Untuk Menekan Biaya Logistik Di Indonesia,

    IndonesianLogistic Association (Asosiasi Logistik Indonesia) Website, accessed on February 5th 2016 through

    http://www.ali.web.id/detail_article.php?id=69

    http://www.worldbank.org/en/news/press-release/2013/09/06/high-logistics-costs-impede-higher-economic-growth-for-indonesiahttp://www.worldbank.org/en/news/press-release/2013/09/06/high-logistics-costs-impede-higher-economic-growth-for-indonesiahttp://www.worldbank.org/en/news/press-release/2013/09/06/high-logistics-costs-impede-higher-economic-growth-for-indonesiahttp://www.ali.web.id/detail_article.php?id=69http://www.ali.web.id/detail_article.php?id=69http://www.ali.web.id/detail_article.php?id=69http://www.worldbank.org/en/news/press-release/2013/09/06/high-logistics-costs-impede-higher-economic-growth-for-indonesiahttp://www.worldbank.org/en/news/press-release/2013/09/06/high-logistics-costs-impede-higher-economic-growth-for-indonesia
  • 7/26/2019 Political Economy on Indonesia's Negative Investment List 2014

    14/16

    13

    2015 to 2017.28Although it is later reported that Indonesias FDI inflow grow about 20%,29its

    FDI is now more concentrated to specific sectors, which leave the other potential sectors being

    uncultivated. This insinuates that the more restrictive measure on NIL 2014 reduces the

    opportunity of the new business players entrance to Indonesia from various business

    background. Finally, the fact that Indonesia owns quite stable democratic regime, abundant

    natural resources, and huge labor advantage will be a waste, as they are no longer attractive for

    the FDI. Without further improvement on the existing NIL 2014, it is expected to jeopardize

    the Indonesias investment activities future.

    Conclusion

    Starting with questioning the government of Indonesias more restrictive measure

    towards FDI through the implementation of NIL 2014, this paper finally discovers several

    findings to explain why the NIL 2014 is contradictory with the initial agenda of the government

    to spur the investment activities and growth in Indonesia.

    First, this paper finds that there is a compromised interests between the government and

    the business players during the formulation of NIL 2014. Related with the argument of Li and

    Resnick in the earlier section, the democracy allows the dialogue between the government and

    the business players within a country. In the case of Indonesia, the business players under the

    Apindo request for the government to set necessary barricade to the sectors which in fact need

    more foreign investment to develop, noting the limited availability of domestic capital and the

    lack of domestic business players capacity of doing so. Considering that the period of new

    election is approaching, the government with its office-seeking motive then accommodates the

    Apindo request in exchange of the political support.

    Second, the negative response from the society and media upon the first initiative of

    the government to open more rooms for FDI, showing that national sentiment plays important

    role in shaping the economic policy outcome in Indonesia. This is particularly consistent with

    the research of Mayda and Rodrick, as well as Sornarajah, about the positive relation between

    nationalistic sentiments and protectionist measure towards FDI.

    Third, the case of NIL 2014 in the logistic distribution sector, also suggests that when

    government accommodate the interests of small groups of the business players, it will conceive

    28 UNCTAD World Investment Report 2015, accessed in February 6 th 2016, through

    http://unctad.org/en/PublicationsLibrary/wir2015_en.pdf29

    Galih Gumelar, Naik 20%, Investasi Asing di Indonesia Tertinggi di ASEAN, CNN Indonesia, June 25th

    2016,accessed through http://www.cnnindonesia.com/ekonomi/20150625010145-92-62208/naik-20-investasi-

    asing-di-indonesia-tertinggi-di-asean/

    http://unctad.org/en/PublicationsLibrary/wir2015_en.pdfhttp://unctad.org/en/PublicationsLibrary/wir2015_en.pdfhttp://www.cnnindonesia.com/ekonomi/20150625010145-92-62208/naik-20-investasi-asing-di-indonesia-tertinggi-di-asean/http://www.cnnindonesia.com/ekonomi/20150625010145-92-62208/naik-20-investasi-asing-di-indonesia-tertinggi-di-asean/http://www.cnnindonesia.com/ekonomi/20150625010145-92-62208/naik-20-investasi-asing-di-indonesia-tertinggi-di-asean/http://www.cnnindonesia.com/ekonomi/20150625010145-92-62208/naik-20-investasi-asing-di-indonesia-tertinggi-di-asean/http://www.cnnindonesia.com/ekonomi/20150625010145-92-62208/naik-20-investasi-asing-di-indonesia-tertinggi-di-asean/http://unctad.org/en/PublicationsLibrary/wir2015_en.pdf
  • 7/26/2019 Political Economy on Indonesia's Negative Investment List 2014

    15/16

    14

    an imbalance supply and demand which gains those who are being protected while burdens

    the more broader society. Besides, the restrictive measure without proper cost and benefit

    consideration will hinder the economic growth and ditch the the sectors which should pose

    greater benefits for the whole economy if they are optimally developed.

    At the end, this paper concludes that specific interest groups, media pressure, national

    perception towards FDI, and political concideration are the important factors which may lead

    the government towards the protectionist policy in Indonesia. In which, the implications of the

    protectionist policy in the name of national interest somehow does not nationally bring optimal

    benefits to the whole society, since it is proven to conversely compensate only specific groups

    within society with whom the government compromise its interests.

    Bibliography

    Books

    Oatley, Thomas.International Political Economy. US: Pearson Education Inc, 2012.

    Frieden, Jeffrey A. Actor and Preferences in International Relations in Strategic Choice in

    International Relations ed. David A. Lake and Robert Powell. New Jersey: Princeton

    University Press, 1999.

    Sornarajah, M. The International Law on Foreign investment. UK: Cambridge University

    Press, 2004.

    Journals

    Goodman, John B. Debora Spar and David B. Yoffie. Foreign Direct Investment and the

    Demand of the Protection in the US,International Organization 50 No. 4 (1996): 565591.

    Li, Quan and Adam Resnick. Reversal of Fortunes: Democratic Institutions and Foreign

    Direct Investment Inflows to Developing CountriesInternational Organization 57 No. 1

    (2003): 175211.

    Mayda, Anna Maria and Dani Rodrik. Why Are Some People (and Countries) MoreProtectionist Than Others?European Economic Review49 No. 6 (2005): 1393 - 1430.

    Pandya, Sonal S. Labor Market and the Demand for Foreign Direct InvestmentInternational

    Organization 64 No. 3(2010): 389409.

    Scheve, Kenneth F. and Matthew J. Slaughter. Labor Market Competition and Individual

    Preferences over Immigration Policy Review of Economics and Statistics83 No. 1 (2001):

    133145.

  • 7/26/2019 Political Economy on Indonesia's Negative Investment List 2014

    16/16

    15

    Reports

    Indonesia Economic Quarterly Report December 2013, accessed in February 1st2016, through

    http://www.worldbank.org/content/dam/Worldbank/document/EAP/Indonesia/IEQ-Dec13-

    ENGLISH.pdf

    UNCTAD World Investment Report 2014, accessed in February 1st 2016, through

    http://unctad.org/en/PublicationsLibrary/wir2014_en.pdf

    UNCTAD World Investment Report 2015, accessed in February 6 th 2016, through

    http://unctad.org/en/PublicationsLibrary/wir2015_en.pdf

    News and Website

    Djumena, Erlangga. Asing Semakin Mendominasi Ekonomi Indonesia, KOMPAS,

    November 7th2013,

    http://bisniskeuangan.kompas.com/read/2013/11/07/0756260/Asing.Semakin.Mendominasi.E

    konomi.Indonesia

    Gumelar, Galih. Naik 20%, Investasi Asing di Indonesia Tertinggi di ASEAN, CNN

    Indonesia, June 25th 2016, accessed through

    http://www.cnnindonesia.com/ekonomi/20150625010145-92-62208/naik-20-investasi-asing-

    di-indonesia-tertinggi-di-asean/

    International Finance Corporation World Bank Group,http://www.doingbusiness.org/

    Ministry of Finance Website, February 5th2015,http://www.kemenkeu.go.id/Berita/pdb-2014-

    mencapai-rp105427-triliun

    Sambijantoro, Satria. Door Widens for Foreign Investors,The Jakarta Post, November 7th

    2013, accessed through http://www.thejakartapost.com/news/2013/11/07/door-widens-

    foreign-investors.html

    Schreiben, Reiy Schreiben. Tingginya Biaya Logistik Dan Solusi Untuk Menekan Biaya

    Logistik Di Indonesia, Indonesian Logistic Association (Asosiasi Logistik Indonesia)

    Website, accessed on February 5th 2016 through

    http://www.ali.web.id/detail_article.php?id=69

    Taylor, Michael and Randy Faby. Foreign Investor Unhappy With Some Indonesias NewInvestment Rules, Reuters, May 14th 2014, http://www.reuters.com/article/indonesia-

    economy-investment-idUSL3N0NV3L920140514

    World Bank Website, High Logistics Costs Impede Higher Economic Growth For Indonesia,

    Says Joint Report, September 6th 2016, accessed through

    http://www.worldbank.org/en/news/press-release/2013/09/06/high-logistics-costs-impede-

    higher-economic-growth-for-indonesia

    Yusman, Linda.Retail, Distribution should be Put on Negative List: Apindo, The Jakarta

    Post, May 11th2013, accessed through

    http://www.thejakartapost.com/news/2013/05/11/retail-distribution-should-be-put-negative-list-apindo.html

    http://www.worldbank.org/content/dam/Worldbank/document/EAP/Indonesia/IEQ-Dec13-ENGLISH.pdfhttp://www.worldbank.org/content/dam/Worldbank/document/EAP/Indonesia/IEQ-Dec13-ENGLISH.pdfhttp://www.worldbank.org/content/dam/Worldbank/document/EAP/Indonesia/IEQ-Dec13-ENGLISH.pdfhttp://unctad.org/en/PublicationsLibrary/wir2014_en.pdfhttp://unctad.org/en/PublicationsLibrary/wir2014_en.pdfhttp://unctad.org/en/PublicationsLibrary/wir2015_en.pdfhttp://unctad.org/en/PublicationsLibrary/wir2015_en.pdfhttp://bisniskeuangan.kompas.com/read/2013/11/07/0756260/Asing.Semakin.Mendominasi.Ekonomi.Indonesiahttp://bisniskeuangan.kompas.com/read/2013/11/07/0756260/Asing.Semakin.Mendominasi.Ekonomi.Indonesiahttp://bisniskeuangan.kompas.com/read/2013/11/07/0756260/Asing.Semakin.Mendominasi.Ekonomi.Indonesiahttp://www.cnnindonesia.com/ekonomi/20150625010145-92-62208/naik-20-investasi-asing-di-indonesia-tertinggi-di-asean/http://www.cnnindonesia.com/ekonomi/20150625010145-92-62208/naik-20-investasi-asing-di-indonesia-tertinggi-di-asean/http://www.cnnindonesia.com/ekonomi/20150625010145-92-62208/naik-20-investasi-asing-di-indonesia-tertinggi-di-asean/http://www.doingbusiness.org/http://www.doingbusiness.org/http://www.doingbusiness.org/http://www.kemenkeu.go.id/Berita/pdb-2014-mencapai-rp105427-triliunhttp://www.kemenkeu.go.id/Berita/pdb-2014-mencapai-rp105427-triliunhttp://www.kemenkeu.go.id/Berita/pdb-2014-mencapai-rp105427-triliunhttp://www.kemenkeu.go.id/Berita/pdb-2014-mencapai-rp105427-triliunhttp://www.thejakartapost.com/news/2013/11/07/door-widens-foreign-investors.htmlhttp://www.thejakartapost.com/news/2013/11/07/door-widens-foreign-investors.htmlhttp://www.thejakartapost.com/news/2013/11/07/door-widens-foreign-investors.htmlhttp://www.ali.web.id/detail_article.php?id=69http://www.ali.web.id/detail_article.php?id=69http://www.reuters.com/article/indonesia-economy-investment-idUSL3N0NV3L920140514http://www.reuters.com/article/indonesia-economy-investment-idUSL3N0NV3L920140514http://www.reuters.com/article/indonesia-economy-investment-idUSL3N0NV3L920140514http://www.worldbank.org/en/news/press-release/2013/09/06/high-logistics-costs-impede-higher-economic-growth-for-indonesiahttp://www.worldbank.org/en/news/press-release/2013/09/06/high-logistics-costs-impede-higher-economic-growth-for-indonesiahttp://www.worldbank.org/en/news/press-release/2013/09/06/high-logistics-costs-impede-higher-economic-growth-for-indonesiahttp://www.thejakartapost.com/news/2013/05/11/retail-distribution-should-be-put-negative-list-apindo.htmlhttp://www.thejakartapost.com/news/2013/05/11/retail-distribution-should-be-put-negative-list-apindo.htmlhttp://www.thejakartapost.com/news/2013/05/11/retail-distribution-should-be-put-negative-list-apindo.htmlhttp://www.thejakartapost.com/news/2013/05/11/retail-distribution-should-be-put-negative-list-apindo.htmlhttp://www.thejakartapost.com/news/2013/05/11/retail-distribution-should-be-put-negative-list-apindo.htmlhttp://www.worldbank.org/en/news/press-release/2013/09/06/high-logistics-costs-impede-higher-economic-growth-for-indonesiahttp://www.worldbank.org/en/news/press-release/2013/09/06/high-logistics-costs-impede-higher-economic-growth-for-indonesiahttp://www.reuters.com/article/indonesia-economy-investment-idUSL3N0NV3L920140514http://www.reuters.com/article/indonesia-economy-investment-idUSL3N0NV3L920140514http://www.ali.web.id/detail_article.php?id=69http://www.thejakartapost.com/news/2013/11/07/door-widens-foreign-investors.htmlhttp://www.thejakartapost.com/news/2013/11/07/door-widens-foreign-investors.htmlhttp://www.kemenkeu.go.id/Berita/pdb-2014-mencapai-rp105427-triliunhttp://www.kemenkeu.go.id/Berita/pdb-2014-mencapai-rp105427-triliunhttp://www.doingbusiness.org/http://www.cnnindonesia.com/ekonomi/20150625010145-92-62208/naik-20-investasi-asing-di-indonesia-tertinggi-di-asean/http://www.cnnindonesia.com/ekonomi/20150625010145-92-62208/naik-20-investasi-asing-di-indonesia-tertinggi-di-asean/http://bisniskeuangan.kompas.com/read/2013/11/07/0756260/Asing.Semakin.Mendominasi.Ekonomi.Indonesiahttp://bisniskeuangan.kompas.com/read/2013/11/07/0756260/Asing.Semakin.Mendominasi.Ekonomi.Indonesiahttp://unctad.org/en/PublicationsLibrary/wir2015_en.pdfhttp://unctad.org/en/PublicationsLibrary/wir2014_en.pdfhttp://www.worldbank.org/content/dam/Worldbank/document/EAP/Indonesia/IEQ-Dec13-ENGLISH.pdfhttp://www.worldbank.org/content/dam/Worldbank/document/EAP/Indonesia/IEQ-Dec13-ENGLISH.pdf