option valuation with conditional … valuation with conditional heteroskedasticity and...

49
Option Valuation with Conditional Heteroskedasticity and Non-Normality Peter Christoersen Redouane Elkamhi McGill University and CREATES McGill University Bruno Feunou Kris Jacobs Université de Montréal McGill University and Tilburg March 18, 2008 Abstract We provide results for the valuation of European style contingent claims for a large class of specications of the underlying asset returns. Our valuation results obtain in a discrete time, innite state-space setup using an equivalent martingale measure and the no-arbitrage principle. Our approach allows for general forms of heteroskedasticity in returns, and valuation results for homoskedastic processes can be obtained as a special case. It also allows for conditional non-normal return innovations, which is critically important because heteroskedasticity alone does not suce to capture the option smirk. For the rich class of innitely divisible distributions we show that the risk-neutral return dynamics take the same distributional form as the physical return dynamics. Interestingly, non-normality drives a wedge between the physical and the risk-neutral variance which is in accordance with previous empirical observations. Our framework nests the valuation results obtained by Duan (1995) and Heston and Nandi (2000) by allowing for a time-varying price of risk and non-normal innovations. We provide extensions of our results to discrete time stochastic volatility models, and we analyze the relation between our results and those obtained for continuous time models. An empirical example demonstrates the usefulness of conditional non-normality for the modeling of the index option smirk. JEL Classication: G12 Keywords: GARCH; risk-neutral valuation; no-arbitrage; non-normal innovations Christoersen and Jacobs are also aliated with CIRANO and CIREQ and want to thank FQRSC, IFM 2 and SSHRC for nancial support. Elkamhi and Feunou were supported by grants from IFM 2 . For helpful comments we thank Tim Bollerslev, Mo Chaudhury, Rene Garcia, Tom McCurdy, Nour Meddahi, Karim Mimouni, Eric Renault, and Marcel Rindisbacher. Any remaining inadequacies are ours alone. Cor- respondence to: Peter Christoersen, Desautels Faculty of Management, McGill University, 1001 Sherbrooke Street West, Montreal, Quebec, Canada, H3A 1G5; Tel: (514) 398-2869; Fax: (514) 398-3876; E-mail: peter.christo[email protected]. 1

Upload: lythuy

Post on 24-Mar-2018

234 views

Category:

Documents


3 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Option Valuation with Conditional … Valuation with Conditional Heteroskedasticity and Non-Normality ∗ Peter Christoffersen Redouane Elkamhi McGill University and CREATES McGill

Option Valuation with Conditional Heteroskedasticityand Non-Normality∗

Peter Christoffersen Redouane ElkamhiMcGill University and CREATES McGill University

Bruno Feunou Kris JacobsUniversité de Montréal McGill University and Tilburg

March 18, 2008

Abstract

We provide results for the valuation of European style contingent claims for a largeclass of specifications of the underlying asset returns. Our valuation results obtain ina discrete time, infinite state-space setup using an equivalent martingale measure andthe no-arbitrage principle. Our approach allows for general forms of heteroskedasticityin returns, and valuation results for homoskedastic processes can be obtained as aspecial case. It also allows for conditional non-normal return innovations, which iscritically important because heteroskedasticity alone does not suffice to capture theoption smirk. For the rich class of infinitely divisible distributions we show that therisk-neutral return dynamics take the same distributional form as the physical returndynamics. Interestingly, non-normality drives a wedge between the physical and therisk-neutral variance which is in accordance with previous empirical observations. Ourframework nests the valuation results obtained by Duan (1995) and Heston and Nandi(2000) by allowing for a time-varying price of risk and non-normal innovations. Weprovide extensions of our results to discrete time stochastic volatility models, and weanalyze the relation between our results and those obtained for continuous time models.An empirical example demonstrates the usefulness of conditional non-normality for themodeling of the index option smirk.

JEL Classification: G12

Keywords: GARCH; risk-neutral valuation; no-arbitrage; non-normal innovations

∗Christoffersen and Jacobs are also affiliated with CIRANO and CIREQ and want to thank FQRSC,IFM2 and SSHRC for financial support. Elkamhi and Feunou were supported by grants from IFM2. Forhelpful comments we thank Tim Bollerslev, Mo Chaudhury, Rene Garcia, Tom McCurdy, Nour Meddahi,Karim Mimouni, Eric Renault, and Marcel Rindisbacher. Any remaining inadequacies are ours alone. Cor-respondence to: Peter Christoffersen, Desautels Faculty of Management, McGill University, 1001 SherbrookeStreet West, Montreal, Quebec, Canada, H3A 1G5; Tel: (514) 398-2869; Fax: (514) 398-3876; E-mail:[email protected].

1

Page 2: Option Valuation with Conditional … Valuation with Conditional Heteroskedasticity and Non-Normality ∗ Peter Christoffersen Redouane Elkamhi McGill University and CREATES McGill

1 Introduction

A contingent claim is a security whose payoff depends upon the value of another underlyingsecurity. A valuation relationship is an expression that relates the value of the contingentclaim to the value of the underlying security and other variables. The most popular approachfor valuing contingent claims is the use of a Risk Neutral Valuation Relationship (RNVR).Most of the literature on contingent claims andmost of the applications of the RNVR have

been cast in continuous time. While the continuous-time approach offers many advantages,the valuation of contingent claims in discrete time is also of substantial interest. For example,when hedging option positions, rebalancing decisions must be made in discrete time. In thecase of American and exotic options, early exercise decisions must be made in discrete timeas well. Moreover, as only discrete observations are available for empirical study, discretetime models are often more econometrically tractable.As a result, most of the stylized facts characterizing underlying securities have been

studied in discrete time models. One very important feature of returns is conditional het-eroskedasticity, which can be addressed in the GARCH framework of Engle (1982) andBollerslev (1986).1 Presumably, because of this evidence, most of the recent empirical workon discrete time option valuation has also focused on GARCH processes.2 The GARCHmodel amounts to an infinite state space setup, with the innovations for underlying assetreturns described by continuous distributions. In this case the market is incomplete, and itis in general not possible to construct a portfolio containing combinations of the contingentclaim and the underlying asset that make the resulting portfolio riskless.3

To obtain a RNVR, the GARCH option valuation literature builds on the approach ofRubinstein (1976) and Brennan (1979), who demonstrate how to obtain RNVRs for lognor-mal and normal returns in the case of constant mean return and volatility, by specifying arepresentative agent economy and characterizing sufficient conditions on preferences.4 For agiven dynamic of the underlying security, specific assumptions have to be made on prefer-ences in order to obtain a risk neutralization result. The first order condition resulting fromthis economy yields an Euler equation that can be used to price any asset. For lognormalstock returns and a conditionally heteroskedastic (GARCH) volatility dynamic, the standardresult is the one in Duan (1995). Duan’s result relies on the existence of a representativeagent with constant relative risk aversion or constant absolute risk aversion.5

1See for example French, Schwert and Stambaugh (1987) and Schwert (1989) for early studies on stockreturns. The literature is far too voluminous to cite all relevant papers here. See Bollerslev, Chou andKroner (1992) and Diebold and Lopez (1995) for reviews on GARCH modeling.

2See Bollerslev and Mikkelsen (1996), Satchell and Timmermann (1996), Garcia and Renault (1998),Heston and Nandi (2000), Christoffersen and Jacobs (2004), and Christoffersen, Heston and Jacobs (2006)for applications to option valuation.

3In a discrete time finite state space setting, Harrison and Pliska (1981) provide the mathematical frame-work to obtain the existence of the risk neutral probability measure, to demonstrate uniqueness in the caseof complete markets, and to get a RNVR for any contingent claim. See also Harrison and Kreps (1979),Cox, Ross and Rubinstein (1979) and Cox and Ross (1976) for discrete-time finite state-space approaches.

4Brennan (1979) characterizes the bivariate distribution of returns on aggregate wealth and the underlyingasset under which a risk-neutral valuation relationship obtains in the homoskedastic case. Camara (2003)uses this approach to obtain valuation results for transformed normal dynamics of returns and state variables.See also Schroder (2004).

5Amin and Ng (1993) also study the heteroskedastic case. Although they formulate the problem in termsof the economy’s stochastic discount factor, they start by making an assumption on the bivariate distribution

2

Page 3: Option Valuation with Conditional … Valuation with Conditional Heteroskedasticity and Non-Normality ∗ Peter Christoffersen Redouane Elkamhi McGill University and CREATES McGill

However, because it is difficult to characterize the general equilibrium setup underlying aRNVR, very few valuation results are currently available for heteroskedastic processes withnon-normal innovations.6 In this paper, we argue that it is possible to investigate optionvaluation for a large class of conditionally non-normal heteroskedastic processes, providedthat the conditional moment generating function exists. It is also possible to accommo-date a large class of time-varying risk premia. Our framework differs from the approach inBrennan (1979) and Duan (1995), and is more intimately related to the approach adoptedin continuous-time option valuation: we only use the no-arbitrage assumption and sometechnical conditions on the investment strategies to show the existence of an RNVR. Wedemonstrate the existence of an EMM and characterize it, without first making an explicitassumption on the utility function of a representative agent. We then show that the price ofthe contingent claim defined as the expected value of the discounted payoff at maturity is ano-arbitrage price and characterize the risk-neutral dynamic.Why are we able to provide more general valuation results than the existing literature?

In our opinion, the analysis in Brennan (1979) and Duan (1995) addresses two importantquestions simultaneously: First, a mostly technical question that characterizes the risk-neutral dynamic and the valuation of options; second, a more economic one that characterizesthe equilibrium underlying the valuation procedure. The existing discrete-time literature forthe most part has viewed these two questions as inextricably linked, and has therefore largelylimited itself to (log)normal return processes as well as a few special non-normal cases. Ourpaper differs in a subtle but important way from most of these studies. We argue thatit is possible and desirable to treat these questions one at a time. We do not attemptto characterize the bivariate distribution of preferences and returns that gives rise to therisk-neutral valuation relationship. Instead, we make the following two assumptions. First,we assume a class of Radon-Nikodym derivatives and search for the EMM within this class.Second, we specify the volatility risk premium. This allows us to provide some general resultson the valuation of options under conditionally non-normal asset returns without resortingto equilibrium techniques. We also show how the normal model and the available conditionalnon-normal models are special cases of our setup.The same approach to separate these two questions occurs in the literature on option

valuation using continuous-time stochastic volatility models, such as for instance in Heston’s(1993a) model. These models also yield different equivalent martingale measures for differentspecifications of the volatility risk premium. For a given specification of the volatility riskpremium, we can find an EMM and characterize the risk-neutral dynamic using Girsanov’stheorem. To derive this result, and to value options, there is no need to explicitly characterizethe utility function underlying the volatility risk premium. The latter task is very interestingin its own right, but differs from characterizing the risk-neutral dynamic and the option valuefor a given physical return dynamic.7 The latter is a purely mathematical exercise. Theformer provides the economic background behind a particular choice of volatility premium,and therefore helps us understand whether a particular choice of functional form for therisk premium, which is often made for convenience, is also reasonable from an economic

of the stochastic discount factor and the underlying return process.6Duan, Ritchken and Sun (2005) analyze a heteroskedastic model with Poisson-normal innovations and

Duan (1999) analyzes a conditionally fat-tailed heteroskedastic model. Christoffersen, Heston and Jacobs(2006) use a heteroskedastic return dynamic with inverse Gaussian innovations.

7See for instance Heston (1993a) and Bates (1996, 2000) for a discussion.

3

Page 4: Option Valuation with Conditional … Valuation with Conditional Heteroskedasticity and Non-Normality ∗ Peter Christoffersen Redouane Elkamhi McGill University and CREATES McGill

perspective.Our paper provides a set of tools that can be used to value options for a large class of

discrete-time return dynamics that are characterized by heteroskedasticity and non-normalinnovations. Whether this valuation exercise makes sense from an economic perspective de-pends on the nature of the assumed risk premium, and the general equilibrium setup thatgives rise to such risk premium. There are two questions: a mostly technical one that char-acterizes the risk-neutral dynamic and the valuation of options, and a more economic onethat characterizes the equilibrium underlying this valuation procedure. In our opinion, theexisting discrete-time literature for the most part has viewed these two questions as inex-tricably linked, and has therefore largely limited itself to (log)normal return processes. Weargue that it is possible and desirable to treat these questions one at a time, and we providenew results on the question of option valuation with conditionally non-normal returns.There is a growing literature that values options for discrete-time return dynamics with

non-normal innovations. A number of other papers obtain risk-neutral valuation relation-ships either under the maintained assumption of a specific kind of non-normal innovations,or under the maintained assumption of a particular form of heteroskedasticity, or both.8

Combining non-normality and heteroskedasticity attempts to correct the biases associatedwith the conditionally normal GARCH model. These biases are similar to those displayedby the Heston (1993) model, which the continuous-time literature has sought to remedy byadding (potentially correlated) jumps in returns and volatility. This paper is therefore alsorelated to empirical studies of jump models.9

The paper proceeds as follows. In Section 2 we define a class of heteroskedastic stockreturn processes, and we characterize the condition for an EMM for this class of processes.We then show sufficient conditions for an EMM to exist and we derive the risk neutraldistribution of returns. In Section 3 we derive the no-arbitrage option price corresponding tothe EMM. Section 4 discusses several special cases of return dynamics that can be analyzedusing our approach. Section 5 uses one of the special cases for an empirical illustration.Section 6 provides continuous time limits of some of the specific models. Section 7 introducesan extension to discrete time stochastic volatility models and discusses issues regardingoption price uniqueness in discrete and continuous time. Section 8 concludes.

2 Conditionally heteroskedastic models

We define the probability space (Ω,F, P ) to describe the physical distribution of the states ofnature. The financial market consists of a zero-coupon risk-free bond index and a stock. Thedynamics of the bond are described by the process BtTt=1 normalized to B0 = 1 and thedynamics of the stock price by StTt=1. The information structure is given by the filtrationF = Ft| t = 1, ..., T generated by the stock and the bond process.

8Madan and Seneta (1990) use the symmetric and i.i.d. variance gamma distribution. Heston (1993b)presents results for the gamma distribution and Heston (2004) analyzes a number of infinitely divisible distri-butions. Camara (2003) uses a transformed normal innovation and Duan (1999) uses a heteroskedastic modelwith a transformed normal innovation. Christoffersen, Heston and Jacobs (2006) analyze a heteroskedasticreturn process with inverse Gaussian innovations.

9See for example Bakshi, Cao and Chen (1997), Bates (2000), Broadie, Chernov and Johannes (2006),Carr and Wu (2004), Eraker, Johannes and Polson (2003), Eraker (2004), Huang and Wu (2004) and Pan(2002).

4

Page 5: Option Valuation with Conditional … Valuation with Conditional Heteroskedasticity and Non-Normality ∗ Peter Christoffersen Redouane Elkamhi McGill University and CREATES McGill

2.1 The stock price process

The underlying stock price process is assumed to follow the conditional distribution D underthe physical measure P . We write

Rt ≡ lnµ

StSt−1

¶= μt − γt + εt εt|Ft−1 ∼ D(0, σ2t ) (2.1)

where St is the stock price at time t, and σ2t is the conditional variance of the log return inperiod t. The mean correction factor, γt, is defined from

exp (γt) ≡ Et−1 [exp (εt)]

and it serves to ensure that the conditional expected gross rate of return, Et−1 [St/St−1], isequal to exp(μt). More explicitly,

Et−1 [St/St−1] = Et−1 [exp (μt − γt + εt)] = exp(μt)

⇐⇒ exp(γt) = Et−1 [exp (εt)]

Note that our specification (2.1) does not restrict the risk premium in any way nor does itassume conditional normality.We follow most of the existing discrete-time empirical finance literature by focusing on

conditional means μt and conditional variances σ2t that are Ft−1 measurable. We do not

constrain the interest rate rt to be constant. It is instead assumed to be an element of Ft−1as well. Our framework is able to accommodate the class of ARCH and GARCH processesproposed by Engle (1982) and Bollerslev (1986) and used for option valuation by Amin andNg (1993), Duan (1995, 1999), and Heston and Nandi (2000). Our results also hold fordifferent types of GARCH specifications, such as the EGARCH model of Nelson (1991) orthe specification of Glosten, Jagannathan and Runkle (1993).In the following, we show that we can find an EMM by defining a probability measure

that makes the discounted security process a martingale. We derive more general results onoption valuation for heteroskedastic processes compared to the available literature, becausewe focus on the narrow question of option valuation while ignoring the economic questionregarding the preferences of the representative agent that support this valuation argumentin equilibrium.We use a no-arbitrage argument that is similar to the one used in the continuous-time lit-

erature. We first prove the existence of an EMM. Subsequently we demonstrate the existenceof a RNVR by demonstrating that the price of the contingent claim, defined as the expectedvalue of the discounted payoff at maturity, is a no-arbitrage price under this EMM.10 Theproof uses an argument similar to the one used in the continuous-time literature, but isarguably more straightforward as it avoids the technical issues involved in the analysis oflocal and super martingales.

10Duan (1995) refers to RNVR as Local RNVR in the case of GARCH. The reason for the distinction isthat the conditional volatility is identical under the two measures only one period ahead. In the remainderof the paper we will drop this distinction for ease of exposition. We emphasize that the result that theconditional volatility differs between the two measures for more than one period ahead is to be expected asvolatility is random in this case. This feature is very similar to the continuous time case, which has randomvolatility for any horizon.

5

Page 6: Option Valuation with Conditional … Valuation with Conditional Heteroskedasticity and Non-Normality ∗ Peter Christoffersen Redouane Elkamhi McGill University and CREATES McGill

2.2 Specifying an equivalent martingale measure

The objective in this section is to find a measure equivalent to the physical measure Pthat makes the price of the stock discounted by the riskless asset a martingale. An EMMis defined as long as the Radon-Nikodym derivative is defined. We start by specifying acandidate Radon-Nikodym derivative of a probability measure. We then show that thisRadon-Nikodym derivative defines an EMM that makes the discounted stock price process amartingale. This result in turn allows us to obtain the distribution of the stock return underthis EMM.For a given sequence of a random variable, νt, we define the following candidate Radon-

Nikodym derivativedQ

dP

¯Ft = exp

Ã−

tXi=1

(νiεi +Ψi (νi))

!(2.2)

where Ψt (u) is defined as the natural logarithm of the moment generating function

Et−1 [exp(−uεt)] ≡ exp (Ψt (u))

Note that we can think of the mean correction factor in (2.1) as γt = Ψt (−1). Note alsothat in the normal case we have Ψt (u) =

12σ2tu

2 and γt = Ψt (−1) = 12σ2t .

We can now show the following lemma

Lemma 1 dQdP

¯Ft is a Radon-Nikodym derivative

Proof. We need to show that dQdP

¯Ft > 0 which is immediate. We also need to show that

EP0

£dQdP

¯Ft

¤= 1. We have

EP0

∙dQ

dP

¯Ft

¸= EP

0

"exp

Ã−

tXi=1

(νiεi +Ψi (νi))

!#.

Using the law of iterative expectations we can write

EP0

∙dQ

dP

¯Ft

¸= EP

0

"EP1 ...E

Pt−1 exp

Ã−

tXi=1

(νiεi +Ψi (νi))

!#

= EP0

"EP1 ...E

Pt−2 exp

Ã−

t−1Xi=1

νiεi −tX

i=1

Ψi (νi)

!EPt−1 exp (−νtεt)

#

= EP0

"EP1 ...E

Pt−2 exp

Ã−

t−1Xi=1

νiεi+1 −tX

i=1

Ψi (νi)

!exp (Ψt (νt))

#

= EP0

"EP1 ...E

Pt−2 exp

Ã−

t−1Xi=1

νiεi −t−1Xi=1

Ψi (νi)

!#Iteratively, using this result we get

EP0

∙dQ

dP

¯Ft

¸= EP

0 [exp (−ν1ε1 −Ψ1 (ν1))]

= exp (−Ψ1 (ν1)) exp (Ψ1 (ν1))

= 1

6

Page 7: Option Valuation with Conditional … Valuation with Conditional Heteroskedasticity and Non-Normality ∗ Peter Christoffersen Redouane Elkamhi McGill University and CREATES McGill

and the lemma obtains.

We are now ready to show that we can specify an EMM using this Radon-Nikodymderivative.

Proposition 1 The probability measure Q defined by the Radon-Nikodym derivative in (2.2)is an EMM if and only if

Ψt (νt − 1)−Ψt (νt)− γt + αtσ2t = 0

where αt =μt − rtσ2t

.

Proof. We need EQ

∙StBt

¯Ft−1

¸=

St−1Bt−1

or equivalently EQ

∙StSt−1

/Bt

Bt−1

¯Ft−1

¸= 1. We

have

EQ

∙StSt−1

/Bt

Bt−1

¯Ft−1

¸= EP

"ÃdQdP

¯Ft

dQdP

¯Ft−1

!StSt−1

/Bt

Bt−1

¯¯Ft−1

#

= EP

"ÃdQdP

¯Ft

dQdP

¯Ft−1

!StSt−1

exp(−rt)¯¯Ft−1

#= EP [exp (−νtεt −Ψt (νt)) exp(μt − γt + εt) exp(−rt)|Ft−1]= exp (−Ψt (νt) + μt − rt − γt)E

P [exp ((1− νt) εt) |Ft−1]

= exp (−Ψt (νt) + μt − rt − γt +Ψt (νt − 1))= exp(Ψt (νt − 1)−Ψt (νt)−Ψt (−1) + αtσ

2t )

Thus Q is a probability measure that makes the stock discounted by a riskless asset amartingale if and only if

Ψt (νt − 1)−Ψt (νt)− γt + αtσ2t = 0 (2.3)

This result implies that we can construct an EMM by choosing the sequence, νt, to make(2.3) hold.

2.3 Solving for the EMM

In this section we develop various results on the existence of a solution to (2.3).Note first that in the conditional normal special case we get the solution to be the well-

known price of risk νt = αt = (μt − rt) /σ2t . Note also that if we additionally specify the

conditional mean of the excess return to be affine in σ2t , so that μt = rt+λσ2t , νt is a constant,

namely the price of risk λ.When allowing for conditional non-normal returns, a multitude of possible return distri-

butions and thus Ψt (.) functions are possible, and we need to put some structure on Ψt (.)in order to analyze the existence of a solution to (2.3). In Section 4 below we consider someimportant non-normal special cases where an explicit solution for νt can be found. In themore general case, we provide the following result.

7

Page 8: Option Valuation with Conditional … Valuation with Conditional Heteroskedasticity and Non-Normality ∗ Peter Christoffersen Redouane Elkamhi McGill University and CREATES McGill

Proposition 2 If Ψ is strictly convex, twice differentiable, and tends to infinity at the bound-aries of its domain (u1, u2) where u1+1 < u2, then there exists a unique solution to equation(2.3).

Proof. See the Appendix.Proposition 2 provides a set of sufficient conditions for a unique solution to exist but the

conditions are not necessary. For example, a similar result can be obtained assuming thatΨ is strictly concave. For the class of infinitely divisible distributions we will consider belowthat strict convexity holds (Feller, 1968) and so we show the above proof for this case.11

In the absence of these types of sufficient conditions, we can find an explicit approximatesolution to the EMM equation in (2.3) from the second-order approximations

Ψt (νt − 1) ≈ Ψt (0) +Ψ0t (0) (vt − 1) + 12Ψ00t (0) (vt − 1)2

Ψt (νt) ≈ Ψt (0) +Ψ0t (0) vt +12Ψ00t (0) v

2t

By definition of the mean-zero shock εt we have that Ψ0t (0) = 0, and Ψ

00t (0) = σ2t so that the

approximation along with the EMM condition in (2.3) gives us

vt ≈ μt − rtσ2t

+1

2− γt

σ2t(2.4)

Notice that this approximation is exact in the normal case where γt =12σ2t and νt =

(μt − rt) /σ2t . This approximate solution can be used in place of the exact solution, or it

can be used as a starting value in a numerical search for the exact vt.Note finally that equation (2.3) suggests that if one is willing to put more structure on

the return process in (2.1) then the problem of finding a solution for νt can be circumventedaltogether. Denote the risk premium, μt− rt, by πt. Then if the return dynamic is specifiedsuch that

Rt = rt + πt − γt + εt εt|Ft−1 ∼ D(0, σ2t )

whereπt = Ψt (νt)−Ψt (νt − 1) + γt (2.5)

then the EMM condition in (2.3) is trivially satisfied for any value of vt. Thus vt can be setto a constant parameter, v, to be estimated as part of the return dynamic. This approachis viable but suffers from the drawback that the return mean dynamic is now chosen forconvenience rather than for empirical relevance. Note that in the normal case this approachyields

Rt = rt +Ψt (ν)−Ψt (ν − 1) + εt εt|Ft−1 ∼ N(0, σ2t )

= rt + vσ2t + εt εt|Ft−1 ∼ N(0, σ2t )

which corresponds to an affine risk-premium.

11Gourieroux and Monfort (2007) found a similar result in the context of the specification of a stochasticdiscount factor. They do not relate their result to the class of inifinitely divisible distributions.

8

Page 9: Option Valuation with Conditional … Valuation with Conditional Heteroskedasticity and Non-Normality ∗ Peter Christoffersen Redouane Elkamhi McGill University and CREATES McGill

2.4 Characterizing the risk-neutral distribution

When pricing options using Monte Carlo simulation, knowing the risk neutral distributionis valuable. In this section, we derive an important result that shows that for the class ofmodels we investigate, the risk neutral distribution is from the same family as the originalphysical distribution.We first need the following lemma, where we recall that Ψt (u), denotes the one-day log

conditional moment generating function of the innovation εt

Lemma 2EQt−1 [exp (−uεt)] = exp (Ψt (νt + u)−Ψt (νt))

Proof.

EQt−1 [exp (−uεt)] = EP

"ÃdQdP|Ft

dQdP|Ft−1

!exp(−uεt)|Ft−1

#= EP [exp (−νtεt −Ψt (νt)) exp(−uεt)|Ft−1]

= exp (Ψt (νt + u)−Ψt (νt))

From this lemma, if we defineΨQt (u) to be the log conditional moment generating function

of εt under the risk neutral probability measure, then we have

ΨQt (u) = Ψt (νt + u)−Ψt (νt) (2.6)

From this we can derive

EQt−1 [εt] =

∂ΨQt (−u)∂u

¯¯u=0

= −Ψ0t (νt)

which represents the risk premium. Define the risk neutral innovation

ε∗t ≡ εt −EQt−1 [εt] = εt +Ψ0t (νt) (2.7)

The risk-neutral log-conditional moment generating function of ε∗t , labeled ΨQ∗t−1 (u), is

thenΨQ∗t (u) = −uΨ0

t (νt) +ΨQt (u) (2.8)

We are now ready to show the following

Proposition 3 If the physical conditional distribution of εt is an infinitely divisible distrib-ution with finite second moment, then the risk-neutral conditional distribution of ε∗t is alsoan infinitely divisible distribution with finite second moment.

Proof. See the Appendix.In the special case of the normal distribution we get simply

ε∗t = εt +Ψ0t (νt) = εt + μt − rt

9

Page 10: Option Valuation with Conditional … Valuation with Conditional Heteroskedasticity and Non-Normality ∗ Peter Christoffersen Redouane Elkamhi McGill University and CREATES McGill

andΨQ∗t (u) =

1

2σ2tu

2

so that the risk-neutral innovations are normal and correspond to the physical shifted bythe equity risk premium. In the more general case the relationship will not necessarily be sosimple.Because of the one-to-one mapping between moment generating functions and distribu-

tion functions, this result can be used to derive specific parametric risk-neutral distributionscorresponding to the parametric physical distributions assumed by the researcher.

2.5 Characterizing the risk-neutral conditional variance

The conditional risk-neutral variance, σ∗2t is of particular interest in the dynamic het-eroskedastic models we consider. It can be obtained by taking the second order derivativeof the risk neutral log moment generating function ΨQ∗

t (u) and evaluating it at u = 0. Wecan write

σ∗2t =∂2ΨQ∗

t (u)

∂u2

¯¯u=0

Using equation (2.8) and (2.6) we get

σ∗2t =∂2ΨQ

t (u)

∂u2

¯¯u=0

=∂2Ψt (vt + u)

∂u2

¯u=0

= Ψ00t (νt)

Recall that by definition, the conditional variance under the physical measure is

σ2t = Ψ00t (0)

Thus in general we have the following relationship between conditional variance under thetwo measures

σ∗2t = σ2tΨ00t (νt)Ψ00t (0)

In the case of conditionally normal returns, we haveΨt (u) =12σ2tu

2 and νt = (μt − rt) /σ2t ,

so that Ψ00t (νt) = Ψ00

t (0) and thus σ∗2t = σ2t but this will not be true in general for non-normal

distributions. Non-normality will drive a wedge between the physical and risk-neutral con-ditional variances. This phenomenon is often observed empirically, as physical volatilitymeasures from historical returns are systematically lower than risk-neutral volatilities im-plied from options. See for example Carr and Wu (2007). We will give explicit examplesof non-normal distributions that generate this interesting and important empirical featurebelow.

3 The valuation of European style contingent claims

We have demonstrated in a general return model with time-varying conditional mean andvolatility and non-normal shocks, conditions under which there exists an EMMQ that makesthe stock discounted by the riskless asset a martingale.

10

Page 11: Option Valuation with Conditional … Valuation with Conditional Heteroskedasticity and Non-Normality ∗ Peter Christoffersen Redouane Elkamhi McGill University and CREATES McGill

We now turn our attention to the pricing of European style contingent claims. Existingpapers on the pricing of contingent claims in a discrete-time infinite state space setup, suchas the literature on GARCH option pricing in Duan (1995), Amin and Ng (1993) and Hestonand Nandi (2000) value such contingent claims by making an assumption on the bivariatedistribution of the stock return and the endowment, or an equivalent assumption. Whilethis approach, which most often amounts to the characterization of the equilibrium thatsupports the pricing, is an elegant way to deal with the incompleteness that characterizesthese markets, we argue that it is not strictly necessary to characterize the equilibrium.Instead, we adopt an approach which is more prevalent in the continuous-time literature,and proceed to pricing derivatives using a no-arbitrage argument alone.To understand our approach, the analogy with option valuation for the stochastic volatil-

ity model of Heston (1993a) is particularly helpful. In this incomplete markets setting, aninfinity of no-arbitrage contingent claims prices exist, one for every different specification ofthe price of risk. When one fixes the price of volatility risk, however, there is a unique no-arbitrage price. For the purpose of option valuation, one can simply pick a price of volatilityrisk, and the resulting valuation exercise is purely mechanical.The question whether a particular price of risk is reasonable is of substantial interest

in its own right, and an analysis of the representative agent utility function that support aparticular price of risk is very valuable. However, this question can be analyzed separatelyfrom the option valuation problem. For the heteroskedastic discrete-time models we consider,a similar remark applies. We can value options provided we specify the price of risk. The linkbetween our approach and the utility-based approach in Brennan (1979), Rubinstein (1976)and Duan (1995) is that assumptions on the utility function are implicit in the specificationof the risk premium in the return dynamic in our case.12 The representative agent preferencesunderlying this assumption are of interest, but it is not necessary to analyze them in orderto value options. Of course, we note that the main difference with the continuous-timestochastic volatility models is that GARCH models are one-shock models, and that thereforethere is only one price of risk.We have already found an EMM Q. We therefore want to demonstrate that the price at

time t is defined as

Ct = EQ

∙CT (ST )

BTBt

¯Ft

¸.

The proof proceeds in a number of steps and requires defining a number of conceptsthat are well-known in the literature. Fortunately, even though our methodology closelyfollows the continuous-time case, we economize on the number of technical conditions in thecontinuous-time setup, such as admissibility, and avoid the concepts of local martingale andsuper martingale. The reason is that the integration over an infinite number of trading timesin the continuous-time case is replaced by a finite sum over the trading days in discrete time.

Definitions

1. We denote by ηt, δt and ψt the units of the stock, the contingent claim and the bondheld at date t. We refer to the Ft predictable processes ηt, δt and ψt as investment

12See Bick (1990) and He and Leland (1993) for a discussion of assumptions on the utility function implicitin the specification of the return dynamic for the market portfolio. We proceed along the lines of Jacob andShiryaev (1998), and Shiryaev (1999).

11

Page 12: Option Valuation with Conditional … Valuation with Conditional Heteroskedasticity and Non-Normality ∗ Peter Christoffersen Redouane Elkamhi McGill University and CREATES McGill

strategies.

2. The value processVt = ηtSt + δtCt + ψtBt

describes the total dollar amount available for investments at date t.

3. The gain process

Gt =t−1Xi=0

ηi(Si+1 − Si) +t−1Xi=0

δi(Ci+1 − Ci) +t−1Xi=0

ψi(Bi+1 −Bi).

captures the total financial gains between dates 0 and t.

4. We call the process ηt, δt, ψtT−1t=0 a self financing strategy if and only if Vt = Gt

∀t = 1, ..., T.5. The definition of an arbitrage opportunity is standard: we have an arbitrage opportu-nity if a self financing strategy exists with either V0 < 0, VT ≥ 0 a.s. or V0 ≤ 0, VT > 0a.s.

6. We denote the discounted stock price at time t as SBt =

StBtand the discounted con-

tingent claim as CBt =

CtBt. Similarly, the discounted value process is denoted V B

t = VtBt

and the discounted gain process GBt =

Gt

Bt.

Note that for a self financing strategy, we have V Bt = GB

t because Vt = Gt and Bt > 0.Furthermore, we can show the following.

Lemma 3 For a self financing strategy we have

GBt =

t−1Xi=0

ηi(SBi+1 − SB

i ) +t−1Xi=0

δi(CBi+1 − CB

i ) ∀t = 1, ..., T

Proof. The proof involves straightforward but somewhat cumbersome algebraic manipula-tions of the above definitions. See the Appendix for the details.

We know that under the EMM we defined, the stock discounted by the risk free asset is amartingale. We now need to show that the contingent claims prices obtained by computingthe expected value of the final payoff discounted by the risk free asset also constitute amartingale under this EMM.

Lemma 4 The stochastic process defined by the discounted values of the candidate contingentclaims prices is an Ft martingale under the EMM.

Proof. We defined our candidate process for the contingent claims price under the EMMas Ct = EQ

hCT (ST )BT

Bt

¯Ft

i. The process for the discounted values of the contingent claims

prices is then defined as

CBt ≡

Ct

Bt= EQ

∙CT (ST )

BT

¯Ft

¸12

Page 13: Option Valuation with Conditional … Valuation with Conditional Heteroskedasticity and Non-Normality ∗ Peter Christoffersen Redouane Elkamhi McGill University and CREATES McGill

We use the fact that the conditional expectation itself is a Q martingale. This in turnfollows from the law of iterated expectations and the European style payoff function. Takingconditional expectations with respect to Fs on both sides of the above equation yields

EQ

∙Ct

Bt

¯Fs

¸= EQ

∙EQ

∙CT (ST )

BT

¯Ft

¸¯Fs

¸∀t > s

Now using the law of iterated expectations we get

EQ

∙Ct

Bt

¯Fs

¸= EQ

∙CT (ST )

BT

¯Fs

¸=

Cs

Bs= CB

s ∀t > s

which gives the desired result.

Lemma 5 Under the EMM defined by (2.2), the discounted gain process is a martingale.

Proof. Under the EMM Q, the process©SBt

ªTt=1

is a Q martingale. Using a standardproperty of martingales the process defined as SSB

t =Pt−1

i=0 ηi(SBi+1 − SB

i ) then is a Q mar-tingale, since the investment strategy ηt is included in the information set.

13 Furthermore,from Lemma 3 we get that

©CBt

ªTt=1

is also a Q martingale. Then using the fact that δt isan Ft predetermined process and using the same martingale property as above we get thatthe process CCB

t =Pt−1

i=0 δi(CBi+1 − CB

i ) is a Q martingale. Then since from Lemma 2 thediscounted gain process

©GBt

ªTt=1is the sum of two Q martingales, SSB

t and CCBt , it is itself

a Q martingale.

At this stage, we have all the ingredients to show the following main result.

Proposition 4 If we have an EMM that makes the discounted price of the stock a martin-gale, then defining the price of any contingent claim as the expected value of its payoff, takenunder this EMM and discounted at the riskless interest rate, constitutes a no-arbitrage price.

Proof. From Lemma 4 GBt is a Q martingale. Because we are considering self financing

strategies we get that V Bt is a martingale. We prove the absence of arbitrage by contradiction.

If we assume the existence of an arbitrage opportunity, then there exists a self financingstrategy with type 1 arbitrage (V0 < 0, VT ≥ 0 a.s.) or type 2 arbitrage (V0 ≤ 0, VT > 0a.s.). Both cases lead to a clear contradiction. Consider type 1 arbitrage: we start from theexistence of a self financing strategy with V0 < 0 that ends up with a positive final value.V0 < 0 implies that V B

0 < 0 since the numeraire is always positive by definition. Also sinceVT ≥ 0 we have V B

T ≥ 0. Taking expectations and using the fact that V Bt is a Q martingale

yields V B0 = EQ

0 [VBT ] ≥ 0. This is a contradiction because we assumed that we start with

a negative value V0 < 0. A similar argument works for type 2 arbitrage. Thus, the Ct fromthe EMM Q must be a no-arbitrage price.

In summary, we have demonstrated that in a discrete-time infinite state space setting,if we have an EMM that makes the underlying asset price a martingale, then the expected

13Note that because we are working in discrete time there is no need to investigate the integrability ofSSBt .

13

Page 14: Option Valuation with Conditional … Valuation with Conditional Heteroskedasticity and Non-Normality ∗ Peter Christoffersen Redouane Elkamhi McGill University and CREATES McGill

value of the payoff of the contingent claim taken under this EMM, discounted at the risklessasset, is a no-arbitrage price. In Section 2.2, we derived such an EMM. Altogether, wehave therefore demonstrated that for any contingent claim paying a final payoff CT (ST ) thecurrent price Ct can be computed as

Ct = EQ

∙CT (ST )

BTBt

¯Ft

¸.

4 Important special cases

In this section we demonstrate how a number of existing models are nested in our setup. Wealso give an example of a model that has not yet been discussed in the literature but can behandled by our setup.

4.1 Flexible risk premium specifications

One of the advantages of our approach is that we can allow for time-varying risk premia. Herewe discuss some potentially interesting ways to specify the risk premium in the return processfor the underlying asset. In order to demonstrate the link with the available literature and forcomputational simplicity, we assume conditional normal returns, although this assumptionis by no means necessary.The conditional normal models in the Duan (1995) and Heston and Nandi (2000) models

are special cases of our set-up. In our notation, Duan (1995) assumes

rt = r, and μt = r + λσt

which in our framework corresponds to a Radon-Nikodym derivative of

dQ

dP

¯Ft = exp

Ã−

tXi=1

µεiσiλ− 1

2λ2¶!

and risk neutral innovations of the form

ε∗t = εt + λσt.

Heston and Nandi (2000) instead assume

rt = r, and μt = r + λσ2t +1

2σ2t

which in our framework corresponds to a Radon-Nikodym derivative of

dQ

dP

¯Ft = exp

Ã−

tXi=1

õλ+

1

2

¶εi − 1

2

µλ+

1

2

¶2σ2i

!!and risk neutral innovations of the form

ε∗t = εt + λσ2t +1

2σ2t .

14

Page 15: Option Valuation with Conditional … Valuation with Conditional Heteroskedasticity and Non-Normality ∗ Peter Christoffersen Redouane Elkamhi McGill University and CREATES McGill

However, many empirically relevant cases are not covered by existing theoretical results.For example, in the original ARCH-M paper, Engle, Lilien and Robins (1987) find thestrongest empirical support for a risk premium specification of the form

μt = rt + λ ln (σt) +12σ2t

which cannot be used for option valuation using the available theory. In our framework itsimply corresponds to a Radon-Nikodym derivative of

dQ

dP

¯Ft = exp

Ã−

tXi=1

Ãλ ln (σi) +

12σ2i

σ2iεi − 1

2

µλ ln (σi) +

12σ2i

σ2i

¶2σ2i

!!and risk neutral innovations

ε∗t = εt + λ ln (σt) +12σ2t

Our approach allows for option valuation under such specifications whereas the existingliterature does not.

4.2 Conditionally inverse Gaussian returns

Christoffersen, Heston and Jacobs (2006) analyze a GARCH model with an inverse Gaussianinnovation, yt ∼ IG(σ2t/η

2). We can write their return dynamic as

Rt = r +¡ζ + η−1

¢σ2t + εt (4.1)

where εt is a zero-mean innovation defined by

εt = ηyt − η−1σ2t

and where the conditional return variance, σ2t , is of the GARCH form.From the MGF of an inverse Gaussian variable, we can derive the conditional log MGF

of εt as

Ψt (u) =

µu+

1−√1 + 2uηη

¶σ2tη

The EMM condition

Ψt (νt − 1)−Ψt (νt)−Ψt (−1) + αtσ2t = 0

is now solved by the constant

νt = ν =1

"(2 + ζη3)

2

4ζ2η2− 1#,∀t

which in turn implies that the EMM is given by

dQ

dP

¯Ft = exp

Ã−

tXi=1

µνεi +

µν +

1−√1 + 2νηη

¶σ2iη

¶!= exp

³−νtεt − δtσ2t

´15

Page 16: Option Valuation with Conditional … Valuation with Conditional Heteroskedasticity and Non-Normality ∗ Peter Christoffersen Redouane Elkamhi McGill University and CREATES McGill

where εt = 1t

Pti=1 εi, σ

2t =

1t

Pti=1 σ

2i , and δ = ν

η+ 1−√1+2νη

η2.

These expressions can be used to obtain the risk-neutral distribution from Christoffersen,Heston and Jacobs (2006) using the results in Section 2. Recall that in general the risk neutrallog MGF is

ΨQ∗t (u) = −uΨ0

t (ν) +Ψt (ν + u)−Ψt (ν)

In the GARCH-IG case we can write

ΨQ∗t (u) =

µu+

1−√1 + 2uη∗η∗

¶σ∗2tη∗

where

η∗ =η

1 + 2νηand

σ∗2t =σ2t

(1 + 2νη)3/2

So that the risk-neutral variance in general will be different from the physical variance.The risk neutral return model can be written as

Rt ≡ lnµ

StSt−1

¶= r −ΨQ∗

t (−1) + ε∗t = r +¡ζ∗ + η∗−1

¢σ∗2t + ε∗t

where

ζ∗ =1− 2η∗ −√1− 2η∗

η∗2and

ε∗t = η∗y∗t − η∗−1σ∗2t

The risk neutral process thus takes the same form as the physical process which is exactlywhat our Proposition 3 in Section 2.4 shows.

4.3 Conditionally Poisson-normal jumps

Another interesting model that can be nested in our framework is the heteroskedastic modelwith Poisson-normal innovations in Duan, Ritchken and Sun (2005).14 For expositional sim-plicity, we consider the simplest version of the model. More complex models, for instancewith time-varying Poisson intensities, can also be accommodated. We can write the under-lying asset return as

Rt = κt + εt

The zero-mean innovation εt equals

εt = σt (Jt − λμ)

where Jt is a Poisson jump process with Nt jumps each with distribution N (μ, γ2) and jumpintensity λ. The conditional return variance equals (1 + λ (μ2 + γ2))σ2t , where σ

2t is of the

14Maheu and McCurdy (2004) consider a different discrete-time jump model.

16

Page 17: Option Valuation with Conditional … Valuation with Conditional Heteroskedasticity and Non-Normality ∗ Peter Christoffersen Redouane Elkamhi McGill University and CREATES McGill

GARCH form. The log return mean κt is a function of σ2t as well as the jump and riskpremium parameters.We can derive the conditional log MGF of εt as

Ψt (u) = ln(Et−1 [exp (−uσt (Jt − λμ))])

= uλμσt +1

2u2σ2t + λ

∙exp

µ−μuσt + 1

2γ2u2σ2t

¶− 1¸

The approach taken in Duan et al (2005) corresponds to fixing νt = ν and setting

κt = r +Ψt (ν)−Ψt (ν − 1)

which in turn implies that the EMM is given by

dQ

dP

¯Ft = exp

Ã−νtεt − νλμtσt − 1

2tν2σ2t + λt− λ

tXi=1

exp

µ−μνiσi + 1

2γ2ν2iσ

2i

¶!

where εt and σ2t are the historical averages as above.We can again show that the risk-neutral distribution of the risk neutral innovation is

from the same family as the physical

ΨQ∗t (u) = lnEQ

t−1 [exp (−uε∗t )]= uλ∗tμ

∗tσt +

1

2u2σ2t + λ∗t

∙exp

µ−μ∗tuσt +

1

2γ2u2σ2t

¶− 1¸

where

λ∗t = λ exp

µ−μνσt + 1

2γ2ν2σ2t

¶and μ∗t = μ− γ2σtν

Note that in this model the mapping between the risk-neutral and physical returns is

ε∗t = εt +Ψ0t (ν) = εt + σt (λμ− λ∗tμ∗t )

and the mapping between the physical and risk-neutral conditional variance is

σ∗2t = σ2t + λ∗tσ2t

¡γ2 + μ∗2t

¢4.4 Conditionally skewed variance gamma returns

We now introduce a new model where the conditional skewness, s, and excess kurtosis, k,are given directly by two parameters in the model.15 Consider the return of the underlyingasset specified as follows

Rt = μt − γt + εt

= μt − γt + σtzt, zti.i.d∼ SV G(0, 1, s, k)

15In Christoffersen, Heston and Jacobs (2006), conditional skewness and kurtosis are driven by functionsof the same parameter.

17

Page 18: Option Valuation with Conditional … Valuation with Conditional Heteroskedasticity and Non-Normality ∗ Peter Christoffersen Redouane Elkamhi McGill University and CREATES McGill

The distribution of the shocks, SV G(0, 1, s, k), is a standardized skewed variance gammadistribution which is constructed as a mixture of two gamma variables.16 The conditionalvariance, σ2t , can take on any GARCH specification. We will provide an empirical illustrationin the next section using a leading GARCH dynamic.Let z1 and z2 be independent draws from two gamma distributions

zi,ti.i.d∼ Γ

¡4/τ 2i

¢, i = 1, 2

parameterized as

τ 1 =√2

Ãs−

r2

3k − s2

!and τ 2 =

√2

Ãs+

r2

3k − s2

!If we construct the SVG random variable from the two gamma variables as

zt =1

2√2(τ 1z1,t + τ 2z2,t)−

√2

µ1

τ 1+1

τ 2

¶then zt will have a mean of zero, a variance of one, a skewness of s, and an excess kurtosis ofk, thus allowing for conditional skewness and kurtosis in the GARCH model, as intended.17

The log moment generating function of εt can be derived from the gamma distributionMGF as

Ψt (u) =√2¡τ−11 + τ−12

¢uσt − 4τ−21 ln

µ1 +

1

2√2τ 1uσt

¶− 4τ−22 ln

µ1 +

1

2√2τ 2uσt

¶so that the mean correction variable, γt, for the return can be found as γt = Ψt(−1).Using the formula for the risk neutral conditional log MGF

ΨQ∗t (u) = −uΨ0

t (νt) +Ψt (νt + u)−Ψt (νt)

we can show that the risk neutral model is

Rt = rf − γ∗t + ε∗t (4.2)

where

ΨQ∗t(u) =

√2¡τ−11 σ∗1,t + τ−12 σ∗2,t

¢u−4τ−21 ln

µ1 +

1

2√2τ 1σ

∗1,tu

¶−4τ−22 ln

µ1 +

1

2√2τ 2σ

∗2,tu

¶with

σ∗i,t =σt√

2 + 12τ iσtνt

, for i = 1, 2. (4.3)

We see that ΨQ∗t(u) is exactly of the same form as Ψt (u), and therefore that γ∗t = ΨQ∗

t(−1) .

This model will be investigated empirically below.

16See Madan and Seneta (1990) for an early application of the symmetric and i.i.d. variance gammadistribution in finance.17The special cases where τ1 or τ2 are zero can be handled easily by drawing from the normal distribution

for the relevant mixing variable z1,t or z2,t. When both τ1 and τ2 are zero then the normal distributionobtains for zt.

18

Page 19: Option Valuation with Conditional … Valuation with Conditional Heteroskedasticity and Non-Normality ∗ Peter Christoffersen Redouane Elkamhi McGill University and CREATES McGill

5 Empirical illustration

In this section we demonstrate how the greater flexibility and generality allowed for by ourapproach can lead to more realistic option valuation models. To do so, we analyze theGARCH-SVG model in Section 4.4, which allows for conditional skewness and kurtosis, andwhich has not yet been analyzed in the literature. We compare its empirical implications withthe more standard conditional normal model. We compute option prices from both modelsusing parameters estimated from return data, and subsequently construct option impliedvolatility smiles. We also compare the two heteroskedastic models to two benchmark modelswith independent returns.

5.1 Parameter estimates from index returns and stylized facts

We start by illustrating some key stylized facts of daily equity index returns using the S&P500as a running example.Figure 1 shows a normal quantile-quantile plot (QQ plot) of daily S&P500 returns, using

data from January 2, 1980 through December 30, 2005 for a total of 6,564 observations. Thereturns are standardized by the sample mean and standard deviation. The data quantiles onthe vertical axis are plotted against the normal distribution quantiles on the horizontal axis.The plot reveals the well-known stark deviations from normality in daily asset returns: actualreturns include much more extreme observations than the normal distribution allows for ina sample of this size. The largest negative return is the famous 20 standard deviation crashin October 1987, but the normal distribution has trouble fitting a large number of extremesin both tails of the return distribution. The actual returns range from -20 to +9 standarddeviations but the normal distribution only ranges from -4 to +4 standard deviations in asample of this size.Figure 2 shows the sample autocorrelation function of the squared daily returns for the

sample. The significantly positive correlations at short lags suggest the need for a dynamicvolatility model allowing for clustering in volatility.Figures 1 and 2 clearly suggest the need for a GARCH model which can capture poten-

tially both the volatility clustering in Figure 2 and the non-normality in Figure 1.As a benchmark, we use the conditional normal NGARCH model of Engle and Ng (1993)

Rt = μt − γt + σtzt, zti.i.d∼ N(0, 1) (5.1)

where

μt = rt + λσt

γt = 12σ2t

σ2t = β0 + β1σ2t−1 + β2σ

2t−1 (zt−1 − β3)

2

Notice that the β3 parameter in the GARCH variance specification allows for an asym-metric variance response to positive versus negative shocks, zt−1. This captures the so-calledleverage effect, which is another important empirical regularity in daily equity index returns.Table 1 reports the maximum likelihood estimates of the GARCH parameters. We also

report parameter estimates for a version of the model where the GARCH dynamics have been

19

Page 20: Option Valuation with Conditional … Valuation with Conditional Heteroskedasticity and Non-Normality ∗ Peter Christoffersen Redouane Elkamhi McGill University and CREATES McGill

shut down, that is, where β1 = β2 = β3 = 0. Notice the large increase in the Log-likelihoodfunction from including the GARCH dynamics.Figure 3 shows the autocorrelation function for the observed squared GARCH shocks,

z2t . If the GARCH model has adequately captured the volatility clustering then the shocksshould be independent and in particular the squared shocks should be uncorrelated. Figure3 suggests that the GARCH model does a good job of capturing the volatility dynamics inthe daily index returns.Figure 4 assesses the conditional normality assumption by plotting a QQ plot of zt against

the normal distribution. It is clear from Figure 4 that much of the non-normality in the rawreturns has been removed by the GARCH model. This is particularly true for the right tail,where the non-normality was least pronounced to begin with. Unfortunately, the left tail ofthe shock distribution still exhibits strong evidence of non-normality with negative shocksas large as -10 standard deviations compared with the normal distribution’s -4.From Figures 3 and 4, we conclude that while the normal GARCH model appears to

provide adequate dynamics for capturing volatility clustering, the conditional normality as-sumption is violated in the data and must be modified in the model.For the implementation of the GARCH-SVG model, μt and σ2t are the same as in the

conditional normal model in (5.1). We can calibrate the s and k parameters in the GARCH-SVG model from Section 4.4 by simply equating them to the sample moments from the ztsequence from the QMLE estimation of the GARCH model. These sample moments arereported in Table 1.Figure 5 shows the QQ plot of the GARCH shocks against the SVG distribution. Com-

pared with the normal QQ plot in Figure 4, we see that the SVG captures the left tail ofthe shock distribution much better than the normal does. Impressively, the SVG model onlyhas trouble fitting the two most extreme negative shocks, whereas the normal distributionmisses a whole string of large negative shocks.

5.2 Option prices and implied volatilities

Armed with estimated return processes we are ready to assess the option pricing implicationsof the different models. From Section 3 we have the general option price relationship whichfor a European call option with strike price K is

Ct(T,K) = EQt

∙Max(ST −K, 0)

Bt

BT

¸Using the estimated physical process from Table 1 we can now simulate future paths for STfrom the current St and compute the option price as the simulated sample analogue to thisdiscounted expectation.We present evidence on the option pricing properties of the various models in Figures

6 and 7. Figure 6 considers an i.i.d. normal and an i.i.d. SVG model where the GARCHdynamics have been shut down (β1 = β2 = β3 = 0), and s and k have been set to the thesample skewness and kurtosis from the raw returns which are reported in Table 1. Figure 7considers the normal GARCH-Normal and GARCH-SVG models. The parameter estimatesused are again from Table 1.We first compute option prices for various moneyness and maturities and we then com-

pute implied Black and Scholes (1973) volatilities from the model option prices. Implied

20

Page 21: Option Valuation with Conditional … Valuation with Conditional Heteroskedasticity and Non-Normality ∗ Peter Christoffersen Redouane Elkamhi McGill University and CREATES McGill

volatilities are plotted against moneyness on the horizontal axis. The three panels corre-spond to maturities of 1 day, 1 week, and 1 month respectively.The i.i.d. SVGmodel in Figure 6 (solid lines) shows a strong implied volatility “smile” for

the 1-day maturity driven by the large excess kurtosis of 27.33 from Table 1. Interestingly,as the maturity increases the smile becomes an asymmetric “smirk” driven by the skewnessparameter of -1.21 in Table 1. The i.i.d. normal model in Figure 6 (dashed line) results ina flat implied volatility curve.The GARCH-SVG model in Figure 7 shows a smirk at the 1 day maturity compared

with the flat implied volatility for the GARCH-Normal model where the conditional 1 daydistribution is normal. The GARCH-Normal model generates a non-trivial volatility smirkfor horizons beyond 1 day where the conditional distribution is no longer normal. However,the GARCH-SVGmodel is capable of capturing much more non-normality than the GARCH-Normal model at all horizons. This is important because the empirical option valuationliterature often finds that existing models are unable to fit short term option prices wherethe implied degree of non-normality is large.18

From this empirical illustration we conclude that it is possible to build relatively simplemodels capturing the conditional volatility and non-normality found in index returns data,and more importantly that such models provide the flexibility needed to price options.

6 Some continuous time limits

In order to anchor our work in the continuous time literature we now explore the links betweensome of the discrete time models we have analyzed above and standard continuous-timemodels. We study three important cases: a homoskedastic model with normal innovations, ahomoskedastic model with non-normal (inverse Gaussian) innovations, and a heteroskedasticmodel with normal innovations.

6.1 Homoskedastic normal returns

Consider the homoskedastic i.i.d. normal model for discrete time interval ∆,

Rt = ln (St)− ln (St−∆) = μ∆− 12σ2∆+ σ

√∆zt zt|Ft−1 ∼ N(0, 1) (6.1)

and for simplicity also consider a constant risk-free rate.The EMM condition (2.3) is solved by choosing a constant ν = (μ − r)/σ2, and the

discrete-time risk-neutral dynamic is given by

ln (St)− ln (St−∆) = r∆− 12σ2∆+ σ

√∆z∗t z∗t |Ft−1 ∼ N(0, 1) (6.2)

The continuous-time limit of the risk-neutral process is given by

d(ln(St)) =¡r − 1

2σ2¢dt+ σdz∗(t)

where z∗(t) is a Wiener process under Q. This is the risk-neutral process in the Black-Scholes-Merton (BSM) model. In the diffusion limit the options are thus priced using theBSM formula.18See Bates (2003) for an excellent discussion of this and other stylized facts in option markets.

21

Page 22: Option Valuation with Conditional … Valuation with Conditional Heteroskedasticity and Non-Normality ∗ Peter Christoffersen Redouane Elkamhi McGill University and CREATES McGill

Consider a European option with strike price K with T − t =M∆ days to maturity. Thecall price can be written as

C∆,t = e−rM∆StEQt

£eRt,M I[Rt,M > ln(K/St)]

¤− e−rM∆KPQt [Rt,M > ln(K/St)]

where Rt,M = ln (St+M∆)− ln (St) and where I [∗] is the indicator function. Using the i.i.d.normal risk-neutral process in (6.2) we can rewrite the call price as

C∆,t = e−rM∆P1,t,∆ − e−rM∆KP2,t,∆

where

P1,t,∆ = erM∆Φ

Ãln(St/K) +

¡r + 1

2σ2¢∆M

σ√∆M

!, P2,t,∆ = Φ

Ãln(St/K) +

¡r − 1

2σ2¢∆M

σ√∆M

!

where Φ is the c.d.f. of the standard normal distribution.Note therefore that the i.i.d. normal discrete time process and its parameterization in

(6.1), and the choice of Radon-Nikodym derivative (and thus EMM) gives the BSM price forany ∆ so long as r and σ are provided in the proper daily log-return units.

6.2 Homoskedastic Inverse Gaussian returns

Consider now a homoskedastic version of the Inverse Gaussian (IG) model in (4.1) writtenfor a discrete time interval ∆,

Rt = r∆+¡ζ(∆) + η(∆)−1

¢σ2(∆) + εt (6.3)

εt = η(∆)yt − η(∆)−1σ2(∆) (6.4)

yt ∼ IG

µσ2(∆)

η(∆)

¶(6.5)

As shown above for the heteroskedastic case, the risk neutral return distribution is in thesame family as the historical model and can be written as follows

Rt = r∆+¡ζ∗(∆) + η∗(∆)−1

¢σ∗2(∆) + ε∗t (6.6)

ε∗t = η∗(∆)y∗t − η∗(∆)−1σ∗2(∆) (6.7)

y∗tQ∼ IG

µσ∗2(∆)η∗(∆)

¶(6.8)

where

η∗(∆) =η(∆)

1 + 2ν(∆)η(∆)

σ∗2(∆) =σ2(∆)

(1 + 2ν(∆)η(∆))3/2

ζ∗(∆) =1− 2η∗(∆)−p1− 2η∗(∆)

η∗(∆)2

22

Page 23: Option Valuation with Conditional … Valuation with Conditional Heteroskedasticity and Non-Normality ∗ Peter Christoffersen Redouane Elkamhi McGill University and CREATES McGill

and where ν(∆) solves (2.3) and is given by

ν(∆) =1

2η(∆)

"(2 + ζ(∆)2η(∆)3)

2

4ζ(∆)2η(∆)2− 1#

Consider a European option with strike price K with T − t =M∆ days to maturity. Thecall price can be written as

C∆,t = e−rM∆P1,t,∆ − e−rM∆KP2,t,∆ (6.9)

where using Fourier inversion of the risk-neutral log MGF of Rt,M , namely ΨQ∗t,M (u), we have

P1,t,∆ =erM∆

2+

Z +∞

0

Re

⎡⎣exp³ΨQ∗t,M (−1− iu)− iu ln

³KSt

´´iπu

⎤⎦ duP2,t,∆ =

1

2+

Z +∞

0

Re

⎡⎣exp³−iu ln

³KSt

´+ΨQ∗

t,M (−iu)´

iπu

⎤⎦ duwhere we have

ΨQ∗t,M (u) ≡ ln

³EQt [exp (uRt,M)]

´= − ¡r∆+ ζ(∆)σ2(∆)

¢Mu+

³1−p1 + 2uη∗(∆)´σ∗2(∆)M

η∗(∆)2

Christoffersen, Heston and Jacobs (2006) show that in the heteroskedastic case, thestochastic volatility model in Heston (1993a) with perfectly correlated shocks can be obtainedas a limit of the IG-GARCH model when discrete time IG-GARCH process converges tothe continuous time stochastic volatility Heston (1993a) process (see below) with perfectlycorrelated shocks when ∆ and η(∆) go to zero. This limit obtains when using a particularparameterization for the IG-GARCH model and the parameterization ζ(∆) = λ−η(∆)−1 forthe return mean. As the homoskedastic IG model is a special case of the IG-GARCH modelit will converge to the homoskedastic Heston (1993) process which is simply the geometricBrownian motion underlying the Black-Scholes model. The continuous-time limit of therisk-neutral process is thus again given by

d(ln(St)) =¡r − 1

2σ2¢dt+ σdz∗(t)

Figure 8 illustrates the convergence of the homoskedastic IG option price in (6.9) to theBSM price when ∆ goes to zero. In the figure we let η(∆) = η∆, σ2(∆) = σ2∆, and setλ = 1, η = −0.001 per day, and σ = .10. per year. Note that skewness is 3η/σ in the IGmodel.Christoffersen, Heston and Jacobs (2004) also show that an alternative pure jump limit

can be obtained in the Inverse Gaussian model.

23

Page 24: Option Valuation with Conditional … Valuation with Conditional Heteroskedasticity and Non-Normality ∗ Peter Christoffersen Redouane Elkamhi McGill University and CREATES McGill

6.3 Heteroskedastic normal returns

Consider the Heston and Nandi (2000) model

Rt = r∆+ λσ2t + σtzt (6.10)

σ2t+∆ = ω + βσ2t + α(zt − γσt)2

Defining vt+∆ = σ2t+∆/∆, we have

vt+∆ = ωv + βvt + αv (zt − γv√vt)

2 (6.11)

with ωv = ω/∆, αv = α/∆ and γv = γ√∆.

Note that the conditional correlation

Corrt−∆ (vt+∆, Rt) = −sign(γv)p2γ2vvtp

1 + 2γ2vvt

so that the correlation goes to plus or minus one when the interval shrinks to zero. Usingthe parametrization α(∆) = 1

4σ2∆2, β(∆) = 0, ω(∆) = (κθ − 1

4σ2)∆2, and γ(∆) = 2

σ∆− κ

σ,

and following Foster and Nelson (1994), Heston and Nandi derive the diffusion limit for thephysical process

d ln(St) = (r + λv)dt+√vdz (6.12)

dv = κ(θ − v)dt+ σ√vdz

which corresponds to a special case of the stochastic volatility model in Heston (1993) withperfectly correlated shocks to stock price and volatility.The Heston-Nandi discrete time option price is

Ct,∆ = StP1,t,∆ − e−rM∆KP2,t,∆

where the formulas for P1,t,∆ and P2,t,∆, which rely on Fourier inversion, are provided inHeston and Nandi (2000).Figure 9 shows the convergence of the Heston and Nandi (2000) discrete time GARCH

option price to the continuous time SV option price in Heston (1993). We use r = 0,K = 100, S = 100, M∆ = 180, σ = 0.1, V = 0.01, κ = 2, θ = .01, and shock correlationρ = −1.Note that markets are complete in the limiting case with ρ = −1 because there is only one

source of uncertainty. Below we analyze the more general case of a discrete-time two-shockstochastic volatility model and its continuous time limit where −1 < ρ < 1 and so wheremarkets are incomplete even in continuous time.Figure 9 shows that convergence is fast suggesting that the added incompleteness arising

from discrete time is minimal. By comparison convergence is slower in Figure 8 because ofthe conditional skewness in the discrete time process which is not present in the limitingprocess considered here.

24

Page 25: Option Valuation with Conditional … Valuation with Conditional Heteroskedasticity and Non-Normality ∗ Peter Christoffersen Redouane Elkamhi McGill University and CREATES McGill

7 Extensions and Discussion

In this section we first develop a discrete-time two-shock stochastic volatility model andderive its continuous time limit. Subsequently we compare the risk neutralization for thismodel with risk neutralization in the continuous time SV model. We discuss the GARCHmodel as a special case of this approach. We also discuss the issue of market incomplete-ness and the resulting non-uniqueness of option prices, again by discussing similarities anddifferences between continuous and discrete time.

7.1 A discrete-time stochastic volatility model

Popular continuous-time stochastic volatility models such as Heston (1993a) contain two(correlated) innovations, whereas the GARCH processes in this paper contain a single inno-vation. Nelson (1991) and Duan (1997) derive a continuous-time two-innovation stochasticvolatility model as the limit of a GARCH model, but as noted by Corradi (2000) for in-stance, a given discrete-time model can have several continuous-time limits and vice versa.19

As shown above, Heston and Nandi (2000) derive a limit to their proposed GARCH processthat contains two perfectly correlated shocks. This limit amounts to a one-shock process,and is therefore intuitively similar to a GARCH process.With this in mind, we now analyze the limits of a class of discrete-time stochastic volatility

processes, which contain two (potentially correlated) shocks.20 We derive the continuous-time limits for these processes, and then analyze the GARCH limit as a special case.Consider the return and volatility dynamics

Rt = ln(St/St−1) = μt + σtz1,t

σ2t+1 = f(σ2t , z2,t)

where

zt ≡ (z1,t, z2,t)0 ∼ N

µµ(0, 0)0,

µ1 ρρ 1

¶¶¶The log MGF is given by

Ψt(u1, u2) = log[Et−1(exp(−u1z1,t − u2z2,t))] =1

2

£(u1 + ρu2)

2 +¡1− ρ2

¢u22¤

By analogy with the one-shock case, we define the following Radon-Nikodym derivative

dQ

dP|Ft = exp

Ã−

tXi=1

(ν1,iz1,i + ν2,iz2,i +Ψi(ν1,i, ν2,i))

!The probability measure Q defined by the Radon-Nikodym derivative is an EMM if and onlyif

Ψt(ν1,t − σtν2,t)−Ψt(ν1,t, ν2,t) + μt − r =1

2σ2t − (ν1,t + ρν2,t)σt + μt − r = 0 (7.1)

19See also Nelson and Foster (1994), Foster and Nelson (1996), Nelson (1996) and Ritchken and Trevor(1999) for limit results.20See Ghysels, Harvey and Renault (1995) for a review of discrete-time stochastic volatility models.

25

Page 26: Option Valuation with Conditional … Valuation with Conditional Heteroskedasticity and Non-Normality ∗ Peter Christoffersen Redouane Elkamhi McGill University and CREATES McGill

Note that this is one equation in two unknowns, namely ν1,t and ν2,t. Thus the secondshock provides a new source of non-uniqueness to be discussed further below.The risk neutral log MGF is given by

EQt−1[exp(−u1z1,t − u2z2,t)] = EP

t−1

"ÃdQdP|Ft

dQdP|Ft−1

!exp(−u1z1,t − u2z2,t)

#= exp(Ψt(u1 + ν1,t, u2 + ν2,t)−Ψt(ν1,t, ν2,t))

where

zt = (z1,t, z2,t)0 Q∼ N

µµ(−ν1,t − ρν2,t,−ν1,tρ− ν2,t)

0,µ1 ρρ 1

¶¶¶(7.2)

We now illustrate this risk-neutralization for a specific parametric example

Rt = r + λσ2t −1

2σ2t + σtz1,t (7.3)

σ2t+1 = ω + βσ2t + α(z2,t − γσt)2

The dynamic in (7.3) can be thought of as a stochastic volatility (two-shock) generaliza-tion of the GARCH dynamic in Heston and Nandi (2000).According to (7.2) the risk-neutral model is given by

Rt = r − 12σ2t + σtz

∗1,t (7.4)

σ2t+1 = ω + βσ2t + α(z∗2,t − ν1,tρ− ν2,t − γσt)2

where

z∗t =µ

z∗1,t = z1,t + ν1,t + ρν2,tz∗2,t = z1,t + ν1,tρ+ ν2,t

¶Q∼ N

µµ(0, 0)0,

µ1 ρρ 1

¶¶¶In the one-shock GARCH case above, we could simply solve (2.3) by choosing the scalar νtas a function of the GARCH parameters. Determining ν1,t and ν2,t in a model with twoinnovations is somewhat more complex, but the intuition underlying the procedure is criticalto understanding the link with the continuous-time literature. From (7.1) and (7.3) we haveν1,t + ν2,tρ = λσt. We then note that if we want to preserve the affine structure in (7.4) weneed ν2,t = ν2σt, which yields the risk neutral dynamic

Rt = r − 12σ2t + σtz

∗1,t (7.5)

σ2t+1 = ω + βσ2t + α(z∗2,t − γ∗σt)2

with γ∗ = γ + ν2(1− ρ2) + λρ.Note that while λ, which is the price of equity risk, can be estimated from returns, ν2,

which arises from the new separate volatility shock is not identified from the return on theunderlying asset only. It must be estimated from option prices as it only appears under therisk neutral measure. This is of course also the case in the continuous time SV models.Using an approach similar to that taken in Heston and Nandi (2000) option valuation in

this discrete-time SVmodel can be done via Fourier inversion of the conditional characteristicfunction.

26

Page 27: Option Valuation with Conditional … Valuation with Conditional Heteroskedasticity and Non-Normality ∗ Peter Christoffersen Redouane Elkamhi McGill University and CREATES McGill

7.2 A diffusion limit of the discrete-time stochastic volatility model

We first write the discrete-time stochastic volatility model as

Rt = r∆+ λσ2t −1

2σ2t + σtz1,t (7.6)

σ2t+∆ = ω + βσ2t + α(z2,t − γσt)2 (7.7)

Reparametrizing vt+∆ = σ2t+∆/∆, we have

vt+∆ = ωv + βvt + αv (z2,t − γv√vt)

2 (7.8)

with ωv = ω/∆, αv = α/∆ and γv = γ√∆.

By analogy with Heston and Nandi (2000) we use the parametrization α(∆) = 14σ2∆2,

β(∆) = 0, ω(∆) = (κθ − 14σ2)∆2, and γ(∆) = 2

σ∆− κ

σ. As ∆→ 0 the dynamic in (7.6) and

(7.8) converges to

d ln(St) = (r + λv − 12v)dt+

√vdz1 (7.9)

dv = κ(θ − v)dt+ σ√vdz2

where z1 and z2 are two Wiener process such that dz1dz2 = ρdt. Note that the discrete timeconditional correlation is given by

corrt−∆ (vt+∆, Rt) = −ρsign(γv)p2γ2vvtp

1 + 2γ2vvt

As ∆ → 0, the variance asymmetry parameter γv(∆) approaches positive or negativeinfinity, and therefore the correlation approaches ρ or −ρ in the limit.We can use a similar argument to demonstrate that as ∆→ 0, the risk neutral discrete-

time stochastic volatility model (7.5) converges to the following dynamic

d ln(St) = (r − 12v)dt+

√vdz∗1 (7.10)

dv = [κ(θ − v) + σ(ν2(1− ρ2) + λρ)v]dt+ σ√vdz∗2

where z∗1 and z∗2 are two Wiener processes such that dz∗1dz

∗2 = ρdt.

7.3 The relationship with the continuous time affine SV model

Both (7.9) and (7.10) are square root stochastic volatility models of the type proposedby Heston (1993). We now link our discrete time stochastic volatility model and its risk-neutralization to the conventional risk-neutralization in the Heston (1993) model. Assumefor simplicity that the parameterization of the conditional mean dynamic under the physicalmeasure is given by (7.9). Heston (1993) proposes the following risk neutralization

d ln(St) = (r − 12v)dt+

√vdz∗1 (7.11)

dv = [κ(θ − v)− σχ∗v]dt+ σ√vdz∗2

27

Page 28: Option Valuation with Conditional … Valuation with Conditional Heteroskedasticity and Non-Normality ∗ Peter Christoffersen Redouane Elkamhi McGill University and CREATES McGill

where z∗1 and z∗2 are two Wiener process under the risk neutral probability Q and21

dz∗1 = dz1 +

µλ− 1

2

¶√vdt (7.12)

dz∗2 = dz2 + χ∗√vdt

In the discrete-time stochastic volatility model, the parameter λ in (7.3) captures the priceof equity risk, and ν2 captures the price of volatility risk. In the Heston model, the price ofequity risk λ plays the same role as in the discrete-time model, and we have also a price ofvolatility risk χ∗ which ensures the affine structure of the risk-neutral process. Comparing(7.11) and (7.10), we find

χ∗ = ν2(1− ρ2) + λρ. (7.13)

Note that for ρ = 0, the continuous time price of volatility risk χ∗ is not related to λ,but is simply equal to the discrete-time price of volatility risk ν2. Moreover, this mappingbetween the price of volatility risk in discrete-time and continuous-time stochastic volatilitymodels also provides insight into the relationship between the discrete-time GARCH modeland the available continuous-time literature. While the GARCH model contains a singleinnovation, it can usefully be thought of as a special case of the two-shock discrete-timestochastic volatility model in (7.4), for ρ = 1 (or ρ = −1). In this case, from (7.13), χ∗ = λ.Because the GARCH model contains a single shock, the specification of the equity riskpremium λ does double duty: it also implicitly defines the price of volatility risk, which isperfectly correlated with the price of equity risk by design. In other words, the GARCHreturn dynamic implicitly makes an assumption about the volatility risk premium. Theparameter governing the equity risk premium also determines the volatility risk premium.Strictly speaking therefore, in the case of the GARCH model the only assumption we makein our approach is on the form of the Radon-Nikodym derivative. All other assumptionsneeded for risk-neutral valuation are implicit in the specification of the return dynamic, or,in other words, the assumptions on the equilibrium supporting the valuation problem areimplicitly incorporated in the risk premium assumption for the return dynamic.

7.4 Option Price Uniqueness

In Section 6.3 and 7.2, we have analyzed continuous-time limits for four discrete-time returnsdynamics: a homoskedastic model with normal innovations, a homoskedastic model withnon-normal innovations, a heteroskedastic GARCH model with normal innovations, and adiscrete time stochastic volatility model. We now further discuss these limit results bydiscussing the implications of three model features: normality, heteroskedasticity and thenumber of innovations (one versus two). We pay particular attention to the uniqueness ofthe option price in the discrete-time models we consider and their continuous-time limits.First, to illustrate the importance of the conditional normality assumption, compare

the results for the homoskedastic normal model in Section 6.1 with the results for the ho-moskedastic IG model in Section 6.2. The option value in the homoskedastic normal model isalways equal to the BSM value, regardless of the value of μ. The existence of a unique option

21Notice that for ease of interpretation, in our notation the price of volatility risk χ∗ has been rescaled by1/σ compared to the notation in Heston (1993a).

28

Page 29: Option Valuation with Conditional … Valuation with Conditional Heteroskedasticity and Non-Normality ∗ Peter Christoffersen Redouane Elkamhi McGill University and CREATES McGill

value, rather than bounds on option values, may seem surprising because the structure ofthe underlying discrete-time economy is very different from that of the continuous-time limiteconomy. Markets are not complete and therefore the EMM is not necessarily unique. How-ever, the intuition for this finding is simple: although there is a unique solution to the EMMcondition (2.3), this finding is conditional on the assumption regarding the Radon-Nikodymderivative. Presumably other solutions may be available given alternative assumptions onthe Radon-Nikodym derivative, but an investigation of this issue is beyond the scope of thispaper.In contrast to the case of conditionally normal innovations, the homoskedastic IG option

value is generally different from the BSM value. The option value depends on the skewnessparameter, as well as on the equity premium. In the limit, as skewness goes to zero, theoption value converges to BSM.Second, Section 7.3 suggests that it is instructive to distinguish between two types of

heteroskedastic discrete-time models: one-shock models, such as GARCH models, and two-shock stochastic volatility models. We focus on normal innovations in order to facilitate thecomparison with continuous-time models. We analyze a discrete-time stochastic volatilitymodel which has the popular Heston (1993) model as a limit, and we are able to relate its riskneutralization to that used in the Heston model. In both cases option valuation takes place inan incomplete-markets setup, and in both cases this involves the use of a price of volatilityrisk which can be conveniently chosen to preserve the affine structure of the risk-neutralmodel dynamic. The intimate relationship between the risk-neutralization in the discrete-time and continuous-time models is due to three model characteristics: first, both modelsare affine; second, both models contain two innovations; and third, the discrete-time modelhas normal innovations. The Wiener processes in the continuous-time model correspond toa normality assumption. While continuous-time specifications can model non-normal returndistributions, the instantaneous distribution is normal.22

GARCH models can be studied as special cases of discrete-time stochastic volatilitymodels. In the GARCH model, one parameter determines the volatility risk premium aswell as the equity risk premium. This is consistent with the interpretation of the GARCHmodel as a one-shock model with perfectly correlated equity and volatility innovations.23

In summary, in our opinion the analysis of discrete-time option valuation models has alot of similarities with the analysis of continuous-time option valuation models. We providea unique EMM solution subject to the choice of Radon-Nikodym derivative. Because thediscrete-time, infinite state-space setup is characterized by incomplete markets, other Radon-Nikodym derivatives may of course exist. But this is analogous to the standard continuoustime stochastic volatility setting, where markets are also incomplete, and where a Radon-Nikodym derivative or a volatility risk premium specification must be chosen in order to

22In a discrete-time model, non-normality can be built in by assuming that the multi-period distributionis non-normal, as in a continuous-time model, or by assuming that the one-period return is conditionallynon-normal. This does of course not mean that the discrete-time setup is superior to the continuous-timesetup. In the end the suitability of either approach will be determined by the trade-off between its flexibilityand its analytical convenience.23While it could be argued that this structure limits the usefulness of the GARCH model, one has to keep

in mind that this structure is exactly what makes the GARCH model econometrically tractable. Indeed,the success of the GARCH model in modeling returns, and its growing popularity in modeling options, areprecisely due to the fact that despite its simple structure it provides a very good fit.

29

Page 30: Option Valuation with Conditional … Valuation with Conditional Heteroskedasticity and Non-Normality ∗ Peter Christoffersen Redouane Elkamhi McGill University and CREATES McGill

select a unique option price.Conceptually, the biggest difference between discrete and continuous time is the classic

i.i.d. normal case, when markets are complete in continuous time but incomplete in discretetime. The discrete time option price is now unique only subject to the choice of a particularRadon-Nikodym derivative. While this striking continuous-time result is of great theoreticalimportance and interest, we also note that the evidence indicates that non i.i.d heteroskedas-tic models characterized by market incompleteness are more empirically relevant for optionvaluation, both in continuous and in discrete time. Bakshi, Cao and Chen (1997) make astrong case for this using continuous time stochastic volatility models, and Heston and Nandi(2000) and Christoffersen and Jacobs (2004) provide evidence using discrete time GARCHmodels.Most existing papers on option pricing in discrete time using an infinite state space setup24

assume normally distributed returns and, in the words of Rubinstein (1976), “complete” themarkets by assuming a representative agent with certain preferences, such as for instanceconstant relative risk aversion. Our approach, much like the one used in the continuous-timestochastic volatility literature, is to let the researcher specify an empirically realistic returndynamic for the underlying asset, and subsequently provide an equivalent martingale measurethat allows us to find option prices using a no-arbitrage assumption. Proposition 1 providesthe form of the EMM and Proposition 4 provides the no-arbitrage option pricing result.Instead of making explicit assumptions regarding a representative agent with particular riskpreferences, we assume a form of the Radon-Nikodym derivative, and a price of volatility risk,much like in the continuous time stochastic volatility literature. Whereas the assumption onthe representative agent’s utility function “completes” the market in the standard normaldiscrete time setting, the Radon-Nikodym derivative “completes” the market in our setup.

7.5 Option Price Bounds

There is a rich literature that derives bounds on option valuation using stochastic dominancetechniques. While some of these papers focus on i.i.d. returns (see for example Perrakis(1986), Perrakis and Ryan (1984), Ritchken and Kuo (1988), and Constantinides, Jackwerthand Perrakis (2008)), recently Perrakis and Oancea (2007) have used stochastic dominanceto derive option pricing bounds in the presence of GARCH processes for returns. Perrakisand Oancea (2007) show that in the GARCH case, stochastic dominance alone does notsuffice to derive option bounds because of nonconvexities, and additional assumptions haveto be made.25 Under these types of assumptions, our approach leads to a unique price.Presumably bounds similar to the ones in Perrakis and Oancea (2007) may be obtainedusing other assumptions on the RN derivative, but this exploration is left for future work.

8 Conclusion

This paper provides valuation results for contingent claims in a discrete time infinite statespace setup. Our valuation argument applies to a large class of conditionally normal and non-

24See for example Rubinstein (1976), Brennan (1979), and Duan (1995).25Perrakis and Oancea (2007) discuss normal innovations. It is not clear how to relate our results to theirs

for non-normal innovations.

30

Page 31: Option Valuation with Conditional … Valuation with Conditional Heteroskedasticity and Non-Normality ∗ Peter Christoffersen Redouane Elkamhi McGill University and CREATES McGill

normal stock returns with flexible time-varying mean and volatility, as well as a potentiallytime-varying price of risk. This setup generalizes the result in Duan (1995) in the sense thatwe do not restrict the returns to be conditionally normal, nor do we restrict the price of riskto be constant.Our results apply to some of the most widely used discrete time processes in finance,

such as GARCH processes. We also apply our approach to the analysis of discrete-timeprocesses with multiple innovations, such as discrete-time stochastic volatility processes.For the class of processes we analyze, the risk neutral return dynamic is the same as thephysical dynamic, but with a different parameterization which we are able to characterizecompletely. To provide intuition for our findings, we extensively discuss the relationshipbetween our results and existing results for continuous-time stochastic volatility models,which can be derived as limits of our discrete-time dynamics.To demonstrate the empirical relevance of our approach, we provide an empirical analysis

of a heteroskedastic return dynamic with a standardized skewed variance gamma distribu-tion, which is constructed as the mixture of two gamma variables. In the resulting dynamic,conditional skewness and kurtosis are directly governed by two distinct parameters. Weestimate the model on return data using quasi maximum likelihood and compare its perfor-mance with the heteroskedastic conditional normal model which is standard in the literature.Diagnostics clearly indicate that the conditionally non-normal model outperforms the con-ditionally normal model, and an analysis of the option smirk demonstrates that this modelprovides substantially more flexibility to value options.It is likely that our risk neutralizations can equivalently be derived using the specification

of a candidate stochastic discount factor or using the Esscher transform, rather than throughour approach which starts with the specification of a Radon-Nikodym derivative and derivesthe EMM.26 However, in most applications that we are aware of, existing work actuallystarts out by assuming a bivariate distribution for the stochastic discount factor and thestock return (see for example Amin and Ng (1993)).27 This assumption clearly goes beyondthe existence of no-arbitrage and is closer in spirit to the general equilibrium setup of Duan(1995) and Brennan (1979). See Garcia, Ghysels and Renault (2006) for a discussion on howsome of these assumed joint distributions effectively amount to degenerate distributions.Our approach is also related to the risk-neutral valuation argument used in Heston (1993b,2004) and Christoffersen, Heston and Jacobs (2006), but in our opinion our approach is moretransparent. Duan, Ritchken and Sun (2005) use a risk neutralization for a Poisson-normalheteroskedastic model that has some similarities with our approach. However, they do notapply their principle to the investigation of more general return dynamics.We leave several important issues unaddressed. First, while we obtain a unique EMM

given the choice of Radon-Nikodym derivative, we cannot exclude that even for a given spec-ification of the risk premium, there exist other EMMs corresponding to different functionalforms of the Radon-Nikodym derivative. Second, it would be interesting to more fully ex-plore the relationship between our findings and those in the stochastic dominance literaturethat derives option bounds. Third, while we advocate separating the valuation issue and thegeneral equilibrium setup that supports it, the general equilibrium foundations of our results

26See for example Hansen and Richard (1987) for a characterization of risk neutralization using the sto-chastic discount factor. See also Buhlman et al (1998) and Siu et al (2004) for applications of the Esschertransform in option valuation.27See Gourieroux and Monfort (2007) for a notable exception.

31

Page 32: Option Valuation with Conditional … Valuation with Conditional Heteroskedasticity and Non-Normality ∗ Peter Christoffersen Redouane Elkamhi McGill University and CREATES McGill

are of course very important. It may prove possible to characterize the equilibrium setupthat gives rise to the risk neutralization proposed for some of the processes considered inthis paper, such as the empirically interesting dynamics considered in Section 5. However,this is by no means a trivial problem, and it is left for future work.

9 Appendix

9.1 Proof of Proposition 2.

Define f(v) = Ψ(v)−Ψ(v − 1). We want to show that f(v) = E [Rt − r] ≡ π has a uniquesolution for any given value of π. Existence is obtained if f(v) can take any real value.The assumption that Ψ tends to infinity at the boundaries of its domain implies that wehave Ψ(u1) = ∞ and Ψ(u2) = ∞. Note that the domain of f(v) is (u1 + 1, u2). Notealso that Ψ is continuous because by assumption it is twice differentiable on its domain.Since Ψ is continuous f(.) is also continuous. Now let us evaluate the function f(.) onu1 + 1 and u2. f(u1 + 1) = Ψ(u1 + 1) − Ψ(u1) = −Ψ(u1) = −∞ since Ψ(u1) = ∞.f(u2) = Ψ(u2)− Ψ(u2 − 1) = Ψ(u2) = ∞ since Ψ(u2) = ∞. Hence f(.) is continuous andcan attain −∞ or ∞. This implies that for any value π between (−∞,∞), there exists avalue v in the domain of the continuous function f(.) such that f(v) = π. Furthermore, wehave that f 0(u) = Ψ0(u)−Ψ0(u− 1). Convexity of Ψ implies that if Ψ00(u) > 0, then Ψ0(.) isincreasing. A direct consequence of this is that if f 0(u) = Ψ0(u)−Ψ0(u− 1) > 0 then f(.) isincreasing. We then have that f(.) is increasing and continuous, which implies that f(.) is abijection, and uniqueness follows.

9.2 Proof of Lemma 2.

For a self financing strategy we have

Gt+1 = Vt+1 = ηtSt+1 + δtCt+1 + ψtBt+1

= ηt+1St+1 + δt+1Ct+1 + ψt+1Bt+1

We also have

Gt =t−1Xi=0

ηi(Si+1 − Si) +t−1Xi=0

δi(Ci+1 − Ci) +t−1Xi=0

ψi(Bi+1 −Bi).

It follows that

Gt+1 −Gt = ηt(St+1 − St) + δt(Ct+1 − Ct) + ψt(Bt+1 −Bt)

We can trivially also write

GBt+1 −GB

t = GBt+1 −GB

t +

µGt+1

Bt− Gt+1

Bt

¶| z

=0

32

Page 33: Option Valuation with Conditional … Valuation with Conditional Heteroskedasticity and Non-Normality ∗ Peter Christoffersen Redouane Elkamhi McGill University and CREATES McGill

This implies that

GBt+1 −GB

t = (ηtSt+1 + δtCt+1 + ψtBt+1)

µ1

Bt+1− 1

Bt

¶+1

Bt(ηt(St+1 − St) + δt(Ct+1 − Ct) + ψt(Bt+1 −Bt)) .

= ηt

∙St+1

µ1

Bt+1− 1

Bt

¶+1

Bt(St+1 − St)

¸+δt

∙Ct+1

µ1

Bt+1− 1

Bt

¶+1

Bt(Ct+1 − Ct)

¸+ψtBt+1

µ1

Bt+1− 1

Bt

¶+1

Btψt(Bt+1 −Bt)| z

=0

Then

GBt+1−GB

t = ηt

∙St+1

µ1

Bt+1− 1

Bt

¶+1

Bt(St+1 − St)

¸+δt

∙Ct+1

µ1

Bt+1− 1

Bt

¶+1

Bt(Ct+1 − Ct)

¸

= ηt(SBt+1 − SB

t ) + δt(CBt+1 − CB

t ) +

µηtSt+1Bt− ηt

St+1Bt

¶+

µδtCt+1

Bt− δt

Ct+1

Bt

¶and therefore

GBt+1 −GB

t = ηt(SBt+1 − SB

t ) + δt(CBt+1 − CB

t ). ∀t = 1, ..., T − 1Because G0 = GB

0 = 0 the discounted gain can be written as the sum of past changes

GBt =

t−1Xi=0

(GBi+1 −GB

i ) ∀t = 1, ..., T.

Therefore the discounted gain can be written

GBt =

t−1Xi=0

ηi(SBi+1 − SB

i ) +t−1Xi=0

δi(CBi+1 − CB

i )

and the proof is complete.

9.3 Proof of Proposition 3.

From Lukacs (1970), page 119, we have the Kolmogorov canonical representation of thelog-moment generating function of an infinitely divisible distribution function. This resultstipulates that a function Ψ is the log-moment generating function of an infinitely divisibledistribution with finite second moment if, and only if, it can be written in the form

Ψ (u) = −uc+Z +∞

−∞

¡e−ux − 1 + ux

¢ dK (x)x2

33

Page 34: Option Valuation with Conditional … Valuation with Conditional Heteroskedasticity and Non-Normality ∗ Peter Christoffersen Redouane Elkamhi McGill University and CREATES McGill

where c is a real constant while K (u) is a nondecreasing and bounded function such thatK (−∞) = 0. Applying this theorem gives the following form for Ψt (u) ,

Ψt (u) = −uct−1 +Z +∞

−∞

¡e−ux − 1 + ux

¢ dKt−1 (x)x2

(9.1)

where ct−1 is a random variable known at t− 1, and Kt−1 (x) is a function known at t− 1,which is nondecreasing and bounded so that Kt−1 (−∞) = 0. Using relation (2.8) and thecharacterisation (9.1) we can write ΨQ∗

t (u) as

ΨQ∗t (u) =

Z +∞

−∞

¡e−ux − 1 + ux

¢ dK∗t−1 (x)x2

where

K∗t−1 (x) =

Z x

−∞e−νt−1ydKt−1 (y)

This implies thatK∗

t−1 (−∞) = 0K∗

t−1 (x) is obviously non-decreasing since Kt−1 (x) is non-decreasing, K∗t−1 (∞) < ∞, be-

cause Kt−1 (∞) < ∞, and e−νty is a decreasing function of y which converge to 0. Recallthat νt is the price of risk, which is positive and known at time t− 1.In conclusion we have constructed a constant c∗t−1 (= 0) and a non-decreasing bounded

function K∗t−1 (x) , with K∗

t−1 (−∞) = 0, such that

ΨQ∗t (u) = −uc∗t−1 +

Z +∞

−∞

¡e−ux − 1 + ux

¢ dK∗t−1 (x)x2

.

Hence, according to the Kolmogorov canonical representation, the conditional distributionof ε∗t is infinitely divisible.

34

Page 35: Option Valuation with Conditional … Valuation with Conditional Heteroskedasticity and Non-Normality ∗ Peter Christoffersen Redouane Elkamhi McGill University and CREATES McGill

References

[1] Amin, K. and V. Ng (1993), ARCH Processes and Option Valuation, Manuscript, Uni-versity of Michigan.

[2] Bakshi, C., Cao, C. and Z. Chen (1997), Empirical Performance of Alternative OptionPricing Models, Journal of Finance, 52, 2003-2049.

[3] Bates, D. (1996), Jumps and Stochastic Volatility: Exchange Rate Processes Implicitin Deutsche Mark Options, Review of Financial Studies, 9, 69-107.

[4] Bates, D. (2000), Post-’87 Crash Fears in the S&P 500 Futures Option Market, Journalof Econometrics, 94, 181-238.

[5] Bates, D. (2003), Empirical Option Pricing: a Retrospection, Journal of Econometrics,116, 387-404.

[6] Bick, A. (1990), On Viable Diffusion Price Processes of the Market Portfolio, Journalof Finance, 45, 673-689.

[7] Black, F., and M. Scholes (1973), The Pricing of Options and Corporate Liabilities,Journal of Political Economy, 81, 637-659.

[8] Bollerslev, T. (1986), Generalized Autoregressive Conditional Heteroskedasticity, Jour-nal of Econometrics, 31, 307-327.

[9] Bollerslev, T., Chou, R. and K. Kroner (1992), ARCH Modelling in Finance: A Reviewof the Theory and Empirical Evidence, Journal of Econometrics, 52, 5-59.

[10] Bollerslev, T., M. Gibbons, and H. Zhou (2005), Dynamic Estimation of VolatilityRisk Premia and Investor Risk Aversion from Option-Implied and Realized Volatilities,Manuscript, Duke University.

[11] Bollerslev, T. and H.O. Mikkelsen (1996), Long-Term Equity AnticiPation Securitiesand Stock Market Volatility Dynamics, Journal of Econometrics, 92, 75-99.

[12] Brennan, M. (1979), The Pricing of Contingent Claims in Discrete-TimeModels, Journalof Finance, 34, 53-68.

[13] Broadie, M., Chernov, M. and M. Johannes (2006), Model Specification and Risk Pre-mia: Evidence from S&P500 Futures Options Market, forthcoming in the Journal ofFinance.

[14] Buhlmann, H., Delbaen, F., Embrechts, P., Shiryaev, A., 1998. On Esscher Transformsin Discrete Finance Models. ASTIN Bulletin, 28, 171—86.

[15] Camara, A. (2003), A Generalization of the Brennan-Rubenstein Approach for thePricing of Derivatives, Journal of Finance, 58, 805-819.

[16] Carr, P. and L. Wu (2004), Time-Changed Levy Processes and Option Pricing, Journalof Financial Economics, 17, 113—141.

35

Page 36: Option Valuation with Conditional … Valuation with Conditional Heteroskedasticity and Non-Normality ∗ Peter Christoffersen Redouane Elkamhi McGill University and CREATES McGill

[17] Carr, P. and L. Wu (2007), Variance Risk Premia, Review of Financial Studies, forth-coming.

[18] Christoffersen, P., S. Heston, and K. Jacobs (2006), Option Valuation with ConditionalSkewness, Journal of Econometrics, 131, 253-284.

[19] Christoffersen, P. and K. Jacobs (2004), Which GARCH Model for Option Valuation?Management Science, 50, 1204-1221.

[20] Corradi, V. (2000), Reconsidering the Continuous Time Limit of the GARCH(1,1)Process, Journal of Econometrics, 96, 145-153.

[21] Cox, J. and S. Ross (1976), The Valuation of Options for Alternative StochasticProcesses, Journal of Financial Economics, 3, 145-166.

[22] Cox, J., Ross, S. and M. Rubinstein (1979), Option Pricing: A Simplified Approach,Journal of Financial Economics, 7, 229-264.

[23] Diebold, F. and J. Lopez (1995), Modeling Volatility Dynamics, in Macroeconometrics:Developments, Tensions and Prospects, Kevin Hoover (ed.). Boston: Kluwer AcademicPress.

[24] Duan, J.-C. (1995), The GARCH Option Pricing Model, Mathematical Finance, 5,13-32.

[25] Duan, J.-C. (1997), Augmented GARCH(p,q) Process and Its Diffusion Limit, Journalof Econometrics, 79, 97-127.

[26] Duan, J.-C. (1999), Conditionally Fat-Tailed Distributions and the Volatility Smile inOptions, Manuscript, University of Toronto.

[27] Duan, J.-C., Ritchken, P. and Z. Sun (2005), Jump Starting GARCH: Pricing and Hedg-ing Options with Jumps in Returns and Volatilities, Working Paper, Rotman School,University of Toronto.

[28] Engle, R. (1982), Autoregressive Conditional Heteroskedasticity with Estimates of theVariance of UK Inflation, Econometrica, 50, 987-1008.

[29] Engle, R., D. M. Lilien and R.P. Robins (1987), Estimating Time Varying Risk Premiain the Term Structure: The ARCH-M Model, Econometrica, 55, 391-407.

[30] Engle, R. and V. Ng (1993), Measuring and Testing the Impact of News on Volatility,Journal of Finance, 48, 1749-1778.

[31] Eraker, B. (2004), Do Stock Prices and Volatility Jump? Reconciling Evidence fromSpot and Option Prices, Journal of Finance, 59, 1367-1403.

[32] Eraker, B., M. Johannes and N. Polson (2003), The Impact of Jumps in Volatility andReturns, Journal of Finance, 58, 1269-1300.

36

Page 37: Option Valuation with Conditional … Valuation with Conditional Heteroskedasticity and Non-Normality ∗ Peter Christoffersen Redouane Elkamhi McGill University and CREATES McGill

[33] Feller, W. (1968), An Introduction to Probability Theory and its Applications. JohnWiley & Sons.

[34] Foster, D. P. and D.B. Nelson (1996), Continuous Record Asymptotics for Rolling Sam-ple Variance Estimators, Econometrica, 64, 139-174.

[35] French, K., G. W. Schwert, and R. Stambaugh (1987), Expected Stock Returns andVolatility, Journal of Financial Economics, 19, 3-30.

[36] Garcia, R., E. Ghysels, and E. Renault (2006), The Econometrics of Option Pricing,forthcoming in the Handbook of Financial Econometrics, Yacine Aït-Sahalia and LarsPeter Hansen, eds., Elsevier-North Holland, Amsterdam.

[37] Garcia, R. and E. Renault (1998), A Note on Hedging in ARCH-type Option PricingModels, Mathematical Finance, 8, 153-161.

[38] Glosten, L. R., R. Jagannathan, and D. Runkle (1993), On the Relation between theExpected Value and the Volatility of the Nominal Excess Return on Stocks, Journal ofFinance, 48, 1779-1801.

[39] Ghysels, E., A. Harvey, and E. Renault (1995), Stochastic Volatility, Handbook ofStatistics 14, Statistical Methods in Finance, G.S. Maddala and C.R. Rao (eds.), NorthHolland. Amsterdam.

[40] Gourieroux, C. and A. Monfort (2007), Econometric Specifications of Stochastic Dis-count Factor Models, forthcoming in the Journal of Econometrics, 136, 509-530.

[41] Hansen, L. and S. Richard (1987), The Role of Conditioning Information in DeducingTestable Restrictions Implied by Dynamic Asset Pricing Models, Econometrica, 55,587-613.

[42] Harrison, M. and D. Kreps (1979), Martingales and Arbitrage in Multi-period SecuritiesMarkets, Journal of Economic Theory, 20, 381-408.

[43] Harrison, M., and S. Pliska (1981), Martingales and Stochastic Integrals in the Theoryof Continuous Trading, Stochastic Processes and their Applications, 11, 215—260.

[44] He, H. and H. Leland (1993), On Equilibrium Asset Price Processes, Review of FinancialStudies, 6, 593-617.

[45] Heston, S. (1993a), A Closed-Form Solution for Options with Stochastic Volatility withApplications to Bond and Currency Options, Review of Financial Studies, 6, 327-343.

[46] Heston, S. (1993b), Invisible Parameters in Option Prices, Journal of Finance, 48, 933-947.

[47] Heston, S. (2004), Option Valuation with Infinitely Divisible Distributions, QuantitativeFinance, 4, 515-524.

[48] Heston, S. and S. Nandi (2000), A Closed-Form GARCH Option Pricing Model, Reviewof Financial Studies, 13, 585-626.

37

Page 38: Option Valuation with Conditional … Valuation with Conditional Heteroskedasticity and Non-Normality ∗ Peter Christoffersen Redouane Elkamhi McGill University and CREATES McGill

[49] Huang, J.-Z. and L. Wu (2004), Specification Analysis of Option Pricing Models Basedon Time-Changed Levy Processes, Journal of Finance, 59, 1405—1439.

[50] Jacob, J. and A. Shiryaev (1998), Local Martingales and the Fundamental Asset PricingTheorems in the Discrete-time Case, Finance and Stochastics, 259-273.

[51] Karatzas, I., and S. Shreve (1998), Methods of Mathematical Finance, Springer-Verlag.

[52] Lukacs, E. (1970), Characteristic Functions, Griffin. London

[53] Madan, D. B., and E. Seneta (1990), The Variance Gamma Model from Share MarketReturns, Journal of Business, 63, 511-524.

[54] Maheu, J., and T. McCurdy (2004), News Arrival, Jump Dynamics and Volatility Com-ponents for Individual Stock Returns, Journal of Finance, 59, 755—793.

[55] Nelson, D. B. (1991), Conditional Heteroskedasticity in Asset Returns: A New Ap-proach, Econometrica, 59, 347-370.

[56] Nelson, D. B. (1996), Asymptotically Optimal Smoothing with Arch Models, Econo-metrica, 64, 561-573.

[57] Nelson, D. B. and D. P. Foster (1994), Asymptotic Filtering Theory for Univariate ArchModels, Econometrica, 62, 1-41.

[58] Pan, J. (2002), The Jump-Risk Premia Implicit in Options: Evidence from an IntegratedTime-Series Study, Journal of Financial Economics, 63, 3—50.

[59] Perrakis, S. (1986), Option Bounds in Discrete Time: Extensions and the Pricing of theAmerican Put, Journal of Business, 59, 119-141.

[60] Perrakis, S. and P. Ryan (1984), Option Bounds in Discrete Time, Journal of Finance,39, 519-525.

[61] Ritchken, P. and S. Kuo (1988), Option Bounds with Finite Revision Opportunities,Journal of Finance, 43, 301-308.

[62] Ritchken, P. and R. Trevor (1999), Option Pricing Under GARCH and StochasticVolatility, Journal of Finance, 54, 377-402.

[63] Rubinstein, M. (1976), The Valuation of Uncertain Income Streams and the Pricing ofOptions, Bell Journal of Economics, 7, 407-425.

[64] Satchell, S., and A. Timmermann (1996), Option Pricing with GARCH and SystematicConsumption Risk, Derivatives Use, Trading & Regulation, Part II, 1, 353-67.

[65] Schroder, M. (2004), Risk Neutral Parameter Shifts and Derivatives Pricing in DiscreteTime, Journal of Finance, 59, 2375-2402.

[66] Schwert, G.W. (1989), Why Does Stock Market Volatility Change over Time? Journalof Finance, 44, 1115-1153.

38

Page 39: Option Valuation with Conditional … Valuation with Conditional Heteroskedasticity and Non-Normality ∗ Peter Christoffersen Redouane Elkamhi McGill University and CREATES McGill

[67] Shiryaev, A. (1999), Essentials of Stochastic Finance. Facts, Models, Theory, WorldScientific.

[68] Siu, T.K., H. Tong, and H. Yang (2004), On Pricing Derivatives under GARCHModels:A Dynamic Gerber-Shiu Approach, North American Actuarial Journal, 8, 17-31.

39

Page 40: Option Valuation with Conditional … Valuation with Conditional Heteroskedasticity and Non-Normality ∗ Peter Christoffersen Redouane Elkamhi McGill University and CREATES McGill

Figure 1: Quantile-Quantile Plot of S&P500 Returns Against the Normal Distribution

-20 -15 -10 -5 0 5 10 15 20-20

-15

-10

-5

0

5

10

15

20

Normal Quantiles

Dat

a Q

uant

iles

Notes to Figure: We take daily returns on the S&P500 from January 2, 1980 to December30, 2005 and standardize them by the sample mean and sample standard deviation. Thequantiles of the standardized returns are plotted against the quantiles from the standardnormal distribution.

40

Page 41: Option Valuation with Conditional … Valuation with Conditional Heteroskedasticity and Non-Normality ∗ Peter Christoffersen Redouane Elkamhi McGill University and CREATES McGill

Figure 2: Autocorrelation Function of Absolute S&P500 Returns

10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100-0.05

0

0.05

0.1

0.15

0.2

Lag Order

Aut

ocor

rela

tion

Notes to Figure: From daily absolute returns on the S&P500 from January 2, 1980 toDecember 30, 2005 we compute and plot the sample autocorrelations for lags one through100 days. The horizontal dashed lines denote 95% Bartlett confidence intervals around zero.

41

Page 42: Option Valuation with Conditional … Valuation with Conditional Heteroskedasticity and Non-Normality ∗ Peter Christoffersen Redouane Elkamhi McGill University and CREATES McGill

Figure 3: Autocorrelation Function of Absolute GARCH Innovations

10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100-0.05

0

0.05

0.1

0.15

0.2

Lag Order

Aut

ocor

rela

tion

Notes to Figure: From the estimated GARCH model in Table 1 we construct the absolutestandardized sequence of shocks and plot the sample autocorrelations for lags one through100 days. The horizontal dashed lines denote 95% Bartlett confidence intervals around zero.

42

Page 43: Option Valuation with Conditional … Valuation with Conditional Heteroskedasticity and Non-Normality ∗ Peter Christoffersen Redouane Elkamhi McGill University and CREATES McGill

Figure 4: Quantile-Quantile Plots of GARCH Innovations Against the Normal Distribution

-10 -5 0 5 10-10

-8

-6

-4

-2

0

2

4

6

8

10

Normal Quantiles

Dat

a Q

uant

iles

Notes to Figure: From the estimated GARCH models in Table 1 we compute the time seriesof dynamically standardized S&P500 returns. The quantiles of these GARCH innovationsare plotted against the quantiles from the standard normal distribution.

43

Page 44: Option Valuation with Conditional … Valuation with Conditional Heteroskedasticity and Non-Normality ∗ Peter Christoffersen Redouane Elkamhi McGill University and CREATES McGill

Figure 5: Quantile-Quantile Plots of GARCH Innovations Against the SVG Distribution

-10 -5 0 5 10-10

-8

-6

-4

-2

0

2

4

6

8

10

SVG Quantiles

Dat

a Q

uant

iles

Notes to Figure: From the estimated GARCH models in Table 1 we compute the time seriesof dynamically standardized S&P500 returns. The quantiles of these GARCH innovationsare plotted against the quantiles from the skewed variance gamma (SVG) distribution.

44

Page 45: Option Valuation with Conditional … Valuation with Conditional Heteroskedasticity and Non-Normality ∗ Peter Christoffersen Redouane Elkamhi McGill University and CREATES McGill

Figure 6: Implied Volatility Functions for Normal and SVG Independent Return Models

0.97 0.98 0.99 1 1.01 1.02 1.030.1

0.15

0.2

0.25

1 Day Maturity

0.92 0.94 0.96 0.98 1 1.02 1.04 1.06 1.080.15

0.2

0.25

1 Week Maturity

0.85 0.9 0.95 1 1.05 1.10.19

0.2

0.21

0.22

0.23

1 Month Maturity

Moneyness

Notes to Figure: From the estimated independent return model in Table 1 we compute calloption prices for various moneyness and maturities and we then compute implied Black-Scholes volatilities from the model option prices. Implied volatility is plotted against mon-eyness on the horizontal axis. The three panels correspond to maturities of 1 day, 1 week,and 1 month respectively. The solid lines show the i.i.d SVG model and the dashed lines thei.i.d. Normal models.

45

Page 46: Option Valuation with Conditional … Valuation with Conditional Heteroskedasticity and Non-Normality ∗ Peter Christoffersen Redouane Elkamhi McGill University and CREATES McGill

Figure 7: Implied Volatility Functions for Normal and SVG GARCH Models

0.97 0.98 0.99 1 1.01 1.02 1.030.15

0.2

0.25

1 Day Maturity

0.92 0.94 0.96 0.98 1 1.02 1.04 1.06 1.080.2

0.21

0.22

0.23

1 Week Maturity

0.85 0.9 0.95 1 1.05 1.10.2

0.21

0.22

0.23

1 Month Maturity

Moneyness

Notes to Figure: From the estimated GARCHmodel in Table 1 we compute call option pricesfor various moneyness and maturities and then we compute implied Black-Scholes volatilitiesfrom the model option prices. The implied volatilities are plotted with moneyness on thehorizontal axis. The three panels correspond to maturities of 1 day, 1 week, and 1 monthrespectively. The solid lines show the SVG GARCH model and the dashed lines the NormalGARCH model.

46

Page 47: Option Valuation with Conditional … Valuation with Conditional Heteroskedasticity and Non-Normality ∗ Peter Christoffersen Redouane Elkamhi McGill University and CREATES McGill

Figure 8: Convergence of Homoskedastic Inverse Gaussian to Black-Scholes Option Price

0 100 200 300 400 500 600 700 8003

4

5

6

7

8

9

Notes to Figure: We illustrate the convergence of the homoskedastic IG option price tothe BSM price when ∆ goes to zero. We let η(∆) = η∆, σ2(∆) = σ2∆, and set λ = 1,η = −0.001 per day, and σ = .10. per year.

47

Page 48: Option Valuation with Conditional … Valuation with Conditional Heteroskedasticity and Non-Normality ∗ Peter Christoffersen Redouane Elkamhi McGill University and CREATES McGill

Figure 9: Convergence of GARCH to Stochastic Volatility Option Price

0 100 200 300 400 500 600 700 8002.776

2.778

2.78

2.782

2.784

2.786

2.788

2.79

2.792

2.794

Notes to Figure: We show the convergence of the Heston and Nandi (2000) discrete timeGARCH option price to the continuous time SV option price in Heston (1993). We use r = 0,K = 100, S = 100, M∆ = 180, σ = 0.1, V = 0.01, κ = 2, θ = .01, and shock correlationρ = −1.

48

Page 49: Option Valuation with Conditional … Valuation with Conditional Heteroskedasticity and Non-Normality ∗ Peter Christoffersen Redouane Elkamhi McGill University and CREATES McGill

Table 1: Parameter Estimates and Model PropertiesDaily S&P500 Returns. January 2, 1980 - December 30, 2005.

Independent Returns GARCH ReturnsParameters Estimate Standard Error Estimate Standard Errorr 1.370E-04 1.370E-04λ 0.0313 0.0129 0.0312 0.0121β0 1.111E-04 9.9781E-06 1.516E-06 6.050E-07β1 0.8916 0.0274β2 0.0617 0.0154β3 0.7422 0.0808

Properties Independent Returns GARCH ReturnsLog-Likelihood 20,615.00 21,586.28Volatility Persistence 0 0.9873Annual Volatility 0.1673 0.1734Conditional Skewness -1.2105 -0.4127Conditional Kurtosis 27.3304 3.4935

Notes: We use quasi maximum likelihood to estimate an independent return and a GARCHreturn model on daily S&P500 returns from January 2, 1980 to December 30, 2005 for a totalof 6,564 observations. We report various properties of the two models including conditionalskewness and excess kurtosis which are later used as parameter estimates in the SVGmodels.

49