norms and rights: a non -recursive model of human...

40
NORMS AND RIGHTS: A NON-RECURSIVE MODEL OF HUMAN RIGHTS PROTECTION Dr. Todd Landman Senior Lecturer, Department of Government Co-Director, Human Rights Centre University of Essex Wivenhoe Park Colchester, Essex CO4 3SQ United Kingdom Tel/Fax: +44-(0)1206-872129 Email: [email protected] http://www.essex.ac.uk Paper prepared for the 99th Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association, Philadelphia 28-31 August 2003. Panel 46-6 Human Rights and Repression: The Quest for Understanding.

Upload: others

Post on 25-Jan-2020

10 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: NORMS AND RIGHTS: A NON -RECURSIVE MODEL OF HUMAN …gmandal.weebly.com/uploads/7/7/7/8/7778263/a_non...NORMS AND RIGHTS: A NON -RECURSIVE MODEL OF HUMAN RIGHTS PROTECTION Dr. Todd

NORMS AND RIGHTS: A NON-RECURSIVE MODEL OF HUMAN RIGHTS PROTECTION

Dr. Todd LandmanSenior Lecturer, Department of Government

Co-Director, Human Rights Centre

University of EssexWivenhoe Park

Colchester, Essex CO4 3SQUnited Kingdom

Tel/Fax: +44-(0)1206-872129Email: [email protected]://www.essex.ac.uk

Paper prepared for the 99th Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association, Philadelphia 28-31 August 2003. Panel 46-6 Human Rights and Repression: The Quest for Understanding.

Page 2: NORMS AND RIGHTS: A NON -RECURSIVE MODEL OF HUMAN …gmandal.weebly.com/uploads/7/7/7/8/7778263/a_non...NORMS AND RIGHTS: A NON -RECURSIVE MODEL OF HUMAN RIGHTS PROTECTION Dr. Todd

Norms and Rights: A Non-recursive model of human rights protection

Abstract

Drawing on theories from international relations, international law, and comparative politics, this paper tests the relationship between international human rights norms and human rights protection. Using a cross-national time series data set for 169 countries over the period 1976-2000, the paper explores the temporal and spatial patterns in the growth in the international human rights regime and the protection of human rights, and then models their mutual relationship using non-recursive estimation techniques, while controlling for the influences of democracy, wealth, international interdependence, warfare, population size, and regional differences. The results of the analysis show three things. First, the norms-rights relationship between the International Covenant of Civil and Political Rights and the protection of civil and political rights is statistically significant and stronger than for the rights-norms relationship. Second, democracy, wealth, and international interdependence help explain both treaty ratification and greater protection of human rights. Third, the norms- rights relationship is less strong for Latin America, Africa, Asia and the Pacific. Overall, the findings suggest that formal participation in the international regime of human rights complements patterns of development, democratisation, and global interdependence, all of which are related to a greater protection of human rights.

Page 3: NORMS AND RIGHTS: A NON -RECURSIVE MODEL OF HUMAN …gmandal.weebly.com/uploads/7/7/7/8/7778263/a_non...NORMS AND RIGHTS: A NON -RECURSIVE MODEL OF HUMAN RIGHTS PROTECTION Dr. Todd

1

Introduction

The turn of the new century offers an opportunity for reflection and critical

assessment of both the achievements and setbacks in the global human rights project.

The post-World War II era has seen the establishment and subsequent growth in the

international law of human rights, the turn away from authoritarianism with the global

spread of democratic forms of rule, and an increasing number of international

interventions carried out on behalf of human rights. The international law of human

rights includes major international and regional treaties, institutions, and

organisations. By the year 2000, between 95 and 191 countries have become

signatories to the main international legal instruments, which many have argued

comprise an international ‘regime’ for the promotion and protection of human rights

(Henkin 1979; Donnelly 1989; Hathaway 2002). This regime has grown both in

breadth and depth as new categories of human rights have been given express legal

protection, while an increasing number of countries have formally committed

themselves to the human rights norms and values originally found in the 1948 UN

Declaration. Similar such regimes have been established in Europe, the Americas, and

Africa.

Alongside this evolution in the international law of human rights, the world has seen a

dramatic turn away from authoritarian forms of rule to nascent forms of democracy.

Since the Portuguese transition to democracy in 1974, the global spread and pace of

democratisation has meant that over 60% of the world is now at least nominally

democratic (Diamond 1999). Global comparative studies on the tangible benefits of

democratic rule demonstrate a decrease in international violent conflict (see Russet

and O’Neal 2001), lower levels of violation in personal integrity rights (Poe and Tate

1994, Poe, Tate, and Keith 1999; Zanger 2000), and levels of economic development

and performance that are no worse than those found under authoritarian regimes

(Ersson and Lane 1996; Przeworski, Alvarez, Cheibub, and Limongi 2000).

In addition to the development of human rights law and processes of democratisation,

the world has witnessed an increasing number of foreign interventions carried out

ostensibly on behalf of human rights or humanitarian grounds such as those in East

Timor and Kosovo. Moreover, the tradition of human rights tribunals first established

Page 4: NORMS AND RIGHTS: A NON -RECURSIVE MODEL OF HUMAN …gmandal.weebly.com/uploads/7/7/7/8/7778263/a_non...NORMS AND RIGHTS: A NON -RECURSIVE MODEL OF HUMAN RIGHTS PROTECTION Dr. Todd

2

in Nuremberg has been renewed with tribunals for Rwanda and the former

Yugoslavia. Variants of such tribunals have appeared at the domestic level with the

formation of numerous truth and reconciliation commissions (TRCs) in Latin

America, Africa, and Eastern Europe whose remit has been to collect information on

past crimes against humanity and to offer some form of reconciliation to deeply torn

societies (De Brito 1997; Roniger and Sznajder 1999; Hayner 1994, 2002). This

proliferation of tribunals has culminated in the establishment of the International

Criminal Court (ICC), a process that has been described as the international

‘institutionalisation of criminal liability’ (Falk 2000: 4).

Scholars and commentators have thus argued by the turn of this Century the world has

entered the ‘age of rights’ (Bobbio 1996), experienced a ‘juridical revolution’

(Ignatieff 2001); a process of international ‘legalization’ (Abbott et al. 2000) and

‘judicialization’ (Stone Sweet 1999) in which rights have established the normative

framework for ‘human conduct in the world of states’ (Jackson 2000). Taken

together, this development of international and regional human rights systems,

coupled with democratisation and ethically oriented foreign relations suggests that

nation states formally participating in the international legal mechanisms for human

rights protection are increasingly embedded into larger institutional structures that

seek to constrain and limit state behaviour in order to protect the sanctity of

individuals and certain collectivities.1 Even those states that have not signed or

ratified the various human rights instruments find themselves under increased

international pressure from intergovernmental and non-governmental organizations to

join these regimes and to change their practices to make them conform to the

normative global expectations that adhere to human rights values (see, e.g. Risse,

Ropp, and Sikkink 1999; Welch 2001).

These developments may lead to the sanguine conclusion that human rights have

finally triumphed and now provide the normative framework for the future of global

1 By certain collectivities, I refer to the various ways in which minority rights have become increasingly protected, for example, by the 1957 International Labour Organisation Convention No. 107 on the Protection of Indigenous and other Tribal and semi-Tribal Populations in Independent Countries, the 1989 ILO Convention No. 169 on Indigenous and Tribal peoples, and the 1992 UN Declaration on the Rights of Minorities (Philips 1997: viii-xiii). Such protection means that certain groups in society (typically non-dominant and numerically small) have special protections against majority incursions in areas such as education, health, employment, language, and religion.

Page 5: NORMS AND RIGHTS: A NON -RECURSIVE MODEL OF HUMAN …gmandal.weebly.com/uploads/7/7/7/8/7778263/a_non...NORMS AND RIGHTS: A NON -RECURSIVE MODEL OF HUMAN RIGHTS PROTECTION Dr. Todd

3

politics, echoing earlier claims about the ‘end of ideology’ (Bell 1960) and the ‘end of

history’ (Fukuyama 1992). In contrast to such a rosy assessment, others suggest that

the rights agenda is certainly on the table but that it has ‘yet to realize the rudiments of

its full political potential’ (Foweraker and Landman 1997: 243), and that we have

witnessed the ‘precarious triumph of human rights’ (Reiff 1999). It is a triumph since

even the most optimistic observers in 1948 could not have imagined the subsequent

growth and influence of human rights discourse and doctrine. But it is precarious

since these same achievements can easily be reversed, where politics and power have

shaped the different ways in which such gains have been achieved. Moreover, the

world is still a place in which 'there are more countries … where fundamental rights

and civil liberties are regularly violated than countries where they are effectively

protected' (Robertson and Merrills 1996: 2).

In 1990, Amnesty International noted that out of 179 UN member states, 104 states

had committed acts of torture against their citizens, while in their 2002 report, 111 out

of 194 member states continue such practices (Amnesty International 1990; Amnesty

International 2002). These numbers indicate only a one percent drop in the number of

states practicing torture (58 percent in 1990 and 57 percent in 2002) over the last

decade of the 20th Century. Additional data on human rights protection shows that in

1985, 35% of all countries score ‘6’ or higher on the Freedom House scale for civil

liberties (range of 1 to 7), 12-13% score a ‘4’ or higher on the ‘political terror scale’

(range of 1 to 5) for both Amnesty and State Department coding sources (Poe and

Tate 1994; Poe, Tate, and Keith 1999), and 22% score a ‘4’ or higher on a scale of

torture (range 1 to 5) (Hathaway 2002). These scores on the various scales are all at

the high end, which depicts a consistent and regular violation of the rights measured

by each. By 1993, the percentage of countries with such scores increased dramatically

to 42% with a score of ‘6’ or higher on the Freedom House scale for civil liberties,

31% with a score of ‘4’ or higher on the political terror scale, and 39% with a score

of ‘4’ or higher on a scale of torture.

There is thus a significant and persistent gap between rights in principle (i.e. those

formally protected by international law) and rights in practice (i.e. those rights

actually protected by states and enjoyed by individuals and groups) (Foweraker and

Page 6: NORMS AND RIGHTS: A NON -RECURSIVE MODEL OF HUMAN …gmandal.weebly.com/uploads/7/7/7/8/7778263/a_non...NORMS AND RIGHTS: A NON -RECURSIVE MODEL OF HUMAN RIGHTS PROTECTION Dr. Todd

4

Landman 1997).2 This paper is concerned precisely with this significant and persistent

gap between principle and practice in human rights protection. Such a gap suggests

that there has thus far been an unfilled expectation that the growth and sophistication

in the international regime of human rights will lead to a greater protection of human

rights. The fact that rights protection continues to be precarious despite the increasing

participation of states in the various systems for their protection raises two

fundamental questions for empirical research: (1) what explains the growth of the

international law of human rights and (2) what is the nature of the relationship

between the international law of human rights and the actual protection of human

rights?

To begin addressing these questions, this paper is divided into four parts. First, it

examines a certain convergence in the theories of public international law,

international relations, and comparative politics around the general topic of regimes,

and makes specific reference to the human rights regime. It shows that legal-

proceduralism, neo-liberal institutionalism, liberal-republicanism, and new

institutionalism have similar concerns over how principles, legal norms, and

institutions both facilitate and constrain state behaviour. This convergence in thinking

raises expectations for the impact of international institutions on state behaviour in

areas such as trade, finance, and environmental protection, while human rights

scholars suggest that such expectations may equally apply to the international human

rights regime (Keith 1999; Hathaway 2002).

Second, the paper uses the analytical categories and variables drawn from these three

areas of theory to specify a preliminary empirical model that depicts the complex

relationship between the international law of human rights and the protection of

human rights. The model includes treaty and rights variables and identifies

independent variables that may modulate the relationship in important and significant

ways, including democracy, wealth, interdependence, involvement in international

and domestic conflict, population size and regional differentiation. Third, it estimates

the model for one international human rights treaty and five separate measures of

human rights protection using two-staged least squares regression with instrumental

2 In the language of international lawyers, this gap exists between the de jure protection and de factorealisation of human rights.

Page 7: NORMS AND RIGHTS: A NON -RECURSIVE MODEL OF HUMAN …gmandal.weebly.com/uploads/7/7/7/8/7778263/a_non...NORMS AND RIGHTS: A NON -RECURSIVE MODEL OF HUMAN RIGHTS PROTECTION Dr. Todd

5

variables. Fourth, it discusses the findings in light of the substantive issues raised in

the first part of the paper. The results of the analysis show a statistically significant

relationship between norms and rights for three out of the five human rights measures,

which is stronger than for the relationship between rights and norms. The norms-

rights relationship, however, must be seen as a function of larger processes of

democratisation, economic wealth, and global interdependence.

Part I: A Nexus for Empirical Theories

Human rights provide an important nexus for empirical theories of law, politics and

international relations. Public international lawyers speak of the problems of

compliance and implementation (Chayes and Chayes 1993; Slaughter-Burley 1993;

Higgins 1994; Koh 1997; Hathaway 2002). International relations scholars speak of

problems of regime creation, effectiveness and enforcement (Keohane 1984;

Rittberger 1997; Young 1992; 1999). Comparativists focus on the ways in which

differences across domestic systems of governance have an impact on regime

participation and rights protection (Moravcsik 1997, 2000; Poe and Tate 1994; Keith

1999; Landman 2002, 2003; Donnelly 1986; 1999), as well as the linkages between

international politics, domestic politics and transnational non-state actors (Keck and

Sikkink 1998; Risse, Ropp, and Sikkink 1999).

Traditionally, these three families of theory and research have had very little to do

with each other (Raustialia and Slaughter 2000). But since the 1980s there appears to

have been a convergence of work around the general topic of regimes to examine the

degree to which international law, norms, and principles shape state behaviour. The

consideration of human rights has increasingly been included in regime analysis, a

process that has brought international law and international relations closer together

(see Donnelly 1986; Keith 1999; Krasner 1997; 1999; Hathaway 2002; Schmitz and

Sikkink 2002). These concerns at the international level have also transcended the

study of domestic forms of state-citizen relations, the traditional domain of

comparative politics. Certain strands of international relations theory focus on

domestic actors, collective domestic preferences, and national institutional

arrangements influence international action (Henkin 1979: 60-68; Putnam 1993;

Moravcsik 1997; 2000; Slaughter Burley 1993: 227-228). Thus the ‘double

Page 8: NORMS AND RIGHTS: A NON -RECURSIVE MODEL OF HUMAN …gmandal.weebly.com/uploads/7/7/7/8/7778263/a_non...NORMS AND RIGHTS: A NON -RECURSIVE MODEL OF HUMAN RIGHTS PROTECTION Dr. Todd

6

convergence’ of theoretical concerns at the international and domestic levels of

analysis around the topic of human rights demonstrates a growing interest in the ways

in which the promotion and protection of human dignity can be analysed empirically.

International Law and International Relations

International law and international relations have long been concerned with the ways

in which states interact with one another, and both fields have traditionally built their

theories on the twin assumptions of state sovereignty and non-intervention, most

notably embodied in the 1648 Treaty of Westphalia. Both the modern state system

and international law have developed dramatically since the end of the Thirty Years

War, where international law moved from 'natural' foundations to 'positive'

foundations (Slaughter-Burley 1993: 207-220; Koh 1997: 2603-2614) addressing an

ever-increasing variety of issue areas. Similarly, international relations theory evolved

from a dominance of ethical and normative perspectives on the conduct of states to

those that are increasingly empirical and positivist (Boucher 1998; Schmidt 2002).

For much of the post-World War II era there has been a natural tension between

international law represented by the legal positivists on the one hand and international

relations represented by the realists on the other.

Legal positivists focus on the ‘neutral’ function of international law as it is meant to

be applied to problem areas devoid of any considerations of the nature of power

differences between states or of the international system more generally (e.g. Austin

1975 [1954]; Kelsen 1949). This could be labelled the ‘law without power’

perspective. In contrast, realist theories of international relations, built on the

assumption of states as unitary rational actors, play down the importance of

international law and relegate it to something that is merely ‘epiphenomenal’. Realists

argue that the structure of power between and among states as they maximise their

preferences is the key determinant of political outcomes (e.g. Kennan 1951;

Morgenthau 1961; Waltz 1979; Schmitz and Sikkink 2000; Donnelly 2000). This

could be labelled the ‘power without law’ perspective.3

3 Kennan (1951: 95-99) argues that international law rests on 'the belief that it should be possible to suppress the chaotic and dangerous aspirations of governments in the international field by the acceptance of some system of legal rules and restraints…[and that such a] legalistic approach to international relations is faulty in its assumptions concerning the possibility of sanctions against offenses and violations…' In similar fashion, Morgenthau (1958: 73) has an equal disdain for legalistic

Page 9: NORMS AND RIGHTS: A NON -RECURSIVE MODEL OF HUMAN …gmandal.weebly.com/uploads/7/7/7/8/7778263/a_non...NORMS AND RIGHTS: A NON -RECURSIVE MODEL OF HUMAN RIGHTS PROTECTION Dr. Todd

7

These two perspectives represent extreme ends of a broad continuum of scholarship

on international law and international relations produced during the 1960-1989 period,

which Slaughter-Burley (1993: 207) has deigned the ‘polarity of law and power’.

Along the continuum, the Yale and Columbia schools of international law offered

alternative perspectives that emphasised the importance of international community

and the formality of norms on the one hand, and sovereign autonomy and informality

of norms on the other (Kennedy 2000: 117-120). This legal scholarship gave way to

new forms of 'legal pragmatism' and 'legal proceduralism' during the 1990s, both of

which temper the neutral understanding of law by focusing on the 'interplay between

rules and social process in enunciating the law' (Koh 1997: 2618). Legal pragmatists

concede that power and ideology not only influence law, but that law itself is a

continuing process of authoritative decisions (Higgins 1968: 58-59 in Higgins 1994:

2, emphasis mine; see also Slaughter-Burley 1993: 209-214), where any conception of

law which ‘banishes power to the outer darkness’ is pure ‘fantasy’ and that ‘[t]he

authority which characterizes law exists not in a vacuum, but exactly where it

intersects with power’ (Higgins 1994: 4).

Within international relations, there has been a similar set of moves away from

extreme realism to include the consideration of how power interacts with law, norms,

principles and institutions more generally. Hegemonic stability theory concedes that

certain norms over time become important but that ultimately the enforcement of

international law depends on the existence, willingness, and capacity of powerful (or

hegemonic) states. In this view, ‘[r]egime creation and maintenance are a function of

the distribution of power and interests among states’ (Krasner 1997: 140). For

example, in comparing regimes on religious practices in the seventeenth century,

slavery in the nineteenth century, minority rights in Central Europe in the late

nineteenth and early twentieth centuries, and individual rights in the late twentieth

century, Krasner (1997: 141) shows that the variance in regime success depends very

much on the ‘capabilities and commitment of those states that supported each of these

regimes.’ Indeed, he contends that the abolition of slavery would not have been

possible without the vigorous monitoring and enforcement of the regime by the major

approaches to international relations whose 'common denominator … is the substitution for the national interest of an assumed supranational standard of action…' (see Henkin 1979: 322-323; 330).

Page 10: NORMS AND RIGHTS: A NON -RECURSIVE MODEL OF HUMAN …gmandal.weebly.com/uploads/7/7/7/8/7778263/a_non...NORMS AND RIGHTS: A NON -RECURSIVE MODEL OF HUMAN RIGHTS PROTECTION Dr. Todd

8

European powers, especially Britain (Krasner 1997: 143-144; 152-155).4 This

perspective thus moves slightly away from ‘power without law’ to one of ‘law, but

only with dominant power(s) willing to enforce it’.

Neo-liberal institutionalists move further away from hegemonic stability theorists and

argue that ‘post-hegemonic’ forms of international cooperation are possible. Such a

perspective focuses on how institutions emerge from state interest and then attenuate

the power relations between and among states. In After Hegemony, Keohane (1984:8)

argues that rational states will cooperate out of self-interest, even though such

cooperation will not always prevail. But interests are malleable and the increased

interdependence of states creates incentives for cooperation. The mutual advantage

and reciprocity that emerge from international co-operation (e.g. lower transaction

costs, access to information, expectations of behaviour) explains why states would

enter into international agreements. And unlike hegemonic stability theory, stable co-

operation 'equilibria' are possible without the presence of a dominant enforcer. This

perspective comes very close to legal-proceduralism outlined above since it too

focuses on the ways in which mutual benefit and reciprocity provide the conditions

under which otherwise self-interested states would cooperate with each other.

This convergence around the relationship between law and power has been further

addressed by ‘constructivist’ approaches in international relations, which occupy a

partly middle and partly lateral position to realist and legal-positivist perspectives. In

contrast to accepting law or power as given, constructivists focus their attention on the

ways in which law and power as well as the agents or 'subjects' that articulate them

are socially constructed within international affairs. They thus look at the origins,

emergence and maintenance of ideas, norms, principles, and laws as constitutive

processes rather than some outcome of the strategic interaction of states (Wendt 1999;

Fearon and Wendt 2002: 56-58). Accentuating the difference between the

intentionality and holism of interstate state relations and behaviour, constructivist

approaches embed their arguments in the logic of 'appropriateness' (i.e. what the

4 In another example, Donnelly (1986: 625) argues that the hegemonic authority of the United States supported the creation of the Inter-American regional system for the protection of human rights with its relatively strong monitoring powers.

Page 11: NORMS AND RIGHTS: A NON -RECURSIVE MODEL OF HUMAN …gmandal.weebly.com/uploads/7/7/7/8/7778263/a_non...NORMS AND RIGHTS: A NON -RECURSIVE MODEL OF HUMAN RIGHTS PROTECTION Dr. Todd

9

international context expects of states)5 rather than the logic of 'consequences' (i.e. the

outcomes of state behaviour) (March and Olsen 1998). Such a constructivist

perspective dovetails with the legal-procedural and neo-institutional perspectives

outlined above. On the one hand, legal-proceduralists are precisely interested in the

construction of international law as an iterative political process. On the other hand,

Wendt (1999) shows convincingly that the social and political construction of

preferences and interests of states precedes any strategic interaction in which they

may engage. Thus, the construction of international cooperative regimes, law, or

institutions must be seen as a function of broader processes of normative transmission

and internalization (see also Henkin 1979: 60-62; Falk 2000: 60-66).

Legal proceduralism, neo-liberal institutionalism, and constructivism are all important

for the theory of regimes. For Young (1992), ‘[r]egimes are sets of rules, decision-

making procedures, and/or programs that give rise to social practices, assign roles to

the participants in these practices, and govern their interactions’. In addition, a regime

is a ‘collection of rights and rules’ that ‘structure the opportunities of the actors

interested in a given activity’, has a significant procedural component for the

resolution of situations involving social or collective choices, and has the expectation

for compliance among its members (Young 1980: 333-342). Realist and neo-liberal

institutionalist theories demonstrate that regimes are created and are effective through

the application of cost-benefit analysis by states, while constructivist theories argue

that regime effectiveness is achieved through ‘internalized identities and norms of

appropriate behaviour’ (Raustiala and Slaughter 2002: 540). Like constructivism,

international law differs from realism and neo-liberal institutionalism in its view of

regimes. It turns its attention away from cost-benefit functions of regimes and

concentrates on their provision of rules. Such rules foster stable expectations for

actors and establish efficient baselines and standards, criteria for the justification of

action, processes of communication, opportunities for domestic and international

‘intermeshing’ of bureaucracies, and routinized habits of compliance (Slaughter-

Burley 1993: 220).

5 Henkin (1979: 93) goes as far as to say that '[m]uch of law, and the most successful part, is a codification of existing mores, of how people behave and they feel they ought to behave. To that extent law reflects rather than imposes, existing order. To say that nations act pursuant to law only as they would act anyhow may indicate not that law is irrelevant, but rather that it is sound and viable, reflecting the true interests and attitudes of nations, and that it is likely to be maintained.'

Page 12: NORMS AND RIGHTS: A NON -RECURSIVE MODEL OF HUMAN …gmandal.weebly.com/uploads/7/7/7/8/7778263/a_non...NORMS AND RIGHTS: A NON -RECURSIVE MODEL OF HUMAN RIGHTS PROTECTION Dr. Todd

10

But not all regimes are the same as Donnelly (1986) demonstrates. For him, regimes

vary according to their level of norms (fully international to entirely national) and

their types of decision-making activities (enforcement, implementation, or promotion)

(Donnelly 1986: 603-604). The combination of these two dimensions (norms and

decision making) creates a typology that ranges from ‘strong declaratory’ regimes to

‘weak promotional’ regimes, where the strength of any one regime is determined by

its normative and procedural scope, as well as by its overall acceptance and coherence

(Ibid., 604-605). While the notion of acceptance is straightforward, coherence

requires a match between the normative and procedural dimensions of the regime

(Ibid., 605), or what Keohane (2002: 135) calls a high degree of ‘precision’. This

difference in regime type and strength is important, as the discussion of the

international human rights regime below will demonstrate. But before bringing

together these different aspects of international law and international relations with

respect to human rights, it is first necessary to consider the contribution from

empirical theories in comparative politics.

Comparative Politics

The field of comparative politics has long been concerned with how and why the

relationship between citizens and the state varies across different national political

contexts. The substantive focus of the field has included patterns of stability and

instability in advanced industrial democracies; the emergence, maintenance, and

performance of liberal democracy; the origins and consequences of violent and non-

violent social mobilization; the emergence, duration and performance of authoritarian

regimes; patterns of democratic transition and consolidation; processes of

regionalization and globalization; and the political economy of development (see

Almond and Powell 1966; Macridis and Brown 1990; Rustow and Erickson 1991;

Chilcote 1994; Apter 1996; Mair 1996; Landman 2000, 2003). Theories in

comparative politics reflect similar concerns to those found in international relations:

rational actors, ideas, norms, institutions, and structures. Like international relations,

rationalist, culturalist, and structuralist theories in comparative politics help account

for and understand political outcomes and patterns that are observed across different

political contexts. These theories have similar tensions that are the product of both

their base assumptions and their analytical scope of human behaviour. Rationalist

Page 13: NORMS AND RIGHTS: A NON -RECURSIVE MODEL OF HUMAN …gmandal.weebly.com/uploads/7/7/7/8/7778263/a_non...NORMS AND RIGHTS: A NON -RECURSIVE MODEL OF HUMAN RIGHTS PROTECTION Dr. Todd

11

perspectives concentrate on the actions and behaviour of individuals who make

reasoned and intentional choices based upon sets of preferences, or interests. Those

who adhere to the rationalist perspective are 'concerned with the collective processes

and outcomes that follow from intentionality, or the social consequences of

individually rational action' (Lichbach 1997: 246; see also Munck 2001). Like realism

in international relations, rationalism in comparative politics concentrates on ‘means-

ends’ calculations and how they affect political outcomes. But realism engages in

‘methodological nationalism’ (Zürn 2002: 248) while rationalism as it is deployed in

comparative politics engages in ‘methodological individualism’ (Przeworski 1985).

In contrast to the rationalist perspective, culturalist perspectives in comparative

politics seek an understanding of political phenomena by focusing on the broader

holistic and shared aspects of collectivities. Single individual interests and actions are

not understood in isolation, but are placed in the context of the shared understandings,

inter-subjective relationships, and mutual orientations that make human communities

possible (Lichbach 1997: 246-247). These shared meanings and understandings form

broader cultures and communities grouped together and analysed as whole units. They

are held together by social rules that are emblematic of the identities of both the

individuals and the groups themselves (ibid.: 247). Identifying the boundaries of these

cultural units and separate identities remains problematic for systematic comparative

research; however, scholars have tried to examine the world views, rituals, and

symbols that provide 'systems of meaning and the structure and intensity of political

identity' across different geographical regions of the world (Ross 1997: 43-44).

Culturalist approaches are akin to their constructivist counterparts in international

relations, where the social construction and meaning of ideas and norms forms the

basis for analysis.

Structuralists focus on the holistic aspects of politics, but unlike culturalists, their

attention is drawn to interdependent relationships among individuals, collectivities,

institutions, and organizations. They are interested in the social, political, and

economic networks that form between and among individuals. Structures that have

become reified over time constrain or facilitate political activity such that individual

actors are not completely free agents capable of determining particular political

outcomes (Lichbach 1997: 247-248). Rather, individuals are embedded in relational

Page 14: NORMS AND RIGHTS: A NON -RECURSIVE MODEL OF HUMAN …gmandal.weebly.com/uploads/7/7/7/8/7778263/a_non...NORMS AND RIGHTS: A NON -RECURSIVE MODEL OF HUMAN RIGHTS PROTECTION Dr. Todd

12

structures that shape human identities, interests, and interaction. Relational structures

have evolved through large historical processes such as capitalist development,

market rationality, nation state building, political and scientific revolutions, and

technological progress (Katznelson 1997: 83), all of which provide possibilities and

limits for human action.

Like the polarity of law and power in the fields of international law and international

relations, rationalist and structuralist accounts of politics have created a polarity

between ‘structureless agents’ on the one hand (extreme rational choice) and

‘agentless structures’ on the other (extreme structuralists). This polarity between

agents and structures (see Hay 1995; 2002) has converged (or has sought to be

resolved) around the idea of ‘new-institutionalism’ (March and Olsen 1984), which

not only seeks to examine the constrained rationality of actors as they confront the

persistence of institutional forms, but also brings in culturalist concerns over symbolic

action, norms, and ideas (March and Olsen 1984:739, 744). Like the claim that

‘international law matters’ from public international lawyers, proponents of new

institutionalism equally make the claim that ‘institutions matter’ (Steinmo, Thelen,

and Longstreth 1992), and there is no surprise that proponents of new institutionalism

at the domestic level have turned their attention to the international level (compare

March and Olsen 1984 to March and Olsen 1998).

Cross-over: two-level games and liberal-republicanism

Examining these developments in international law, international relations and

comparative politics shows that the traditional polarities in international and

comparative research have been partly transcended and have produced similar

convergences around the idea of constrained action. Legal-proceduralism, neo-liberal

institutionalism, and new-institutionalism are all concerned with the ways in which

law, power, ideas, norms, and institutions intersect to both facilitate and limit choices

that are available to individuals and states. The insights from these seemingly

disparate perspectives contribute to our understanding of the ways in which states

make agreements and how such agreements affect their behaviour. Legal-

proceduralism shows how norms emerge through express consent of states, the

absence of opposition to such norms, or the failure of attempts to oppose them.

Obligations to abide by these norms arise through a perception that there is a

Page 15: NORMS AND RIGHTS: A NON -RECURSIVE MODEL OF HUMAN …gmandal.weebly.com/uploads/7/7/7/8/7778263/a_non...NORMS AND RIGHTS: A NON -RECURSIVE MODEL OF HUMAN RIGHTS PROTECTION Dr. Todd

13

reciprocal advantage in cautioning self-restraint (Higgins 1994: 16). Thus, both the

emergence of norms and adherence to them can be seen as a process that involves the

power of states to engage in activity that yields mutual benefit. Equally, for

proponents of neo-liberal institutionalism, individual and mutual state advantage can

be achieved through the formation of agreements. New-institutionalists see such

interactions between formal institutions and individual actions at the domestic level.

Robert Putnam’s (1993) work on ‘two-level’ games brings these convergent views in

international and comparative research together. He observes that ‘[t]he most

portentous development in the fields of comparative politics and international

relations in recent years is the dawning recognition among practitioners in each field

of the need to take into account entanglements between the two’ (Putnam 1993: 459).

Thus, any engagement of a state in international relations reflects the domestic array

of social and political forces, including key actors and institutions (Ibid., 435). The

politics of such a two-level game is neatly summarised as follows:

At the national level, domestic groups pursue their interests by pressuring the government to adopt favourable policies, and the politicians seek power by constructing coalitions among those groups. At the international level, national governments seek to maximize their own ability to satisfy domestic pressures, while minimising the adverse consequences of foreign developments (Ibid., 436).

While there may be different ‘rational’ strategies available at either level of the game,

Putnam (1993: 473) argues that ‘there are powerful incentives for consistency

between the two games.’ What is absent from the formulation of the two-level game is

any consideration of the type of government that is in place, although it appears that

Putnam implies some form of representative government and most of his empirical

examples are of advanced industrial democracies.6 Indeed, liberal democratic states

are simply more open to and reflective of competing claims from domestic groups

than authoritarian states. Nevertheless, as the elite-centred work on democratic

transitions demonstrates (e.g. Przeworski 1991; Colomer 2000), authoritarian regimes

are susceptible to competing demands within the authoritarian coalition as well as

6 In drawing on the two-lebvel game, Ripsman (2002) shows that different degrees of executive autonomy in Britain, France,and the United States affect the ways in which they conducted foreign policy in the immediate post war period.

Page 16: NORMS AND RIGHTS: A NON -RECURSIVE MODEL OF HUMAN …gmandal.weebly.com/uploads/7/7/7/8/7778263/a_non...NORMS AND RIGHTS: A NON -RECURSIVE MODEL OF HUMAN RIGHTS PROTECTION Dr. Todd

14

from groups in civil society, however repressed it may be. Thus, it is possible to think

in broader terms on how the games played at the domestic level (whatever type of

government is in place) will be important for the types of interaction in which states

will engage at the international level.

Drawing on the insights of the two-level game and combining them with variants of

democratic peace theory, Moravcsik (1997, 2000) develops a theory of ‘liberal

republicanism’, which makes explicit reference to democratic forms of rule and how

such domestic systems will have an influence on countries’ propensity for making

international agreements. He argues that making international agreements can ‘lock

in’ and consolidate democratic institutions, thereby enhancing their credibility and

stability in the long run against possible threats from non-democratic forces. In

echoing realist language, he argue that states will make such agreements when the

benefits of reducing future uncertainty outweigh the costs of membership in an

international regime (Moravcsik 2000: 220). He claims that this argument only really

applies to newly established democracies since they face more immediate uncertainty

which regime membership tempers, but other scholars suggest that regime

membership, particularly for human rights, is a function of democracy in general (see

Zacher 1992: 94; Vincent 1986).

The International Human Rights Regime

This ‘double convergence’ in international and comparative research combined with

concerns over the interaction of domestic and international politics provides a rich

theoretical basis that helps explain the growth and effectiveness of the international

human rights regime. The growth of the international human rights regime

demonstrates that human rights have now become enshrined in bodies of international

law represented most forcefully by the existence of international treaties to which

states become a party and, at least in formal terms, agree to abide by the obligations

found within them. From the International Covenant on Civil and Political Rights

(1966) through to the Rome Statute on the establishment of the International Criminal

Court (2002), increasing types of human rights have found expression in international

law and an increasing number of states have signed and ratified the treaties. Table 1

summarises these instruments, lists the date when they became open for signature, and

shows the number of states parties to the instruments as of 2000. It is clear from the

Page 17: NORMS AND RIGHTS: A NON -RECURSIVE MODEL OF HUMAN …gmandal.weebly.com/uploads/7/7/7/8/7778263/a_non...NORMS AND RIGHTS: A NON -RECURSIVE MODEL OF HUMAN RIGHTS PROTECTION Dr. Todd

15

table that the regime has become increasingly specialised beyond the main

International Bill of Human Rights (i.e. the Universal Declaration and the two

International Covenants) to include the rights of women and children, as well as

prohibition of specific acts such as torture and racial discrimination. It is also clear

that overall formal participation of states ranges from 22% to 98%.

Table 1. The international human rights regime: instruments, dates, and membershipName Date when open

for signatureStates parties 2000 N and %

International Covenant on Civil and Political Rights (ICCPR)

1966 146(75.6)

International Covenant on Economic, Social, and Cultural Rights (ICESCR)

1966 142(73.6)

Optional Protocol to the International Covenant on Civil and Political Rights (OPT1)

1976 95(49.2)

Second Optional Protocol to the International Covenant on Civil and Political Rights (OPT2)

1989 44(22.8)

International Convention on the Elimination of all Forms of Racial Discrimination (CERD)

1966 156(80.8)

Convention on the Elimination of All Forms of Discrimination against Women (CEDAW)

1979 164(85.0)

Convention against Torture and other Cruel, Inhuman, or Degrading Treatment or Punishment (CAT)

1984 122(63.2)

Convention on the Rights of the Child (CRC) 1989 190(98.4)

Data source: OUNHCHR (Sept. 2000), Status of Ratification of the principal International Human Rights Treaties, www.unhchr.ch/pdf/report.pdf and International Service for Human Rights (January 2000), Info-Pack, pp. 46-50. See also Bayefsky (2001: 11).

Unlike other international regimes in areas such as environmental protection and trade

which involve the regulation of the interaction between states, human rights is a

special area since the international regime seeks to uphold state obligations and state

responsibility towards individuals and groups (Higgins 1994: 95; Moravcsik 2000:

217). Its growth appears counter-intuitive if one adopts a purely realist perspective,

which is captured effectively by the following question:

Why would any government, democratic or dictatorial, favour establishing an effective, independent international authority, the sole purpose of which is to constrain its domestic sovereignty in such an

Page 18: NORMS AND RIGHTS: A NON -RECURSIVE MODEL OF HUMAN …gmandal.weebly.com/uploads/7/7/7/8/7778263/a_non...NORMS AND RIGHTS: A NON -RECURSIVE MODEL OF HUMAN RIGHTS PROTECTION Dr. Todd

16

unprecedentedly invasive and overtly non-majoritarian manner? (Moravcsik 2000: 219).

The inability for a purely interest-based theory of state action to explain the

proliferation of human rights norms suggests that neo-liberal institutionalism and

legal-proceduralism offer a more satisfactory account by focusing on the historically

iterative process of norm proliferation and the construction of state behaviour. The

fact that states have signed and ratified human rights treaties of the years has led to

certain optimism among international lawyers that increased state participation in the

international human rights regime ought to make a difference for human rights

protection. But analysis of regime effectiveness is incomplete if one merely focuses

on either the international law of human rights or on domestic political arrangements

and institutions. Legal-proceduralism, neo-liberal institutionalism, and new-

institutionalism help build a fuller picture of the ways in which both domestic and

international factors are important in considering the relationship between the

international human rights regime and human rights protection.

The preceding examination of the double convergence in theories from international

law, international relations, and comparative politics is summarised in Figure 1. The

top of the figure charts the transformation in international legal and international

relations scholarship, while the bottom of the figure charts the ways in which rational,

structural, and cultural approaches in comparative politics have converged on the

‘rediscovery’ of institutions. The two halves of the figure converge within the shaded

elliptical area, which represents the study of regimes, including the liberal-republican

perspective. Finally, the human rights regime lies at the centre of the figure as the

important nexus for these theories. From these theories and the figure, it is now

possible develop a preliminary empirical model from which it is possible to derive a

series of hypothesised relationships and testable propositions about the growth and

effectiveness of the international human rights regime.

Page 19: NORMS AND RIGHTS: A NON -RECURSIVE MODEL OF HUMAN …gmandal.weebly.com/uploads/7/7/7/8/7778263/a_non...NORMS AND RIGHTS: A NON -RECURSIVE MODEL OF HUMAN RIGHTS PROTECTION Dr. Todd

17

Figure 1. Human rights as a nexus for theories of international law, international relations, and comparative politics

Part II: Building an Empirical Model

If the norms contained within the international human rights regime are important, as

legal-proceduralists, neo-liberal institutionalists, and liberal-republicans argue, then

there ought to be a positive relationship between the international law of human rights

(rights in principle) and the protection of human rights (rights in practice). Such an

expectation is often supported by Henkin's (1979: 47) claim that ‘it is probably the

case that almost all nations observe almost all principles of international law and

almost all of their obligations almost all of the time (emphasis in the original). In

response to this claim, Chayes and Chayes (1993: 176-177) argue that no such

empirical attempt has been made, that 'it would not be easy to devise a statistical

protocol that would generate such evidence', and that 'general compliance with

international agreements cannot be empirically verified.' In contrast, Koh (1997:

2599-2600) shows that initial empirical work on international trade, international

adjudication, US policy on human rights, and international environmental protection

'seems largely to have confirmed this hedged but optimistic description'. In addition, a

Legal positivismLaw without power

RealismPower without law

Hegemonic stabilityLaw with dominant power (s)

Legal pragmatismLaw as leverage

INTERNATIONAL LAW INTERNATIONAL RELATIONS

Neo-liberal institutionalismLaw and power

Legal proceduralismLaw and power

HUMAN RIGHTS REGIME

COMPARATIVE POLITICS

New institutionalismConstrained rationality

RationalistAgents without structure

StructuralistStructure without agents

Liberal republicanismTwo-level game

CulturalistNorms, ideas, and meaning

ConstructivismNorms, ideas, and meaning

Page 20: NORMS AND RIGHTS: A NON -RECURSIVE MODEL OF HUMAN …gmandal.weebly.com/uploads/7/7/7/8/7778263/a_non...NORMS AND RIGHTS: A NON -RECURSIVE MODEL OF HUMAN RIGHTS PROTECTION Dr. Todd

18

recent study on the IMF demonstrates that countries comply with exchange rate

demands of the regime (Simmons 2000).

Outside these issue areas, two recent studies in the field of human rights test the

relationship between treaty ratification and human rights protection across a variety of

human rights measures and indicators. Keith (1999) examines the relationship

between ratification of the International Covenant on Civil and Political Rights

(ICCPR) and the protection of personal integrity rights, while Hathaway (2002) tests

the relationship between a broader range of treaties and rights protection, including

torture, genocide, and women's rights. Both studies achieve mixed results where

simple bi-variate analysis (correlation and difference in means tests) shows a positive

association between treaty ratification and rights protection, which tends to drop away

in their multivariate analyses. They both use data sets that are pooled over time and

across space, which gives them a large number of observations, but masks the growth

of the regime, its time-dependent effects on rights protection, possible feedback

effects, and the importance of complementary social and political developments.

Replicating these analyses for selected years across the period 1976-2000 shows that

by 1993, ratification of the ICCPR has a positive relationship with the protection of

personal integrity rights, even with the presence of important control variables

(Landman 2001).

These extant studies testing compliance suggest that this is fruitful and necessary area

of research to enrich our understanding of global human rights protection. Indeed, it

seems paramount for political science theories and methods to provide meaningful

explanations as to why countries ratify human rights treaties in the first place and

whether such ratification makes a difference for human rights protection. Drawing on

the achievements of these extant studies and the theories outlined above, it is possible

to construct an empirical model that helps explain both the growth and effectiveness

of the international human rights regime. Figure 2 depicts the simple bi-variate

relationship between treaty ratification and human rights protection.

Figure 2. Simple bi-variate relationship between international human rights law and human rights protectionInternational

human rights lawHuman rights

protection(+)

Page 21: NORMS AND RIGHTS: A NON -RECURSIVE MODEL OF HUMAN …gmandal.weebly.com/uploads/7/7/7/8/7778263/a_non...NORMS AND RIGHTS: A NON -RECURSIVE MODEL OF HUMAN RIGHTS PROTECTION Dr. Todd

19

The figure captures the simple relationship as expected from legal-proceduralism,

noe-institutionalism, and new-institutionalism, but fails to take into account a series of

other important factors. Since norms exhibit trends and human rights protection can

accumulate over time, it is necessary to add three different time-series feedback

processes to the model. First, there are feedback processes between previous

ratifications of human rights treaties and current ratifications, both of which operate

within the same state as well as among states. These are known as ‘social’ or

‘bandwagon’ effects.7 Second, there are feedback processes between previous and

current years of human rights protection, capturing the time-dependent performance

of a country with respect to human rights protection (Poe and Tate 1994; Poe, Tate,

and Keith 1999; Keith 1999). Third, there are feedback processes between human

rights protection and treaty participation itself, such that human rights protection in

one year may have an effect on a country's propensity to ratify in subsequent years

(Hathaway 2002: 2001). This third feedback process thus suggests that ratification

and protection are not necessarily mutually exclusive processes. Figure 3 depicts the

simple relationship with these additional feedback processes, showing that the first

two processes are expected to have positive relationships, while the third process

remains opaque. If a state improves its human rights practices before ratification, the

relationship should be positive, while if it improves its practices after ratification, the

relationship should be negative.

7 In her study of IMF compliance, Simmons (2000: 833) adds a regional norm variable, which captures contiguous participation in IMF article VIII of countries from the same region.

Page 22: NORMS AND RIGHTS: A NON -RECURSIVE MODEL OF HUMAN …gmandal.weebly.com/uploads/7/7/7/8/7778263/a_non...NORMS AND RIGHTS: A NON -RECURSIVE MODEL OF HUMAN RIGHTS PROTECTION Dr. Todd

20

Figure 3. Feedback processes in human rights law and human rights protection

These relationships are complicated further by a series of important additional

independent variables that reflect the issues and concerns outlined in the various

theories in Part I of this paper as well as findings from extant studies in international

relations and comparative politics.8 First, studies within the neo-liberal institutional

and liberal republican traditions have repeatedly shown the benefits of democratic rule

both for the ratification of treaties and the protection of human rights. In testing the

liberal-republican model, Moravcsik (1997; 2000) shows that democratic states have a

greater propensity to ratify the European Convention on Human Rights, a finding that

is upheld at the global level (Landman 2002a). Empirical studies show that

democracies are less likely to violate personal integrity rights (Poe and Tate 1994;

Poe, Tate, and Keith 1999; Keith 1999; Hathaway 2002) and even within the first year

of a democratic transition, such rights violations decrease significantly (Zanger 2000).

Second, extant studies in comparative politics have repeatedly shown the importance

of wealth for the emergence and maintenance of democracy, as well as the protection

of personal integrity rights. From Lipset's (1959) seminal study on the 'economic

correlates of democracy' to Przeworski et al's (2000) cross-national time-series

comparative study, overall levels of wealth are positively related to the level of

democracy (see Landman 2003, Chapter 4). These findings are also upheld by studies

8 Young (1992: 163) notes that in any analysis of regime effectiveness and compliance, ‘multivariate relationships will constitute the norm rather than the exception’.

Internationalhuman rights law

Human rights protection(+)

(+)(+)

(+/-)

Page 23: NORMS AND RIGHTS: A NON -RECURSIVE MODEL OF HUMAN …gmandal.weebly.com/uploads/7/7/7/8/7778263/a_non...NORMS AND RIGHTS: A NON -RECURSIVE MODEL OF HUMAN RIGHTS PROTECTION Dr. Todd

21

on the violation of personal integrity rights (Mitchell and McCormick 1988; Poe and

Tate 1994; Poe, Tate, and Keith 1999; Keith 1999; Zanger 2000; Hathaway 2002).

Fourth, international relations research on the 'Kantian tripod' demonstrates the

overall importance of international interdependence of countries in reducing their

propensity of international conflict (e.g. Russett, O'Neal, and Davis 1998; Russett and

O'Neal 2001). These findings are consistent with the work on the growth of 'world

culture', which maps the global evolution and proliferation of international

governmental (IGOs) and non-governmental organizations (INGOs) (Boli and

Thomas 1999). The degree of 'embeddedness' of countries in global networks of IGOs

and INGOs, it is argued, increases their exposure to value transfers and demonstration

effects that ought to have a positive impact on regime participation and compliance.

Indeed, in The Power of Human Rights, eleven comparative case studies on the

protection of political and civil rights demonstrate that the existence of international

human rights norms coupled with increased activity from domestic and international

NGOs makes a positive contribution to state compliance (Risse, Ropp, and Sikkink

1999). Thus, democracy, wealth, and membership in IGOs and INGOs are seen to be

crucial independent variables that mediate the relationship between norms and rights.

Finally, three further control variables need to be specified for the model. Again, the

extant studies argue that any explanation of personal integrity rights protection must

take into account the degree of a country's involvement in international and national

conflict. One of the key findings of this research, not surprisingly, is that involvement

in civil war poses the largest threat to the protection of personal integrity rights (Poe

and Tate 1994: 866). But involvement in international and domestic conflict may also

have an impact on regime participation. On the one hand, states in conflict may need

external allies and see treaty ratification as an important way in which to garner

support. On the other hand, states in conflict may be so preoccupied with the

immediate nature of the conflict that they simply have no interest in treaty

negotiations. The final two variables control for the size of the population and for the

geographical differentiation across Latin America, Africa, Asia, and the Pacific.

Figure 4 depicts the fully specified model with expected signs for all the relationships,

including those for the feedback loops and control variables. The model clearly shows

Page 24: NORMS AND RIGHTS: A NON -RECURSIVE MODEL OF HUMAN …gmandal.weebly.com/uploads/7/7/7/8/7778263/a_non...NORMS AND RIGHTS: A NON -RECURSIVE MODEL OF HUMAN RIGHTS PROTECTION Dr. Todd

22

that the simple bi-variate relationship between treaty ratification and rights protection

must take into account past state behaviour with respect to treaties and rights, levels of

democracy, wealth, international interdependence, involvement in conflict, size of the

population, and regional differentiation.

Figure 4. The fully specified model for human rights protection

Part III: Estimating the Model

Estimation of this model requires the construction of a global data set with regime

variables, rights variables, and control variables. While the full methodological

discussion and operationalisation of these variables is beyond the scope of this paper,

it is possible to list the ways in which the variables have been created and discuss how

the model can be estimated. The data set that has been constructed is for all the

countries in the world from 1976 to 2000. It has ratification variables for the main

international human rights treaties and the regional systems of Europe, the Americas,

and Africa. Following the UNDP, Keith (1999) and Hathaway (2002), the ratification

variables award a country for signing (coded 1) and ratifying (coded 2) the treaties.

For this paper, only the ratification of the International Covenant on Civil and

Political Rights is used. This choice is based on a similar logic found in The Power of

Internationalhuman rights law

Human rights protection(+)

(+)(+)

Instruments:

(+) Democracy (+)

(+) Wealth (+)

(+) Interdependence (+)

Control variables:

(+/-) Internal/External Conflict (-)

(+) Population (-)

(+/-) Region (+/-)

(+/-)

Page 25: NORMS AND RIGHTS: A NON -RECURSIVE MODEL OF HUMAN …gmandal.weebly.com/uploads/7/7/7/8/7778263/a_non...NORMS AND RIGHTS: A NON -RECURSIVE MODEL OF HUMAN RIGHTS PROTECTION Dr. Todd

23

Human Rights, in which the authors concentrate on that set of rights on which there is

greatest global consensus. The choice also has a methodological basis since there

currently exist several measures of the protection of various types of civil and political

rights. These measures are not without their problems and controversies but as a first

cut, they provide a reasonable baseline for testing the hypothesised relationships

between treaty ratification and rights protection. The human rights variables include

the Freedom House indices for political and civil rights (www.freedomhouse.org), the

five-point scale for personal integrity rights (Poe and Tate 1994), and the five-point

scale for torture (Hathaway 2002). Comparable indicators for the protection of

economic, social, and cultural rights have not yet been made available on a global

basis, but work is progressing on violations approaches to the measurement of such

rights (shr.aaas.org), while others have advocated using aggregate development

indicators as proxy measures for these rights (Green 2001).9

Democracy is measured using the Polity IV combined indicator for democracy, which

subtracts the ten-point autocracy score from the ten-point democracy score (Jaggers

and Gurr 1995). Wealth is measured using per capita gross domestic product.

International interdependence has separate variables for the number of international

governmental organizations (IGOs) and international non-governmental organizations

(INGOs) with registered offices in each country collated by the Union of International

Associations (see also Russett and O’Neal 2001). The international and national

conflict variables are drawn from the ‘correlates of war’ project (see Poe and Tate

1994). Population figures were obtained from the World Bank world development

indicators database. Finally, there are separate dummy variables for Latin America,

Africa, Asia, and the Pacific.

Table 2 is bi-variate correlation matrix of first order relationships between the treaty,

rights, and other variables. Consistent with Keith (1999), the table shows that

ratification of the International Covenant on Civil and Political Rights is significantly

correlated with the greater human rights protection across all the human rights

measures except Hathaway's (2002) measure of torture.10 Ratification of the treaty is

9 In similar fashion to the personal integrity rights measure of human rights, David Cingranelli has coded the US State Department and Amnesty International country reports for certain categories of worker's rights, but the data have not yet been available (see Cingranelli and Tsai 2002).10 The signs are negative since all the measures give higher scores to countries for violating rights.

Page 26: NORMS AND RIGHTS: A NON -RECURSIVE MODEL OF HUMAN …gmandal.weebly.com/uploads/7/7/7/8/7778263/a_non...NORMS AND RIGHTS: A NON -RECURSIVE MODEL OF HUMAN RIGHTS PROTECTION Dr. Todd

24

also significantly correlated with higher levels of democracy and wealth, as well as

larger membership figures for IGOs and NGOs. The table also shows that democracy,

wealth, and IGO and NGO membership are significantly correlated with all five

measures of human rights. These correlations provide preliminary support for the

expectations of the model. But without multivariate and non-recursive estimation of

the model, support remains suggestive at best.

Page 27: NORMS AND RIGHTS: A NON -RECURSIVE MODEL OF HUMAN …gmandal.weebly.com/uploads/7/7/7/8/7778263/a_non...NORMS AND RIGHTS: A NON -RECURSIVE MODEL OF HUMAN RIGHTS PROTECTION Dr. Todd

25

Table 2. Correlation co-efficients for all variables

ICCPR (1966)

ICCPR growtha

Amnesty PIR

State Dept. PIR

Freedom House Civil Rights

Freedom House Political Rights

Torture Scale

Polity IV Dem Score

Per capita GDP 1995 USD WB (logged)

IGO Membership LN INGOS

Civil War (COW)

Internat.War (COW)

LN populat.

ICCPR (1966) - -.08 -.07 -.21 -.22 -.03 .37 .15 .29 .48 -.09 .04 .27Amnesty PIR - .85 .51 .45 .67 -.39 -.44 -.9 -.04* .16 0.00 .36State Department PIR - .57 .51 .71 -.43 -.49 -.18 -.09 .14 -.02 .32Freedom House Civil Rights - .92 .50 -.85 -.62 -.16 -.36 .04* .06 .17Freedom House Political Rights - .42 -.91 -.58 -.14 -.37 .03 .06 .11Torture Scale (Hathaway) - -.34 -.42 -.15 -.15 .13 -.02 .36Polity IV Democracy Score - .54 .24 .60 -.03 -.04* .09Per capita GDP 1995 USD WB (logged) - .30 .53 -.07 .02 -.08IGO Membership (Linear Interpolation) - .51 -.06 .01 .42LN Ingos (Linear Interpolation) - -.05* -.03 .59Civil War (COW) - -.02 .02International War (COW) - .05Natural log of population -Pearson’s correlation co-efficients, all are significant at p < .01; *p < .05; non-significant correlations are in shaded cells.ICCPR growth is a variable that measures the time since ratification of the ICCPR.

Page 28: NORMS AND RIGHTS: A NON -RECURSIVE MODEL OF HUMAN …gmandal.weebly.com/uploads/7/7/7/8/7778263/a_non...NORMS AND RIGHTS: A NON -RECURSIVE MODEL OF HUMAN RIGHTS PROTECTION Dr. Todd

26

It is not surprising that the democracy, wealth, and the interdependence measures

correlate with both treaty ratification and rights protection. The data suggest that there

is perhaps a global 'club' of states and a complementary set of social and political

processes that have are associated both with treaty ratification and rights protection.

Such relationships may be thought of in instrumental terms for estimating the model,

since it appears that both treaty ratification and rights protection are a function of

democracy, wealth, and interdependence. One method of capturing these

complementary developments is to use two-staged least squares regression (2SLS),

which provides a way to resolve systems of two equations. To estimate the full model,

two systems of two equations have been specified. One system is for the norms-rights

relationship (Equations 1.1-1.3) and one is for the rights-norms relationship

(Equations 2.1-2.3), while both systems give special emphasis to the importance of

democracy, wealth, and interdependence.

For the norms-rights relationship, Equation 1.1 shows that human rights protection is

a function of past rights protection, ratification of the ICCPR, civil war, international

war, population size, and regional differentiation. Equation 1.2 shows that ratification

of the ICCPR is a function of democracy, wealth, the two interdependence measures,

and past ratification action (no signature, signature, or ratification). Equation 1.3

resolves the system through substituting Equation 1.2 into Equation 1.1. For the

rights-norms relationship, Equation 2.1 shows that ratification of the ICCPR is a

function of past ratification action (no signature, signature, or ratification), human

rights protection, civil war, international war, population size, and regional

differentiation. Equation 2.2 shows that human rights protection is a function of

democracy, wealth, the two interdependence measures, and past human rights

protection. As in the solution for the norms-rights system of equations, Equation 2.3

resolves the rights-norms system through substituting Equation 2.2 into Equation 2.1.

Page 29: NORMS AND RIGHTS: A NON -RECURSIVE MODEL OF HUMAN …gmandal.weebly.com/uploads/7/7/7/8/7778263/a_non...NORMS AND RIGHTS: A NON -RECURSIVE MODEL OF HUMAN RIGHTS PROTECTION Dr. Todd

27

Norms⇒⇒⇒⇒Rights

[1.1] Rights = Rights at t-1 + ICCPR ratification + Civil War + International War + Population + Regional Dummies + e

[1.2] ICCPR ratification = Democracy + Wealth + IGO membership + NGO membership + ICCPR ratification at t-1 + e

Which is resolved into

[1.3] Rights = Rights at t-1 + (ICCPR ratification = Democracy + Wealth + IGO membership + NGO membership + ICCPR ratification at t-1) + Civil War + International War + Population + Regional Dummies + e

Rights⇒⇒⇒⇒Norms

[2.1] ICCPR ratification = ICCPR ratification at t-1 + Rights + Civil War + International War + Population + Regional Dummies + e

[2.2] Rights = Democracy + Wealth + IGO membership + NGO membership + Rights at t-1

Which is resolved into:

[2.3] ICCPR ratification = ICCPR ratification at t-1 + (Rights = Democracy + Wealth + IGO membership + NGO membership + Rights at t-1) + Civil War + International War + Population + Regional Dummies + e

To estimate parameters for the norms-rights relationship, 2SLS regresses the ICCPR

ratification variable on the independent variables in Equation 1.2 and saves the

regression fit values as a new variable. It then uses this new 'instrumented' form of the

ICCPR ratification in a new regression of rights protection on the independent

variables specified in Equation 1.1. Since the analysis uses a pooled cross-section

time-series data set, the 2SLS parameters were estimated using the xtivreg procedure

in STATA 7.0. The procedure takes into account the panel and time structure of the

data set (i.e. countries and years), while also carrying out the instrumental stage of the

regression common to 2SLS estimation. The final parameter estimates are for

Equation 1.3. The exact same procedure was used to estimate the parameters in

Equation 2.3, while the results for both estimations across the different human rights

measures are shown in Tables 3 and 4.

Tables 3 and 4 report unstandardised co-efficients for the variables with z-scores in

parentheses. Parameter estimates are not reported for those variables used in the first

Page 30: NORMS AND RIGHTS: A NON -RECURSIVE MODEL OF HUMAN …gmandal.weebly.com/uploads/7/7/7/8/7778263/a_non...NORMS AND RIGHTS: A NON -RECURSIVE MODEL OF HUMAN RIGHTS PROTECTION Dr. Todd

28

stage of the 2SLS since they are captured by the 'instrumented' variables denoted in

Equations 1.2 and 2.2. Table 3 shows that ICCPR ratification is significantly related

to lower levels of human rights violation across the Amnesty measure of personal

integrity rights and the two Freedom House measures of civil and political rights, after

controlling for past human rights practices, conflict, population and regional

differences. Civil war and population size are significantly related to higher levels of

human rights violation, while by and large the norms-rights relationship is less strong

in Latin America, Africa, Asia, and the Pacific. Table 4 shows that only the Freedom

House civil and political rights measures are significantly related to ICCPR

ratification, while very few of the other control variables achieve levels of

significance.

Comparing the results from the two tables suggests that the norms- rights relationship

is slightly stronger than the rights-norms relationship; however, there are three

reasons to be cautious. First, the results for the Amnesty measure of personal integrity

rights in Table 3 are significant at a 10% level of confidence, and the same is true for

the Freedom House measure of political rights in Table 4. Second, the Freedom House

measures of civil and political rights also contain institutional elements that make

them correlate with democracy measures. Table 2 shows that both Freedom House

measures are correlated with the Polity IV measure of democracy, while the political

rights measure is highly correlated (r = .85). The 2SLS parameters were thus

estimated with and without the Polity IV measure of democracy in the first stage of

the estimation. Tables 3 and 4 report those estimations without Polity IV. Third, the

2SLS procedure captures a model specification that assumes that the possible mutual

relationship between norms and rights is highly influenced by levels of democracy,

wealth, and interdependence. Thus, the results should not be seen as having

established a firm direct link between norms and rights, even though the norms-rights

direction of the relationship appears stronger.

Page 31: NORMS AND RIGHTS: A NON -RECURSIVE MODEL OF HUMAN …gmandal.weebly.com/uploads/7/7/7/8/7778263/a_non...NORMS AND RIGHTS: A NON -RECURSIVE MODEL OF HUMAN RIGHTS PROTECTION Dr. Todd

29

Table 3. Two Stage Least Squares estimation of human rights protection with instrumental variables (Norms ⇒ Rights)

Dependent Variables (Human Rights measures)IndependentVariablesa

PIR Amnesty

PIR State Department

Freedom House CRb

Freedom House PRb

Torture

Constant -.47**(-2.89)

-.47**(-3.08)

.02(.15)

-.05(-.47)

-.95***(-3.44)

ICCPR Ratification

-.03*(-1.82)

-.02(-1.16)

-.03**(-1.98)

-.03**(-1.98)

-.04(-1.21)

PIR Amnestyt-1 .76***(48.10)

PIR State Departmentt-1

.79***(50.19)

Freedom House CRt-1

.92***(109.07)

Freedom House PRt-1

.92***(109.07)

Torturet-1 .67***(26.16)

Civil War .13**(2.27)

.13*(2.43)

.07*(1.67)

.07*(1.67)

.22**(2.60)

International War .03(.49)

-.03(-.65)

.03(.72)

.03(.72)

.07(.75)

Ln Population .06***(5.35)

.05***(5.22)

.02**(2.45)

.02**(2.45)

.10***(5.63)

Americas .30***(5.90)

.26***(5.56)

.05(1.32)

.05(1.32)

.47***(5.45)

Africa .29***(6.01)

.27***(5.75)

.21***(4.82)

.21***(4.82)

.42***(5.26)

Asia .19***(3.57)

.21***(4.15)

.17***(3.77)

.17***(3.77)

.34***(3.83)

Pacific .11*(1.64)

.10(1.55)

.04(.85)

.04(.85)

.21*(1.97)

N 1651 1651 2003 1998 819R2 .71 .72 .92 .91 .64Wald Chi2 3972.57*** 4228.22*** 22452.94*** 20852.63*** 1437.99***G2SLS random effects regression co-efficients reported with z-scores in parentheses; *p < .10, **p < .05, ***p < .001aInstruments: Democracy (Polity IV), Wealth (Natural log of per capita GDP, IGO Membership, Natural log of NGO membership, ICCPR ratificationt-1 bSince Freedom House and Polity IV are highly correlated (r > .80), Polity IV was dropped as an instrument for CCPR in the equations for Freedom House Civil and Political Rights Measures. Initial parameter estimates using Polity IV were inflated.

Page 32: NORMS AND RIGHTS: A NON -RECURSIVE MODEL OF HUMAN …gmandal.weebly.com/uploads/7/7/7/8/7778263/a_non...NORMS AND RIGHTS: A NON -RECURSIVE MODEL OF HUMAN RIGHTS PROTECTION Dr. Todd

30

Table 4. Two Stage Least Squares estimation of ICCPR ratification with instrumental variables(Rights ⇒ Norms)

ICCPR ratification by different human rights measuresIndependentVariablesa

PIR Amnesty

PIR State Department

Freedom House CRb

Freedom House PR b

Torture

Constant .03(.74)

.04(.39)

.01(.15)

.01(.15)

.11(.72)

ICCPR Ratificationt-1

.91***(90.70)

.91***(90.74)

.91***(95.30)

.91***(96.78)

.91***(62.97)

PIR Amnesty -.01(-1.13)

PIR State Department

-.01(-.87)

Freedom House CR

-.02***(-3.78)

Freedom House PR

-.01*(-2.18)

Torture .003(.15)

Civil War -.02(-.61)

-.02(-.63)

-.01(-.27)

-.01(-.40)

-.03(-.76)

International War .04(1.34)

.04(1.26)

.03(1.20)

.04(1.25)

.05(1.08)

Ln Population .01(1.52)

.01(.16)

.01***(3.08)

.01**(2.64)

.005(.53)

Americas .01(.39)

.01(.24)

.01(.41)

.01(.17)

-.01(-.18)

Africa -.02(-.82)

-.03(-.87)

.04(1.13)

.01(.28)

-.05(-1.12)

Asia -.08**(-2.40)

-.09**(-2.39)

-.04(-1.16)

-.06(-1.89)

-.10**(-2.15)

Pacific -.07(-1.57)

-.07(-1.59)

-.08**(-2.03)

-.08(-2.11)

-.11**(-1.93)

N 1651 1651 2003 1998 819R2 .91 .91 .91 .91 .90Wald Chi2 10169.20*** 9816.00*** 11519.46*** 11778.03*** 4893.19***G2SLS random effects regression co-efficients reported with z-scores in parentheses; *p < .10, **p < .05, ***p < .001aInstruments: Democracy (Polity IV), Wealth (Natural log of per capita GDP, IGO Membership Natural log of NGO membership, ICCPR ratificationt-1 bSince Freedom House and Polity IV are highly correlated (r > .80), Polity IV was dropped as an instrument for both equations using Freedom House Civil and Political Rights Measures as independent variables. Initial parameter estimates using Polity IV were inflated.

Page 33: NORMS AND RIGHTS: A NON -RECURSIVE MODEL OF HUMAN …gmandal.weebly.com/uploads/7/7/7/8/7778263/a_non...NORMS AND RIGHTS: A NON -RECURSIVE MODEL OF HUMAN RIGHTS PROTECTION Dr. Todd

31

Part IV. Conclusions and Implications

This paper has been concerned with the mutual relationship between the norms of

human rights contained within the international human rights regime, country

participation in that regime, and the degree to which such participation makes a

difference for human rights protection. It approached these areas of concern using

empirical theories drawn from international law, international relations, and

comparative politics. It showed that against certain sceptical corners within each of

these three traditions, there has been a convergence of ideas around the notion of

constrained agency at the domestic and international level. Such constrained agency

suggests that norms, ideas, and institutions limit the degree to which individuals and

states can act. This paper is concerned with the norms and institutions relating to

human rights protection. Unlike the norms and institutions that constrain agency for

inter-state relations around issues such as trade, environmental protection, and

finance, human rights seek to constrain the agency of states to violate the rights of

their own citizens. Thus, the international human rights regime is a special type of

regime that uses the mechanism of inter-state relations to govern the capacity of states

to protect individual human dignity, formally codified as a set of rights. Human rights

activists and scholars have long argued that the growth and proliferation of the human

rights regime out to make a difference for the de facto protection of human rights.

Using the notion of constrained agency, the paper specified and estimated a non-

recursive model of the norms-rights relationship that takes into account the

international variables of treaty ratification, membership in IGOs and NGOs, conflict,

and regional location combined with domestic variables of government type, level of

wealth, and population size. The results of analysis suggest that we ought to be

cautiously optimistic about the tangible benefits of the human rights norms

proliferation. On the one hand, the statistical results of the analysis show that the

norms- rights relationship appears stronger than the rights-norms relationship, at least

for the ratification of the ICCPR and the protection of civil and political rights. A

crude reading of these results would suggest that the international law of human rights

matters. On the other hand, the positive statistical results for ratification of the ICCPR

are obtained in the presence of patterns of democratisation, international inter-

dependence, and wealth, while controlling for conflict, regional differentiation, and

Page 34: NORMS AND RIGHTS: A NON -RECURSIVE MODEL OF HUMAN …gmandal.weebly.com/uploads/7/7/7/8/7778263/a_non...NORMS AND RIGHTS: A NON -RECURSIVE MODEL OF HUMAN RIGHTS PROTECTION Dr. Todd

32

population size. Thus, the growth of the international human rights regime and the

protection of human rights themselves complement larger social and political

processes occurring in the world. Wealthy countries that are democratic and

increasingly interdependent are more likely to ratify human rights treaties and more

likely to protect civil and political rights. Such a reading suggests that larger social

and political processes mediate the direct relationship between norms and rights.

Increased levels of democratisation, wealth, and global interdependence in terms of

membership in IGOs and NGOs have produced in some sense a club of nations that

also participates in the international human rights regime. It may well be then that the

international law of human rights merely codifies existing state behaviour, but if the

norms- rights relationship is indeed stronger, then the proliferation of human rights

norms is important in shaping the ways in which new members of that regime behave.

Further research in this area ought to focus on third things. First, it needs to examine

whether the findings obtained here can be extended to other categories of human

rights. It is clear that using development indicators as proxy measures for the

protection of economic and social rights would uncover similar complementary and

inter-related social and political processes, where wealthy, interdependent, and

democratic countries would have a greater propensity to ratify treaties and would have

higher human development scores. Using violations measures for economic, social,

and cultural rights, however, may show a different picture altogether since it is

entirely possible for wealthy democracies to have de facto discrimination in their

health and educational systems. Second, further research should weight the

ratification of international human rights treaties for the presence of reservations to

the treaties. For example, many Middle Eastern and Arab countries have ratified

CEDAW (see Table 1) with so many reservations that the original intent of the treaty

is virtually undermined (see Landman 2004). Third, future research should examine

the activities of domestic and international non-state actors who use the language of

human rights as a powerful discourse to bring about positive change through

lobbying, grass-roots mobilizing, and campaigning within international fora for

human rights protection. While this analysis has been conducted for a handful of

comparative cases (Foweraker and Landman 1997; Risse, Ropp, and Sikkink 1999),

global analysis of non-state actors has not yet been conducted.

Page 35: NORMS AND RIGHTS: A NON -RECURSIVE MODEL OF HUMAN …gmandal.weebly.com/uploads/7/7/7/8/7778263/a_non...NORMS AND RIGHTS: A NON -RECURSIVE MODEL OF HUMAN RIGHTS PROTECTION Dr. Todd

33

References

1. Abbott, K. W., Keohane, R. O., Moravscik, A., Slaughter, A., and Snidal, D. (2000) 'The Concept of Legalization', International Organization, 54 (3): 401-419.

2. Almond, G. and Bingham Powell, G. (1966) Comparative Politics: A Developmental Approach, Boston: Little Brown.

3. Alston, P. and Crawford (eds) (2000) The Future of the UN Human Rights Treaty Monitoring, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

4. Amnesty International (1990) Annual Report 1990, London: Amnesty International, www.amnesty.org.

5. Amnesty International (2002) Annual Report 2002, London: Amnesty International, www.amnesty.org.

6. Apter, D. E. (1996) 'Comparative Politics, Old and New', in R. E. Goodin and H. Klingemann (eds) The New Handbook of Political Science, Oxford: Oxford University Press, 372-397.

7. Austin, J. (1875 [1954]) Lectures on Jurisprudence or the Philosophy of Positive Law, 5th

Edition.

8. Bell, D. (1960) The End of Ideology: On the Exhaustion of Political Ideas in the 1950s, New York: Free Press.

9. Bobbio, N. (1996) The Age of Rights, Cambridge: Polity Press.

10. Boli, J., Loya, T. A., Loftin, T. (1999) 'National Participation in World-Polity Organization', in Boli, J. and Thomas, G. (eds) Constructing World Culture, Stanford: Stanford University Press, 50-80.

11. Boli, J. and Thomas, G. (eds) (1999) Constructing World Culture, Stanford: Stanford University Press.

12. Boucher, D. (1998) Political Theories of International Relations, Oxford: Oxford University Press.

13. Brito, A. B. de (1997) Human Rights and Democratization in Latin America: Uruguay and Chile, Oxford: Oxford University Press.

14. Chayes, A. and Chayes, A. H. (1993) ‘On Compliance’ International Organization, 47 (2): 175-205.

15. Chilcote, R. H. (1994) Theories of Comparative Politics: The Search for a Paradigm Reconsidered, 2nd edn, Boulder, CO: Westview Press.

16. Churchill, R. R. and Young, J. R. (1992) ‘Compliance with Judgements of the European Court of Human Rights and the Decisions of the Committee of Ministers: The Experience of the United Kingdom, 1975-1987’, British Yearbook of International Law, 63: 283-345.

17. Colomer, J. M. (2000) Strategic Transitions: Game Theory and Democratization, Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.

18. Diamond, L. (1999) Developing Democracy: Toward Consolidation, Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.

19. Dogan, M. and Pelassy, D. (1990) How to Compare Nations: Strategies in Comparative Politics, 2nd edn., Chatham, NJ: Chatham House.

Page 36: NORMS AND RIGHTS: A NON -RECURSIVE MODEL OF HUMAN …gmandal.weebly.com/uploads/7/7/7/8/7778263/a_non...NORMS AND RIGHTS: A NON -RECURSIVE MODEL OF HUMAN RIGHTS PROTECTION Dr. Todd

34

20. Donnelly, J. (1986) 'International Human Rights: A Regime Analysis,' International Organisation, 40: 599-642.

21. Donnelly, J. (1989) Universal Human Rights in Theory and Practice, Ithaca and London: Cornell University Press.

22. Donnelly, J. (2000) Realism and International Relations, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

23. Ersson, J. and Lane, E. (1996) ‘Democracy and Development: A Statistical Exploration’ in Leftwich, A. (ed) Democracy and Development: Theory and Practice, Cambridge: Polity Press.

24. Falk, R. (2000) Human Rights Horizons, London: Routledge.

25. Fearon, J. and Wendt, A. (2002) 'Rationalism v. Constructivism: A Skeptical View', in W. Carlsnaes, T. Risse, and B. Simmons, B. (eds) Handbook of International Relations, London: Sage, 52-72.

26. Foweraker, J. and Landman, T. (1997) Citizenship Rights and Social Movements: A Comparative and Statistical Analysis, Oxford: Oxford University Press.

27. Freedom House, www.freedomhouse.org

28. Fukuyama, F. (1992) The End of History and the Last Man, Harmondsworth: Penguin.

29. Green, M. (2001) 'What We Talk about Whne We Talk about Indicators: Current Approaches to Human Rights Measurement', Human Rights Quarterly, 23: 1062-1097.

30. Hathaway, O. (2002) 'Do Treaties Make a Difference? Human Rights Treaties and the Problem of Compliance', Yale Law Journal, 111: 1932-2042.

31. Hay, C. (1995) 'Structure and Agency', in D. Marsh and G. Stoker (eds) Theories and Methods in Political Science, London: Macmillan, 189-206.

32. Hay, C. (2002) Political Analysis, London: Palgrave.

33. Hayner, P. B. (1994) 'Fifteen Truth Commissions- 1974-1994: A Comparative Study, HRQ 16: 597-655.

34. Hayner, P. B. (2002) Unspeakable Truths: Facing the Challenge of Truth Commissions, London: Routledge.

35. Henkin, L. (1979) How Nations Behave: Law and Foreign Policy, New York: Columbia University Press.

36. Higgins, R. (1968) ‘Policy Considerations and the International Judicial Process,’ International and Comparative Law Quarterly, 17.

37. Higgins, R. (1994) Problems and Process: International Law and How We Use It, Oxford: Oxford University Press.

38. Ignatieff, M. (2001) Human Rights as Politics and Idolatry, Princeton: Princeton University Press.

39. Jackson, R. (2000) The Global Covenant: Human Conduct in a World of States, Oxford: Oxford University Press.

40. Jaggers, K. and Gurr, T. R. (1995) 'Tracking Democracy's Third Wave with the Polity III Data', Journal of Peace Research, 32 (4): 469-482.

Page 37: NORMS AND RIGHTS: A NON -RECURSIVE MODEL OF HUMAN …gmandal.weebly.com/uploads/7/7/7/8/7778263/a_non...NORMS AND RIGHTS: A NON -RECURSIVE MODEL OF HUMAN RIGHTS PROTECTION Dr. Todd

35

41. Katznelson, I. (1997) 'Structure and Configuration in Comparative Politics', in M. Lichbach and A. Zuckerman (eds.) Comparative Politics: Rationality, Culture, and Structure, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 81-112.

42. Keck, M. and Sikkink, K. (1998) Activists Beyond Borders: Advocacy Networks in International Politics, Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.

43. Keith, L. C. (1999) 'The United Nations International Covenant on Civil and Political Rights: Does it Make a Difference in Human Rights Behavior?' Journal of Peace Research, 36 (1): 95-118.

44. Kelsen, H. (1961) General Theory of Law and State, translated by A. Wedberg, New York: Russell and Russell.

45. Kennan, G. F. (1951) American Diplomacy, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

46. Keohane, R. (1984) After Hegemony: Cooperation and Discord in World Political Economy, Princeton: Princeton University Press.

47. Keohane, R. O. (2001) 'Governance in a Partially Globalized World', American Political Science Review, 951 (1): 1-13.

48. Keohane, R. O. (2002) Governance in a Partially Globalized World, London: Routledge.

49. King, G., Keohane, R. O., and Verba, S. (1994) Designing Social Inquiry: Scientific Inference in Qualitative Research, Princeton: Princeton University Press.

50. Koh, H. H. (1997) ‘Review Essay: Why Do Nations Obey International Law?’ Yale Law Journal, 106: 2598-2659.

51. Krasner, S. D. (1997) 'Sovereignty, Regimes, and Human Rights', in V. Rittberger, (ed) Regime Theory and International Relations, Oxford: Clarendon Press, 139-167.

52. Krasner, S. D. (1999) Sovereignty: Organized Hypocrisy, Princeton: Princeton University Press.

53. Landman, T. (2000) Issues and Methods in Comparative Politics: An Introduction, London: Routledge.

54. Landman, T. (2001a) 'Measuring the International Human Rights Regime' Paper presented at the 97th Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association, San Francisco.

55. Landman, T. (2001b) 'Measuring Human Rights and the Impact of Human Rights Policy', paper presented at the EU Conference on Human Rights Impact Assessment, Brussels November.

56. Landman, T. (2002a) 'The Evolution of the International Human Rights Regime: Political and Economic Determinants', Paper presented at the 98th Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association, Boston 29 August - 1 September.

57. Landman, T. (2002b) 'Comparative Politics and Human Rights', Human Rights Quarterly, 24 (4): 890-923

58. Landman, T. (2003) Issues and Methods in Comparative Politics: An Introduction, Second Edition, London: Routledge.

59. Landman, T. (2004) Protecting Human Rights: A Global Comparative Study, Washing, DC: Georgetown University Press.

Page 38: NORMS AND RIGHTS: A NON -RECURSIVE MODEL OF HUMAN …gmandal.weebly.com/uploads/7/7/7/8/7778263/a_non...NORMS AND RIGHTS: A NON -RECURSIVE MODEL OF HUMAN RIGHTS PROTECTION Dr. Todd

36

60. Lichbach, M. (1997) 'Social Theory and Comparative Politics', in M. Lichbach and A. Zuckerman (eds), Comparative Politics: Rationality, Culture, and Structure, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 239-276.

61. Lipset, S. M. (1959) ‘Some Social Requisites from Democracy: Economic Development and Political Legitimacy’, The American Political Science Review, 53: 69-105.

62. Macridis, R. C. and Brown, B. E. (eds) (1986) Comparative Politics, 6th edn, Chicago: Dorsey Press.

63. Mair, P. (1996) 'Comparative Politics: An Overview', in R. E. Goodin and H. Klingemann (eds) (1996) The New Handbook of Political Science, Oxford: Oxford University Press, 309-335.

64. March, J. G. and Olsen, J.P. (1984) 'The New Institutionalism: Organizational Factors in Political Life', American Political Science Review, 78: 734-749.

65. March, J. G. and Olsen, J.P. (1998) 'The Institutional Dynamics of International Political Orders', International Organization, 52 (4): 943-969.

66. Mitchell, N. J. and McCormick, J. M. (1988) 'Economic and Political Explanations of Human Rights Violations, World Politics, 40: 476-498.

67. Moravcsik, A. (1997) 'Taking Preferences Seriously: A Liberal Theory of International Politics', International Organization, 51(4): 513-553.

68. Moravcsik, A. (2000) 'The Origins of Human Rights Regimes: Democratic Delegation in Postwar Europe', International Organization, 54 (Spring): 217-52.

69. Morgenthau, H. J. (1961) Politics among Nations: The Struggle for Power and Peace, 3rd

edition, New York: Alfred A Knopf.

70. Munck, G. (2001) ‘Game Theory and Comparative Politics’, World Politics, 53 (January): 173-204.

71. Pennings, P., Keman, H., and Kleinnijenhuis, J. (1999) Doing Research in Political Science: An Introduction to Comparative Methods and Statistics, London: Sage.

72. Peters, Guy (1998) Comparative Politics: Theory and Methods, New York: New York University Press.

73. Philips, A. (1997) ‘Preface’ in Minority Rights Group, World Directory of Minorities, London: Minority Rights Group International, pp. viii-xiii.

74. Poe, S. and Tate, C.N (1994) 'Repression of Human Rights to Personal Integrity in the 1980s: A Global Analysis, American Political Science Review, 88: 853-872.

75. Poe, S. C., Tate, C. N., and Keith, L. C. (1999) 'Repression of the Human Right to Personal Integrity Revisited: A Global Cross-National Study Covering the Years 1976-1993', International Studies Quarterly, 43: 291-313.

76. Przeworski, A. (1985) ‘Marxism and Rational Choice’, Politics and Society, 14 (4): 379-409.

77. Przeworski, A. (1991) Democracy and the Market, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

78. Przeworski, A. and Teune, H. (1970) The Logic of Comparative Social Inquiry, New York: Wiley.

Page 39: NORMS AND RIGHTS: A NON -RECURSIVE MODEL OF HUMAN …gmandal.weebly.com/uploads/7/7/7/8/7778263/a_non...NORMS AND RIGHTS: A NON -RECURSIVE MODEL OF HUMAN RIGHTS PROTECTION Dr. Todd

37

79. Przeworski, A., Alvarez, M. E., Cheibub, J. A., and Limongi, F. (2000) Democracy and Development: Political Institutions and Well-Being in the World, 1950-1990, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

80. Putnam, R. (1993) ‘Diplomacy and Domestic Politics: the Logic of Two-Level Games,’ in P. B. Evans, H. K. Jacobson, and R. D. Putnam (eds) Double-Edged Diplomacy: International Bargaining and Domestic Politics, Los Angeles: University of California Press, 431-468.

81. Raustalia, K. and Slaughter, A. (2002) 'International Law, International Relations and Compliance', in W. Carlsnaes, T. Risse, and B. Simmons, B. (eds) Handbook of International Relations, London: Sage, 538-558.

82. Ragin, C. (1987) The Comparative Method: Moving beyond Qualitative and Quantitative Strategies, Berkeley: University of California Press.

83. Ragin, C. (2000) Fuzzy Set Social Science, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

84. Reiff, D. (1999) ‘The Precarious Triumph of Human Rights’, New York Times Magazine, 8 August, 36-41.

85. Risse, T., Ropp, S. C., and Sikkink, K. (1999) The Power of Human Rights: International Norms and Domestic Change, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

86. Rittberger, V. (1997) Regime Theory and International Relations, Oxford: Clarendon Press.

87. Robertson, A. H. and Merrills, J. G. (1996) Human Rights in The World: An Introduction to the Study of the International Protection of Human Rights, Fourth Edition, Manchester: University of Manchester Press.

88. Roniger, L. and Sznajder, M. (1999) The Legacy of Human Rights Violations in the Southern Cone: Argentina, Chile, and Uruguay, Oxford: Oxford University Press.

89. Russett, B. Oneal, J. R., and Davis, D. R. (1998) 'The Third Leg of the Kantian Tripod90. for Peace: International Organizations and Militarized Disputes, 1950–85', International

Organization, 52 (3): 441-67.

91. Russett, B. and O'Neal, J. (2001) Triangulating Peace: Democracy, Interdependence and International Organizations, New York: W. W. Norton.

92. Rustow, D. A. and Erickson, K. P. (1991) (eds) Comparative Political Dynamics: Global Research Perspectives, New York: Harper Collins.

93. Schmidt, B. C. (2002) 'On the History and Historiography of International Relations', in W. Carlsnaes, T. Risse, and B. Simmons, B. (eds) Handbook of International Relations, London: Sage, 3-22.

94. Schmitz, H. P. and Sikkink, K. (2002) 'International Human Rights', in W. Carlsnaes, T. Risse, and B. Simmons, B. (eds) Handbook of International Relations, London: Sage, 517-537.

95. Simmons, B. (2000) 'International Law and State Behaviour: Commitment and Compliance in International Monetary Affairs', American Political Science Review, 94 (4): 819-836.

96. Slaughter Burley, A. (1993) ‘International Law and International Relations Theory: A Dual Agenda’, American Journal of International Law, 87 (2): 205-239.

97. Steinmo, S., Thelen, K., and Longstreth, F. (eds) (1992) Structuring Politics: Historical Institutionalism in Comparative Analysis, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

98. Stone Sweet, A. (1999) 'Judicialization and the Construction of Governance', Comparative Political Studies, 32 (2): 147-84.

Page 40: NORMS AND RIGHTS: A NON -RECURSIVE MODEL OF HUMAN …gmandal.weebly.com/uploads/7/7/7/8/7778263/a_non...NORMS AND RIGHTS: A NON -RECURSIVE MODEL OF HUMAN RIGHTS PROTECTION Dr. Todd

38

99. Vincent R.J. (1986) Human Rights and International Relations, Cambridge: CambridgeUniversity Press.

100.Waltz, K. N. (1979) Theory of International Politics, New York: Random House.

101.Welch, C. E. Jr. (2001) NGOs and Human Rights: Promise and Performance, Philadelphia: University of Pennsylvania Press.

102.Wendt, A. (1999) Social Theory of International Politics, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

103.Young, O. R. (1980) 'International Regimes: Problems of Concept Formation', World Politics, 32 (3): 331-356.

104.Young, O. R. (1992) ‘The Effectiveness of International Institutions: Hard Cases and Critical Variables’, in J. N. Rosenau and E. Czempiel (eds) Governance without Government: Order and Change in World Politics, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 160-194.

105.Young, O. R. (1999) Governance in World Affairs, Ithaca: Cornell University Press.

106.Zacher, M. W. (1992) ‘The Decaying Pillars of the Westphalian Temple: Implications for International Order and Governance’, in J. N. Rosenau and E. Czempiel (eds) Governance without Government: Order and Change in World Politics, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 58-101.

107.Zanger, S. C. (2000) 'A Global Analysis of the Effect of Regime Changes on Life Integrity Violations, 1977-1993', Journal of Peace Research, 33.

108.Zürn, M. (2002) 'From Interdependence to Globalization', in W. Carlsnaes, T. Risse, and B. Simmons, B. (eds) Handbook of International Relations, London: Sage, 235-25.