money demand in the us a quantitative review.docx

Upload: manuel-mercy-garcia

Post on 19-Oct-2015

131 views

Category:

Documents


1 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 5/28/2018 Money Demand in the US A quantitative review.docx

    1/3

    Carnegie-Roch ester Conf erence Series on Pub lic Polic y 29 (1988) 137-168

    North-Holland

    MONEY DEMAND IN THE UNITED STATES: A QUANTITATIVE REVIEW

    ROBERT E. LUCAS, JR.1

    The University of Chicago

    I. INTRODUCTION

    Allan Meltzer's research career has been so productive and so varied that it

    would be an act of folly, not friendship, to attempt to review it in a single paper. Yet

    I do want to talk about his research on this occasion, for research is what Allan's

    career is mainly about, and I want to do so in detail, because details are the way

    scholarship is carried out. Accordingly, I will focus my attention mainly on a singlepaper, one that has influenced my own thinking on monetary economics a great

    deal, Meltzer's "The Demand for Money: The Evidence from Time Series," published

    in the Journal of Political Economy in 1963.

    Meltzer's "Demand for Money" was one in a series of his empirical studies in

    monetary economics, much of which involved joint research with Karl Brunner. It

    followed earlier work by Latane and others, especially Friedman, and helped to

    stimulate closely related later contributions by Laidler and others.* The shared

    objective of this research program was, in Friedman's (1956) terms, to demonstrate

    that the demand for money is a "highly stable function" of a limited number of

    variables, to discover the most useful, operational measures of money and these

    other variables, and (again citing Friedman) to work "toward isolating the numerical

    'constants' of monetary behavior." Meltzer's paper was the first to estimate an

    income

    1This paper was prepared for the Novembert 1987 Carnegie-Rochester Conference. I would like to

    thank John Cochrane, Thomas Cooley, Milton Friedman, Lars Peter Hansen, Robert King, Leonardo

    Leiderman, Bennett McCallum, Sherwin Rosen, Thomas Sargent and Lawrence Summers for helpful

    discussions and/or comments on an earlier draft. I also benefitted from a stimulating discussion at the

    Conference. P.S. Eswar-Prasad provided excellent research assistance.

    'Two important sequels to this paper are Brunner and M^lfzer (1963) and Laidler (1966). Of course,

    this and other work on money demand wss closely related to rther contemporary research, especially

    the ear l ier contr ibut ions of Fr iedman (1956) a n d h i s s t u d e n t s , , a n d Friedman (1959). See Laidler

    (1977)and,more recently, McCallum and Goocf r i end (1987) for some of the relevant background.

    0 167 - 2231/88/S3.50 1988 Elsevier Science Publishers B.V. (North-Holland)

  • 5/28/2018 Money Demand in the US A quantitative review.docx

    2/3

    138

    (or wealth) elasticity and an interest elasticity simultaneously from time series data

    from a single country (the U.S.). The objective of the present paper will be to review

    and replicate these results, to reconsider how they might be interpreted

    theoretically, and to see how well they stand up to the 25 years of new data that

    have become available since Meltzer wrote.

    An estimated money demand function provides answers to two important

    questions of economic policy. The income elasticity, in a setting in which long run

    real output growth is both fairly predictable and insensitive to changes in monetary

    policy, provides the answer to the question: What rate of growth of money is

    consistent with long run price stability? The interest elasticity is the key parameter

    needed to answer the question: What are the welfare costs to society of deviations

    from long run price stability? Purely qualitative answers to these questions, along

    the lines of "Inflation rates are significantly related to money growth rates" or

    "Inflation reduces welfare" are interesting and useful, perhaps, but surelypropositions such as "An HI growth rate of 3 percent per year will bring about price

    stability" or "A ten percent annual inflation rate has a social cost equivalent to a 0.5

    percent decline in real income" are more interesting and, if accurate, much more

    useful.

    Though the objective of an economics that provides quantitative answers to

    important questions of economic policy is now very widely subscribed to, it is

    remarkable how little attention is paid in many of our discussions to the substance

    of parameter estimation, and how little honor is paid to those few economists who

    do it well. All of us have sat through many discussions of econometric work in

    which the theoretical underpinnings of the relationships estimated and tested and

    the econometric methods used are subjected to intense scrutiny and yet no one

    seems to care what the numerical results were! Even in Laidler's (1977) survey of

    the evidence on money demand, or in McCallum and Gcodfriend's (1987) more

    recent summary, it is difficult to find clear statements of what the money demand

    function is. As quantitative economists we often seem to be, in Samuel son's (1947)

    phrase, "like highly trained athletes who never run a race, and in consequence

    grow stale."

    Meltzer ran this particular race, in 1963, and turned in his two numbers. Much

    has happened since to monetary theory and to the development of econometric

    methods, and almost three decades of new data have since become available. In

    Section II I will sunmarize the evidence on the income (or wealth) and interest

    elasticities of money demand from 1900-58 data, essentially identical to those

    Meltzer used. Section III introduces a

  • 5/28/2018 Money Demand in the US A quantitative review.docx

    3/3

    139

    utility-theoretic framework for thinking about money demand, from which I will

    conclude that there is some reason to view these two parameters as structural.

    Section IV reviews U.S. time series evidence from the 1958-85 period, a period

    during which nominal interest rates reached levels about twice the highest levels

    attained in the U.S. in the earlier years of the century. Remarkably, in view of the

    stringent nature of the experiment, these new data precisely confirm the estimates

    Meltzer obtained in 1963.

    I I . R E V I E W O F T H E E V I D E N C E F R O M 1 9 0 0 - 1 9 5 8

    The hypothetical household decision problem underlying the results reported

    in Meltzer (1963) is that of allocating a given stock of wealth across different assets,

    given a vector of asset returns. I will come back to this problem in more detail in

    Section III, but I have said enough to rationalize a demand function for money of the

    form

    = f(r,w) .

    Throughout his paper, Meltzer used the log-linear form:

    in(mt) = a - b?n(rt) + can(wt) + ut, (1)

    where m^. is the stock of real balances at t, w tis real wealth or real income, rtan

    interest rate, utis an error term, and a, b and c are parameters. Meltzer used a long

    term interest rate to measure rt, treated as a stand-in for the entire vector of returns

    on alternative assets. He experimented with a very wide variety of income and

    wealth variables as measures of real wealth, and with both Ml and M2 as measures

    of the money stock. The sample period was 1900-1958, with results also reported

    for the two subperiods 1900-1929 and 1930-1958.

    lne experimental approach Meltzer used for measuring money and wealth is

    obviously suitable: we do not have theories that single out particular measures asclearly superior to others. One could indeed criticize the paper for reporting too few

    results, since the single interest rate he used to represent asset returns was

    arbitrarily chosen. But much of this experimentation indicated that the choice of

    wealth and money aggregates was not critically important. This finding has been

    confirmed by much subsequent research, as described in Laidler (1977). I will

    therefore report and

  • 5/28/2018 Money Demand in the US A quantitative review.docx

    4/3

    140

    replicate only a small subset of the results reported by Meltzer (1963).

    Table 1 transcribes results in Meltzer (1963). Line 1 is equation (3) on p. 225,

    with R1reported instead of R and "standard errors" instead of "t-statistics."^ Lines

    2,3,5,6,7 and 8 are from Table 2, p. 232. Line 4 is from Table 1, p. 229. Of course, al l

    regressions reported in this and al 1 other tables in this paper were estimated with

    constant terms. Since the units of the dependent variable I used are not

    meaningful, I wi 11 not report these constants.

    The central findings in lines 1-3 of Table 1 (these and all subsequent

    references are to tables in this paper), confirmed by other results in the original

    paper, are the wealth or income elasticities of about unity and the strong, negative

    effect of interest rates on real balances demanded. Notice that neither finding

    shows up very clearly when the period is divided in two, as reported in lines 4-8 of

    Table 1. For the early period, the income and wealth elasticities diverge, in different

    directions, from unity and the interest elasticities are much reduced. Meltzer doesnot report the results with wealth only for 1930-1958. From what is reported,

    however, it appears that the results for the full period were mainly dictated by

    events in the latter half.)

    Table 2 contains my replications of the results in Table 1. I dropped

    1

    The residuals from my replications of Meltzer's equations show very severe autocorrelation, and it is

    clear from the Durbin-Watson statistics reported in Meltzer (1964) t viat this is also true of his original

    regressions. As a result, I do not know how to interpret the "standard errors" reported in these tables. I

    experimented with a variety of methods for correcting for serial correlation, but obtained only wildly erratic

    elasticity estimates.

    ^For money, I used Ml throughout the paper. For 1900-14, this series is taken from Historical

    Statistics (1960), series X267. From 1914-47, it is from Friedman and Schwartz (1970), pp. 704-718, column

    7. For 1948-85, it is the "IMF series 3" from the International Monetary Fund's "International Financial

    Statistics" tape. (The primary source for these IMF data is the Federal Reserve Bulletin.)

    For 1900-49, real wealth is from Goldsmith (1956), Table W-3, column 1 ("total national wealth at 1929

    prices"). For 1950-57, this series is from Historical Statistics (1960), series F446.

    For 1884-1975, real income is real net national product from Friedman and Schwartz (1982), Table 4.8.

    For 1976-85, it is taken from various July issues of the Survey of Current Business. The price level (used to

    deflate Ml) is the implicit NNP deflator from the same sources. Permanent income is the geometrically

    weighted sum of current and past real NNP's used in Friedman (1957). The weight on current income is .33.

    The long term interest rate (used only for 1900-57) is the "basic yield on 20 year corporate bonds" in

    Historical Statistics (1960), series X346. The short term rate for 190075 .s the "6 month commercial paper"

    rate from Friedman and Schwartz (1982), Table 4.8, column 6. For 1976-85 I used Table B-68 in the Economic

    Report of Jhe President (1987).

  • 5/28/2018 Money Demand in the US A quantitative review.docx

    5/3

    TABLE 1

    141

    Meltzer (1963) Results Dependent variable: n(Mj/P)

    Coeff icients on:(standard errors)

    regressions track this well (of course, with the interest rate also included as a

    regressor). Real balances did not decrease nearly as much as did NNP in the 1930s,

    but they increased much more than income in the 1940s. I conclude (though this is

    the sort of issue reasonable people can disagree on) that current income induces

    "too much" cyclical responsiveness in predicted money demand, relative to wealth,

    and that wealth or some other "smoothed" income measure is preferred as the

    regressor. This is also the conclusion reached by Laidler (1977).In Table 3, I report the consequences of some variations on Meltzer's results.

    The objective of this experimentation is to locate a version of Meltzer's model that

    is reasonably faithful, conceptually and quantitatively, to the original and is at the

    same time inexpensive to test on more recent data.1

    Line 1 in Table 3 uses permanent income (defined by Friedman's distributed

    lag on current and past real NNP's) in place of wealth. This change does an

    excellent job of reproducing line 1 of either Table 1 or 2. From a comparison of

    Figure 1 with Figure 2, one can see that permanent income behaves more like

    wealth than like current NNP in the 1930s.

    Lines 2 and 3 report two variations on line 1. In line 2, the long interest rate

    used by Meltzer is replaced by a short rate. I will explain my strong preference for

    the latter in Section III. The short rate (over this period) varies sympathetically with

    the long, but with more amplitude: hence its smaller coefficient. Otherwise, this

    variation doesn't matter much. In line 3, I use an unlogged short rate. The issue

    1The variations reported in Table 3 are very close to results in Laidler (1966). Laidle r used U.S. annual

    series from 1892-1960, and deflated real balances and permanent income population. In his counterpart to

    line 1 of Table 3 (his Table 2, A, p.548) he obtained permanent income and interest elasticities respectively

    of 1.51 and .25. His counterpart of my line 2 (also Table 2, A in his paper) are 1.39 and .16. He did not try

    unlogged interest rates .

    Line ___________ Years ___________ ftn(r ) ___________ &n(W/P) __________ &n(Y/P)_____________ __ R*1 1900-58 -.949 1.11 .984

    (.044) (.026)

    2 1900-58 -.79 1.05 .960

    (.083) (.041)

    3 1900-58 -.92 .97 .13 .980

    (.053) (.103) (.093)

    4 1900-29 -.32 1.84 .960

    (.107) (.114)

    5 1900-29 -.05 .70 .960

    (.094) (.45)

    5 1900-29 -.22 .48 .3) .960

    (.122) (.240) (.194)

    7 1930-58 -.69 .94 .902

    (.160) (.094)

    8 1930-58 -1.15 1.35 -.10 .980

    (.097) (.155) (.125)

  • 5/28/2018 Money Demand in the US A quantitative review.docx

    6/3

    142

    between the different functional forms in lines 2 and 3 is mainly aesthetic: the semi-

    elasticity at the sample mean value of r (3.26 for 1900-57) is, from the estimate of

    the elasticity in line 2, (-18)/(3.26) = .055. From line 3, this same semi-elasticity is

    estimated at .07. (In this, as in all other economic applications with which I am

    familiar, the choice of functional form is of little substantive consequence.) Thus I

    will take Table 3 as justifying my referring to the model reported in line 3 as

    "Meltzer's theory".

  • 5/28/2018 Money Demand in the US A quantitative review.docx

    7/3

    TABLE 1

    143

    Let me conclude this section with a somewhat less formal summary of the

    information on income and interest elasticities contained in this 190057 sample.

    Over this period, real Ml balances grew at the annual rate of .03356 and real

    permanent income at the rate .03126. Short term ir erest rates fluctuated between

    .69 (during World War II) and 7.4 (in 1920) but with a negligible trend. Hence the

    ratio of the money growth rate to the income growth rate, 1.07, is a good estimate

    of the income elasticity. This is about the number obtained, under various

    assumptions, in Table 3. Over long periods, it must always be the case that the

    trend in the dependent variable must be "explained" by that subset of the

    regressors that have trends. In this application, real income does and interest rates

    do not.Now imposing an income elasticity of unity, the semi-elasticity of money

    demand with respect to the interest rate is just the slope of a plot of ln(Ml/Pyp)

    against r$. This plot is displayed in Figure 3. This "estimation method" - get the

    income elasticity from money and income trends and then get the interest elasticity

    from a two-variable regression

    Rjplicat ions Dependent variable: ln(Mj/P)Line Years !n (r) Coeff icients on:

    (standard errors)

    tn(W/P)

    in(Y/P) R

    1 1900-57 -1 .v 1.32 .957

    ( . 0 1) (.056)

    2 1900-57 6 7 1.04 .971

    (.077) (.036)

    3 1900-57 .90 .49 .68 .978

    (.089) (.122) (.095)

    4 1900 29 -.21 .86 .957

    (.099) ( . 0 5 1 )

    5 1900-29 -.07 .73 .932

    (.119) (.057)

    6 1900-29 -.20 .65 .19 .960

    (.098) (.149) (.132)

    7 1930-57 -1.72 1.53 .901

    (.139) (.163)

    8 1930 57 -.55 .93 .937

    (.141) (.075)

    9 1930-57 -.78 .34 .75 .939

    .264 .332 .191

  • 5/28/2018 Money Demand in the US A quantitative review.docx

    8/35

    900

    144

    (Q4>3*

    >T30>

    cCD

    To3->

    U

  • 5/28/2018 Money Demand in the US A quantitative review.docx

    9/3

    145

    Predicted Ml/P using current income (line 2, Table 1).

    ,Predicted Ml/P using wealth (line 1, Table 1).

  • 5/28/2018 Money Demand in the US A quantitative review.docx

    10/

    146

    Actual Ml/P

    Predicted Ml/P using current income (line 2, Table 1).

    Predicted Ml/P using permanent income (line 1, Table 3).

    Figure 2

    Year

  • 5/28/2018 Money Demand in the US A quantitative review.docx

    11/

    TABLE 1

    147

    ftn(r) n(rs)Line

    rs

    n(yp)

    .9891.03

    (.021

    )

    -.77

    (.044)

    96 61.07

    (.039

    )

    2 -.18

    (.025)

    96 31.06

    (.042

    )

    3 -.07

    ( . 0 1 1

    )

    Variations on Table 2 for 1900-1957

    Dependent variable: ftn(M1/P)

    Coefficients on: (standard errors)

    - does not depend very critically on our ability to characterize the residuals

    accurately, or even on the residuals having a common structure over the entire

    period. Since we have much more reason, to which I will turn in the next section,

    for believing these elasticities to be stable than we have reason to believe anything

    in particular about the residuals, this seems to me a desirable feature.^

    Of course, no estimation method is satisfactory under all assumptions about

    the errors, and the critical assumption here is that the errors are trend-free. If there

    were important technical changes, not occurring in response to interest rate

    movements, permitting agents to economize on their use of Ml balances my

    method (and Meltzer's too) has understated the income elasticity. I do not see how

    one can learn snore about this possibility by examining the series at hand.

    'These informal remarks are not intended as a substitute for econometric theory. One would

    certainIy have a better understanding of the estimates reported here and below if one could write down a

    be I ievable stochastic model and use it to derive the proper t i es of these estimates explicitly. But I have

    not done this and so am obIiged to follow a second best route and explain why I proceeded as I did in alooser (and hence less informative) way.

  • 5/28/2018 Money Demand in the US A quantitative review.docx

    12/

    148

    Short-terrr Interest Rate

    Figure 3 : 1900-57

    2 3 4 5 6

  • 5/28/2018 Money Demand in the US A quantitative review.docx

    13/

    149

    I I I . A T H E O R E T I C A L F R A M E W OR K

    As an aid in interpreting the results reported in the last section and the

    additional results to be reported in Section IV, I will introduce a simple theoretical

    framework based on the model analyzed in Lucas and Stokey (1987). The

    framework has the advantage (relative to the framework Meltzer used) of being

    explicit about the connection between the portfolio and transactions demands for

    money, and the disadvantage of being unrealistically stylized about the way trading

    occurs. It will take some care to exploit the explicitness of this model without being

    led too far astray by its unrealistic features.

    We consider an economy in which the representative agent has the ultimate

    objective of maximizing the discounted expected utility from consumption of

    goods,

    3t E{z8U(c.)} .

    t=0 z

    This agent lives in a Markovian world, the state of which at t is summarized by a

    vector s^.. The distribution ofSj.+j, given s^., is given by a fixed transition function

    F(s,A) = Pr{sule A|s = s) .

    In this setting, all equilibrium date-t prices and quantities will be fixed (no time

    subscript) functions of the current state, s^.Agents are assumed to alternate between securities trading and goods

    trading in lockstep fashion. At the beginning of each period, all agents trade in

    securities, including money, in a single centralized market, all with full knowledge

    of the current realization of st. When securities trading is concluded, all agents

    disperse either to produce or to purchase consumption goods. Some of these

    goods can only be purchased with money acquired during the course of securities

    trading: This transactions requirement is the sole reason for including cash in a

    portfolio, in preference to interest bearing claims to future cash.

    Consider first the decision problem facing an agent who is engaged in

    securities trading at a time in which the state of the economy is s and his personal

    wealth in dollar terms is W. (In a centralized securities market all assets are priced,

    so the single number W summarizes his asset position fully.) Let v(s,W) denote the

    value of this agent's expected,

  • 5/28/2018 Money Demand in the US A quantitative review.docx

    14/

    150

    discounted utility if he proceeds optimally from this point on.

    At this point, the agent is faced by a vector Q(s) of securities prices (in

    dollars, so the price of money is unity). He must choose money holdings M and a

    vector of securities holdings z, subject to a portfolio constraint:

    N + Q(s) z < W . (2)

    Let G(M,z,s) be the indirect utility function he uses to make this choice. (Clearly G

    will depend on s, since the current state variable includes all the information he has

    about the returns from these securities.) Then v(s,W) must satisfy:

    v(s,W) = max G(M,z,s) subject to (2). (3)M,z

    I call (3) the agent's portfolio problem.

    Now where does this indirect utility function G come from? Having completed

    securities trading, the agent is about to engage in purchasing a vector c of

    consumption goods. He will also receive an endowment y(s) of goods, but this he

    must sell for cash or future cash: He cannot consume his own endowment. The

    rules of trading in this goods market are summarized by a vector of constants a,

    where a^ e [0,11 is the fraction of purchases of good i that must be covered by

    money. It will be an expositional simplification in what follows to postulate a

    technology together with a choice of units for measuring goods such that all goods

    sell for the same nominal price P(s). In this case, the agent's Clower- or cash-in-

    advance constraint is:

    P(s)a c < M . (4)

    The outcome (M,z) of the portfolio decision plus the outcome (c,y(s)) of his

    goods trades plus a given vector D(s') of nominal returns (dividends, interest,

    principal) on securities will determine this agent's nominal wealth position W as of

    tomorrow, conditional on tomorrow's state s'. He begins next period with his dollar

    holdings as of today, M, plus the dividends and resale value of his securities,

    (Q(s')+D(s'))"z, plus the dollar value of his endowment, P(s)S y (s), less the dollar

    value of his goods purchases, P(s)S c . That is:

  • 5/28/2018 Money Demand in the US A quantitative review.docx

    15/

    151

    W = H + [Q(s')+D(s')lz + p(s)fIyi(s)-C|I

    These considerations determine what I call the transactions problem:

    G(M,z,s) = max U(c) + 3/ v(s',W)F(s,ds') subject to (4) , (6)c

    where W is defined in (5).

    Eliminating the function G between (3) and (6) defines a functional equation

    in the value function v. See Lucas and Stokey (1987) for an analysis of this

    equation and its use in constructing an equilibrium for this economy. My purpose

    here is not so much analysis as it is clarifying what we mean by a "demand

    function for money," and hence in understanding what an empirical money

    demand function might mean. Let me begin with what I think Meltzer (1963) and

    certainly Hamburger (1977) meant by a "demand function for money."From the portfolio problem (3) one obtains the first order conditions:

    G(yj(M,z,s) = v , (7)

    G (M,z,s) = (hv , j = l,...,m , (8)J J

    where \> is the multiplier associated with the wealth constraint (?) and where j

    indexes the m available securities. These m+1 equations together with (2) can be

    solved to obtain the demand functions for the assets (M,z) which have as

    arguments the prices Q and wealth W. Singling out the demand function (in this

    sense) for money:

    M = f(Q,W,s) . (9)

    Note that the entire vector Q of securities prices enters on the right of (9). In

    practice, as in any empirical application of demand theory, one would focus on theprices of securities thought to have strong substitution or complementary

    relationships with money. In this spirit, Meltzer used a long term bond yield in his

    econometric work. In the same spirit, Hamburger (1977) experimented with equities

    yields and other securities returns in his.Certainly (9) is a respectable bas i s for an empirical study,

    (5)

  • 5/28/2018 Money Demand in the US A quantitative review.docx

    16/

    152

    consistent with what we knew then about monetary theory and, I would say,consistent with what we know now. Yet it does not seem to me that one would haveany confidence that the demand function (9), based on portfolio considerations onlyas in my derivation, would remain stable over time. Included as suppressedarguments in this functions f are all variables s characterizing the current state ofthe system, including all the information used by agents in forecasting futurereturns on all securities. Moreover, if the stochastic environment in which agentsoperate (the "regime," as it is often called) should change from time to time, these

    changes too will induce shifts in f. Surely shifts in the realizations of informationalvariables and/or in the processes assumed to generate these realizations must havebeen substantial over so long a period as 1900-1958.

    To decide whether the fact that the functions f are not likely to be structural is

    an important objection to the empirical application of (9), consider the fact that by

    exactly the above argument on money demand, we could derive a demand function

    of the same form as (9) for any portfolio item. Would one, for example, attempt to

    estimate a demand function for Brazilian government securities, including as

    arguments only their own current yield and another interest rate standing in for the

    composite security consisting of all other portfolio items, and expect thisrelationship to be stable over a 60 year period? I think there is more to Meltzer's

    money demand theory than portfolio considerations alone.

    To see what this is, turn to the transactions problem (6), which also defines

    the indirect utility function G. The first order conditions for the n consumption

    goods in this problem are:

    Mc)= B fvw(s',W')P(s)F(s,ds') + yP(s)ai, i=l,...,n, (10)

    where y is the multiplier associated with the cash-in-advance constraint (4). One

    can also calculate the derivatives of the function G from (6):

    G|y|(M,z,s) = u + 0/ vw(s',W')F(s,ds') , (11)

    Gz.(M,z,s) =B fvw(s',W')[Qj(s')+Oj(s')]F(s,ds'), j=l,...,m. (12)

    That is, the value (in utiIs) of a dollar is its "liquidity" value y during

    goods trading plus the marginal valueof nominal wealth one period hence. The value

    of any other security is the v/alue of the increment it provides

  • 5/28/2018 Money Demand in the US A quantitative review.docx

    17/

    153

    to future wealth. Equations (11) and (12) thus reduce the values of securities,

    money included, to the values of their associated "fundamentals."

    Now suppose that among the m available securities is a (nominal) risk free,

    dollar denominated, one period bond. For this security,Qj(s') = 0

    and Dj(s') = 1. Let its current price be i+r(s) , so r(s) is the one

    period nominal interest rate. Then combining (7) and (8) from the portfolio problem

    and (11) and (12) from the transactions problem (where both (8) and (12) are

    specialized to this one period bond) and inserting into the first order

    conditions (10) we obtain:

    Uj(c) - P(s)ulai+ ^ry| , i =

    That is to say, the relative "prices" of these consumption goods, as seen by

    consumers (normalized so that the prices of each received by sellers are all equalto P(s)) depend on the cash holdings required to purchase them together with the

    opportunity cost of holding cash, as measured by the nominal interest rate.

    In the environment I have been describing, in which no new information

    reaches agents after they have switched from securities trading to goods trading,

    agents will plan money holdings so that the cash-in-advance constraint (4) holds

    with equality: In the theory, as in fact, cash is dominated by nominal bonds as a

    store of value. In this case (13) and (4) (with equality) form a system of n+1

    equations in the consumption vector c and the multiplier p. It is not quite a demand

    system (since the "prices" in (13) are not the same as the "r.rices" in (4)) but it can

    be

    treated just as if it were and solved fp Vn consumption vector c as a

    . ' 'function of iVP(s) and r(s), say: ^

    C = g ( p . r ) .

    Thus we obtain, from transactions considerations, ar exact relationshipbetween agents' desired consumption mix, their demand for real balances, and the

    nominal interest rate. Noticc that no other securities prices or returns enter into

    this relationship, nor does the state s

    (13)

    (14)

  • 5/28/2018 Money Demand in the US A quantitative review.docx

    18/3

    154

    (except through the two prices P(s) and r(s)).^ Changes in information or in the

    information structure of the system will not shift these curves. They will be stable

    over time provided only that preferences are and that the trading technology as

    sunmarized in the coefficients a^,...,anis stable.

    It seems to me a violation of common usage to call the relationship (14) a

    "demand function for money." It is a relationship among complementary choice

    variables that the demand functions must satisfy. Whatever one calls it, however, it

    is a relationship that must obtain in equilibrium and it seems more likely to be an

    empirically stable one than does the "true" demand function (9). Why not provide

    an operational specification of these coefficients a^ and try to estimate it

    econometrically? This is the approach taken in a recent paper by Mankiw and

    Sumners (1986), with very interesting results that I wil 1 come back to in the next

    section, first, however, it will be useful to go into more detail about the connections

    between (9) and (14).Meltzer's estimated income and wealth elasticities are around unity,

    suggesting (under the utility-theoretic framework I am using here) that the current

    period utility function U takes the form of a constant relative risk aversion function

    of a homogeneous of degree one function of consumption. Let us impose this on

    the model above. Then equations (13) can be solved for the ratios c^/c of

    consumption of each good to total consumption c = c^ = g^(r)c , say.

    Substituting into the cash constraint gives:

    = Eiaigi(r) c = h(r)c , (15)

    where the second equality defines the function h. This is just a consolidated

    special case of (14), stil1 not a demand function for money. Under these same

    assumptions, the "true" demand function for total

    ^Th i s rationale for (14) is essen t i a I I y the same as that used for a simila! purpose by McCallum

    and Goodfriend (1987). See Ando, Modigliani and Shell (1975) for the earliest derivation of (14) along these

    lines that I have found. These writers draw the same conclusion I have in the text: that on Iy the short rate

    ought to appear on the right side of a money demand function. Hamburger (1977) views (14) as a

    "Keynesian" formulation, explicitly contrasting it to the "monetarist" emphasis on portfolio considerations.

    If he is right, then my use of (14) to derive Mel^er's equat ion (18) is a very "un-monetar i si" argument. But

    one of the purposes of this sect ion is exactly to argue that port folio and transactions considerations are

    complementary in thinking about money demand.

  • 5/28/2018 Money Demand in the US A quantitative review.docx

    19/

    (16)

    155

    consumption c takes the form:

    c - k(Q,s) .

    Then combining (15) and (16), we have shown that, under this homotheticity

    assumption, the true demand function for money (9) takes the form:

    p = h(r)k(Q,s) p .

    Now there is no theoretical reason to expect (17) to be more stable

    empirically than (9): They are the same relationship! But empirically, total

    consumption has been found to be a fairly stable function of permanent income,

    suggesting that k(Q,s)/r is nearly constant over a wide range of circumstances. If

    so, then:

    F *(r>*p

    where

  • 5/28/2018 Money Demand in the US A quantitative review.docx

    20/

    156

    characterization of transactions demand that leads to a relationship between real

    balances, short term interest rates and permanent income or wealth that one might

    want to view as structural. This characterization was made tractable by the

    assumption that everyone engages in securities trade at the same time, all with the

    same fixed period. That this assumption is unrealistic is obvious. That it is

    unrealistic in a way that is critical to the theory of money demand was shown by

    Grossman and Weiss (1983) and Rotemberg (1984), who examined theoretical

    settings in which only a subset of agents is engaged in securities trading at any

    time. This modification alters the way the system responds to open market

    operations, because when the central bank issues money for bonds, interest rates

    must move so that the subset of private agents on the other side of this exchange

    is willing to acquire a disproportionate share of the economy's new money supply.

    This alteration introduces a Keynesian "liquidity preference" element into money

    demand that is entirely absent from the formulation I have sketched. Cochrane(1988) appears to have identified these liquidity effects, for periods up to a year, in

    post-1979 U.S. weekly series on Treasury bill rates and money growth rates. (I say

    "appears" because the connections between theoretical models of the Grossman-

    Weiss-Rotemberg type and the estimation methods used by Cochrane have not

    been worked out in any detail.)

    By using annual data, it seemed possible that Meltzer's results and mine

    might avoid contamination from these "liquidity preference" effects. We will see in

    the next section, however, that this hope is not confirmed, at least for post-1958

    data. The trick will thus be to get as much as we can out of a money demand theory

    that is not adequate to account for some short run events.

    I V . H O N E Y D E M A N D S I N C E 1 9 5 8

    Econometric research on money demand has undergone considerable

    development since the early 1960s. In the main, this work (with the notable excption

    of Friedman and Schwartz's (1963) and (1982) studies of long U.S. and U.K. timeseries) has focused on evidence from postwar U.S. quarterly series. Meltzer's work

    is not cited in Judd and Scadding's (1982) review article (though they do make

    repeated use of Laidler (1977), which was in turn heavily influenced by Meltzer's

    work) and, in general, the research cited in this survey is not much concerned with

    comparison of postwar evidence with evidence from the earlier years of the

    century.

  • 5/28/2018 Money Demand in the US A quantitative review.docx

    21/

    157

    The pioneering paper in this "modern" era of money demand studies is

    Goldfeld (1973), which introduced distributed lag methods that seem to be needed

    to obtain close fits to quarterly data. Subsequent work has, in large part, been

    devoted to the refinement of Goldfeld's studies and to dealing with the fact

    (stressed most forcefully by Goldfeld (1976)) that his equations deteriorated in fit

    on data outside the original sample period.

    There is no doubt that recent work is based on a much more sophisticated

    awareness of econometric issues specific to time series analysis than was the

    research of the 1950s and 60s. At the same time, the substantive results have been

    disappointing. Judd and Scadding refer to "the observed instability in the demand

    for money after 1973," and endorse the conclusion reached earlier by Cooley and

    LeRoy (1981) "that the negative interest elasticity of money demand reported in the

    literature represents prior beliefs much more than sample information." The unit

    income (or wealth) elasticity is no longer regarded as wel1-established, and mostrecent work has focused on find i "scale variables" that sharpen short-term

    forecast errors rather than on estimates of the income elasticity that stand up well

    over different data sets. In short, one gains the impression that subsequent

    research has generally failed to support Meltzer's findings, that the income and

    interest elasticities he estimated are inconsistent with more recent evidence and

    were even, perhaps, as much the product of his "prior" as they were inferences

    drawn from the time series he studied.

    I think al 1 of these conclusions, or impressions, are incorrect. In this section

    I will argue that Meltzer's 1963 results are not only qualitatively but quantitatively

    consistent with observations since 1958: that even if one takes the income and

    interest elasticities estimated, by his methods, from pre-1958 data alone one

    obtains a more useful account of money demand in the 25 year period sinee than is

    obtained from more recent distributed lag formulations. Moreover, I will exhibit the

    information on the interest elasticity of money demand contained in 1900-1985 data

    in such a way as to concentrate even Cooley and LeRoy4s posterior distribution on

    Meltzer's 1963 co .usion.

    At the sair.. time, this application of Meltzer's equation to more recent data

    will also reveal repeated, systematic patterns in the residuals. These are patterns

    that are not consistent with the theoretical model reviewed in Section II (and hence

    not consistent with Meltzer's theory as I have interpreted it). I think it will be easy to

    see why these patterns motivated Goldfeld and others to resort to distributed lag

    methods. But I

    4 1900-85 -.07 .97 .967

    (.044) (.019)

  • 5/28/2018 Money Demand in the US A quantitative review.docx

    22/

    158

    will argue that these methods have served to obscure rather than reveal both the

    sense in which this theory helps to understand recent events and the sense in

    which it falls short.

    Table 4 provides results for the entire 1900-85 period and for the recent

    subperiod 1958-85. Line 1 is exactly the same regression as line 3, Table 3 for the

    full period. Line 3 of Table 4 is the same regression for the period 1958-85 only. One

    can see that simply adding the later years to the full sample results in virtually no

    change in the estimated elasticities. However, the results for the later years taken

    by themselves show a drastic deterioration in fit and large changes in estimated

    coefficients as compared to the 1900-57 period. In lines 2 and 4 of Table 4, the

    income elasticity is constrained to be unity (so no "standard error" is reported).

    Line2is, not surprisingly, the same as line 1, but so too is line 4.

    Examining trends over the later period (as I did in Section II for the earlier

    years) helps in interpreting Table 4. In the27 year period 195885, real money

    balances grew at an annual rate of .004 while real income grew at a rate of .03.

    Short term interest rates increased (though not at all smoothly) from around 3

    percent to around 9 percent, or at a rate of about.22percentage points per year. To

    fit these trends, the interest semi-elasticity nrand the income elasticity have to

    lie on the

    line: nr= -.02 + (.14)ny With an income elasticity of unity, this implies an interest

    semi-elasticity of .12. This pair of estimates is roughly

    TABLE 4

    Results from 1900-85 Dependent variable: n(Ml/P)

    Coeff icients on:(standard errors)

    2

    Line Years r^ R consistentwith the estimates 1.06 and .07 reported in line 3 of Table

    3. It is also consistent with the estimates .97 and .07 in line 1 of Table4, and with the constrained estimates in lines 2 and 4 of Table 4. Similarly, the

    unconstrained estimates .21 and -.01 on line 3 of Table 4 lie roughly on this line.

    One can account for the divergent trends in income and real balances over the

    1953-85 period either with the 1900-57 estimated income and interest elasticities or

    with much lower income and interesto

    elasticities.

    Figure 4 illustrates, in part, why I prefer tu?. constrained estimates reported

    on lines 2 and 4 of Table 4 to the unconstrained estimates on line 3. This figure

  • 5/28/2018 Money Demand in the US A quantitative review.docx

    23/

    159

    plots the log of P/Pyp against the short term interest rate for the entire 1900-85

    period, with the post 1957 observations indicated by different symbols from the

    1900-57 observations. One can see that if one constrains the income elasticity for

    the entire period to be unity, one gets in return a single interest semi-elasticity for

    the entire period. The most recent points lie exactly or the line defined by the

    earlier ones and, since interest rates behaved so differently in the recent period,

    the estimate is greatly sharpened by the new observations.

    Let me try to summarize the sense in which Figure 4 confirms both Meltzer1s

    hypothesis that real money demand is a stable function of permanent income (or

    wealth) and interest rates and the numerical estimates h? obtained. Meltzer

    estimated these two parameters by least squares. As Figure 2 shows, the estimated

    income elasticity is mainly dictated by the common trend of real balances and

    income. At this estimated value of unity, Figure 3 shows that the interest elasticity

    is determined by a reasonably tight scatter of an(Ml/Pyp) against rs. If one imposesthe same income elasticity of unity on the 1953-85 period, this same scatter.,

    reproduced as Figure 4, confirms the original interest elasticity estimates and since

    interest rates were so much higher in the later period, the new experiment is a very

    good one. Notice that there is nothing arbitrary or experimental about Figure 4: It is

    precisely the scatter one would want to look at in view of the estimates Meltzer

    obtained using pre-1958 data only.

    However, as 1ine 3 of Table 4 shows, these two elasticity estimates cannot be

    recovered from the 1958-85 data using least squares (as Meltzer

  • 5/28/2018 Money Demand in the US A quantitative review.docx

    24/

    Figure 4 :1900-65

    160

    6

    J * 5| " .

    5 - denotes observations from 1900 to 1957. 0 - denotes

    observations from 1958 to 1985.

    1.8

    1.6

  • 5/28/2018 Money Demand in the US A quantitative review.docx

    25/

    161

    1612 144 6 8 10

    Short-Term Interest Rate

    m_ e * t 4 .

    f o f l o * n r> * C

    0.8

    0.6

    1.4

    1.2

  • 5/28/2018 Money Demand in the US A quantitative review.docx

    26/

    162

    recovered them from the earlier data). There is a reason why these estimates came

    out as they did, as Figure 5 shows. Interest rates were not only increasing

    dramatically over the 1958-85 period but were also highly erratic. The relatively high

    interest semi-elasticity on line 3 reconciles the trends with a high income elasticity,

    but the cost of this reconciliation is that the "predicted" path of real balances from

    the constrained estimates is much too interest-sensitive to fit observed, year-to-year

    movements. Actual real balances move in the predicted direction in response to

    interest rate changes, but by much less than is predicted. These lead to large

    residuals, which are also strongly correlated with interest rates. This is why the

    order revealed in Figure 4 cannot be discovered using unconstrained least squares.

    Mankiw and Summers (1986) recover exactly an income elasticity of unity and

    an interest semi-elasticity of .05 from least squares applied to 1960-84 U.S. quarterly

    series. They do so using consumption in place of permanent income (justified in part

    by the kind of argument I used in Section III) and by using Almon lags to average the

    independent variables over time. One can conjecture from Figure 5 that averaging

    interest rates will "work," and Mankiw and Summers1s results confirm this. (I

    suspect that long interest rates worked as well as they did in Meltzer's study for

    much the same reason: Long rates are a kind of average of short rates.)

    V. CONCLUSIONS

    This paper has had three main objectives. As reported in Section II, I first

    replicated some of the results in Meltzer (1963), using his 1900-1957 sample period,

    and showed that two variations of interest to me are empirically indistinguishab1e

    from the model he used. Second, in Section III, I reviewed a theoretical model of

    money demand in which the two parameters Meltzer estimated could be expected to

    be "structural." Thirc?, in Section IV, I compared the predictions of Meltzer's model,

    with his original parameter estimates, to post-1958 data, and concluded that this

    comparison yields additional confirmation of the theory and of these two estimates.

    Meltzer (1963) was criticized (for example, by Courchene and Shapiro (1964))

    for, among other things, his failure to correct his estimates for severely serially

    correlated residuals and his failure, despite great emphasis on the "stability" of the

    money demand function, to apply standard statistical tests for the stability of

    parameter estimates across different

  • 5/28/2018 Money Demand in the US A quantitative review.docx

    27/

    163

    Actual Ml/P.

    Predicted Ml/P from line 4, Table 4.

    Figure 5

    Year

  • 5/28/2018 Money Demand in the US A quantitative review.docx

    28/3

    164

    sample periods. These two criticisms can certainly be applied as well to the present

    paper, for I share Meltzer's emphasis on the "stability" of the money demand

    function.

    But I agree with Meltzer (1964) that these econometric criticisms are very badly

    off the economic point. We begin with a simple economic model that suggests a two-

    parameter description of money demand. When we hypothesize that this relationship

    is "stable," we mean that we expect these two parameters to reflect relatively stable

    features of consumer preferences and the way in which business is carried out, and

    we expect them not to shift around as monetary or other policies are altered over

    time. This theory does not suggest that the residuals can be characterized in a

    simple, elegant fashion over a given time period, or even that the stochastic structure

    of the residuals should be stable over time. Accordingly, there is little point in testing

    the theory by maintaining an extreme hypothesis on the residuals that is not implied

    by any theoretical considerations and then performing a Chi-square test for the

    equality of coefficients over subperiods. One needs a maintained hypothesis in

    which one has more, not less, confidence than one has in the hypothesis being

    tested.

    Thus Meltzer argued, and I agree, that we can only test the theory by comparing

    its numerical predictions to as wide a variety of data as we can find. In carrying out

    such tests, it is of no interest whatever to let the two crucial elasticities isolated by

    the theory change arbitrarily from one data set to the next. The theory is of no

    interest or use unless these two parameters are stable under a wide range of

    circumstances.

    Over the time period Meltzer studied, in which income has a strong trend and

    interest rates had none, the method of least squares isolates an income elasticity of

    unity, just as does a comparison of income and real balance trends. With this income

    elasticity, one can see from Figure 3 that there is enough interest variability to trace

    out a fairly clear demand curve. Over the more recent period, interest rates have a

    very strong upward trend, as does income, so that there are many combinations of

    elasticities that are consistent with trends in the holding of real balances. Least

    squares picks out a combination of elasticities that is very different from the pair thatis consistent with earlier evidence. Yet imposing the same elasticities in the later

    period is also consistent with long term trends and, as Figure 4 shows, traces out a

    demand function that is consistent with theearlierdata, and much clearer than was

    possible

  • 5/28/2018 Money Demand in the US A quantitative review.docx

    29/

    165

    with those data alone.^ This picture did not arise by chance!

    The evidence from the post-1960 years also reveals strong patterns in the

    residuals from this estimated demand function that did not appear in the earlier

    years of the century. It is clear that, as investigators sinee Goldfeld have

    concluded, the portfolio adjustment process is subject to lags in a way that neither

    the theory Meltzer had in mind nor the cash-in- advance model I sketched in

    Section III helps to understand. This fact is hardly surprising: One is, if anything,

    surprised that this simple model captures as much as it does.

    In these circumstances, it seems to me that it is the econometrician1s job to

    display as clearly as he can the respects in which the model he has is a good

    approximation to reality and the sense in which it is not. This is what Meltzer did in

    his 1963 paper, and it is what I have tried to do in this one. I hope Figure 4

    convinces anyone who sees it that the interest semi-elasticity of money demand

    has remained stable at something between .05 and .10 for nearly a century in the

    U.S. I hope Figure 5 helps to stimulate someone, perhaps along the lines suggested

    by Grossman, Weiss and Rotemberg, to discover the short run dynamics that can

    reconcile this fact with year-to-year or even quarter-to-quarter movements in

    observed money holdings.

    ^An income elasticity of unity is a I so consi stent wi th the cross-section evidence reported in Meltzer

    (1963b). The interest semi-eIast i c i t i es est imated from U.S. t i me series are a I so consistent wi th the

    range ot estimates Cagan (1956) found in his study of hyper i nfI at ions.

  • 5/28/2018 Money Demand in the US A quantitative review.docx

    30/

    166

    REFERENCES

    Ando, A., Modigliani, F., and Shell, K.

    1975 Some Reflections on Describing Structures of Financial Sectors, in Gary

    Froran and Lawrence R. Klein, (eds.)Brookings Model Perspective and

    Recent Developments .Amsterdam: North- Holland, 524-563.

    Stunner, K. and Meltzer, A.H.

    1963 Predicting Velocity: Implications for Theory and Policy. Journal of

    Finance, 18: 319-354.

    Cagan, P.

    1956 The Monetary Dynamics of Hyperinflation, in Milton Friedman, (ed.),

    Studies in the Quantity Theory of Money. Chicago: University of Chicago

    Press.

    Cochrane, J.H.

    1988 The Return of the Liquidity Effect: A Study of the Short Run Relation

    Between Money Growth and Interest Rates.Journal of Business and

    Economic Statist ics. Forthcoming.

    Cooley, T.F. and LeRoy, S.F.

    1981 Identification and Estimation of Money Demand. Amer ican Economic

    Review, 71: 825-844.

    Courchene, T.J. and Shapiro, H.T.

    1964 The Demand for Money: A Notes from the Time Series.Journal of

    Pol i t ical Econom y, 72: 498-503.

    Economic Repor t of the President

    1987 Washington D.C.

    Friedman, M.

    1956 The Quantity Theory of Money - A Restatement," in Milton Friedman,

    (ed.),Studies in th e Quantity Theor)> of Money. Chicago: University of

    Chicago Press.

  • 5/28/2018 Money Demand in the US A quantitative review.docx

    31/

    167

    A Theory of the Consumpt ionrunct ion.Princeton: Princeton University

    Press, for the National Bureau of Economic Research.

    1959 The Demand for Money - Some Theoretical and Empirical Results.Journal r f

    Pol i t ica l Econom y,67: 327-351.

    ________ and Schwartz, A.J.

    1963A Monetary History of the United States, 1867-1960.Princeton:

    Princeton University Press, for the National Bureau of Economic

    Research.

    ________ and _________

    (1970)Monetary Stat ist ics of th e United States.New York: Columbia University Press

    for the National Bureau of Economic Research.

    ________ and _________

    1982Monetary Trends in the United States and the United Kingdom.

    Chicago: University of Chicago Press, for the National Bureau of

    Economic Research.

    Goldfeld, S.M.

    1973 The Demand for Money Revisited.Brookings Papers on Economic A ct iv i ty

    , 577-638.

    1976 The Case of the Missing Money."Brookings Papers on Economic Act iv i ty, 683-

    730.

    Goldsmith, R.W., et al.

    1956A Study of Saving in th e United States,Vol. III. Princeton: Princeton University

    Press, for the National Bureau of Economic Research.

    Friedman, H.

    1957

  • 5/28/2018 Money Demand in the US A quantitative review.docx

    32/

    168

    Grossman, S. and Weiss, L.

    1983 A Transactions-Based Model of the Monetary Transmission Mechanism."

    Amer ican Economic Review, 73: 871-880.

    Hamburger, M.J.

    1977 Behavior of the Money Stock: Is There a Puzzle?Journal of MonetaryEconomics, 3: 265-288.

    Judd, J.P. and Scadding, J.L.

    1982 The Search for a Stable Money Demand Function.Journal of Economic

    Literature, 20: 993-1023.

    Laidler, D.E.W.

    1966 The Rate of Interest and the Demand for Money - Some Empirical

    Evidence.Journal of Pol i t ica l Economy,74: 545-555.

    1977The Demand for Mo ney: Theoret ical and Empir ical Evidenc e. Second Edition. New

    York: Dun-Donneley.

    Lucas, R.E., Jr. and Stokey, N.L.

    1987 Money and Interest in a Cash-in-Advance Economy. Econometr ica, 55: 491-

    514.

    Mankiw, N.G. and Summers, L.H.

    1986 "Money Demand and the Effects of Fiscal Policies.Journal of Money,

    Credit , and Bankin g, 18: 415-429.

    McCallum, B.T. and Goodfriend, M.S.

    1987 Money: Theoretical Analysis of the Demand for Money." Paper

    prepared for The New Palgrave: A Dict ionary of Economic Theory and

    Doctr ine.

    Meltzer, A.H.

    1963 The Demand for Money: The Evidence from the Time Series. Journal of

    Pol i t ical Econom y, 71: 219-246.

  • 5/28/2018 Money Demand in the US A quantitative review.docx

    33/

    169

    Meltzer, A.H.

    1963b The Demand for Money: A Cross-Section Study of Business Firms.

    Quarter ly Jo urnal of Econom ics,77: 405-422.

    1954 A Little More Evidence from the Time Series.Journal of Pol i t ica l Economy,72:

    504-508.

    Poole, W.

    1970 Whither Money Demand?Brookings Papers on Economic A ct iv i ty , 485-501.

    Rotemberg, J.J.

    1984 A Monetary Equilibrium Model with Transactions Costs.Journal of Polit ical

    Economy,92: 40-58.

    Samuel son, P.A.

    (1947)Foundat ions of Econom ic Analysis.Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    U.S. Bureau of the Census.

    1960Histor ical Stat ist ics of the United States, Colonial Times to 1957. Washington D.C.

    1958 from the sample because I could not find w for that year. Otherwise, I attempted

    to follow the sources and procedures described in Meltzer (1963). One can see that

    lines 1 and 2 from Tables 1 and 2 are very close, though closer for the income

    regression than the wealth regression. When both variables are included (line 3) I

    obtained very different results from his, for reasons I cannot explain. Notice,

    however, that Meltzer*s and my estimates of the sum of these coefficients are very

    close: I suspect this is all either of us is estimating with much precision. The other

    striking difference is in line 4 of Tables 1 and 2: my wealth elasticity for this

    subperiod is well below one; Meltzer's is 1.8.

    I wanted to use a graphical device to help me see how different a theory one

    obtains with different wealth or income measures. I know this question is not very

    well posed, but Figure 1 seems to me helpful. It exhibits three series, all for the fullperiod 1900-1957. They are: actual Ml/P; the "predicted" Ml/P from line 1 of Table 2;

    and the predicted Ml/P from line 2 of Table 2. One can see that real balances followed

    a different trend from 1930 on than in the earlier years. Both the income and wealth

  • 5/28/2018 Money Demand in the US A quantitative review.docx

    34/

    170

    2 190C-85 -.09 1.0 ~

    (.001) -------------------

    3 1958-85 -.01 .21 .328

    (.005) (.059)

    4 1958-85 -.07 1.0 ---

    (.008)

  • 5/28/2018 Money Demand in the US A quantitative review.docx

    35/

    171

    Q

    Poole (1570) argued much earlier that cnc- needs to constrain the income elasticity in ot der to obtain an

    interest elasticity from post-World War II data that is consistent vith pre-war evidence.