mobilising investment ee final

Upload: peter-christensen

Post on 03-Apr-2018

216 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 7/28/2019 Mobilising Investment EE FINAL

    1/156

    The views expressed in this IEA Insights paper do not necessarily reflect the views or policy of the International Energy Agency (IEA)

    Secretariat or of its individual member countries. This paper is a work in progress and/or is produced in parallel with or

    contributing to other IEA work or formal publication; comments are welcome, directed to email [email protected].

    OECD/IEA,2012

    OECD

    IEA

    2012

    Mobilisinginvestment

    inenergyefficiency

    Economicinstruments

    forlowenergybuildings

    AnuschkaHilke

    LisaRyan

  • 7/28/2019 Mobilising Investment EE FINAL

    2/156

    INTERNATIONAL ENERGY AGENCY

    The International Energy Agency (IEA), an autonomous agency, was established in November 1974.Its primary mandate was and is two-fold: to promote energy security amongst its membercountries through collective response to physical disruptions in oil supply, and provide authoritative

    research and analysis on ways to ensure reliable, affordable and clean energy for its 28 membercountries and beyond. The IEA carries out a comprehensive programme of energy co-operation amongits member countries, each o which is obliged to hold oil stocks equivalent to 90 days o its net imports.The Agencys aims include the following objectives:

    n Secure member countries access to reliable and ample supplies o all orms o energy; in particular,through maintaining eective emergency response capabilities in case o oil supply disruptions.

    n Promote sustainable energy policies that spur economic growth and environmental protectionin a global context particularly in terms o reducing greenhouse-gas emissions that contributeto climate change.

    n Improve transparency of international markets through collection and analysis ofenergy data.

    n Support global collaboration on energy technology to secure uture energy supplies

    and mitigate their environmental impact, including through improved energyefciency and development and deployment o low-carbon technologies.

    n Find solutions to global energy challenges through engagement anddialogue with non-member countries, industry, international

    organisations and other stakeholders.IEA member countries:

    Australia

    Austria

    Belgium

    Canada

    Czech Republic

    Denmark

    Finland

    France

    Germany

    Greece

    Hungary

    Ireland

    Italy

    Japan

    Korea (Republic of)

    Luxembourg

    NetherlandsNew Zealand

    Norway

    Poland

    Portugal

    Slovak Republic

    Spain

    Sweden

    Switzerland

    Turkey

    United Kingdom

    United States

    The European Commission

    also participates in

    the work of the IEA.

    OECD/IEA, 2012

    International Energy Agency9 rue de la Fdration

    75739 Paris Cedex 15, France

    www.iea.org

    Please note that this publicationis subject to specic restrictionsthat limit its use and distribution.

    The terms and conditions are available online athttp://www.iea.org/termsandconditionsuseandcopyright/

  • 7/28/2019 Mobilising Investment EE FINAL

    3/156

    OECD/IEA2012 MobilisinginvestmentinenergyefficiencyEconomicinstrumentsforlowenergybuildings

    Page|1

    TableofContents

    Acknowledgements..........................................................................................................................5

    ExecutiveSummary..........................................................................................................................7

    Economicinstrumentsinenergyefficiencypolicy....................................................................8

    Economicinstrumentsforlowenergybuildings.......................................................................8

    Fundingeconomicinstruments...............................................................................................11

    Futureconsiderations..............................................................................................................11

    Introduction....................................................................................................................................13

    Reportscopeandstructure.....................................................................................................13

    Methodologicalissues.............................................................................................................14

    PARTI:Economicinstrumentsinenergyefficiencypolicy...........................................................15

    Energytaxes

    and

    price

    subsidies

    .............................................................................................

    17

    Taxrelief..................................................................................................................................18

    Grants......................................................................................................................................19

    Loanprogrammes....................................................................................................................20

    Guarantees..............................................................................................................................21

    Otherstructuredfinance.........................................................................................................22

    Whitecertificatesandobligationschemes.............................................................................23

    Carbonmarkets.......................................................................................................................24

    Publicprocurementandinfrastructureinvestment................................................................24

    Energyefficiency

    R&D

    support

    ................................................................................................

    25

    PARTII:Economicinstrumentstomobiliseinvestmentinenergyefficiencyinbuildings..........26

    II.1Introductiontothebuildingssectorandenergyefficiencypolicy....................................26

    Energyefficiencyandbuildings.......................................................................................26

    Theroleofgovernmentstoreduceenergyconsumptioninbuildings...........................28

    II.2Economicinstrumentsandlowenergybuildings.............................................................32

    Energytaxesandpricesubsidies.....................................................................................33

    Taxrelief..........................................................................................................................35

    Grants...............................................................................................................................37

    Loanprogrammes

    ............................................................................................................

    40

    Guarantees.......................................................................................................................43

    Otherstructuredfinance.................................................................................................45

    Whitecertificatemarketsandobligationschemes.........................................................53

    Carbonmarkets................................................................................................................56

    Publicprocurementandinfrastructureinvestment........................................................59

    R&Dsupportforenergyefficiency..................................................................................61

    II.3Discussionofcurrentuseofeconomicinstrumentsforlowenergybuildings.................63

    II.4Movingtowardsdeepretrofithowcaneconomicinstrumentshelp?...........................64

    II.5Selection

    and

    design

    of

    economic

    instruments

    for

    low

    energy

    buildings

    ........................

    66

  • 7/28/2019 Mobilising Investment EE FINAL

    4/156

    Mobilisinginvestmentinenergyefficiency OECD/IEA2012Economicinstrumentsforlowenergybuildings

    Page|2

    II.6Returnonpublicinvestmentinlowenergybuildings.......................................................69

    PARTIII:Fundingeconomicinstruments.......................................................................................73

    III.1Sourcesoffunding............................................................................................................73

    Generalbudgetallocationsandearmarkedtaxrevenuesandcharges..........................74

    Emissionallowanceauctioning........................................................................................77

    Institutionalinvestingandprivateinvestmentfunds......................................................80

    III.2Intermediariesandgreenbonds......................................................................................82

    Energyefficiencyagencies...............................................................................................82

    Dedicatedfundsforenergyefficiency.............................................................................83

    Publicbanks.....................................................................................................................85

    Greenbonds.....................................................................................................................88

    III.3Discussionoffundingforlowenergybuildings...............................................................90

    Conclusions.....................................................................................................................................94

    Annexselectedcasestudies........................................................................................................96

    Canada:ecoENERGYRetrofit HomesProgram......................................................................97

    France:EcoPTZgreenloanandtaxincentives.....................................................................103

    Germany:KfWloansandgrantsforenergyefficiencyinresidentialbuildings....................114

    Italy:taxincentivesandwhitecertificates............................................................................126

    Ireland:HomeEnergySavingSchemegrants........................................................................136

    Acronyms,abbreviationsandunitsofmeasure..........................................................................142

    References....................................................................................................................................144

    Listof

    Figures

    Figure1Overviewofeconomicinstruments...............................................................................16Figure2RD&DnationalpublicspendingforEEinbuildings,appliancesandequipment...........62Figure3Developmentofeconomicinstrumentsovertime........................................................67Figure4Designoptionsforgovernmentinvolvementinloansforlowenergybuildings...........68Figure5Multiplebenefitsoflowenergybuildings.....................................................................70Figure6Volumeofgrantsandloans20012009.......................................................................118Figure7Numberofgrantsandloans20052010......................................................................118Figure8Reductionsinfinalenergydemand20052010...........................................................120Figure9AvoidedCO2equivalentemissionscumulated20052010..........................................121Figure10Employmenteffects20052010.................................................................................123Figure11Percentageeffectivenessofenergyefficiencymeasures..........................................134

    ListofTables

    Table1IEAmembercountrieswithhighesttaxesonhouseholdenergyin2011.......................33Table2ObligationschemeswithtradingoptionsinEurope.......................................................54Table3Comparisonofeconomicinstrumentsforlowenergybuildings....................................71Table4Examplesofearmarkedenvironmentallyrelatedtaxes..................................................75Table5Comparingcharges,earmarkedtaxesandgeneralbudgetallocations..........................77

    Table6Overview

    of

    existing

    emission

    trading

    schemes

    .............................................................

    78

    Table7ExamplesforGreenInvestmentSchemesinHungary,LatviaandCzechRepublic.........80

  • 7/28/2019 Mobilising Investment EE FINAL

    5/156

    OECD/IEA2012 MobilisinginvestmentinenergyefficiencyEconomicinstrumentsforlowenergybuildings

    Page|3

    Table8ThemarketpremiumofgreencommercialbuildingsintheUnitedStatesandAustralia....................................................................................................................81

    Table9Existinggreenbondsforenergyefficiency......................................................................88Table10Summaryoffundingsourcesforeconomicinstrumentsforenergyefficiency............92Table11ResidentialEnergyUseandEnergySavingsperHousehold,Pre1945to

    20002009.....................................................................................................................

    99

    Table12SummaryofecoENERGYretrofit HomesprogrammeApril20072012....................102

    Table13CIDD:taxcreditsavailableforvarioustypesofequipment........................................105Table14CIDD:estimatedenergydemandandemissionreductions........................................106Table15CIDD:costs20052009................................................................................................107

    Table16EcoPTZ:eligiblemeasuresandmaximumloansizesandterms................................109Table17EcoPTZ:uptakeandcharacteristicsofloans..............................................................111Table18CO2refurbishmentofbuildingsandEnergyefficientrefurbishment:

    mainfeatures...............................................................................................................115Table19Measuresundertakeninbuildingsparticipatingintheprogrammes20052010.......119Table20Estimatedratioofpubliccoststoenergyandemissionsavings.................................122

    Table21

    Total

    impact

    in

    millions

    of

    Euros

    according

    to

    the

    two

    employment

    scenarios

    .........

    124

    Table22Annualenergysavingsachievedin2010comparedtotargetsfor2010and2016....126Table23CumulativeTargetsfortheItalianWhiteCertificateSystem(Mtoe/year).................129Table24EnergysavingsachievedthroughWhiteCertificatesby30September2010.............130Table25MeasuressupportedandleveloftaxcreditsinItaly..................................................132Table26ClaimsandinvestmentsupportedbytheItaliantaxcredits,2009.............................132Table27Performanceindicatorsofthe55%taxdeductionprogramme..................................133Table28Economicefficiencyofincentives...............................................................................134Table29MeasuresandgrantamountsundertheHomeEnergySaving(HES)Scheme...........137Table30Installedmeasuresperdwellingtype2009/2010.......................................................138

    Table31Estimatedsavingsperyear..........................................................................................138

    Table32

    Value

    of

    awarded

    tax

    credits

    =government

    revenue

    foregone

    (Euros)

    .....................

    139

    Table33OverviewofCostBenefitAnalysisresults(includingsensitivityanalysis)..................140

    ListofBoxes

    Box1Definitionoflowenergybuildingsanddeepretrofitofbuildings.....................................28Box2Investmentneededgloballytoreduceenergyconsumptionofbuildingsby2050...........31Box3ExperienceswiththeuseofhouseholdenergytaxesinDenmark....................................35Box4GrantsforlowincomehouseholdsinNewZealand..........................................................39

    Box5Experiences

    with

    green

    loans

    from

    Australia

    .....................................................................

    43

    Box6ExperienceswithrisksharingfacilitiesinEasternandCentralEuropeforresidentialbuildings...........................................................................................................................44

    Box7ExperienceswithonbillfinancingintheUnitedStates.....................................................46Box8NewonbillfinancinginitiativeintheUnitedKingdom:theGreenDeal...........................47Box9ExperienceswithPACEintheUnitedStates......................................................................49Box10ESCOmarketandperformancecontractingintheUnitedStates....................................52Box11Emissiontradingforbuildings:TheTokyourbancapandtradeprogramme.................57Box12CDMProgrammeofActivitiesforsustainablehousinginMexico...................................58Box13GermanexperienceinearmarkingrevenuesfromETSallowanceauctioning................79Box14Privateinvestmentfundsandenergyefficiency:TheClimateChangePropertyFund....81

    Box15

    Efficiency

    Vermont

    ...........................................................................................................

    83

  • 7/28/2019 Mobilising Investment EE FINAL

    6/156

    Mobilisinginvestmentinenergyefficiency OECD/IEA2012Economicinstrumentsforlowenergybuildings

    Page|4

    Box16EuropeanUnionfundsusedforenergyefficiencyfinance..............................................85Box17ExperiencewithpublicbanksfromGermanyandUnitedKingdom................................87Box18QualifiedEnergyConservationBondsintheUnitedStates.............................................90Box19TheroleandfunctioningoftheSGFGASinFrance........................................................110Box20TheGermanEnergySavingsOrdinance(EnEV)..............................................................114Box

    21

    Application

    procedures

    ..................................................................................................

    116

    Box22ENEA:Italysagencyfornewtechnologies,energyandsustainableeconomicdevelopment..................................................................................................................127

  • 7/28/2019 Mobilising Investment EE FINAL

    7/156

    OECD/IEA2012 MobilisinginvestmentinenergyefficiencyEconomicinstrumentsforlowenergybuildings

    Page|5

    Acknowledgements

    ThemainauthorsofthisreportareAnuschkaHilke(previouslyofthe IEA)andLisaRyanoftheEnergy Efficiency Unit in the Sustainable Technology Policy Directorate of the IEA. Charlotte

    Forbesand

    Ellina

    Levina

    made

    substantial

    contributions

    in

    the

    early

    conception

    of

    the

    project.

    In

    addition, Charlotte Forbes provided background research and compilation of information oneconomicinstrumentsused inIEAcountriesto improvetheenergyefficiencyofbuildings.EllinaLevinaauthoredthecasestudyonItaly.

    Theauthorsaregrateful fortheguidanceandsupportgivenbyRobertTromop,asheadoftheEnergyEfficiencyUnit,andPhilippeBenoit,headoftheEnergyandEnvironmentDivision,andfortheirconsidered reviewof thework. BoDiczfalusy,directorof theSustainableTechnologyandPolicyDirectorateprovidedleadershipandoverallencouragement.

    We are also particularly grateful for the time taken to review this report by IEA colleagues:

    Grayson Heffner, Christina Hood, Marc Lafrance, Yamina Saheb, Cecilia Tam; and by OECD

    colleagues

    also:

    Nils

    Axel

    Braathen,

    Christopher

    Kaminker,

    and

    Virginie

    Marchal.

    The IEAwould like to thank participants in theworkshop hosted by the IEA onThe Future ofEnergyEfficiencyFinance inMarch2012,which includedpresentationsonthetopicsdiscussedhere.1

    Many of these participants also provided review comments on the final report as part of anextensiveconsultationandreviewprocess indevelopingthispublication.Weparticularlythankthefollowingpeoplefortheirreviewsandcontributionstotheworkshopanddocument:

    BogdanAtanasiu,BPIE

    Mlanie Barcet and Colas Paris, Ministre de lEcologie, du Dveloppement Durable et delEnergie,France

    CatherineJ.

    Bell,

    American

    Council

    for

    an

    Energy

    Efficient

    Economy

    MurrayBirt,DeutscheBankGroupBenCaldecott,ClimateChangeCapitalDean Cooper, United Nations Environment Programme, Division of Technology, Industry andEconomicsSusanneDyrboel,RockwoolInternationalA/SAlessandroFederici,ENEAAgimeGerbeti,GestoredeiServiziEnergetici GSES.pp.a.,MartinGaudet,DebraHaltrecht,VictoriaIngram,PhilJago,AnnKowal,ReneLazarowich,ClaudeLefranois,LauraOleson,SiddiqMcDoom,KellySmith,NaturalResourcesCanadaIngridHolmes,E3G

    BretKadison,

    Rosebud

    Capital

    AlexandraLangenheldandPaoloBertoldi,JointResearchCentre,EuropeanCommissionDilipR.Limaye,SRCGlobalInc.

    VivienLo,GudrunGumb,RudolfHennes,MartinMllerandMarkusSchnborn,KfWBankMariaMendiluceandPhilippeFonta,WorldBusinessCouncilforSustainableDevelopmentMurrayBirt,DeutscheBankGroupRobertNuijandRomanDoubrava,DGEnergy,EuropeanCommissionKarstenNeuhoff,DIWBerlinChristinePatterson,EnergyEfficiencyandConservationAuthority,NewZealandRobinReid,WorldEconomicForum

    1http://www.iea.org/newsroomandevents/workshops/workshop/name,14184,en.html

  • 7/28/2019 Mobilising Investment EE FINAL

    8/156

    Mobilisinginvestmentinenergyefficiency OECD/IEA2012Economicinstrumentsforlowenergybuildings

    Page|6

    NickRobins,HSBCBankPlcStephanedelaRueduCan,LaurenceBerkeleyNationalLaboratoryJimScheerandJosephineMaguire,SustainableEnergyAuthorityofIrelandThomasSchubert,EuropeanCommission,DGResearchMikaelSkouAndersen,EuropeanEnvironmentAgency

    PeterSweatman,

    Climate

    Strategy

    and

    Partners

    Matthew Wittenstein, Molly Lunn, Johanna Zetterberg and John Cabaniss, United StatesDepartmentofEnergy.

    TheresultingdocumentistheIEAinterpretationoftheseworkshops,withadditionalinformation

    incorporatedtoprovideamorecompletepicture,anddoesnotnecessarilyrepresenttheviewsofalltheworkshopparticipantsandreviewers.

    This publication has benefitted from the inputs of Angela Gosman, Marilyn Smith, Astrid

    Dumond,MurielCustodio,CherylHaines,andRebeccaGaghen inthe IEACommunicationsandInformationOffice.JennyGellandAudreyGlynnformattedthereport.

  • 7/28/2019 Mobilising Investment EE FINAL

    9/156

    OECD/IEA2012 MobilisinginvestmentinenergyefficiencyEconomicinstrumentsforlowenergybuildings

    Page|7

    ExecutiveSummary

    Taxes, loans and grants, trading schemes and white certificates, public procurement and

    investment inR&Dor infrastructure:known collectivelyaseconomic instruments, these tools

    canbepowerfulmeansofmobilisingthefinancesneededtoachievepolicygoalsbyimplementingenergyefficiencymeasures.Theroleofeconomicinstrumentsistokickstarttheprivatefinancialmarkets and to motivate private investors to fund EE measures. They should reinforce and

    promoteenergyperformanceregulations.

    This IEA analysis addresses the fact that, to date, relatively little effort has been directed

    towardevaluatinghowwelleconomicinstrumentswork.Usingthebuildingssectortoillustratehowsuchmeasurescansupportenergyefficiency,thispapercanhelppolicymakersbetterselectanddesigneconomicinstrumentsappropriatetotheirpolicyobjectivesandnationalcontexts.

    Thisreportsthreemainaimsareto:

    Examinehoweconomicinstrumentsarecurrentlyusedinenergyefficiencypolicy;

    Considerhow

    economic

    instruments

    can

    be

    more

    effective

    and

    efficient

    in

    supporting

    lowenergybuildings;and

    Assesshoweconomicinstrumentsshouldbefunded,wherepublicoutlayisneeded.

    The purpose of economic instruments in energy efficiency policy is to provide financial

    incentives to invest inenergy efficiencymeasures through price and investment signals. Thesignalsmaybeintheformofincentives(e.g.viasubsidiesintheformofagrant,aconcessionalloanorsomeformofdirectpublic investment)ordisincentives(e.g.throughprice increasesviataxes or the creation of a market for energy efficiency certificates). Economic instruments canalso be used to increase the amount of finance available or to improve financing terms (e.g.throughreducedinterestrates,theunlockingofthirdpartyfinanceordedicatedcreditlines).

    Economic

    instruments

    can

    be

    clustered

    into

    four

    categories,

    each

    of

    which

    has

    specific

    advantagesinsomecontexts:

    Fiscalinstruments:

    o taxeso taxreliefs

    Financialmeasures:

    o loans

    o grants

    Tradingschemes:

    o emissionstradingschemes

    o whitecertificates Directinvestment:

    o publicprocuremento publicinvestmentinR&D

    o investmentinpublicinfrastructure.

    Thisreport isstructured inthreeparts:(i)ataxonomyofeconomic instrumentsused inenergy

    efficiencypolicy; (ii) theuseofeconomic instruments toachieve lowenergybuildings;and (iii)how these economic instruments are funded when public funds are needed. As a broadintroduction,thefirstsectiondescribesandcomparesthemaindesignfeaturesofeacheconomic

    instrument.The

    second

    section

    investigates

    how

    economic

    instruments

    are

    used

    to

    improve

    the

  • 7/28/2019 Mobilising Investment EE FINAL

    10/156

    Mobilisinginvestmentinenergyefficiency OECD/IEA2012Economicinstrumentsforlowenergybuildings

    Page|8

    energyperformanceinthebuildingssector,providinginsightsastowhichislikelytobeeffectiveindifferentcircumstancesortoovercomespecificbarrierstoenergyefficiency.Thefinalsectionexplores how economic instruments in energy efficiency policy can be funded and/or raiserevenue. The first and third sections are crosssectoral, and relevant for improving energyefficiency in all sectors. The middle section provides lessons learned from implementing

    economicinstruments

    specifically

    to

    support

    the

    finance

    of

    low

    energy

    buildings.

    Many

    of

    the

    experiences in the buildings sector will surely be useful to policy makers seeking to improveenergyefficiencyinothersectors.

    Economicinstrumentsinenergyefficiencypolicy

    Economic instrumentsareusedbyall IEAcountrygovernments inenergyefficiencypolicy to

    address barriers such as externalities, split incentives, perceived high investment risk, lackingaccesstofinance,hightransactioncostsandbehaviouralissues.

    Some general lessons canbedrawn from experienceswitheconomic instruments inenergy

    efficiencypolicy

    to

    date.

    Whenpartofawelldesignedandcoherentpolicypackage,economic instrumentshavebetter potential to deliver maximum impact on the market and to be economically

    efficient.Thepolicypackageshouldalsoincludeminimumenergyperformancestandardsorregulations,informationandawarenessraisingmeasures,andcapacitybuilding.

    Barriersthatneedtobeovercometoencourageinvestmentshouldunderpinthechoiceand design of economic instruments for energy efficiency. Other determining factorsincludethesector(s)tobeaddressed,nationalcircumstancesandotherpoliciesinplace.

    Asenergypricesaredriversfor investment inenergyefficiency,theuseofenergytaxesand removal of energy price subsidies are prerequisites to putting in place any public

    financingprogramme

    or

    other

    subsidies.

    Tax relief and grants can act as sweeteners to encourage investment in energyefficiency that might otherwise not take place but are likely to leverage only smallerinvestments.

    Public funds and guarantees provide access to finance as the energy efficiency marketdevelopsandlargerinvestmentsareencouragedormandated.Financemaybecombinedwithincentivestoencourageuptakeoftheprogramme.

    Publicprivatefinancing instrumentsopenupnewwaysoffinancing,enablingpeopletoinvestinenergyefficiencymeasuresthatmightnotbeeligibleforregularbankloans.

    Todate,

    thorough

    evaluations

    of

    economic

    instruments

    have

    been

    rare,

    even

    though

    these

    instruments are widely used in IEA member countries. Most reporting on governmentprogrammes focuses only on outcomes in terms of related costs and programme participants;reallifeimpactsarerarelyassessedandatbestmodelled.Divergingindicatorsandmetricsusedin the few available evaluations make it difficult to conduct a comparative analysis of impactsgenerated through government programmes. This paper aims to address gaps in knowledge,advanceunderstandingandidentifyareasforfutureinvestigation.

    Economicinstrumentsforlowenergybuildings

    Makingthebuildingssectormoreenergyefficient isaglobalchallengeof increasingurgency.

    Thebuildingssectorrepresents32%ofglobalfinalenergyconsumptionandrecenttrendsshow

  • 7/28/2019 Mobilising Investment EE FINAL

    11/156

    OECD/IEA2012 MobilisinginvestmentinenergyefficiencyEconomicinstrumentsforlowenergybuildings

    Page|9

    annual demand growth at almost 2%. While many costeffective measures to deliver energysavingshavebeenidentifiedforbothnewandexistingbuildings,implementationishinderedbyanumber of sectorspecific barriers. Policy makers need to put in place a strong and enablingpolicy framework, comprising regulation, information and economic instruments, in order tomobilisetheestimatedUSD11.5trillionneededonagloballevelupto2050todrasticallyreduce

    theenergy

    consumption

    in

    buildings

    compared

    with

    business

    as

    usual.

    Policy goals should be set to deliver nearly zeroenergy new buildings and deep retrofit of

    existing buildings. As the rate of construction of new buildings is low in IEA countries, deepretrofitsoftheexistingbuildingstockwillplaythecrucialpart inreducingenergyconsumptionfromthebuildingssector.

    All IEA countrieshaveat leastoneeconomic instrument inplace to supportenergyefficient

    buildings.2 Historically, energy taxes,grants and tax relief have been the schemes favoured bymostgovernments.

    Current targets and eligibility requirements attached to the economic instruments used for

    energy

    efficiency

    in

    buildings

    are,

    with

    few

    exceptions,

    not

    very

    ambitious.

    This

    analysis

    shows

    thatthere isastrong focuson lowcostandquickwinsthroughthereplacementofequipment(lightingandHVAC),ratherthanimprovementsinthebuildingenvelopeorwholebuildingenergyperformance.Subsidieshavebeenmainlyattachedtorequirementsforeligibleenergyefficiencytechnologies and do not take a wholebuilding approach. It is difficult to find examples ofeconomicinstrumentsorsubsidiesthatapplytoambitiouslevelsofoverallbuildingperformanceimprovements,althoughsomedoexist(e.g.theKfWloanschemeinGermany).

    Sofarefficiencyimprovementsof10%to30%,ratherthantrulylowenergybuildings,havebeendeliveredthroughmostprogrammes.Onaverage,greaterimprovementsinenergyefficiencyarelikelytobeneededacrossthebuildingsstock(amountswillvaryforeachbuilding,dependingontype, location and other factors). Achieving only 20%, for example, can be expected to have a

    lockin

    effect

    that

    results

    in

    unrealised

    energy

    savings

    potential

    over

    the

    next

    decades.

    Economic

    instrumentsareneededthatenableand incentivisedeeperenergyretrofits,whethervoluntaryormandated.

    Moreambitiousandtargeteddeepcutsinenergyconsumptionforretrofitofbuildingsshould

    be the core element of energy efficiency policy. Governments should design economicinstrumentsthat:

    (i) Provide greater access to finance for deep retrofit of buildings: policy makers need toreplace or complement direct subsidies as incentives for individual energy efficiencymeasuresandequipmentwith financing instruments thatare tied tosignificantcuts inwholebuildingenergyperformance.

    (ii) Supportprivate

    investment

    in

    low

    energy

    buildings

    by:

    o Setting up loan programmes directly through public banks or financial

    institutions,withpreferentialrateloanswhereneeded;

    o Assistingfinancialinstitutionswithriskguaranteesorcreditlinesuntiltheyhavebuiltupexperience;

    o Encouraging the private sector through changes to legal requirements thatfacilitatepublicprocurement,energyperformancecontracting,onbill financingorotherthirdpartyfinance.

    2Available

    at

    http://www.iea.org/policiesandmeasures/energyefficiency/

  • 7/28/2019 Mobilising Investment EE FINAL

    12/156

    Mobilisinginvestmentinenergyefficiency OECD/IEA2012Economicinstrumentsforlowenergybuildings

    Page|10

    In all cases, government support should be tied to ambitious energy performanceimprovementsinlinewithadeepretrofittingstrategy.

    (iii)Focusonwholebuildingenergyperformance:evenwhenastepbysteprefurbishmentapproachistaken,anintegratedassessmentofefficiencypotentialforthewholebuildingshouldbecarriedoutsothatearlyrefurbishmentstepsdonotimpedelaterones.

    (iv)Addresssplitincentives:thelandlordtenantproblemislikelytoberesolvedonlythroughmandatory retrofitting obligations. The issue of the full costs being recouped over thelong term canbeaddressed through financingmechanisms thatattach the loan to the

    property,ratherthantotheinitialinvestor.

    (v) Encouragehigherrenovationrates:incentiveswillplayanimportantroleinencouraginginvestors to undertake renovation and deep retrofit. Unless future regulatoryrequirementsorsignificantenergypricehikesareexpected, it isunlikely,however,thatany financial incentive on its own would be large enough to encourage the depth ofretrofitneededinmanybuildings.

    (vi)Timethe

    economic

    instruments

    to

    match

    the

    development

    of

    mandatory

    standards

    and

    themarketforlowenergybuildings:atanearlystageofawarenessandimplementationof lowenergy buildings (i.e. before introducing ambitious energy codes for existingbuildings), energy taxes and grants and/or tax relief can encourage early movers toinvest.Anyannouncementoffuturestringentenergyperformancebuildingsregulationsshouldbecombinedwithstraightforwardaccesstofinancewithfavourableterms,whichmightincludesomeincentives.Onceambitiousenergyperformancerequirementsareinplaceforrenovation,subsidiesshouldnotberequired;however,financialarrangementsandguaranteesareneeded toencourageprivatesector investment in themarket.Anypublicfinanceshouldbereferencedtothebuildingenergycodesinforceorplanned,andshouldnotestablishalternativemetricsinparallel.

    Monitoringand

    evaluation

    are

    key

    to

    understanding

    the

    effectiveness

    and

    efficiency

    of

    economic instruments, and to making necessary adjustments to improve their impact.Monitoringandevaluation,includingthedefinitionofabaselinestartingpointandtargetstobeachieved,needtobepartofthedesignofeconomicinstruments.Closemonitoringofrealcostsanduptakeoftheprogrammecangiveearlyindicationsofdesignflaws.Regularevaluationshelptoensuretheprogrammeismeetingitstargetsand,eventually,toidentifynecessarychanges.

    Training and capacity building are needed at many levels to complement effective policy

    design. Financial institutions need greater capacity to assess risks and potentials attached toenergyefficiencyinvestments.Publicinstitutionsneedtrainingforthesmoothimplementationofprogrammes.Assessorsneed tobetrainedandcertified tocarryoutbuildingenergyefficiency

    audits

    to

    a

    high

    standard

    in

    terms

    of

    accuracy

    so

    that

    audits

    are

    credible

    as

    a

    basis

    for

    programmesorloanapplications.

    Experiencetodatewith innovativefinancialmechanismsshouldbeuseful indeterminingthe

    instruments needed to develop longterm financing options for deep retrofits. Multipleinnovativeapproacheshavebeendevelopedinrecentyears,suchaspreferentialrateloans,onbill and financing through initiatives such as the Property Assessed Clean Energy (PACE)programmeintheUnitedStates.DetailedcasestudiesinthisreportassessexamplesofeconomicinstrumentsforenergyefficiencyinthebuildingssectorinCanada(grants),France(taxreliefandloans),Germany(loansandgrants),Ireland(grants)andItaly(whitecertificatesandtaxrelief).

  • 7/28/2019 Mobilising Investment EE FINAL

    13/156

    OECD/IEA2012 MobilisinginvestmentinenergyefficiencyEconomicinstrumentsforlowenergybuildings

    Page|11

    Fundingeconomicinstruments

    Someeconomicinstrumentsrequireoutlayofpublicbudget.Grants,loansandtaxreliefrequirebudgets,whichcanbemadeupofamixofpublicandprivate funds.Thefundingmayevenberaisedfromothereconomicinstrumentssuchastaxesandemissionstradingauctionrevenues.

    Arangeofpublicfundingsourcescanbeusedtofundeconomicinstruments,includingbudget

    allocations,dedicated funds,publicbanks,earmarked taxesandcharges,and revenues from

    emission allowance auctioning. Private sources of funds such as institutional investors and

    private investment funds can beblendedwith public resources to fund economic instruments.Theseoptionsareequallyvalidforenergyefficiencyprojectsbeyondthebuildingssector.

    Policymakers should consider several factorswhendecidingappropriate sourcesof funding

    streamsforenergyefficiencyeconomicinstruments,eachofwhichisexaminedinmoredetailinthepaper:

    stabilityandsustainabilityofthefundingstream;

    leastoverall

    cost

    to

    society

    including

    public

    and

    private

    costs;

    splitbetweencostspaidbypublicandprivatesectors;

    administrativesimplicity;

    abilitytoleverageprivatefunds;and

    publicbudgetconstraints.

    The longterm goal should be to engage the private sector such that the energy efficiency

    market becomes selfsustaining. Financial institutions need to recognise energy efficiencyinvestmentsasasourceofvaluablenewclientsanddeals;yettoworkinthismarket,theymusthavethecapacitytoevaluatetheriskassociatedwithdifferentinvestments.Policymakersneedto develop partnerships with financial institutions to build familiarity and trust in the business

    casefor

    energy

    efficiency

    investments.

    Futureconsiderations

    Thisreportfindsthat investments inenergyefficiencymeasuresare lowriskandcanprovide

    high returns to investorsand lenders. Financial instruments have the advantage of being lesscapitalintensiveforthepublicbudget,leveragingmoreprivateinvestmentsandprovidingmorestable longterm financingopportunities.Governmentscouldhelpmotivatethe financialsectortoinvestinlowenergybuildingsbybuildingupevidenceandgoodpracticesinthreemainareas:

    Accumulate proof that default rates of loans for lowenergy buildings are low and

    presentalow

    risk

    investment

    opportunity;

    Monetise the multiple benefits attached to energy efficiency investments andstandardisemethodologiestocompletecostbenefitassessmentsofinvestment;and

    Develop rating criteria for energy efficiency investments to increase attractiveness tolargeinvestors.

    The lessons learned from this evaluation and the relevant case studies can be transferred andadaptedtoothersectorandcountrycontexts.Whileregulationswillcontinuetoplayakeyrolein creating demand for ambitious energy efficiency, economic instruments and private financewill be crucial in meeting that demand. Without stringent energy performance requirements,economic instruments are unlikely to deliver enough of an incentive to mobilise the finance

    neededfor

    dramatic

    reductions

    in

    energy

    consumption.

  • 7/28/2019 Mobilising Investment EE FINAL

    14/156

    Mobilisinginvestmentinenergyefficiency OECD/IEA2012Economicinstrumentsforlowenergybuildings

    Page|12

    Betterevaluationanddata relatedtothetechnicaland financialrequirementsof lowenergy

    buildingsareneeded to be able to assess properly the design of finance to meet longer termpolicygoalsforlowenergybuildings.Alsothewidersocietalbenefitsassociatedwithlowenergybuildingsshouldbeestimatedand internalised in interestrates for financeofenergyefficiencymeasuresinthebuildingssector.

    Public investments inenergyefficiencyyieldmore thanenergy savingsalone. The return onpublic investment can include increased wellbeing, economic development, energy security,health, andothersocietal benefitswell into the future.Policy makersshould takeawideviewand consider these benefits in designing and funding more ambitious policy instruments toimproveenergyefficiency.

  • 7/28/2019 Mobilising Investment EE FINAL

    15/156

    OECD/IEA2012 MobilisinginvestmentinenergyefficiencyEconomicinstrumentsforlowenergybuildings

    Page|13

    Introduction

    The IEAprojectoneconomic instrumentsforthepromotionofhigherenergyefficiencyaimstoidentifyeffectivewaysofmobilisingincreasedinvestmentinenergyefficiency,byevaluatingthe

    useof

    economic

    instruments

    across

    different

    sectors.

    This

    analysis

    should

    help

    policy

    makers

    from relevant institutions (such as energy,economy, financeor environmentministries)betterunderstand,selectanddesignappropriateeconomicinstrumentstoimproveenergyefficiencyinindividual sectors. Future reports under this project will focus on the transport and industrialsectors.

    Thisreportfocusesontheuseofeconomicinstrumentstosupportenergyefficiency,particularlyinthebuildingssector.Theobjectivesofthereportareto:

    Examine how economic instruments are currently used to improve energy efficiency,with a particular focus on improving the energy performance of buildings in IEAcountries;

    Considerthe

    most

    effective

    and

    efficient

    use

    of

    economic

    instruments

    to

    drive

    forward

    lowenergybuildings;and

    Identify the sources of public funding of economic instruments, where subsidies areneeded.

    It should draw out insights for policy makers trying to identify and design the most applicablepoliciesfortheirnationalcircumstancesto improveenergyefficiency,notonly inbuildings,butalsoinothersectorswheresimilarconditionsexist.

    Reportscopeandstructure

    Thisreport

    examines

    the

    experience

    with

    economic

    instruments

    in

    energy

    efficiency

    policy.

    It

    is

    targetedatpolicymakersdevelopingenergyefficiencypolicyinthebuildingsandothersectors.

    Thisfirstsectionpresentseconomicinstrumentsrelevanttoenergyefficiencypolicy.Itdescribesthe range of economic instruments used in energy efficiency policy generally and outlines themain featuresofeach. Itshould providesomebackground on economic instruments and theirstrengthsandweaknesses.

    The second section investigates how economic instruments are used to improve the energyperformanceofonesectorinparticular,thebuildingssector.Inthisinstance,thebuildingssectorserves to examine more closely the use of economic instruments in practice. This sectionprovides a systematic overview of the effectiveness of existing economic policies in delivering

    low

    energy

    buildings

    in

    IEA

    member

    countries.

    The

    focus

    is

    on

    policies

    for

    the

    energy

    efficiency

    (EE)refurbishmentofexistingbuildings,andinparticulardeepretrofit,whichisthepriorityinIEAcountries,eventhoughinsomecasesalsopoliciesfornewbuildingsarecovered.

    Thethirdsectionofthereportprovidesanoverviewofpossiblefundingsourcesandtherelevantintermediariesforeconomicinstrumentswhereapplicabletoenergyefficiencypolicy.Economicinstruments are made up of revenue raisers, i.e. taxes, charges, and trading schemes; andsubsidies.Thepublicfundingpartofthereportfocusesonthesourceoffundsforthesubsidiespart of economic instruments. The discussion of the different approaches to funding energyefficiencyisenrichedbyawiderangeofexamplesfromexperiencesinIEAcountries.

    Thefirstandthirdsectionsarecrosssectoralandrelevantfor improvingenergyefficiency inallsectors. The middle section provides lessons learned from implementation of economicinstruments to improve the energy efficiency specifically in the buildings sector. It examines

  • 7/28/2019 Mobilising Investment EE FINAL

    16/156

    Mobilisinginvestmentinenergyefficiency OECD/IEA2012Economicinstrumentsforlowenergybuildings

    Page|14

    whether the current crop of economic instruments is delivering the deep cuts in energyconsumptioninbuildingsneededandhoweconomicinstrumentsshouldbeadaptedtomobilisethefinancethatwillberequiredinthefuture.

    Methodologicalissues

    The initial information on existing economic instruments has been obtained mainly from thecurrentIEApoliciesandmeasures(PaMs)databaseonenergyefficiency.3Thisdatabaseprovidesanoverviewofeconomic instrumentscurrentlyinoperation inIEAcountriestosupportenergyefficiencymeasures;thesehavebeenverifiedbycorrespondingwithcountriesthroughthe IEAEnergy efficiency Working Party government delegates and crosschecked with the OECDeconomicinstrumentsdatabase.4Insomecountries,thesameinstrumentsareusedtopromoterenewableenergyandthedistinctionhasbeenmadewherepossible.

    The information was completed by a literature review of evaluations of economic instrumentsand funding mechanisms in the buildings sector. For selected countries (France, Germany,

    Ireland,and

    Italy),

    in

    depth

    case

    studies

    of

    country

    experiences

    with

    different

    types

    of

    economic

    instruments and funding mechanisms were developed with input from policy makers in therespectivecountries.Thecasestudiesevaluatetheeffectivenessandefficiencyofdifferentpolicyinstruments using an evaluation matrix developed by the authors. First results, as well asevaluation methods and case studies, were discussed during an expert workshop, which tookplaceon15March2012inParis,France.5

    Veryfewthoroughevaluationsofeconomicinstrumentsinenergyefficiencypolicyareavailablethatwouldfacilitatebenefitcostratiocomparisons.Theavailablesourcesdonotallowgeneralrecommendations on which policies are most effective or efficient. In many cases, evaluations

    include more outcomerelated indicators (e.g. public spending, number of programmeparticipants)thanimpactrelatedindicators(reductioninenergydemand,reboundeffects,freeridership6) and where these are available, they are in many cases based on surveys of a smallsampleofprogrammeparticipantsandreportthetechnicalpotentialsofpoliciesratherthanreallife savings achieved. Additionally, the indicators used in available evaluations in differentprogrammesaretoodifferenttoallowacomparativeanalysis.7Oftenbaselinesarenotdefinedat thestart ofprogramsand then it ishard toevaluatewhatchanges haveoccurred from thebaselineasaresultofthisprogramme.Duetothelackofcomparabledata,theanalysisremainsqualitativeanddescriptivebutshouldneverthelessprovideinsightsforpolicymakersdevelopingstrategiestodramaticallyimprovetheenergyperformanceinbuildingsandothersectors.

    3Availableatwww.iea.org/policiesandmeasures/

    4www.oecd.org/env/policies/database

    5Fordocumentationoftheworkshopsee:www.iea.org/newsroomandevents/workshops/name,14184,en.html

    6Reboundeffectortakebackeffectiswhenimprovementsinenergyefficiencydonotrealisetheexpectedenergysavings

    due to either more intensive activity (the direct rebound effect) or reinvestment of the financial savings in other energyintensiveactivitiesorservices.Freeridershipisthephenomenonofinvestorstakingadvantageofasubsidyeventhoughtheywouldhaveinvestedintheenergyefficientmeasureintheabsenceoftheincentive.Thismeansthatthesubsidyisgrantedtoconsumers who did not need it and that the programme is not creating any incentives for increased energy efficiencymeasures.7Althoughsomecountriesaredevelopingstandardisedmethodstoevaluateenergysavingsdatafromenergyefficiencypolicy

    (i.e. in the US see http://www1.eere.energy.gov/office_eere/de_umpp. html; in the EU see http://www.evaluateenergy

    savings.eu/emeees/en/publications/reports/EMEEES_WP61_report_090430.pdf

  • 7/28/2019 Mobilising Investment EE FINAL

    17/156

    OECD/IEA2012 MobilisinginvestmentinenergyefficiencyEconomicinstrumentsforlowenergybuildings

    Page|15

    PARTI:Economicinstrumentsinenergyefficiency

    policy

    Economic

    instruments

    in

    energy

    efficiency

    policy

    include

    all

    policy

    instruments

    that

    relate

    to

    fiscal, financial and other economic incentives and disincentives to deliver energy efficiencyimprovementsacrossallsectors.

    The term economic instruments is not welldefined in the context of energy efficiency policy.Often inenergyefficiencypolicythetermfinancial instruments isusedtodescribepoliciesthat

    provide incentives forenergyefficiency measures.However, the termeconomic instruments isbroader and is used in the economics and environmental policy literature to describe price,incentives, finance, or trading schemes in policy. The term economic instruments moreaccuratelyencompassestherangeoffiscalinstrumentsandfinancialmechanismsusedbypolicymakersinenergyefficiencypolicy.

    Economic instrumentsareusedbyallgovernmentsofIEAmembercountriesto improveenergy

    efficiencyindifferentsectors.Theycanaddressbarrierstoenergyefficiencysuchas:

    Marketfailuresincludingexternalities,whereenergyendusersdonotpaythefullcosttosociety of their energy consumption, and split incentives, which is when the economicbenefits of an energy efficiency measure do not accrue to the financier of thosemeasures;

    Uncertainty and risk associated with recoupment of the costs of energy efficiencyinvestmentinthefuture;

    Lackofaccesstofinanceforenergyefficiencyprojectsthroughunfamiliarity infinancialinstitutions, lackofcollateral,anddifficulty inmeasuringenergysavingsassociatedwithinvestmentsinenergyefficiency;

    Relativelyhightransactioncostsofsmallprojects;and

    Behaviouralissuesintheformofinertiaandboundedrationality.8

    Figure 1 provides a schematic diagram for economic instruments. We categorise economicinstruments under four headings fiscal instruments, financial mechanisms, trading schemes,anddirectinvestment.Theclassificationofpolicyinstrumentscanbeamatterforsomedebate.We define fiscal instruments as those policy instruments that relate to the public treasury orgovernmentrevenuesandtherefore includetaxes,taxrelief,andusercharges inthiscategory.Financialmechanismsrelatetoraisingmoneyandmarketsthroughthe issuanceofdebtand/orequity.Aswithalldefinitions,therearesomegreyareas.Grantscouldbeincludedineitherthefiscalorfinancialcategories.Herewehaveincludedtheminthefinancialmechanismscategory,

    as

    most

    governments

    provide

    grants

    with

    the

    goal

    of

    leveraging

    further

    private

    finance

    for

    energy efficiency.Direct investmentsbygovernmentsareoftennot included indescriptionsofsubsidiesandincentivesforenergyefficiencybutplayanimportantroleininfluencingpricesandmarketsforenergyefficiencymeasures.Theindividualinstrumentsaredescribedinmoredetailinthenextsections.

    8 Bounded rationality iswhen decisionmakers do not make choices rationally, as generallyassumed in classicaleconomic

    theory.

  • 7/28/2019 Mobilising Investment EE FINAL

    18/156

    Mobilisinginvestmentinenergyefficiency OECD/IEA2012Economicinstrumentsforlowenergybuildings

    Page|16

    Figure1Overviewofeconomicinstruments

    Economicinstrumentsforenergyefficiency

    Fiscalinstruments

    Taxrelief

    Taxes

    Charges

    Financialmeasures

    Loans

    Grants

    Tradingschemes

    Emissionstradingschemes

    Whitecertificateschemes

    Directinvestment

    Publicprocurement

    rules

    Publicinfrastructure

    RD&Dinvestment

    Source:IEA

    Economic instruments can overcome the presence of externalities by adjusting the costs andbenefits of an energy efficiency measure or by internalising the costs to society of pollutingbehaviour in order to reflect the effects on the public good associated with energy efficiencyimprovements on the one hand and pollution on the other hand. Split incentives can beaddressedbyensuringthattherearebenefitstotheagentinvesting inenergyefficiencyorthat

    theinvestment

    costs

    can

    be

    passed

    on

    to

    the

    tenant

    or

    beneficiary

    of

    the

    reduced

    energy

    bills.

    The second barrier of uncertainty or risk can also be addressed by sending a longterm pricesignaltothemarket thatenergyefficiency is importantandreducingthecostsassociatedwithenergy efficiency investments. Similarly, the proportionally high transaction costs triggered bythesmallsizeofenergyefficiencyprojectscanalsobepartiallyovercomethrougharealignmentofincentivestoinvestinenergyefficiencybyeconomicinstruments.

    Finally, evidence that consumer decisions are not always perfectly rational is quite strong(Gillingham et al., 2009). Economic instruments can address this partly by, for example,overcoming inertia through giving a strong price signal, by bringing energy efficiency to theattentionofboardsofmanagementinbusinessesorbysimplygivingconsumersthefeelingthat

    theycan

    make

    agood

    deal.

    Tailoring to national circumstances and good design are important in the successful use ofeconomic instruments in energy efficiency policy. Firstly, the appropriate choice of economicpolicyinstrumenttoaddressalackofinvestmentinenergyefficiencymaydifferineachcountrydepending on national circumstances, such as economic situation, demographics, and energyprices,thebarriers identifiedto improvementsinenergyefficiency,andthetargetedsector.Ananalysis of these factors should be carried out in advance of the choice of instrument. Forexample, taxes, tax relief and grants are likely to be suitable tools to address externalities byreadjusting the prices of energy and energyusing equipment to promote energyefficientbehaviourandinvestments.However,biggerenergyefficiencyprojectsinindustryorinbuildings

    may require additional economic instruments in the form of financial mechanisms, if the

    significantfinance

    needed

    to

    fund

    these

    projects

    is

    not

    available

    from

    traditional

    sources

    due

    to

  • 7/28/2019 Mobilising Investment EE FINAL

    19/156

    OECD/IEA2012 MobilisinginvestmentinenergyefficiencyEconomicinstrumentsforlowenergybuildings

    Page|17

    theissuesgivenaboveinthebarrieronlackofaccesstocapital.Countriesmayprioritiseenergyefficiencyinonesectoroveranotherbecauseofhistoricalorprojectedenergyuseinthatsectororperceivedaccessibility. It is importanttoknowwhicheconomic instrumentsare likelytobemoresuitabletoaddressenergyefficiencyintheprioritysectors.

    Secondly,good

    design

    of

    economic

    instruments

    is

    important

    and

    may

    have

    as

    strong

    an

    influence

    on the effectiveness and economic efficiency of the policy as the type of policy instrumentchosen in some cases. Monitoring and evaluation of the economic instrument are importantchecks to determine if progress is made towards energy efficiency goals, as defined at theintroductionoftheeconomic instruments.Stability inthedesignand longtermfunding(wherenecessary) of economic instruments is needed to give investors confidence in the viability ofenergy efficiency measures. Choosing the appropriate source of funds for such economicinstrumentsispartofthisprocess.

    Thegoalofeconomicinstruments istoultimatelykickstarttheprivatefinancialmarketsandtomotivate investors to fund energy efficiency measures. An important indicator of theeffectiveness of economic instruments is the amount of private funds leveraged through the

    public

    funds

    spent,

    called

    the

    leverage

    ratio.

    The

    definition

    of

    leverage

    ratio

    varies

    between

    financial institutions and countries. From a government authoritys perspective it can beapproximatelydefinedastheratiobetweenthetotalamountfinancedforanenergyefficiencymeasure and the total amount of public funding provided. However, there can be differentdefinitionsused(asreviewedbyBrownetal.2011,CDCClimate2012,Clappetal.2012,UNAGF2010) and therefore clear definitions are needed when discussing the leverage ratio. In thisreport,thetermleverageratioisusedtomeantheratioofthepublictoprivatecofinancingofanenergyefficiencymeasureorproject.9

    Theleverageratiomaynotbethemostimportantmeasureofeffectivenessofpublicfunds.Forexample,itismaybepossibletofindprivatefinancemorereadilyforlowercostmeasuresthanhighercostmeasures,resultinginahigherleverageratio,althoughitmaybeinsocietysinteresttousepublicfundingforhighercostenergyefficiencymeasures.Moreimportantmaybewhichkindsofenergyefficiencyprojectsarebeingdeliveredasaresultoftheeconomicinstrument,i.e.whetherdeepercutsinenergyconsumptionareachieved.Nevertheless,ahighleverageratioisaveryimportantaspectasitmaximisestheimpactofeveryunitofpublicmoneyinvested.

    In all cases, economic instruments should be part of a policy package made up of regulatory,informationandeconomicpolicies.Withoutacoherent,consistentpolicyframework,economicinstrumentsarelesseffectiveandeconomicallyefficient.Economicinstrumentsontheirownwilloftennotbeenoughtotransformthemarketforenergyefficiencyproductsandservices;longertermregulationsandframeworksareneededtoprovideforwardlookinginvestorswithdirectionand reassurance that energy efficiency is a longterm trend and requirement. Information and

    awarenessraising

    measures

    are

    needed

    to

    support

    behavioural

    change

    and

    achieve

    real

    world

    reductionsinenergydemand.

    The next subsections describe the main features of economic instruments as they are used inenergyefficiencypolicy.

    EnergytaxesandpricesubsidiesEnergy taxes and price subsidies are economic instruments that directly affect the price ofenergy.Theyarethetwomainfiscaltoolsatgovernmentsdisposaltoinfluencethepricepaidfor

    9ThisissimilartothedefinitionusedbyclimatefundssuchastheGlobalEnvironmentFundandtheCleanTechnologyFund

    (Brownet

    al.

    2011).

  • 7/28/2019 Mobilising Investment EE FINAL

    20/156

    Mobilisinginvestmentinenergyefficiency OECD/IEA2012Economicinstrumentsforlowenergybuildings

    Page|18

    energybyconsumers.Highenergypricesprovidean incentive to invest inenergyefficiency astheyshortenpaybackperiodsandincreasethenetbenefitsofsuchinvestments.Conversely,lowenergypricesanddirectenergysubsidiesencouragemorewastefulconsumptionofenergyandmakeinvestmentsinenergyefficiencylessattractive.

    Asafirst

    step

    to

    encourage

    improved

    energy

    efficiency,

    it

    is

    important

    to

    remove

    energy

    price

    subsidies as far as possible. This is a precondition for the effective use of other economicinstruments.Subsidisingenergyefficiencyinvestments,whileatthesametimesubsidisingenergyconsumption, is a less efficient and effective use of public funds. The uptake of financinginstruments that address the availability of financing for energy efficiency investments is alsolikelytobehigherifenergypricesareelevated.

    Within OECD countries,directly subsidised energy prices remain the exception rather than therule, even though a number of various indirect subsidies exist (e.g. subsidies for R&D, publicinsurancefornuclearplants,military interventionstosecureenergysupply infrastructure,etc.).But indirect subsidies are very difficult to track. A preliminary OECD inventory of estimatedbudgetarysupportandtaxexpendituresforfossilfuelsacross24OECDcountries,remarksthat,

    withinthe

    OECD,

    the

    consumption

    of

    the

    majority

    of

    fuels

    is

    taxed

    to

    some

    degree.

    And

    even

    though between USD 45 billion and USD 75 billion in support for production and use of fossilfuelshasbeenidentified,thesearemainlyexemptionsfromsomeformofenergytaxes.Notallofthemcanclearlybe labelledas inefficientsubsidies(OECD,2011b).Whereenergyconsumptionsubsidiesexistandaredeemednecessary, itshouldbeensuredthatthesearewelltargetedtoservetheiroriginalpurposesandtoavoidincentivisingwastefulenergyconsumption.

    Energy taxes are often set with the main purpose of raising revenue rather than influencingenergy consumption. However, a large area of study is on the potential double dividend ofraisingenergyorotherenvironmentaltaxes.This literature focusesonestimatingthepotentialdoublebenefitofenergytaxesthroughbothareductionindemandforenergyconsumptionandincreased revenue, facilitating the lowering of other taxes, for example on labour (Bovenberg,1999).

    The OECD/EEA database on instruments used for environmental policy and natural resourcemanagementdefinesenvironmentallyrelatedtaxesasanycompulsory,unrequitedpaymenttogeneral government levied on taxbases deemed to be of particular environmental relevance.Taxes are unrequited in the sense that benefits provided by government to taxpayers are notnormally in proportion to their payments.10 Environmentallyrelated taxes can be used toincludecosts inthepriceofenergy thatarenot includedbythemarketbutwhicharepaidbysociety,suchase.g.healthcostsduetoenvironmentalpollution.Therevenuesfromenergytaxesmay flow intocentralgovernment treasuriesbut inmanycountriesaportionalsomaybeearmarkedforenergyrelatedpurposessuchasenergyefficiencyandrenewableenergy.

    TaxreliefTax relief isaneconomic instrument thateffectivelyreducestaxesonparticulargoodsorforacertain part of the population to correctmarket failuresand in this case overcome barriers toenergy efficiency investment. It is referred to by the OECD as taxexpenditures and defined asprovisions of tax law, regulation or practices that reduce or postpone revenue for acomparatively narrow population of taxpayers relative to a benchmark tax (OECD, 2010a). Inenergyefficiencypolicyseveraltypesoftaxreliefarecommonlyusedwhichreducetax liabilitywheninvestmentstoimproveenergyefficiencyaremade:

    10The

    database

    and

    definitions

    are

    available

    at

    www2.oecd.org/ecoinst/queries/

    version

    from

    13.04.2012.

  • 7/28/2019 Mobilising Investment EE FINAL

    21/156

    OECD/IEA2012 MobilisinginvestmentinenergyefficiencyEconomicinstrumentsforlowenergybuildings

    Page|19

    Tax deduction: eligible investment costs relating to energy efficiency measures can bededucted (fully or in part) from income or revenues liable to taxation. Eligible investmentcostsmostlycoverpurchasecostsof materialsorequipmentimprovingenergyefficiency,butmay also include related services such as the installation costs of an energy efficiency

    measure;

    Taxcredits:aresimilartotaxdeductionsbutinvestmentcostsarededucted(fullyorinpart)from respective taxes due to be paid. Tax credits may also be refundable if tax credits arehigherthantaxesdue,whichisthecaseforexampleinBelgium.11

    Tax reductions and rebates: purchase taxes or sales taxes are reduced for qualifyingequipmentorservices,e.g.reducedvalueaddedtaxesforinsulationmaterialandinstallationservices in the United Kingdom.12 This is either done directly at the point of sale (taxreductions)orapplicationsfortaxrefundmustbefiledafterthepurchase(taxrebates);

    Accelerated depreciation allowances, which allow purchasers to writeoff the cost ofdepreciationofqualifyingequipmentmorerapidlythanstandardequipment,thuseffectivelyreducingtheaftertaxtotalcostoftheequipment;

    Tax or customs duty exemptions

    which

    relieve

    purchasers

    from

    paying

    customs

    duties

    or

    importtaxesonqualifying importedequipmentorexcisetaxonconsumptionorpurchaseofspecifiedproducts,e.g.highlyefficientappliances.

    TheWorldEconomicForumnotesthatoneadvantageoftax incentivesovergrants, isthattheyaremore likelytoencouragegreaterscaleofprojectsastheyareusuallygrantedovera longertimeperiodanddonothavealimitedbudgetattached(WEF2011,pp.25).

    GrantsThrough grant schemes, an amount of money that covers all or part of the energy efficiencyinvestment is provided to individuals or businesses. The award of a grant may be for specific

    piecesof

    energy

    efficient

    equipment

    (on

    atechnology

    list

    for

    example)

    or

    may

    be

    tied

    to

    energy

    performance,andmaybesetatafixedamountorasashareoftheinvestmentmade.Grantscanbefundedthroughenergyefficiencyagencies,dedicatedfundsorpublicbanks.

    Grants can be effective in encouraging people to undertake investment in energy efficiencymeasures that they might not otherwise do. But in order to actually influence investmentdecisions,theyneedtocoverasignificantshareofthetotalinvestmentcosts.Thereforegrantsinenergy efficiency programmes have tended to favour less ambitious measures where theinvestmentcostsarelower.

    Grant schemes are costly to public budgets compared to other forms of finance such as lowinterestloans.Fromanadministrativepointofview,programmerunningcostscanbelowerfor

    grantsschemes,

    compared

    to

    loan

    schemes,

    because

    no

    payback

    needs

    to

    be

    administered.

    Comparedtotaxincentives,grantsmightbeequallycostlyinthattheamountssubsidisedmaybethe same. However, grants require outlay of the public budget, while tax incentives impactrevenues. Costs for grants may, however, be easier to track and control as they will have acertainbudget limit,whereastax incentivesaredifficultto limittoacertainamountofrevenueforgoneandtheamountsmayonlycometolightattheendofthefiscalyear.Taxincentivesmaybemoresuitable for larger investments,asthesubsidy is likelytorepresentasmallershareof

    11Seeformoreinformation(inFrench):http://www.minfin.fgov.be/portail2/fr/themes/dwelling/energysaving/index.htm

    12Seeformoreinformation:http://webarchive.nationalarchives.gov.uk/+/http://www.hm

    treasury.gov.uk/budget/budget_2000/press_notices/bud_bud00_pressenergy.cfm

  • 7/28/2019 Mobilising Investment EE FINAL

    22/156

    Mobilisinginvestmentinenergyefficiency OECD/IEA2012Economicinstrumentsforlowenergybuildings

    Page|20

    theoverallinvestmentbecauseitislimitedtothetaxratenormallypaid.13

    Freeriding,i.e.theshareofpeoplethatwouldalsohaveinvestedintheabsenceoftheincentive,is an important issue for both grants and tax incentives. Therefore eligibility criteria for botheconomicinstrumentsshouldbeambitioustoensurethatthesubsidytargetsadvancedproducts

    andreal

    energy

    efficiency

    improvements.

    LoanprogrammesFinancemaybeneededtocovertheupfrontcostsofmeasurestoimproveenergyefficiency.Forambitious measures thatsignificantly improve the energy performance of a building, industrialfacility or other assets, the investment may be considerable and require debt financing. Debtfinancing,suchasloans,seemstobeparticularlyadaptedtothecharacteristicsofcomprehensiveenergy efficiency investments, which can have high upfront costs and lead to monthly savingsthatmaybeusedtoservicethedebt.

    Anotheradvantageof loan financing isthat it isawellestablishedwayof financingupgradeor

    constructionmeasures

    and

    that

    expenditures

    for

    energy

    efficiency

    investments

    may

    piggy

    back

    on loan financing for othergeneral investments.However there areseveralbarriers to privatedebtfinanceforenergyefficiency improvements,whichmeansthatpublicpolicyandfundsareneededtointerveneinthemarket.

    From the investors perspective, there may a number of reasons for reluctance to take onincreaseddebtto financeenergyefficiencymeasures.Thesemay includeageneralaversion todebt, a lack of interest in undertaking investment in energy efficiency measures or a lack ofconfidence that investments will lead to the estimated savings. Another barrier is that a largeinvestmentin,forexample,adeepretrofit,mayrequireasubstantialloanoveralongperiodoftime.Howeveriftheassetissoldintheshortormediumterm,i.e.beforematurityofthatloan,theinitialinvestorwillberesponsibleforfullrepaymentoftheloanwithoutanyguaranteethat

    theresale

    value

    of

    the

    property

    or

    business

    will

    reflect

    the

    energy

    efficiency

    investment.

    Fromthelendersperspective,despitetheslowlybutsurelyincreasingamountofinformationon

    theeffectivenessofenergyefficiencyinvestments,privatelendersstilldonottranslatethelowerrisksandhigherreturnsofgreeninvestmentsinto lowerinterestrates(Katsetal.,2011pp.2021).Sincetherepaymentisbasedonprojectedenergysavingsratherthanassetstosecuritisetheloan, financial institutions may perceive energy efficiency loans as higher risk. Additionally,industrialfacilitiesorbuildingsoftenalreadyhaveaprimaryloanattachedforwhichthebuildingisusedascollateral.Acquiringasecond loan for thesamebuildingoranextensionto the firstloan can be complicated, but may be possible especially when much of the original loan hasalready been repaid or when the upgrade positively affects the business or property value.Evidenceonmarketpremiumsforenergyefficiency investmentsarediscussed inmoredetail inthesectiononinstitutionalinvestingandprivateinvestmentfundsinthethirdpartofthereport.

    Variousformsofeconomic instrumentsareused inenergyefficiencypolicytosupportthedebtfinance or loans market for energy efficiency measures. Governments can support loans byinterveninginthemarket,eitherdirectlywithcreditlinestofinancialinstitutionsatconcessionalormarketratesorprovidingloansdirectlytoinvestors,orindirectlythroughpoliciesthatenablefinancing arrangements through third parties (described under Other structured finance). Inbothcases taking loans forenergyefficiencybecomesmoreattractive topotential investorsas

    13 This depends on the rate of tax normally paid; for industry, corporate tax varies considerably between countries. In

    countrieswherecorporatetaxisloworthereistaxreliefondepreciationofequipmentinanycase,thesubsidyforenergy

    efficiencymeasures

    is

    likely

    to

    be

    alow

    share

    of

    the

    investment.

  • 7/28/2019 Mobilising Investment EE FINAL

    23/156

    OECD/IEA2012 MobilisinginvestmentinenergyefficiencyEconomicinstrumentsforlowenergybuildings

    Page|21

    wellastolocalfinancialinstitutions.

    Closecooperationwithprivatefinancialinstitutionswithregardtoprogrammeimplementationis very important for several reasons. Governments can use the existing, often highlydecentralised, structures of private financial institutions to engage directly with potential

    investors.

    Also

    making

    use

    of

    their

    financial

    expertise

    and

    methods

    of

    client

    advice

    andassessmentisveryimportant.Inordertofamiliarisefinancialinstitutionswiththespecifications

    oftheloanprogrammes, includingtechnicalknowhowonenergyefficiencyaswellaseligibilitycriteria,specialisedtrainingandtechnicalassistanceisnecessary.Thisisalsoimportanttoenablethe private financial sector in the long term to serve this market segment without furthergovernmentengagement.

    Concessionalloans

    Concessional loansarewhensubsidiesareprovidedto reduce thecostof loans to investors inenergyefficiencymeasures.Thereareseveralwaysthiscanbedone.Publicfundsmaybeusedto

    fundthe

    whole

    loan

    amount

    through

    credit

    lines

    to

    commercial

    financial

    institutions

    that

    are

    thenonlentatpreferentialtopotentialinvestors.Financialinstitutionscanfindthismechanismattractive,astheydonotneedtousetheirownfunds,anditcanencouragethemtoengage innew(energyefficiency) lendingactivities.This isespeciallyattractive intimeswhere liquidity isconstrained,i.e.whenitisdifficultorexpensivetogetrefinancingonthefinancialmarkets.

    Alternatively,public fundscansubsidiseonlythe interestratesand/orcanprovidepartialdebtrelief for energy efficiency loans. The remaining loan amount is provided by fully participatingfinancialinstitutionsorthirdparties.Theinterestratesubsidymaybepassedoninfulloronlyinparttotheborrowers.Subsidisedinterestratescanbeofgreatinteresttopotentialinvestors,asthey can significantly cut financing costs depending on how high is the subsidy. However, incontrast to credit lines, subsidised interest rates may not be enough to encourage financialinstitutionstoactivelyseekcustomersforloansforenergyefficiencymeasures,asthereisstillariskinvolvedwiththeloanthatmaybeperceivedashighcomparedtoloansinareasthebankismorefamiliar.

    GuaranteesSomeofthebarrierstoenergyefficiencyfinancerelatenottoa lackofavailabilityoffundsbutrathertotheperceptionofrisk.Risksharingarrangements inthe formof loanguaranteesthatreducetheperceived risksassociatedwith the investmentcan increase the leverageofprivatedebtfinanceandinvolvenewactorsinfinancinginvestmentsinenergyefficiency.

    Loanguarantees

    are

    when

    public

    funds

    provide

    default

    guarantees

    for

    loans

    to

    energy

    efficiency

    projects.Therisksharingfacilitycomprisesapublicpartnerthatwillguaranteeallorsomepartof the risk, a local financial institution that provides loans and energy efficiency projectdevelopers in need of project finance (IEA, 2011a). Guarantees can be given for specific largescale projects with a risk sharing agreement adapted to the specific project design or to aportfolio of similar projects, i.e. all loans to a certain class of borrowers (portfolio guarantee).Alternatively,a loan lossreserve fundcanbesetuptopay (fullyorpartially) for loandefaults.Suchafundcanalsoserveasatemporalbuffer,whenthere isnottheriskofaclientsdefault,

    but payments are simply delayed (Rezessy and Bertoldi, 2010). Risk guarantee funds typicallyhaveasizeof210%oftheoverallloanportfolio(Katsetal.,2011pp.37).

    Losses

    can

    be

    taken

    over

    fully

    or

    partially

    by

    the

    public

    institution.

    The

    risk

    remaining

    with

    the

    privatebankwilldeterminebyhowmuchtheriskpremiumontheloancanbedecreased.There

  • 7/28/2019 Mobilising Investment EE FINAL

    24/156

    Mobilisinginvestmentinenergyefficiency OECD/IEA2012Economicinstrumentsforlowenergybuildings

    Page|22

    existanumberofdifferentwaystosharetheriskbetweenthepublicinstitutionandtheprivatebank(IEA,2011a):

    Equalrisksharing(paripassu):eachpartnertakesonanequalshareoftheloss.

    Prorataguarantee:thelossissharedaccordingtoapredefinedpercentagebetweenthe

    partners;atypical

    share

    of

    the

    public

    party

    can

    lie

    between

    50%

    and

    80%.

    Firstlossguarantee:all lossesuptoapredeterminedmaximumamountwillbecoveredbythepublicinstitution,whiletheprivatebankpaysforlossesabovethisamount.

    Secondloss guarantee: all losses exceeding a predefined amount are paid for by thepublic institution.Potential lossesoftheprivate institutionarethuscappedandcannot

    exceedthedeterminedamount.14

    OtherstructuredfinanceOther financial instruments do not require public funds directly but enable financingarrangements to facilitate third party finance for projectbased loans (loan enhancements).

    Governments

    can

    ensure

    that

    the

    legislative

    framework

    is

    in

    place

    to

    enable

    various

    loan

    repaymentmodesandnewbusinessmodelstofinanceenergyefficiencymeasures.

    Thisencouragesprivate finance in themarket forenergyefficiency.Wegroupseveraloftheseinstrumentstogetheras:

    Energyprovideronbillfinancing(tariffsandloans)

    Propertyassessedcleanenergy(PACE)

    Energyperformancecontracting

    Onbillfinancearrangementsthroughenergyproviderstietherepaymentsofloanstopaymentofexistingutilitybills.Policyisfrequentlyrequiredtoenableenergyproviderstoprovidefinance

    to

    customers

    and

    to

    develop

    the

    legal

    arrangements

    required

    to

    sort

    out

    seniority

    of

    payments,

    andliabilityfornonpaymentissues.

    The investor avoids putting up the full amount of finance initially for the upfront costs of theenergyefficiencymeasuresbutpaysthecostsaspartofregularutilitybillpaymentsovertime.The loan can, in some cases, be transferred with ownership of the business or property, thusenablinglongerpaybackperiodsofupto20years.

    Onbillfinancecanassistinovercomingthemarketfailure,splitincentives,thatoftenoccursasabarrier to investment in more ambitious and/or costly energy efficiency measures over longperiods because the investor may not recoup the benefit of his investment. Firstly, tying theamountofrepaymentstotheenergysavedgivesasenseofsecurityandaperceivedavoidanceofupfront costs. Secondly, attaching repayment of the loan to the asset rather than the initialinvestor

    means

    that

    there

    can

    be

    an

    incentive

    to

    undertake

    longer

    term

    finance

    and

    therefore

    moreambitionsmeasures,even ifhewishestosellthebusinessorpropertybeforethe loan ismatured. Energyproviders are wellpositioned to provide onbill finance since they have aregular payment method in place. They also have a large and broad commercial and privatecustomerbasethatcanbetargetedforenergyefficiencyimprovements.

    Property assessed clean energy (PACE) schemes represent a special kind of onbill financingarrangement where the local government institutions that administer property taxes provideloansforenergyefficiencyinvestments.Thelocalpublicinstitutionprovidesaloantotheowner,which is repaidviaanassessment (orsurcharge)on thepropertytax.PACEcan inprinciplebe

    14These

    are

    described

    in

    detail

    in

    another

    IEA

    report

    PublicPrivatePartnershipsforEnergyefficiencyFinance

    (IEA

    2011).

  • 7/28/2019 Mobilising Investment EE FINAL

    25/156

    OECD/IEA2012 MobilisinginvestmentinenergyefficiencyEconomicinstrumentsforlowenergybuildings

    Page|23

    appliedtotheresidentialandthecommercialsector,butonlybuildingownerscanmakeuseofit(RezessyandBertoldi,2010ppp. 3839).Thesplitincentivebetweenownersandtenantscanbeovercome incaseswherepropertytaxpaymentsarepassedthroughtotenants,which isoftenpossibleforcommercialorindustrialtenants(DellaCroce,KaminkerandStewart,2011ppp. 4344).

    Energy performance contracting (EPC) presents another way of organising energy efficiencyfinance. It involvesan EnergyService Company (ESCO)whichcanprovideavarietyofservices,includingfinanceinsomecases,butmostimportantlywillguaranteeenergysavingsofacertainamount.TheremunerationoftheESCOdependsontheachievementoftheguaranteedsavings.As the guarantor of the savings, the ESCO remains involved in measuring and verifying thesavingsduringthedebtrepaymentperiod.ESCOsmayalsoprovideother formsofcontracting,suchaschauffage,firstout,BuiltOwnOperateTransferorleasingcontracts(BertoldiandRezessy,2005).ESCOsandenergyperformancecontractingaremainlyfoundinthepublicsectorbutalsosomeexamplesexistintheindustrialandcommercialbuildingssectors.

    ManygovernmentsareinterestedinonbillfinancingmechanismsandESCObusinessmodelsfor

    theirability

    to

    address

    some

    of

    the

    key

    barriers

    to

    energy

    efficiency

    finance.

    However,

    they

    can

    be complex and costly to set up and there have been varying levels of success in theirimplementationtodate.

    WhitecertificatesandobligationschemesAwhitecertificateisadocumentissuedbyanauthorisedbodycertifyingthataspecifiedamountof energy savings has been achieved. Markets for white certificates can be set up as part ofenergysupplierobligationschemes.Thecertificatescanbeusedbythecompanywhohassavedtheenergyforcompliancewiththeirenergysavingtargetsorcanbetradedwithotherfirms in

    thesameobligationscheme.

    Obligation

    schemes

    that

    require

    energy

    providers

    to

    engage

    in

    energysaving

    activities

    are

    a

    growing phenomenon worldwide. Obligation schemes as such can be considered a regulatoryinstrument, as energy providers are obliged by law to engage in energy saving activities withregardtotheirclients(UNEP,2007ppp. 3233).

    Underobligationschemes,energyprovidersmayachievetherequiredenergysavingsviaarangeof instruments implemented by themselves or through subcontractors, these may include:information, communication, advice and assistance as well as offering customers financialincentives, offering the replacement of equipment which may be acquired through bulkprocurement or even the implementation of comprehensive measures (Heffner, DuPont andRybka,2012).Thescopeofenergyprovidersincludedintheschemediffersbycountryinsomecases only electricity suppliers are obligated whereas in others, the scope is much wider andincludesheatingfuelandtransportfuelproviders.

    Some obligation schemes enable energy providers to provide some form of energy efficiencyfinance and to eventually recover the related costs via the energy bills (onbill finance asdescribedabove)orthroughspecificusercharges(publicbenefitcharges).Thismayincludethepossibilityforenergyproviderstotakeondebt.Throughtheobligationscheme,energysuppliersmaybemotivatedtoprovideanimportantsourceoffinanceforinvestmentsinenergyefficiencytocustomersorprovideincentivestoencourageprivateinvestmentinenergyefficiency.

    Tradingofwhitecertificatesencouragessomeflexibilityinthemarketandeconomicefficiencysothat energyproviders with lower costoptions carry out moreenergy efficiencymeasures thanthosewithhighercosts.Whitecertificateschemescanalsoenableotheractorsthantheobliged

    partiesto

    engage

    in

    energy

    efficiency

    investments

    as

    the

    white

    certificates

    provide

    aform

    of

  • 7/28/2019 Mobilising Investment EE FINAL

    26/156

    Mobilisinginvestmentinenergyefficiency OECD/IEA2012Economicinstrumentsforlowenergybuildings

    Page|24

    (additional) remuneration to these investors. This additional revenue can be an incentive toinvest in the firstplace (asthepaybackperiodcanbeshortened toanacceptable level)or tomakeagreaterinvestment(whilekeepingthepaybackperiodconstant).

    CarbonmarketsCarbonmarketscanprovideasourceoffundsforenergyefficiencymeasures.Therevenuesfromemissions trading schemes can be used to fund energy efficiency measures. Alternatively,greenhouse gas (GHG) emission reduction projects, i.e. energy efficiency measures, in need offundscanbematchedwith investorsthatareobligedtofinanceabatementactivitiesundertheUNFCCCKyotoprotocol.15 In this latter case, there isno lending or granting of funds involved;instead, emission reductions are purchased. Carbon markets thus present a way of leveragingprivate and public funds for energy efficiency measures for the purpose of reducing GHGemissions(RezessyandBertoldi,2010).

    Twogeneraltypesofmarketmechanismshavebeensetupp. ThefirstisGHGemissionstradingschemes, both at the national or regional level, to fulfil local climate objectives, and

    internationallyunder

    the

    UNFCCC

    Kyoto

    Protocol.

    Companies

    covered

    by

    the

    emissions

    trading

    schemesarerequiredtoholdsufficientallowancesfortheGHGemissionstheyproduce.Theseallowancescanbetradedwithothercompanies inthescheme.Energyefficiencymeasurescan

    be an important lowcost way for companies to reduce their emissions. If allowances areauctioned,therevenuesareaccruedbythetreasuryandcanberingfencedforenergyefficiencymeasures.

    The second type of mechanism is crediting schemes, such as the Kyoto Protocols CleanDevelopment Mechanism (CDM) and Joint Implementation (JI). These allow obliged parties tofinance GHG emission reduction activities outside their territories. Through a CDM project, an

    obligedpartycanfinanceabatementactivitiesindevelopingcountries,whilethroughJIprojects,

    an

    obliged

    party

    can

    finance

    abatement

    activities

    in

    another

    country

    equally

    obliged

    under

    the

    Protocol. In both types of schemes GHG emissions reductions in industrial sectors and energyprovidershavemainlybeentargeted.

    PublicprocurementandinfrastructureinvestmentThepublicsectorholdssignificantpotentialtoimproveenergyefficiencybydeployingadvancedtechnologies and/or developing the market for improved energy efficiency. The small size ofenergy efficiency projects is a significant barrier facing energy efficiency measures. The publicsectorisanimportantmarket,representingbetween10and20%ofnationalGDP,thatcanassistindevelopingthemarketforenergyefficiencyproductsandservicesthroughitsnotinsignificantpurchasingpower(Singhetal.,2010).Inmanycountriesfacilitieswithacommonfunctionsuch

    as

    schools

    and

    hospitals

    offer

    opportunities

    to

    bundle

    energy

    efficiency

    projects,

    attracting

    largerscale financeand new businesses to theenergyefficiencymarket. Thepublicsectorcanalsoplaya leadershiprole indemonstratingthepotentialofenergyefficiencytoreduceenergyconsumptionandshowcasingnewtechnologiesandenergymanagement.The largepurchasingpowerofthepublicsectorcanbeacatalystfordevelopingtheenergyefficiencymarket(Singhetal.,2010)

    However, in many countries, barriers remain to public sector investment in energy efficiency.Rules governing the public procurement of energy savings performance contracts (ESPCs) and

    15UnitedNationsFrameworkConventiononClimateChangeKyotoProtocolavailableat

    http://unfccc.int/kyoto_protocol/mechanisms/items/1673.php

  • 7/28/2019 Mobilising Investment EE FINAL

    27/156

    OECD/IEA2012 MobilisinginvestmentinenergyefficiencyEconomicinstrumentsforlowenergybuildings

    Page|25

    energyefficient equipment can overcome many of these barriers. Governments have useddifferentapproachestoencouragetheprocurementofenergyefficiencyservicesandproducts,including the creation of dedicated agencies to the procurement of energy efficiencyrelatedservices, establishing model contracts, creation of public energy service providers to avoidprocurementrelatedissues(Singhetal.,2010;IEA,2011a).Anotherwayistorequirethatagiven

    energyperformance

    improvement

    is

    achieved

    by

    the

    public

    sector

    and

    ensure

    that

    there

    are

    no

    institutionalormarketbarrierstoimplementingtherequirement.

    EnergyefficiencyR&DsupportReducingenergyconsumptionrequiresnotonly incremental improvements intechnologiesbutalso breakthrough developments. There are three welldocumented steps in technologicalchange invention, innovation, and diffusion or adoption (Schumpeter, 1942). The economicinstrumentsforenergyefficiencydescribedabovefocusonimprovingthepricesignaltosupportthis third step by encouraging consumers and businesses to invest in energy efficiency.Governments also need to ensure sufficient longterm research and development (R&D) to

    provideincentives

    for

    supply

    driven

    technological

    change.

    Thejustification for using public funds to invest in R&D is explained by two market failuresfirstly,therearepositiveexternalities,where thebenefitsof theR&Darenot recoupedby the

    investor, in the form of a time lag between the moment of investment and the benefits fromR&D to the company and the public. There are also spillover effects where other companiesbenefitfromtheR&Dofthecompanywhoinitiallyinvestedinatechnology.Secondly,ifenergypricesarenothighthereislit