migration, knowledge diffusion and the comparative...

57
Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative Advantage of Nations * Dany Bahar (IADB, Brookings and Harvard CID) Hillel Rapoport (Paris School of Economics and Bar Ilan University) September 20, 2014 [Download Newest Version] Keywords: migration, knowledge, comparative advantage, exports JEL Classification Numbers: F14, F22, F62, O33, D83 This paper benefited from helpful comments at various stages from Martin Abel, Sam Asher, Sebastian Bustos, Michael Clemens, Michele Coscia, Ricardo Hausmann, Elhanan Helpman, Juan Ariel Jimenez, Bill Kerr, Michael Kremer, Anna Maria Mayda, Frank Neffke, Paul Novosad, Nathan Nunn, Rodrigo Wagner, Muhammed Yildirim, Andres Zahler and the participants of the 7th International Conference on Migration and Development at Oxford University as well as participants at numerous seminars in Harvard Economics Department, Harvard Kennedy School, Georgetown University Economics Department, the Hebrew Uni- versity of Jerusalem and Bar Ilan University. All errors are our own. Corresponding Author: [email protected] 1

Upload: others

Post on 20-Mar-2020

4 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative ...sites.bu.edu/neudc/files/2014/10/paper_108.pdf · Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative Advantage of Nations

Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the

Comparative Advantage of Nations∗

Dany Bahar†(IADB, Brookings and Harvard CID)

Hillel Rapoport (Paris School of Economics and Bar Ilan University)

September 20, 2014

[Download Newest Version]

Keywords: migration, knowledge, comparative advantage, exports

JEL Classification Numbers: F14, F22, F62, O33, D83

∗This paper benefited from helpful comments at various stages from Martin Abel, SamAsher, Sebastian Bustos, Michael Clemens, Michele Coscia, Ricardo Hausmann, ElhananHelpman, Juan Ariel Jimenez, Bill Kerr, Michael Kremer, Anna Maria Mayda, Frank Neffke,Paul Novosad, Nathan Nunn, Rodrigo Wagner, Muhammed Yildirim, Andres Zahler and theparticipants of the 7th International Conference on Migration and Development at OxfordUniversity as well as participants at numerous seminars in Harvard Economics Department,Harvard Kennedy School, Georgetown University Economics Department, the Hebrew Uni-versity of Jerusalem and Bar Ilan University. All errors are our own.

†Corresponding Author: [email protected]

1

Page 2: Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative ...sites.bu.edu/neudc/files/2014/10/paper_108.pdf · Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative Advantage of Nations

Abstract

To what extent are migrants a source of evolution of the comparative

advantage of both their sending and receiving countries? We study the

drivers of knowledge diffusion by looking at the dynamics of the export

basket of countries. The main finding is that migration, and particularly

skilled immigration, is a strong and robust driver of productive knowl-

edge diffusion. In terms of their ability to induce exports, we find that a

twofold increase of the migration stock, which amounts to 65,000 people

for the average country, is associated with a 60% increase in the likeli-

hood of adding a new product to a country’s export basket in the next

ten year period. We also find that, in terms of expanding the export

basket of countries, a migrant is worth about US $90,000 of foreign direct

investment. For skilled migrants these same figures are, on average, about

20,000 people and US $250,000. Our identification strategy is based on

instrumenting for migration stocks using estimates from a gravity model

based on bilateral exogenous geographic, cultural and historic variables,

inspired by Frankel and Romer (1999).

2

Page 3: Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative ...sites.bu.edu/neudc/files/2014/10/paper_108.pdf · Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative Advantage of Nations

1 Introduction

Franschhoek valley, a small town in the Western Cape province of South Africa,

is known today for its beautiful scenery and for its high-quality wineries. The

town was founded in the late 17th century by French Huguenot refugees, who

settled there after being expelled from France following King Louis XIV elim-

ination of the Edict of Nantes. As of today, the wineries in Franschhoek are

among the main producers of South African wine exports. Is this story part

of a much larger pattern that can be identified in the data?1 In this paper we

explore the role of migrants in developing the comparative advantage of both

their sending and receiving countries.

Ricardian models of trade usually assume as given the exogenous productiv-

ity parameters that define the export basket of countries which are generated

in equilibrium. A large part of the literature has focused on understanding

the characteristics of this equilibrium and the mechanisms through which it is

conceived (e.g. Eaton and Kortum 2002, Costinot et. al. 2011). However, a

burgeoning literature deals with understanding the evolution of these produc-

tivity parameters, and consequently, of the actual export baskets of countries

(e.g. Hausmann and Klinger 2007; Hausmann et. al. 2014). This paper con-

tributes to this literature by documenting industry-specific productivity shifts

as explained by the variation in international factors movement with particular

focus on migration. We study productivity by exploiting changes in the export

baskets of countries. The key assumption is that, after controlling for product-

specific global demand, firms in a country will be able to export a good only

after they have become productive enough to compete in global markets (see

Bahar et. al. 2014). Of all international factors flows, the results point to

migration as the strongest of those drivers. We find that migrants, and even

more so, skilled immigrants, can explain variation in good-specific productivity

as measured by the ability of countries to export those goods, for products that

are intensively exported in the migrants’ home/destination countries. In partic-

ular we find that, on average, a twofold increase in the stock of migrants, which

amounts to about 65,000 people for the average country, is associated with a

60% increase in the likelihood of exporting a new product. The same figure for

skilled migrants is reduced to about 20,000 people, on average. Also, in terms of

expanding the export basket of countries, a migrant is worth over US $90,000 of

1Hornung (2014) studies the Huguenot migration to Prussia and its effect on local produc-tivity with historical data.

3

Page 4: Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative ...sites.bu.edu/neudc/files/2014/10/paper_108.pdf · Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative Advantage of Nations

foreign direct investment (FDI), while a skilled migrant is worth over $250,000.

By focusing on industry-specific productivity dynamics, this paper con-

tributes to previous literature that focuses on the link between international

factor flows and changes in aggregate productivity (e.g. Coe and Helpman

1993; Coe et. al. 2009; Aitken and Harrison 1999, Javorcik 2004, Andersen

and Dalgaard 2011).

In addition, another contribution of this work is that it focuses on migra-

tion, while at the same time controlling for other factor flows such as trade

and FDI. The focus on migrants relates to tacit knowledge as a main input for

productivity increases (knowledge, either through learning or experience, allows

economic agents to do more with the same resources). Bahar et. al. (2014)

suggest that the appearance of new industries in the export basket of countries

can be partly explained by the local character of knowledge diffusion. That is,

productivity inducing knowledge follows a highly geographically localized dif-

fusion pattern, which is attributed to its "tacitness" (e.g. Jaffe, Trajtenberg

and Henderson 1993; Bottazi and Peri 2003; Keller 2002; Keller 2004). There-

fore, as suggested by Kenneth Arrow (1969), the transmission of this tacit or

non-codifiable knowledge relies on human minds rather than on written words.

Thus, if tacit knowledge can induce sector-specific productivity as measured by

exports, then migrants, who are naturally carriers of tacit knowledge, would

shape the comparative advantage of their sending and/or receiving countries.

This is precisely what this paper documents.

To do this, we undertake an empirical exercise that looks at how migration

figures correlate with a country’s extensive and intensive margin of trade. We

use new appearances of products in a country’s export basket to measure the

extensive margin, while the intensive margin refers to the future annual growth

rate of a product that is already exported by a country. For this purpose we put

together different publicly available data sources that include data on bilateral

trade, FDI and migration stock figures. From it, we construct a sample that

includes for each country, product and year total exports to the rest of the world.

The sample also includes total stocks of trade, FDI and migration (disaggregated

in immigrants and emigrants) to or from partner countries.

The empirical analysis takes into consideration a number of other alternative

explanations, unrelated to knowledge transmission channels, on how migration

could be associated to good-specific productivity increases.

First, even if our focus is on migrants, omitted variable bias could arise if we

exclude other correlated flows such as FDI and trade that could be driving the

4

Page 5: Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative ...sites.bu.edu/neudc/files/2014/10/paper_108.pdf · Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative Advantage of Nations

results through channels others than the diffusion of tacit knowledge. Therefore,

all of our specifications control for all international factor flows.

Second, if a given country c receives migrants from countries exporters of

a given product p, then there could be a local shift in demand for product p,

given the plausible shift in aggregate preferences. This could result in a shift in

local preferences, that could be simultaneously occurring in all other countries

that also received the same type of migrants. This shift in preferences could

result in a shift of global demand, which could be supplied by exports from the

countries under consideration to the rest of the world.2 To rule out this possible

explanation, we control for global demand of each good by adding product-year

fixed effects. We also add country-year fixed effects which would control for all

country level time variant characteristics that would make a given country more

likely to export and receive migrants at the same time.

Third, migrant networks could generate lower transaction costs for bilateral

trade in specific goods, thus inducing bilateral exports between the sending and

receiving country of the migrants (i.e. Gould 1996; Rauch and Trindade 2012;

Kugler and Rapoport 2007; Aubry et. al. 2012). Therefore, in order to deal

with this possibility, we calculate all the specifications using an alteration of the

dependent variable, which measures exports to the rest of the world excluding

flows to countries where migrants are in or from. In this case, the increase in

exports cannot be explained by its bilateral component.

Fourth, the changes in the extensive and the intensive margin are explained

by an unobserved historical trend that results in new or more exports of partic-

ular goods, independently of where migrants come from or go to. To rule out

this possibility, we perform a “placebo” test, in which we find that the increases

in exports cannot be explained in countries that receive or send migrants to

other countries that do not export such product.

Finally, even after including these controls, endogeneity concerns remain.

For instance, migrants can decide to relocate to countries with an ex-ante un-

derstanding of the industries that will flourish in that other location. To deal

with all endogeneity concerns, we use the instrument for migration stocks us-

ing estimates from a bilateral gravity model based on geographic, cultural and

historic bilateral variables between the sending and receiving countries of the

migrants, following Frankel and Romer (1999). To improve the fit between

the estimated and actual values we estimate the gravity model using a poisson

2Linder (1961) suggests, in this case, country c will become a trade partner of the homecountries of the migrants.

5

Page 6: Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative ...sites.bu.edu/neudc/files/2014/10/paper_108.pdf · Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative Advantage of Nations

pseudo maximum likelihood estimator. The instruments provide an exogenous

variation to the number of migrants in and from partner countries. Further-

more, for this methodology, we use the reconstructed dependent variable which

excludes exports to countries where migrants are in or from, thus reducing all

left endogeneity concerns.

The body of the paper discusses in detail all the data collection, the empir-

ical strategies and present all the results with their correspondent explanation.

The paper is divided as follows: the next section describes the data and the

construction of the sample. Section 3 details the empirical strategy and the

specifications to be estimated. Section 4 presents the main results, and Section

5 discusses them. Section 6 concludes.

2 Data and Sample

Bilateral migration data comes from Docquier et. al. (2010). The dataset con-

sists of total bilateral working age (25 to 65 years old) foreign born individuals

in 1990 and 2000. The data provide figures for skilled and non-skilled migrants

at the bilateral level as well. Skilled migrants are considered to have completed

some tertiary education at the time of the census. Figures 1 and 2 represent

the migration data in year 2000.

[Figure 1 about here.]

[Figure 2 about here.]

Bilateral FDI stocks (positions) are from the OECD International Direct

Investment Statistics (2012). It tracks FDI from and to OECD members since

1985 until 2009. Using this data we compute 10-year stocks of capital flows for

each country in 1990 and 20003. Negative FDI stocks are treated as zero4.

Bilateral trade data comes from Hausmann et. al. 2011, based on the

UN Comtrade data from 1984 to 2010. The dataset uses the 4-digit Standard

Industry Trade Classification (SITC) to classify products. Thus, the list of

products is fairly disaggregated. For instance, products in this classification

are "Knitted/Crocheted Fabrics Elastic Or Rubberized” (SITC code 6553), or

"Electrical Measuring, Checking, Analyzing Instruments" (SITC code 8748).

3For 1990 we use the stock from 1985 to 1990 due to limitations of the data.4This follows the same methodology suggested by Aubry et. al. (2012). Only 1.7% of the

original dataset is affected by this.

6

Page 7: Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative ...sites.bu.edu/neudc/files/2014/10/paper_108.pdf · Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative Advantage of Nations

The words product, good and industry interchangeably referring to the same

concept throughout the paper. We use this trade dataset to construct two

variables: first, total exports per product per country to the rest of the world,

to be used to compute the dependent variable in the empirical specifications;

and second, we also compute 10-year stocks for bilateral trade (imports plus

exports) to be used as an independent variable. Both the 10-year Trade and

FDI stocks are deflated using the US GDP deflator (base year 2000) from the

World Development Indicators (WDI) by the World Bank. Other information

at the country level is also taken from the WDI.

Finally, we also incorporate variables from the GeoDist dataset (Mayer and

Zignago 2011) from CEPII on bilateral relationships such as distance, common

colonizer, colony-colonizer relationship, and common language, to construct the

instrumental variables. We also include data from The World Religion Dataset

for the same purpose (Zeev and Henderson, 2014).

The final sample consists of 135 countries and 781 products.5 We define two

10-year periods for the analysis due to the limitations imposed by the bilateral

migration data, which are 1990-2000 and 2000-2010.

The summary statistics for the variables to be used in the analysis are in

Table 1. Panel A presents the summary statistics for the extensive margin

sample (i.e. for all observations of c, p and t for which RCAc,p,t = 0), while

Panel B does it for the intensive margin sample (i.e. for all observations of c, p

and t for which exportsc,p,t > 0).

[Table 1 about here.]

From Panel A we see that the unconditional probability of achieving an RCA

above 1 (starting with an RCA below 0.1 at the beginning of the period) for the

average country-product is 1.6%. Similarly, from Panel B , the average country-

product exports CAGR is about 4.8% in the data. The tables also include the

sum of immigrants and emigrants for the average country and year from and in

countries exporting a product with RCA above 1. It presents the same statistics

for aggregated FDI and trade figures in million USD, after the deflation process

explained above. Note that FDI and trade variables total inwards and outwards

stock figures.

5Following Bahar et. al. (2014), we exclude Former Soviet Union countries from the samplegiven their poor trade data in the period 1990-2000, as well as small countries with populationbelow 1 million.

7

Page 8: Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative ...sites.bu.edu/neudc/files/2014/10/paper_108.pdf · Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative Advantage of Nations

3 Empirical Strategy

3.1 Research Question and Empirical Challenges

The empirical strategy studies the relationship between international factor

flows and the dynamics in the export basket of the receiving and sending coun-

tries, with emphasis on migration. In particular, the question is: can migrants

induce product-specific productivity shifts in their sending (destination) coun-

tries, on products already intensively exported in their destination (sending)

countries?

For the sake of better understanding, we use the following hypothetical ex-

ample. Suppose there are two countries in the world: Italy (a pizza exporter),

and the US (a hamburger exporter). The analogous question then becomes

whether the presence of more Italians in the US is associated with the ability of

the US to export pizza, and, whether this same presence is also associated with

the ability of Italians to export hamburgers.

There are a number of empirical challenges in studying the relationship be-

tween productivity and international factor flows. First, all flows are highly

correlated among themselves. Moreover, several empirical studies have shown

that migration networks are an important determinant of bilateral trade flows

and bilateral FDI.6

Hence, the positive correlation between international flows of capital, goods

and labor is a matter of consideration to any study of this kind. In fact, in

the sample for year 2000, the correlation matrices between total migration,

FDI and trade across countries are all positive, and above 0.4, with the excep-

tion of migration and FDI per capita (see Tables 2 and 3). That is, countries

that receive/send more FDI tend to also receive/send more migrants and ex-

port/import in larger quantities. Hence, to deal with this challenge, the empir-

ical specification controls for all three factors simultaneously.

[Table 2 about here.]

[Table 3 about here.]

Second, we are interested exclusively in productivity shifts and not on demand-

driven exports. The nature of our dataset allow us to achieve this by introducing

6e.g. Gould, 1994; Rauch and Trindade, 2002; Combes, Lafourcade and Mayer, 2005;Iranzo and Peri 2009; Felbermayr and Jung, 2009; Tong, 2005; Kugler and Rapoport, 2007;Javorcik et. al. 2011; Aubry et. al. (2012)

8

Page 9: Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative ...sites.bu.edu/neudc/files/2014/10/paper_108.pdf · Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative Advantage of Nations

product-by-year and country-by-year fixed effects.7 This allow us to rule out

explanations such as global demand for that particular good (driven by shifts in

preferences due to the arrival of migrants), or that results are driven by a third,

uncontrolled for, variable such as an openness shock, could induce migration

and induce exports at the same time.

In addition, we are also interested in disentangling between an increase of

exports due to lower transaction costs induced by migrant networks8 and exports

due to purely productivity increases. Since we are exclusively interested in the

latter, we exclude from our dependent variable exports to the countries where

migrants are in or from.

We also want to rule out the possibility that our results are driven by un-

observable trends that are unrelated to migration. To deal with this, we run

placebo tests that use in the right hand side migrants coming from and going

to countries that do not export the product under consideration. If migrants

are an essential part of the dynamics we document, we would expect no results

from the placebo test.

Finally, our most important empirical challenge is to rule out all other

sources of endogeneity which we are unable to control for. For instance, migrants

could relocate themselves based with ex-ante knowledge on future potential of

specific sectors of growing. Thus, in order to further reduce these concerns,

we implement an instrumental variable approach based on Frankel and Romer

(1999). In particular, we construct estimated migration stocks using a gravity

model based on bilateral geographic, cultural and historic characteristics be-

tween the sending and receiving countries of these migrants. The estimated

figures are used to instrument for actual migration stocks.

Having estimated migration stocks using variables such as distance, same re-

gion, sharing borders, common colonizer, colony-colonizer relationship, common

language and same religion, among others, we create figures that are exogenous

to the ability of a country to export a particular good to the rest of the world.9

Using this exogenous variation we instrument for the actual migration stocks

and find that our results hold.

7That implies a fixed effect for each combination of product and year, as well as for eachcombination of country and year.

8Evidence suggests that migrant networks can lower transaction costs for bilateral trade(i.e. Gould 1996; Rauch and Trindade 2012; Kugler and Rapoport 2007; Aubry et. al. 2012).

9Country-by-year fixed effects in the specification would deal with concerns that coun-tries with particular languages or cultures, for instance, are more likely to gain comparativeadvantage in particular goods.

9

Page 10: Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative ...sites.bu.edu/neudc/files/2014/10/paper_108.pdf · Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative Advantage of Nations

3.2 Empirical Specification

The aim of the paper is to study the dynamics of the extensive and intensive

margin of trade (with exports to the rest of the world) given different levels of

migration stocks, controlling for FDI and trade stocks. The specification also

disentangles between immigration and emigration, and between unskilled and

skilled migrants.

Throughout the paper we will use the concept of Revealed Comparative

Advantage (RCA) by Balassa (1965), which will be used to construct export-

related variables both in the left-hand-side and right-hand-side of the specifica-

tion. RCA is defined as follows:

RCAc,p ≡

expc,p/∑p

expc,p

∑c

expc,p/∑c

∑p

expc,p

where expc,p is the exported value of product p by country c. This is a yearly

measure.

For example, in the year 2000, soybeans represented 4% of Brazil’s exports,

but accounted only for 0.2% of total world trade. Hence, Brazil’s RCA in

soybeans for that year was RCABrazil,Soybeans = 4/0.2 = 20, indicating that

soybeans are 20 times more prevalent in Brazil’s export basket than in that of

the world.

The empirical specification is defined as follows:

Yc,p,t→T = βim

c′

immigrantsc,c′ ,t × Rc′,p,t + βem

c′

emigrantsc,c′ ,t × Rc′,p,t

+ βFDI

c′

FDIc,c′,t × Rc′,p,t + βtrade

c′

tradec,c′,t × Rc′,p,t (1)

+ γControlsc,p,t + αc,t + ηp,t + εc,p,t

The definition of the dependent, or left hand side (LHS) variable, Yc,p,t→T ,

alternates according to whether the specification is studying the intensive or the

extensive margin of trade for a specific product p and country c. When studying

the extensive margin, Yc,p,t→T is 1 if country c achieved an RCA of 1 or more

in product p in the period of time between t and T (conditional on having an

RCAc,p,t = 0). That is:

Yc,p,t→T = 1 if RCAc,p,t = 0 and RCAc,p,T ≥ 1

10

Page 11: Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative ...sites.bu.edu/neudc/files/2014/10/paper_108.pdf · Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative Advantage of Nations

To avoid noise on the dependent variable, we restrict Yc,p,t→T = 1 to two

additional conditions: first, the country-product under consideration must keep

an RCA value above 1 for five years after the end of the period, year T ; and

second, the country-product under consideration must have had an RCA value

equal to 0 during all five years before the beginning of the period, year t.

When studying the intensive margin, Yc,p,t→T is the annual compound av-

erage growth rate (CAGR) in the exports value of product p, between years t

and T , conditional on having exportsc,p,t > 0.10 That is:

Yc,p,t→T =

(

exportsc,p,Texportsc,p,t

)1/T−t

− 1 if exportsc,p,t > 0

The independent variables include the following:

• The sum of the stock of immigrants and of emigrants from and to other

countries (denoted by c’) at time t, weighted by a dummy Rc,´,p,t which

is 1 if RCAc′,p,t ≥ 1. In this sense, for each country c and product p, we

include in the right hand side the total of immigrants from and emigrants

in countries that export product p with an RCA above 1, at the beginning

of the period.

• The sum of stock of FDI and stock of trade using the same weighting

structure as above.

• Product-by-year fixed effects to allow for a different constant for each

combination of year and product. This will control for global demand

for the product in that period of time. Thus, all dynamics in exports

after this control are supply-induced and therefore can be attributed to

productivity shifts.

• Country-by-year fixed effects to control for all the country level time vari-

ant characteristics that correlate with both national migration determi-

nants and aggregate productivity levels; such as income, size, institutions,

etc.

• A vector of controls of baseline variables when estimating the intensive

margin equations: the baseline level of exports for that same product;

10Appendix A.1 presents robustness tests that use log-growth as the dependent variable,

where Yc,p,t→T =ln(exportsc,p,T )−ln(exportsc,p,t)

T−t

11

Page 12: Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative ...sites.bu.edu/neudc/files/2014/10/paper_108.pdf · Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative Advantage of Nations

and the compound average growth rate (CAGR) of the export value in

the previous period, in order to control for the previous growth trend.11

• A binary variable indicating whether exportsc,p,t−1 = 0 (see footnote 11).

All level variables (migration, FDI, trade, export and RCA levels) are trans-

formed using the inverse hyperbolic sine (see MacKinnon and Magee, 1990).

This linear monotonic transformation behaves similar to a log-transformation,

except for the fact that it is defined at zero. The interpretation of regression

estimators in the from of the inverse hyperbolic sine is similar to the interpre-

tation of a log-transformed variable.12 Results are robust to using a regular

log-transformation.

4 Results

4.1 Ordinary Least Squares

Table 4 presents the OLS estimation for Specification (1). The upper panel

estimates the extensive margin (measured by the likelihood of adding a new

product to a country’s export basket) while the lower panel estimates the in-

tensive margin (measured by the annual growth in exports of a product already

in the country’s export basket). It is important to notice that the dependent

variables in both panels are computed using exports from country c to product

p to the world. The columns titled "All" indicate that the migration figures

include both skilled and unskilled, whereas the columns titled "Unskilled" and

"Skilled" includes only unskilled and skilled migration figures as independent

variables, respectively.

Note that, as explained above, the migration, FDI and trade independent

variables correspond to a sum over all partner countries c′ weighted by the

11The CAGR during 1985-1990 for the 1990-2000 period, and 1990-2000 for the 2000-2010period. In order to correct for undefined growth rates caused by zeros in the denominator, wecompute the CAGR following the above equation using exportsc,p,t + 1 for all observations.Note that when studying the intensive margin the CAGR of export value in the dependentvariable will always be defined, given that we limit the sample only to products which arebeing exported at the beginning of the period (that is, exportsc,p,t > 0). However, the CAGRin the previous period included as a control may have an undefined growth rate; therefore, tocontrol for our own correction, we also add as an additional control a binary variable indicatingwhether exportsc,p,t−1 = 0 (at the beginning of the previous period, i.e. 1985 or 1990), whichcorrespond to the observations most likely to be distorted.

12The inverse hyperbolic sine (asinh) is defined as log(yi +√

(y2i + 1)). Except for small

values of y, asinh(yi) = log(2) + log(yi). The results in this paper are robust to using aregular log-transformation (after the proper correction to allow for zero values).

12

Page 13: Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative ...sites.bu.edu/neudc/files/2014/10/paper_108.pdf · Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative Advantage of Nations

binary variable Rc,´,p,t which is 1 if RCAc′,p,t ≥ 1. That is, the dependent

variables vary at the country, year and product level.

The upper panel of Table 4 uses country-product pairs which had zero ex-

ports in the baseline years (1990 and 2000), which corresponds to 83,100 obser-

vations (thus, baseline variables are not included because lack of variation).

[Table 4 about here.]

The results in column 1 of Panel A indicate that a country with 10% in-

crease in its stock of total migrants –immigrants from plus emigrants to nations

exporters of product p– is associated with an increase from 1.6% to 1.81% in

the unconditional probability of exporting product p with an RCA above 1 in

the next ten years. This corresponds to a 1.3% increase. This means, based on

the average country figure in the sample, that about 65,000 more migrants from

and in countries exporters of p is associated with an increase in the likelihood

of exporting p of 13%.

Column 2 shows a slightly smaller coefficient for unskilled migration while

Column 4 shows a slightly larger one. Note also the mean and standard deviation

values for skilled migrants in the sample is considerably lower (see Table 1).

Thus, the estimator in Column 4 indicates that a twofold increase in the stock

of skilled migrants (about 15,000 individuals on average) from and to countries

exporters of p is associated with approximately a 15% increase in the likelihood

of adding p to a country’s export basket.

The trade regressor has a negative estimated coefficient across all specifi-

cations. This intuitively means that a country is less likely to start exporting

product p the more it trades with countries that export p. This makes sense,

given that countries will tend to trade with other countries that have a comple-

mentary export basket.

The estimators for the FDI variable are positive though without statisti-

cal significance. However, the results suggest that, in terms of their ability

of expanding a country’s export basket, an unskilled migrant is worth USD

$16,519.46 of FDI (p-value=0.061), while a skilled migrant is worth USD $82,352.52

(p-value =0.127, thus not significant), using the estimators from Table 4.13

Columns 3 and 5 disentangle between immigration and emigration. The

above documented partial correlations hold for both across the sending and

13To compute this calculate βM

βFDI

FDI

Migrants; where βM is the estimator for migration in

columns 1 or 3 and βFDI is the estimator for FDI in columns 1 or 3. FDI and Migrants arethe mean values of FDI and Migrants from Table 1.

13

Page 14: Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative ...sites.bu.edu/neudc/files/2014/10/paper_108.pdf · Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative Advantage of Nations

receiving countries of the migrants. The larger estimated coefficient in skilled

migration seems to be driven by skilled immigration, when comparing columns

3 to 5.

Panel B of Table 4 uses a product-level CAGR for a 10-year period as the

dependent variable, in order to study the intensive margin of trade. The num-

ber of observations is different than the sample used for Panel A because we

are using all country-product-year combinations with export value above zero

in the baseline year. The results present evidence that both the presence of

immigrants from and of emigrants in countries exporters of product p, is asso-

ciated with a larger future rate of growth in export value of product p in the

country under consideration. In particular, looking at Column 1 suggests that,

for a given product p, a 10% increase in the stock of (total) migrants from and

to countries exporting such product is associated with an increase in the future

annual growth rate in export value for the receiving country of about 0.084

annual points. The coefficient for skilled migration in column 4 implies that a

10% increase in the stock of skilled migrants to and from countries exporters of

p, is associated with an increase of 0.026 points in the CAGR for the next ten

years, though it lacks statistical significance. This lack of significance seems to

be driven by the poor explanatory power of skilled emigration which, judging by

column 5, drives down the overall value of the coefficient reported in column 4.

Interestingly, skilled immigration seems to correlate positively with CAGR with

a higher coefficient by over 20% than unskilled immigration. In Section 5 we

look into this issue and find that, in fact, the coefficient for unskilled emigration

is also not robust to different cuts of the data, as opposed to immigration figures.

In light of this, less can be said about emigrants, both skilled and unskilled, in

explaining the documented productivity dynamics.

An interesting implication of the results is that FDI and trade figures seem

not to correlate positively with the ability of countries to expand their the export

baskets under the studied context. That is, trading with countries which are

exporters of a particular product is not associated with the likelihood of gaining

comparative advantage in that same product. However, when it comes to the

intensive margin of trade (panel B), trading with countries that export a given

product seem to positively correlate with the future annual growth of export

value of such product. Precedents of this result tracks to Coe and Helpman

(1995), where they find evidence on how trade leads to increases in aggregate

productivity.

All the specifications presented above include product-by-year fixed effects

14

Page 15: Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative ...sites.bu.edu/neudc/files/2014/10/paper_108.pdf · Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative Advantage of Nations

and country-by-year fixed effects. The former set of fixed effects would control

for global demand for all products. Given that we are looking at exports to the

rest of the world, the shifts we identify must be related to the supply side. The

country-by-year fixed effects would control for time variant countries’ character-

istics, such as country-level aggregate demand and supply shocks, which would

rule out that the results are driven by a third factor that positively correlates

with both migrant figures and overall productivity within countries.

4.2 Bilateral transaction costs and placebo test

A valid concern would be that the partial correlations we are observing are

being driven by bilateral trade: the country is exporting more of the product to

those countries where the migrants are from or in. This relates to the evidence

presented by Gould (1994) and Aubry et. al. (2012), who find that migrants

facilitate the creation of business networks which induces bilateral trade and

capital flows. Under this possibility, it would be harder to attribute the results

to a gain in productivity, but to a decrease in bilateral trade or transaction

costs. In order to deal with this we estimate again the same specification, but

we exclude from the dependent variable all exports to countries where migrants

are in or from. That is, we reconstruct the dataset such that the export value

to the rest of the world for each product and country combination, excludes

exports to nations that send or receive that same country’s migrants.

A critical caveat is that the exclusion requires defining a threshold on the

number of migrants in or from the partner countries. If one migrant is enough to

activate this rule, we will probably clean all world trade given that it is very rare

not to have one alien citizen of every country in most developed nations, which

generate the largest share of world trade. In this sense, we define a number of

arbitrary thresholds which are 500, 1000, 2500 or 5000 migrants. For example,

let’s suppose we are looking at Canadian exports of television sets to the rest of

the world in year 1990. We will exclude from that figure exports of TV sets from

Canada to countries that (1) have a number X of Canadians migrants and (2)

a number Y of their citizens are migrants in Canada, as long as X+Y is larger

than 500, 1000, 2500 and 5000. The assumption is that an effective business

network that can reduce bilateral transaction costs require more than 500, 1000,

2500 or 5000 migrants among the two countries.

In fact, Figure 3 shows the magnitude of the reduction of total trade figures

after revising the exports figures as explained above. For instance, with the 500

15

Page 16: Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative ...sites.bu.edu/neudc/files/2014/10/paper_108.pdf · Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative Advantage of Nations

threshold world trade figures are reduced by about 92.5%; while using the 5000

threshold reduces total trade figures by about 83%.

[Figure 3 about here.]

Nevertheless, despite the strong decline in the variation of the dependent

variable, the results show consistent patterns with the previous results. For

instance, Table 5 shows results using the 500 threshold (the most conservative

one).

[Table 5 about here.]

Excluding bilateral trade amounts from the dependent variable allow us to

rule out lower bilateral transaction costs as driving the results shown above.

Moreover, all migration related estimators have positive and statistical signifi-

cance when doing this exercise, as shown in Table 5 (besides skilled emigration

in the intensive margin panel). For Panel A, the estimates are similar in mag-

nitude to those in Table 4. For instance, according to column 1, a country

with 10% increase in its stock of total migrants is associated with an increase of

about 1.3% in the likelihood the receiving country will export product p with

an RCA above 1 in the next ten years.14 In the case of skilled migration, an

increase of 10% in the stock of migrants in and from countries exporting p,

is associated with an increase of 1.5% in the likelihood of the sending and/or

receiving country to add p to its export basket.

The estimators in Panel B of Table 5 are larger in magnitude that those

in Table 4. For instance, according to column 1, a 10% increase in the stock

of migrants is associated with an increase of 0.24 points in the CAGR for the

next ten years. When looking at skilled migration a 10% increase in the stock

of migrants is associated with an increase in the CAGR of 0.09 points. This

coefficient is statistically significant, as opposed to the analogous one in Table

4. However, we still see lack of significance for skilled emigration figure, what

seems to lower the estimator for overall migration as compared to the unskilled

figures. As mentioned above, Section 5 discusses this result in detail, and show

that emigration figures are usually not robust to most cuts in the data, regardless

of their skill level.

As an additional test, we present results of a "placebo test", in order to

lower the concerns that the results are generated uncontrolled for trends in the

14In this case, as specified in Table 1, we use 1.5 as the unconditional probability of addinga new product as the baseline value for this calculation.

16

Page 17: Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative ...sites.bu.edu/neudc/files/2014/10/paper_108.pdf · Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative Advantage of Nations

data. Thus, we replicate Specification (1), but this time the weighting parameter

Rc′,p,t = 1 if RCAc′,p,t = 0. That is, we exploit variation in the migrants in and

from countries that are not exporters of product p, to understand how does that

correlate with the ability of the sending/receiving country of those migrants to

export good p in the future.

In practical terms, we are testing whether we see an average effect in the data

of countries becoming better at products even when there are no migrants in or

from other countries that do such product. Why? Because if the estimators for

the migration variables are reduced in value, this will imply that the results of

the previous section are not driven by the fact that those countries were already

in a trend to add the products to their export basket, or increase their export

value. The results are presented in Table 6.

[Table 6 about here.]

The upper panel of Table 6 shows that the estimators for migration figures

across all specifications and disaggregations become statistically insignificant

and often negative, as opposed to the results of the previous section. That is,

when countries receive migrants from or send migrants to other nations that do

not export a product at the beginning of the period, the likelihood of gaining

comparative advantage on such product is unaffected or even lower. We see a

similar pattern in the lower panel of the same table, where nations exporters of

p with migrants from or to countries that do not export p, tend to experience a

lower export value growth rate for p in the next ten years.

Therefore, based on the evidence of this section, we claim our results are not

driven by bilateral migrant networks nor explained by an unobservable increas-

ing productivity trend unrelated to migrants.

Yet, there is still room for endogeneity concerns, which keeps us from con-

cluding anything causal on the relationships we have found so far. The next

subsection deals with this issue and attempts to solve the remaining concerns.

4.3 Endogeneity

The documented correlations may be partly driven by endogeneity: migrants

relocate themselves following potential growth in particular sectors they are

familiar with. In order to reduce endogeneity concerns, we employ an instru-

mental variable approach that will serve as exogenous variation to migration

figures.

17

Page 18: Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative ...sites.bu.edu/neudc/files/2014/10/paper_108.pdf · Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative Advantage of Nations

To do this we follow the methodology devised by Frankel and Romer (1999)

and employ a gravity model to create our instruments. Our gravity model,

though, aims to estimate bilateral migration stocks (as opposed to trade figures)

based on bilateral characteristics of the sending and receiving countries of the

migrants. Some examples of other studies that use a gravity model to instrument

for migration stocks are Felbemayr et. al. (2010), Ortega and Peri (2011) and

Alesina et. al. (2013).

Biases arising in the estimation for gravity models are a matter of concern

in the literature. In the trade literature, in particular, this concern has been

approached Santos Silva and Tenreyro (2006), who suggest the application of

a pseudo-poisson maximum likelihood estimator (PPML), given its better per-

formance relative to linear models.15 Additionally, Helpman et. al. (2008)

estimate a trade gravity model in an heterogenous firms setting using a Heck-

man (1979) selection model, which allows them to estimate zero bilateral trade

and asymmetric flows.

Taking this into account we first we estimate a gravity equation following

the next specification:

migrantsc,c′,t = α+Xc,c′ × βc,c′ + θc + θc′ + γt + vc,c′,t (2)

The left hand side, migrantsc,c′,t, is the actual number of migrants in coun-

try c from country c′ at time t. The vector Xc,c′ includes exogenous variables

that are common to countries c and c′: bilateral distance (in logs) as well as

binary variables indicating border sharing, same geographic region, (former)

colony-colonizer relationship, same colonizer and same language.16 Xc,c′ also

includes a continuos variable that measures the probability that two individuals

in countries c and c’ picked at random share the same religion beliefs.17

We also include receiving-country and sending-country fixed effects as multi-

lateral resistance terms (Anderson and Van Wincoop, 2001; Bertoli and Fernández-

Huertas Moraga 2013). It also includes year dummies, and in addition, includes

interactions of the variables in Xc,c′ with these year dummies, to allow for differ-

ential effects of these exogenous variables in both periods of time. We purposely

exclude GDP per capita terms for both receiving and sending countries in the

15The PPML estimator also solves the censoring problem generated by zeros in the data.16This data comes from the GeoDist dataset (Mayer and Zignago 2011) from CEPII.17This data was constructed using data from the Correlates of War Project at

http://www.correlatesofwar.org (Zeev and Henderson, 2014).

18

Page 19: Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative ...sites.bu.edu/neudc/files/2014/10/paper_108.pdf · Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative Advantage of Nations

equation to avoid further endogeneity concerns.18.

Table 7 presents results using four different gravity models estimated with

different methodologies: OLS in columns 1 and 2 (with the difference that the

latter adds 1 to the left hand side before its log transformation), the Heckman

(1979) selection model in column 3 and PPML in column 4.

Column 3 corresponds to the outcome of the second stage of the selection

model. The exclusion variable for the first stage is the unemployment rate in

the receiving country at the beginning of the period. The choice is based on

the fact that the decision whether to migrate is partly explained by the ability

of the migrant to find a job in the destination country. Therefore, following

the intuition presented by Helpman et. al. (2008), one can argue that a higher

unemployment rate is likely to result in a higher (fixed) search cost for em-

ployment. Thus, we believe this variable complies with the proper exclusion

restriction.

[Table 7 about here.]

It can be seen how, as noted by Santos Silva and Tenreyro (2006), the

non-linear estimators result are very different than the OLS ones. Among all

results, however, we see some constant patterns. First, distance between the

sending and receiving countries negatively correlate with migration stock figures.

Other variables that positively correlate with migration stocks are sharing a

border, being in the same region, having a current or former colony-colonizer

relationship, having a common colonizer, speaking a common language and

sharing the same religion beliefs with a higher likelihood. We can also see that

there are no statistical differences between these relationships in years 1990 or

2000, as evidenced by the interacted variables, besides for common continent

and region, which seems to explain about 30% less in migration stocks in year

2000.

Across all models we choose the PPML as our preferred one to construct the

instruments, given that it points to have unbiased estimates and provides the

best fit (R-squared of 0.80). Nevertheless, robustness tests using instruments

generated by the Heckman selection model are presented in the Appendix Sec-

tion A.2.

We use the same PPML model to estimate both total, unskilled and skilled

migration stocks. The results for such estimation are presented in Table 8.

18The results, however, are robust to their inclusion.

19

Page 20: Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative ...sites.bu.edu/neudc/files/2014/10/paper_108.pdf · Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative Advantage of Nations

[Table 8 about here.]

Column 1 of Table 8 presents the estimation of the gravity model for total

migration stocks (thus, it replicates the same results as column 4 of Table 7).

Column 2 replicates the gravity model using a PPML estimation for unskilled

migration as the dependent variable and column 3 does so for skilled migration

figures. Interesting results arise when comparing both estimations. First, the

geographic components of the gravity model (distance, region and border) are

reduced significantly when estimating skilled migration stocks. That is, geogra-

phy is a less elastic determinant to skilled individuals when they choose where

to migrate. Interestingly, cultural and institutional variables such as “Common

Language”, “Common Colonizer” and “Same Religion” positively correlates with

skilled migration stocks with coefficients that are larger than in column 1 and

2; meaning that cultural variables seem to be a more elastic determinant of

skilled migration. The variables are better explaining unskilled migration, with

an R-squared of 0.82, as compared to the fit for skilled migration with an R-

squared of 0.78. Overall, however, across all specifications all variables have the

expected sign and a good fit.

After using this model to predict the expected migrant stock we recon-

struct these variables to instrument for the actual migration stocks in the same

weighted structured detailed in Section 3.2. That is, for each combination of

country c, product p and year t, we compute the total sum of expected immi-

grants from and expected emigrants to all other countries that export p with

an RCA above 1. We also estimate figures for skilled and unskilled migration.

Thus, there will be always the same amount of instruments than of endogenous

regressors. This construction provides variance at the country, product and year

level.

The relevance of the instruments is fully testable. For intuition purposes,

Figures 4 and 5 present the analogous of a first stage in a 2SLS regression,

using South Africa and the United States as examples.19 In both the figures

each observation is a product labeled with its SITC 4-digit code, and the scales

use the hyperbolic inverse sine transformation

For instance, Figure 4 uses only data from South Africa in 1990. The vertical

axis measures the total migration stock (immigrants plus emigrants) for South

Africa in year 2000, while the horizontal axis measures the estimated migration

19The IV regression pools across all countries and periods in the sample. This figure limitsthe observation to a country and a period only for the sake of a better understanding.

20

Page 21: Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative ...sites.bu.edu/neudc/files/2014/10/paper_108.pdf · Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative Advantage of Nations

stock computed with the PPML gravity model. Each observation in the figure

matches the actual total migrants stock vs. the estimated total migrant stocks

from and in countries that export each product with an RCA above 1. It can be

seen in the figure that there is an obvious positive correlation between the actual

values and the expected ones based on the gravity model after the weighting

procedure.

[Figure 4 about here.]

Similarly, Figure 5 shows different panels for immigrants and emigrants for

the United States in Year 1990. The left panel shows, for each product, the

actual vs. estimated total amount of immigrants from countries that export

such product with an RCA above 1; while the right panel does so for emigrants.

[Figure 5 about here.]

For the instruments to be valid, the exclusion restriction must be that, prod-

uct specific exports to the whole world are not correlated with common bilat-

eral geographic, cultural or historical ties with its migrants’ countries, once we

control for country-year fixed effect. While it is a valid argument that the ge-

ographic position of the country, its particular language or culture, could be a

source of comparative advantage for particular products; our country-by-year

fixed effects would account for these concerns.

Furthermore, we assume that countries do not engage in product specific

export-inducing agreements based on their cultural or historical ties, which are

not captured via flows such as FDI or trade.

To avoid all possible remaining concerns on endogeneity, for all instrumental

variable regressions, we exclude all exports to countries where there are over 500

combined immigrants and emigrants when constructing the dependent variables

(see subsection 4.2).20 Thus by excluding bilateral trade, which could be partly

explained by the exogenous variables that we use to estimate migration stocks,

we also eliminate the possibility that our instrument is correlated with the

dependent variable through other, uncontrolled for, variables.

Since often the specification includes n > 1 endogenous regressors, we rely on

Stock and Yogo (2002) to define whether the instruments are weak and use the

Kleibergen-Paap F statistic. For the case of one endogenous regressor and one

instrument the critical Kleibergen-Paap F value is 16.78, but for the case of two

20Appendix Section A.4 presents robust results with other less conservative thresholds.

21

Page 22: Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative ...sites.bu.edu/neudc/files/2014/10/paper_108.pdf · Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative Advantage of Nations

endogenous and two instruments the critical value is 7.03. A Kleibergen-Paap

F statistic above the critical value implies that in a 5% Wald test the coefficient

of interest is not size-distorted over 10%. The Kleibergen-Paap F statistic will

be reported in all regressions.

Results using the instrumental variables (estimated through GMM) are pre-

sented in Table 9.

[Table 9 about here.]

First, note that in all specifications the Kleibergen-Paap F statistics shows

evidence of a strong instrument in all columns. Panel A, similarly to previous

tables, presents results for the extensive margin while Panel B presents results

for the intensive margin.

With regards to the extensive margin, note that the estimated coefficients

are larger in magnitude by a factor of four or more than in Table 5, which present

the OLS results. This is consistent with Frankel and Romer (1999) results who

also find larger coefficients after their instrumentation. In particular, the results

suggest that, for a given country, a 10% increase in the stock of migrants from

and to countries that export a particular product translates into an increase of

0.08 percentage points, or about 6%, in the likelihood of such country adding

that product to its export basket in the next ten year period, on average.21 This

corresponds to about 6,500 migrants for the average country.

In the case of skilled migration in Column 4, an increase of 10% in the stock

of migrants, or for the average country about only 1,500 skilled migrants (from

and to countries exporters of product p), translates into an increase of 0.068

percentage points, or 4.5%, in the likelihood of the country under consideration

adding that product to its export basket in the next ten year period, on average.

Thus, for the average country, 65,000 more migrants from and to other

nations exporters of p results on about a 60% increase in the likelihood of

adding p to its export basket; while the same number for skilled migration is

reduced to slightly over 20,000 individuals, on average.

Columns 2 and 3 uses unskilled migration figures as regressors. We find that,

while overall unskilled migration seems to have a higher estimated coefficient

than skilled migration, seems that this is driven by the fact that, consistently

with previous results, we find no statistically significant effect of skilled emi-

gration on the dependent variable. The estimator for skilled immigration, on

21Note from Table 1 that the unconditional probability of adding a new product is 1.5%when excluding exports to countries where migrants are in or from.

22

Page 23: Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative ...sites.bu.edu/neudc/files/2014/10/paper_108.pdf · Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative Advantage of Nations

the other hand, is almost twice of that for unskilled immigration. It can be

claimed that skilled immigration is driving an important part of the effect in

the estimations.

Similarly to the OLS estimation, the coefficients for the FDI variable are

positive though without statistical significance. However, a non-linear combina-

tion of the estimators reveal that with these new results, an unskilled migrant

is worth about USD $90,000 of FDI (p-value = 0.027) and a skilled migrant is

worth about $250,000 of FDI (p-value=0.025), when it comes to their ability to

induce a new export for the average country.22

Panel B shows also results in which the coefficients are much larger than in

the OLS regression of Table 5. A 10% increase in the stock of migrants from

and to countries exporters of p translates into a higher average growth for such

product by 0.51 points per annum in a ten year period, while the same number

for skilled migrants is 0.15. Note that column 5 reveals, consistently with the

upper panel, that most of the skilled migrants effect is driven by immigrants,

and in this case the coefficient for skilled immigration is about 30% higher than

for unskilled immigration in column 3.

If the exclusion restrictions presented before are valid, and the results can-

not be attributed to a third uncontrolled for variable, then these results are

particularly strong and a solid contribution to the literature. The presence of

migrants from or in nations that export a particular good induce a productivity

shift in the sending and receiving country of the migrants, which results in the

diversification of their export baskets.23

5 Discussion and Interpretation

The results in the previous section show through a variety of ways that migra-

tion, in both directions, is a determinant of the evolution of the comparative

advantage of nations. What stands behind such claim?

22To compute this calculate βM

βFDI

FDI

Migrants; where βM is the estimator for migration in

columns 1 or 3 and βFDI is the estimator for FDI in columns 1 or 3. FDI and Migrants arethe mean values of FDI and Migrants from Table 1.

23In the Appendix there are robustness tests to these results, which include using aHeckman-based gravity model to construct the instruments (Appendix Section A.2); usingHausmann and Klingler (2007) density variable as a control (Appendix Section A.3) andvarying the thresholds used to clean the left hand side from bilateral trade (Appendix SectionA.4). It also presents results that uses RCAc′,p,t = 2 to weight the right hand side variables(Appendix Section A8).

23

Page 24: Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative ...sites.bu.edu/neudc/files/2014/10/paper_108.pdf · Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative Advantage of Nations

If knowledge is tacit, and thus it requires human interaction for its trans-

mission and diffusion, then we could expect that migrants are a driver of such

process, which results in increased productivity of the particular sectors that

are especially productive in the sending and receiving countries of the migrants.

The results are consistent with such hypothesis.

In particular, the results using the instrumental variable approach are sug-

gestive of immigrants as the main source of this effect. The mechanisms are

clear: immigrants are physically present in their receiving country, and thus

they interact with the local population in ways that could lead to the diffusion

of knowledge in the receiving country. This knowledge translate into productiv-

ity shifts in industries typical of the home country of the migrant, and is able to

shape the export basket of the receiving country. These new exports, though,

are not going to the migrants’ home country; but rather to the rest of the world.

We are unable to find robust evidence that emigration plays a role in these

dynamics.24 In most of our regressions skilled emigration figures were statis-

tically insignificant, as opposed to unskilled emigration regressors. In order to

study these phenomenon of the data in more detail, we reestimate Table 9 across

different periods and types of products. We do this to understand whether there

are differential effects across any of these dimensions and which sets of observa-

tions in the sample are driving the observed overall results.

This time, we standardize the immigrants and emigrants figures to have zero

mean and unit standard deviation, to be able to compare them properly. That

is, the reported beta coefficients are standardized. Table 10 summarizes this

exercise.

[Table 10 about here.]

The left panel of Table 10 reports estimators of βim (immigration) while the

right panel reports the estimators for βem (emigration) based on specification

(1), focusing on the extensive margin (thus, observations are limited to having

an initial RCA equal to zero). In particular, the re-estimation uses on the

24However, it could theoretically still be a relevant channel. Knowledge diffusion couldhappen through return migration or through links and open communication between theemigrants and their co-nationals back home. With regards to the first channel, estimates showthat about 30% of emigrants return to their home countries after some period of time (e.g.Borjas and Bratsberg, 1996). These migrants spend enough time in the foreign country to bepart of the labor force, which eventually could lead to generate industry-specific productivityshifts back home. More recently, Choudhury (2014) shows how Indian return migrants induceproductivity improvements in their firm back home, after spending time in the multinationalcorporation headquarters abroad.

24

Page 25: Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative ...sites.bu.edu/neudc/files/2014/10/paper_108.pdf · Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative Advantage of Nations

right hand side figures for both unskilled migrants (estimators reported under

βUnskilled) and skilled migrants (estimators reported under βSkilled ).

The first row uses all 83,100 observations (the same sample presented in the

upper panel of Table 1). βUnskilledim is estimated to be 0.014 while βSkilled

im is

estimated to be 0.020. Both estimates are statistically significant. This actually

means that one standard deviation above the mean for (un)skilled immigration

translates into an increase of (0.014) 0.020 percentage points in the probability of

exporting product p in the next ten year period. The table also reports that the

estimator for skilled immigration is 1.44 times that of unskilled immigration.25

As the table reports, the effects for immigration documented are present

in both developed (OECD) and developing (non-OECD) countries, as well as

during different time periods. Across almost all cuts of the sample the esti-

mated coefficient for skilled immigration is larger than the one for unskilled

immigration (though not always statistically significant).

Alternatively, we find that the results for emigration are not robust to the

standardization of the right hand side variables (i.e. in the first row) or to using

different cuts of the dataset. This could explain the fact that in all previous

tables, the figures for emigration were seldom statistically significant. Thus, we

limit of concluding anything on emigration in particular.

Back to immigration on the left panel, the table also divides the sample into

ten product groups based on the first digit SITC code. Note that in industries

that are more knowledge intensive, such as Machinery and Transport Equip-

ment, the ratio of the skilled vs. unskilled immigration coefficient estimators is

higher.

We also present results dividing the sample in goods above and below the

median in terms of their capital intensity, using the measures by Shirotori (2010)

. The results hold for all goods in the capital intensity scale, ruling out the

results being driven by the forces suggested by Rybczynski (1955). In particular,

skilled immigration has a similar effect on both non-capital and capital intensive

goods.

Finally, we also divide the sample into differentiated goods and homogenous/reference-

priced goods, using Rauch’s (1999) definition.26 The results suggest that the

effect is present among both categories. This provides further evidence that

migrant networks (by generating markets for differentiated products) are not

25In the cases when one of the estimator is negative the ratio is not reported. In all thecases where the estimators are negative, they also lack statistical significance.

26In particular, we use the “conservative” definition.

25

Page 26: Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative ...sites.bu.edu/neudc/files/2014/10/paper_108.pdf · Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative Advantage of Nations

explaining our results.

In general, we see that the documented effect is robust to many different

types of products. While the magnituted of the effect might vary with the

knowledge intensity or other characteristics of the good, migrants can still play

a role in the export of “easier-to-produce” goods. Why? Because when export-

ing a good, one not only needs to be able to produce it efficiently, but also

firms need industry-specific knowledge to efficiently perform post-production

processes fundamental to exports such as packaging, managing inventory, dis-

tributing to airports or seaports with the proper transportation and many other

activities that directly affect productivity, and consequently, export levels. In

this sense, our evidence suggests that migrants play an important role in improv-

ing productivity in the overall sequence of export activities for all industries.

6 Concluding Remarks

This paper presents evidence suggesting that migrants are a source of evolution

for the comparative advantage of nations; a relationship that has not been

documented in the literature thus far. The results contribute to the growing

literature that aims to explain the evolution of industry-specific productivity of

countries, and to the literature of international trade that aims to understand,

in a Ricardian framework, dynamics of the comparative advantage of nations. It

also contributes to the literature of international knowledge diffusion by studying

the possible drivers of knowledge across borders, using the setting suggested by

Bahar et. al. 2014, which uses product-level exports figures as a measure of

knowledge acquisition, after controlling for global demand.

The main result in all these settings is that people, serving as international

drivers of productive-knowledge, can shape the comparative advantage of na-

tions. In all of the specifications we include controls for a set of variables that

leave us with empirical evidence suggestive that this is the mechanism in place.

The instrumental variables approach also reduces possible remaining endogene-

ity concerns.

This finding is particularly important to understand some known charac-

teristics of knowledge diffusion. First, the short-ranged character of knowledge

diffusion can be explained by the fact that part of knowledge is embedded in

people, that tend to move in a more localized manner than goods or capital.

Second, the fact that diffusion of knowledge and technology is more widespread

26

Page 27: Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative ...sites.bu.edu/neudc/files/2014/10/paper_108.pdf · Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative Advantage of Nations

today than decades ago (i.e. the diffusion process has accelerated over time)

can be explained by the fact that people flows, such as migration or short term

travel, have also increased rapidly.

All in all, we should expect industry-specific knowledge diffusion to be ex-

istent through channels other than migration in which people are at the center

of the story: short-term travel, internet interactions, etc. The study of these

channels and the exact mechanisms are part of our future research agenda.

The importance of these results, however, go beyond the pure relationship

between migration and productivity. It serves to understand the ways and means

through which knowledge diffuses around the globe. After all, the limitations

of knowledge diffusion stand at the center of the discussion on convergence,

productivity and even inequality. As Thomas Piketty (2014) in his book “Capital

in the Twenty-First Century” puts it “knowledge and skill diffusion is the key of

the overall productivity growth as well as the reduction of inequality both within

and between countries.”

References

Aitken, B.J., and A.E. Harrison. “Do domestic firms benefit from direct foreign

investment? Evidence from Venezuela.” American Economic Review 89, 3:

(1999) 605–618.

Alesina, A, J Harnoss, and H Rapoport. “Birthplace Diversity and Economic

Prosperity.” NBER Working Paper Series , 18699.

Andersen, Thomas Barnebeck, and Carl-Johan Dalgaard. “Flows of people,

flows of ideas, and the inequality of nations.” Journal of Economic Growth

16, 1: (2011) 1–32.

Anderson, JE, and Eric Van Wincoop. “Gravity with gravitas: A solution to

the border puzzle.” American Economic Review 93, 1: (2001) 170–191.

Arrow, Kenneth J. “Classificatory Notes on the Production and Transmission

of Technologcal Knowledge.” The American Economic Review 59, 2: (1969)

29–35.

Aubry, Amandine, Maurice Kugler, and Hillel Rapoport. “Migration, FDI, and

the Margins of Trade.” mimeo .

27

Page 28: Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative ...sites.bu.edu/neudc/files/2014/10/paper_108.pdf · Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative Advantage of Nations

Bahar, Dany, Ricardo Hausmann, and Cesar A. Hidalgo. “Neighbors and the

evolution of the comparative advantage of nations: Evidence of international

knowledge diffusion?” Journal of International Economics 92, 1: (2014)

111–123.

Balassa, B. “Trade Liberalisation and Revealed Comparative Advantage.” The

Manchester School 33, 2: (1965) 99–123.

Bertoli, Simone, and Jesús Fernández-Huertas Moraga. “Multilateral resistance

to migration.” Journal of Development Economics 102: (2013) 79–100.

Borjas, George J., and Bernt Bratsberg. “Who Leaves? The Outmigration of

the Foreign-Born.” The Review of Economics and Statistics 78, 1: (1996)

165.

Bottazzi, Laura, and Giovanni Peri. “Innovation and spillovers in regions :

Evidence from European patent data.” European Economic Review 47: (2003)

687–710.

Choudhury, Prithwiraj. “Return Migration and Geography of Innovation in

Mnes: A Natural Experiment of On-the-Job Learning of Knowledge Produc-

tion by Local Workers Reporting to.” Harvard Business School Working Paper

, 14-078.

Coe, David T, and Elhanan Helpman. “International R&D spillovers.” European

Economic Review 2921, 94: (1995) 859–887.

Coe, David T., Elhanan Helpman, and Alexander W. Hoffmaister. “Interna-

tional R&D spillovers and institutions.” European Economic Review 53, 7:

(2009) 723–741.

Combes, Pierre-Philippe, Miren Lafourcade, and Thierry Mayer. “The trade-

creating effects of business and social networks: evidence from France.” Jour-

nal of International Economics 66, 1: (2005) 1–29.

Costinot, A., D. Donaldson, and I. Komunjer. “What Goods Do Countries

Trade? A Quantitative Exploration of Ricardo’s Ideas.” The Review of Eco-

nomic Studies 79, 2: (2011) 581–608.

Docquier, Frédéric, Abdeslam Marfouk, C. Ozden, and C.R. Parsons. “Geo-

graphic, gender and skill structure of international migration.” In Report

written for the Economic Research Forum. 2010, 1–27.

28

Page 29: Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative ...sites.bu.edu/neudc/files/2014/10/paper_108.pdf · Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative Advantage of Nations

Eaton, Jonathan, and Samuel Kortum. “Technology, Geography and Trade.”

Econometrica 70, 5: (2002) 1741–1779.

Felbermayr, Gabriel J., Sanne Hiller, and Davide Sala. “Does immigration boost

per capita income?” Economics Letters 107, 2: (2010) 177–179.

Felbermayr, Gabriel J., and Benjamin Jung. “The pro-trade effect of the brain

drain: Sorting out confounding factors.” Economics Letters 104, 2: (2009)

72–75.

Frankel, Jeffrey, and David Romer. “Does Trade Cause Growth?” American

Economic Review 89, 3: (1999) 379–399.

Gould, DM. “Immigrant links to the home country: empirical implications for

US bilateral trade flows.” The Review of Economics and Statistics 76, 2:

(1994) 302–316.

Hausmann, Ricardo, César A Hidalgo, Sebastián Bustos, Michele Coscia, Sarah

Chung, Juan Jímenez, Alexander Simoes, and Muhammed A. Yildirim. The

Atlas of Economic Complexity: Mapping Paths to Prosperity. Cambridge,

MA, 2011.

Hausmann, Ricardo, Cesar A Hidalgo, Daniel P Stock, and Muhammed A

Yildirim. “Implied Comparative Advantage.” CID Working Paper Series

, 276.

Hausmann, Ricardo, and Bailey Klinger. “The Structure of the Product Space

and the Evolution of Comparative Advantage.” CID Working Paper Series ,

146.

Heckman, JJ. “Sample Selection Bias as a Specification Error.” Econometrica

47, 1: (1979) 153–161.

Helpman, E, M Melitz, and Y Rubinstein. “Estimating trade flows: Trading

partners and trading volumes.” Quarterly Journal of Economics CXXIII,

May: (2008) 441–487.

Hidalgo, César A, Bailey Klinger, AL Barabási, and Ricardo Hausmann. “The

product space conditions the development of nations.” Science (New York,

N.Y.) 317, 5837: (2007) 482–7.

Hornung, Erik. “Immigration and the Diffusion of Technology : The Huguenot

Diaspora in Prussia.” American Economic Review 104, 1: (2014) 84–122.

29

Page 30: Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative ...sites.bu.edu/neudc/files/2014/10/paper_108.pdf · Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative Advantage of Nations

Iranzo, Susana, and Giovanni Peri. “Migration and Trade: Theory with an

Application to the Eastern-Western European Integration.” Journal of Inter-

national Economics 79: (2009) 1–19.

Jaffe, A.B., M. Trajtenberg, and R. Henderson. “Geographic Localization of

Knowledge Spillovers as Evidenced by Patent Citations.” The Quarterly Jour-

nal of Economics 108, 3: (1993) 577.

Javorcik, Beata S. “Does foreign direct investment increase the productivity

of domestic firms? In search of spillovers through backward linkages.” The

American Economic Review 94, 3: (2004) 605–627.

Javorcik, Beata S., Caglar Ozden, Mariana Spatareanu, and Cristina Neagu.

“Migrant networks and foreign direct investment.” Journal of Development

Economics 94, 2: (2011) 231–241.

Keller, Wolfgang. “Geographic localization of international technology diffu-

sion.” American Economic Review 92, 1: (2002) 120–142.

. “International Technology Diffusion.” Journal of Economic Literature

XLII, September: (2004) 752–782.

Kugler, Maurice, and Hillel Rapoport. “International labor and capital flows:

Complements or substitutes?” Economics Letters 94, 2: (2007) 155–162.

MacKinnon, JG, and Lonnie Magee. “Transforming the Dependent Variable in

Regression Models.” International Economic Review 31, 2: (1990) 315–339.

Maoz, Zeev, and Errol A. Henderson. “The World Religion Dataset 1945-2010:

Logic Estimates and Trends.” International Interactions 39, 3: (2013) 265–

291.

Mayer, Thierry, and Soledad Zignago. “Notes on CEPII distances measures :

The GeoDist database.” CEPII Working Paper , 25.

OECD. “International Direct Investment Statistics.”, 2012. http://www.oecd/

investment/statistics.

Ortega, F, and Giovanni Peri. “The Aggregate Effects of Trade and Migration:

Evidence from OECD Countries.” IZA Discussion Paper Series , 5604.

Piketty, T. Capital in the Twenty-First Century. Harvard University Press,

2014. http://books.google.com/books?id=J222AgAAQBAJ.

30

Page 31: Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative ...sites.bu.edu/neudc/files/2014/10/paper_108.pdf · Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative Advantage of Nations

Rauch, James E, and Vitor Trindade. “Ethnic chinese networks in international

trade.” 84, February: (2002) 116–130.

Rauch, JE. “Networks versus markets in international trade.” Journal of inter-

national Economics 48, June 1996: (1999) 7–35.

Rybczynski, T. M. “Factor Endowment and Relative Commodity Prices.” Eco-

nomica 22, 88: (1955) 336–341.

Shirotori, M, B Tumurchudur, and O Cadot. “Revealed Factor Intensity Indices

at the Product Level.” Policy Issues in International Trade and Commodities

2010, 44.

Silva, JMCS, and Silvana Tenreyro. “The log of gravity.” The Review of Eco-

nomics and statistics 88, November: (2006) 641–658.

Stock, JH, and M Yogo. “Testing for Weak Instruments in Linear IV Regression.”

NBER Technical Working Papers Series , 284.

Tong, SY. “Ethnic Networks in FDI and the Impact of Institutional Develop-

ment.” Review of Development Economics 9, 4: (2005) 563–580.

World Bank. “World Development Indicators Online.”, . http://data.

worldbank.org/.

31

Page 32: Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative ...sites.bu.edu/neudc/files/2014/10/paper_108.pdf · Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative Advantage of Nations

Figure 1: Cartogram Share of Migrants, Year 2000

32

Page 33: Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative ...sites.bu.edu/neudc/files/2014/10/paper_108.pdf · Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative Advantage of Nations

Figure 2: Cartogram of Migrants Per Capita, Year 2000

33

Page 34: Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative ...sites.bu.edu/neudc/files/2014/10/paper_108.pdf · Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative Advantage of Nations

Figure 3: Proportion of World Trade Left

0.0

5.1

.15

.2P

ropo

rtio

n of

Wor

ld T

rade

Lef

t

1990 2000

500 1000 2500 5000

34

Page 35: Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative ...sites.bu.edu/neudc/files/2014/10/paper_108.pdf · Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative Advantage of Nations

Figure 4: First stage, common language

951059893352

7245

6812

7512

5822

4312

2512

8942

2682

576

71315838

6794

7251

742

2651

6760

78314239

7638

5419 7788811 288189746647

78536112

572

6639

8822

7518

571

7492

6593

8999

642874417493412

56227435

6623

8946

34353232667

7259

1211

5829574

5629

2820

8421

2320

8941

2119

7849

759975216851

2479

129

6831

3353

8432

6576

7621

721

251

6584

87208841

6591

5722

6954

5223

7758

93106577

84636974

230

8973

7267

8935

350

7269 6658

65177246

1124

2440

8433292921147248 71325530

2111

2741

5513

8441

7753

7931

5621

2613

1118821

7732

3221

2789 6354

7284

2483

77516551

371

5155

4242

6992

78417852

1123 7223

7272

54146642

2516

7411

8993

693253127373

6574

14

8981

8983

1212

7915

89968743

573

8749 1222764871387372

1221

6512

7643488

76425833

7264

2871

6832

7283

5827

8472

615

13

7757

470

64182860

7914

6931

4243

6596

8731

5169

7923

6116747

6359

8484

21206863

141

2711

88528851

7912

7523

8481

89288745

711

583

6511

2786

7851

546

74347924

27715147

452

2875

26657921

8830

6746

7919

360

4311582

7781

575914

4817783

7868

5983

2742 8991

62512731

5837

741

7842

2924

6645

7149

6940

7233

2226

7761

6553

6733

913

7119

6673

5831

76285723

6594

2782

2634

2450

6793

7169

565

7499

8952

3223

78616731

65216419

3413

6852 2925

8461

54116880

548

7913

2225

12

7929 61236651

67836595

77648483

2221

6648

8471

2873

542

6253

7252

51382331

26595249

6744

34476498121 61306351

6745

8741

8435

7933

6417

7938

51235146

2816

74914111

6652

26406666

7188

8211

8451

6674

63494822687

7212

8212

6911

6994

8431

5849

6424 8429

5913

142

6552

6618

79118732 2238

2518

7754

7244

8443

68992690

78327219

5826 8464

7449430

7361

6891

8459

422

51625156

84627822

7243

2235

6536

712

8951

6861

545

8998

8310

6996

8933

6121

8939

6289

8465

6991

7422

6515

3330

7126

6582

1213

72687139

7821 71337371

84392239

8922

9610

8742

69786631

460

77415148

5842

2633

411

6998 2332

7752

65715137

723

7144

5335

2460

2117

6975

6549

7442

7742

7782

89606960

7932

26726951

6330

752

6572

6342

5912

7631

8744

81227362

72637368

89978510

6924

722

6782

121

7148

6732

7763

89322631

8424

585

2652

68416632

82196821

2814

69535154

6725

751

2783

114

8482

4236

5921

341

67856784

7431

7234

5832

8921

451

2882

78106724

112

8994

5222

4245

5417

7367

2223

3354

6118

8947

730 941051452666

544

6727

2517

74126665

6252

2655

5122

7224

6716

8124

7928

6749

2472

116

484

2681

6116

6671

6597

8982

6535

6664

7187

65816560

6999

1223

66498842

6411

5322

6646

6993

43137922

2926

72137712

7111

2785

6641

2922

7522

2224 8442

252

7429

77311121

5239

27326516

34146624

5645824

620

2685

64216613240

6612223

3232

589

5232

8452

9710

6712

5163

149

6912 4598931

6592

5241

7421

6573

2683

7369

7413

2879

65132784

7528

7721

6579

6611

2872 6872

65758423

51217511

764189596546 5843

6545

4234

6282

6543

440

74162874

6541

8748

2614

7622

87106542

6638

6423

6531

61147162

66446518

6353

61157451

6341

6672

3224 6352

68117611

6210

5825

6254

2890

3351

2815

52215225

6422

8813

7439

1110

11227163

6534

224 6416

6522

66332234

64136412

5415

3425331

582142416770

1187112

4249

63447612

5224

6343

5111

3231

2686

8811

6259483

2919

26543222

69354233

51612511

3345

2231

586

7723

554167815413

5416

65397161

2519

6544

2481

7452

612

6168989

7722

59223510

561

619

6122

7281

5911

6973

74325852

579

7414

7423

7768

813

6643

6538

6519

58396997

5841

814

4232

5836

6921

5233

6589

980

2911

5851

2116

2232

5777436

7129

42357711

2713

3415

41135981

4244

5835

7239

5231

5914

65835721

2876

53118812

2632

5543

4314

15

7591

5542

6113

65145415112

5623 8422

5834

2714

7271 51135514 2734

6822

5114

7784

2877

62812923

7247

7762

2471

5334

115

2112

5332

5139

5982

6532

8434

6713

89727525

2733

7415

2222

7211421

812

113 24825823

26716842

8924

11

2772

66378197428

271261296415

6635

6871

2927

372

5157

910

1112

1314

Tot

al M

igra

nts

10 11 12 13 14Estimated Total Migrants

Total Migrants Fitted values

South Africa Year 2000

35

Page 36: Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative ...sites.bu.edu/neudc/files/2014/10/paper_108.pdf · Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative Advantage of Nations

Figure 5: First stage, common language

7247511351695514

6129

52235914

7642

7919

6582

742252322816722

7784

5312

6513

6831

7914

6812

5332

6116

8996

7413

2222

54136412

5983

69118442

451

8951

15

5417

3231

58315156

28147768

27897416

8710

7239

586

5629

5828

2112

7762

7492

6953

1122

5821

572

7641

8939

58265827

6664341

24812652

421

6531

6632

5835

7643

63432877

12116536

2785

7761

5513

73682742

2712

6861

7248

2614

58256872

5911

8433

3510

6423

8852

6521

5989

6115

6330

2820

61135155

5331

742

58375851

2440

412

8941

2879

6252

7518

619

819

6259

6282

149

6613

6251

29242711

142

6349

6351

2872

6352

7251

75237711

1212

615

64167361129

64216422

360

6553

2226

8463

5225

844169328991

541956214313

372

8459

2671

66746522

2682

9610

7764

66426535

71295839

2221

5111

8932

94107411

223

6546

5723

26597431

6253

5541

13

6574

7149

8745

6931

7263

2871

7442

7441

6584

2114

7187

7439

8830

7932

2923

6852

8732

8481

72842640

6973

8471

7412

6612

7722

2772

7283

2225

6342

6940628952336638

7628

6912

88126541

77817757

6538

2232

4235

5824

2450

6713

6647

6899

67826746

6649

2516

7782

620

2471

6666

483

8122

6593

6671

3354

6415

7783

75257832

77216516

663567476724

8952

6727

67315157

4242

6745

3415

5148

75215161

6770

2771

2654

4239

664111106784

8121

6978

6596430

711178525542

69758921

7822

6999

8982

4241

6851

6716

5833

19

2472

2882

6871

913

7161

6651

2483

2873

7163

8435

5249

8443

224

6543

6935

51127212

8743

6645

2681

7269

3224

8989

7144

741

6672

7493

6994

6631

84326997

7188

65526544

2926

75226591

7434

69217369

8429

6130

914

7133 7131

545

7428

7148

2922

5838

8431

6646

121

26728997

89997452

6353

7213

6511

6514

2111

4236

2876

7233 8960

8842

247979227244

4312

7599

2634

116

6549

7931

89726760

813

2633

7224

7753

7264

7271

6749

6960

7499

5981

58497138

6822

71195842

8439

7415

6992

7362 2733

8462

89736954

113

7429

6594

7132

6781118

343

7763

6254

4234

5221

8510

7915

5622

6417

76125623

812

68412120

7234

5335

8993

65127621

576

6560

2667

269075127638

6341

2331

2713

512273676623

76482116

6418

69247723

5721

7731

72676542

7741

7611

7742

7449

4233

66488928

7758

612

582

6519

2741

7259

5922

781067257841

571

459

2517

78536572

7861

7924

541

2512

6712

7436

79127754

812482118482

7929

8421

2223

5841

775172456413

6996589

579

5411

6951

561

7435

230

845184528461

9510

5913

575452

2632

481

8720

5334

2925

6665

58326515

4244

8731

4708744

57226118

2613

2666

8811

7139

5145

7649

711

7831

8821

5982

8841

5530

6785

6673

6518

51638933

8935

51146744

6583

564

6359

1222

6597

411311212238813

5147

2231

8994

7928846421175241

6281

91107921

9310

8981

8924

114

6783

2784

5823

8748532365716424

814

2929

2714

2235

5415

22386114

8931

7423

1221

6539

8998

2320

2519

5822

6123

7631

5829

6732

11245224

6863811

2875

6344

8946

7243

1121

7371

77522783

574

64284222874697455436532

78212332

87492927

6210723

2734

7433

2518

66117252

2234

3223

6741980

7868

751

5154

7414

7272

52315222

75286517

3353

546

6579730

3351

440

2655

8422

6750

3222

2665

721

7591

752

2786

2651344

7849

14

6639

6644

2224

65516633

2683

616

7938

7933

2239

7211

5322

2687

611

6658

6595

6534

7788

6411

583

7851

2119

8959

67946733

240

577

24828942

6545

8465

7913

6643

7112

5123

252

7373

281588517268

7421

26856618

548

7712

5239

8741

6998

7732

565

7281

251

5311

5421123

6592

59125921

8434

5852

2890

488

484

4243

8947

8742

1213

544

8310

7923

82122919

460

7511

6842

7219

2460

1116419

2782

3352

3221

66522732

6993

6575

51467123232

3330

341365737842

2511

26865416

8472

34147432

8423

7622

5843

5834

2860

5139

4111

5137

7372

51388219

4232

6624

61126637

2911

8822

5121

5414

585

8983

5737246

74912731

51628974

33457223

65816991

7162

342

8922

6891

6589

7126

4245

68114314

350

7169

6577

42496880

8483

141

4311

115

6121

6793

971065762881

842411

371

6832

6122

7911

6821

12

4825836

7451

411

26318484

6354

1213

1415

1617

Tot

al Im

mig

rant

s

10 12 14 16 18Estimated Total Immigrants

Immigrants Fitted values

Immigrants

7247

5113

5169

5514

6129

522359147642

7919

6582

74225232

2816

722

77845312

6513

6831

7914

6812

5332

6116

89967413

2222

5413

6412

59836911

8442

4518951

15

54173231

5831

5156

2814

7768

27897416

8710

7239

586

56295828

2112

7762

7492

69531122

5821

572

76418939

5826

5827

6664

341

2481

2652

4216531

6632

58357643

6343

2877

1211

6536

2785

7761

5513

7368

2742

2712

6861

7248

2614

5825

687259118433

35106423

8852

6521

59896115

6330

2820

6113

5155

5331

742

58375851

2440

412

8941

2879

6252

7518

619

819

6259

6282

149

6613

6251

2924

2711

142

6349

6351

2872

6352

7251

7523

7711

1212

615

6416

7361

129

6421

6422

360

6553

2226

8463

5225

8441

6932

89915419

5621

4313

372

8459

2671

6674

6522

2682

9610

7764

6642

6535

7129

5839

2221

5111

8932

9410

7411

223

6546

5723

2659

7431

62535541

13

6574

7149

874569317263

2871

7442

7441

65842114

7187

7439

8830

79322923

6852

8732

8481

7284

2640

6973

8471

7412

66127722

2772

7283

2225

6342

6940

62895233

6638

7628

69128812

6541

7781

7757

6538

2232

4235

5824

2450671366476899

67826746

6649

2516

7782

620

2471

6666

483

8122

6593

6671 3354

6415

77837525

7832

77216516

66356747

6724

8952

6727

6731

5157

4242

6745

3415

5148

7521

5161

6770

2771

2654

4239

6641

1110

6784

8121

6978

6596

4307111

7852

5542

6975

8921

7822

6999

89824241

6851

6716

5833

192472

2882

6871913

7161

6651

24832873

71638435

5249

8443

224

6543

6935

5112

7212

87436645

2681

7269

32248989

7144741

6672

7493

6994

66318432

6997

7188

65526544

2926

7522

6591

74346921

7369

8429

6130914

7133

7131

5457428

7148

2922

58388431

6646

121

2672

8997

8999

7452

6353

7213

6511

65142111

4236

2876

7233

89608842

2479

7922

72444312

75992634

116

6549

7931 8972

6760

813

26337224

77537264

7271674969607499

5981

58497138

6822

7119

58428439

7415

6992

736227338462

8973

6954113

74296594

7132

6781

118

343

77636254

4234

5221

8510

7915

5622

6417

7612

562381268412120

723453358993

6512

7621

576

6560

2667

2690

75127638

6341

2331

2713

5122

73676623

7648

21166418

6924

7723

5721

773172676542

7741

7611

7742

7449

4233

6648

89287758

612

582

6519

2741

72595922

7810

67257841

571

459

2517

7853

6572

7861

7924

54125126712

7436

7912

7754

8124

8211

8482

7929

8421

2223

5841

77517245

64136996

589

5795411

6951

561

7435230845184528461

9510

5913

575

452

2632

48187205334

2925

6665

5832

6515

4244

8731

470

874457226118

2613

2666

8811

7139

51457649

711

7831

8821

59828841

5530

6785

6673

6518

51638933

8935

5114

6744

6583564

6359

1222

6597

4113

1121223

8813

5147

2231

8994

7928

8464

2117

5241

62819110 7921

9310

8981

8924

114

678327845823

87485323

65716424

814

2929

2714

2235

54152238

6114

8931

7423

12216539

8998

2320

2519

5822

6123

7631

5829

6732

1124

5224

6863

8112875

6344

8946

7243

1121

7371

7752

2783

574

6428

422

2874

6974

5543

6532

7821

23328749

2927

6210

723

27347433

25186611

72522234

3223

6741980

7868

751

5154

7414

7272

5231

5222752865173353

546

6579

730

3351

4402655

8422

6750

3222

2665

721

7591

752

278626513447849

146639

6644

2224

6551

6633

2683616

7938

7933

2239

7211

5322

2687

611

6658

6595

6534

77886411

583

7851

2119

89596794

6733240

577

2482

8942

6545

84657913

66437112

5123

252

7373

2815

8851

72687421

2685

6618

548

7712

5239

8741

69987732

5657281

251

5311

5421123

6592

5912

59218434

5852

2890

488484

4243

8947

8742

1213

5448310

7923

82122919

460

75116842

7219

2460

111

6419

2782

3352

3221

6652

2732

69936575

5146712

3232

3330

34136573

7842

2511

26865416

8472

3414

7432

8423

7622

5843

5834

2860

5139

4111

513773725138

8219

42326624

6112

6637

2911

8822

5121

5414

585

8983

573

7246

7491

2731

51628974

3345

722365816991

7162 342

89226891

6589

7126

4245

6811

4314

350

7169

6577

4249

6880

8483

141

4311

115

61216793

9710

6576

2881

8424

11371

6832

6122

7911

6821

12

482

58367451

411

263184846354

910

1112

1314

Tot

al E

mig

rant

s

6 8 10 12 14Estimated Total Emigrants

Emigrants Fitted values

Emigrants

United States, Year 1990

36

Page 37: Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative ...sites.bu.edu/neudc/files/2014/10/paper_108.pdf · Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative Advantage of Nations

Table 1: Summary StatisticsVariable N Mean sd Min Max

Panel A: Extensive Margin Sample (RCAc,p,t = 0)New Product (RCA>1) 83,100 0.016 0.13 0.0 1.0New Product (RCA>1, Exc. Bilateral) 83,100 0.015 0.12 0.0 1.0Migrants, total 83,100 64,281.9 171,431.6 0.0 6,475,689.0Immigrants 83,100 14,284.6 69,813.4 0.0 3,141,585.0Emigrants 83,100 49,997.3 139,620.6 0.0 6,398,312.0Migrants (Unskilled), total 83,100 49,549.0 146,947.0 0.0 5,519,892.0Immigrants (Unskilled) 83,100 12,415.7 62,648.9 0.0 3,128,850.0Emigrants (Unskilled) 83,100 37,133.3 116,694.3 0.0 5,473,783.0Migrants (Skilled), total 83,100 14,732.9 39,517.1 0.0 1,100,395.0Immigrants (Skilled) 83,100 1,869.0 9,728.5 0.0 441,937.0Emigrants (Skilled) 83,100 12,864.0 37,028.3 0.0 1,078,071.0FDI (total, mn USD) 83,100 508.1 15,174.1 0.0 2,239,724.0Trade (total, mn USD) 83,100 9,542.2 33,089.9 0.0 3,043,429.2Panel B: Intensive Margin Sample (exportsc,p,t > 0)Growth Exports 127,770 0.048 0.30 -0.9 4.4Growth Exports (Exc. Bilateral) 127,770 0.291 0.75 -0.8 6.8Baseline Exports 127,770 13.951 3.73 0.9 25.4Migrants, total 127,770 362,313.4 766,143.4 0.0 16,381,010.0Immigrants 127,770 171,004.1 585,556.2 0.0 16,196,984.0Emigrants 127,770 191,309.4 447,325.1 0.0 6,467,568.0Migrants (Unskilled), total 127,770 257,023.6 551,693.8 0.0 10,635,011.0Immigrants (Unskilled) 127,770 121,784.9 393,248.4 0.0 10,529,596.0Emigrants (Unskilled) 127,770 135,238.7 362,121.0 0.0 5,522,274.0Migrants (Skilled), total 127,770 105,289.8 268,256.5 0.0 5,798,469.0Immigrants (Skilled) 127,770 49,219.2 221,873.6 0.0 5,667,388.0Emigrants (Skilled) 127,770 56,070.6 120,796.6 0.0 1,466,219.0FDI (total, mn USD) 127,770 128,033.7 577,972.5 0.0 11,705,466.0Trade (total, mn USD) 127,770 248,415.3 608,942.6 0.0 9,570,523.0

37

Page 38: Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative ...sites.bu.edu/neudc/files/2014/10/paper_108.pdf · Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative Advantage of Nations

Table 2: Correlation Matrix International Flows (log)

Variables Migrants (asinh) FDI (asinh) Trade (asinh)

Migrants (asinh) 1.000FDI (asinh) 0.332 1.000Trade (asinh) 0.528 0.722 1.000

38

Page 39: Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative ...sites.bu.edu/neudc/files/2014/10/paper_108.pdf · Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative Advantage of Nations

Table 3: Correlation Matrix International Flows (per capita)

Variables Migrants PerCap FDI PerCap Trade PerCap

Migrants PerCap 1.000FDI PerCap 0.152 1.000Trade PerCap 0.409 0.539 1.000

39

Page 40: Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative ...sites.bu.edu/neudc/files/2014/10/paper_108.pdf · Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative Advantage of Nations

Table 4: Ordinary Least SquaresPanel A: Extensive Margin

All Unskilled Skilled

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5)Total Migrants 0.0021 0.0020 0.0024

(0.001)*** (0.001)*** (0.001)***Immigrants 0.0007 0.0013

(0.000)*** (0.000)***Emigrants 0.0019 0.0018

(0.001)*** (0.001)**Total FDI 0.0010 0.0010 0.0010 0.0010 0.0009

(0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001)Total Trade -0.0064 -0.0064 -0.0069 -0.0066 -0.0072

(0.003)* (0.003)* (0.003)** (0.003)** (0.003)**

N 83100 83100 83100 83100 83100r2 0.15 0.15 0.15 0.15 0.15Panel B: Intensive Margin

All Unskilled Skilled

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5)Total Migrants 0.0084 0.0084 0.0026

(0.002)*** (0.001)*** (0.002)Immigrants 0.0045 0.0057

(0.001)*** (0.001)***Emigrants 0.0076 0.0011

(0.001)*** (0.002)Total FDI -0.0005 -0.0005 -0.0006 -0.0004 -0.0005

(0.000)* (0.000)* (0.000)** (0.000) (0.000)**Total Trade 0.0114 0.0107 0.0050 0.0179 0.0115

(0.004)** (0.005)** (0.004) (0.004)*** (0.004)***Baseline Exports -0.0418 -0.0418 -0.0424 -0.0414 -0.0420

(0.002)*** (0.002)*** (0.002)*** (0.002)*** (0.002)***Previous Exports Log-Growth -0.0058 -0.0058 -0.0058 -0.0059 -0.0058

(0.001)*** (0.001)*** (0.001)*** (0.001)*** (0.001)***Zero Exports in t-1 -0.0873 -0.0874 -0.0863 -0.0874 -0.0867

(0.007)*** (0.007)*** (0.007)*** (0.007)*** (0.007)***

N 127770 127770 127770 127770 127770r2 0.34 0.34 0.34 0.34 0.34

All specifications include country-by-year and product-by-year fixed effects. SE clustered at the country level pre-

sented in parenthesis∗p < 0.10,∗∗ p < 0.05,∗∗∗ p < 0.01

40

Page 41: Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative ...sites.bu.edu/neudc/files/2014/10/paper_108.pdf · Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative Advantage of Nations

Table 5: OLS, excluding bilateral exports (500 migrants threshold)Panel A: Extensive Margin

All Unskilled Skilled

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5)Total Migrants 0.0020 0.0020 0.0022

(0.001)*** (0.001)*** (0.001)***Immigrants 0.0006 0.0014

(0.000)** (0.000)***Emigrants 0.0016 0.0012

(0.001)*** (0.001)*Total FDI 0.0010 0.0010 0.0010 0.0010 0.0010

(0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001)Total Trade -0.0070 -0.0070 -0.0073 -0.0070 -0.0076

(0.004)* (0.004)* (0.004)** (0.004)* (0.004)**

N 83100 83100 83100 83100 83100r2 0.12 0.12 0.12 0.12 0.12Panel B: Intensive Margin

All Unskilled Skilled

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5)Total Migrants 0.0236 0.0238 0.0093

(0.004)*** (0.003)*** (0.003)***Immigrants 0.0110 0.0142

(0.002)*** (0.002)***Emigrants 0.0190 0.0052

(0.003)*** (0.004)Total FDI -0.0013 -0.0013 -0.0015 -0.0011 -0.0015

(0.001)*** (0.001)** (0.001)*** (0.000)** (0.001)***Total Trade 0.0212 0.0192 0.0083 0.0378 0.0219

(0.009)** (0.009)** (0.009) (0.008)*** (0.009)***Baseline Exports (Exc. Bilateral) -0.0955 -0.0955 -0.0959 -0.0952 -0.0956

(0.002)*** (0.002)*** (0.002)*** (0.002)*** (0.002)***Previous Exports Growth (Exc. Bilateral) -0.0015 -0.0014 -0.0014 -0.0016 -0.0015

(0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002)Zero Exports in t-1 (Exc. Bilateral) -0.1678 -0.1676 -0.1649 -0.1690 -0.1662

(0.012)*** (0.012)*** (0.012)*** (0.012)*** (0.012)***

N 127770 127770 127770 127770 127770r2 0.46 0.46 0.46 0.46 0.46

All specifications include country-by-year and product-by-year fixed effects. The dependent variable in all specifications is con-

structed using exports of country c to the whole world excluding to countries c′ where total migration between c and c′ exceeds 500

people.∗p < 0.10,∗∗ p < 0.05,∗∗∗ p < 0.01

41

Page 42: Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative ...sites.bu.edu/neudc/files/2014/10/paper_108.pdf · Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative Advantage of Nations

Table 6: OLS, Placebo TestPanel A: Extensive Margin

All Unskilled Skilled

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5)Total Migrants -0.0009 -0.0009 -0.0006

(0.001)* (0.001) (0.000)*Immigrants -0.0003 -0.0007

(0.000) (0.000)**Emigrants -0.0008 0.0003

(0.000)** (0.000)Total FDI 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000

(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)Total Trade 0.0018 0.0018 0.0018 0.0017 0.0017

(0.001)** (0.001)** (0.001)** (0.001)** (0.001)**

N 83100 83100 83100 83100 83100r2 0.12 0.12 0.12 0.12 0.12Panel B: Intensive Margin

All Unskilled Skilled

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5)Total Migrants -0.0115 -0.0115 -0.0121

(0.002)*** (0.002)*** (0.002)***Immigrants -0.0055 -0.0054

(0.002)*** (0.002)***Emigrants -0.0087 -0.0080

(0.001)*** (0.002)***Total FDI -0.0014 -0.0014 -0.0011 -0.0014 -0.0010

(0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001)Total Trade -0.0051 -0.0051 -0.0047 -0.0056 -0.0058

(0.002)*** (0.002)*** (0.002)*** (0.001)*** (0.001)***Baseline Exports (Exc. Bilateral) -0.0949 -0.0949 -0.0949 -0.0948 -0.0949

(0.002)*** (0.002)*** (0.002)*** (0.002)*** (0.002)***Previous Exports Growth (Exc. Bilateral) -0.0020 -0.0020 -0.0020 -0.0020 -0.0019

(0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002)Zero Exports in t-1 (Exc. Bilateral) -0.1676 -0.1676 -0.1670 -0.1673 -0.1673

(0.012)*** (0.012)*** (0.012)*** (0.012)*** (0.012)***

N 127770 127770 127770 127770 127770r2 0.46 0.46 0.46 0.46 0.46

All specifications include country-by-year and product-by-year fixed effects. The dependent variable in all specifications is con-

structed using exports of country c to the whole world. The migration independent variables sum all migrants from and in countries

with no exports for product p∗p < 0.10,∗∗ p < 0.05,∗∗∗ p < 0.01

42

Page 43: Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative ...sites.bu.edu/neudc/files/2014/10/paper_108.pdf · Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative Advantage of Nations

Table 7: Gravity Models ResultsDependent Variable: Bilateral Migrants Stocks

OLS ln(x) OLS ln(x+1) Heckman PPMLDistance (log) -0.8989 -0.8130 -0.3695 -0.7596

(0.075)*** (0.076)*** (0.084)*** (0.117)***Share Border 1.1262 3.4311 0.5031 1.3413

(0.163)*** (0.293)*** (0.151)*** (0.240)***Same Continent/Region 1.1199 1.0540 1.0946 1.0869

(0.118)*** (0.115)*** (0.072)*** (0.194)***Colony-Colonizer Relationship 1.8456 2.8853 0.4185 1.9555

(0.212)*** (0.296)*** (0.250)* (0.204)***Common Colonizer 1.1260 0.7854 1.5246 1.0443

(0.293)*** (0.147)*** (0.111)*** (0.260)***Common Language 0.7468 0.4457 0.2954 0.7065

(0.139)*** (0.106)*** (0.095)*** (0.157)***Same Religion 0.6880 0.7406 0.3519 0.6692

(0.349)* (0.284)** (0.161)** (0.274)**Distance (log) X Yr2000 -0.0112 -0.1318 -0.0185 -0.0078

(0.057) (0.044)*** (0.038) (0.039)Share Border X Yr2000 -0.0888 0.0473 -0.1027 -0.0559

(0.094) (0.134) (0.153) (0.126)Same Continent/Region X Yr2000 -0.2379 -0.0194 -0.2297 -0.2853

(0.091)*** (0.076) (0.085)*** (0.086)***Colony-Colonizer Relationship X Yr2000 -0.1544 0.1304 -0.1453 -0.3276

(0.088)* (0.103) (0.184) (0.084)***Common Colonizer X Yr2000 -0.0085 -0.1089 0.0034 -0.1554

(0.109) (0.074) (0.109) (0.112)Common Language X Yr2000 -0.0623 0.0740 -0.0845 0.1760

(0.073) (0.077) (0.082) (0.070)**Same Religion X Yr2000 0.0534 -0.0997 0.0639 -0.2523

(0.206) (0.235) (0.183) (0.126)**Constant 14.1277 8.6394 11.4382 11.5991

(0.720)*** (0.741)*** (0.666)*** (0.898)***

N 12937 44700 44700 44104r2 0.72 0.41 0.41 0.80

All specifications include sending country, receiving country and year fixed effects. All models use a log transformation

for the dependend variable except for the PPML model, which uses untransformed levels. SE clustered at the receiving

country level presented in parenthesis.∗p < 0.10,∗∗ p < 0.05,∗∗∗ p < 0.01

43

Page 44: Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative ...sites.bu.edu/neudc/files/2014/10/paper_108.pdf · Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative Advantage of Nations

Table 8: PPML Gravity Models Results

Dependent Variable: Bilateral Migrants Stocks

Total Unskilled SkilledDistance (log) -0.7596 -0.8610 -0.4079

(0.117)*** (0.121)*** (0.100)***Share Border 1.3413 1.3939 0.7979

(0.240)*** (0.233)*** (0.241)***Same Continent/Region 1.0869 1.1460 0.7876

(0.194)*** (0.198)*** (0.190)***Colony-Colonizer Relationship 1.9555 2.0536 1.8268

(0.204)*** (0.222)*** (0.178)***Common Colonizer 1.0443 0.9564 1.4494

(0.260)*** (0.253)*** (0.354)***Common Language 0.7065 0.6838 0.8950

(0.157)*** (0.166)*** (0.147)***Same Religion 0.6692 0.6213 0.9325

(0.274)** (0.294)** (0.176)***Distance (log) X Yr2000 -0.0078 -0.0175 -0.0284

(0.039) (0.039) (0.067)Share Border X Yr2000 -0.0559 -0.0237 -0.1060

(0.126) (0.125) (0.189)Same Continent/Region X Yr2000 -0.2853 -0.3015 -0.1630

(0.086)*** (0.106)*** (0.070)**Colony-Colonizer Relationship X Yr2000 -0.3276 -0.3671 -0.2329

(0.084)*** (0.102)*** (0.074)***Common Colonizer X Yr2000 -0.1554 -0.1052 -0.3257

(0.112) (0.116) (0.151)**Common Language X Yr2000 0.1760 0.1553 0.1609

(0.070)** (0.083)* (0.043)***Same Religion X Yr2000 -0.2523 -0.2322 -0.2962

(0.126)** (0.144) (0.100)***Constant 11.1263 11.7079 6.3518

(0.958)*** (0.983)*** (0.778)***

N 44104 43808 42328r2 0.80 0.82 0.78

All specifications include sending country, receiving country and year fixed effects. SE clustered

at the receiving country level presented in parenthesis.∗p < 0.10,∗∗ p < 0.05,∗∗∗ p < 0.01

44

Page 45: Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative ...sites.bu.edu/neudc/files/2014/10/paper_108.pdf · Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative Advantage of Nations

Table 9: Instrumental Variables Estimation (GMM)Panel A: Extensive Margin

All Unskilled Skilled

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5)Total Migrants 0.0084 0.0080 0.0068

(0.003)*** (0.003)*** (0.003)**Immigrants 0.0036 0.0063

(0.001)*** (0.003)**Emigrants 0.0047 0.0014

(0.002)** (0.001)Total FDI 0.0009 0.0009 0.0008 0.0009 0.0007

(0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001)Total Trade -0.0114 -0.0114 -0.0126 -0.0102 -0.0124

(0.005)** (0.005)** (0.005)** (0.005)** (0.006)**

N 83099 83099 83099 83099 83099r2 0.11 0.11 0.11 0.12 0.11KP F Stat 341.22 311.28 80.45 331.18 55.21Panel B: Intensive Margin

All Unskilled Skilled

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5)Total Migrants 0.0515 0.0527 0.0146

(0.007)*** (0.007)*** (0.007)*Immigrants 0.0357 0.0579

(0.005)*** (0.008)***Emigrants 0.0433 -0.0041

(0.009)*** (0.009)Total FDI -0.0018 -0.0018 -0.0024 -0.0012 -0.0026

(0.001)*** (0.001)*** (0.001)*** (0.001)** (0.001)***Total Trade -0.0082 -0.0136 -0.0553 0.0331 -0.0296

(0.012) (0.012) (0.014)*** (0.010)*** (0.014)**Baseline Exports (Exc. Bilateral) -0.0960 -0.0961 -0.0973 -0.0952 -0.0971

(0.002)*** (0.002)*** (0.002)*** (0.002)*** (0.002)***Previous Exports Growth (Exc. Bilateral) -0.0013 -0.0012 -0.0009 -0.0016 -0.0011

(0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002)Zero Exports in t-1 (Exc. Bilateral) -0.1662 -0.1657 -0.1572 -0.1689 -0.1582

(0.012)*** (0.012)*** (0.012)*** (0.012)*** (0.012)***

N 127770 127770 127770 127770 127770r2 0.46 0.46 0.45 0.46 0.45KP F Stat 254.97 284.80 49.82 249.51 55.36

All specifications include country-by-year and product-by-year fixed effects. The dependent variable in all specifications is con-

structed using exports of country c to the whole world excluding to countries c′ where total migration between c and c′ exceeds 500

people. The instrumental variables are based on the estimation of a gravity model using the PPML methodology. SE clustered at

the country level presented in parenthesis.∗p < 0.10,∗∗ p < 0.05,∗∗∗ p < 0.01

45

Page 46: Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative ...sites.bu.edu/neudc/files/2014/10/paper_108.pdf · Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative Advantage of Nations

Table 10: Skilled vs. Unskilled Migration on the Extensive Margin

Immigrants Emmigrants

N βUnskilledim βSkilled

im Ratio βUnskilledem βSkilled

em RatioAll Observations 83100 0.014*** 0.020** 1.44 0.008 -0.002 .

Non OECD 79504 0.010*** 0.011* 1.06 0.004 -0.000 .

OECD 3596 0.053*** 0.217 4.12 0.058* -0.188 .

Period 1990-2000 50143 0.017** 0.031** 1.85 0.017* -0.003 .

Period 2000-2010 32957 0.007*** 0.004 0.52 -0.002 -0.003 .

Animal and vegetable oils, fats & waxes 2600 -0.009 0.001 . 0.013 0.001 0.05

Beverages & tobacco 1153 0.016 0.024* 1.48 -0.006 -0.010 .

Chemical and related products, n.e.s. 11119 0.001 0.009 13.54 0.015 0.003 0.21

Commodities & transactions not classified 514 0.047* 0.038* 0.82 -0.030 -0.071 .

Crude materials, inedible, except fuels 13969 0.012*** 0.013*** 1.09 -0.001 -0.004 .

Food & live animals 10103 0.014*** 0.015*** 1.08 0.003 -0.005 .

Machinery & transport equipment 15126 0.015 0.029* 1.92 -0.001 -0.020 .

Manufactured goods classified by material 19979 0.022** 0.025** 1.12 -0.000 -0.005 .

Mineral fuels, lubricants & related materials 2470 0.022** 0.018 0.82 -0.014 -0.008 .

Miscellaneous manufactured articles 6067 0.026 0.030 1.18 0.015 0.011 0.71

Above Median Capital Intensity 30378 0.007 0.018* 2.71 0.012 -0.004 .

Below Median Capital Intensity 33778 0.015*** 0.020*** 1.35 0.002 -0.004 .

Differentiated Goods 37759 0.017** 0.021* 1.29 0.006 -0.002 .

Homogenous and Reference-Priced Goods 34653 0.011*** 0.017*** 1.46 0.006 -0.003 .

This table summarizes IV regressions for different cuts of the sample. The reported beta coefficients are standardized. The dependent

variable in all specifications is constructed using exports of country c to the whole world excluding to countries c′ where total migration

between c and c′ exceeds 500 people. Significance levels reported based on SE clustered at the country level.

46

Page 47: Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative ...sites.bu.edu/neudc/files/2014/10/paper_108.pdf · Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative Advantage of Nations

A Appendix

A.1 Substituting CAGR with log-growth as the depen-

dent variable

Throughout the paper, when studying the intensive margin, we define the de-

pendent variable as the ten year CAGR for a given product, as defined in Section

3.2. Table A1 shows the results are robust to constructing the dependent vari-

able using log-growth, such that:

Yc,p,t→T =ln(exportsc,p,T )− ln(exportsc,p,t)

T − tif exportsc,p,t > 0

[Table A1 about here.]

Note that the results of Table A1 estimates the instrumental variables model,

and excludes from the constructed dependent variable all bilateral trade to the

countries where migrants are in or from, whenever immigrants plus emigrants

exceeds 500 people.

A.2 Instruments using Heckman’s (1979) Selection model

Following Helpman et. al. (2008), we construct instruments that are based on a

migration gravity equation that uses the Heckman selection model. The model

uses the same structure discussed in Section 4.3. However, for the first stage of

the selection model, we use the unemployment rate in the receiving country as

our exclusion variable.

The use of this variable aims to capture the some fix cost of adaptation to a

new country for the migrant. The assumption is that working age immigrants

will be less likely to emigrate to a country with a higher unemployment rate

given the difficulties they will face in finding a job. However, this variable

proxies for a fix cost of entry to the job market, which is in the spirit of the

exclusion variables used by Helpman et. al. (2008).

Table A2 presents results of the gravity model using the Heckman selection

estimation.

[Table A2 about here.]

The table presents results for estimating both total and skilled migrants

stock. The odd columns present the second stage of the selection model while

47

Page 48: Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative ...sites.bu.edu/neudc/files/2014/10/paper_108.pdf · Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative Advantage of Nations

the even columns present the first stage maximum likelihood estimators for the

selection equation.

Notice first that the signs of the exclusion variable, the unemployment rate,

is negative. This implies that the likelihood of migrating is lower when the

unemployment rate is higher, as expected. Interestingly, the second-stage coef-

ficients for both total and skilled migration are similar, as opposed to Table 8,

where the estimates differ substantially in most variables. Nevertheless, in both

specifications (all and skilled), we can see that the reported λ is statistically

significant, implying that the inverse Mills ratio is statistically significant in the

second stage.

We use these results to create an alternative instrument by computing the

expected bilateral migration stocks and following the procedure described in

Section 4.3. The results of the IV regressions using the Heckman-based instru-

ments are presented in Table A3 and are similar in magnitude to those in Table

9 which uses instead as an instrument the expected migration stocks based on

the PPML estimator.

[Table A3 about here.]

A.3 Including Hausmann and Klinger (2007) Density Vari-

able

Table A4 presents results which include as control the “density” of the country

in the product at the beginning of the period. The variable “density”, which

distributes between 0 and 1, was developed by Hausmann and Klinger (2006)

and used in Hidalgo et. al. (2007). It measures the intensity with which a

country exports products that are strongly co-exported by other countries who

also export the product under consideration. In other words, the density of a

product proxies for the existence of other exports that share similar technolo-

gies or inputs (as measured by their co-occurrence across countries). Density

strongly affects the likelihood that a country adds the product to its export

basket (Hausmann & Klinger, 2007; C. A. Hidalgo et al. 2007). We use density

to control for the likelihood that a country would export a new good given the

initial composition of its export basket.

[Table A4 about here.]

48

Page 49: Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative ...sites.bu.edu/neudc/files/2014/10/paper_108.pdf · Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative Advantage of Nations

A.4 Excluding Bilateral Exports

To clear any doubt of endogeneity in our instrumental variables implementation,

which estimates bilateral migration stocks through a gravity model, our depen-

dent variable Yc,p,t→T excludes all exports to countries when migrants are in or

from. This methodology also allow us to rule out a story in which our results

are driven by lower bilateral trade transaction costs induced by the presence of

migrants, as Aubry et. al. (2012) suggest.

This constraint, as explained above, requires from us to define an arbitrary

threshold on the amount of migrants above for which bilateral exports should

be excluded from exports to the rest of the world to construct Yc,p,t→T . In the

main body of the paper we choose to exclude all bilateral exports to countries

for which there are over 500 combined immigrants and emigrants. This reduces

world trade by about 93% (see Figure 3).

Tables A5 to A7 present results using as thresholds 1000, 2500 and 5000

migrants, to complement the result in the main body of the paper that uses the

500 threshold.

[Table A5 about here.]

[Table A6 about here.]

[Table A7 about here.]

A.5 Modifying Weights in Right Hand Side

Specification (1) suggests using RCAc′,p,t = 1 to define Rc′,p,t, in order to

produce weights for the sum of migration, trade and FDI figures. Table A8

presents results that use RCAc′,p,t = 2 for robustness purposes.

[Table A8 about here.]

49

Page 50: Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative ...sites.bu.edu/neudc/files/2014/10/paper_108.pdf · Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative Advantage of Nations

Table A1: IV Estimation GMM (Intensive Margin Using Log-Growth)Dependent Variable: 10 Year Average Log-Growth, Excluding Bilateral Trade

All Unskilled Skilled

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5)Total Migrants 0.0343 0.0351 0.0088

(0.006)*** (0.005)*** (0.006)Immigrants 0.0250 0.0408

(0.003)*** (0.006)***Emigrants 0.0305 -0.0021

(0.007)*** (0.006)Total FDI -0.0011 -0.0011 -0.0016 -0.0008 -0.0018

(0.000)*** (0.000)*** (0.000)*** (0.000)** (0.001)***Total Trade -0.0020 -0.0056 -0.0370 0.0263 -0.0200

(0.008) (0.008) (0.010)*** (0.007)*** (0.010)**Baseline Exports (Exc. Bilateral) -0.0638 -0.0639 -0.0648 -0.0633 -0.0646

(0.001)*** (0.001)*** (0.001)*** (0.001)*** (0.001)***Previous Exports Growth (Exc. Bilateral) -0.0106 -0.0105 -0.0103 -0.0108 -0.0104

(0.002)*** (0.002)*** (0.002)*** (0.002)*** (0.002)***Zero Exports in t-1 (Exc. Bilateral) -0.1204 -0.1201 -0.1139 -0.1222 -0.1146

(0.008)*** (0.008)*** (0.008)*** (0.008)*** (0.008)***

N 127770 127770 127770 127770 127770r2 0.49 0.49 0.49 0.49 0.48KP F Stat 254.97 284.80 49.82 249.51 55.36

All specifications include country-by-year and product-by-year fixed effects. The dependent variable in all specifications is con-

structed using exports of country c to the whole world excluding to countries c′ where total migration between c and c′ exceeds 500

people. SE clustered at the country level presented in parenthesis.∗p < 0.10,∗∗ p < 0.05,∗∗∗ p < 0.01

50

Page 51: Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative ...sites.bu.edu/neudc/files/2014/10/paper_108.pdf · Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative Advantage of Nations

Table A2: Heckman Selection Gravity Models ResultsDependent Variable: Bilateral Migrants Stocks

All Unskilled Skilled

2nd Stage Select 2nd Stage Select 2nd Stage SelectDistance (log) -0.3695 -0.4018 -0.4291 -0.4199 -0.0161 -0.3884

(0.084)*** (0.010)*** (0.081)*** (0.010)*** (0.117) (0.010)***Share Border 0.5031 0.8462 0.7205 0.8338 0.1527 0.4426

(0.151)*** (0.054)*** (0.141)*** (0.054)*** (0.159) (0.047)***Same Continent/Region 1.0946 -0.0075 1.0534 -0.0010 1.2299 -0.1224

(0.072)*** (0.021) (0.071)*** (0.021) (0.082)*** (0.021)***Colony-Colonizer Relationship 0.4185 1.4625 0.6587 1.4691 0.2302 1.1743

(0.250)* (0.070)*** (0.234)*** (0.069)*** (0.312) (0.060)***Common Colonizer 1.5246 -0.3143 1.4441 -0.3033 2.3109 -0.5117

(0.111)*** (0.026)*** (0.108)*** (0.026)*** (0.180)*** (0.028)***Common Language 0.2954 0.3287 0.3217 0.3283 0.3625 0.3154

(0.095)*** (0.021)*** (0.092)*** (0.021)*** (0.117)*** (0.022)***Same Religion 0.3519 0.2152 0.3792 0.2401 0.1039 0.2570

(0.161)** (0.047)*** (0.160)** (0.047)*** (0.180) (0.047)***Distance (log) X Yr2000 -0.0185 -0.0465 -0.0507

(0.038) (0.039) (0.037)Share Border X Yr2000 -0.1027 -0.0834 -0.1186

(0.153) (0.149) (0.160)Same Continent/Region X Yr2000 -0.2297 -0.2231 -0.2306

(0.085)*** (0.086)*** (0.084)***Colony-Colonizer Relationship X Yr2000 -0.1453 -0.1087 -0.0641

(0.184) (0.177) (0.188)Common Colonizer X Yr2000 0.0034 0.0751 -0.1545

(0.109) (0.111) (0.114)Common Language X Yr2000 -0.0845 -0.1400 -0.1121

(0.082) (0.083)* (0.082)Same Religion X Yr2000 0.0639 0.0673 -0.0259

(0.183) (0.184) (0.181)Unemployment Rate -0.0185 -0.0210 -0.0204

(0.001)*** (0.001)*** (0.001)***Constant 11.4382 3.0074 11.5652 3.1515 7.5288 2.8061

(0.666)*** (0.092)*** (0.667)*** (0.093)*** (0.737)*** (0.093)***

N 44700 44700 44700λ -2.05*** -1.72*** -2.48***

Columns 1 and 3 include sending country, receiving country and year fixed effects. Columns 2 and 4 represent the Maximum Likelihood Estimator

for the first stage of the Heckman selection model, which uses the unemployment rate in the destination country as the exclusion variable.∗p < 0.10,∗∗ p < 0.05,∗∗∗ p < 0.01

51

Page 52: Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative ...sites.bu.edu/neudc/files/2014/10/paper_108.pdf · Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative Advantage of Nations

Table A3: IV Estimation GMM (Heckman-based Instruments)Panel A: Extensive Margin

All Unskilled Skilled

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5)Total Migrants 0.0092 0.0105 0.0138

(0.003)*** (0.003)*** (0.005)***Immigrants 0.0054 0.0059

(0.002)*** (0.003)**Emigrants -0.0004 0.0035

(0.003) (0.003)Total FDI 0.0009 0.0009 0.0008 0.0008 0.0007

(0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001)Total Trade -0.0120 -0.0133 -0.0112 -0.0150 -0.0132

(0.005)** (0.006)** (0.005)** (0.007)** (0.006)**

N 83099 83099 83099 83099 83099r2 0.11 0.11 0.11 0.10 0.11KP F Stat 173.45 104.13 19.44 102.59 23.01Panel B: Intensive Margin

All Unskilled Skilled

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5)Total Migrants 0.1140 0.1034 0.1469

(0.015)*** (0.012)*** (0.023)***Immigrants 0.0331 0.0455

(0.007)*** (0.010)***Emigrants 0.0521 0.0701

(0.015)*** (0.028)**Total FDI -0.0028 -0.0026 -0.0025 -0.0038 -0.0037

(0.001)*** (0.001)*** (0.001)*** (0.001)*** (0.001)***Total Trade -0.0742 -0.0709 -0.0618 -0.0855 -0.0803

(0.019)*** (0.018)*** (0.015)*** (0.024)*** (0.022)***Baseline Exports (Exc. Bilateral) -0.0971 -0.0971 -0.0974 -0.0964 -0.0971

(0.002)*** (0.002)*** (0.002)*** (0.002)*** (0.002)***Previous Exports Growth (Exc. Bilateral) -0.0008 -0.0007 -0.0009 -0.0012 -0.0012

(0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002)Zero Exports in t-1 (Exc. Bilateral) -0.1626 -0.1625 -0.1569 -0.1669 -0.1578

(0.012)*** (0.012)*** (0.012)*** (0.012)*** (0.012)***

N 127770 127770 127770 127770 127770r2 0.45 0.45 0.45 0.43 0.45KP F Stat 61.92 74.92 21.84 34.66 15.93

All specifications include country-by-year and product-by-year fixed effects. The dependent variable in all specifications is con-

structed using exports of country c to the whole world excluding to countries c′ where total migration between c and c′ exceeds

500 people. The instrumental variables are based on the estimation of a gravity model using the Heckman selection model. SE

clustered at the country level presented in parenthesis.∗p < 0.10,∗∗ p < 0.05,∗∗∗ p < 0.01

52

Page 53: Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative ...sites.bu.edu/neudc/files/2014/10/paper_108.pdf · Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative Advantage of Nations

Table A4: IV Estimation GMM (Adding Density as a Control)Panel A: Extensive Margin

All Unskilled Skilled

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5)Total Migrants 0.0082 0.0078 0.0066

(0.003)*** (0.003)*** (0.003)**Immigrants 0.0033 0.0059

(0.001)*** (0.002)**Emigrants 0.0047 0.0015

(0.002)** (0.001)Total FDI 0.0009 0.0009 0.0008 0.0009 0.0007

(0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001)Total Trade -0.0111 -0.0111 -0.0121 -0.0099 -0.0119

(0.005)** (0.005)** (0.005)** (0.005)** (0.006)**Baseline Density 0.2865 0.2841 0.2284 0.2815 0.1946

(0.114)** (0.113)** (0.104)** (0.114)** (0.087)**

N 83099 83099 83099 83099 83099r2 0.11 0.11 0.11 0.12 0.11KP F Stat 339.76 309.22 81.58 332.38 53.14Panel B: Intensive Margin

All Unskilled Skilled

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5)Total Migrants 0.0378 0.0392 0.0110

(0.007)*** (0.006)*** (0.007)*Immigrants 0.0204 0.0288

(0.004)*** (0.006)***Emigrants 0.0275 -0.0036

(0.008)*** (0.008)Total FDI -0.0003 -0.0003 -0.0006 0.0002 -0.0005

(0.000) (0.000) (0.001) (0.000) (0.001)Total Trade -0.0174 -0.0218 -0.0372 0.0125 -0.0126

(0.011)* (0.011)** (0.011)*** (0.009) (0.011)Baseline Exports (Exc. Bilateral) -0.1009 -0.1010 -0.1012 -0.1003 -0.1009

(0.002)*** (0.002)*** (0.002)*** (0.002)*** (0.002)***Previous Exports Growth (Exc. Bilateral) 0.0027 0.0028 0.0026 0.0025 0.0025

(0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002)Zero Exports in t-1 (Exc. Bilateral) -0.1598 -0.1595 -0.1554 -0.1618 -0.1570

(0.012)*** (0.012)*** (0.012)*** (0.012)*** (0.012)***Baseline Density 1.8841 1.8747 1.7542 1.8895 1.7788

(0.188)*** (0.188)*** (0.183)*** (0.188)*** (0.188)***

N 127770 127770 127770 127770 127770r2 0.47 0.47 0.47 0.47 0.47KP F Stat 267.44 294.74 50.97 256.24 56.50

All specifications include country-by-year and product-by-year fixed effects. The dependent variable in all specifications is con-

structed using exports of country c to the whole world excluding to countries c′ where total migration between c and c′ exceeds

500 people. The instrumental variables are based on the estimation of a gravity model using the Heckman selection model. SE

clustered at the country level presented in parenthesis.∗p < 0.10,∗∗ p < 0.05,∗∗∗ p < 0.01

53

Page 54: Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative ...sites.bu.edu/neudc/files/2014/10/paper_108.pdf · Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative Advantage of Nations

Table A5: IV Estimation GMM (Max 1000 Migrants Threshold)Panel A: Extensive Margin

All Unskilled Skilled

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5)Total Migrants 0.0084 0.0081 0.0067

(0.003)*** (0.003)*** (0.003)**Immigrants 0.0033 0.0061

(0.001)*** (0.003)**Emigrants 0.0052 0.0017

(0.003)** (0.001)Total FDI 0.0008 0.0008 0.0007 0.0009 0.0006

(0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001)Total Trade -0.0109 -0.0109 -0.0120 -0.0096 -0.0118

(0.005)** (0.005)** (0.005)** (0.005)** (0.006)**

N 83099 83099 83099 83099 83099r2 0.11 0.11 0.11 0.11 0.10KP F Stat 341.22 311.28 80.45 331.18 55.21Panel B: Intensive Margin

All Unskilled Skilled

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5)Total Migrants 0.0461 0.0476 0.0103

(0.007)*** (0.007)*** (0.007)Immigrants 0.0354 0.0566

(0.005)*** (0.007)***Emigrants 0.0370 -0.0112

(0.009)*** (0.009)Total FDI -0.0018 -0.0018 -0.0024 -0.0013 -0.0025

(0.000)*** (0.001)*** (0.001)*** (0.000)*** (0.001)***Total Trade -0.0021 -0.0074 -0.0470 0.0373 -0.0210

(0.011) (0.012) (0.013)*** (0.009)*** (0.013)Baseline Exports (Exc. Bilateral) -0.0951 -0.0952 -0.0964 -0.0943 -0.0962

(0.002)*** (0.002)*** (0.002)*** (0.002)*** (0.002)***Previous Exports Growth (Exc. Bilateral) -0.0033 -0.0032 -0.0029 -0.0037 -0.0030

(0.002)* (0.002)* (0.002) (0.002)* (0.002)Zero Exports in t-1 (Exc. Bilateral) -0.1624 -0.1622 -0.1543 -0.1640 -0.1559

(0.011)*** (0.011)*** (0.011)*** (0.011)*** (0.011)***

N 127770 127770 127770 127770 127770r2 0.46 0.46 0.46 0.46 0.45KP F Stat 255.21 285.17 49.73 249.57 55.67

All specifications include country-by-year and product-by-year fixed effects. The dependent variable in all specifications is con-

structed using exports of country c to the whole world excluding to countries c′ where total migration between c and c′ exceeds 1000

people. The instrumental variables are based on the estimation of a gravity model using the PPML methodology. SE clustered at

the country level presented in parenthesis.∗p < 0.10,∗∗ p < 0.05,∗∗∗ p < 0.01

54

Page 55: Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative ...sites.bu.edu/neudc/files/2014/10/paper_108.pdf · Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative Advantage of Nations

Table A6: IV Estimation GMM (Max 2500 Migrants Threshold)Panel A: Extensive Margin

All Unskilled Skilled

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5)Total Migrants 0.0090 0.0086 0.0070

(0.003)*** (0.003)*** (0.003)**Immigrants 0.0032 0.0064

(0.001)*** (0.003)**Emigrants 0.0064 0.0022

(0.003)** (0.001)*Total FDI 0.0008 0.0008 0.0007 0.0009 0.0006

(0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001)Total Trade -0.0112 -0.0112 -0.0126 -0.0097 -0.0123

(0.005)** (0.005)** (0.005)** (0.005)* (0.006)**

N 83099 83099 83099 83099 83099r2 0.11 0.11 0.11 0.12 0.11KP F Stat 341.22 311.28 80.45 331.18 55.21Panel B: Intensive Margin

All Unskilled Skilled

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5)Total Migrants 0.0468 0.0482 0.0111

(0.007)*** (0.006)*** (0.007)Immigrants 0.0333 0.0546

(0.005)*** (0.007)***Emigrants 0.0399 -0.0069

(0.009)*** (0.008)Total FDI -0.0017 -0.0017 -0.0023 -0.0011 -0.0024

(0.001)*** (0.001)*** (0.001)*** (0.000)** (0.001)***Total Trade -0.0022 -0.0073 -0.0467 0.0372 -0.0214

(0.011) (0.011) (0.013)*** (0.009)*** (0.013)Baseline Exports (Exc. Bilateral) -0.0947 -0.0949 -0.0962 -0.0939 -0.0959

(0.002)*** (0.002)*** (0.002)*** (0.002)*** (0.002)***Previous Exports Growth (Exc. Bilateral) -0.0056 -0.0055 -0.0050 -0.0061 -0.0052

(0.002)*** (0.002)*** (0.002)*** (0.002)*** (0.002)***Zero Exports in t-1 (Exc. Bilateral) -0.1468 -0.1467 -0.1394 -0.1479 -0.1403

(0.012)*** (0.012)*** (0.012)*** (0.012)*** (0.012)***

N 127770 127770 127770 127770 127770r2 0.47 0.47 0.47 0.47 0.46KP F Stat 255.03 284.93 49.86 249.77 55.45

All specifications include country-by-year and product-by-year fixed effects. The dependent variable in all specifications is con-

structed using exports of country c to the whole world excluding to countries c′ where total migration between c and c′ exceeds 2500

people. The instrumental variables are based on the estimation of a gravity model using the PPML methodology. SE clustered at

the country level presented in parenthesis.∗p < 0.10,∗∗ p < 0.05,∗∗∗ p < 0.01

55

Page 56: Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative ...sites.bu.edu/neudc/files/2014/10/paper_108.pdf · Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative Advantage of Nations

Table A7: IV Estimation GMM (Max 5000 Migrants Threshold)Panel A: Extensive Margin

All Unskilled Skilled

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5)Total Migrants 0.0090 0.0086 0.0069

(0.003)*** (0.003)*** (0.003)**Immigrants 0.0037 0.0068

(0.001)*** (0.003)**Emigrants 0.0060 0.0017

(0.003)** (0.001)Total FDI 0.0007 0.0007 0.0006 0.0008 0.0005

(0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001)Total Trade -0.0110 -0.0110 -0.0127 -0.0095 -0.0123

(0.005)** (0.005)** (0.005)** (0.005)* (0.006)**

N 83099 83099 83099 83099 83099r2 0.11 0.11 0.11 0.12 0.11KP F Stat 341.22 311.28 80.45 331.18 55.21Panel B: Intensive Margin

All Unskilled Skilled

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5)Total Migrants 0.0420 0.0434 0.0076

(0.006)*** (0.006)*** (0.006)Immigrants 0.0317 0.0508

(0.005)*** (0.007)***Emigrants 0.0367 -0.0089

(0.008)*** (0.008)Total FDI -0.0016 -0.0015 -0.0021 -0.0010 -0.0022

(0.000)*** (0.000)*** (0.001)*** (0.000)** (0.001)***Total Trade 0.0010 -0.0038 -0.0426 0.0386 -0.0161

(0.010) (0.010) (0.013)*** (0.009)*** (0.013)Baseline Exports (Exc. Bilateral) -0.0941 -0.0942 -0.0957 -0.0932 -0.0954

(0.002)*** (0.002)*** (0.002)*** (0.002)*** (0.002)***Previous Exports Growth (Exc. Bilateral) -0.0081 -0.0080 -0.0074 -0.0085 -0.0075

(0.002)*** (0.002)*** (0.002)*** (0.002)*** (0.002)***Zero Exports in t-1 (Exc. Bilateral) -0.1286 -0.1286 -0.1217 -0.1296 -0.1227

(0.012)*** (0.012)*** (0.012)*** (0.012)*** (0.012)***

N 127770 127770 127770 127770 127770r2 0.48 0.48 0.48 0.48 0.47KP F Stat 254.38 284.27 49.93 249.32 55.27

All specifications include country-by-year and product-by-year fixed effects. The dependent variable in all specifications is con-

structed using exports of country c to the whole world excluding to countries c′ where total migration between c and c′ exceeds 5000

people. The instrumental variables are based on the estimation of a gravity model using the PPML methodology. SE clustered at

the country level presented in parenthesis.∗p < 0.10,∗∗ p < 0.05,∗∗∗ p < 0.01

56

Page 57: Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative ...sites.bu.edu/neudc/files/2014/10/paper_108.pdf · Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative Advantage of Nations

Table A8: IV Estimation GMM (RCA=2 on RHS)Panel A: Extensive Margin

All Unskilled Skilled

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5)Total Migrants 0.0061 0.0058 0.0058

(0.002)** (0.002)** (0.003)**Immigrants 0.0027 0.0035

(0.001)** (0.002)*Emigrants 0.0037 0.0035

(0.002)* (0.002)*Total FDI 0.0005 0.0005 0.0004 0.0005 0.0004

(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)Total Trade -0.0023 -0.0023 -0.0027 -0.0020 -0.0024

(0.001)** (0.001)** (0.001)** (0.001)* (0.001)**

N 83099 83099 83099 83099 83099r2 0.11 0.11 0.11 0.11 0.11KP F Stat 533.08 538.86 97.37 475.51 60.31Panel B: Intensive Margin

All Unskilled Skilled

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5)Total Migrants 0.0362 0.0364 0.0189

(0.004)*** (0.004)*** (0.005)***Immigrants 0.0224 0.0413

(0.003)*** (0.005)***Emigrants 0.0256 -0.0076

(0.005)*** (0.006)Total FDI 0.0005 0.0005 -0.0004 0.0007 -0.0004

(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)** (0.000)Total Trade -0.0073 -0.0085 -0.0202 0.0071 -0.0089

(0.004)* (0.004)** (0.004)*** (0.004) (0.004)**Baseline Exports (Exc. Bilateral) -0.0960 -0.0961 -0.0970 -0.0953 -0.0966

(0.002)*** (0.002)*** (0.002)*** (0.002)*** (0.002)***Previous Exports Growth (Exc. Bilateral) -0.0011 -0.0011 -0.0009 -0.0015 -0.0012

(0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002)Zero Exports in t-1 (Exc. Bilateral) -0.1665 -0.1662 -0.1608 -0.1688 -0.1626

(0.012)*** (0.012)*** (0.012)*** (0.012)*** (0.012)***

N 127770 127770 127770 127770 127770r2 0.46 0.46 0.46 0.46 0.45KP F Stat 385.13 433.54 83.29 357.65 125.81

All specifications include country-by-year and product-by-year fixed effects. The dependent variable in all specifications is con-

structed using exports of country c to the whole world excluding to countries c′ where total migration between c and c′ exceeds 500

people. SE clustered at the country level presented in parenthesis.∗p < 0.10,∗∗ p < 0.05,∗∗∗ p < 0.01

57