micro review (including externalities)

44
Micro Review (including externalities) Econ 312 Credit to Emma Hutchinson for putting these notes together. They are useful for any microeconomics course with a 103 pre-req

Upload: hoshi

Post on 24-Feb-2016

92 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

DESCRIPTION

Micro Review (including externalities). Econ 312 Credit to Emma Hutchinson for putting these notes together. They are useful for any microeconomics course with a 103 pre- req. Review of Microeconomics. Reading for Micro Review Your principles of micro text and/or notes O’Sullivan appendix - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Micro Review (including externalities)

Micro Review (including externalities)

Econ 312Credit to Emma Hutchinson for

putting these notes together. They are useful for any microeconomics

course with a 103 pre-req

Page 2: Micro Review (including externalities)

Econ 312--Farnham 2

Review of Microeconomics

• Reading for Micro Review– Your principles of micro text and/or notes– O’Sullivan appendix

• In this course we will analyze market outcomes in urban settings with an interest in policy that will correct market failures when such failures occur

• Primary questions throughout:– To what outcomes do markets lead?– Under what circumstances are these outcomes desirable?

– If markets outcomes are undesirable, what would be the desirable outcome? What is the correct policy response?

Page 3: Micro Review (including externalities)

Econ 312--Farnham 3

Review of Microeconomics• Analyzing what happens involves positive analysis

• Terms desirable and undesirable imply we are also interested in normative analysis.

• Positive analysis involves asking what an outcome will be under certain circumstances:– Ex: in equilibrium, how far will people commute to work?

• Normative analysis involves asking questions about what outcomes we would like to see. (what should be)– Ex: what is the right (socially optimal) commuting distance? Is an

hour drive too long? Why?

• Points to the need for a normative criterion by which to judge outcomes as “good” or “bad”.

Page 4: Micro Review (including externalities)

Econ 312--Farnham 4

Review of Microeconomics• Normative criterion we use in economics is typically that of economic

efficiency.

• Important to keep in mind that economic efficiency– has utilitarianism as its philosophical base

– says nothing (much) about fairness or equity

– is only one of many criteria that we can (should?) use to judge market outcomes.

• With these caveats in mind, in this class we will (usually) judge outcomes in terms of whether or not they are economically efficient.– Normative statements like “outcome X should happen” should be

read as shorthand for “outcome X should happen if we are using economic efficiency as the sole criterion for decision-making.”

Page 5: Micro Review (including externalities)

Econ 312--Farnham 5

Review of Microeconomics• Economic efficiency defined:

– An outcome is efficient if it maximizes net benefits, where net benefits are equal to total benefits minus total costs.

• Tells us that, at its core, the analysis of economic efficiency is simply cost-benefit analysis.

• We will be analyzing efficiency in a variety of contexts, such as:1. What is the efficient level of provision of a public service?

• Ex: what is the efficient level of policing?

2. Should we undertake a particular project (binary decision-making)?• Ex: should Victoria build a light-rail transit system?

3. How should we allocate a scarce resource across competing uses?• Ex: how much land on the Saanich Peninsula should be used for

residential building vs. agriculture vs. public parks?

Page 6: Micro Review (including externalities)

Econ 312--Farnham 6

Review of Microeconomics• We will focus on answering questions such as these by using cost-benefit

analysis to identify the outcomes that make net benefits as large as possible.

• Important point: we need to make sure we have correctly identified and measured all of the costs and benefits associated with a given activity/outcome.

• An alternative characterization of efficiency (that we may pick up on at various points throughout the term):– An outcome is efficient if it is impossible to come up with an

alternative outcome in which at least one person can be made better off without any one person being made worse off.

• Although it may not be immediately obvious, we will see that this characterization of efficiency will be satisfied if net benefits are maximized.

Page 7: Micro Review (including externalities)

Econ 312--Farnham 7

Review of Microeconomics• In order to answer normative questions such as those posed above, we

first need to understand how to answer positive questions.

– For instance, we need to understand what market outcomes look like, in order to work out whether they are desirable (efficient).

• This means we need to recall some basic ideas we learned in principles of microeconomics.

• Specifically, we want to understand:1. How consumers decide what goods to buy (demand).2. How producers decide what goods to produce (supply).3. How markets bring producers and consumers together

(equilibrium).

• Once we understand this, we can assess whether consumers and producers act in such a way as to achieve an economically efficient outcome.

Page 8: Micro Review (including externalities)

Econ 312--Farnham 8

Review of Microeconomics1. Review of Demand.

• Three areas to cover on the demand side:

i. Interpreting an individual consumer’s demand curve

ii. Measuring consumer well-being using the demand curve

iii. Deriving aggregate demand from individual demand

Page 9: Micro Review (including externalities)

Econ 312--Farnham 9

Review of Microeconomics: Demandi. Interpreting an individual’s demand curve

• Recall that a demand curve maps out a relationship between price and quantity.

Price (P)

Quantity (Q)

Demand curves usually slope downwards: known as the “law” of demand

while on the vertical axis we are measuring the price per unit (P), in some form of currency (dollars, cents etc)

Remember, on the horizontal axis we are measuring units of the good consumed (Q),

How to interpret this demand curve?

Two interpretations, each of which will be useful, depending on the context.

DemandCurve (D)

Page 10: Micro Review (including externalities)

Econ 312--Farnham 10

Review of Microeconomics: Demand

• The first interpretation of the demand curve is probably the most familiar to you:

P

Q

Interpretation 1: the D curve tells us how many units of a good a consumer wishes to buy in total, at a given price per unit for the good.

For instance, the D curve tells us that if the price per unit is P1, then the consumer would like to buy Q1 units.

We can think of this interpretation as reading the D curve horizontally: that is, if we plug in values for P, we get out values for Q.

D

P1

Q1

etc.Q2

P2

Page 11: Micro Review (including externalities)

Econ 312--Farnham 11

Review of Microeconomics: Demand

• The second interpretation of the demand curve may be less familiar to you:

P

Q

Interpretation 2: the height of the D curve at any given point tells us how the consumer values additional units of the good.

For instance, the D curve tells us that if the consumer currently has Q1 units of the good, then a small increase in quantity would be worth P1 per unit to the consumer.

D

P1

Q1 etc.Q2

P2

We can think of this interpretation as reading the D curve vertically: that is, if we plug in values for Q, we get out values for P.We will elaborate on this interpretation by use of an example.

Page 12: Micro Review (including externalities)

Econ 312--Farnham 12

Review of Microeconomics: Demand

Example: Suppose that demand is given by Q = 5 - (1/2)P.

P($)

Q

From the D function, if P=$10, Q=0 will be demanded.But if P = $8, Q = 1 will be demanded.

consumer’s maximum willingness to pay for the first unit is greater than $8, but less than $10.

D

10

5

So we know that the maximum willingness to pay for the first unit is something less than $10. Can we do better than this?

Area of the rectangle ($10) thus gives an upper bound on consumer’s willingness to pay for the first unit. 1

8

Page 13: Micro Review (including externalities)

Econ 312--Farnham 13

Review of Microeconomics: DemandNow consider smaller changes in P. Say P from $10 to $9 so that Q from 0 to 0.5.

P($)

Q

Consumer did not buy the first half unit when it cost $5, but does when it costs $4.50.

consumer’s maximum willingness to pay for this first half unit is something less than $5.

D

10

0.5

Now suppose P from $9 to $8, so that total Q from 0.5 to 1.

Consumer did not buy the second half unit when it cost $4.50, but does when P falls.

1 5

98

consumer’s maximum willingness to pay for this second half unit is something less than $4.50.This tells us that the consumer’s maximum willingness to pay for the first unit is in fact something less than $9.50 (as opposed to $10).

Page 14: Micro Review (including externalities)

Econ 312--Farnham 14

Review of Microeconomics: DemandWe could consider even smaller changes in prices and quantities.

P($)

Q

For instance we could now lower the price in $0.50 increments, rather than in $1.00 increments.

Doing this allows us to see that the consumer’s maximum willingness to pay for the first unit is something less than $9.25.

D

10

9

8

0.5 1 5

In the limit, as we consider smaller and smaller price changes, what we are doing here is calculating the area under the demand curve between Q=0 and Q=1.

This area tells us the exact maximum willingness to pay by this consumer for the first unit of the good.

In this case, the area of that trapezoid is equal to $9. The consumer is willing to pay at most $9 for the first unit.

Page 15: Micro Review (including externalities)

Econ 312--Farnham 15

Review of Microeconomics: DemandBy the same logic, the area under the demand curve as we increase Q from 1 to 2 units tells us the maximum willingness to pay for the second unit.

P($)

Q

In this case, that area equals $7.

10

1 5

Indeed, the area under a D curve between any two quantities tells us the maximum willingness to pay for that additional quantity.

In the limit, as we consider tiny tiny increases in Q, the base of the trapezoid goes to zero, and the willingness to pay (per unit) for these tiny tiny increases in Q is just equal to the height of the demand curve.

2

6 If we consider very small increases in quantity, than the trapezoid representing the willingness to pay has a very small base.

8

Page 16: Micro Review (including externalities)

Econ 312--Farnham 16

Review of Microeconomics: DemandThis is the logic behind the second interpretation of the demand curve, that the height at any point tells us how consumers value small Q.

P($)

Q

As we have seen, this is equivalent to telling us how much the consumer is willing to pay for small Q.

When we are thinking about the D curve in this way, we will refer to it variously as the:

We can also think about this as telling us how much additional benefit a consumer would get from a small Q.

1. Marginal Value (MV) curve2. Marginal Willingness to Pay (MWP) curve3. Marginal Benefit (MB) curve

Note that these terms are equivalent!

Page 17: Micro Review (including externalities)

Econ 312--Farnham 17

Review of Microeconomics: Demandii. Measuring consumer well-being using the demand curve.

P($)

Q

1st interpretation of D curve: tells us Q demanded at a given P.

But, how much did consumer actually have to pay for Q1?

2nd interpretation of D curve: area under the D curve measures consumer’s willingness to pay for Q1 units.

Definition: consumer surplus (CS) = what a consumer is willing to pay minus what they have to pay.

P1

Q1

Expenditure (price times quantity) given by area P1Q1.

consumer willing to pay more than she has to pay.

Difference between willingness to pay and expenditure measures consumer well-being.

In the diagram above, the CS from buying Q1 units at P1 per unit is equal to the triangle A.

A

Page 18: Micro Review (including externalities)

Econ 312--Farnham 18

Topic 1(b): Review of Consumer Theoryiii. Deriving aggregate demand from individual demand

P

QA

Suppose two individuals - A and B - each with D curves drawn below.

At P1, A demands Q1A and B demands Q1

B.

P1

QA1

We are horizontally aggregating individual demands to get aggregate demand.

DA

QB

QB1

DB

QA1+QB

1QA

2 QB2 QA

2+QB2

Aggregate D

P2

Aggregate demand at P1 therefore equals Q1A + Q1

B.

At P2, A demands Q2A, B demands Q2

B, and agg. D = Q2A

+ Q2B.

P

Page 19: Micro Review (including externalities)

Econ 312--Farnham 19

Topic 1: Introduction and Review1. Review of Supply.

• Three areas to cover on the supply side:

i. Interpreting an individual producer’s supply curveii. Measuring producer well-being using the supply curveiii. Deriving aggregate supply from individual supply

Page 20: Micro Review (including externalities)

Econ 312--Farnham 20

Topic 1: Introduction and Review: Supplyi. Interpreting a firm’s supply curve

• Recall that a supply curve maps out a relationship between price and quantity.

Price (P)

Quantity (Q)

Supply curves usually slope upwards: known as the “law” of supply

i.e., firms that take the prices of output and inputs as given.

NB: Throughout this class we will only be looking at the supply behavior of competitive firms.

How to interpret this supply curve?

Like D curve, there are two interpretations of the S curve.

SupplyCurve (S)

Page 21: Micro Review (including externalities)

Econ 312--Farnham 21

Topic 1: Introduction and Review: Supply

• The first interpretation of the supply curve is (again) probably most familiar:

P

Q

Interpretation 1: S curve tells us how many units of a good a producer wishes to sell in total, at a given price per unit for the good.

If the price per unit is P1, then the firm would like to sell Q1 units. etc, etc.

We can think of this interpretation as reading the S curve horizontally: that is, if we plug in values for P, we get out values for Q.

SP1

Q1

Page 22: Micro Review (including externalities)

Econ 312--Farnham 22

Topic 1: Introduction and Review: Supply

• The second interpretation of the supply curve should also be (relatively) familiar:

P

Q

Interpretation 2: the height of the S curve at any given point tells us how much additional units of the good cost to produce.

i.e., the supply curve is also a Marginal Cost (MC) curve.

If the firm is currently producing Q1 units of the good, then a small increase in quantity would cost P1 per unit to produce.

SP1

Q1

We can think of this interpretation as reading the S curve vertically: that is, if we plug in values for Q, we get out values for P.Again, useful to work through an example.

Page 23: Micro Review (including externalities)

Econ 312--Farnham 23

Topic 1: Introduction and Review: Supply

Example: Suppose that supply is given by Q = P - 5.

P($)

Q

From the S function, if P=$5, Q=0 will be supplied.But if P = $6, Q = 1 will be supplied.

firm’s cost of supplying that first unit (the MC of that unit) is somewhere between $5 and $6.

S

And area under S curve from Q=1 to Q=2 equals cost of producing 2nd unit.

And area under S curve from Q=0 to Q=2 tells us how much the firm’s costs increase going from Q=0 to Q=2.

Turns out that the exact cost of producing this first unit = area under the S curve between Q=0 and Q=1.

1

5

6

7

2

$5.50 $6.50

$12

Page 24: Micro Review (including externalities)

Econ 312--Farnham 24

Topic 1: Introduction and Review: Supply

• Area under S curve up to a given Q actually tells us the Variable Cost (VC) of producing that Q.

• Recall that a firm’s Total Costs (TC) have 2 components:TC = Fixed Costs + Variable Costs

= FC + VC.

• By definition, FC don’t change as Q changes, while VC do.

• So MC = ΔTC/ΔQ = Δ (FC+VC) /ΔQ = ΔVC /ΔQ.

area under the S curve up to a given Q = MC of 1st unit + MC of 2nd unit + MC of third unit etc. etc.

• And adding up MCs is the same as calculating VC.

Page 25: Micro Review (including externalities)

Econ 312--Farnham 25

Topic 1: Introduction and Review: Supplyii. Measuring producer well-being using the supply curve.

P($)

Q

1st interpretation of S curve: tells us Q supplied at a given P.

If producer sells Q1 units at P1 per unit, then Total Revenue (TR) received = area of rectangle P1Q1.

2nd interpretation of S curve: area under S curve measures VC of producing Q1 units.

Definition: producer surplus (PS) = TR - VC.

P1

Q1

producer receives revenue greater than VC.

Difference between TR and VC provides a measure of producer well-being.

In the diagram above, the PS from selling Q1 units at P1 per unit is equal to the triangle A.

A

Page 26: Micro Review (including externalities)

Econ 312--Farnham 26

Topic 1: Introduction and Review: Supply

ii. Measuring producer well-being using the supply curve.

• More common measure of producer well-being is profit (π).– What is the relationship between PS and π?

• Recall:

PS = TR - VC; and

π = TR - TC π = TR - VC - FC

PS π = PS - FC

or PS = π + FC.

Page 27: Micro Review (including externalities)

Econ 312--Farnham 27

Topic 1: Introduction and Review: Supply

• Recall that CS measures the NB to consumers from consuming.

• Similarly, we can think about PS as telling us about the NB to producers from producing.

• That is, tells us how much better off the firm is by choosing Q>0.

• If Q = 0, TR=0 and TC=FC. π = -FC.

• If Q>0, TR>0 and TC=FC+VC. π = PS - FC.

• Tells us that maximizing π is equivalent to maximizing PS.

• So even though π is the “true” measure of firm well-being, we can use PS instead.

π as Q = PS as Q

Page 28: Micro Review (including externalities)

Econ 312--Farnham 28

Topic 1: Introduction and Review: Supplyiii. Deriving aggregate supply from individual firm supply

P

QA

Suppose two firms - A and B - each with S curves drawn below.

At P1, A supplies QA1 and B supplies QB

1.

P1

QA1

We are horizontally aggregating individual firm supplies to get aggregate supply.

SA

QB

QB1

SB

QA1+QB

1QA2 QB

2 QA2+QB

2

Aggregate S

P2

Aggregate supply at P1 therefore equals QA1 + QB

1.

At P2, A supplies QA2, B supplies QB

2, and agg. S = QA2 + QB

2.

Page 29: Micro Review (including externalities)

Econ 312--Farnham 29

Topic 1: Introduction and Review• Final topic in Intro/Review: Equilibrium.

– Bringing both sides of the market together.

• Definition of equilibrium:– a state of balance or rest;– a state where there is no tendency for change.

• In our supply and demand model, an equilibrium is where:1. Consumers are choosing the Q that makes them happiest, given P.

(Consumers choose Q to set MB=P)– i.e., maximizing CS.

2. Producers are choosing the Q that makes them happiest, given P. (Producers choose Q to set MC=P)– i.e., maximizing PS.

3. Prices are such that consumer and producer behavior are consistent.– Usually means supply equals demand. (Qs=Qd)

Page 30: Micro Review (including externalities)

Econ 312--Farnham 30

Topic 1: Introduction and Review: Equilibrium• Example: take the S and D curves illustrated below

Q1

P1

P

Q

S

D

At price P1, consumers want to buy Q1 units, producers want to sell Q1 units consumer and producer behavior is consistent.

If P > P1, S > D and there would be pressure on P to fall.

At equilibrium of P1 and Q1, NB to consumers = CS = area A and NB to producers = PS = area B.

Agg NB = CS + PS = A + B

A

B

Note that area A is aggregate CS and area B is aggregate PS.

That is, CS is sum of all individual consumers’ CS and PS is sum of all individual producers’ PS.

Page 31: Micro Review (including externalities)

Econ 312--Farnham 31

Topic 1: Introduction and Review: Equilibrium• One very important thing to note: aggregate NB always the same if Q

the same, no matter what happens to P.

• Another way of saying this is that aggregate NB function only of total Q, while the distribution of NB depends on P.

Q1

P1

P

Q

S

D

Example: here equilibrium would be P1, Q1.

But, if government imposes a quota at Q2,

new equilibrium would be at P2, Q2 where:

CS = A PS = B + C + D

But now suppose that (instead of quota), government instead says P cannot rise above P3 (“price ceiling”).

Equilibrium still Q2 but with different P. Now we have: CS = A + B + C PS = D

Agg NB = CS + PS = A + B + C + D

Q2

P2A

B

CP3

D

Agg NB = A + B + C + DSame in total, distribution different.

Page 32: Micro Review (including externalities)

Econ 312--Farnham 32

Topic 1: Introduction and ReviewSummary:• We have seen that (absent quotas, price ceilings etc):

– Consumers choose Q such that P = MB • i.e., choose to consume where P cuts D curve.• NB to consumers = CS.

– Producers choose Q such that P = MC • i.e. choose to produce where P line cuts S curve.• NB to producers = PS.

– Producer and consumer decisions are such that S=D• Aggregate NB = sum of individual NB • Sum of individual NB = CS + PS (if consumers and producers are

the the only agents affected by the market).

• Note that these are positive questions - describing the way in which markets DO work.

• Can also ask corresponding normative questions.

Page 33: Micro Review (including externalities)

Econ 312--Farnham 33

Topic 1: Introduction and Review• Normative questions of interest are:

1. What quantity of goods should be produced?• We know that in equilibrium Q is where S=D.• Under what circumstances is this the “right” Q in total (the one that

maximizes NB)?

2. Which firms should produce these goods?• We know that in equilibrium each firm produces until P=MC.• Under what circumstances is the the “right” Q for each firm (the one

that minimizes aggregate production costs)?

3. Which consumers should get to consume these goods?• We know that in equilibrium each consumer chooses Q such that

P=MB. • Under what circumstances is the the “right” Q for each consumer (the

one that maximizes aggregate benefits from consumption)?

Page 34: Micro Review (including externalities)

Econ 312--Farnham 34

Topic 1: Introduction and Review• We will focus primarily on question (1). The efficient allocation will occur

(in all cases discussed in this course) where MC=MB.– Try to understand the intuition for this:

• If MC>MB, this tells us the last little bit produced cost more to produce that it gave to consumers in added benefit. Society would be better off with less of the good (Q should fall).

• If MC<MB, this tells us the last little bit produced cost less to produce that it gave to consumers in added benefit. This suggest that increasing output would raise overall well-being in society (Q should rise).

• If MC=MB, this tells us the last little bit produced cost exactly the same amount to produce as it gave consumers in added benefit. This tells us this unit made society no better off than it was before (nor any worse off). This is the efficient point.

– Note that MC=MB in the equilibrium diagram 4 slides back. In a well-functioning market, MC=MB at equilibrium so that the equilibrium is efficient. However, this does not always have to be the case!

• When market failure occurs (due to something like the presence of an externality or due to monopolistic control of an industry), it may not be the case that MC=MB at equilibrium

• In such a case, the equilibrium quantity may be different from the efficient quantity.

Page 35: Micro Review (including externalities)

Econ 312--Farnham 35

Externalities—A Typical Cause of Market Failure in Urban Settings

• Externalities occur when some market transaction involves costs and/or benefits that accrue to people outside the transaction– This means consumers and producers aren’t taking all of the relevant

costs and benefits into account==>Social MB may not equal Social MC in equilibrium.

– In such a case, equilibrium is inefficient• In the ideal case we just examined, the only people affected

by market transactions were producers and consumers: all costs and benefits in the market were internalized. So (Social MB)=(Social MC) in equilibrium and, therefore, the equilibrium was efficient.

Page 36: Micro Review (including externalities)

36

Some Urban Externalities• Negative externalities (external costs)

– Pollution (noise, light, emissions)– Congestion (traffic, sidewalks, parks, etc.)– Spread of disease (especially where water treatment is poor)

• Positive externalities (external benefits)– Knowledge spillovers (arguably huge in cities)– “Energy” one feels from being in a bustling city

• When externalities are present, market outcomes will typically be inefficient; if the inefficiency is large, this provides solid justification for government intervention in the market (i.e. policy)– In equilibrium, markets produce too much of goods with negative

externalities; policy should discourage production– In equilibrium, markets produce too little of goods with positive

externalities; policy should encourage production

Page 37: Micro Review (including externalities)

37

Externalities—Some Definitions• We defined private costs and benefits previously—those

that occur to producers and consumers• Now consider external costs and benefits: those accruing

to people outside a market transaction– e.g. Pollution hurts people--it imposes costs on them– Just as we can show the private marginal cost curve for producers

in an industry, we can think of the marginal external cost imposed on others by different levels of production.

– If we add up the marginal private costs and marginal external costs of production, we get the overall marginal social cost of production. (mpc+mec=msc)• Marginal social cost curve describes the costs, on the margin, imposed on

both producers and people external to the transaction, for different levels of production. Note that mec can be positive (in the case of negative production externalities) or negative (in the case of positive production externalities—like information spillovers between firms)

Page 38: Micro Review (including externalities)

38

Externalities—Some Definitions• Similarly marginal social benefits are the marginal private

benefits plus marginal external benefits (mpb+meb=msb)– meb can be positive (in the case of positive consumption

externalities) or negative (in the case of negative consumption externalities)

• We show production externalities using MC curves.• We show consumption externalities using MB curves

Page 39: Micro Review (including externalities)

Econ 312--Farnham 39

Consider a negative production externality (MEC>0)

• MEC is vertical distance between MPC and MSC• Equilibrium at Qeq where S=D• But is this efficient?

– MSC=MPC+MEC– MSC>MSB at Qeq implies that too much is being produced– Want MSC=MSB!– Qeff is efficient level of production

D=MSB

S=MPC

MSC

Qeq

Peq

Qeff

P

Q

Page 40: Micro Review (including externalities)

Econ 312--Farnham 40

Neg Production Externality--Welfare Analysis

• What does society gain from moving from Qeq to Qeff?– Loses total social benefits of E– Gains total social cost reduction equal to D– Net gain of F– Note that F is equilibrium deadweight loss– Social Welfare (SW) society could have if only it moved from Qeq to Qeff.

D=MSB

S=MPC

MSC

Qeq

Peq

Qeff

P

Q

E

D

=gain

loss=

F

Page 41: Micro Review (including externalities)

Econ 312--Farnham 41

Policy Example: Using a per unit tax to correct a pollution externality

• Taxes generally reduce SW when equilibrium is efficient (market success)

• Taxes Can be SW improving for mkt failure– w/neg externality, can restore Qeff – Impose tax that sets t=MEC at Qeff

• SW after tax equals areas CS+PS+GR-TEC

CS= GR=PS=

MSC

Peq

P

QQeq

S=MPC

Q’eq=Qeff

S(w/tax)

t=MEC(Qeff)Pc

Ps

TEC=

D=MSB

Page 42: Micro Review (including externalities)

Econ 312--Farnham 42

SW With Tax-Corrected Externality

• Social welfare in this case is the area shown to the right. – It’s CS plus the part of GR not cancelled out by

TEC.– Note that PS is cancelled out by part of TEC

• Social Welfare

=

SW CS+GR+PS

-TEC

Page 43: Micro Review (including externalities)

Econ 325--Martin Farnham 43

Now Consider a Positive Production Externality

• Suppose a constant MEB results from production activity (knowledge spillovers?); show externality with S curve– Vertical shift (down) of S curve by amount of MEB– MSC=MPC-MEB– MSB=MPB because no externality on consumption side– Too little produced in equilibrium

Positive production externality

D=MPB=MSB

S=MPC

Qeq

Peq

Qeff

P

Q

MEB

MSC

Page 44: Micro Review (including externalities)

Econ 312--Farnham 44

What is correct policy response?

• Work this out on your own– Remember, you want to

encourage increased production of this good

• Do graphical welfare analysis– Show how a policy

instrument can be used to correct the market failure.