marine reserves and fishery profit: practical designs offer optimal solutions

87
Marine reserves and fishery profit: practical designs offer optimal solutions. w White, Bruce Kendall, Dave Siegel, and Chris Cost University of California – Santa Barbara

Upload: teague

Post on 27-Jan-2016

32 views

Category:

Documents


1 download

DESCRIPTION

Marine reserves and fishery profit: practical designs offer optimal solutions. Crow White, Bruce Kendall, Dave Siegel, and Chris Costello University of California – Santa Barbara. Larval export. No Fishing. When is larval export maximized? - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Marine reserves and fishery profit: practical designs offer optimal solutions

Marine reserves and fishery profit: practical designs offer

optimal solutions. 

Crow White, Bruce Kendall, Dave Siegel, and Chris Costello University of California – Santa Barbara

Page 2: Marine reserves and fishery profit: practical designs offer optimal solutions

Larval export

No Fishin

g

Page 3: Marine reserves and fishery profit: practical designs offer optimal solutions

When is larval export maximized?

What reserve design (size and spacing) maximizes larval export to fishable areas?

Do reserves benefit fisheries?

Is fishery yield/profit greater under optimal reserve design than

attainable without reserves?

Page 4: Marine reserves and fishery profit: practical designs offer optimal solutions

Research Question:

To maximize larval export (and thus benefit fisheries) should reserves be…

…few and large,

When is larval export maximized?

…or many and small?

SLOSS debate

Page 5: Marine reserves and fishery profit: practical designs offer optimal solutions

Coastal fish & invert life history traits in model Adults are sessile, reproducing seasonally (e.g. Brouwer et al. 2003, Lowe et al. 2003, Parsons et al. 2003)

Larvae disperse, mature after 1+ yrs (e.g. Dethier et al. 2003, Grantham et al. 2003)

Larva settlement and/or recruitment success decreases with increasing adult density at that location

(post-dispersal density dependence) (e.g. Steele and Forrester 2002, Lecchini and Galzin 2003)

Page 6: Marine reserves and fishery profit: practical designs offer optimal solutions

sy'all

txyxy

ty

ty

tx

tx

tx

tx

1tx RLK)FH(A)HM(AHAA

An integro-difference model describing coastal fish population dynamics:

Adult abundance at location x during time-step t+1

Number of adults

harvested

Natural mortality of adults that

escaped being harvested

Fecundity

Larval survival

Larval dispersal (Gaussian)(Siegel et al. 2003)

Larval recruitment at x

Number of larvae that successfully recruit to location x

Page 7: Marine reserves and fishery profit: practical designs offer optimal solutions

Incorporating Density Dependence

Post-dispersal: )Hc(Ao

tx

tx

txeRR

sy'all

txyxy

ty

ty

tx

tx

tx

tx

1tx RLK)FH(A)HM(AHAA

Larva settlement and/or recruitment success decreases with increasing adult population density at that location.

Page 8: Marine reserves and fishery profit: practical designs offer optimal solutions

FEW LARGE RESERVES

SEVERAL SMALL RESERVES

Page 9: Marine reserves and fishery profit: practical designs offer optimal solutions

θ = 5

θ = 0

Cost of catching one fish

= Density of fish at that location

θ

Page 10: Marine reserves and fishery profit: practical designs offer optimal solutions

θ = 5

θ = 0

Bottom line for fishermen:

Profit = Revenue - cost

Cost of catching one fish

= Density of fish at that location

θ

Page 11: Marine reserves and fishery profit: practical designs offer optimal solutions

θ = 20

θ = 0

Bottom line for fishermen:

Profit = Revenue - cost

Cost of catching one fish

= Density of fish at that location

θ

Page 12: Marine reserves and fishery profit: practical designs offer optimal solutions

FEW LARGE RESERVES

SEVERAL SMALL RESERVES

Page 13: Marine reserves and fishery profit: practical designs offer optimal solutions

Scale bar = 100 km

Page 14: Marine reserves and fishery profit: practical designs offer optimal solutions

Scale bar = 100 km

Page 15: Marine reserves and fishery profit: practical designs offer optimal solutions

Scale bar = 100 km

Page 16: Marine reserves and fishery profit: practical designs offer optimal solutions
Page 17: Marine reserves and fishery profit: practical designs offer optimal solutions
Page 18: Marine reserves and fishery profit: practical designs offer optimal solutions
Page 19: Marine reserves and fishery profit: practical designs offer optimal solutions
Page 20: Marine reserves and fishery profit: practical designs offer optimal solutions
Page 21: Marine reserves and fishery profit: practical designs offer optimal solutions
Page 22: Marine reserves and fishery profit: practical designs offer optimal solutions
Page 23: Marine reserves and fishery profit: practical designs offer optimal solutions
Page 24: Marine reserves and fishery profit: practical designs offer optimal solutions
Page 25: Marine reserves and fishery profit: practical designs offer optimal solutions
Page 26: Marine reserves and fishery profit: practical designs offer optimal solutions

Max Yield without Reserves

Page 27: Marine reserves and fishery profit: practical designs offer optimal solutions

Max Yield without Reserves

Page 28: Marine reserves and fishery profit: practical designs offer optimal solutions

Max Yield without Reserves

Page 29: Marine reserves and fishery profit: practical designs offer optimal solutions

Max Yield without Reserves

Page 30: Marine reserves and fishery profit: practical designs offer optimal solutions

Max Yield without Reserves

Page 31: Marine reserves and fishery profit: practical designs offer optimal solutions

Max Yield without Reserves

Page 32: Marine reserves and fishery profit: practical designs offer optimal solutions

Max Yield without Reserves

Page 33: Marine reserves and fishery profit: practical designs offer optimal solutions

Max Yield without Reserves

Page 34: Marine reserves and fishery profit: practical designs offer optimal solutions

Max Yield without Reserves

Page 35: Marine reserves and fishery profit: practical designs offer optimal solutions

A spectrum of high-profit scenariosMax Yield without Reserves

Page 36: Marine reserves and fishery profit: practical designs offer optimal solutions

A spectrum of high-profit scenarios

Cost = θ/density

Max Yield without Reserves

Page 37: Marine reserves and fishery profit: practical designs offer optimal solutions

A spectrum of high-profit scenarios

Cost = θ/density (Stop fishing when cost = $1)

Max Yield without Reserves

Page 38: Marine reserves and fishery profit: practical designs offer optimal solutions

A spectrum of high-profit scenarios

Cost = θ/density (Stop fishing when cost = $1)

Escapement = % of virgin K (K = 50)

Max Yield without Reserves

Page 39: Marine reserves and fishery profit: practical designs offer optimal solutions

A spectrum of high-profit scenarios

Cost = θ/density (Stop fishing when cost = $1)

Escapement = % of virgin K (K = 50)

Zero-profit escapement level = θ/K = 40%

Max Yield without Reserves

Page 40: Marine reserves and fishery profit: practical designs offer optimal solutions

A spectrum of high-profit scenarios

Cost = θ/density (Stop fishing when cost = $1)

Escapement = % of virgin K (K = 50)

Zero-profit escapement level = θ/K = 40%

Max Yield without Reserves

Page 41: Marine reserves and fishery profit: practical designs offer optimal solutions

A spectrum of high-profit scenariosθ/K = 15/50 = 30%

Max Yield without Reserves

Page 42: Marine reserves and fishery profit: practical designs offer optimal solutions

A spectrum of high-profit scenariosθ/K = 10/50 = 20%

Max Yield without Reserves

Page 43: Marine reserves and fishery profit: practical designs offer optimal solutions

A spectrum of high-profit scenariosθ/K = 5/50 = 10%

Max Yield without Reserves

Page 44: Marine reserves and fishery profit: practical designs offer optimal solutions

Summary 1. Post-dispersal density dependence generates larval

export.

2. Larval export varies with reserve size and spacing.

3. Fishery yield and profit maximized via…

Less than ~15% coastline in reserves

…Any reserve spacing option.

More than ~15% coastline in reserves

…Several small or few medium-sized reserves.

Page 45: Marine reserves and fishery profit: practical designs offer optimal solutions

Summary

4. Reserves benefit fisheries when escapement is moderate to low (E < ~35%*K)

5. Reserves become more beneficial as fish become easier to catch (low θ)

Page 46: Marine reserves and fishery profit: practical designs offer optimal solutions

Summary 4. Given optimal reserve spacing, a near-maximum

profit is maintained across a spectrum of reserve and harvest scenarios:

ReservesNone/few

Many

EscapementHigh Low

Page 47: Marine reserves and fishery profit: practical designs offer optimal solutions

Summary

Along this spectrum exists an optimal reserve network scenario, based on the fisheries’ self-

regulated escapement, that maximizes profits to the fishery.

4. Given optimal reserve spacing, a near-maximum profit is maintained across a spectrum of reserve and harvest scenarios:

ReservesNone Many

EscapementHigh Low

None/few

Page 48: Marine reserves and fishery profit: practical designs offer optimal solutions

University of California – Santa Barbara

National Science Foundation

THANK YOU!

Page 49: Marine reserves and fishery profit: practical designs offer optimal solutions

Logistic model:

post-dispersal density dependence

No reserves:

Nt+1 = Ntr(1-Nt)

Yield = Ntr(1-Nt)-Nt

MSY = max{Yield}

dYield/dN = r – 2rN – 1 = 0

N = (r – 1)/2r

MSY = Yield(N = (r – 1)/2*r) = (r – 1)2 / 4r

Page 50: Marine reserves and fishery profit: practical designs offer optimal solutions

Logistic model:

Scorched earth outside reserves

post-dispersal density dependence

Reserves:

Nt+1 = crNr(1-Nr)

Nr* = 1 – 1/cr

Yield = crNr(1 – c)(1 – No)

Yield(Nr* = 1 – 1/cr) = -rc2 + cr + c – 1

dYield/dc = -2cr + r + 1 = 0

c = (r + 1)/2r

MSY = Yield(c = (r + 1)/2r) = (r – 1)2 / 4r

Page 51: Marine reserves and fishery profit: practical designs offer optimal solutions

Ricker model:

post-dispersal density dependence

No reserves:

Nt+1 = rNte-gNt

Surplus growth = Yield = rNe-gN – N

dYield/dN = re-gN – grNe-gN – 1 = 0

1. Find N for dYield/dN = 0

2. Plug N into Yield(N,r,g) = MSY

Page 52: Marine reserves and fishery profit: practical designs offer optimal solutions
Page 53: Marine reserves and fishery profit: practical designs offer optimal solutions
Page 54: Marine reserves and fishery profit: practical designs offer optimal solutions

Ricker model:

Reserves:

Nr = crNre-gNr

Nr* = Log[cr] / g

Recruitment to fishable domain =

Yield = crNr(1 – c)e-gNo

Yield(Nr* = Log[cr] / g) = crLog[cr](1 – c) / g

dYield/dc = (rLog[cr] + r – 2crLog[cr] – cr) / g = 0

1. Find c for dYield/dc = 0

2. Plug c into Yield(c,r,g) = MSY

Page 55: Marine reserves and fishery profit: practical designs offer optimal solutions
Page 56: Marine reserves and fishery profit: practical designs offer optimal solutions
Page 57: Marine reserves and fishery profit: practical designs offer optimal solutions
Page 58: Marine reserves and fishery profit: practical designs offer optimal solutions
Page 59: Marine reserves and fishery profit: practical designs offer optimal solutions

Older, bigger fish produce many more young

Page 60: Marine reserves and fishery profit: practical designs offer optimal solutions
Page 61: Marine reserves and fishery profit: practical designs offer optimal solutions

Channel Islands

Page 62: Marine reserves and fishery profit: practical designs offer optimal solutions

0 500 1000 15000

10

20

30

40

50Optimal Reserve Spacing

Distance between reserve centers [km]

Mea

n H

arv

est

Den

sity

[#

fis

h/k

m]

Reserve = 50% of the coastline

Page 63: Marine reserves and fishery profit: practical designs offer optimal solutions

0 500 1000 15000

10

20

30

40

50Optimal Reserve Spacing

Distance between reserve centers [km]

Mea

n H

arv

est

Den

sity

[#

fis

h/k

m]

Dd = 100 kmDd = 200 kmDd = 300 km

Reserve = 50% of the coastline

Page 64: Marine reserves and fishery profit: practical designs offer optimal solutions

FUTURE RESEARCH

1. Evaluate under post-dispersal dd where larvae recruitment success depends on sympatric larvae density.

2. Conduct analysis within a finite domain.

3. Add size structure to the fish population.

Page 65: Marine reserves and fishery profit: practical designs offer optimal solutions
Page 66: Marine reserves and fishery profit: practical designs offer optimal solutions
Page 67: Marine reserves and fishery profit: practical designs offer optimal solutions

Scale bar = 100 km

Page 68: Marine reserves and fishery profit: practical designs offer optimal solutions

Scale bar = 100 km

Page 69: Marine reserves and fishery profit: practical designs offer optimal solutions

Marine reserves and fishery profit: practical designs offer

optimal solutions. 

Crow White, Bruce Kendall, Dave Siegel, and Chris Costello University of California – Santa Barbara

Page 70: Marine reserves and fishery profit: practical designs offer optimal solutions

Can Marine Reserves bolster fishery

yields?

Page 71: Marine reserves and fishery profit: practical designs offer optimal solutions

NO RESERVES

RESERVES (E = 0% outside)

Larvae-on-larvae density dependence

equal

Page 72: Marine reserves and fishery profit: practical designs offer optimal solutions
Page 73: Marine reserves and fishery profit: practical designs offer optimal solutions

0.2

0

0

0

00

Fraction protected

d/L

= 0

.01

d/L

= 0

.03

d/L

= 0

.1d

/L =

0.3

Traditional 3-Reserve network

Pre-dispersal

nand

Pre- or post-

dispersaln andN

0.4

0.4 0.8 0 0.4 0.8 0 0.4 0.8

Two size classes

Yie

ld

0.2

0.4

0.2

0.4

0.2

0.4

Post-dispersal

nand

Short disperser

Long disperser

Marine reserves can exploit population structure and life history in improving potential fisheries yieldsBrian Gaylord, Steven D. Gaines, David A. Siegel, Mark H. Carr. In Press. Ecol. Apps.

Post-dispersal density dependence:

survival of new recruits decreases with increasing density of adults at settlement location.

Page 74: Marine reserves and fishery profit: practical designs offer optimal solutions
Page 75: Marine reserves and fishery profit: practical designs offer optimal solutions

Logistic model:

post-dispersal density dependence

No reserves:

Nt+1 = Ntr(1-Nt)

Yield = Ntr(1-Nt)-Nt

MSY = max{Yield}

dYield/dN = r – 2rN – 1 = 0

N = (r – 1)/2r

MSY = Yield(N = (r – 1)/2*r) = (r – 1)2 / 4r

Page 76: Marine reserves and fishery profit: practical designs offer optimal solutions

Logistic model:

Scorched earth outside reserves

post-dispersal density dependence

Reserves:

Nt+1 = crNr(1-Nr)

Nr* = 1 – 1/cr

Yield = crNr(1 – c)(1 – No)

Yield(Nr* = 1 – 1/cr) = -rc2 + cr + c – 1

dYield/dc = -2cr + r + 1 = 0

c = (r + 1)/2r

MSY = Yield(c = (r + 1)/2r) = (r – 1)2 / 4r

Page 77: Marine reserves and fishery profit: practical designs offer optimal solutions
Page 78: Marine reserves and fishery profit: practical designs offer optimal solutions

Ricker model:

post-dispersal density dependence

No reserves:

Nt+1 = rNte-gNt

Surplus growth = Yield = rNe-gN – N

dYield/dN = re-gN – grNe-gN – 1 = 0

1. Find N for dYield/dN = 0

2. Plug N into Yield(N,r,g) = MSY

Page 79: Marine reserves and fishery profit: practical designs offer optimal solutions
Page 80: Marine reserves and fishery profit: practical designs offer optimal solutions
Page 81: Marine reserves and fishery profit: practical designs offer optimal solutions

Ricker model:

Reserves:

Nr = crNre-gNr

Nr* = Log[cr] / g

Recruitment to fishable domain =

Yield = crNr(1 – c)e-gNo

Yield(Nr* = Log[cr] / g) = crLog[cr](1 – c) / g

dYield/dc = (rLog[cr] + r – 2crLog[cr] – cr) / g = 0

1. Find c for dYield/dc = 0

2. Plug c into Yield(c,r,g) = MSY

Page 82: Marine reserves and fishery profit: practical designs offer optimal solutions
Page 83: Marine reserves and fishery profit: practical designs offer optimal solutions
Page 84: Marine reserves and fishery profit: practical designs offer optimal solutions
Page 85: Marine reserves and fishery profit: practical designs offer optimal solutions

Comparing MSYs:

MSYreserve = max{crLog[cr](1 – c) / g}

MSYfishable = max{ rNe-gN – N}

dYfishable/dN = re-gN – grNe-gN – 1 = 0

n 1 ProductLog

r

g

ProductLog[z] = w is the solution for z = wew

Page 86: Marine reserves and fishery profit: practical designs offer optimal solutions

INCREASE

Page 87: Marine reserves and fishery profit: practical designs offer optimal solutions

Costello and Ward. In Review.