kalòs kai agathòs? government quality and cultural ...kalòs kai agathòs? government quality and...

27
7618 2019 April 2019 Kalòs kai agathòs? Government quality and cultural heritage in the regions of Europe Enrico Bertacchini, Federico Revelli

Upload: others

Post on 11-May-2020

1 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Kalòs kai agathòs? Government quality and cultural ...Kalòs kai agathòs? Government quality and cultural heritage . in the regions of Europe . Abstract . This paper uses panel

7618 2019

April 2019

Kalòs kai agathòs? Government quality and cultural heritage in the regions of Europe Enrico Bertacchini, Federico Revelli

Page 2: Kalòs kai agathòs? Government quality and cultural ...Kalòs kai agathòs? Government quality and cultural heritage . in the regions of Europe . Abstract . This paper uses panel

Impressum:

CESifo Working Papers ISSN 2364-1428 (electronic version) Publisher and distributor: Munich Society for the Promotion of Economic Research - CESifo GmbH The international platform of Ludwigs-Maximilians University’s Center for Economic Studies and the ifo Institute Poschingerstr. 5, 81679 Munich, Germany Telephone +49 (0)89 2180-2740, Telefax +49 (0)89 2180-17845, email [email protected] Editor: Clemens Fuest www.cesifo-group.org/wp

An electronic version of the paper may be downloaded · from the SSRN website: www.SSRN.com · from the RePEc website: www.RePEc.org · from the CESifo website: www.CESifo-group.org/wp

Page 3: Kalòs kai agathòs? Government quality and cultural ...Kalòs kai agathòs? Government quality and cultural heritage . in the regions of Europe . Abstract . This paper uses panel

CESifo Working Paper No. 7618 Category 2: Public Choice

Kalòs kai agathòs? Government quality and cultural heritage

in the regions of Europe

Abstract This paper uses panel data on over 200 regions of Europe to study the spatial distribution of UNESCO sites and the capacity of regional governments to conserve heritage, using new designations in the World Heritage List as a proxy. We test whether the location of a region matters by controlling for the stock of World Heritage in the surrounding regions, and if low regional government quality is an obstacle to inclusion of sites into the List. We find some evidence of within-country regional competition for inscription, and of a positive impact of government quality on the chances of having a UNESCO designation.

JEL-Codes: C230, R100.

Keywords: UNESCO World Heritage, quality of government, regions of Europe, spatial analysis.

Enrico Bertacchini Department of Economics and Statistics

Cognetti de Martiis University of Torino / Italy [email protected]

Federico Revelli Department of Economics and Statistics

Cognetti de Martiis University of Torino / Italy [email protected]

April, 2019

Page 4: Kalòs kai agathòs? Government quality and cultural ...Kalòs kai agathòs? Government quality and cultural heritage . in the regions of Europe . Abstract . This paper uses panel

2

1 Introduction

The recent decades have seen growing awareness amongst international institutions,

academic circles, and the public at large of the crucial role of good and democratic

governance for economic and social development (UNDP, 2014). The United Nations

system claims to base its actions on the idea of a governance that “promotes equity,

participation, pluralism, transparency, accountability and the rule of law, in a manner

that is effective, efficient and enduring, (...) advances development, by bringing its

energies to bear on such tasks as eradicating poverty, protecting the environment,

ensuring gender equality, and providing for sustainable livelihoods.” (UN, Global

Issues), and the World Bank sees good governance as “the capacity of the government

to effectively formulate and implement sound policies” (World bank, Worldwide

Governance Indicators).

The economic literature has focused on the long-term relationship between the quality

of institutions and economic growth, unveiling their historical role in shaping countries’

and regions’ current economic performance (Acemoglu et al. 2001; Rodrik et al., 2004;

Tabellini 2010). Contemporary government institutions have been also found to affect

the innovative capacity of regions, the effectiveness of their policies, and the return to

investment (Rodriguez-Pose and Di Cataldo, 2015; Rodriguez-Pose and Garcilazo,

2015; Crescenzi et al., 2016).

Despite the growing interest in institutional factors, there has been little research so

far on how government quality affects the effectiveness of public intervention in

complex and multi-dimensional domains such as cultural heritage policy. Cultural

heritage is in fact considered an asset owning public good characteristics (Peacock and

Rizzo, 2008), whose protection requires the design and effective implementation of

appropriate public policies and regulations. For historical reasons, cultural heritage is

particularly relevant in Europe and its conservation and support have become major

policy issues in the last decades. Although the EU has limited powers with respect to

cultural heritage, its relevance has been included in numerous EU Council declarations

and EU funding programs. According to a Eurobarometer special report (European

Commission, 2018), 91% (87%) of European citizens think cultural heritage is important

for their country (region), and 74% of respondents agree that public authorities should

allocate more resources to Europe’s cultural heritage.

The question we address here is if the quality of government at the sub-national level

throughout Europe is an important ingredient for the protection and promotion of

heritage. More specifically, we ask whether the quality of government in the European

regions is a relevant factor in explaining the successful selection of their heritage sites

into the UNESCO World Heritage List, an event that we consider as a proxy of a regional

government’s capacity to effectively protect and promote its heritage sites. In doing so,

Page 5: Kalòs kai agathòs? Government quality and cultural ...Kalòs kai agathòs? Government quality and cultural heritage . in the regions of Europe . Abstract . This paper uses panel

3

we take for the first time a ‘local’ perspective by combining a novel dataset on UNESCO

World Heritage designations of European regions for the period 2010-2015 with data on

government quality gathered by the Quality of Government Institute at the University of

Gothenburg. Moreover, since we deal with territorial units whose spatial location might

have potentially important implications, we make explicit use of spatial econometric

methods in investigating the determinants of inclusion in the List, in particular by

accounting for potential spill-overs from the existence of already listed sites in the

regions that are adjacent to a candidate site’s region.

In the European context, regional governments play an active role in heritage policy

and in the nomination of sites in the UNESCO World Heritage List. As noted by Rizzo

(2004), sub-central government intervention might in fact be optimal in heritage policy

when the support to cultural heritage is used with the objective of promoting local

economic development (i.e., by enhancing the attractiveness and tourist potential of

heritage sites) or of stimulating the local identity and cohesion of communities. Such an

instrumental approach to link cultural heritage with local development is not limited to

Europe, but has increasingly become a mainstream public policy paradigm in many

industrialized countries (OECD, 2005), suggesting the growing importance of a regional

and local perspective in the design of heritage policies.

Although the proposal to nominate heritage sites for the World Heritage List remains

a prerogative of national governments, the role of local governments in Europe has

become crucial for two main reasons. Firstly, after over 40 years of the UNESCO World

Heritage Convention, most of European countries have already included in the List the

most outstanding heritage sites of national relevance (Frey and Steiner, 2011). New

nominations on the World Heritage List, albeit still proposed for their outstanding

universal value, are thus more likely to be expressions of cultural heritage with greater

local significance. Regional governments might thus be interested in playing a more

active role in the preservation and promotion of their cultural heritage through the World

Heritage List. Secondly, we argue that the changes occurred in the last decade in the

selection process of the UNESCO World Heritage List (UNESCO, 2007), which allow

a state party to submit only up to two complete nominations per year, has increased the

competition between regions in the same country to propose and have their heritage sites

included in the List. As a result, political and institutional differences across regions may

have a dramatic influence on the selection process of heritage sites.

The results of our empirical analysis can be briefly summarized as follows. First,

estimation of a random effects Probit model suggests that the chances of a region having

a heritage site inscribed in the UNESCO list in a given year are positively affected by

the quality of the government of the region, particularly when measured in terms of

ability to curb corrupt behavior and of quality of public services provided. As far as inter-

Page 6: Kalòs kai agathòs? Government quality and cultural ...Kalòs kai agathòs? Government quality and cultural heritage . in the regions of Europe . Abstract . This paper uses panel

4

regional interdependencies are concerned, we find no significant spill-over on a region

from the stock of World Heritage in surrounding regions. However, the number of

regions in a country turns out to have a significant and negative impact on a region’s

success in site inscription, pointing to within-country competition between regions for

nominating and inscribing sites in the World Heritage List.

The paper is organized as follows: Section 2 presents the local quality of government

indicators; Section 3 discusses the rationale and features of the UNESCO World Heritage

List and its recent trends; in Section 4 we show the spatial distribution of World Heritage

sites across the European regions; in Section 5 we introduce the empirical models and

discuss the results of the econometric analysis; Section 6 concludes.

2 Quality of government

In order to capture the quality of institutions at the regional level, we use the sub-national

Quality of Government (QoG) index proposed by Charron et al. (2014, 2015). Developed

by the Quality of Government Institute at the University of Gothenburg (Sweden), the

index is commonly considered as one of the few sources of data for systematic

comparison of government institutions’ performance across European regions. It is based

on survey data from samples of respondents across countries and regions within the EU

and addresses three main dimensions of government quality, namely public sector

corruption, impartiality and effectiveness in the provision of three public services

(education, healthcare, law enforcement). A region’s QoG index is constructed by

combining the national score of the Worldwide Governance Indicators (Kaufmann et al.,

2009) standardized for the EU sample, with the variation of the QoG index obtained from

the regional survey respect to the country average. The index is available for the sub-

national regions at the NUTS 1 or NUTS 2 level, depending on the country, and is

standardized with a mean of zero and a standard deviation of one, with higher scores

implying higher QoG.

Information on the regional quality of government has been published for three years,

based on subsequent rounds of surveys conducted in 2010, 2013 and 2017. In 2010, 172

NUTS1 and NUTS2 regions in 18 EU countries hosted surveys of about 200 respondents

per region, for a total of 34,000 respondents overall (Charron, 2013). The 2013 index

(Charron et al., 2015) is based instead on a larger survey-based dataset (84,000

respondents) of regions from all EU 28 countries, plus Turkey and Serbia, for a total of

236 political units in 30 countries. Finally, the 2017 survey collects the opinions of

78,000 respondents in 202 regions from 21 European countries (Charron and Lapuente,

2018). The regional scores from the three waves of data are not immediately comparable.

Due to the process of standardization, adding or subtracting units can impact the scores

of other units artificially. However, with each new release, the values of the index from

Page 7: Kalòs kai agathòs? Government quality and cultural ...Kalòs kai agathòs? Government quality and cultural heritage . in the regions of Europe . Abstract . This paper uses panel

5

the previous years have been retroactively adjusted with validated techniques (see

Charron et al., 2015; Charron and Lapuente, 2018). The regionalisation of the perceived

quality of government institutions unveils interesting patterns that we aim at exploiting

here, notably the very large variance of the index in a number of countries including

Italy, Spain and Portugal, relative to more homogeneous countries like Denmark,

Sweden or the Netherlands.

The QoG index has been used so far to test several research questions, notably how

the quality of regional government institutions affect the innovative capacity of regions

(Rodriguez-Pose and Di Cataldo, 2015), the rates of small and medium-sized enterprises

in the local economy (Nistotskaya et al., 2015), the return of public investments

(Rodriguez-Pose and Garcilazo; Crescenzi et al., 2016) and the regional attractiveness to

migrants (Ketterer and Rodríguez-Pose, 2015).

Although it is based on perception of local government institutions in three specific

areas of public service provision (health care, education, and law enforcement), we

contend that the QoG index can be extended to assess the effectiveness of heritage

policies at the local level as well. Protection and promotion of heritage can be considered

in many respects as a form of government’s provision of public goods and services

(Throsby, 2010), for the quality of political decision-making and policy implementation

influence the outcome of public intervention in this domain. Furthermore, as the regional

quality of government is positively associated with higher levels of social trust (Charron

et al., 2014), it is very likely that more cohesive communities exhibit stronger

preferences for the conservation and support to their heritage assets, being expressions

of their local identities.

3 The UNESCO World Heritage list

The World Heritage List is the main implementing mechanism of the 1972 UNESCO

World Heritage Convention, an international agreement that seeks to encourage the

identification, protection and preservation of cultural and natural heritage around the

world that is considered to be of outstanding value to humanity. Inclusion of cultural and

natural sites on the World Heritage List is the result of a selection process that occurs

during the annual World Heritage Committee sessions. State parties propose, among the

national properties previously included in a Tentative List, 1 heritage sites to be

nominated in the final List, and these are included if they meet at least one of the 10

criteria defining the outstanding universal value and, additionally, the conditions of

uniqueness, authenticity, and integrity (UNESCO, 2017).

1 National Tentative Lists are inventories of sites that State Parties submit for possible inscription in the World

Heritage List and thus represent the first act of initiative as well as a necessary condition for obtaining the World

Heritage designation.

Page 8: Kalòs kai agathòs? Government quality and cultural ...Kalòs kai agathòs? Government quality and cultural heritage . in the regions of Europe . Abstract . This paper uses panel

6

The World Heritage List has become increasingly popular and many have regarded it

as the most effective international legal instrument for the protection of cultural and

natural heritage (Titchen 1996; Strasser 2002). As of 2016, some 191 countries have

ratified the Convention and a total of 1,031 properties have been included on the World

Heritage List. In line with the principles of the Convention, the inclusion of a site in the

World Heritage List signals the quality of the property and the government’s

commitment towards the international community for its protection and conservation.

As the World Heritage designation does not directly guarantee greater protection or

access to financial resources from UNESCO, to ensure the integrity of the selected sites

governments have thus to comply through their heritage policies and interventions with

international recognized standards. Yet, given the popularity of the List, obtaining a

UNESCO World Heritage designation has become also highly desirable as it might

attract the attention of donors and for-profit firms, or it can be used to market the sites

as tourist destinations (Harrison and Hitchcock 2005; Fyall and Rakic 2006 ).

The List has been long recognized to be unbalanced in the geographical areas of the

world that are represented, with the majority of World Heritage being cultural sites

located in developed regions, in particular in Europe and North America (UNESCO

2007). While some commentators have stressed as a cause of this unbalance the Western-

centered conceptualization of tangible heritage in the design of selection criteria

(Musitelli 2002), a growing empirical literature has unveiled political and economic

determinants that may have influenced the selection process and led to unbalances in the

World Heritage List (Bertacchini and Saccone 2012; Frey et al. 2013; Parenti and De

Simone 2015, Bertacchini et al. 2016). Significantly, factors such as a country’s income

level, economic power, tourism specialization and active involvement on the World

Heritage Committee sessions have been found to have an impact on the composition of

the World Heritage List.

In order to rectify some of the representativeness gaps, since 2002 new measures to

achieve a balanced representation have limited both the nomination capacity of states

and the number of proposals examined at yearly Committee sessions. Currently, states

can submit up to two complete nominations per year, provided that at least one is a

natural heritage site, and the Committee can review up to forty-five nominations each

year, inclusive of nominations deferred and referred by previous sessions.

4 The distribution of World Heritage sites across the EU regions

Studies and statistics concerning UNESCO World Heritage have usually focused on the

distribution of sites at the country level, as state parties are the key actors within the

UNESCO World Heritage Convention. Conversely, there has been little attention to a

regional perspective on UNESCO World Heritage and in particular to the distribution of

Page 9: Kalòs kai agathòs? Government quality and cultural ...Kalòs kai agathòs? Government quality and cultural heritage . in the regions of Europe . Abstract . This paper uses panel

7

World Heritage sites across the European regions. Europe is the area hosting the highest

share of World Heritage properties, with some countries, namely France, Italy and Spain,

ranking at the top for the number of sites in the World Heritage List. A regional

perspective on European World Heritage can thus be useful to verify in a more fine-

grained way whether geographical imbalances in the List noticed at the global level and

between-countries do occur across European regions too. Further, through this approach

it is possible to add insights into the spatial dependence of regions as to the localization

of World Heritage sites, overcoming national boundaries.

To obtain the number of World Heritage sites in each region we use the information

about heritage properties drawn from the UNESCO World Heritage Center Database

(Source: http://whc.unesco.org/en/list). The database provides unique GIS coordinates

that we use to identify the region (NUTS2 level) in which the heritage property is located.

In cases where the UNESCO site area extends over multiple regions, the site is assigned

to the region according to the official coordinates.2

As for trans-boundary sites (those sites that are recorded in the List as belonging to

different countries), we adopt the following approach. For those sites that are located at

the border of neighboring regions in two or more countries, we assign them equally to

all involved regions. Conversely, we exclude transnational serial properties that are

extremely scattered across countries and regions because it is difficult to identify the

leading region in the World Heritage nomination process. 3 We do not make any

distinction between cultural, natural and mixed properties as defined by UNESCO World

Heritage Convention. Differentiating between cultural and natural sites would create

difficulties in the European context due to the very low number of natural sites.4

UNESCO sites are spread in a relatively homogeneous way through the European

continent, with 63.5% of the regions having at least one property included on the List.

However, the regions scoring the highest number of sites tend to be located in the

Mediterranean area and, in particular, in countries like Italy and Spain that exhibit also

the highest number of sites on the List. On the other hand, regions without World

Heritage sites are more likely to be found in the United Kingdom and in Central and

Eastern Europe.

Figure 1 displays the distribution of World Heritage sites in 2015 across European

regions (NUTS2), providing a first illustration of the most visible spatial patterns.

2 To give an example, the World Heritage site of the Dolomiti in Italy, that extends through both the Veneto and the

Trentino Alto Adige regions, has been assigned to Veneto based on the reported GIS coordinates 3 Transnational serial properties are those where two or more spatially distinct components stretch across two or more

neighbouring countries, as individual components if they create a thematic, functional, historic, stylistic or typological

series with other, spatially distinct components. 4 Natural sites are only about 10% of listed properties in Europe compared to about 20% on the whole World Heritage

List.

Page 10: Kalòs kai agathòs? Government quality and cultural ...Kalòs kai agathòs? Government quality and cultural heritage . in the regions of Europe . Abstract . This paper uses panel

8

Figure 1: Number of UNESCO World Heritage Sites per region (NUTS2), 2015

In order to detect spatial dependence of World Heritage sites across the European

regions, we first use a global Moran’s I statistic as a measure of association, and then

local indicators of spatial association (LISA). LISA provide insights at the local level by

showing the tendency of observed phenomena to locate or not in neighboring regions

and are computed through a local Moran’s statistic where the population is a group of

neighboring regions depending on a contiguity criterion (Anselin, 1995).

Figure 2 presents the two measures using the first-order contiguity neighborhood

criterion, where the set of neighbors of region i includes all regions sharing a border with

it, and where each neighboring region j is attributed the same weight.5

5 Because the Queen contiguity weight matrix drops from the analysis 17 neighborless regions (i.e. islands), we also

tested a 5-nearest neighbors weight matrix as an alternative approach, obtaining very similar results.

Page 11: Kalòs kai agathòs? Government quality and cultural ...Kalòs kai agathòs? Government quality and cultural heritage . in the regions of Europe . Abstract . This paper uses panel

9

Figure 2: Global and Local indicators of spatial association for World Heritage sites

(First order Queen contiguity weight matrix)

(a) Global Moran’s I, p-value = 0.001 (b) LISA Map, significant clusters

The spatial association of UNESCO World Heritage sites across European regions

measured by the Global Moran’s I statistic is positive (0.16), but it is not particularly

high.6 Looking at the Moran scatterplot (Figure 2(a)), this is due to a relatively large

number of regions in the upper left and lower right quadrants, which indicate spatial

clustering of observations with diverging values. In other words, while some European

regions with many (few or none) World heritage sites do tend to cluster in space, there

are parts of the continent where regions with many (few) sites are surrounded by

neighboring regions with few (many) sites. The map of local indicator of spatial

association (LISA) displayed in Figure 2(b) highlights the most relevant local patterns

of concentration between regions. Even if a large part of reported local Moran’s I

statistics are not significant, a look at both the high-high (red) and low-low (blue) clusters

confirms the descriptive finding identified in Figure 1. Regions with high number of

World Heritage sites tend to be located in Southern European countries, whereas clusters

of regions scoring low values of heritage sites are more likely to be located in Central

and Eastern Europe (including Turkey).

6 A deeper inspection of the data indicates a Global Moran’s I statistics of 0.23 when considering only the regions in

Western European countries (Portugal, Spain, France, UK, Ireland, Italy, Germany and Benelux), while no spatial

association (0.07) for the regions in Eastern and Northern Europe.

Page 12: Kalòs kai agathòs? Government quality and cultural ...Kalòs kai agathòs? Government quality and cultural heritage . in the regions of Europe . Abstract . This paper uses panel

10

To explain the geographical distribution of World Heritage Sites across the European

Regions, Table 1 presents the estimated coefficients from a cross-sectional linear

regressions including as covariates geographical and historical factors that may have

determined the potential of a region to obtain a World Heritage deignation.7 The size of

the regions is a first rough indicator for the potential of having heritage sites included in

the List, assuming that the larger is a region, the higher is the likelihood to host within

its borders some outstanding heritage worth to be nominated in the UNESCO List. As

expected, the coefficient for this variable is always positive and significant (varying

between 5% and 10% significance level, depending on the specification). More

interestingly, the number of World Heritage sites is significantly explained by proxies of

the cultural potential of the region, based on its historical development. In particular,

using Chandler and Fox’s data on the geographical evolution of major urban settlements

in history (Chandler and Fox, 2013), we construct variables for different historical

periods (XI, XVI and XVIII century) reflecting the number of the most populated cities

in Europe (top one hundred) located in each region. From an historical perspective, major

urban centers have been the loci of the most intense socio-economic activities as well as

of the highest achievements in cultural and artistic expression. As a result, one can expect

that the more a region has hosted major urban centers during the past, the more World

Heritage sites it contains today. As can be noted in Regressions 1-3 in Table 1, the

coefficients indicating the effect of the number of major cities in European history on

the number of current sites is positive and highly significant, with the distribution of

major cities across regions in the XVI century leading to the largest effect on the number

of World Heritage sites. This result also points out how most of European World

Heritage can be traced back to this specific historical period. The effect of the historical

cultural potential of regions also holds when we use a cumulative variable based on the

previous three periods (regression 4).

7 Following Frey et al. (2013) we have also estimated count data models considering that the dependent variable can

only take natural numbers. The results and significance of coefficients are similar in the two settings and for clarity

and convenience in interpreting the results we opted for the OLS ones in this case.

Page 13: Kalòs kai agathòs? Government quality and cultural ...Kalòs kai agathòs? Government quality and cultural heritage . in the regions of Europe . Abstract . This paper uses panel

11

Table 1: Determinants of the total number of sites in the World Heritage List 2015

(1) (2) (3) (4)

SIZEmil 0.00910* 0.00838** 0.0111** 0.00881**

(0.00451) (0.00407) (0.00542) (0.00411)

XIcen 0.730***

(0.192)

XVIcen 0.811***

(0.182)

XVIIIcen 0.687***

(0.180)

TotHistUrb 0.303***

(0.0674)

Constant 0.842*** 0.833*** 0.836*** 0.796***

(0.120) (0.129) (0.122) (0.126)

Observations 289 289 289 289

R-squared 0.220 0.242 0.184 0.252

Adjusted R-squared 0.215 0.237 0.179 0.247

Standard errors (clustered at country level) in parentheses: *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1.

As a final piece of evidence, figure 3 presents the distribution of new sites included

in the World Heritage List over the period 2010-2015, based on the regional allocation

method previously described. With only 25 new listed properties,8 the relatively low

number of inscriptions is mainly the effect of the rules and procedures adopted in the last

decade by UNESCO, which have restricted to one (or two in special cases) the number

of nominations that can be submitted by state parties for selection. As a result, as shown

in figure 3, very few regions have obtained a UNESCO designation in the reference

period, with the exception of only two (Sicily in Italy and Izmir in Turkey) with two new

listed sites. Interestingly, the regions that have been able to include new sites in the List

tend to be relatively clustered in some specific countries (i.e., France, Germany,

Portugal, Italy, and Turkey) suggesting that regions’ behavior may still be influenced to

some extent by group or country factors.

8 The number of new sites considered here for the period 2010-2015 is lower than the actual number of

inscriptions as we excluded transnational serial sites for methodological reasons.

Page 14: Kalòs kai agathòs? Government quality and cultural ...Kalòs kai agathòs? Government quality and cultural heritage . in the regions of Europe . Abstract . This paper uses panel

12

Figure 3: Regions with new sites inscribed in the World Heritage List, 2010-2015

5 Econometric analysis

5.1 Empirical strategy and variables

To investigate the determinants of the probability of European regions having a site

included in the UNESCO World Heritage List we focus on two main channels. First, we

consider the regional quality of government as a factor affecting the level of protection

and support to heritage and, consequently, the ability of a region to obtain the World

Heritage designation. Secondly, we test whether the location of a region matters for the

chances of its nominations to obtain the World Heritage designation by controlling for

the stock of listed heritage sites that are located in the surrounding regions. In fact, the

documented process of spatial concentration of world heritage sites might indicate, after

controlling for the quality and stock of the heritage endowment, potential spill-overs

across regions in heritage policy and their ability to obtain World Heritage designations.

We use a panel data set of European regions r=1,...,R over six years t=2010,...,2015.

The key variable that we observe at the regional level is a binary variable, 𝑖𝑟𝑡, equaling

1 if a region r has (at least) one new site inscribed into the UNESCO list in a given year

Page 15: Kalòs kai agathòs? Government quality and cultural ...Kalòs kai agathòs? Government quality and cultural heritage . in the regions of Europe . Abstract . This paper uses panel

13

t. 𝑖𝑟𝑡 depends in turn on the realization of an underlying (unobserved) score, 𝑖𝑟𝑡∗ , with

𝑖𝑟𝑡 = 1 (0) if 𝑖𝑟𝑡∗ 0 (< 0). The 𝑖𝑟𝑡

∗ score is modelled in equation (1):

𝑖𝑟𝑡∗ = 𝒙𝑟𝑡

′ 𝛽 + 𝜃𝑄𝑜𝐺𝑟�̃� + 𝛾𝑊𝐻𝑟𝑡−1 + 𝛿 ∑ 𝜔𝑟𝑗𝑗 𝑊𝐻𝑗𝑡−1 + 𝜏𝑇𝑟𝑡−2 + 𝑦𝑡 + 휀𝑟𝑡 (1)

𝒙𝑟𝑡′ in equation (1) is a vector of regional variables at year t, namely (logarithm

transformations of) population, size and income per capita. These covariates have been

commonly considered as determinants of countries’ ability to inscribe heritage sites in

the UNESCO World Heritage List, and we include them to test their effect at the sub-

national level.

The Quality of Government index 𝑄𝑜𝐺𝑟�̃� is observed in 2010 and 2013, and:

�̃�=2010 if t≤2012 and �̃�=2013 if t≥2013. 𝑊𝐻𝑟𝑡−1 and 𝑊𝐻𝑗𝑡−1 index the stock of

World Heritage sites in regions r and j at time t−1, respectively. 𝜔𝑟𝑗 ∈ (0,1), r,j=1,...,R,

is an (R×R) set of spatial weights, with 𝜔𝑟𝑗 = 1 if regions r and j are adjacent (i.e., they

share a common border), 0 otherwise, so that 𝛿 captures the impact of the total number

of listed sites in the neighborhood at the end of the previous period on the probability of

having a site listed in a region in period t. 𝑇𝑟𝑡−2 is the number of properties in the

UNESCO Tentative List in region r at time t−2. As the Tentative List is made of sites

which state parties consider to be of outstanding universal value and suitable for

inscription on the World Heritage List, this variable is a proxy of the quality and quantity

of regions’ total heritage endowment not yet included in the List. The two years lag has

been chosen in this case, because, according to UNESCO operational guidelines, state

parties must submit sites to the Tentative List at least one year prior to the submission of

any nomination.

The inclusion of the lagged stock of sites in the World Heritage List deserves some

further consideration for potential endogeneity concerns. In fact, one could argue that

the same factors that we claim currently influence the new inscriptions of World Heritage

sites at the regional level may have equally affected the ability to include sites in the

World Heritage and Tentative List by regions in the past. However, it is worth to remind

that the stock of World Heritage sites in each region is the result of a cumulative process

of inscriptions in the List over more than 40 years, a period during which regions have

played a minor role in the nomination and selection process relatively to the period we

are analyzing here.

As for the Quality of Government index at the regional level (𝑄𝑜𝐺𝑟�̃�), we consider

both the global index and its sub components, expressing the quality of public services,

impartiality in provision, and control of corruption. We use the values observed in 2010

and 2013 and reported in the dataset released with the 2013 wave, which excludes the

observations for the Turkish regions. Previous works (Rodriguez-Pose and Di Cataldo,

Page 16: Kalòs kai agathòs? Government quality and cultural ...Kalòs kai agathòs? Government quality and cultural heritage . in the regions of Europe . Abstract . This paper uses panel

14

2015; Rodriguez-Pose and Garcilazo, 2015; Crescenzi et al., 2016) have adopted the

regional quality of government in panel settings, but used only the value observed in one

wave. As a result, by using two waves, our approach can capture the within-country

evolution of regions’ quality of government during the period of analysis.

While we seek to isolate the determinants of the conservation of heritage at the

regional level and the ability to include heritage in the World Heritage List, we cannot

completely rule out that this outcome can be influenced by some country-level

characteristics that may enable or hinder regions’ activity depending on the procedures

of the UNESCO World Heritage nomination and selection process. As a result, we

include in our specification the number of regions of a country to capture the effect of

the competition between regions in the same country. Further, we consider two

additional dimensions of the activity of a country in the World Heritage system that may

affect the actual capacity of its regions to inscribe sites in the List. The variable

Committee is a binary variable indicating whether or not a country is serving on the

World Heritage Committee. Previous works (Bertacchini and Saccone 2012; Frey et al.

2013) suggest that this variable has a positive impact on the inscription of World

Heritage sites, as countries that serve the World Heritage Committee in a given year

might be more likely to propose and inscribe sites, thus generating a greater chance for

the regions within their borders. Finally, we include the total number of years a country

has been member of the World Heritage Committee. This variable captures differences

in the active involvement of countries in the UNESCO World Heritage system, and may

signal the interest of national and local governments in using the World Heritage List as

a mechanism for the protection and promotion of their heritage. Table A1 in the

Appendix presents the summary statistics of all variables used. We estimate equation (1)

by Probit with random effects.9

5.2 Results

Table 2 summarizes the results obtained by estimating equation (1) under different

specifications. First, we consider the spatial effect of the stock of World Heritage sites

in neighboring regions on the likelihood of obtaining a new inscription (regressions 5

and 6); next, we include the regional quality of government scores (regressions 7 and 8);

finally, we estimate the full model with both effects (regressions 9 and 10). In all

instances, we show the results when taking (or not) into account year fixed effects that

pick common time factors, i.e., the specific World Heritage Committee behavior and

9 A random effects specification is preferable to a fixed effects one in this context because of significant

between-group variation in the explanatory variables and little within-group variation (due to the rare

occurrence of non-zero outcomes) in the dependent variable.

Page 17: Kalòs kai agathòs? Government quality and cultural ...Kalòs kai agathòs? Government quality and cultural heritage . in the regions of Europe . Abstract . This paper uses panel

15

attitude towards selection of properties to be included in the List in a given annual

session.

Table 2: Random-effects panel Probit estimation of having a new site included in the

World Heritage List

(5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10)

WH -0.0238 -0.0252 0.0169 0.0147 0.0171 0.0149

(0.0637) (0.0612) (0.0664) (0.0642) (0.0676) (0.0655)

Sites Tentative List 0.107** 0.110** 0.109* 0.113** 0.109* 0.113*

(0.0502) (0.0507) (0.0567) (0.0578) (0.0574) (0.0583)

Neighboring WH -0.00468 -0.00398 -0.00449 -0.00391

(0.0218) (0.0216) (0.0253) (0.0251)

QoG 0.339*** 0.349*** 0.336*** 0.346***

(0.116) (0.116) (0.120) (0.119)

Population (ln) 0.132 0.142 0.204* 0.218* 0.204* 0.218*

(0.104) (0.103) (0.118) (0.117) (0.117) (0.116)

Size (ln) 0.0555 0.0497 -0.0284 -0.0326 -0.0210 -0.0261

(0.0753) (0.0743) (0.0848) (0.0845) (0.0879) (0.0870)

Income p.c. (ln) 0.482** 0.446** -0.0388 -0.0862 -0.0286 -0.0770

(0.207) (0.200) (0.313) (0.312) (0.316) (0.313)

Num. Regions -0.00960 -0.00907 -0.0149* -0.0145* -0.0149* -0.0146*

(0.00766) (0.00766) (0.00825) (0.00824) (0.00821) (0.00820)

Years in WH Comm. 0.0320*** 0.0312*** 0.0442*** 0.0435*** 0.0450*** 0.0441***

(0.0119) (0.0114) (0.0111) (0.0104) (0.0126) (0.0120)

WH Committee -0.0308 -0.0340 -0.129 -0.133 -0.135 -0.138

(0.200) (0.195) (0.206) (0.201) (0.212) (0.207)

Constant -9.621*** -9.639*** -4.768 -4.762 -4.917 -4.892

(2.658) (2.506) (3.348) (3.266) (3.445) (3.344)

Year Dummies NO YES NO YES NO YES

Observations 1,664 1,664 1,606 1,606 1,606 1,606

Number of regions 279 279 269 269 269 269

Log Pseudo-

likelihood

-126.5 -125.4 -119.1 -118 -119.1 -118

Note: Robust standard errors in parentheses: *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1.

Considering the stock of World Heritage sites in the neighboring regions first

(Neighboring WH), the coefficient for this variable is never significant under any

specification. Thus we can reject the hypothesis that a spatial spill-over impacts the

probability to obtain new inscriptions at the regional level. Conversely, the coefficient

on the regional quality of government (QoG) is estimated to be positive and always

significant at the 5% level (reg. 7-10) indicating that local governments that are more

accountable are also more likely to protect and support their cultural heritage, leading to

a higher chance to obtain the UNESCO World Heritage recognition. Holding all other

variables to their means, one unit increase in the quality of government (corresponding

to one standard deviation) raises the probability by one region of obtaining a World

Page 18: Kalòs kai agathòs? Government quality and cultural ...Kalòs kai agathòs? Government quality and cultural heritage . in the regions of Europe . Abstract . This paper uses panel

16

Heritage designation in one year by one percentage point. To have a clearer picture of

the size of the effect for this variable, Figure 4 displays the predicted probability of

inscribing in one year a new site according to variation in the regional quality of

government. Regions with a quality of government score equal to 1 (e.g., Vlaams Gevest

region in Belgium) exhibit a 3% probability of having a new heritage site included in the

World Heritage List during any year, which is five times larger than the corresponding

chances of regions where the quality of government score is equal to -1 (e.g., Abruzzo

region in Italy).

Figure 4: Predictive probabilities of obtaining a World Heritage Site according to

variation in quality of government

As one could expect, a region’s capacity to nominate and inscribe site in the World

Heritage List is positively affected by the number of sites in the Tentative List. This

effect is stable over regressions, even if only at the 10% significance level. At the same

time, the results point out that a number of circumstances at the country level play a role.

In particular, while being member of the World Heritage Committee by a country does

not lead to a significant effect at the regional level, the coefficient of the number of years

a country has served to the Committee is positive and highly significant. This finding

suggests that the likelihood regional governments have to protect and promote the

cultural heritage through the UNESCO List varies based on the historical involvement

in the World Heritage system by their country. Additionally, the number of regions in a

country turns out significant at the 10% level and with a negative coefficient, indicating

Page 19: Kalòs kai agathòs? Government quality and cultural ...Kalòs kai agathòs? Government quality and cultural heritage . in the regions of Europe . Abstract . This paper uses panel

17

some effect of within-country competition between regions for nominating and

inscribing World Heritage sites.

Among the other regional variables, the coefficient of population is statistically

significant and with a positive sign. One possible explanation of this result is that more

populated European regions tend to have historically more urbanized areas and this may

reflects into a larger stock of available cultural heritage. Moreover, the effect of regional

income per capita is significant only when the quality of government is not included in

the model (reg. 5-6) suggesting that the latter factor is a more robust predictor of regions’

capacity in protecting heritage and inscribing sites in the World Heritage List.

The decomposition of the Quality of Government index into its three basic

components in Table 3 (Regressions 11-13) displays interesting differences in the link

between specific institutional factors and the capacity to inscribe World Heritage Sites

at the regional level. In all three cases, the main results obtained in previous

specifications hold, with the coefficients for the three sub-indexes being positive and

significantly different from zero. Interestingly, the component referring to the control of

corruption exhibits the highest significance and largest coefficient value among the three

sub-indexes, while government impartiality has the lowest significance and smallest

effect. This finding is in line with previous research showing that the level of perceived

corruption has the strongest and most significant effect on regional performance in

various domains, such as innovation capacity (Rodriguez-Pose and Di Cataldo, 2015)

and presence of small and medium-sized enterprises (Nistotskaya et al., 2014). Similarly,

since the conservation of cultural heritage strongly relies on the enforcement of

regulations and investment in capital assets, the corruption dimension, rather than the

quality and impartiality in the provision of public services, is possibly the one that better

captures the capacity of regional governments in heritage policy-making and

enforcement.

Considering we find no spatial effect for the stock of World Heritage in neighboring

regions on the likelihood of inscription of World Heritage sites, in regression 14 we

additionally test whether spatial spillovers might occur only within country, due to

national institutional factors which might hinder the effect across national borders. For

this reason, as alternative specification we employ a spatial weighting matrix that

accounts only for within-country adjacent regions. In this case too, though, the stock of

World Heritage sites in adjacent regions does not turn out to be a significant predictor,

while the other effects hold.

Page 20: Kalòs kai agathòs? Government quality and cultural ...Kalòs kai agathòs? Government quality and cultural heritage . in the regions of Europe . Abstract . This paper uses panel

18

Table 3: Random-effects panel Probit estimation

(11) (12) (13) (14)

WH 0.00905 -0.00420 0.0155 0.0184

(0.0636) (0.0664) (0.0707) (0.0667)

Sites Tentative List 0.113* 0.112* 0.125* 0.111*

(0.0601) (0.0577) (0.0637) (0.0605)

Neighboring WH -0.00876 -0.00520 -0.000241

(0.0247) (0.0232) (0.0267)

Neighboring WH (within

country)

-0.0257

(0.0268)

QoG 0.336***

(0.117)

Quality public services 0.302**

(0.125)

Impartiality 0.225**

(0.107)

Control of corruption 0.433***

(0.121)

Population (ln) 0.209* 0.179 0.230** 0.215*

(0.112) (0.116) (0.116) (0.113)

Size (ln) 0.00805 0.0167 -0.0378 -0.00596

(0.0885) (0.0889) (0.0919) (0.0818)

Income per capita (ln) 0.0237 0.180 -0.196 -0.0229

(0.300) (0.288) (0.319) (0.298)

Num. Regions -0.0127 -0.0144* -0.0149* -0.0140*

(0.00789) (0.00863) (0.00806) (0.00807)

Years in WH Committee 0.0410*** 0.0402*** 0.0459*** 0.0476***

(0.0115) (0.0121) (0.0127) (0.0118)

WH Committee -0.145 -0.103 -0.154 -0.170

(0.209) (0.207) (0.205) (0.208)

Constant -6.044* -7.215** -3.824 -5.537*

(3.227) (3.120) (3.493) (3.228)

Year Dummies YES YES YES YES

Observations 1,600 1,600 1,600 1,606

Number of regions 267 267 267 269

Log Pseudo-likelihood -118.3 -119.2 -116 -117.5

Note: Robust standard errors in parentheses: *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1.

One peculiar characteristic of World Heritage designation is that the preparation of

the nomination until the successful inclusion in the List is a lengthy process that might

take several years. One concern in analyzing new World Heritage inscriptions by regions

is that a year-by-year perspective within a panel data approach might be too fine-grained

to account for the World Heritage designation process. For example, if a region is able

to inscribe a heritage site at year t, the probability of obtaining a new World Heritage

designation at year t+1 is possibly lower and conditioned on the previous outcome. To

check the robustness of our results against this argument, Table 4 provides estimations

using a collapsed dataset to a single period. In this case, we estimate the probability that

Page 21: Kalòs kai agathòs? Government quality and cultural ...Kalòs kai agathòs? Government quality and cultural heritage . in the regions of Europe . Abstract . This paper uses panel

19

European regions obtain at least one heritage site in the period 2010-2015 by exploiting

the cross-sectional variance of our explanatory variables.

Table 4: Probit on collapsed dataset and Linear Probability Spatial Error Model (SEM)

(15) (16) (17) (18) (19)

Probit Probit Probit Probit LP SEM

WH 0.0267 0.0116 -0.00978 0.0123 -0.0026

(0.0937) (0.0896) (0.0898) (0.0974) (0.014)

Sites Tentative List 0.192** 0.201* 0.195** 0.224** 0.040***

(0.0979) (0.103) (0.0991) (0.102) (0.014)

Neighboring WH 0.0114 0.00357 0.00752 0.0166 0.0002

(0.0451) (0.0457) (0.0426) (0.0458) (0.004)

QoG 0.623** 0.061**

(0.255) (0.029)

Quality public services 0.578***

(0.221)

Impartiality 0.425*

(0.223)

Control of corruption 0.764***

(0.267)

Population (ln) 0.324* 0.313* 0.267 0.336* 0.0435

(0.174) (0.168) (0.169) (0.176) (0.027)

Size (ln) -0.117 -0.0578 -0.0404 -0.105 -0.003

(0.103) (0.0846) (0.0876) (0.0969) (0.021)

Income per capita (ln) -0.179 -0.0267 0.260 -0.285 0.0028

(0.480) (0.390) (0.395) (0.520) (0.068)

Num. Regions -0.0258* -0.0249* -0.0282* -0.0253* -0.0025

(0.0147) (0.0142) (0.0148) (0.0143) (0.002)

Years in WH Committee 0.0645*** 0.0570*** 0.0551** 0.0699*** 0.008***

(0.0234) (0.0217) (0.0219) (0.0259) (0.003)

WH Committee 0.0604 0.0785 0.0952 0.0385 0.0094

(0.0891) (0.0848) (0.0850) (0.0886) (0.014)

Lambda 0.170**

(0.081)

Constant -3.735 -5.561 -7.814* -3.086 -0.592

(4.589) (4.028) (4.084) (4.854) (0.759)

Observations 267 265 265 265 267

Log Pseudo-likelihood -66.70 -66.28 -67.51 -64.35 -30.22

R-Squared 0.140

Note: Standard errors in parentheses: *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1.

Page 22: Kalòs kai agathòs? Government quality and cultural ...Kalòs kai agathòs? Government quality and cultural heritage . in the regions of Europe . Abstract . This paper uses panel

20

Regressions 15-18 show Probit estimation with robust standard errors using the global

index of the regional quality of government and its components. The main results hold

in this specification too, with similar level of significance for the coefficients and,

expectedly, higher marginal effects. As shown in Figure 5, differences in the regional

quality of government scores have a large impact on the success of regional heritage

policy: regions registering a regional QoG score of 1 have an 18% chance to inscribe at

least one World Heritage site during the period, relatively to a 3% probability of regions

scoring -1.

Figure 5: Predictive probabilities of obtaining a World Heritage Site according to

variation in quality of government, 6 years period

Finally, in regression 19 of Table 4 we estimate a spatial error model (SEM), that is, a

linear regression model that allows for a first-order spatial auto-regressive process in the

residuals to test the robustness of our results against unobserved neighboring effects. The

results are in line with those obtained with the Probit model, and the coefficient on the

spatially correlated errors (lambda) is positive and significant, confirming the presence

of spatially correlated unobserved determinants of the chances of a region having its sites

included in the World Heritage list.

6 Concluding Remarks

This paper has used a newly constructed panel dataset that matches the distribution of

UNESCO world heritage sites across over 200 European regions with indicators of

quality of government to test whether the characteristics of governments in terms of

probity, fairness and ability to provide public services positively affect regions’ capacity

Page 23: Kalòs kai agathòs? Government quality and cultural ...Kalòs kai agathòs? Government quality and cultural heritage . in the regions of Europe . Abstract . This paper uses panel

21

to protect and support their heritage, and proxied that capacity by the chances to have

heritage sites nominated and included in the UNESCO World Heritage list. The paper

contributes to the literature on the political and economic determinants of UNESCO

World Heritage by adding a regional and spatial perspective to the analysis. Further, it

contributes to the scholarly debate on the effects of the quality of institutions and

governance by providing novel insights in the field of heritage and cultural policies.

Knowledge of the geographical distribution of sites across the European regions has

allowed us to give a fresh picture of the spatial pattern of the existing stock of UNESCO

sites in Europe as well as to test for the existence of spill-overs from the presence of

heritage sites in a region to the chances of new sites being inscribed in neighboring

regions. After controlling for regional and national factors previously used to explain the

nomination and inscription activity of World Heritage sites, the empirical analysis

unveils that the quality of the regional governments positively influences the chances of

a region having a heritage site inscribed in the UNESCO list in a given year. Conversely,

we find no significant spill-over impact across regions on the ability to obtain World

Heritage designations based on the stock of world heritage sites in neighboring regions.

The results of the analysis have relevant policy implications too. They empirically

confirm that the effective protection and support to cultural heritage is influenced not

only by national heritage policies, but also by indicators of government ‘health’ at the

sub-national level that can be considered as proxies of a more general commitment of a

local community to protect and promote its heritage. In particular, high levels of

corruption emerge as the main obstacle to effective heritage protection policy in the

regions of Europe. Additionally, as for the UNESCO World Heritage selection process,

the findings suggest that, at least in the European context, the rules adopted to limit the

annual number of national sites to be included in the World Heritage List might have

partly shifted the competition from states to regions within the same country, making the

accountability of regional governments an increasingly relevant factor for obtaining new

designations.

Page 24: Kalòs kai agathòs? Government quality and cultural ...Kalòs kai agathòs? Government quality and cultural heritage . in the regions of Europe . Abstract . This paper uses panel

22

References

Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S., and J. Robinson (2001) The colonial origins of comparative

development: An empirical investigation. American Economic Review 91: 1369-1401.

Anselin, L. (1995) Local indicators of spatial association. Geographical Analysis 27: 93-

115.

Bertacchini, E., Liuzza, C., Meskell, L., and D. Saccone (2016) The politicization of

UNESCO World Heritage decision making. Public Choice 167: 95-129.

Bertacchini, E., Saccone, D., (2012) Toward a political economy of world heritage.

Journal of Cultural Economics 36: 327-352.

Chandler, T., & Fox, G. (2013). 3000 Years of Urban Growth. Amsterdam: Elsevier.

Charron, N., (2013). From AAland to Ankara: European Quality of Government index.

Data, sensitivity analysis and final results, Quality of Government Institute, University

of Gothenburg, Working Paper Series 2013:11.

Charron, N., Dijkstra, L., and V. Lapuente (2014) Regional governance matters: Quality

of government within European Union member states. Regional Studies 48: 68-90.

Charron, N., Dijkstra, L., and V. Lapuente (2015) Mapping the regional divide in

Europe: A measure for assessing quality of government in 206 European regions. Social

Indicators Research 122: 315-346.

Charron, N., Lapuente, V. (2018). Quality of government in EU regions: spatial and

temporal patterns. QoG Working Paper Series 2018.1.

Crescenzi, R., M. Di Cataldo, and A. Rodriguez-Pose, (2016). "Government quality and

the economic returns of transport infrastructure investment in European regions."

Journal of Regional Science 56: 555-582.

European Commission (2018) Cultural Heritage. Special Eurobarometer Report 466

Fyall, A., Rakic, T. (2006) The future market for World Heritage sites. Managing World

Heritage Sites, 159-175.

Frey, B., Steiner, L. (2011) World Heritage List: does it make sense? International

Journal of Cultural Policy, 17(5), 555-573.

Frey, B., Pamini, P, and L. Steiner (2013) Explaining the world heritage list: an empirical

study. International Review of Economics, 60, 1-19.

OECD (2005). Culture and local development. OECD Publishing

Harrison, D., Hitchcock, M. (2005) The politics of world heritage: Negotiating tourism

and conservation. Channel View Publications.

Page 25: Kalòs kai agathòs? Government quality and cultural ...Kalòs kai agathòs? Government quality and cultural heritage . in the regions of Europe . Abstract . This paper uses panel

23

Kaufmann, D., Kraay, A., and M. Mastruzzi (2009) Governance Matters VIII: Aggregate

and Individual Governance Indicators for 1996–2008. World Bank Policy Research

Working Paper No. 4978. World Bank, Washington, DC

Ketterer, T., Rodríguez-Pose, A. (2015) Local quality of government and voting with

one’s feet, Annals of Regional Science 55: 501-532.

Musitelli, J. (2002) World heritage, between universalism and globalization.

International Journal of Cultural Property 11: 323.

Nistotskaya, M., Charron, N., and V. Lapuente (2015) The wealth of regions: quality of

government and SMEs in 172 European regions. Environment and Planning C:

Government and Policy 33: 1125-1155.

Peacock, A., Rizzo, I. (2008) The Heritage Game. Economics, Politics, and Practice,

Oxford: Oxford University Press

Parenti, B., De Simone, E. (2015) Explaining determinants of national UNESCO

Tentative Lists: an empirical study, Applied Economics Letters 22: 1193-1198.

Rizzo, I. (2004) The relationship between regional and national policies in the arts. In:

V. Ginsburgh (Ed.) Economics of Art and Culture. Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp. 203-219.

Rodriguez-Pose, A., Di Cataldo, M. (2014). Quality of government and innovative

performance in the regions of Europe. Journal of Economic Geography 15.4: 673-706.

Rodriguez-Pose, A., Garcilazo, E. (2015). Quality of government and the returns of

investment: Examining the impact of cohesion expenditure in European regions.

Regional Studies 49: 1274-1290.

Rodrik D., Subramanian F. and F. Trebbi (2004) Institutions rule: the primacy of

institutions over geography and integration in economic development, Journal of

Economic Growth 9: 131-165.

Strasser, P. (2002) Putting Reform Into Action. Thirty Years of the World Heritage

Convention: How to Reform a Convention without Changing Its Regulations.

International Journal of Cultural Property 11: 215-266.

Tabellini, G. (2010) Culture and institutions: economic development in the regions of

Europe. Journal of the European Economic association, 8.4: 677-716.

Titchen, S. (1996) On the construction of outstanding universal value: Some comments

on the implementation of the 1972 UNESCO World Heritage Convention. Conservation

and Management of Archaeological Sites 1.4: 235-242.

Throsby, D. (2010) The Economics of Cultural Policy. Cambridge University Press.

Page 26: Kalòs kai agathòs? Government quality and cultural ...Kalòs kai agathòs? Government quality and cultural heritage . in the regions of Europe . Abstract . This paper uses panel

24

UNDP (2014) Governance for Sustainable Development: Integrating Governance in the

Post-2015 Development Framework, United Nations Development Programme.

UNESCO (2007) World Heritage: Millenium challenges. Paris: World Heritage Centre.

UNESCO (2017) Operational guidelines for the implementation of the World Heritage

Convention. https://whc.unesco.org/document/163852.

Page 27: Kalòs kai agathòs? Government quality and cultural ...Kalòs kai agathòs? Government quality and cultural heritage . in the regions of Europe . Abstract . This paper uses panel

25

APPENDIX

Table A1: Summary Statistics

VARIABLES N mean sd min max

New Sites (Dependent variable) 1,890 0.0180 0.133 0 1

WH (lag) 1,890 1.108 1.292 0 7

Neighboring WH (lag) 1,890 4.903 4.222 0 24

Site Tentative List 1,890 0.733 1.312 0 9

Number of Regions 1,920 20.42 12.80 1 40

Quality of Government 1,608 0.141 0.957 -2.838 2.639

- Quality public services 1,602 0.142 0.949 -3.273 2.797

- Impartiality 1,602 0.130 0.956 -3.241 2.670

- Control of corruption 1,602 0.124 0.960 -2.836 2.240

World Heritage Committee 1,914 0.219 0.414 0 1

Years World Heritage Committee 1,914 8.617 7.099 0 23

Population (ln) 1,910 14.13 0.848 10.23 16.48

Size (ln) 1,920 9.163 1.330 2.565 12.33

Income per capita (ln) 1,696 10.09 0.394 8.854 12.07