japanese industrial policy the postwar record and the case

55
Chapter 6 Japanese Industrial Policy : The Postwar Record and the Case of Supercomputers

Upload: others

Post on 11-Jan-2022

1 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Chapter 6

Japanese Industrial Policy:

The Postwar Record andthe Case of Supercomputers

CONTENTSPage

ECONOMIC TRADITIONS AND INDUSTRIAL POLICY . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 239OVERVIEW OF TOOLS AND TARGETED SECTORS . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 241

Institutions of Industrial Policy . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 241Industrial Policy and Steel Industry Development . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 244Industrial Policy and Motor Vehicle Industry Development . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 246Color Televisions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 248Semiconductors . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 249

SUCCESSES AND FAILURES OF INDUSTRIAL POLICY . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 250INDUSTRIAL POLICY FOR THE 1990s . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 252SUPERCOMPUTER INDUSTRY DEVELOPMENT . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 253

Supercomputer Companies . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 254Potential Market . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 255Comparisons of U.S. and Japanese Supercomputers . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 256

HISTORICAL BACKGROUND: THE EFFECT OF PAST TARGETING OF THEMAINFRAME COMPUTER AND SEMICONDUCTOR INDUSTRIES . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 260

TARGETING SUPERCOMPUTERS . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 264The High Speed Computing System for Scientific and Technological Uses . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 265Other Government-Sponsored Projects Related to Supercomputer Technologies . . . . . . . . . . . . 268

PROCUREMENT OF SUPERCOMPUTERS . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 270Private Sector Procurement . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 270Public Sector Procurement . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 272

OTHER FACTORS CONTRIBUTING TO JAPAN’S SUCCESS IN NURTURING ADOMESTIC SUPERCOMPUTER INDUSTRY.. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 278Industry and Corporate Structure . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 278Japan’s Industrial Enterprise Groups . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 279

UNITED STATES POLICIES TOWARD THE SUPERCOMPUTER INDUSTRY . . . . . . . . . . . 279Appendix 6-A. Government Financial Assistance to the Computer Industry and Its Size

Relative to Private Sector Investment 1961-89. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 289

FiguresFigure Page6-1. Actual v. Peak Supercomputer Performance . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 2586-2. Performance/Price Data . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 2596-3. Schedule of Research and Development for High Speed Computing System for Scientific

and Technological Uses Project . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 2656-4. organization of the Supercomputer Project, 1981-89. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 266

TablesTable Page

6-1. Comparison of Cray Research, Fujitsu, Hitachi, and NEC Revenues, R&D Expenditures,and Profits, 1981, 1982, 1988, 1989 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 254

6-2. Cray Researches Revenues, R&D Expenditures, and Profits . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 2556-3. Divisions of U.S. and Japanese Supercomputers Firms, 1989 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 2556-4. Value of Worldwide Supercomputer Shipments . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 2566-5. Number of New Installations in Japanese Supercomputer Market . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 2576-6. Japanese Procurement of Supercomputers, 1980-90 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 2606-7. Government Subsidies for Computer-Related Government-SponsoredR&D Projects . . . . . 2636-8. U.S. and Japanese Supercomputer Companies’ Share of the World Market . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 2706-9. U.S. and Japanese Supercomputer Companies’ Share of the European Market, 1989 . . . . . 270

6-10. U.S. and Japanese Supercomputer Companies’ Share of the Japanese Market, Installed Base . . 2716-11. Purchases by Firms with Keiretsu Ties to Japanese Supercomputer Makers, 1980-90.......2716-12. List Purchase and Rental Prices of Japanese Supercomputers . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 276

Chapter 6

Japanese Industrial Policy:The Postwar Record and the Case of Supercomputers

Japan is the world’s most successful practitionerof industrial policy. Japan’s industrial policies arelargely, though not solely, responsible for its eco-nomic recovery from World War II and its increasingpreeminence in high-technology industries. Otherfactors influencing these successes are intelligentcorporate strategies, an emphasis on saving andinvestment rather than consumption, and socialethics that place premium value on hard work andgood education.

The Japanese Government has used industrialpolicies throughout the postwar period-and indeeddid so for decades before the war-to guide theeconomy in the direction of higher value added andgreater knowledge intensity, and away from heavyreliance on unskilled labor and natural resources.l

While there is no consensus on the impact ofJapanese industrial policy on national income,research suggests that by reducing the costs and risksfor domestic firms to invest in a given industry, andby helping firms to advance technologically, indus-trial policies and targeting have contributed toJapan’s international competitiveness in many in-dustries, including steel, motor vehicles, semicon-ductors, and computers. Considering the impact thatcompetitive companies in these industries have onother industries both upstream and downstream, theeffect is profound.

American analysts are divided in their assess-ments of Japanese industrial policy. All acknowl-edge that the Japanese bureaucracy has tried tocreate competitive advantages both in specificindustries and for business in general. There is lessagreement about the results. It is rare in economicsor political science to encounter a bona fide controlgroup; lacking one, it is difficult to know whatwould have happened in a particular nation if somehistorical circumstance had been different. Wecannot be certain what Japan’s economic develop-ment would have been without industrial policy; thisleaves ample room for disagreement. At one end ofthe spectrum are analysts who view industrial policyas the major explanation of Japan’s success. Ana-lysts at the other end hold the view that Japan’sindustrial policies have had a marginal impact at

best. OTA’s conclusion is that industrial policy hasbeen a key ingredient, along with several otherattributes of Japanese society, policy, and businesstradition. 2

The debate over the effectiveness of Japan’sindustrial policies has been fierce for reasons otherthan the wide latitude for interpretation of historicalevents. Accepting that Japan’s approach has beensuccessful is close to admitting that perhaps our ownpolicies and ideology might need rethinking, adifficult and painful process for any nation. But theadmission of Japan’s success does not mean amakeover of America in Japan’s image. Othernations can learn from Japan’s success, as Japan didfrom nations more advanced; most of the world’sdeveloped nations or regions are in the process ofstrengthening their commitments to industrial poli-cies, in part because of Japan’s economic perform-ance. This does not mean that other nations orregions are blindly copying Japanese policies of thepast or present.

As most Western writers on the subject havenoted, Japan is changing, and has been throughoutthe postwar period. The speed and character of thechanges in Japan are another part of the vigorousdebate over Japanese policy. Some argue that Japanis becoming more like the West, in terms of botheconomic performance and government policy. Insome ways, it is; yet the Japanese industrial policytradition and bureaucracy are still powerful, andcontinue to operate in very different ways than theUnited States. Moreover, Japan’s Government andeconomic system continue to support developmentof industries and products at the high-technologyfrontier, although the intervention is less heavyhanded than it was a couple of decades ago.

ECONOMIC TRADITIONS ANDINDUSTRIAL POLICY

From very early in its history, the JapaneseGovernment took the initiative in industrializationand economic development. Threatened by foreignpowers and lagging behind economically and tech-nologically, the Meiji Government, together withthe top merchant families, took the lead in the 1870s

–239–

240 . Competing Economies: America, Europe, and the Pacific Rim

in establishing and promoting Japan’s basic infra-structure and industries.3 By the turn of the century,the policies devised by the Meiji Government topromote industrial development were paying off:iron and steel production doubled between 1875 and1895, machinery production rose sevenfold, andtextile production increased eightfold. Japan wasdeveloping military power as well, and was strongenough to renegotiate a few treaties that had rankledfor some time.4

Successful experience with a strong bureaucracyand close relations between business and govern-ment gives modem Japan a view of competition andthe appropriate role of the state that is quite differentfrom the laissez-faire traditions of the United Statesor Great Britain. Active government intervention inthe economy is considered natural and indispensiblein the Japanese bureaucracies, and unfettered priceand investment competition is viewed with reserva-tion, at best. Many of the practices of business andgovernment that are considered perfectly normalmeans of promoting industrial health and develop-ment in Japan are considered unfair in America.According to one analyst:

The American criticism of Japan. . . stem[s] fromthe conviction that in many cases market outcomesare shaped by Japanese business practices consid-ered unfair-predatory pricing, patent infringement,industrial espionage, and explicit or implicit protec-tion of Japanese markets from import competition. . . the basis on which the problem must rest [is that]Japanese success in blocking imports into their owncountry or in penetrating U.S. markets comes, atleast in part, from anticompetitive behavior ratherthan from competitive ability.5

Scholars differ not only on whether Japaneseindustrial policy has succeeded but also on thecriteria they use to measure success. Some studiesfocus on the contribution of industrial policies(including targeting) to the development of thetargeted industry,6 others on consumer welfare ornational return on investment,7 and still others onhow policies affect both specific industries and thenation’s long-term technological trajectory.8

Analysts at one end of the spectrum believe thatJapan’s active state bureaucracy, close government-business relationships, the stable political rule of theLiberal Democratic Party, the weak Diet (legisla-ture), and strong industrial policy are key ingredientsof Japan’s success. According to this school, Japan

is a mercantilist country that focuses primarily onnational economic goals and self-sufficiency. Withthe decline of U.S. hegemony, analysts of this stripeare particularly concerned about what they see asJapan’s hesitation to take on a fair share of theeconomic and political burden of supporting theworld economic order. They argue that Japan isbenefiting tremendously from the open tradingsystem, exploiting the openness of other nations.They acknowledge that fierce market competitionhas been another key ingredient of Japan’s success,but suggest that market forces have been shaped bystate industrial and trade policies and other institu-tional guidelines in ways that often benefit Japanesebusinesses at the expense of both foreign businessesand Japanese consumers. They identify institutionslike MITI (the Ministry of International Trade andIndustry), the keiretsu, the government’s JapanDevelopment Bank, and the quasi-governmentaltelecommunications giant, NIT, as hindering for-eign access to the Japanese market. While theyacknowledge that MITI’s power has waned inrecent years and that Japan’s economy is more opennow than it was a decade ago, they believe that MITIstill plays an important role in nurturing industriesand technologies, and that Japan’s market is stillmore closed to imports than those of most otherdeveloped nations.

There are a variety of views within this school ofthought. Some see the bureaucracy as having beenthe most important actor guiding development, somesee big business as having the upper hand in thegovernment-business relationship, and some believethat no one group in the ruling elite is really incharge.9

At the other end of the spectrum are those who seeJapan’s industrial policy as having had, at best, amarginal effect on Japan’s success. These analystsargue that high rates of savings and investmentoperating in a free market, a good educationalsystem, and willingness to quickly adopt foreigntechnologies are the key sources of Japan’s success.This group sees Japan as being very similar to theUnited States and Western capitalist democracies inhaving policies that both support the free traderegime and focus on maximizing consumer welfare.Some argue that Japan has developed in spite ofindustrial policy, others that industrial policy hasonly compensated for Japan’s underdeveloped stockand venture capital markets and small supply ofscientists, and still others that industrial policy has

Chapter 6--Japanese Industrial Policy: The Postwar Record and the Case of Supercomputers ● 241

helped at the margin in some industries.10 Overall,they believe that the role of Japan’s industrial policyhas been greatly exaggerated and point out that sometargeted industries, such as petrochemicals, have notbeen successful, while many competitive industries,such as consumer electronics, have not been activelytargeted. Proponents of this view argued for a longtime that the U.S. trade deficit with Japan had littleto do with Japan’s industrial and trade policies andwas instead primarily the result of an overvalueddollar. The failure of the sharp plunge of the dollarsince 1985 to correct the U.S.-Japan trade imbalancehas led several of these analysts to change theirviews. 11

In addition to the stubborn trade deficit withJapan, another development is reconciling some ofthe differences between the views described above.In the past decade or so, a group of economists oftenreferred to as ‘‘the new international economists,”using accepted economic methods, have given newlife to an old idea: that there are industries that addmore to national income and well-being than others,and that governments can raise national income bypromoting such industries. These sectors are charac-terized by significant barriers to entry (in terms ofboth knowledge and resources), increasing returns toscale, a steep learning curve, high value added, andsignificant positive spillovers to other sectors of theeconomy. Some of these analysts suggest that theJapanese Government, by using strategic industrialand trade policies, has been able to increase nationalincome in some cases by targeting such sectors.12

As new evidence becomes available, it seemsincreasingly clear that Japan’s industrial policy hascontributed significantly to the development ofseveral specific industries, and has created a climateconducive to development in many more; its role hasbeen particularly significant in high-risk, high-cost,and innovative industries.

OVERVIEW OF TOOLS ANDTARGETED SECTORS

There have been four main periods of industrialpolicy since World War II. The earliest, 1945 to1952, included the creation or rebuilding of many ofthe industrial-policy institutions to help Japan’seconomy get back on its feet. From the mid- 1950s tothe mid-1960s, the government began to allocatescarce funds to specific industries, including steel,automobiles, and electronics. The following decade

was the peak of Japan’s so-called high-growthperiod, and represented to many Japan’s last chanceto gain a foothold in high-technology industriesbefore the inevitable pressure to open up its marketsbegan. Government still wielded powerful tools,though with less heavy handed policies than in the1950s.

The current period began in the mid-1970s,following the first energy shock. Starting in the early1970s, the state, besieged by the oil crisis andvarious pollution and quality-of-life problems, beganto shift its support away from energy-intensiveindustries, such as steel, towards more knowledge-intensive, high value-added industries, such ascomputers, semiconductors, and biotechnology. Inthis period, and particularly in the 1980s, manyJapanese companies became very strong, and thusless dependent on government for protection andsubsidies. In response to increased trade friction,industrial and trade policies became less visible andformal, and tariffs and quotas were eliminated orsubstantially reduced. At the end of the decade, legalhindrances to foreign investment were removed aswell. Despite this liberalization, Japan’s marketremains one of the most difficult to enter, especiallyamong advanced capitalist countries; most of thecurrent barriers are business practices and institu-tions, many of which evolved to serve other pur-poses as well as protection.

Institutions of Industrial Policy

The Japanese bureaucracy, fortified by new toolsinstituted during the Occupation, used industrialpolicy to try to change Japan’s industrial structurefrom labor-intensive industries during and before thewar to capital-intensive industries in the two decadesfollowing the war, and to knowledge-intensiveindustries beginning in the 1970s. In the first fewyears following the war, Japanese and Occupationleaders set up many of the institutions and laws thatwould provide a foundation for postwar industrialpolicy. MITI, the central and most powerful of thoseinstitutions, was created in 1949 (before that, it wasthe Ministry of Commerce and Industry, or MCI). In1950, the Japan Export Bank (later called theExport-Import Bank) was established to promoteexports by providing financing. The government’sJapan Development Bank (JDB) was established in1951 to help supply low interest loans to designatedindustries for investment in plant and equipment.JDB went on to be an important bellwether for

242 ● Competing Economies: America, Europe, and the Pacific Rim

commercial bank lending, as well as being a lenderitself. 13

Several laws, such as the Foreign ExchangeControl Law of 1933, the Foreign Exchange andForeign Trade Control Law of 1949, and the ForeignInvestment Law of 1950, gave the Japanese Govern-ment control over the flow of foreign exchange,investment, and goods. Though necessary in theearly years to deal with balance-of-payment prob-lems, these laws also provided the government withan effective tool with which to protect Japaneseindustries from foreign competition. MITI’s controlover the foreign exchange budget “played a largerole in protecting and fostering domestic industry, ”states Professor Nakamura Takafusa of TokyoUniversity .14

Numerous studies show how these laws prohib-ited or controlled the entry of foreign products andinvestment and promoted production-oriented ratherthan consumer products-oriented industries.15 Forexample, the threat to fledgling Japanese producersfrom foreign firms that wished to sell cars or investin automobile production in Japan was substantial inthe early 1950s. The Japanese Government remem-bered that, in the 1930s, vehicles manufactured inJapan by General Motors and Ford came to dominatethe market, inhibiting the development of Japaneseauto companies. By 1934, vehicles made in Japan byAmerican companies held almost 90 percent of theJapanese market, and the large volume of importedparts threatened to leave Japan with a chronic tradedeficit.16 So, when several European and one Amer-ican automobile firm began to explore possibilitiesfor building assembly plants in Japan in the early1950s, MITI took several steps. One was to issue its“Basic Policy for the Introduction of ForeignInvestment into Japan’s Passenger Car Industry,”supplementing the Foreign Exchange Law, whichstated that repatriation of earnings from foreigninvestment in marketing facilities was not guaran-teed, and earnings repatriation from productionfacilities would be guaranteed only if those facilities“contributed significantly to the development ofdomestic industry.”17 In effect, this gave MITI theauthority to determine on a case-by-case basis whoseearnings could be repatriated, and effectively barredmarketing. Moreover, MITI stated that foreign firmswould be allowed to enter the Japanese market onlythrough technical tie-ups with domestic fins. Itannounced four provisions for inclusion in thecontracts:

1.

2.

3.

4.

small European cars were more suitable thanlarge American cars;the use of foreign currency allocated for carsshould be used for importing parts instead, andMITI could only allocate enough for produc-tion of 1,200 cars per company;the Japanese company should try to obtain theright to sell the cars in Southeast Asia; anddomestically made parts should eventuallysubstitute for imported parts.

Using these tough criteria, MITI rejected all but 4 of11 proposed tie-ups.18

Access to foreign technology was preferred overboth foreign direct investment and imports. Foreigntechnology was seen as an important source ofprofit, and access to it was tilted mostly towardsbasic industries.19 The automobile case was perhapsthe most notable exception; and even there, one ofthe primary reasons for promoting automobile pro-duction was to support the metalworking andmachinery industries that auto production demanded.MITI (which was MCI before 1949, but which isreferred to as MITI throughout this report, forconvenience) emphasized that automobile produc-tion was closely connected with parts and machineryindustries and established an automobile section inJanuary 1946.20 Later, in the 1950s, MITI used thesame argument more strongly, again in support of itsthen uncompetitive automobile industry, promotingpassenger car development as “the pinnacle of themodem machinery industry in our country wherethere is no aircraft industry.”21 Making cars wouldraise technology and quality in both machinery andsteel industries, as well as create markets.

Though originally enacted to deal with immediatepostwar problems, the laws controlling foreigninvestment and foreign exchange were retained farlonger than the Occupation forces intended; in manycases, they were not revised until the late 1970s and1980s, and many of the revisions were cosmetic. Onthe other hand, the antitrust law was weakened 1year after the Occupation ended; this enabled thegovernment to restrict competition and promoteeconomies of scale, authorized anti-recession andrationalization cartels, sanctioned retail price main-tenance, and relaxed restrictions on cooperativearrangements such as cross-shareholding, interlock-ing directorates, and mergers. In the late 1950s and1960s, the Japanese Government exempted from the

Chapter 6--Japanese Industrial Policy: The Postwar Record and the Case of Supercomputers ● 243

law certain sectors such as the machinery andelectronics industries.22

The weakening of the antitrust laws was also apart of the government’s strategy to encourage therebuilding of the industrial groups after the Occupa-tion. Industrial groups, or keiretsu, were also aprominent part of the Japanese economic scenebefore the war, but in somewhat different forms; thepre-war zaibatsu were family controlled enterprises,in many cases of quite grand proportions. While theJapanese authorities initially cooperated with theOccupation forces in dismantling the zaibatsu afterthe war, they had little commitment to a lessconcentrated economic structure overall.23 The reemer-gence of these groups as looser, bank-centeredalliances had two benefits: the government couldmore easily influence the behavior of firms throughcentralized control over funds and banking, and theclose relations of buyers and suppliers (includingcross-shareholding) within groups helped keep im-ports and foreign investment down. The cohesive-ness of the industrial groups became even moreimportant in the late 1950s and early 1960s, whenforeign pressure to liberalize Japan’s market steppedup. Japan also joined the Organization for EconomicCooperation and Development (OECD) and in 1964agreed to accept the obligations of a developedcountry under Article 11 in the General Agreementon Tariffs and Trade (GATT), which meant workingto eliminate quantitative restrictions on trade.24

Another institutional innovation that providedkey financial support for industrial policies is theFiscal Investment and Loan Program (FILP), a hugediscretionary “second budget” separate from thegeneral account budget.25 First established in 1953when the Ministry of Finance (MOF) pooled thepostal savings accounts, national pensions, andvarious other accounts, this budget is made annuallyby MITI and MOF bureaucrats with little input fromelected officials and other constituents. It is enormous;it has been from one-third to one-half the size of theGeneral Account Budget and has ranged from a lowof 3.3 percent of GNP in 1956 to a high of 6.3 percentin 1972.26 In 1990, the FILP was in the neighbor-hood of 34.6 trillion yen, or about $250 billion (at anexchange rate of Y135 per dollar) .27 The postalsavings system, which contributes nearly a quarterof the money in the total FILP budget, has depositsof over V134 trillion (about $1 trillion), making it thelargest financial institution in the world.28 Thesystem was able to attract savings from citizens by

allowing a lower tax rate on interest to depositorsand allowing the post offices to offer higher interestrates than banks, although these ‘‘higher” rates arestill low by American standards. In 1988, theyincreased to what was then a high of 1.68 percent,and recently went up to 3.48 percent.29 By payinglow interest rates to depositors, the FILP system hasbeen able to subsidize producers with low interestloans. 30

FILP money goes directly to finance governmentpolicies; it is still an important instrument of MITIinfluence. 31 In the 1950s especially, FILP wasindispensable for implementing government poli-cies; in the early part of that decade, it accounted fornearly 30 percent of the capital available to industry.In the 1980s, in contrast, FILP’s contribution fell toless than 10 percent. Japan’s companies now havemany sources of capital and far less need for publiclyfunded capital investments or indicative loans toencourage private sector lending.32

Targeting was also supported indirectly by abroader financial system that favors producers overconsumers. Indeed, by not allowing instruments ofconsumer credit to develop until recently, Japan hasmade it imperative that its citizens save a large partof their income for any major expenditures. The lackof adequate provisions for retirement also madesaving for old age a must. By limiting the develop-ment of viable alternatives to savings deposits andlimiting interest rates on those deposits, the govern-ment gave citizens little choice but to put theirsavings in bank or post office accounts at very lowinterest rates, while Japanese financial institutionswere able to invest those savings abroad at interestrates often exceeding 10 percent.

MITI thus controlled a large source of money thatwas unaffected by political maneuvering or lobby-ing, foreign exchange and investment, and trade.Also in the toolkit of policies to promote industrialdevelopment were policies to gain cheap access toforeign technology, tax measures to encouragespecific types of investment, the ability to organizecartels, and a limited ability to affect industrialconcentration (the number and size of firms in anindustry). Through a process of constant consensusbuilding with industry representatives, MITI bu-reaucrats could bring many specific measures intoplay as needed for the industries it wished topromote, as illustrated by the case studies below.

244 ● Competing Economies: America, Europe, and the Pacific Rim

Industrial Policy andSteel Industry Development

The steel industry is a key example of Japanbuilding up a competitive industry in an area inwhich it clearly had no comparative advantage. Thesteel industry was badly damaged during the war,leaving only about 25 to 30 percent of plant capacityfunctional as late as 1949.33 Japanese producers alsohad tremendous cost disadvantages, largely due tothe high price of imported raw materials and poorlabor productivity resulting from inefficient equip-ment.34 To help the industry become competitive,the government protected it from foreign competi-tion, gave it financial aid for investment in newtechnologies and improved plants, created variousmechanisms to manage domestic price and invest-ment competition, and encouraged mergers to helpthe firms gain greater economies of scale.

Initially the steel industry was protected by hightariffs. Japan imported very little steel during the1950s, even though domestic steel cost more thanU.S. steel. Except during the 1957 recession, steelimports never exceeded 2.7 percent of internaldemand. 35 Imports of raw materials and equipmentnecessary to produce steel were generally exemptfrom import duties.

Financial assistance in the form of grants, lowinterest loans, and tax breaks were given to theindustry, especially in the 1950s and early 1960s.Much of the aid came from Japanese coffers, but inthe 1957 to 1958 recession, MITI arranged for theWorld Bank to funnel loans to the steel industrythrough the Japan Development Bank. The JDBguaranteed the loans and also got the World Bank toloosen its regulations on the percent of equity andliquidity required for a firm receiving World Bankloans. 36 As in other industries, financial aid hadstrings attached: it went only to the firms MITI feltwere strongest and most capable of using the moneyeffectively, and it was given for investment inspecific types of equipment, especially to larger,modern factories using efficient technologies.

MITI’s control over access to foreign exchangeenabled it to play a key role in the introduction anddiffusion of basic oxygen furnace (BOF) technol-ofg.37 In 1955, two Japanese steel makers asked tolicense BOF technology from an Austrian firm.Mill, concerned that competition between the twofor technology would result in a higher price,

selected one to be the general licensee and requiredthat it give the other steel makers equal access to thetechnology as sublicensees.38 This kept the Austrianpatent holder from playing the Japanese companiesoff against each other to get a higher license fee, astrategy MITI would use again in gaining access toforeign technology, notably in semiconductors andcomputers. A complex agreement was worked outby which all firms using the BOF technologycontributed to the $1.2 million license fee. AS aresult, the technology was cheap: during the 14-yearperiod of the license, it cost Japanese steel makers0.36 cents per ton, compared with the 15 to 25 centsper ton that North American firms paid in royalties.39

In addition, MITI’s action helped diffuse the tech-nology quickly.

40 The competition, then, quicklyshifted from who could gain access to the technol-ogy to who could apply it rapidly and efficiently.MITI did not pick BOF technology as a winner; thetwo firms discovered it themselves. But by makingit available at a reasonable rate and on terms thatpromoted rapid diffusion, MITI helped upgradeJapan’s steel industry faster and more cheaply thanmarket forces would likely have done.

MITI also helped stabilize prices, production, andinvestment through cartels. A major problem incapital-intensive, high-freed-cost industries like steel,which make relatively undifferentiated producergoods, is that their boom-bust cycle can often lead tosevere investment and price competition. Duringboom times, the firms expand capacity to cut coststhrough economies of scale; during recessions theycut prices to minimize losses inherent in businessesthat have high freed costs.

41 Many studies haveconcluded that these investment and price cartelshelped provide the industry with stability of supplyand prices, especially during recessions.42 Japan’scompanies were particularly vulnerable to economicdownturns because of lifetime employment, highdebt-to-equity ratios, and especially intense domes-tic competition. Because of these, it was muchharder for Japan’s companies than for their foreigncompetitors to lay off workers, cut back on produc-tion and investment, and operate at low capacityutilization. While these rigidities are partially offsetby other institutions such as widespread use oftemporary workers, subcontracting, close relation-ships with banks, deep pockets and ready availabil-ity of capital, recessions still pose a special prob-lem.43 Of course, this also means that part of theproblem of over-investment and excessive price

Chapter 6--Japanese Industrial Policy: The Postwar Record and the Case of Supercomputers .245

competition is a result of government industrialpolicy; some studies argue that MITI’s cartels, bysharply reducing risks, encouraged firms to overin-vest in plant and equipment, which in turn exacer-bated the problems of recession vulnerability.44

While Japan’s steel makers have had excess capacityproblems, particularly right after the first oil shockin 1974, their capacity utilization has almost alwaysbeen higher than that of their U.S. and Europeancounterparts, 45 perhaps enabled by the very fastgrowth of the Japanese economy, the emphasis onexports, or both. And Japan’s big integrated millsdid contribute to Japan’s becoming the world’slowest cost producer of steel.

MITI’s original plan for the steel industry encour-aged cooperation in order to stabilize investment,prices, and output. Later, it encouraged mergers toincrease the size of firms, hoping to strengthen thesteel companies to compete with foreign firms.46 Inthe 1960s, as Japan was beginning to liberalize itsmarkets to conform with GATT and OECD require-ments, MITI pushed for mergers in many industriesto strengthen them and thus prevent U.S. firms fromdominating Japanese producers.47 Yawata and FujiSteel, Japan’s two largest steel fins, were onefirm--a nationalized steel company-until it wasbroken up and privatized by the U.S. Occupation.With MITI pressure and financial assistance, the twocompanies merged to form New Japan Steel inMarch 1970, creating the world’s largest steelmaker. MITI’s goals were to create a dominant firmthat could provide stable leadership in price, tech-nology, and production volume, and to decreasecosts. 48 The merger attained these goals, and thehigher steel prices that Japanese scholars fearedwould result never materialized. Imai Kenichi, ascholar who was particularly concerned that the newcompany’s size and domination of the market wouldhave a negative impact on market performance,admits that:

within only 2 years after the merger, the Nippon(Japan) Steel Corp. developed its internationalcompetitiveness beyond a necessary level to thepoint where Japanese-U.S. relations maybe broughtto another crisis similar to that which developed overtextiles. ..49

In short, the merger was so successful it caused tradefriction.

Other policies promoted development of the steelindustry. Special depreciation allowances promote

investment in rationalization (a term that coversmany things having to do with achieving the propersize of industry and enterprises, including down-sizing to eliminate excess capacity, advancement oftechnology, improvement of quality, reduction ofcosts, and improvement of efficiency), acquisition ofexperimental equipment, and exports. During the1950s, the steel and automobile industries receivedexceptionally large benefits from special deprecia-tion schemes, and between 1962 and 1973, the steelindustry ratio of special depreciation allowances tototal depreciation was, at 15 percent, almost twicethe industry average of 8 Percent.so By anotherestimate, a revision of the depreciation schedule in1961 reduced the statutory life (depreciation period)of industrial equipment by 20 percent; anotherrevision 3 years later reduced it an additional 15Percent.51

Early in the 1950s, the steel industry was also anobject of special attention from the Japan Develop-ment Bank. JDB provided up to 15 percent of thefunds to implement MITI’s first rationalization planfor the industry from1951 to 1953.52 Until the late1960s, the iron and steel industries were protectedfrom imports by measures equivalent to a 30-percenttariff. By 1973, the effective rate of protection hadfallen to 17 percent, but it shot backup to over 50percent in 1975 (Japan’s severe post-oil-shockrecession), and fell again to below 20 percent by1978.53 The steel industry got approval to importneeded industrial equipment without paying thetariff on it. Finally, the industry was encouraged toexport through the use of a tax deduction in the earlyyears; this provision disappeared in 1963.

Without industrial policy it is extremely unlikelythat such a competitive industry would have emergedso rapidly after the devastation of the war. WhileJapan’s steel industry has had some problems—especially excess capacity after the oil shock in themid-1970s--it has been able to scale back itsoperations and shift into specialty steel. Somescholars nonetheless argue that steel may be “thesuccess that never was” because it had a relativelylow return on investment compared with otherindustries in Japan;54 they assert that the resourcespoured into the steel industry could have beenallocated more efficiently in other industries to gaina higher return. Targeting steel, they maintain,“probably reduced Japanese national income.”55

246 ● Competing Economies: America, Europe, and the Pacific Rim

Japan’s steel industry did have a relatively lowreturn on investment. But this was not the concern ofthe Japanese Government, nor the firms or theirshareholders. Their goal was to gain greater worldmarket share and to provide the foundation forindustries that use steel, such as automobiles,machine tools, and shipbuilding. Low return oninvestment in an industry that provides key inputsinto other industries does not necessarily lead to anet loss for the economy.

Indeed, evaluating the effectiveness of industrialpolicy on the basis of return on investment oftenleads to the conclusion that Japan is largely a failure.Many of Japan’s top firms today have returns oninvestment that are unacceptable by U.S. standards,made possible by, for example, cross-shareholdingand stable shareholding, low capital costs, and ageneral preference for increasing market share overincreasing share prices.56 But while many Japanesefirms and industries may be inefficient by U.S.financial standards, they are effective in consistentlywinning market share in many key industries. Also,the low returns on steel may well have beencompensated by higher returns in industries that usesteel, including automobiles and machinery. Steelhad other benefits for Japan; by 1960 it was thecountry’s largest earner of precious foreign ex-change. 57 More generally, it provided the industrialinfrastructure necessary for an advanced, industrial-ized nation, including a large pool of skilled workerswith high-paying jobs.

Industrial Policy and Motor VehicleIndustry Development

Policies towards nurturin“ g an internationally com-petitive automobile industry followed a patternsimilar to those of the steel industry: heavy protec-tion and subsidization, incentives for investment intechnology, and increased concentration in theindustry.

Efforts to support Japan’s fledgling auto industrybegan before the war.58 Early car producers weretrue entrepreneurs, but without support they mightwell have withered on the vine. The Japanesemilitary became interested in motor vehicles as earlyas 1906; by 1918 the government had passed theMilitary Vehicle Subsidy Law to provide manufac-turing, maintenance, and purchasing subsidies toproducers and buyers of qualifiedd vehicles (busesand trucks). To qualied for the subsidies, a producer

had to show that over half the capital and votingrights of the company were held by Japanesenationals, and most parts had to be made in Japan.This was an important stimulus to the domesticindustry, but not enough to protect it. Ford andGeneral Motors, watching their sales take off afterthe Great Kanto Earthquake of 1923 damaged all ofJapan’s domestic auto producers, rushed to set uptheir own offices in 1924 and 1925, and quicklycame to dominate the market. It became apparent tothe government that imports and foreign directinvestment could cripple the technologically back-ward domestic industry, which could in turn contrib-ute a chronic deficit to the trade accounts and be adrain on Japan’s scarce foreign exchange. TheAutomobile Manufacturing Enterprise Law of 1936,through various regulations, forced Ford and GM toterminate their successful operations in Japan andenabled Toyota and Nissan to use the U.S. compa-nies’ dealer networks to build their own distributionsystems. This law also gave the army control overpolicies affecting the automobile industry, andturned domestic producers’ attention almost exclu-sively to making trucks and buses.

After a few chaotic postwar years during whichJapanese automobile producers had trouble gettingpermission from the Occupation forces to producecars or obtain the raw materials and parts needed todo so, responsibility for promoting the auto industrywas transferred to MITI. The Ministry pushedautomobile industry targeting because, it argued, theauto industry would provide the source of demandneeded for Japan to modernize related industries,including machinery.59 This decision was controver-sial—the governor of the Bank of Japan, forexample, initially argued that:

. . . since Japan should develop its foreign trade onthe basis of the international division of labor, effortsto develop the auto industry will be futile. . . As wecan get inexpensive motor vehicles of excellentquality from the United States, why don’t we relyupon them?60

MITI prevailed.

The first 5-year plan for promotion of the autoindustry came from MITI in 1948, and it featured theuse of imported technology and financial assistanceprovided by the Reconstruction Finance Bank tohelp obtain capital, raw materials, electricity, andlabor. The Asian market was the main export target,and controls on prices and distribution were put in

Chapter 4-Japanese Industrial Policy: The Postwar Record and the Case of Supercomputers .247

place for an interim period, to be lifted whenappropriate. 61 Recession caused by economic poli-cies known as the Dodge Line (after Joseph Dodge,the Detroit banker who drafted and implementedJapan’s deflationary program) forced abandonmentof the plan and threw the automobile companies intochaos. Nissan laid off over 1,800 employees inOctober 1949 and cut wages 10 percent, DieselMotors abolished its agreement with its union andlaid off nearly a quarter of its workers, and Toyotaalmost collapsed (although its founder refused to layoff anyone and was eventually forced out of thecompany as layoffs were implemented). Rescuecame in the form of the Korean War. Japan, as thebest source of emergency supplies, received manyorders for special procurements by the U.S.-led U.N.forces, enough to end the recession and save thestruggling automobile industry.62

The hiatus in government promotion of theautomobile industry brought by the Dodge Line wasbrief. After the recovery, many new policies wereimplemented to support the industry. They includedan ambitious road construction program; protectionfrom imports and direct investment; imports offoreign technology under favorable terms; and directfinancial assistance.63 Protection consisted of hightariffs (35 to 40 percent on cars until 1969, falling tozero by 1978), commodity taxes that favored domes-tic automobiles, foreign exchange allocation thatrestricted imports, and foreign exchange controls ondirect investment. Excise taxes that favored smallcars over large, luxury vehicles effectively kept outAmerican cars, but after a surge in imported smallcars from Europe, additional measures were imple-mented. Among them were allocation of foreignexchange to buy European cars only for taxicompanies and the media, and prohibition of resalefor 3 years.64

Other measures were similar to those used insteel: low interest government loans, subsidies,special depreciation allowances, exemption of nec-essary equipment from import duties, and approvalof foreign exchange essential for foreign technologyimports. 65 In 1956, the Law on Temporary Measuresfor Promoting the Machinery Industries added autoparts and automobiles, and research suggests thatthis promotion was particularly effective.66 Forexample, financial aid along with efforts to encour-age standardization and increase concentration ofthe auto parts industry contributed to a 56-percent

cut in the cost of producing a passenger car between1961 and 1965.67

Even with all these supports and the outstandingperformance of the Japanese motor vehicle produc-ers, the auto industry is frequently pointed to as afailure of Japan’s industrial policy because ofMITI’s repeated failures to consolidate the industryinto one or two firms or groups. In 1955, forexample, MITI tried to promote production of anexportable subcompact by a single company, an ideathe firms rejected strongly. In 1961, MITI tried toconsolidate the industry into three groups to developthree types of cars. This plan was rejected, too. Hadit been adopted, it would by widespread agreementhave damaged the industry’s long-term competitive-ness. It is important to realize, however, that whatwould clearly have been a mistake did not, in fact,occur. Indeed, there have been very few largeblunders of industrial policy, such as would haveoccurred if MITI had succeeded in merging the autocompanies, because there is a system of checks andbalances among the firms and government officials;policies are made through a process of negotiationand compromise, and in cases where the firmsbelieve that a government policy goes sharply. .against their long-term interest, they reject it. Theauto case is not the sole example of MITI unsuccess-fully attempting to merge firms; in the late 1960s andearly 1970s the ministry also tried to get the sixmajor computer firms to merge into two or threecompanies, and the firms refused. A compromisewas reached whereby the six firms formed threedifferent groups for cooperative research and devel-opment. Despite this failed MITI attempt to consoli-date the computer industry, even the most skepticalanalysts acknowledge that industrial policy contrib-uted to the development of the computer industry.68

Protection from imports and foreign investment,along with financial assistance, help in importingneeded inputs, and special access to foreign technol-ogy were necessary though not sufficient conditionsfor Japan to develop comparative and competitiveadvantage in the automobile industry. The govern-ment did not create the automobile industry in Japan,nor did it create other successful industries such aselectronics. Clearly, the companies’ willingness toinvest in new technologies, their persistence infinding new and better ways to use technologies,their continual improvement, and intelligent strate-gies for penetrating foreign markets played a vitalrole, as did Japan’s well-educated and disciplined

248 . Competing Economies: America, Europe, and the Pacific Rim

workers and overall financial policies that encour-aged savings and discouraged consumption.

Color Televisions

Many proponents of the market explanation ofJapan’s economic development point to consumerelectronics as an industry that succeeded withoutgovernment promotion. In fact, they argue that theindustry boomed in spite of a blunder by MITI: thatof delaying Sony’s acquisition of transistor technol-ogy by restricting Sony’s use of foreign exchange.69

In 1953, MITI refused Sony permission to acquiretransistor technology from the United States becauseMITI did not want to use scarce foreign exchange forthe technology; it also felt that a small, recentstart-up such as Sony would not be able to use abrand new technology successfully .70 While thefrequently cited American account of this refusa171

says that MITI delayed Sony’s access for 3 years,Akio Morita of Sony says it took 6 months topersuade MITI to give them the needed foreignexchange. 72 Nonetheless, this mistake stands out asone of MITI’s more serious errors.

The argument that the industry succeeded withoutgovernment help is less powerful when the evidenceis analyzed. The producers of televisions did notenjoy the number of tailor-made policies and degreeof support given to targeted industries like automo-biles, steel, semiconductors, and computers. But thetelevision industry, like many others in Japan,benefited from government policies that loweredcapital costs, protected against imports and foreigninvestment, promoted exports, and tolerated behav-ior that, in the United States, would have run afoulof antitrust laws.73 MITI’s policies made it possiblefor the color television industry to keep prices highat home and low abroad—in fact, Japanese produc-ers were found guilty of dumping in the U.S. andEuropean markets. For over a decade, Japanesemakers sold televisions in the United States forabout one-third to one-half the price of the same setsin Japan; this export price was also below cost.74

High prices at home could only work under certainconditions: that is, if all major manufacturers agreednot to undercut one another’s prices (collusivebehavior, by U.S. standards), and if the market wereeffectively closed to imports. Both occurred. To fixexport and domestic prices, the managers of themajor manufacturers met regularly in groups such asthe Okura Group and the Palace Group, named afterthe hotels in which the meetings took place.75 And

in the first half of the 1960s, the tariff on televisionimports was 40 percent.76

While Japanese firms needed to charge low pricesto win U.S. market share, they avoided undue pricecompetition with each other. Domestic firms setminimum export prices,77 which MITI monitored.Another safeguard was the so-called “five companyrule,’ which required that each Japanese exporterspecify five U.S. dealers as its only and exclusivecustomers. This kept large U.S. retailers such asSears from playing the Japanese suppliers againsteach other to lower prices. An export associationmanaged the formal registration of these buyer-supplier relationships; firms reported to that associa-tion each specific shipment of color televisions tothe United -States, stating the buyers and suppliersinvolved, and the type, quantity, and price of thetelevisions. 78

When the United States started to complain aboutthis dumping in the late 1960s, Japanese consumersbecame aware of the discrepancy and boycottedJapanese televisions. MITI immediately gave guid-ance to the industry to reduce domestic prices, andthe firm complied, though export prices were stillmuch lower.79 The secret meetings among the firmsand control of distributors were allowed to con-tinue.80

Japanese firms raised prices in the United Statesin 1974 in response to growing allegations ofdumping and antitrust violations. This price changereduced but did not eliminate the gap between highdomestic and lower export prices. Moreover, Japa-nese television manufacturers reportedly began togive kickbacks to U.S. retailers, making the actualprices much lower than those reported in accountingrecords, customs forms, and invoices.81

Collusion and dumping were not the only reasonsfor the success of the Japanese television makers.Japanese manufacturers worked hard to reduce theircosts by introducing new technologies; in particular,they converted their TV production to solid-stateintegrated circuits early on. Japanese televisionsgained a reputation for reliability in America, andmade it possible for televisions to be repaired bylarge retail establishments rather than repair shops.As in every other successful Japanese industry,success came from a combination of intelligentcompany strategy and diligence, good workers, andgovernment policies. None of these factors alonewould have resulted in the same record of success.

Chapter 6--Japanese Industrial Policy: The Postwar Record and the Case of Supercomputers ● 249

Semiconductors

While there is a range of views about howimportant industrial and trade policies have been tosome industries (consumer electronics particularly),there is much less skepticism when it comes to thesemiconductor industry, and still less for the com-puter industry. There is no question that in a freemarket, U.S. companies would have dominated theJapanese semiconductor industry. Texas Instru-ments (TI) applied for 14 patents in Japan in 1960and for permission to establish a wholly ownedsubsidiary there in 1964. These applications threat-ened to disrupt the development of a domesticsemiconductor industry, an area that business andgovernment leaders had decided was strategic toJapan’s long-term economic growth. By refusing toact on either application, the bureaucracy allowedthe Japanese companies to copy TI’s technology foryears without paying for it.82 TI did finally winapproval of some of its patents in 1977, andcombined the others into one application, pursuingthem until it was granted its final patent in October1989.83 This was an exceptional case, even byJapanese standards, where it commonly takes 6 to 7years to process a patent application (compared with18 months in the United States).

TI threatened that any Japanese exports using itstechnology would be met with an immediate lawsuitbased on TI’s patents in the destination country, andthis began to pose a problem for Japanese consumerelectronics makers in the late 1960s.84 Somethingneeded to be done to appease TI. MITI had to agreewith TI’s request for a wholly owned subsidiarybecause it needed [a license under] TI’s patents [toexport],” explained a former MITI official closelyinvolved in the negotiations.85 But granting TIpermission to operate a wholly owned subsidiary inJapan also posed serious problems.

Fairchild and Motorola both had wholly ownedsubsidiaries in Okinawa. The Japanese Governmentwas then negotiating with the U.S. Government forthe return of Okinawa. Had TI been allowed to opena subsidiary in Japan proper, it would have beendifficult to keep Motorola and Fairchild fromretaining theirs in Okinawa when that island cameback into the Japanese fold. To avoid the precedent,MITI pressured TI to make a nominal joint venturewith Sony ‘‘on paper, ’ one that would last only 3years, after which Sony would sell its shares to TI.86

MITI’s strategy worked. When the United Statesreturned Okinawa to Japan, the Okinawan subsidiar-ies of Fairchild and Motorola were forced to enter50-50 joint ventures with Japanese partners.87 Inaddition, it was difficult for these American compa-nies to form ventures with any of Japan’s majorelectronics companies, because MITI favored pureblooded (junketsu) Japanese firms over mixed breed(konketsu) joint ventures.88 MITI ultimately foundthem relatively small, inexperienced partners.89

Japanese firms only began to produce sophisti-cated chips in the 1960s; in 1966, a couple of yearsafter beginning production, Japanese firms wereselling one type of IC (integrated circuit) for overY1,000, some three times the price of a similar onesold in the United States. The higher Japanese costsreflected lower yields, which were about 10 percentin the mid-1960s, compared with 25 percent in theUnited States on average.90 As late as 1972, thesemiconductor divisions of all the major Japaneseproducers were in the red;91 in 1971, Japanesemakers had to sell at more than 20 percent belowcost to compete with U.S. manufacturers.92

Protection is only part of the story. Governmentfinancial assistance, such as low interest loans,accelerated depreciation, and other measures thatlowered capital costs, enabled Japanese companiesto continue investing heavily despite years of largelosses. Another major theme of the Japanese ap-proach to a home grown semiconductor industry wastechnology development and acquisition. U.S. firmsthat wanted to make joint ventures in Japan wereobliged to transfer technologies as part of the deal.93

The government also sponsored several cooperativeR&D projects that helped domestic firms gain thetechnological expertise necessary to compete withU.S. companies over the long term. To help the sixmajor companies get an early jump on integratedcircuit R&D, MITI organized a 2-year cooperativeR&D project from 1964 to 1966. Tarui Yasuo, amember of MITI’s Electrotechnical Lab who partici-pated in this project and later led MITI’s well-knownVLSI project (1976-1979), said that a major goal ofthe government was to “reduce duplication ofeffort” by dividing up the labor; another purposewas “frankly to avoid patents that cover proceduresdeveloped in the U. S.A.’ ’94 Government-sponsoredprograms continue through the present.

Some of the most famous projects were the VLSIproject, which accelerated the rate at which Japanese

292-889 0 - 91 - 9 QL:3

250 . Competing Economies: America, Europe, and the Pacific Rim

producers caught up with American memory tech-nology; a software and peripheral developmentprogram from 1979 to 1983; the optoelectronic IC(OEIC) project lasting from 1981 to 1986; and aproject in the mid-1980s to develop super-high-speed device technologies.95 By the mid- 1980s, theJapanese companies had come to dominate severalsemiconductor markets, had made inroads into all ofthem, and were poised to advance in almost everyarea of computer technology.

SUCCESSES AND FAILURES OFINDUSTRIAL POLICY

So far, this chapter has focused on successes ofJapanese industrial policy. It probably bears repeat-ing at this point that a number of the cases that someobservers regard as failures-such as MITI’s failureto reduce the number of firms in the automobileindustry-ended up as very successful industries.There is a big difference between mistakes, orunsuitable proposals, and failures of industrialpolicy. Not every proposal MITI advances is awinner, but even so, its interventions have helpedtargeted industries and Japanese industry on thewhole become more competitive. MITI and otherministries reduce the likelihood of mistakes byextensive consultation with the private sector.

A few targeted industries have not improved theircompetitiveness. Industrial policies towards petro-chemicals, oil, and coal are often pointed to asfailures. 96 For example, the petrochemical industry,completely dependent on imported oil, was left withhuge excess capacity when the oil shock hit Japan inthe early 1970s. It had to be scaled back dramaticallyin a process that was costly to the government andthe firms. The huge subsidies that have supportedJapan’s uncompetitive agricultural sector are alsosometimes identified as industrial-policy failures.Overall, the fact that the Japanese Governmentspends more on declining industries than on ascend-ing ones is also cited as proof that industrial policyis a waste of government resources.

It is important, however, to evaluate the success ofpolicies based on their goals. Japan has neverentertained the idea of developing an internationallycompetitive energy sector, which would obviouslybe impossible given the nation’s lack of energyresources; policies toward oil and coal have beenaimed at providing Japan with a stable and predicta-ble energy supply and at keeping as much domestic

control over energy as possible. Such a policy makessense considering Japan’s vulnerability to disrup-tions in energy supply and price; it took fully 5 yearsfor Japanese manufacturing production to exceed1973 levels after the oil-shock-induced recession of1974-75.9 7 Similarly, Japan has never aspired tohaving an internationally competitive agriculturalsector; rather, the industry has been protected andsubsidized for political and social reasons—primarily to assure farming communities’ strongsupport for the pro-business Liberal DemocraticParty.

To a skeptic, the heavy support for Japaneseagriculture is proof of the proposition that govern-ment intervention in the economy is prone tobecome the servant of political power and specialinterests. Yet most nations do not wish to depend onimports for food, particularly for dietary staples. Asa result, all developed nations support their agricul-tural sectors (some more than others). In Japan, it isnot easy to find other industries as heavily subsi-dized as agriculture with as little economic payoff;for the most part, the separation between Japan’slegislature (Diet) and bureaucracy hinders specialinterests from getting MITI support unless there isgood economic sense behind their appeals.

For MITI to spend more on declining than onsunrise industries is not unreasonable. Supportingso-called ‘structurally depressed’ industries, whichare not expected to recover from recessions orexceed past output records, is an inherently expen-sive activity. Industrial adjustment-contracting thesize of an industry and shifting workers, managers,and capital from one industry to another-is diffi-cult, time-consuming, and expensive in any Country.Countries differ in the extent to which those costs areborne by workers and owners of enterprises, asopposed to the public sector. Japan’s governmenttakes more responsibility for adjustment, and bearsmore of the cost, than do most developed nations.One reason is the value Japan places on employmentsecurity. Culturally and economically, Japan de-pends on steady employment; the option of layingoff workers without making some provision for theirfuture employment is abhorrent to the JapaneseGovernment and employers alike. While not allJapanese employees are covered by so-called life-time employment, most Japanese employers arereluctant to lay people off. It is even more importantin Japan than in the United States that downsizing beorderly. As a result, the government has frequently

Chapter 6--Japanese Industrial Policy: The Postwar Record and the Case of Supercomputers ● 251

organized cartels among producers to promotesteady contraction and paid for some of the workeradjustment costs. While the money the governmentspends on declining industries does not contribute toincreasing the competitiveness of a sunrise sector (agoal that some American analysts think is the onlysupportable objective of government targeting), it isnot wasted. It contributes to a stable businessenvironment, prevents cutthroat competition andlarge-scale, chaotic layoffs, and helps keep Japan’sunemployment rate extraordinarily low.

A few efforts have disappointed MITI’s expecta-tions. Promotion of software development in the1970s and 1980s has not been very effective;projects were scattered and inadequately funded andmoney was generally given to software houses todevelop products approved by the InformationPromotion Agency (IPA), a MlTI-related associa-tion, rather than responding to the software needs ofthe users. By neglecting to tie its aid to the market,the government ended up with mostly unusedsoftware.

An even clearer example of disappointed expecta-tions is the aircraft industry. Commercial aircraftwas targeted in MITI’s visions for the 1970s and1980s, yet Japanese industry has never become asuccessful assembler of large commercial aircraft, asMITI hoped. But even here, calling MITI’s policiesa failure is inaccurate. With MITI support, Japan’saircraft industry has become a major supplier ofparts, generating $1.2 billion worth of commercialaircraft products in 1989; over half were exported.Japanese companies had a 15-percent share indeveloping Boeing’s 767, making most of thefuselage and underwing fairing; they have taken a20-percent workshare as a risk-sharing partner in thedevelopment of the new 777 (see ch. 8, or volume 2).Moreover, Japan’s aircraft industry faced unusuallyformidable obstacles to development; for example,after World War II the country was barred fromaviation-related activities while the rest of the worldmoved into the jet age.

While there have been failures as well as suc-cesses in Japan’s efforts to promote certain indus-tries, Japan has a good batting average in targetingindustries for international competitiveness. Severalfactors distinguish the Japanese experience fromthose of less successful nations. Most criticalperhaps is that on the whole, policies have beenstructured to preserve the forces of competition.

While that may sound strange to say about a nationthat protected its developing industries as assidu-ously as Japan did, still the government almostalways promoted several firms in an industry. R&Dprojects usually had two or more companies worktogether on a topic, each of which could bring thenew technology to the market. Moreover, firms werestrongly encouraged to export-often to America,where they had to compete with then-dominantfins. In a few instances, MITI has given a companya monopoly position in an industry or an R&Dproject; generally these have been failures.98 InEurope, attempts to nurture domestic computerindustries by promoting national champions alsofailed, in part due to their lack of domestic competi-tion (see ch. 5). The lesson from Japan is that if astate protects the domestic market from foreigncompetition, it is imperative to at least keep domes-tic competition intact. Another lesson is that firmsmust compete somewhere (in Japan’s case, in exportmarkets) with the best producers.

Business input into the policymaking process hascontributed to the success of Japan’s industrialpolicies. Government officials consult closely andextensively with industry. This consultation isnecessary because industry representatives knowmore about their products, technologies, and busi-ness environment than bureaucrats do, and often cantell better what will or will not work. Businessfunctions as a check on government policies, and, inturn, the state counterbalances business demands.For example, the automobile industry resisted MITI’splans to merge the firms, which likely would havehurt the industry; but MITI did increase specializa-tion in the industry. The private sector’s role inpolicymaking increases business’ commitment tomake the policies succeed.

Another’ attribute of Japan’s industrial policystructure is stability. A stable institution, partiallyinsulated from day-to-day interest group demands, isessential for consistent, long-term guidance. Evenwhen an administration changes, Japanese compa-nies can be assured that MITI’s basic policies willnot, and that there will not be a sudden turnover ofministry officials. The relative impartiality and lackof corruption of MITI officials is also critical:industrial policy can only work in an environment oftrust in which high-quality career bureaucrats workin the national interest.

252 ● Competing Economies: America, Europe, and the Pacific Rim

Tying government aid to performance and requir-“ some of their own funds to R&Ding firms to Commit

projects have helped to increase the success ofJapanese policies. Japan’s market is another factor;the domestic market is relatively large, enablingdomestic firm to gain economies of scale at homebefore entering foreign markets. Of course, havingaccess to the world’s biggest market-the UnitedStates-was also key.

The importance of the comprehensive approach tonurturing an industry cannot be overstated. MITI haspromoted not just products, but the entire industries,including the needed parts and infrastructure. Forexample, Japanese policy frost encouraged develop-ment of semiconductors and computer parts, then thehardware of small computers, large computers, andfinally software and supercomputers.

As stated before, all of Japan’s targeting policieswere boosted to a large degree by economy-widepolicies and cultural factors. Without government’sprovision for a large pool of savings-and manyother measures designed to transfer capital fromconsumers to producers—Japan would not havebeen able to finance its targeting policies. Japan’sindustrial policies and targeting have cost consum-ers a great deal in terms of current consumption(while the resulting increases in productivity allowthem to improve their living standards in the longrun), and the contribution of this deferred gratifica-tion on the part of millions of ordinary Japanesecitizens should not be underestimated. A first-rateeducation system, and a culture that reinforces evenfor small children the importance of educationalperformance, is another factor. A long history ofadopting and modifying for Japanese use successfulpolicies and practices (including technology) fromother countries was helpful, as was sheer diligence.It is worth remembering that in most cases where aninfant, technologically backward industry was pro-tected in Japan, that industry was working towardworld leadership in technology application anddevelopment. Most of them got there.

INDUSTRIAL POLICY FORTHE 1990s

Japan’s star is on the rise. Its people are growingricher faster than any others among the developedcountries; its fins-at least, its international firms—are cash-rich and outstripping their American andEuropean competitors in advancing and applying

technology. In foreign policy, Japan is, with caution,taking a more independent path. In business, Japa-nese firms are increasingly independent of theirgovernment and their banks. Some have suggestedthat MITI’s power and Japan’s industrial policy areartifacts of the past.

But a look at MITI policy today indicates thatwhile targeting policies are less important than theyonce were, the role of MITI and its sister ministriesis far from marginal. Indeed, while Japanese compa-nies have money, they may still need encouragementto invest much in technologies that are unlikely tobring about a profit for a decade or more; competingfirms also need more encouragement to cooperatewith one another than in the past, when cooperationwas considered necessary for survival. In manyindustries, a Japanese fro’s fiercest competitioncomes from other Japanese firms. Finally, Japan’sera of cheap capital may be over; in the past year,Japanese interest rates and capital costs have in-creased rapidly as the bubble burst in the Nikkeistock market.99 For these reasons, MITI’s role inproviding seed money and in coordinating coopera-tive R&D remains important.

MITI is funding more R&D directly, in absoluteamounts, than previously. This may seem ironicconsidering the wealth of many Japanese firms, butthey have also moved from being technologicalfollowers to positions of leadership, which meansthe payoffs of R&D are less certain. For example,one new large-scale MITI project focuses on devel-oping micromachines that combine sensing deviceswith microprocessors and motors (a technology thatoriginated in the United States) for uses such assurgery without incisions and inspection of coolingpipes in nuclear plants (see app. 6-A).100 MITI willplow some $200 million into this 10-year projectbeginnin g in autumn of 1991. Another projectfocuses on electronic lasers. Eight companies—Mitsubishi Electric, Toshiba, Hitachi, NEC, SumitomoDenki Kogyo, Kobe Steel, Kansai Electric Power,and Nisshin Electric-have created a cooperativeR&D association for the project. Each firm will putin 4 percent of the Y10 billion ($78 million) project,and government will provide the remaining 68Percent. l0l The aim is to catchup with the UnitedStates in an area that Japan sees as important forapplications such as medical equipment, spacecommunications, energy transmission, semiconduc-tors, uranium enrichment, and nuclear fusion.102

Chapter 6-Japanese Industrial Policy: The Postwar Record and the Case of Supercomputers .253

As the content of these two projects suggests,MITI is increasingly supporting basic technologiesthat, while not close to the market, will have a broadimpact on many areas. This strategy makes it easierfor competing firms to cooperate and minimizesforeign criticism. Other targeted technologies in-clude new materials, biotechnology, superconductivity,hypersonic flight, high-definition television, bio-computers, parallel processing, and optoelectronics.

Japan’s long history of outright trade protectionand the fact that her market is still especially difficultto penetrate, in combination with the spectacularsuccesses of many Japanese industries in interna-tional competition, have led to increasingly sharptrade conflicts with major trading partners. If theconflicts were only with the United States, it mightbe possible to attribute them to jealousy. But tradefriction is growing rougher with Europe, too, andthere are reports of growing wariness toward Japa-nese investment and imports in Australia. MITI hasassumed much of the responsibility for oiling thesetroubled waters, helping to ease trade fictionthrough negotiations and encouragement of Japa-nese firms to use foreign products.103 For example,MITI loans companies roughly $1 billion to promoteaircraft imports. To escape being even larger targetsfor those who urge retaliatory protection or recip-rocity, Japanese firms might need some powerfulagency to mediate, intervene, and palliate.

A nation with little or no formal trade protectionand a huge market should not need such an agency;Japan’s market should be a magnet for foreign goodsand companies, as is America’s. But MITI’s role asombudsman for the interests of foreign governmentsand enterprises arises from the Japanese Govern-ment’s still-powerful ability to govern the activitiesof foreign firms (be they investors or traders) inJapan. Government procurement practices, customsclearances, inspection standards, approvals on for-eign investment, antimonopoly law enforcement,and administrative guidance on issues such as priceand production cartels are done largely at govern-ment’s direction, rather than according to strict legalcriteria. There are few clear rules for foreign firms tofollow and there are few open, transparent systemsfor dispute resolution. This discretionary systemenables the Japanese Government to use relativelysubtle, informal tactics that, according to the weightof anecdotes of those who do business there, still canimpede (or assist) the efforts of foreign firms in theJapanese market.

SUPERCOMPUTER INDUSTRYDEVELOPMENT

A supercomputer is a general purpose computerthat is faster than commercial competitors and thathas sufficient central memory to compute problemsets of general scientific interest.104 A supercom-puter can do in 1 minute what it takes a mainframecomputer 3 hours to do, a workstation 15 hours anda personal computer 96 hours.105 These very fastmachines enable researchers to analyze a wide rangeof physical phenomena. They are used, for example,to predict and analyze weather, to design airplanesand automobiles to reduce air turbulence, to discoverpharmaceutical compounds with desired effects, andto design semiconductor chips.

A healthy supercomputer industry is consideredimportant because it is a technology driver. ‘‘Super-computers are the testing ground for Japanese logicand memory chips and new types of technology[which can then also be used in mainframes andother products],” explains Raul Mendez, a U.S.supercomputer expert, who after working at the U.S.Office of Naval Research in Tokyo is now theDirector of the Institute of Supercomputing Re-search in that city.106 Sekimoto Tadahiro, Presidentof NEC, one of Japan’s major supercomputercompanies, agrees: ‘‘Japanese supercomputer mak-ers can use their technological improvements [re-lated to supercomputers] in their mainframe comput-ers; in that sense we are in a more advantageousposition than the U.S. firms that specialize insupercomputers." 107 Uenohara Michiyuki, execu-tive adviser to NEC and formerly the VP in chargeof NEC’s research division, explains: “The reasonJapanese companies are going into the supercom-puter business is for the same reason that autocompanies get into race cars; even though it’s asmall market, it drives the technology. "108IBM,which had not been a supercomputer producer since1970, reentered the field in 1985 with a vectorversion of the IBM 3090 that performed in thesupercomputer class at the low end;109 moreover,IBM is providing financial support to Supercom-puting Systems, Inc. (SSI), a new company thatexpects to produce a new supercomputer in the early1990s. This suggests that IBM came to the sameconclusions about the importance of supercomputertechnology as the Japanese companies.

254 ● Competing Economies: America, Europe, and the Pacific Rim

Supercomputers are important tools for otherindustries. Increasingly, designs of automobiles andaircraft, pharmaceutical products, and new materialsall rely on supercomputers. For example, supercom-puters allow simulation of automobile crashes,which in turn can reduce time and expense involvedin developing new products. Proposed designs canbe tested by computer, without the need to build amodel. The computer simulation gives much moreprecise results than some actual experiments, such asslow-motion blow-up movies of critical parts. Realtest crashes can be reduced in number and designedprecisely to confirm that a design will work.Similarly, NASA uses a supercomputer to simulateairflow inside aircraft engines, allowing designers toobserve things that could not be seen directly in awind tunnel. To have the benefits of supercomputersin applications, however, it may not be necessary tohave a domestic industry.

There are two major types of supercomputers:traditional supercomputers and massively parallelprocessing supercomputers. Traditional supercom-puters —with one or a small number of processors(currently up to eight)--are the major focus of thisstudy. (A processor, sometimes called a centralprocessing unit or CPU, is the heart of a computer.

A processor manipulates data. Other parts of acomputer are memory, which stores data, andinput-output devices, which transfer data betweenthe computer and the outside world.) Massivelyparallel processing machines, which have fromabout 64 to thousands of processors, may be thetrend for supercomputing in the next century; theirprospects will be discussed as well.110

Supercomputer Companies

There are four major companies in the worldsupercomputer industry today: Cray Research of theUnited States, and Fujitsu, Hitachi, and NEC ofJapan. Two other companies are also working tobring out their first supercomputers, Cray Computerand SSI (Supercomputer Systems, Inc.). Cray Com-puter, Seymour Cray’s firm that broke off from CrayResearch in 1989, has just sold and (as of mid-1991)plans to deliver the first unit of its new supercom-puter, the Cray-3, to the Lawrence LivermoreNational Laboratory before the end of 1991. SSI, afirm started by Stephen Chen after he left CrayResearch in 1987, is backed by IBM. Chen’s newsupercomputer, a 48 to 64 processor machine, is notexpected until 1992 or 1993. ETA, a subsidiary of

Table 6-l-Comparison of Cray Research, Fujitsu, Hitachi, and NEC Revenues,R&D Expenditures, and Profits, 1981,1982, 1988, 1989

Revenue R&D expenditures R&D as percent Profit as percent($ millions) ($ millions) of revenue of revenue

1981Cray . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .Fujitsu . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .Hitachi . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .NEC . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

1982Cray . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .Fujitsu . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .Hitachi . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .NEC . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

1988Cray . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .Fujitsu . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .Hitachi . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .NEC . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

1989Cray . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .Fujitsu . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .Hitachi . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .NEC . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

101.62,5298,4653,882

141.22,9189,3084,583

756.315,42024,86219,554

784.716,35127,11721,235

17.0141NA214.4

29.5185NA221

117.81,8261,5421,561

143.42,1021,8381,780

16.85.6NA5.5

20.96.3NA4.8

15.611.86.28.0

18.312.96.88.4

17.93.43.52.4

13.53.83.72.5

20.72.73.62.4

11.33.43.73.0

NA-not available.NOTE: Japanese yen converted at 230/$ in 1981 and 1982, 130/$ in 1988 and 1989. The Japanese year ends on Mar.

31. Thus Japanese data are for years ending Mar. 31, 1982, 1983, 1989, 1980.

SOURCE: Company financial reports.

Chapter 6--Japanese Industrial Policy: The Postwar Record and the Case of Supercomputers ● 255

Table 6-2-Cray Research’s Revenues, R&D Expenditures, and Profits

R&D Profit asRevenues expenditures R&D as percent percent

Year ($ millions) ($ millions) of revenues of revenues

1977 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 11.39 1.90 16.7 17.81978 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 17.18 2.53 14.7 20.41979 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 42.72 6.42 15.0 18.31980 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 60.75 9.55 15.7 17.91981 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 101.64 17.04 16.8 17.91982 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 141.15 29.51 20.9 13.51983 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 169.69 25.54 15.1 15.41984 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 228.75 37.54 16.4 19.81985 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 380.16 49.17 12.9 19.91986 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 596.69 87.68 14.7 20.91987 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 687.34 108.83 15.8 21.41988 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 756.31 117.76 15.6 20.71989 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 784.70 143.35 18.3 11.3SOURCE: Cray Research annual financial reports.

Table 6-3-Divisions of U.S. and Japanese Supercomputers Firms, 1989(by percent of sales)

HeavyTelecom- Electronic Consumer electric

Computers munications devices electronics equipment Other

Cray Research . . . . 100 — — — — —Fujitsu . . . . . . . . . . . . 70.5 16.3 13.2 — — —NEC . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 47.0 29.4 20.1 3.5 — —Hitachia . . . . . . . . . . . 30.0 5.0 10.2 13.7 21.4 19.7aHitachi data give totals for computers, telecommunications, and electronic”~ devices only. The percent are

estimated based on other sales data.

SOURCES: Company financial reports. Japanese figures are as of Mar.31,1990.

Control Data Corp. (CDC), was a major player untilit withdrew from the market in 1989.

The sales, R&D, and profit data of the four majorfirms are given in tables 6-1 and 6-2. It is hard tomake direct comparisons between Cray Researchand the Japanese firms because Cray makes oneproduct line-super-computers-whereas the Japa-nese firms are both vertically integrated and diversi-fied into various related electronics industries (table6-3). What is clear from the numbers is that CrayResearch is very small compared with its chiefcompetitors: in 1989 its sales were 4.8 percent thoseof Fujitsu, 2.9 percent those of Hitachi, and 3.7percent those of NEC. Cray spends a much higherpercentage of revenues on R&D than its Japanesecounterparts, 18 percent in 1989 compared to 7 to 13percent for the Japanese makers.111 The data alsoshow that healthy Japanese companies have profitrates (profits as a percentage of revenues) of onlysome 2 to 4 percent per year, a level that would puta U.S. firm in serious trouble; Cray’s profit as apercent of revenues has ranged from a high of 20.7percent in 1988 to 11.3 percent in 1989 (table 6-2).

Potential Market

The world supercomputer market is over $1.1billion today. Its annual growth rates in the 1980sranged from a high of 84.3 percent in 1981 to a lowof 4.5 percent in 1989, with an average of 30 percent(table 6-4). The Japanese market has been growingmuch faster although it has slowed suddenly in thepast year: the growth in the number of supercomput-ers sold has ranged from a high of 145.5 percent in1986 to a negative growth rate in 1990 of about -47percent (table 6-5). One reason for the sharp declinein 1990 is that higher prices charged to the JapaneseGovernment (resulting from the 1990 U.S.-Japansupercomputer agreement, which limits Japanesecompanies’ discounts) have not been matched byequally high government budgets, inevitably lead-ing to fewer procurements. Public and private sectorpurchases of upgraded models have also declinedbecause users are waiting for new, more sophisti-cated models expected out in 1991.

The drive for ever faster computers pushes thetechnology in two directions: making faster proces-

256 ● Competing Economies: America, Europe, and the Pacific Rim

Table 6-4-Value of Worldwide SupercomputerShipments

AnnualShipments growth rate

Year ($ millions) (in percent)

1980 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 891981 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1641982 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 2111983 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 2451984 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 3081985 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 4791986 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 6511987 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 8801988 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1,0341989 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1,0811990 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1,164

NA84.3%28.716.125.755.535.935.217.54.57.7

SOURCE: Gartner Group, lncv High Performance Computing andCom-munications:lnvestmentinAmerican Competitiveness,Mar .15,1991, p.73.

sors (a processor is the part of the computer that doesarithmetic calculations), and using many processorsat once. The latter is becoming more important.Traditional supercomputers rely heavily on havingfast processors, but manufacturers have been in-creasing the number of processors to gain extraspeed. Cray Research’s top-of-the-line machinetoday has 8 processors; both Cray Research and CrayComputer have announced that they are developing16-processor machines that they expect to debut inthe next few years. Cray Research, along with othercompanies, is working on machines with 64 proces-sors. The world market for traditional supercomput-ers is expected to continue healthy growth for therest of the 1990s, but some analysts expect mas-sively parallel machines to begin taking some of themarket from traditional supercomputers.

In the future, the greatest speeds will be achievedby having a large number of processors, even if eachprocessor is only moderately fast. The market formassively parallel supercomputers, which havefrom 64 processors to many thousand, could proveto be much greater than for traditional supercomput-ers in the future. To use so many processors toadvantage, it is necessary to divide the problem intomany independent parts that individual centralprocessing units (CPUs) can work on in parallel. Itis difficult to write software to break down problemsin this way and even harder to write the software sothat all of the CPUs are able to communicate withone another. “There are daunting software problemsin massively parallel processing machines, ” ex-plained an expert at Lawrence Livermore NationalLaboratory. 112 Even if writing software were sim-pler, there is still a much larger existing stock of

software for traditional supercomputers; it will takesome time before a comparable library is availablefor massively parallel machines. The software thathas been written was designed to handle specialproblems, such as pattern recognition. Writingsoftware to make a massively parallel machine intoa general purpose machine is much harder.

Scientists and supercomputer users give varyingpredictions of the future market for massivelyparallel processing computers, ranging from pessi-mistic predictions that such machines will never begeneral purpose machines to optimistic views thatthey will became more important than traditionalsupercomputers within the next 5 to 10 years.113

Several companies-including Thinking Machines,Alliant, Intel, BBN, Ncube, MasPar, and Cray—arebetting on the latter. Most supercomputer expertsand supercomputer users agree that the softwareproblem may take a decade to solve, and someanalysts see the massively parallel machines asremaining niche machines for the foreseeable fu-ture. 114

Comparisons of U.S. and JapaneseSupercomputers

Japanese manufacturers have faster components,which, all other things equal, would mean fastermachines. However, Cray appears to have threecompensating advantages. First, Cray excels inpackaging and connectors, which also affect ma-chine speed. Second, Cray’s processors appear tohave a “more balanced” design, meaning that itsdifferent elements work together more smoothly,with fewer bottlenecks.115(A bottleneck couldoccur, for example, if the processor’s arithmeticunit-that part of the processor that actually adds,multiplies, etc.—has to stand idle waiting for data tobe fetched from memory.) Third, some of Cray’ssupercomputers gain speed by using more than oneprocessor; no Japanese machines with more than oneprocessor have yet been sold. While using more thanone processor is an advantage, it is often tricky tokeep all processors busy at once, just as it is trickyto keep different parts of one processor busy at once.Cray’s multiprocessor machines tend to work bestwhen doing many problems at once, so that eachprocessor can be assigned its own problem to workon by itself; this reduces the need for inter-processorcoordination. Thus, these machines perform better intimesharing systems, running many applications at

Chapter 6--Japanese Industrial Policy: The Postwar Record and the Case of Supercomputers ● 257

Table 6-5--Number of New Installations in Japanese Supercomputer Market

1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990

Total (number ofsupercomputers) . . . . . 2

Annual growth rate . . . . . —

Sales to public sector:Total . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 0By foreign firms . . . . . . —By Japanese firms . . . —

Percent of publicprocurement offoreign machines . . . . . —

Sales to private sector: 2Total . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .By foreign firms . . . . . . 2By Japanese firms . . . 0

Percent of privatesector procurementof foreign machines . . 100%

Foreign share of allnew procurements . . . 100%

Japanese share of allnew procurements . . . O%

o.

———

——

o—

———

——

——

4400%

202

0%2

02

0%

0%

100%

6 11 2750% 83.3’%. 145.5%

4 4 121 0 03 4 ‘ 12

25% 0% 0%

2 7 15

0 1 22 6 13

0% 14.3% 13.3%

16.7% 9.1% 7.4%

83.3% 90.9% 92.6%

3633.3%

11011

O%

25

223

8.O%

5.6%

94.4540

372.8%

826

25%

29

623

20.7%

21.670

78.4%

3213.5%

413

25%

28

820

28.6%

28.1%

71.9%

1746.9%

615

16.7%

11

29

18.2%

17.6%

82.4%NA=Not applicable.

SOURCE: NIkkel Uotcha, IBM-Ban, Apr. 30, 1990, pp. 21-24.

once, than when dedicated to solve one very largeproblem.

As these last two factors suggest, measuring asupercomputer’s speed is not a cut-and-dried affair.Each machine has what is called a theoretical or peakspeed-the speed at which the hardware in principlecan do raw calculations. However, on real problemsthe speed is usually much less—typically betweenone-half and one-tenth of the peak speed. How muchless depends on the hardware design (issues ofbalance within a processor and coordination amongprocessors), the software (which might be more orless clever at breaking up the problem to keep thewhole machine busy at once), and the particularproblem (which may, for example, require a greatdeal of multiplication and division but relativelylittle fetching and storing of data to and frommemory, or vice versa).

One way of comparing the performance of differ-ent supercomputers is by benchmarking-runningcertain problems on each, and comparing the speeds.While benchmarking results depend on which prob-lems are chosen and what software is used, allcomparative analyses of supercomputers use bench-mark tests as at least one important indicator ofperformance. Benchmark tests have been done onU.S. and Japanese supercomputers by various uni-versities and labs. Cray Research reported as of May,

1990, that its machines always came out on top(figure 6-1).116

In the next generation, however, the gap willnarrow; if current rates of progress do not change,Japanese makers will exceed Cray in the peak speedsof multiprocessor machines and likely the actualperformance of hardware in the next decade. Japa-nese supercomputers are rapidly catching up inspeed. In recent tests run by Jack J. Dongarra, acomputer scientist at the Oak Ridge National Labo-ratory and a specialist on supercomputer speeds, theone processor SX-3 ran nearly three times as fast asa single processor Cray Y-MP, though not quite asfast as the eight processor Y-MP.117 Hideo Yo-shihara, a former Boeing specialist in the use ofsupercomputers for computational fluid dynamics,estimates that the four processor NEC SX-3, whichis expected out in late 1991, will have an actualspeed of some 7 gigaflops, higher than current Craymachines (1.5 gigaflops), and that the Cray ResearchC-90 (which will be released as the Y-MP16), alsoexpected in late 1991, will have a similar speed-7to 8 gigaflops. Cray disputes this, predicting that itsC-90 will be considerably faster than NEC’s four-processor SX-3. Yoshihara estimates that CrayComputer’s Cray-3 will have an actual speed of 7 to8 gigflops,118 and another estimate agrees119 that allthree new machines will have similar speeds.120

Fujitsu is said to be working on an eight CPU

258 ● Competing Economies: America, Europe, and the Pacific Rim

Figure 6-l—Actual v. Peak Supercomputer Performance (megaflops)

6,848? 6,848?6228? 16,000 16,000

[ Estimated Benchmark

2,1305,500

1,292 I I1007 2;667 928

486 502 1,951 396 623 5,000129 131 116 940 1,300 1,700 183 3,000235 630 500

l,n,333

1 1 I I 1 P/Al 1 1 I 111 1 1‘ Cray “Hitachi” Fuiitsu Cray NEC Cray-2 Fuiitsu Cray Cray Hitachi Fuiitsu NEC NEC Cray Cray-3

X - M P S - 8 1 0 / 2 0 V P - 2 0 0 X - M P S X - 2 A - VP-400E Y-MP Y-MP S-820/80 VP-_2600 SX-3 SX-3 Y-MP16 -

(4) (4) (8) (4) (16) (16)

11983

I1984 1985 I

1987 1988I

1989 1990 1991 ?1 I I

NOTES: Bars show actual or estimated performance on Navier/Stokes benchmark. Numbers show actual or estimated benchmark performance (top) and peakperformance (bottom). All systems have only one processor, except where a different number is indicated in parentheses.

SOURCE: Gartner Group, Inc., High Performance Compti”ng and Communications: Investment in American Competitiveness, report prepared for U.S.Department of Energy and lms Alarms National Laboratory, Mar. 15, 1991, p. 205.

machine, 121 and to have a four CPU machine likelyto be introduced in 1992, but no estimates have beenmade of their speeds.

In short, while Japanese supercomputers currentlyin use are slower than their U.S. counterparts, andtheir actual speeds have been substantially slowerthan their advertised peak speeds, they are still fastand closing the gap. In price/performance ratio,Japanese supercomputers are less competitive thanCrays even when the Japanese machines are dis-counted by 50 percent, according to data from Cray(figure 6-2). According to a different source (andusing peak rather than actual performance data)Japanese machines do better in price/performance,and will maintain this edge over traditional U.S.supercomputers, though the United States could beatJapan with massively parallel supercomputers.122 Inreliability, Japanese machines excel; Japanese ma-chines have been running at more than 5,000 hoursmean time between failures (MTBF), compared withCray’s record of less than 1,000 for the Cray X-MPseries. While the Y-MP machines are much better inMTBF than the X-MPs, they are not as good as theJapanese machines.123

While Japanese manufacturers are closing the gapwith Cray in speed and are ahead in reliability, theystill suffer from a relative lack of applicationssoftware. When NEC announced the SX-3, in April1989, with the claim that it was the world’s fastestsupercomputer:

. . . people in America were amazed, but Japaneseusers were not nearly as impressed; they understandthat even if it is potentially very fast, it is worthlessunless NEC provides [applications] software to usethat Speed.124

Indeed, NEC has only sold seven supercomputers inJapan to firms outside of the government and its ownindustrial group (table 6-6).

In massively parallel machines, the United Statesholds the clear lead. There are no commercializedmassively parallel processing machines in Japan.Matsushita, together with Kyoto University, hasbeen developing a parallel processing minisuper-computer, the Adena 256. This machine has 256processors and a speed of 1.6 gigaflops, and will sellfor about Y150 million ($1.15 million). They arealso working on a 25-gigaflop machine that they

Chapter 6-Japanese Industrial Policy: The Postwar Record and the Case of Supercomputers ● 259

Y-MP 8/8

Y-MP 4/4

Y-MP 2/2

X-MP EA/1 se

Y-MP2/1

S820/20

SX-JA

SX-1 EA

S820/40

S820/60

SX-l A

SX-2A

S820/80

VP-30E

VP-50E

VP-1OOE

VP-200EVP-400E

Y-MP 818

Y-MP 4/4

Y-MP 2/2

X-MP EA/1 se

S820/20

Y-MP2/l

SX-JA

SX-1 EA

S820/40

S820/60

SX-l A

SX-2A

S820/80

VP-30E

VP-50E

VP-1OOE

VP-200E

VP-400E

Figure 6-2—Performance/Price Data

Performance/price ratio

L

I

/ / / A

I

I

E=

E=1 I I I 1

I

o 2 4 6 8 10

50% discount onJapanese supercomputers

1 1 1 I II

12 14 16 18 20

Number of floating point operations per dollar(45-month lease)

Performance/price ratio

I

I

f=

~ 1, t I I I I I I I I{

o 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20

Number of floating point operations per dollar(45-month lease)

NOTE: Performance/Price ratio is calculated from published list prices on all supercomputers shown as of Sept. 30, 1989. A 45-month lease is assumed. Itis also assumed that the code run on the computer is 70 to 80 percent vectorized.

SOURCE: Cray Research, Inc.

260 ● Competing Economies: America, Europe, and the Pacific Rim

Table 6-6-Japanese Procurement of Supercomputers, 1980-90

Number of machines

Purchase by a Purchases byPurchase by firm in another Purchases Purchases private companies

Total Procurement for own group supercomputer by the by privateCompany

unaffiliated withprocurement internal use company maker’s group government universities the three groups

Fujitsu . . . . . . . . . . . . 85 9 10 5 26 14 21Hitachi . . . . . . . . . . . . 35 12 3 0 11 1 8NEC . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 24 3 5 1 9 3 3Cray Research . . . . 26 — — 8 4 1 13CDC . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 2 — — — 1 1 —

SOURCES: Nikkm” Uotcha, IBM-Ban, Apr. 30, 1990, pp. 21-24; Kigyo Keiretsu Soran, 1991.

hope to finish by 1992 and a 100-gigaflop machineby 1995-96.125 U.S. and Japanese scientists do not

see these efforts as a real threat to U.S. dominancein this area in the near future, but the Japanese arebeginning to invest heavily in this technology.126

HISTORICAL BACKGROUND: THEEFFECT OF PAST TARGETING OFTHE MAINFRAME COMPUTER ANDSEMICONDUCTOR INDUSTRIESJapan’s three supercomputer firms-Fujitsu,

Hitachi, and NEC--are also its major producers ofmainframe computers, and three of its major produc-ers of semiconductor devices. These firms’ experi-ence with computers and semiconductors was cru-cial in preparing them to make supercomputers.Their rise in the supercomputer industry todaydepended on previous Japanese Government poli-cies that helped these companies acquire the neces-

sary technological knowledge and skills.

In the late 1950s, Japanese Government officialsand businessmen decided to nurture a domesticcomputer industry. Their main concern at the timewas not whether computers alone would become aprofitable business, although they hoped it would be.Instead, the primary interest was in the positivecontributions of computers to other industries, suchas telecommunications, automation, and aerospace,and to the economy’s overall productivity. “It wasclear to both the government and the telecommuni-cations and heavy electric equipment makers that tosurvive they had to go into computers,” explainedYoshioka Tadashi, who was a MITI official closelyinvolved in nurturing computers in the 1950s and1960s and more recently the Director and adviser ofthe Japan Electronics Industry Development Associ-ation (JEIDA). 127 The first step, in 1957, was to passthe Extraordinary Measures Law for Promotion of

the Electronics Industry, targeting electronics ingeneral and computers in particular. This law and its

later extensions provided various subsidies and tax

benefits for the industry; it also exempted the

industry from antitrust law and encouraged firms to

cooperate on price, production, investment, and

R&D to gain the economies of scale necessary to

compete with IBM. Japan did not want to depend on

foreign firms for something as critical as comput-

e r s .1 2 8

There were four key types of policies that the

Japanese Government used to nurture a competitivecomputer industry: protection, a computer rental

company, substantial financial aid, and government-

sponsored R&D projects. In the 1960s and early

1970s protection was heavy against both imports

and foreign investment. While IBM had a sales

office in Japan since 1925, MITI repeatedly rejected

IBM’s efforts to transfer the technology and capital

necessary to produce in Japan.129 In the late 1950s,

according to a former MITI official, IBM started

warning the Japanese electronics firms and the

government about their infringement of IBM’s

patents. 130 MITI realized that the industry would not

be able to get off the ground without licenses under

IBM’s basic patents 131 and thus negotiated with

IBM. IBM agreed to license its basic patents in

exchange for permission to set up a wholly owned

subsidiary to produce computers in Japan. 132 B y

negotiating with IBM on the behalf of the firms,MITI was able to get licenses at lower rates than ifIBM had been permitted to negotiate with each firm

alone. MITI also controlled which models IBMcould produce and sell in Japan, quantities of eachmodel, and how much and which specific parts IBMcould import for its production. 133 It also decidedhow much IBM had to export134 (indeed, IBM wasone of Japan’s largest earners of foreign exchange atthe time) and limited the profit IBM’s Japanese

Chapter &Japanese Industrial Policy: The Postwar Record and the Case of Supercomputers .261

subsidiary could repatriate to its parent company.135

Finally, it delayed the start of IBM’s production by2 years after the agreement had been made.136

Even with all MITI’s controls, IBM was lucky. Byreestablishing itself in Japan in 1949 (after receivingback its assets that had been confiscated during thewar), IBM Japan avoided being forced by theForeign Investment Law of 1950 to make a joint

137 When Sperry Randventure with a Japanese firm.(UNIVAC computers) wanted to sell computers inJapan in the late 1950s, MITI used this law to requireit to make a joint venture with Japanese companiesand to give the Japanese partners a majority of theshares; MITI felt it could more easily control a firm

138 When Sperrywith majority Japanese ownership.Rand decided in the early 1960s that it wanted toproduce computers in Japan, MITI insisted that itmake another joint venture, this time with OkiElectric, to create Oki UNIVAC; Oki was requiredto hold 51 percent of the shares. Similarly, MITIallowed Hewlett Packard into Japan only on thecondition that it make a joint venture with YokogawaElectric, with the latter holding 51 percent of theshares.139

In addition to controlling the actions of U.S.manufacturers, the state also had a ‘‘Buy Japan’policy. In the 1960s and early 1970s the governmentprocured some 25 percent of all Japanese computers;in the last half of the 1970s and early 1980s, thisincreased by up to 5 percentage points.l40 In both

1984 and 1989,90 percent of the computers used bythe government were Japanese machines while only59 percent of the machines used by the private sectorwere domestic.141 “Protectionism was one of themost important policies [to promote the computerindustry]. The government created the computermarket, first by making government labs buy domes-

tic machines, then having national universities

purchase them,’ explained Takeuchi Hiroshi, Man-

aging Director of the Long Term Credit Bank of

Japan. 142

While not a formal government policy, the

tendency of Japanese firms to purchase computers

made by their group (keiretsu) computer companyalso serves to protect the market; in 1968, forexample, about half the computers being used byfirms in the major industrial groups were machinesmade by their own group’s computer firm.143 As ofthe late 1980s, 45.7 percent of the Sumitomo groupmachines were of NEC origin and 54.3 percent of

foreign origin (the Sumitomo group did not usemachines of other Japanese computer makers); 70.6percent of machines being used by Daiichi-Kangyogroup companies were of their group membersFujitsu and Hitachi, 28 percent were of foreignorigin, and a mere 1.4 percent were machines ofother Japanese makers.144 This pattern, with Japa-nese firms in each group buying computers eitherfrom their own group or from foreign fins, suggeststhat the fins’ in-group purchases are made at leastpartly because of group loyalty rather than themachines’ worth. This loyalty handicaps foreignfirms operating in Japan. The foreign share of theJapanese installed computer base plunged from 93percent in 1958 to 48 percent by 1965 and 42.5percent by 1969.145 In 1989, the foreign share stoodat about 37 Percent.146

While early protection gave the computer firms asafe harbor within which to develop, it was clear thatthe government would ultimately have to open up itsmarkets; the firms had to become competitive inorder to survive over the long term. A major problemthey faced was that of renting their machines. MostJapanese computer users did not have the hugeamounts of money needed to purchase computers;rapid technological advances deterred those that didfrom purchasing machines that would inevitablybecome obsolete within a year or two. IBM wasrenting its machines, so domestic companies neededto be able to rent to compete. But domestic firms didnot have the funds necessary to finance a rentalsystem, nor were banks willing to lend them themoney.147 To enable the firms to offer rentals, MITIhelped them establish the Japan Electronic Com-puter Co. (JECC), a joint venture among the majorcomputer makers, in 1961. JECC’s role was tofinance the rental of mainframe computers; by the1980s it would also become the major renter ofsupercomputers. Between 1961 and 1989, the gov-ernment channeled over $6 billion in loans intoJECC to help the company buy computers frommember firms and rent them to users for lowmonthly fees.148

When a user wanted to rent a computer, it notifiedJECC, and JECC purchased it from the maker andrented it to the user. The effect of purchasing themachines was to give the makers their return oninvestment up front-similar in effect to an interestfree loan.149 Since the firms themselves put capitalinto JECC,150 to some extent the firms were lendingmoney to themselves. However, between 1961 and

262 . Competing Economies: America, Europe, and the Pacific Rim

1989 JECC also received low interest loans from theJapan Development Bank with an implicit subsidyvalue of $461 million.151 ‘‘JECC had a very bigeffect in reducing our need for capital; if there hadnot been a JECC in the 1960s and 1970s, we[Fujitsu] could not have expanded our scale ofproduction; in that sense JECC played a very bigrole,’ explained Tajiri Yasushi, a manager atFujitsu.152

By enabling Japanese computer companies to renttheir machines at low monthly fees, JECC stimu-lated both the supply and demand for domesticcomputers.

153 JECC also managed a price cartel for

the industry and did not allow any discounting. Bylimiting price competition, JECC assured firms thatprofits would not evaporate in cutthroat price warsand shifted the competition to cost, technology, andquality.

JECC and domestic protection severely limitedforeign computer fins’ market share in the Japa-nese market, but they were not enough to improve

Japanese electronics companies’ competitiveness to

match that of IBM or Cray Research. In the early

1970s, the Japanese computer makers’ scale of

production was, on any given model, 1 to 2 percent

that of IBM154 and the technology was far inferior.

They needed financial help. One estimate is that

government financial assistance-subsidies, loans,

and tax benefits—to the industry amounted to some

$14.3 billion from 1961 to 1989. 155 According tothis estimate, in the 1960s, government aid was

some 188 percent of what the firms themselves were

investing in R&D and plant and equipment; from

1970 to 1975, it was 168 percent; from 1975 to 1981,

92 percent, and from 1982 to 1989,26 percent. As a

percent of sales, government aid was 53 percent

from 1961 to 1969; 40 percent from 1970 to 1975;

14 percent from 1976 to 1981 and 5 percent from

1982 to 1989.156 OTA has reestimated the totalgovernment financial assistance as $12.6 billion (seeapp. 6-A). Under OTA’s reestimated, government aidas a percentage of investment in these four timeperiods, from earliest to latest, was 87, 148, 84, and23 percent; as a fraction of sales it was 24, 35, 13,and 4 percent respectively.

This does not include the tremendous benefit thefirms received from the Japan Telegraph and Tele-phone Co. (NIT’), which was a government-ownedcompany until April 1, 1985, when the Ministry ofFinance started to sell some of its shares to the public

(the government intends to keep one-third of NTT’sshares permanently, and the company remains underthe supervision of the Ministry of Post and Telecom-munications). NTT has long been referred to as thedoru bako (dollar box) helping the computer compa-nies by purchasing their products (according tosome, at artificially high prices).157 Tajiri Yasushi,a manager in Fujitsu’s marketing department, statedin 1987 that:

NIT has probably been the greatest help toFujitsu’s business. Because of the profitability ofdoing business with NIT, it was more important[than MITI] for private industry. Our business withNTT has always been based on NTT purchasing theproduct, and we have always made a profit onbusiness with NTT.158

Indeed, Fujitsu, NEC, and Hitachi got the bulk ofNTT’s computer procurement, which totaled some$13.3 billion from 1965 to 1975159 and $13.6 billionfrom 1980 to 1986.160

The government also used cooperative R&Dprojects to nurture a competitive computer industry.These were aimed at helping the firms reduce theirtechnological gap with U.S. computer companies byreducing duplicative research and accelerating tech-nological advances. Numerous projects were under-taken from the early 1960s through the 1980s andearly 1990s (table 6-7). Several have been particu-larly important in enabling Japanese firma to de-velop the technologies and skills necessary toproduce supercomputers in the 1980s. Early proj-ects, such as the 1966 Super High-PerformanceComputer Project, helped the firms gain a footholdin the supercomputer industry both in design and inintegrated circuits.

The “New Series” Project, from 1972 to 1976,was critical in getting Fujitsu and Hitachi tostandardize their architectures and go the IBMcompatible route.161 Standardizing their architec-tures meant that with minor modifications, softwarecreated for a Fujitsu machine could also run on aHitachi and vice versa, and that the two machinescould be used with each other. This assured potentialusers that if one of the two companies withdrew fromthe computer business, machines and softwarepurchased from the defunct supplier could be keptand used with machines and software from theremaining firm.

162 Possibly, these decisions alsohelped Japanese companies to compensate for weak-ness in software development and small libraries of

Chapter 6--Japanese Industrial Policy: The Postwar Record and the Case of Supercomputers ● 263

Table 6-7-Government Subsidies for Computer-Related Government-SponsoredR&D Projects

Yen DollarsProject Year in billions in millions

FONTAC . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . ............ 1962-65Very High-Performance Computer Systems . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1966-71DIPS-I . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . ............. 1968-71Pattern Information Processing Systems (PIPS) ............... 1971-80New Series Project . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .1972-76Software Module Project . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .1973-75DIPS-II . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1973-75NTTs VLSI Project . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .1975-77MITI’s VLSI Project . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .1976-79Software Production Technology Development ................ 1976-81Basic Technology for Next Generation Computer Systems

(Fourth Generation Computer Systems) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1979-83Optical Measurement and Control Systems (Optoelectronics

Application Systems) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1979-85Basic Industrial Technology for the Next Generation ........... 1981-90Very High-Speed Scientific Computing Systems

(Supercomputers) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1981-89Fifth Generation Computer Systems (FGCS) .................. 1982-91Software Industrialized Generator and Aids (SIGMA) . . . . . . . . . . . 1985-89Interoperable Database Systems . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .1985-92

Y 0.3512.030.022.070.3

3.05.0

20.030.0

6.5

$ 0.97233.3383.3366.67

235.509.09

15.15100.00150.0032.5

21.15

18.050.0

18.250.012.520.0

105.75

90.00333.33

121.33333.33

96.2153.8

NOTE: There have been sharp exchange rate changes since the late 1970s. Thus, exchange rates used vary sharplydepending on the project’s date.

SOURCE: Marie Anchorodoguy, Cornputem /nc..’ Japan’s Challenge to IBM, pp. 225-244; JECC Kompyufa Noto,various issues.

area of strength for IBM). At any rate,software (anFujitsu and Hitachi cooperated just long enough to“unravel the secrets” of the architecture of IBMcomputers.

163 In explaining to his employees Fujitsu’sdecision to cooperate with Hitachi in this project,Kiyomiya Hire, Fujitsu’s Vice President, said:

Frankly speaking, if we do not do this, we cannotconfront our American competitors. If Japanesemakers in the domestic market did not cooperate andonly competed, before we knew it, we would betaken over by the American firms; there is a dangerthat every maker would be dealt a fatal blow. On theother hand, if we only cooperate and do not competeat all, we will all slide into stagnant waters, whichalso would be bad. The British and French computerindustries are examples of this. Thus, using coopera-tive relations during the early stages of developmentas a base, we will then compete on commercializingthe product; as a whole, we must oppose the threatposed by foreign capital. Thus we will cooperate onR&D, but in sales and production we will competefiercely as we have in the past. . . . Finally, I wouldlike to add that in the background of this move is theearnest guidance of MITI and the deep understand-ing of NTT. In regards to the big problems created bythe decision to liberalize the computer industry inthree years, both NTT and MITI have been seriousand forward-looking in considering what form ourcomputer industry should take in order to oppose thegiant power of American capital.164

The architecture of the M-series computers Fujitsuand Hitachi developed during this project is the basisof their mainframe and supercomputer architecturetoday; Fujitsu’s M-380 mainframe and Hitachi’sM-280H mainframe were used as the starting pointfor the development of their Fujitsu VP series ofsupercomputers and Hitachi S-81O supercomputersrespectively. 165 When Fujitsu Chairman, KobayashiTaiyu, was asked how the Japanese were able tosurvive during this volatile period in the early 1970seven though RCA and GE withdrew from thecomputer industry at this time, he replied:“[B]ecause MITI started providing research grantsand made different companies get together forcooperative development of new machines; for thefirst time, Japanese makers were ready for bat-tle. " 166

NIT’s and MITI’s VLSI (very large scale inte-grated circuit) projects, from 1975 to 1977 and 1976to 1980 respectively, were also key in helping theJapanese companies catch up in device technology.This was a necessary step to their becoming compet-itive in supercomputers today. NTT provided Y20billion ($100 million) to work with Fujitsu, Hitachi,and NEC on 64K RAMs (random access memorieswith 64 kilobits, or 64 thousand bits, of memory),something immediately commercializable.167 Whilethe NTT project formally lasted only 3 years, NTT,

264 ● Competing Economies: America, Europe, and the Pacific Rim

which does no production of its own, continued towork closely with these firms on advanced chipsafter the project ended. These efforts led to manyadvances in developing 64K RAMs in the last halfof the 1970s168 and a 256K RAM in early 1980.“NTT played a great role in the development ofVLSI technology,” according to Sakai Yoshio,senior researcher at Hitachi’s Central ResearchLaboratory. 169

MITI’s VLSI project targeted the development ofthe production equipment necessary for very largescale integration. Denser packing of integratedcircuits, which increases speed and decreases cost,would be key to advances in electronics in generaland computers in particular. The problem was howto develop equipment to draw narrower lines onwafers and thereby squeeze more circuits onto awafer. To study these topics, MITI divided up thefive firms involved in the project—Fujitsu, Hitachi,Mitsubishi, NEC, and Toshiba—into three groupsand had them take seven different approaches to thesame problem. The rationale was that there arealways failures in R&D; if several firms approach aproblem differently and agree to share their results,the time and money it takes to develop a successfultechnology can be cut substantially. The 4 yearproject cost Y72 billion ($360 million), of which Y30billion was funded by the government.170 “Thetiming of the project was critical,” explainedShimizu Sakae, Senior Managing Director of Toshiba,“there was no electron beam [for drawing very finelines] and we needed a breakthrough to get ahead.The firms did not have any of the equipment forproducing VLSIs, such as the electron beam ortesting equipment. ’’171 The firms would not havedone research on such advanced chips at that time ifnot for the project.172 Indeed, the project was toorisky for firms to do without the government sharingcosts and risks. As one maker put it:

Because of the limited resources of a private firm,we domestic makers cannot allow a failure; wecannot deny that this [participation in MITI’s VLSIproject] was taking a big hedge against risk.173

Without MITI’s VLSI Project, explained MatsukaraYasuo, General Manager of NEC’s VLSI develop-ment division, each company would have had tospend five times as much on R&D to developelectron-beam technology.174

Several specialists point to the VLSI projectresults as being a critical ingredient in Japan’s ability

to enter the supercomputer market in the early1980s. 175 Indeed, the speed of Japan’s supercomput-ers today is largely the result of very advancedsemiconductors. While Japanese companies’ privateefforts account for most of the advances in devicesused in supercomputers, the VLSI project did allowthem to get a foothold in this field at a critical time.

Japanese policies supporting the development ofthe computer and semiconductor industries werecharacterized by flexibility-making fast responsesto new developments and supporting the firms thatseemed strongest at various points in time-andstrategic use of market signals to provide firmsincentives to improve technology. For example,JECC only bought domestic computers that usersspecifically asked to rent. There was a direct tie tothe market; if no one asked to rent a particularcomputer, JECC did not buy it. Those firms with thebest machines got the most orders from customersand thus the most benefit from JECC. By managingprices, JECC helped the firms avoid destructivecompetition, but prices were set at levels competi-tive with IBM. Price cooperation pressured the firmsto compete on other dimensions key to developingcompetitiveness-like cost, quality, and technol-ogy. R&D subsidies were important but the firmsoften had to match R&D grants and always had tocontribute their engineers. This assured some degreeof commitment from the companies, as well as directtransfer of technologies to the private sector. Andsubsidized R&D was tied to performance. If acompany did not commercialize the results of aproject, or in general became uncompetitive, it couldexpect to be left out of the next project. Thishappened to Oki Electric-it was left out of theVLSI project due to its failure to commercialize theresults of the research it did in MITI’s earlier ‘NewSeries” project.176 Finally, cooperation on R&D astep before the commercialization stage helped thefirms but still left substantial room for competition,which provided incentives for rapid developmentand manufacturing efficiency.

TARGETING SUPERCOMPUTERSAs the earlier analysis of U.S. and Japanese

supercomputers suggests, Japanese companies havealmost caught up with (and maybe poised to moveahead of) their U.S. competitor (Cray Research) inthe hardware for traditional supercomputers, thoughthey lag in software (especially applications soft-ware) and in developing massively parallel process-

Chapter 6-Japanese Industrial Policy: The Postwar Record and the Case of Supercomputers .265

ing machines. Government policies have been animportant ingredient enabling them to rapidly closethe technological gap with American companies.

The High Speed Computing System forScientific and Technological Uses

The major R&D effort targeting supercomputerswas the High Speed Computing System for Scien-tific and Technological Uses Project, 1981 to1989. 177 It was clear to MITI and the computercompanies that both high speed devices (compo-nents) and architectures (overall designs) that per-mitted many calculations to be done in parallelwould be necessary to make better computers, andthat these computers would have important applica-tions.

For nuclear fusion, nuclear power, energy explo-ration, weather and earthquake forecasting, anddefense-areas related to national security-it isnecessary to have a high speed computer [such asthat to be developed in this project],

according to a MITI statement on the project.178

MITI also knew that the R&D needed to make bettercomputers would be useful in other industries aswell:

Completing the High Speed Computer System forScientific and Technological Uses will have broad

spillovers sharply raising the scientific and techno-logical level of every industry. . . thereby contribut-ing to our aim of establishing our nation as a leaderin technology.179

The primary goal of the project was to help the firmsacquire the technological building blocks for mak-ing their own supercomputers, but the formal goal

.180 in order to get moneywas to develop a prototype,from the Ministry of Finance for projects, MITIneeds to be able to show them something specific atthe end.181 The project was fully funded by thegovernment; the initial budget was Y23 billion but inthe end the government spent only Y18.2 billion($121.33 men).182 It called for development of a10-gigaflops parallel processing supercomputer, aspeed that at that time seemed like a dream.183 Thesix major vertically integrated computer/semicon-ductor companies-Hitachi, Fujitsu, NEC, Mitsu-bishi, Oki, and Toshiba-participated in the project(figures 6-3 and 6-4). Matsushita and Sony wantedto join the project but were not allowed in.184

The project focused on high-speed devices andparrallel architectures. The research on high-speeddevices was divided up among the six participatingfirms: NEC, Toshiba, Hitachi, and Mitsubishi re-searched gallium arsenide chips; 185 Fujitsu, Hitachi,and NEC, Josephson junctions; and Fujitsu and Oki,HEMT (high electronic mobility transistor) de-

Figure 6-3-Schedule of Research and Development for High Speed ComputingSystem for Scientific and Technological Uses Project

Fiscal year

R & Dareas

(1)High-speedlogic andmemory devices

(2)Parallelarchitectureand software

(3)Integratedsystem

1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988

J J deviceHEMT deviceGaAs FET device I I Refinement

I I/

Architecture

ID

Basic Softwareresearch 1

Y v4

Integratedsystem

I

1989

1.Evaluation

I

SOURCE: MITI.

266 ● Competing Economies: America, Europe, and the Pacific Rim

Figure 6-4-Organization of the Supercomputer Project, 1981-89

● MITI Sponsors Industrial Technology

● Agency for Industrial Promotion Agency

Science and Technology I. National R&D Program

vMITI consignmentpayments (Itakuhi)

+Association for the

Development of High-SpeedScientific Computers 4

(formed December 1981)

‘es””~ Fiizi==systems incorporating arrays

L.Produce processors with Combine a large numberspeeds in the 40-100

MFLOPS rangeof 4-M FLOPS elements to

reach 1 GFLOPS

rlJosephsonJunctionDevices

t. NEC● Fujitsu● Hitachi

I ISOURCE: Dataquest, Inc.

I

Sale ofpatents

nHighElectronMobilityTransistor(HEMT)

● Fujitsu● Old

nGalliumArsenide(GaAs)Field-EffectTransistors(FETS) andMemorydevices

vices.186 Both U.S. and Japanese researchers agreethat this project helped the Japanese firms gainproficiency in these technologies.187

The research on parallel processing was dividedinto three subgroups: the high-speed parallel subproj-ect; the sigma-1 dataflow subproject; and the satel-lite image processing subproject. The high-speedparallel subproject was the most important. Aimedat quickly developing a four CPU machine, thesubproject combined into one machine four ofFujitsu’s already successful single processor ma-

● Hitachi • Fujitsu ● Toshiba● Mitsubishi ● Hitachi ● Mitsubishi

Electric ● NEC Electric. Old

chines,188 which had an architecture based on thatdeveloped in an earlier MITT project.189 Fujitsufocused on developing the software needed to get thefour processors to operate in parallel. The prototypehigh-speed parallel system ran at over 10 gigaflops.The system was designed to accommodate up to 16processors, but because of budget constraints only 4were used.190

The second architectural subproject--Sigma-1Dataflow subproject—focused on developing a

machine with 128 processors, a precursor to one

Chapter 6-Japanese Industrial Policy: The Postwar Record and the Case of Supercomputers ● 267

with 1,024 processors.191 Dataflow machines weretried in the United States and were not verysuccessful; thus most U.S. scientists do not expectthis subproject to have a big impact on Japanesesupercomputers.

192 The subpl-eject also had softwareproblems, according to a U.S. researcher who visitedthe ETL (MITI’s Electrotechnical Laboratory) inboth 1989 and 1990 and saw little progress made onthe software necessary to run the machine.193

Nonetheless, the research group’s successful com-pletion of a 128-processor machine adds to theparticipants’ understanding of massively parallelarchitectures.

The third subproject was the satellite image dataprocessing system,

194 mother way of exploringparallel architectures; this system can be used fordata processing of images and visualization. Threetypes of architecture were explored: Toshiba fo-cused on a high-speed three-dimensional displayprocessor using 16 very fast VLSI processors;Mitsubishi worked on a simpler machine aimed atprocessing image data obtained from satellites; andOki worked on a two-dimensional display using 8processors for use in global data processing net-works. 195 These results will help these firms makeparallel processing machines for voice and patternrecognition and visualization, areas considered in-creasingly important in the 1990s.

As early as the mid-1980s, people from the firmsinvolved said that the project was helping themsignificantly; 196 but the big results of the projecthave yet to be incorporated into the firms’ machines.The final prototype, completed in early 1990,demonstrates how the main technologies developedin the project work together, primarily the devicetechnologies and the results of the high speedparallel subproject.197 It is not, however, a prototypeof a machine that could be directly commercialized.While Fujitsu was the main contractor for theprototype of a 10-gigaflop machine, doing thecomputing system and integration of all the parts,Hitachi did the operating system, and NEC thehigh-speed, large-capacity storage system.198 Manyconcrete results were achieved: in the final proto-type, gallium arsenide devices were used, though notas extensively as initially envisioned; Josephsonjunction devices were not used at all in the finalprototype, although the project advances in Jo-sephson junctions put Japan in the lead in this area,which is considered to have good prospects in thelate 1990s and after.199 Fujitsu used these results to

develop a recently announced hybrid Josephsonjunction-VLSI device, which it plans to use in itsnext generation supercomputers, scheduled for themid-1990s. 200 All in all, some 602 patents resultedfrom the project.

201 Licenses are available to allparticipating companies for a nominal fee and othercompanies for a higher though still reasonable fee.

Another contribution of the project was that it gotJapanese computer makers to focus on supercomput-ers. The companies were not initially interested inthe project because they thought there was not alarge enough market for supercomputers.202 ‘Whenthe project was started, there were few supercomput-ers in use worldwide, so we thought there was notenough demand. I do not think that one companywould have made such a big effort in supercomput-ers [as the project has], ” explained Oketani Kisa-buro, section chief of Fujitsu’s Market PlanningDepartrnent. 203 When asked why Fujitsu does notrefuse to join MITI projects it is not interested in,Tajiri Yasushi of Fujitsu explained: ‘ ‘If we ever said,‘forget about Fujitsu [for a given project] and do itwith someone else, ’ we would never be invited tojoin a government project again,’‘204 a consequenceFujitsu was not willing to accept.

The government offered to fund the entire projectand the firms went along. Supercomputer develop-ment might have happened eventually, but theproject started things moving sooner, and, throughcooperation, probably got the job done faster andmore efficiently than if any one firm had worked onits own. “The Japanese industry and R&D institutesare very cooperative and often go on ‘division-of-labor’ arrangements. This gives us a considerableedge over IBM, which has to do everything on itsown, ’ ‘ stated Fujitsu Chairman Kobayashi Taiyu.205

The companies supplemented the project withtheir own research. A Japanese expert closelyinvolved in the project said the three Japanesesupercomputer makers are each spending three tofour times the project budget on supercomputerresearch themselves,206 suggesting spending of some$360 to 490 million investment by each of the threefins. This investment, along with the $121.33million provided by this government project, payspart of the development of new generation super-computers. Cray forecast that it would spend $100million in development costs for its C-90 machinedue out in late 1991.207 Cray’s spending should notbe compared directly with the Japanese companies’

268 ● Competing Economies: America, Europe, and the Pacific Rim

spending during the High Speed Computing Systemproject, for that project spans more than onegeneration of product development; moreover, it isnot clear how many years Cray’s $100 millionexpenditure on the C-90 covers. Nevertheless, thevery rough comparison is instructive. The Japanesefirms can outgun Cray in R&D, in part because ofhelp from their government.

NTT has its own supercomputer project, whichinvolves Fujitsu, NEC, and Hitachi.208 In early 1985,the NTT lab successfully developed a 1K lead-basedJosephson memory chip, which ranks as one of thefastest in the world, and also a pace-setting 4Kgallium arsenide memory.209 Unfortunately, it isimpossible to get any further information on NTT’ssupercomputer project.

Other Government-Sponsored ProjectsRelated to Supercomputer Technologies

Several other projects have contributed to Japan’sability to produce parallel processing machines.Indeed, there are over 70 projects exploring paralleland massively parallel processing in Japan’s publicand private sectors; about 25 percent focus on highspeed supercomputing, 25 percent on artificialintelligence, and the remaining 50 percent on areassuch as image processing, computer graphics, com-puter aided design (CAD), and databases.210.

The largest is the Fifth Generation ComputerProject, 1981 to 1991, a Y100 billion project, whichthe government is supporting with Y50 billion($333.33 million). This project focused on develop-ing parallel processing for artificial intelligence (asopposed to numerical computing applications). Thegoal was for a machine able to infer knowledgebased on data stored in its memory, for example, acomputer able to write its own software for newapplications and able to process and understand avariety of symbols, including kanji (the Chinesecharacters that are part of the Japanese writtenlanguage) and photographs. The initial expectationwas that the fifth generation machine would be ableto “reason” at an elementary level, and thus helpmanagers, doctors, and others who analyze problemsthrough complex sequences of inferences.

Eight companies (Fujitsu, Hitachi, NEC, Mitsu-bishi, Toshiba, Oki, Matsushita, and Sharp), alongwith NTT, have sent engineers to ICOT (Institute forNew Generation Computer Technology), a centrallaboratory established in 1982 to conduct the re-

search. (NTT also has its own fifth generationcomputer project, which it invited NEC, Hitachi, andFujitsu to join.

211) At ICOT, researchers from thedifferent companies work side by side, somethingunusual in MITI projects. ICOT also distributeswork among five other laboratories.

The Fifth Generation Project worked on bothsoftware and hardware. The Japanese companiesoriginally did not want to join the cooperative effortbecause they believed that the goals were far toovague; they were particularly concerned that theproject did not target an IBM-compatible ma-chine.212 But the government agreed to put upmoney to get the project started, and the firms wentalong and ultimately matched the government fund-ing.

It is too early to assess the project’s impact. It isgenerally believed that the project fell far short of itsambitious goal of creating a prototype ‘‘thinkingmachine.” Some U.S. scientists in particular criti-cize the project’s focus on logic programming andthe fact that it has not produced any fundamentaladvances. 213 Even SO, the project probably is not adead loss. Speaking of one of the project’s interimresults-Mitsubishi’s uniprocessor and 16-proces-sor parallel inference machines, which were demon-strated at Argonne National Lab in Illinois-anArgonne scientist said:

They are learning a lot about parallel processing.By working in this project, the companies havegotten their brightest people exposed to many issuesin parallel processing and to the international scien-tific community. Now that the project is ending,these people will go back to their firms with thisknowledge. The project has not been a total successbut I expect a favorable long-term effect.214

Computer makers expect some spin-offs from tech-nology researched in the project, according toShimizu Sakae, Toshiba’s Senior Managing Direc-tor;215 some spin-offs have already been commer-cialized.

The project has played a role in pushing theindustry to explore new technologies, especiallynon-IBM compatible machines. The industry wasrattled in mid-1982 when IBM cooperated with theFBI in a sting to catch Hitachi and Mitsubishistealing IBM’s technological secrets. The Japanesefirms have been forced to make licensing agree-ments with IBM involving large sums. Hitachi, forinstance, reportedly paid IBM Y1O billion ($45.45

Chapter &Japanese Industrial Policy: The Postwar Record and the Case of Supercomputers ● 269

million) for the cost of a lawsuit and for past use ofsoftware similar to IBM’s, and in the mid to late1980s was paying some Y8 to Y12 billion ($60-90million) a year for its use; IBM also received theright to inspect new Hitachi machines to confirmthat Hitachi is keeping the agreement.216 Japanesecompanies felt that, to survive over the long term,they would have to develop their own operatingsystem standard. “We have to make a completebreak from the IBM standard in order to survive,”said Yamamoto Kinko, the Managing Director of theJapan Information Processing Development Center(JIPDEC). 217 “We’ve got to find another standard,”agrees Tomioka Susumu, manager of Fujitsu’ssoftware division.218 If Japanese companies dodevelop their own standard, and it is widely ac-cepted, this could have serious consequences forIBM, as well as other U.S. systems and componentproducers.

Finally, the technologies investigated in theproject will help Japanese companies to movetowards massively parallel machines. In the interimstage of the Fifth Generation Project, Mitsubishicompleted a prototype of a 64-processor parallelinference machine. The project is concluding withthree prototypes: a full version 1000 VLSI process-ing unit made by Fujitsu, one with about 256processors made by Mitsubishi, and a smallerversion made by a third company.

219 It is too earlyto know how good these machines will be; but eventhough they are unlikely to be commercial suc-cesses, the firms and their researchers will havegained experience.

As a successor to the Fifth Generation Project,MITI is exploring a New Information ProcessingTechnology Project (NIPT). This so-called “SixthGeneration Computer Project” is expected to focuson basic principles of massively parallel processing,three dimensional information, and visual and audi-tory recognition, aimed at developing a reliablecomputer with a million or more processors.220 Theproject will continue the Fifth Generation project’sfocus on a” “thinking” computer, one that performstasks such as pattern recognition and intuitiveinformation processing better than conventionalcomputers. The goal is to be able to deal withambiguous or incomplete information.221 Though inJuly 1991 the project was still in the planning stageand had not yet been given the official go-ahead, itwas expected to be approved, to be of the same scaleas the Fifth Generation Project, and to follow an

organizational structure such as that used by ICOT.222

Two U.S. computer scientists familiar with thisproposal argue that while there will be difficultproblems in designing and building the proposedsixth-generation computer, it will likely serve as amagnet attracting Japan’s top research minds.223 Theproject would require a major software effort andfurther R&D on massively parallel processing archi-tectures, areas where Japanese companies lag Amer-ican companies.

Finally, there have been a few government proj-ects to help Japanese companies develop softwarefor supercomputers, another area of comparativeweakness. One small national project run by theFluid Dynamics Analysis System Research Associa-tion aims to develop fluid dynamics software forsupercomputers. Started in March 1988, five compa-nies, seven major users, and one software house areparticipating in this 4-year project; members includeAsahi Kasei, Takenaka Komuten, Tokyo ElectricPower, Toshiba, NICK, NEC, Hitachi, Fujitsu, Mat-sushita Denko, Marubeni, and Mitsubishi HeavyIndustries. Some experts see the involvement ofusers in software R&D projects as a promisingapproach to ensure that the project will be commer-cially useful. The group has received Y1 billion($7.7 million) from the government for the 4-yearperiod from March 1988 to March 1992.2X Membercompanies are charged Y60 million each, andsupporting members (which they hope to increase tosome 200-300 fins) Y4.8 million.225 Another small-scale software project that will have an impact onsupercomputers is MITI’s New Software Structur-ing Project, which aims to make it easier to maintainlarge software systems such as online systems forbanks, companies, and government agencies. Thisproject is expected to begin in 1991 with actualresearch starting in 1992; it will last 8 years and willbe funded at about Y5 billion (about $35 million).226

The Japanese Government is playing a criticalrole in providing the seed money and the coordina-tion necessary to get Japan’s government labs, majorcompanies, and universities to cooperate in develop-ing very future-oriented supercomputer technolo-gies, work that they would not be doing otherwise.When asked in the late 1980s whether governmentprojects such as the Fifth Generation and supercom-puter projects have any significance given thatJapanese firms have become very strong in their ownright, Kuwahara Yutaka, head of R&D Administra-

270 . Competing Economies: America, Europe, and the Pacific Rim

Table 6-8—U.S. and Japanese Supercomputer Companies’ Share of the World Market

Market share in percent(number of installations)

Company 1980 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989

Cray . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 90% 56% 60.7% 67% 64% 53.1%(148) (219)

Fujitsu . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 00/0

I

15.5% 1770 12% 21 .6%(38) (89)

NEC . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 0% 24% 2.5°10 6% 4% 6.3%(6) (26)

Hitachi . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . O%

I

4.5% 4% 4% 7.8%(11) (32)

CDC/ETA . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 10% 20% 16.8% 6% 16% 11.2%(41) (46)

Total . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 100% 100% 100% 100% 100% 100%(244) (340) (412)

SOURCES: Kompyutopia December 1989,p. 76; Nikkei Sangyo Shh??6un,Apr. 19, 1989, p.3; bsArrge/es Tines,Sept. 4, 1987; High Performance Computing and Communications: Investment in American Competitive-ness, Gartner G~oup, Inc., p. 69.

tion at Hitachi’s Central Research Laboratory,replied:

Government projects are significant because thereare many things for us to challenge in the future,many of which can be better done in a governmentproject than a private one. . . .When profit de-creases. . due to the recession, the increasinglyhigher yen, and trade friction, we, in our [corporate]lab, are pressured to cut costs and to be moreproduct-oriented. It is very difficult to propose afuture-oriented technology because we will be asked,‘Is it necessary? How profitable will the results be?’So we believe that national projects are very veryimportant when they are future-oriented-when theyfocus on very risky R&D that is very difficult for theprivate sector to challenge alone.227

JECC also provides implicit subsidies to Japanesesupercomputer makers. A third of Fujitsu’s super-computers are rented through JECC, and “A sub-stantial amount of our supercomputer businesscomes from JECC," stated Watanabe Tadashi ofNEC.228

PROCUREMENT OFSUPERCOMPUTERS

A major aspect of targeting supercomputers hasbeen the procurement of domestic machines by thegovernment and the private sector. While companiesin the United States and Europe bought Americanmachines (which, until recently, performed muchbetter and still have more software than Japanesemachines), the Japanese Government and privatesector bought Japanese machines (tables 6-8 through6-10).

Table 6-9-U.S. and Japanese SupercomputerCompanies’ Share of the European Market, 1989

Market share in percent(number of installations)

Cray . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 84%(73)

Fujitsu . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 9%(8)

CDC/ETA . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 6%( 5 )

NEC . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .(1)

Hitachi . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . O%(o)

Total . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 100%(87)

SOURCE: Cray Research.

Private Sector Procurement

Analysis of private sector procurement of super-computers in Japan shows that a significant amountare purchases of a group member’s machine. Of 12machines owned by Fujitsu group companies, 10 areFujitsus and 2 are foreign machines; of 11 machinesowned by NEC group companies, 5 are NECs, 3 areFujitsus, and 3 are foreign machines; and of 9machines owned by Hitachi group companies, 3 areHitachis, 3 are machines of other Japanese super-computer makers, and 3 are foreign machines (table6-11). (These figures do not include machines usedinternally by Fujitsu, Hitachi, and NEC.)

Keiretsu feelings are strong, and firms only goagainst them when they feel their survival is at stake.“We would like ideally to purchase the supercom-puter of the maker in our group, but if we try to savethe face of each firm in our group, we’d be defeated

Chapter 6--Japanese Industrial Policy: The Postwar Record and the Case of Supercomputers ● 271

Table 6-10-U.S. and Japanese Supercomputer Companies’ Share of theJapanese Market, Installed Base

Market share in percent(number of installations)

Company 1987 1988 1989 1990 (3/90)

Cray . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 13.O% 11 .5% 10.1% 15.6%( 7 ) (13) (14) (23)

Fujitsu . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 54.O% 49.6% 49.O%(30) (61) (69) (72)

NEC . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 13.0% 15.9’YO 16.6Y0 14.3%(7) (18) (23)

Hitachi(21)

. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 18.5% 17.770 23.0% 19.7%(lo) (20) (32) (29)

CDC/ETA . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . — 0.9% 0.7% 1 .4%(1) (1)

Total(2)

. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 100.0% 110.O’% 100.0% 100.O%(54) (113) (139) (147)

SOURCES: Dempa Shimbun, Apr. 9, 1987, p. 1; Nikkei Uotcha BM-Ban, Apr. 30, 1990, p. 22; and AdvancedComputing in Japan, Japan Ttinology Evaluation Center, October 1990, p. 140.

Table 6-n—Purchases by Firms with Keiretsu Ties to Japanese SupercomputerMakers, 1980-90

Number of machines

Total Purchases Purchasespurchases by Purchases from from other of foreign

Company group group members affiliated makers Japanese makers supercomputers

Fujitsu’s group . . . . . . . . 12 10 0 2Hitachi’s group . . . . . . . . 9 3 3 3NEC’S group . . . . . . . . . . 11 5 3 3

Total . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 32 18 6 8SOURCE: Nikkei Uotcha, IBM-Ban, Apr. 30, 1990, pp. 21-24; Kigyo Keiretsu Soran, 1991.

in the severe competition we face, and we cannotafford to do that,” explained one auto maker.229

Many argue that supercomputers are driving thecompetition in automobile design today; for exam-ple, Toyota’s purchase of a Cray after it learned thatNissan had made many key product developmentadvances using a Cray supports this notion. Toyotahad been using a Fujitsu, and the switch only servesto underline the superiority of Cray machines andtheir software (at that time) for auto industryapplications.230

Mazda, which is heavily indebted to the Sumitomogroup for bailing it out when it was threatened withbankruptcy, solved its obligation by a compromise;it bought an NEC machine to save face with theSumitomo group and a Cray for its applicationssoftware. 231 Sumitomo Chemical did not make sucha compromise; it completely went against NEC (itsgroup computer maker) when, in September 1989, itbought a Cray because of Cray’s better software.232

Nissan, which has a long relationship withHitachi, bought two Cray supercomputers. But

Nissan’s first purchase of a Cray in 1986 only cameafter U.S. pressure. According to some reports,Nissan engineers leaked to the U.S. Embassy inTokyo and to Cray’s office there that they wanted aCray but that top company executives had decided topurchase a Hitachi due to their “relationship.” Theleak had its intended effect; the United States TradeRepresentative (USTR) and Department of Com-merce officials discussed the issue with MITI, whichin turn pressured Nissan to purchase a Cray.233 Sincethen, Nissan officials have frequently stated thatCray’s simulations software and its UNIX-basedoperating system are the deciding factors in itspurchase of Cray machines.234 “For our needs, Crayperformed the best,” explained a Nissan manager.235

Automobile companies are the clearest exampleof a Japanese industry in which all the major actorshave Cray machines. Of Cray’s 26 Japanese installa-tions, 10 are in the auto industry, which purchasedthe Cray machines primarily for their performance,especially the crash simulations applications soft-ware. Of less significance, Japanese auto companies

272 . Competing Economies: America, Europe, and the Pacific Rim

are aware that purchasing foreign machines helps tobalance their huge exports of autos to the UnitedStates, potentially reducing trade friction.236

While Cray has been able to attract some custom-ers from the groups of Japan’s supercomputermakers, its biggest Japanese market is firms that arenot part of the groups to which NEC, Fujitsu, andHitachi belong. Of all supercomputer purchases inJapan, 26 percent (46 of 172) have been by privatecompanies unaffiliated with the groups of Japan’sthree supercomputer makers; 50 percent of thepurchases of Cray machines were by such compa-nies (13 of 26), compared to 25 percent for Fujitsu(21 of 85),23 percent for Hitachi (8 of 35), and 13percent for NEC (3 of 24) (table 6-6). Toshiba is onesuch example. In 1989 it bought a Cray Y-MP8/4128for its applications software and the fact that itworked on UNIX, which was compatible withToshiba’s engineering work stations.237 That manysuch companies have purchased Cray machinessupports the notion that Cray is very competitive.

The fact that Japanese firms are vertically inte-grated and can use their own supercomputers in theirsemiconductor divisions also explains a chunk ofprivate sector procurement. Of Hitachi’s total salesof 35 supercomputers, 12 are used internally; ofNEC’s 24 supercomputers, 3 are used internally; ofFujitsu’s 85 supercomputers, 9 are used internally(table 6-6). Finally, strong societal pressure to buyJapanese probably also tilts the market in domesticfirms’ favor.

It is very difficult to estimate how many foreignsupercomputers would have been purchased in anopen market. There are two issues: quality and price.On quality, most U.S. observers would say that atleast through 1989 U.S. machines were superior. Amore conservative approach is to say that, on thebasis of quality alone, U.S. firms would have won allsales to the private sector through 1986, all sales toJapanese auto manufacturers through 1989, and thethree additional keiretsu-related sales during 1987-1989. This amounts to 20 supercomputers. The U.S.machines would have cost substantially more, and itis impossible to know how many Japanese userswould have paid to obtain a better foreign machineif the market had been fully open. However, on thesomewhat tenuous assumption that the customerswould have been willing and able to pay higherprices for foreign machines, Cray and ETA wouldhave sold 20 more supercomputers. If three later

upgrades of those machines are counted, the totallost sales amount to 23 machines.238

Public Sector Procurement

While Cray and CDC have faced keiretsu ties intheir efforts to sell to Japan’s private sector, publicsector sales have been even harder to win. Of 51government procurements of supercomputers, 5have been of foreign machines (see tables 6-5 and6-6).239 This record ultimately led to two agreementsbetween the United States and Japan over supercom-puter procurement, one in 1987 and another in 1990.

The Japanese Government did not purchase anysupercomputers until 1983, the year Japanese firmsintroduced their first models; the Cray-1 had beenout since 1976 and Japan’s private sector hadpurchased two foreign machines as early as 1980(table 6-5). When Japan’s public sector did startbuying supercomputers, the U.S. Government andsupercomputer makers realized that the public pro-curement process was not transparent-U.S. firmswere never notified when a procurement wouldoccur-and the Japanese firms gave deep discounts,which the U.S. Government and supercomputermakers maintained were some 80 to 90 percent offlist prices.

The Japanese Government budget is a primarycause of the heavy discounts on supercomputers soldin public sector markets; the Ministry of Financedoes not give the Ministry of Education a largeenough budget to allow the public universities andlaboratories to purchase supercomputers at or nearlist prices. A high level Ministry of Educationofficial says that the Ministry has a responsibility touse taxpayer money with as much care as possibleand thus to have universities purchase supercomput-ers as cheaply as Possible.240 These discounts havethe effect of decreasing net government aid to thesupercomputer makers, though in ways that helpthem win sales in important markets.

Indeed, discounting to universities can make goodbusiness sense. IBM long ago began giving universi-ties big discounts on its mainframes, and universityusers often develop software, which increases thedemand for a machine. Also, when students accus-tomed to using a certain machine graduate and entera company, they tend to want to continue with thesame type of machine. A discount sale can also helpto secure future business. Once a computer makerinstalls its machine, it has a very high probability of

Chapter &Japanese Industrial Policy: The Postwar Record and the Case of Supercomputers ● 273

continued sales (though if the customer is a univer-sity, probably at discounts) in the future because ofcompatibility.

Small public sector budgets encourage Japanesemakers to offer heavy discounts to universities andgovernment laboratories or forego the businessaltogether. Discounts of 80 percent or more areconsidered natural. ‘It’s not that we like to give suchdiscounts. If only the government would give[public institutions] a sufficient budget, then thiswould not have to happen, ’ explained one mid-levelFujitsu manager.

241 But the benefits to Japanesemakers still outweigh the costs: “When they use ournew machine, it helps us improve upon the productin the future,” explained a Hitachi manager; “Whena university uses our machine. . . it improves ourimage,’ adds an NEC manager; ‘‘We want to giveassistance to Japan’s researchers; not just in super-computers, but in other products too; it [the heavydiscounting of supercomputers] is the price of thatbusiness,’ explains a Fujitsu manager.242 Discountsalso oblige university professors, who are closelyinvolved in recommending their top graduates torecruiting firms, to give their best graduates to firmsgiving big discounts.243 Aware of their weakness insoftware, firms see universities as helping themimprove their software.244 ‘‘Actually it would befine to give it to them for free, but that becomes a giftand causes tax problems; that’s why we take theapproach of just giving them a big discount,”explained a manager of a Japanese supercomputerfirm.245

By late 1985 and early 1986, the United Statesstarted to express more forcefully its dissatisfactionwith the lack of transparency and the lack of publicprocurement of foreign supercomputers. By 1986,the Japanese Government had purchased 22 super-computers, only 1 of which was foreign, even thoughU.S. machines were far superior at the time. Inresponse to U.S. complaints, Prime Minister Na-kasone Yasuhiro assured the United States that NTTwould buy another Cray supercomputer to improvethe trade balance.246 (The Ministry of Financeowned 100 percent of NTT’s stock until April 1985;MOF has since sold some of its NIT shares but thecompany is still mostly government-owned.) Ac-cording to Japanese documents, Nakasone’s deci-sion to have NTT buy another foreign supercom-puter came at a time when NTT was at pains toincrease purchases from the United States. Soonafter, NTT President Shinto made a deal with the

head of the Recruit Corp., a Japanese real estate/job-referral firm, to have Recruit repurchase the super-computer NTT planned to buy from Cray.247

By late 1986, it was clear that no big changes inpublic procurement were forthcoming; discountingof up to 80 to 90 percent off list prices continued.After various negotiations among the USTR, Com-merce Department, and State Department, the Ad-ministration decided to conduct an inquiry intoJapanese procurement under section 305 of the 1974Trade Act and to negotiate with Japan in theframework of the MOSS (Market-Oriented, SectorSelective) talks. From the beginning the U.S.Government made it clear that it wanted an openmarket, not a few token procurements.

Negotiations did not get off to a good start. Inearly 1987, talks with MITI vice-minister KurodaMakoto were abruptly adjourned after a lunchmeeting in which Kuroda allegedly stated that theUnited States would have to nationalize Cray ormerge it with larger U.S. firms in order for it tosurvive in today’s world of large vertically inte-grated fins, and that no matter how much theUnited States tried, it would not be able to sellsupercomputers in Japan.248 A month later, onMarch 26, 1987, the Washington Post printed a copyof a U.S. Embassy cable regarding this allegedKuroda statement, which Kuroda immediately de-nied.249 Whether or not Kuroda really said this, thesentiment is echoed in Japanese language docu-ments that talk of Cray’s dependence on Japan formemory chips and suggest that Cray will beoverwhelmed by Japanese competition in the nextfew years.250

Japan responded immediately to the publicationof the alleged Kuroda statement by announcing thatNTT would purchase another Cray supercomputer.NTT, which was mostly government-owned, wasreported to have said that the government pressuredit to make this purchase to ease U.S.-Japan tradefriction. 251 This supercomputer, like the one NTThad purchased in 1986, was resold to Recruit.252 Thetwo Crays that NIT purchased and sold to Recruitwere token purchases; they did not signal a movetowards more open public markets.253 Ministry ofPosts and Telecommunications (MPT) MinisterNakayama reportedly explained in a Diet committeethat NTT’s purchase and resale of a Cray to Recruit‘‘was at a time when, as a policy to help U.S.-Japan

274 . Competing Economies: America, Europe, and the Pacific Rim

trade friction, we were searching for someplace [thatwould take the supercomputer off our hands].’’254

At the same time as this NTT announcement, theJapanese Government was hurrying to get approvalof an emergency budget to provide bigger budgetsfor the universities.255 Even before the allegedKuroda statement hit the newspapers, JapaneseGovernment officials knew the United States wasupset not just over supercomputers but also aboutsemiconductors-semiconductor trade friction wouldlead President Reagan to impose tariffs on someJapanese personal computers, power hand tools, andtelevisions in April 1987. In March 1987, MITIMinister Tamura told Prime Minister Nakasone thatif Japan bought a couple of the Cray-2s, it would bevery useful in alleviating trade friction.256 A formerU.S. Government official closely involved in negoti-ations on both semiconductors and supercomputerssaid that he received several calls from Japaneseofficials asking him if the United States would backoff retaliation over semiconductor trade if Japanbought more supercomputers.257

In October 1987, after the emergency budget wasapproved, MITI’s Agency of Industrial Science andTechnology (AIST) and the Tokyo Institute ofTechnology (TIT), a public institution, announcedthat they would each buy an American supercom-puter. The Japanese Government decided to havethem purchase one Cray Research machine and oneETA, the latter because they felt CDC, the parent ofETA, might complain if only Cray machines werepurchased. 258 The bidding was formally open butthere was no chance for Japanese companies to winthese bids because the emergency budget had beenapproved to alleviate U.S.-Japan trade friction.259 AMITI official acknowledged that TIT’s directedpurchase of an ETA machine was contradictory tothe principle of open competition that the U.S.-Japanagreement was to provide.260

With these two purchases the Japanese Govern-ment felt it had fulfilled its promise to procuresupercomputers. 261 U.S. officials, however, saw twotoken purchases rather than a free competitive bidprocess. CDC’s late delivery of its supercomputer,along with the machine’s failure to operate at thespeed promised, hurt the U.S. case.262 ‘ ‘The Ameri-cans never looked so foolish,’ said one Japaneseexpert.263 To this day TIT researchers vent theirfrustration at this CDC machine; CDC’s withdrawal

from the supercomputer business in 1989 onlyexacerbated their problem.

TIT researchers’ complaints were not the onlyones. Researchers in Japanese public sector labsvoiced concern that purchasing more expensiveforeign supercomputers would cut sharply into therest of their research budget.264 There was alsoconcern about foreign supercomputers’ compatibil-ity with existing mainframes and peripherals, espe-cially since Japanese supercomputer firms also mademainframes and peripherals while Cray Researchdid not.265

A formal agreement between the two countrieswas finalized in summer 1987 requiring that govern-ment institutions give full public notice of theirintentions to procure a machine. The agreement didnot deal with discounting; U.S. Government offi-cials involved in the negotiations say that the U.S.administration believed that by charging discountedprices, the Japanese firms would only be hurtingthemselves. The United States also knew that itwould be difficult to criticize Japanese supercom-puter makers for discounting when IBM was ac-tively discounting its mainframes for Japaneseuniversities. There was also concern that Europeancountries would object if the United States tried tolimit discounting on sales to third countries.

The agreement was not effective. Since Japan’smarket was now formally open and U.S. makerswere notified when public procurements would bemade, they had to make bids (a costly process) orelse look like they were not trying. But these bidswere useless because the Japanese makers were stillusing very heavy discounts, selection did not have tobe based on actual performance, and the Japaneseuniversities preferred Japanese machines because oflongstanding ties with companies.

The 1987 agreement did accomplish one thing: ithushed U.S. criticism for a time.266 This allowedJapanese supercomputer companies additional timeto improve their competitiveness. Other than the twoemergency budget procurements completed beforethe agreement, there were no more purchases of U.S.machines until the start of new negotiations onsupercomputer procurement in 1989.

The first public sector procurement after the 1987agreement-Tohoku University’s Large-Scale Cormputing Center’s decision to purchase a supercomput-er—is a good example of how the heavy discounts

Chapter 4-Japanese Industrial Policy: The Postwar Record and the Case of Supercomputers .275

work. The bid was for a machine to replace theCenter’s NEC SX-1 model, so it was expected thatNEC would win the bid; Cray nonetheless made abid since the market was now officially open. NECbid the SX-2 and Cray the Y-MP-832. The first bidwas made in June 1988, with NEC offering amonthly price of Y48 million against Cray’s bid ofY74.739 million. NEC appeared to have an unbeata-ble advantage, but instead of awarding NEC thecontract, the university asked for a second round ofbids trying to get a better discount. NEC cut its bidto Y40.1 million and Cray cut its slightly to Y74.73million. When the university asked for a third round,Cray dropped out. The university did not give NECthe contract until the eighth round of bids. The finalprice was V14.6 million, a 70-percent cut fromNEC’s original bid and a 90-percent discount fromthe original list price.267 The person in charge of theuniversity’s procurement said “to have to rebid isnatural not just for computers; even making eightbids is not necessarily too many.”268 These lowprices are possible for Japanese companies becauseof government aid to the industry and because thefirms can funnel mainframe and semiconductorprofits to support their supercomputer business. Butto Cray, these are “market-shattering” prices,explained Jonathan Streeter of the Department ofCommerce. 269 In numerous interviews with Japa-nese Government officials and industry people, allagreed that Japan’s supercomputer makers are losingmoney on their supercomputers but that they aregoing for long-term market share rather than imme-diate profits. ‘‘We don’t need to make a profit on ourline of supercomputers,’ admits Watanabe Tadashi,the major architect of NEC supercomputers; “what-ever is spun off from our supercomputer R&D helpsin other information-technology fields. ’ ’270

The Tohoku University case is not an exception.In 1988, Hitachi won a bid to Hokkaido University’sLarge-Scale Computing Center but only after fiverebids, for a monthly rental price of Y15.75 million;the list price was Y89 million a month; including theperipherals and application software, the discountwas between 80 and 90 percent.271 A similar casewas the Japan Railways Technical Research Insti-tute (RTRI) purchase of an NEC supercomputer in1988. Cray was interested in the procurement but‘‘withdrew when RTRI demanded an 80 percentdiscount,” explained Yoshikazu Hori, President ofCray Research’s subsidiary in Japan.272

By early 1989 the United States, realizing that theagreement was not having its intended effect, startedto consider targeting supercomputers under Super301 of the 1988 Omnibus Trade and Competitive-ness Act. This Act required the USTR to identify thehighest priority offenders among countries thatunfairly restrict the sales of U.S. goods and services,to investigate the practices involved, and to negoti-ate to eliminate the market barriers. If the barrierswere not removed, sanctions could be applied (seech. 4).

Trade friction between the United States andJapan worsened when in April 1989 NEC announcedthat Japan’s frost 4 CPU machine, the SX-3, wouldbe coming out soon. That machine had a theoreticalpeak speed of 22 gigaflops, far faster than anyother.273 Soon thereafter, CDC withdrew from thesupercomputer business, and the United States’competitive position deteriorated. MITI reportedlyscolded NEC, saying “Why are you irritating theUnited States by announcing a new advanced seriesof supercomputers] at a time when they are thinkingabout invoking Super 301 against Japan?’ ’274 NECthen announced that it had decided to increase its useof U.S.-made semiconductors in its SX-3 series ofsupercomputers to help alleviate U.S.-Japan fictionover supercomputers.275 It didn’t work.

In late May 1989, the U.S. Government listedJapan under Super 301; in June it started investigat-ing Japanese practices regarding supercomputers,wood products, and satellites. In this second set ofsupercomputer negotiations, the United States madeit clear that it wanted to deal with the heavydiscounting of supercomputers. Right after the U.S.announcement, MITI reportedly advised computermakers to keep their supercomputer discounts under50 percent, although bigger discounts on main-frames were okay.276

The first Japanese public sector supercomputerprocurement after these negotiations began (butbefore they were concluded) was the purchase of aFujitsu machine by the National AstronomicalLaboratory to replace its existing Fujitsu. The onlybidder was Fujitsu, which offered a 60-percentdiscount off the list price for a system of 134machines, including 3 mainframes, engineeringworkstations, and other equipment. Fujitsu wascareful, however, to keep the discount on thesupercomputer within the 50-percent limit and togive the entire product a 60-percent discount by

276 . Competing Economies: America, Europe, and the Pacific Rim

discounting the mainframe parts of the system more

heav i l y .2 7 7

Soon after, in early December 1989, Fujitsu won

a bid for the Japan Atomic Energy Research Institutewith a 25-percent discount off list price, a level thatthe government suggested would allow the firms toescape U.S. displeasure.

278 But this and subsequent“smaller” discounts were the result of Japanese

companies cutting their list prices in order to make

their discounts appear smaller (table 6-12). For

example, in October 1989 NEC dropped the list

price of its new SX-3 series machines by 35.279 Fujitsu and Hitachi had already loweredpercent,

their list prices by 20 to 35 Percent.280 When Fujitsu

won the Japan Atomic Energy Research Institute

procurement after lowering its list prices to give a

lower discount, MITI Minister Matsunaga said that

“Fujitsu’s drop in list price is the result of the

operation of competitive market forces.” 28l T h i s

25-percent discount was a 53-percent discount over

the previous list price: the two Fujitsu VP26OO-10

supercomputers purchased had an original list price

of Y80 million a month each, but had been dropped

to Y50 million a month; the final bid was Y37.389

million a month.282 The United States complained

that dropping the list prices just made it look like a

smaller discount and was in no way a solution to theproblem, 283 but no further changes have been made.

Before the 1990 agreement was finalized, TohokuUniversity decided to buy a Cray machine for itsFluid Dynamics Research Lab. Formally, this was afirst installation for the lab, but the researchers hadbeen using the university Computing Center’s NECmachine, so everyone expected NEC to win the bid.But NEC suddenly withdrew, citing government

pressure aimed at easing U.S.-Japan trade prob-

l e m s .2 8 4

This strategy worked. A draft of the agreementwas finalized in late March, and the U.S. administra-tion did not target Japan for a second year underSuper 301. The agreement was formally signed onJune 15, 1990, a day before USTR would have beenrequired to make a recommendation regardingsanctions.

There was a consensus among the Japaneseministries to do the agreement to protect the U. S.-Japan relationship. SII [the Structural ImpedimentsInitiative Talks] did not go well. Trade figures were

bad. It was crisis management. The United Statesthreatened retaliation under Super 301; without thatthreat, many ministries would not have gone along,

explained an official of the Ministry of Foreign

Affairs involved in the negotiations.285

The primary difference between the 1987 and

1990 agreements is that the latter requires real

performance criteria, not just theoretical peak per-

formance data, to be used and that discounts be

Table 6-12-List Purchase and Rental Prices of Japanese Supercomputers

Old monthly Old monthly Date ofrental price rental price Percent of price

Vendor Model (yen) (yen) reduction reduction

Fujitsu . . . . . . . . . . . VP-200E-2100/10-2100/20-2200/10-2200/20-2400/10-2400/20-2600/10-2600/20

Hitachi . . . . . . . . . . . S-820/20-820/40-820/60-820/80

NEC . . . . . . . . . . . . . SX-3/11-3/12-3/14-3/22-3/24-3/42-3/44

Y56.oM38.059.050.077.064.091.080.0

170.0Y38.0M

50.062.089.0

Y52.OM64.077.096.0

112.0140.0170.0

Y45.00M24.9539.0532.8050.6040.0057.8050.0067.80

Y27.60M35.6044.7066.40

Y34.00M42.0050.0062.0073.0091.00

111.00

19.6%34.333.834.434.337.536.537.536.627.428.827.925.434.634.435.435.434.835.034.7

May 1989Dec. 1989Dec. 1989Dec. 1989Dec. 1989Dec. 1989Dec. 1989Dec. 1989Dec. 1989Oct. 1989Oct. 1989Oct. 1989Oct. 1989Oct. 1989Oct. 1989Oct. 1989Oct. 1989Oct. 1989Oct. 1989Oct. 1989

SOURCE: Nikkei Computer, Mar. 26, 1990, p. 97.

Chapter 6--Japanese Industrial Policy: The Postwar Record and the Case of Supercomputers ● 277

limited. In this regard, the agreement is an improve-ment. But virtually everyone agrees that the secondagreement, like the first, is deeply flawed. First, theagreement may very well strengthen the Japanesesupercomputer makers. MITI and the firms arehappy with the agreement because it is better for thefirms not to have to discount their machines somuch. “Because discounts are only 20 to 30 percentnow, the firms make more money, ’ stated aMinistry of Foreign Affairs official closely involvedin the negotiations.286 Before the agreement wassigned, a spokesman for a maker said, ‘‘there wouldbe nothing better for us than to be able to sell oursupercomputers at list price.”287

Another problem with the agreement concernsreciprocity. As a strictly legal matter, reciprocity isnot an issue. The agreement was intended to remedyJapan’s violation of the GATT Procurement Code;Japan has not complained of any U.S. violation, sothere is no need for the United States to change itsprocurement practices. While the United States hasrefused to buy Japanese supercomputers for defensepurposes (e.g., for defense research at the nationallaboratories and in defense applications at NASAfacilities), that does not violate the Code, whichexempts defense purchases.

However, most U.S. Government supercomputerprocurement is for defense purposes, and Japancould ask on grounds of fairness that the UnitedStates open that market for Japanese machines.Watanabe Tadashi, the chief architect of NEC’ssupercomputers, says, “The U.S. Government hasn’tbought a single Japanese supercomputer; now youtell me who’s being unfair.”288 Fujitsu chairmanYamamoto Takuma agrees that the United States isunfair in calling on the Japanese Government to buy

U.S. supercomputers when the U.S. Government

does not buy Japanese machines: “We do not intend

to crush them under our feet; nothing can be gained

by doing that. That is why Fujitsu has always tied up

with a ~. S.] partner, and we will continue this

strategy in the future.”289

The Japanese not only see the lack of reciprocity

as a problem, they also see the United States as

having a double standard on discounts. Japan argues

that the United States is complainingg about Japanesedumping of supercomputers because Cray Research,a relatively small one-product company, cannotafford to sell its machines at such low prices.290

Even if the agreement were perfect, however, itwould be hard to overcome the effects of pastpreferential procurements. Public institutions withJapanese supercomputers in place would normallywish to replace their machines with an upgradedmodel from the same maker. “The most significantpart of the agreement is for frost installations.Japanese first-time buyers will be able to choose thebest company,’ explained Jonathan Streeter of theU.S. Department of Commerce.291

The agreement’s usefulness to U.S. manufactur-ers is also limited by university budgets; with higherprices, probably fewer machines will be bought.Total budgets for universities rise at only 10 percenta year (or less); thus, sharp increases in expenditureson supercomputers would require cutting anotherpart of the budget. The fact that six public sectorlabs, four of which are universities, have delayedsupercomputer procurements originally planned for1990292 suggests that the kind of governmentfunding the U.S. Government and Cray Research arehoping for will not be forthcoming in the near future.Indeed, Japanese public procurement has plungedfrom 12 and 11 machines in 1986 and 1987,respectively, to 8,4, and 6 in 1988, 1989, and 1990.

The Japanese and U.S. Governments are publiclycalling the 1990 agreement a success. ‘‘The TohokuUniversity procurement is the first application of the1990 agreement. It is an example of the success of the talks. Cray’s success is not artificial, ratherCray’s machine fits the needs of Tohoku Univer-sity,” stated Kawamura Yasuhisa, a Ministry ofForeign Affairs official involved in the negotia-tions. 293 A few days after Tohoku University de-cided on a Cray, Kyoto University decided on aFujitsu for a replacement machine of the same brand.“After the 1987 agreement there were no Craypurchases in the public market, and after the 1990agreement there have been two purchases, one ofwhich was a Cray. Cray has a 50-percent marketshare of purchases made after the agreement,’explained this same official.294

It has cost Cray Research a total of $158.1 millionto develop the Cray-1, Cray-2, and Cray X-MP andY-MP models; the company estimates that the C90machine currently being developed will cost $100million.295 Had Japan’s market been open, Craymight have afforded more R&D. As discussed, itseems reasonable to assume that the 20 Japanesemachines sold to the private sector were inferior to

278 . Competing Economies: America, Europe, and the Pacific Rim

available U.S. machines. This is also true for the 21Japanese machines sold to the public sector through1986. Thus, had supercomputers been selected onquality alone, the U.S. firms would have made 41additional sales. But price is also a factor. The U.S.machines would have been much more expensive topublic sector customers. Again, assuming the cus-tomers would have paid the higher prices, Cray andETA would have sold 41 more machines. Withsubsequent upgrades, the total would be 56. Basedon historical market share,296 about 52 of these saleswould have gone to Cray, the remainder to ETA.Cray’s X-MP series available at the time was pricedbetween $7 and $20 million, with the higher pricedmodels selling the most. If the 56 machines cost anaverage of $13 million each (a conservative esti-mate), this would have meant $676 million inrevenue for Cray. Cray invests about 15 percent ofrevenues in R&D each year, so this would havemeant $100 million in extra R&D, which could havehelped fund a whole new generation of supercom-puters.297

OTHER FACTORSCONTRIBUTING TO JAPAN’SSUCCESS IN NURTURING A

DOMESTIC SUPERCOMPUTERINDUSTRY

Industry and Corporate Structure

Japan’s targeting and procurement policieshelped Hitachi, Fujitsu, and NEC to build theirsupercomputer business, but the policies were notsolely responsible for the companies’ successes. Inpart, their success is related to the ways in whichJapanese corporations are organized and run.298

Japan also created apolitical and economic environ-ment that fostered corporate arrangements givingJapanese companies advantages in internationalcompetition. The state’s encouragement of interfirmcooperation on dimensions such as price, produc-tion, and R&D; government encouragement of thereemergence of industrial groups after World War II;and its centralized control over financial capital haveled to the emergence of large, vertically integratedfirms making supercomputers. All of them aremiembers of Japan’s large industrial groups.299

In targeting specific industries, the JapaneseGovernment has usually given priority to such fins.In mainframe computers and in telecommunica-

tions, MITI and NTT have consistently favoredFujitsu, Hitachi, and NEC. “MITI promotes thelarger, more stable, more promising fins, ” statedTakashi Harumi, Director of International ResearchExchange at MITI.300

Vertical integration gives Japanese firms makingsupercomputers several advantages. It allows themto cross-subsidize among divisions, using profitsfrom healthy divisions to fund new areas such assupercomputers, and to keep divisions such assemiconductors alive despite their sharp boom-bustcycles. Second, it provides them with a relativelystable internal market, which affords greater abilityto experiment with high speed integrated circuitsthat they can use in-house. Third, it provides anassured supply of components. For example, in 1988and 1989, when semiconductor prices increasedrapidly, U.S. computer and systems makers werescrambling to obtain enough memory chips that onlyJapanese firms produce in volume; Japanese makerswere not similarly vulnerable. Finally, makingproduction equipment in-house allows the Japanesefirms to tailor-make production processes for theirspecific products, giving them a competitive edge.301

Japan’s institutional environment encourages Jap-anese managers to view industries as belonging to aninterdependent chain with valuable skill and knowl-edge spillovers for one another. Unlike their U.S.counterparts, Japanese companies do not necessarilystop making a product or bail out of a given industrysolely because it does not provide as high a profit asinvestment of those same resources in anotherindustry would. DRAMS are an example. Japanesecompanies regard the skills involved in producingDRAMS as important for other electronics compo-nents and systems; even if DRAMS are not inthemselves highly profitable, they make a criticalcontribution to the bottom line in other ways that areless visible, though no less important. “The U.S. isgoing backwards in developing the componentsneeded to make supercomputers. We want to makemoney and there is not a lot of money in thosecomponents, says Sidney Fernbach, a U.S. super-computer expert.302

The view of many Japanese businesses of theinterdependence of the different electronics indus-tries is reflected in a statement by Ota Hideo ofMitsubishi: “We are not thinking of loss or profitjust for computers, but for the whole company. Andwe use computers in all our businesses. When we

Chapter 6-Japanese Industrial Policy: The Postwar Record and the Case of Supercomputers ● 279

cannot follow computer technology, we will be introuble all over. ’’303

There are heavy costs associated with this verticalintegration and diversification; these high costs arepart of the reason why several U.S. electronics firmsthat were vertically integrated and diversified in the1960s and 1970s, such as Motorola, General Elec-tric, and RCA, narrowed their focus to a fewdivisions and products. But Japanese firms are betterable to bear these costs because of an environmentthat encourages long-term investment.

Japanese Industrial Enterprise Groups

Deep pockets are also the result of other institu-tional arrangements that help buffer Japanese firmsmaking supercomputers from international competi-tion and short-term market fluctuations. In particu-lar, the fact that Fujitsu, NEC, and Hitachi are allmembers of or allied with keiretsu is an advantage.The U.S. Occupation had partially dismantled thesegroups, but by the late 1950s, the groups wererebuilding with government encouragement. A keymotivation of both the firms and the government wasthat the groups would help keep out foreign productsand investments at a time when Japan was underincreasing pressure to liberalize its markets.

There are several advantages to membership in akeiretsu. These groups hold shares in other compa-nies that are group members and agree not to sellthem. This practice is known as mutual sharehold-ing. In addition, large Japanese firms have stableshareholders, non-group firms who hold a com-pany’s stock and do not trade it. This combination ofstable and mutual shareholding means that about 60to 80 percent of member fins’ stocks are nevertraded. 304 Thus managers do not have to worry abouttakeovers or short-term fluctuations in their stockprices; they have more latitude than U.S. managersto focus on long-term goals.

Second, these groups provide their members withsomewhat of an assured market. This is particularlyimportant when a fro’s products are not yetcompetitive. As mentioned earlier, as of 1968 abouthalf of the mainframe computers being used by firmsin the industrial groups were made by their keiretsucomputer firm.305 Among firms with keiretsu ties tosupercomputer makers, 56 percent of purchases (18of 32, see table 6-11) were from the affiliate. Manyargue that these groups are the most potent forceprotecting the Japanese market today. Their control

over a significant share of Japanese business306

raises barriers to entry-in many cases bars entry—to foreign firm in many major industries.

Third, these groups are centered around mainbanks, which helps group members get relativelyeasy access to capital; until recently, that also meantlow-cost capital. Banks help out member companiesduring hard times.307 The close ties between Japa-nese companies and their main banks are lessimportant today, when so many Japanese companiesare enjoying unprecedented success and marketpower, but it was very important in the 1960s and1970s and is still important for firms involved inrisky ventures such as supercomputers.

UNITED STATES POLICIESTOWARD THE SUPERCOMPUTER

INDUSTRYConsistent with their concern for the decline in

U.S. competitiveness in supercomputers, most com-puter scientists and industry people, and manypolicymakers believe that the U.S. Governmentshould support the industry more thoroughly. TheU.S. Government had and still has an important rolein the development and competitiveness of thesupercomputer industry in America, though that roleis far smaller than that of the Japanese governmentpast and present. The primary forms of support theU.S. Government offers are procurement and thecontributions of national laboratories and NASA indeveloping software. Procurement, in particular, islikely to diminish in value. While defense-relatedsupercomputer purchases have been and will proba-bly remain closed to foreign firms, other Federalprocurements are open to foreign competition. As ofmid-1991 Japanese supercomputer makers had notwon any sales. However, as the Japanese firms catchup in performance and software, they are more likelyto do SO.

The U.S. Government funnels some $500 millioninto advanced computing each year through theNational Science Foundation (NSF), NASA, theDepartment of Defense, and the Department ofEnergy. 308 But there is growing agreement amongsupercomputer experts that it is not doing enough.‘‘It could be too late unless we act and act forcefully;our infrastructure is going fast and the rest will godown with it,” argued one supercomputer ana-lyst.309

280 ● Competing Economies: America, Europe, and the Pacific Rim

One proposal for increased government support isthe Federal High Performance Computing Program,presented to Congress in 1989, which called for anadditional $1.917 billion in U.S. Government fi-nancing of research related to advanced computingtechnologies over a 5-year period.310 The programhas four parts. The first, high-performance comput-ing systems, would provide Federal support for basicresearch in high-performance computer technology(including massively parallel systems) and its trans-fer to industry; in addition, this part of the programcalls for the Department of Energy, NASA, and theDefense Advanced Research Projects Agency (DARPA),to continue to acquire the first production models ofnew high-performance computers. The second part,advanced software technology and algorithms, wouldencourage joint research (government, industry, anduniversity) to improve the basic tools, languages,algorithms and associated theory for solving verycomplex, large-scale problems in science and tech-nology, or the so-called Grand Challenges. TheOffice of Science and Technology Policy (OSTP)listed the following as examples of Grand Chal-lenges:

prediction of weather, climate, and globalchange;challenges in materials science (including sem-iconductor materials);semiconductor design;superconductivity;structural biology, including the structure andfunction of biologically important molecules;design of drugs;human genome mapping;quantum chromodynamics;astronomy, including manipulation of datagathered by Very Large Array or Very LongBaseline Array radiotelescopes;challenges in transportation, including model-ing of airflows around aircraft, inside engines,and around ship hulls;reduction of vehicle signatures for low detec-tion military vehicles;vehicle dynamics;nuclear fusion;efficiency of combustion systems;enhanced oil and gas recovery;computational ocean sciences, including devel-opment of a global ocean prediction modelincorporating temperature, chemical composi-

The

tion, circulation and coupling to the atmos-phere;speech as a communications interface withcomputers;machine vision; andundersea surveillance for anti-submarine war-fare.

third part of the High Performance ComputingProgram is the national research and educationnetwork, providing distributed computing that linksthe governmental research, industry, and highereducation communities. The network, using fiber-optic trunks now being installed by communica-tions carriers, will incorporate new switching sys-tems and network protocols to support interactivegraphics, nationwide data files, and high-definitiondisplays. The fourth part is for basic research andhuman resources, supporting basic research in com-puter science and improved computational scienceeducation in universities.311 For fiscal year 1991, theprogram received $489 million and was carried outby eight agencies,312 with 71 percent coming fromDARPA and NSF. In fiscal year 1992, the proposedbudget is $638 million, with 69 percent fromDARPA and NSF.313

Many computer scientists, industry executives,independent analysts, and policymakers argue thatthe U.S. Government needs to support more than thisproject if it is to stem the erosion of U.S. competi-tiveness in supercomputers and other high-technology areas, and that the focus needs to be onsupporting commercial applications. Only in thisway, they suggest, can supercomputer companiescompete with Japanese companies and avoid de-pendence on Japanese suppliers in the long term. Inthe past several years, some U.S. high-technologycompanies have reported delays of supplies of eithercomponents or machinery from their Japanese sources.Complaints have become so numerous that theGeneral Accounting Office has recently startedexploring them.314 While these U.S. companies tendto believe that delaying or withholding parts isunfair, it makes good sense for a company to supplyitself and its related companies first, then its bestdomestic customers, and finally its overseas ones; itis neither unwise nor unfair to delay delivery ofstrategic components or machinery to competitors.

Because Crays are widely regarded in the UnitedStates as superior, and have a much larger library ofsoftware, there have been few procurements of

Chapter 6-Japanese Industrial Policy: The Postwar Record and the Case of Supercomputers ● 281

Japanese machines in the private sector; Fujitsu hassold two machines to the U.S. subsidiary of France’sSchlumberger, but other than that the only procure-ment of a Japanese supercomputer was that of anNEC machine by the Houston Area Research Centerin 1986, a center closely connected to NEC’s U.S.supercomputer subsidiary, HNSX. More Japanesemachines will undoubtedly sell in the private sector,for they are getting faster and already are veryreliable. The financial resources of the Japanesecompanies leave little doubt as to their stayingpower in the industry; there is more doubt amongU.S. supercomputer experts as to Cray’s ability tostand up to this kind of competition in the long run(it should be noted that officials of Cray do notregard their company as endangered). As a result,public procurement in the United States is still animportant issue.

Most experts agree that the U.S. Government’ssupercomputer procurement has been a key factorencouraging the growth of the supercomputer indus-try here, and the government remains a key cus-tomer. In the beginning, only U.S. companies madesupercomputers, and developments in high-performance computing were tied to the needs ofresearchers in government labs. Most governmentpurchases are still by institutions that use themachines for military purposes at least part of thetime (national laboratories and NASA, for example),and it is consistent with the GATT ProcurementCode for any Government to maintain an absolutepreference for domestic goods in such purchases. Inaddition, many scientists in institutions that use thesupercomputers feel that their support is necessaryto keep Cray Research alive; although many wouldprefer that there were additional U.S. competitors,they do not want the field narrowed only to Japanesecompanies.

This opinion is not universally shared. Some U.S.supercomputer specialists argue that the U.S. Gov-ernrnent should not protect U.S. supercomputermakers; rather it should protect the right of research-ers to have access to the latest and most technologi-cally sophisticated research tools.315 ‘User access tosupercomputers is more important than the super-computer industry itself; it is more important thatU.S. petroleum, aerospace, and automobile firmshave access to the best tools [supercomputers] thanthat Cray Research continues to exist.’’316 LarrySmarr, director of the National Center for Supercom-puting Applications, adds that using national secu-

rity considerations as a reason for barring Japanesecompetitors is contradictory and self-defeating.“Just count the number of Crays and IBM vectormachines the Japanese manufacturers can study inJapan compared to the number of their supercomput-ers that we have access to in the United States. If theJapanese firms are truly our competitors, it wouldbenefit us greatly to know everything we can abouttheir design capabilities. The oldest rule in the bookis to ‘Know your enemy. ’ ‘’317 Whether reliance solely on Japanese companies would eventually costU.S. supercomputer users their ability to get firstcrack at the fastest, newest machines is a matter ofdisagreement among specialists.

Export control policy is another issue. Getting alicense for exports of high-performance computersis often time consuming and difficult, and that canput Japanese companies at an advantage in selling inforeign markets. For small (relative to Hitachi,Fujitsu, and NEC) U.S. companies like Cray Re-search, streamlinin“ “ g the export licensing process asmuch as possible, consistent with national security,would be a big help. Since the first installation isparticularly important in the case of selling super-computers, speed in making changes to exportcontrol policy is also important to Cray. Third-country markets are growing fast and if U.S. makersmiss out on these markets today, it could diminishtheir income stream far into the future.

1 This chapter is drawn extensively from two contractor reports:Marie Anchordoguy, “The Nature and Effectiveness of Japan’s PostwarIndustrial Policy,” contractor report for the Office of llxhnologyAssessment, February 1991; and Marie Anchordoguy, “JapanesePolicies for the Supercomputer Industry,” contractor report for theOffice of llxhnology Assessment, February 1991.

2 These include hardwor~goodand universal educatio~f~cialpolicies tbat embled Japanese firms to invest heavily and patiently intechnology acquisition development and diffusiom and vigorous, if notfree and ope~ competition.

3 The top me~hant f-es were later to become the zaibatsu,some of which persist today in the form of keir-etsu, or industrial groups.

4 ‘Ibssa Morns-Suzu@ A History of Japanese Economt”c Thought(lmdon: Nissan Institute for Japanese Studies, 1989), p. 62.

5 Edward J. LincolrL Japan’s Unequal Trade (Washingto~ DC:The Brookings Institutiorq 1990), pp. 5-6.

6 See for example, Marie Anchordoguy, Computers Inc: Japan’sChallenge to EM (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1989);and Phyllis A. Genther, “A History of Japan’s Government-BusinessRelationship: The Passenger Car Industry,” Michigan Papers inJapanese Studies No. 20 (Ann lwbor, MI: Center for Japanese Studies,University of Michigtuq 1990).

7 See, for example, Paul R. Km= “’lhrgeted IndustrialPolicies: Theory and Evidence,’ The New Protectionist Threat to WorldWe~are, Dominick Salvatore (cd.) (New York, NY: North HollandPress, 1987), pp. 266-296.

292-889 0 - 91 - 10 QL:3

282 . Competing Economies: America, Europe, and the Pacific Rim

8 See, for example, Giovanni Dosi, Laura D’Andrea ~som andJohn Zysman+ “Trade, Technologies, and Development: A Frameworkfor Discussing JapU” Politics and Productivity: How Japan’sDevelopment Strategy Works, Chalmers Johnson, Laura D’Andrea~SO~ and John Zysman (eds.) (Cambridge, MA: Ballinger, 1989), pp.3-38.

9 A representative sampling of these three views is the followingthree sources: Chalmers Johnsoq MITI and the Japanese Miracle(Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press, 1987); Richard Samuels, TheBw”ness of the Japanese State (ltbacq NY: Cornell University Press,1987); and Karel Van Wolfereu The Enigma of Japanese Power (NewYor& NY: Alfred Knopf, 1989).

10 See, for example, Charles Schultz, “Industrial Policy: ADissen~” The Brookings Review, fall 1983, and “Industrial Policy: ASolution in Search of a Probl~” California Management Review,summer 1983; Komiya Ryutam and Kazutomo Irie, “The U.S.-JapanTrade Problan: An Economic Analysis from a Japanese Viewpoin4°Japan’ sEconon”c Structure: Should it Change?, Kozo Yamam ura (cd.)(Seattle, WA: Society for Japanese Studies, 1990) pp. 65-104; GarySaxonhouse, “Why Japan is Wirmin g,’ Is~es in Science and Technol-ogy, spring 1986, pp. 72-80; and Hugh Patrick “Japanese High‘lkchnology Industrial Policy in Comparative Contex4° Japan’s HighTechnology Industries, Hugh Patrick (cd.) (Seattle, WA: University ofWashington Press, 1986), pp. 3-33.

11 See, for example, Robert Z. Lawrence, “Imports in Japan:Closed Markets or Minds?,” Brookings Papers on Econondc Activity,No. 2,1987, pp. 5 17-548; RudigerDombuscb “Give Japana Target andSay ‘Import! ’,” The New York Times, Sept. 24, 1989; “MisguidedEfforts Won’t Open Japan’s Marke6° The Japan Economic Journal,Dee. 16, 1989, p. 9; and Mordechai E. K-rein@ “How Closed is Japan’sMarket? Additional Evidence,” The World Economy, vol. 11, no. 4,December 1988, pp. 529-542.

12 See Paul R. Krugman, “Introduction: New Thinkhg AboutTrade Policy,” and James A. Brander, “Rationales for Strategic Tradeand Industrial Policy,” Paul R. Krugman (cd.), Strategic Trade Policyand the New International Economics (Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press,1986), pp. 1-46.

13 Robert J. Ballon and Iwao ‘Rnn@ The Financial Behaw”or ofJapanese Corporations (Tokyo: Kodansha I.nternatio@ 1988), p. 37.

14 Nakamura ~ The Postwar Japanese Economy, ItsDevelopment and Structure, Jacqueline Kamins@“ translator (Tokyo:lbkyo University Press, 1981), p. 44.

15 See, for example, Johusom op. cit.; and Anchordoguy, Comput-ers Inc.: Japan’s Challenge to IBM, op. cit.

16 Genther, op. cit., p. 23.17 Genther, op. cit., p. 80.

18 Genther, op. cit., pp. 81-82.

19 Merton J. Peck and Shuji llunw “lkchnology,” in Asia’sNew Giant, Hugh Patrick and Henry Rosovslg (eds.) (Washington DC:The Brookings Institution 1976), p. 152.

20 Genther, op. cit., p. 47.

21 Genther, op. cit., p. 70.

22 This was done in the Extraordinary Measures Laws for thePromotion of the Machinery and Electronics Industries of 1956 and 1957and their subsequent extensions.

23 JohnsoL op. cit., p, 174.

24 Japan also accepted obligations under Article 14 of G~,which specified no subsidies of exports. See Johnsou op. cit., p. 263.

25 Johnso~ op. cit., p. 210.

26 Johnso~ op. cit., p. 211.

27 Nomura Research Institute, NIR Review, February 1991. The1990 figure was a projection the 1989 figure was 32.3 trillion yen.

28 “Postal Savings Deposits Set Monthly Record,” The JapanTimes, Jan. 10,1990, p. 9; and Ministry of Finance, The Budget in Bri#,1988, Budget Bureaq 1989, p. 66.

29 Marcus W. Brauchli, “BanksFeudwithP ostal Service inJapanover Citicorp Proposal,” The Wall Street Journal, Sept. 22, 1988, p. 35;and personal communication Marie Anchordoguy with local post officein JaparL January 1991.

30 Koichi Hamada and Akiyoshi Horiucl@ “The Political Econ-omy of the Financial hlarke~’ in Kozo Yamamura and YasukichiYasuba (eds.), The PoliticalEconomy ofJapan, Volume 1: The DomesticTransformation (Stanford, CA: Stanford Univemity Press, 1987), pp.223-260.

31 Daniel I. Okimoto, Between MIT’I and the Market: JapaneseIndusm”al Policy for High Technology (Stanforq CA: Stanford Univer-sity Press, 1989), p. 150.

32 Ibid., p. 77.

33 Leonard Lynq How Japan Innovates: A Comparison with theU.S. in the Case of Oxygen Steehnaking (Boulder, CO: Westiew Press,1982), p. 145.

34 Ibid., pp. 4546.

35 Yamawaki Hideki, “’lkkko Gyo,” (The Steel Industry), inNihon no Sangyo Seisaku, Komiya Ryutaro, Okuno Masatatsu andSuzumura Kotaro (eds.) (Tokyo: lbkyo University Press, 1984), pp.258,263.

36 Nihon Kaihatsu Ginko25Nenshi (llventy-five YearHistory ofthe Japan Development Bank) (’Iokyo: Japan Development B* 1976),p. 537.

37 BOF technology was pioneered in Austria in the early 1950s,and in the succeeding thee decades came to account for the majority ofthe world’s mass-produced carbon steel. Its advantages over the openhearth technology that preceded it were that it offered economies of scalein integrated steel mills, had lower energy costs, took much less time toheat the iroq and was generally more cost-effective. See Luc Kiers, TheAmerican Steel Industry: Problems, Challenges, Perspectives (Boulder,CO: Westview Press, 1980), pp. 19-20 and Bela Gold, GerhardRosegger and Myles G. Boyw Jr., Evaluating Technological Innova-tions (bdngtou MA: Lexington Books, 1980), pp. 120121.

38 LymL op. cit., p. 83.

39 LymL op. cit., pp. 84-85.

40 Peck and l%rn~ Op. cit., pp. 556-558.

41 In such industries, fii lose less money by cutting prices thanby idling mills, since fixed costs accrue whether or not productionoccurs.

42 See, for example, Patricia A. O’Briem “Coordinating MarketForces: The Anatomy of Investment Decisions in the Japanese SteelIndustry, 1945 -1975,” dissertation from the Harvard Business School1986, p. 268.

43 Okimoto, op. cit., p. 37.

44 See, for example, Okimoto, op. cit., pp. 38-48; Imai Kenic@“Iron and Steel: Industrial Organization” in Japanese Econonu”cStudies (White Plains, NY: International Arts and Sciences Press, Inc.,winter 1974-75); and Yamawaki, Op. Cit.

45 Walter Adams, “The Steel Industry,” in The Structure ofAmerican Industry, Walter Mama (cd.) (lNew York NY: MacmW“anPublishing Company, 1977, fti edition), p. 117; and Tekko Jukyo noUgoh” (Trends in the Supply of and Demand for Steel) (T@o: KozaiKurabu) quarterly repom various issues.

46 Yamaw@ Op. cit., p. 281.47 Tsuruta lbshimasa , Sengo Nihon no Sangyo Seisaku &dustrial

Policy in Post-War Japan) (Tbkyo: Nihon Keizai Sbimbunsk 1982), p.49.

48 ‘l’he Long lkrm Credit Bank of Jap~ Shuyo Sangyo Sengo 25

Chapter 4-Japanese Industrial Policy: The Postwar Record and the Case of Supercomputers ● 283

Nenshi (Twenty-five Year History of Major Industries in the PostwarPeriod) (’1’bkyo: Kurihara Shigeo, 1972), pp. 361-364.

49 Imai, op. cit., pp. 52-53.50 Seiritsu OguraandNaoyu.ki Yoshino, “The’llu System and the

Fiscal Investment and tian progrm” in Ryutaro Korniy% ~“ookuno, and Kotaro S uzurnura (eds.), Industrial Policy of Japan (Tbkyo:Academic Press, Inc, 1988), pp. 127-132.

51 Yamawaki, op. cit., p. 286.

52 Yamawaki, op. cit., p. 136.

53 Motoshige Itoh and Kazuham Kiyono, “Foreign Trade andDirect Investment” in Komiya et al. (c&.), op. cit., p. 161.

54 Paul R. KrugmaIL “Targeted Industrial Policies: Theory andEvidence,’ op. cit., pp. 283-288.

55 Ibid., p. 289.

56 Hitachi, Fujitsu and NEC are among the world’s mostsuccessful and competitive corporations, yet they have profits as apercent of sales in the 2-4 percent range.

57 Kiyoshi Kawahito, The Japanese Steel Industry (New YorkNY: Praeger Publishers, 1972), p. 48.

58 The foUowing summary of prewar motor vehicle industrialpromotion is drawn from Genther, op. cit., pp. 15-39 passim.

59 Hiroya Ueno and Hiromichi Muto, “Japan’s AutomobileIndustry,” in Japanese Economic Studies (White Plains, NY: Interna-tional Arts and Sciences Press, Inc., fall 1974), pp. 12-13.

60 See ibid., p. 12; and C.S. Chang, The Japanese Auto Industryand the U.S. Market (New Yorlq NY: Praeger Publishers, 1981), p. 47.

61 Oenther, op. cit., pp. 52-55.

62 Genther, op. cit., pp. 55-64.

63 Hiromichi Muto, “The Automotive Industry,” in Komiy~ et.al. (eds.) op. cit., pp. 310-313.

64 Muto, op. cit., p. 313.

65 Muto, op. cit., pp. 314-315.

66 See, for example, Eugene KaplaIL Japan: The Government-Bu”ness Relationship (Washington DC: U.S.Govemment PrintingOffice, 1972); Tenkati” no Jidbsha Sangyo (liming Point in the AutoIndustry), MITI Kikai Joho Sangyo@oku Jidoshaka (cd.) (lbkyo:Nikkan Kogyo Shimbunsha, 1976), pp. 89-91; Nihon no Jidosha Kogyo(Japan’s Auto Industry), MITI Jukogyokyolm Jidoshaka (ext.) (l@o:MIT’I Ken@ukai, 1959), pp. 46-62; Ueno and Himmic~ op. cit., pp.3-9Q 11.iromic~ “Jidosha” (Autos), in Nihon no Sangyo Seisaku, op.cit.

67 Nihon Choki Shinyo Ginko Sangyo Kmkyukai, Shin Jidai niChosen suru Nihon no Sangyo (Japan’s Industries Challenging the NewEra) (TOkyO: hhiLdChi Shimbundq 1968), p. 48.

68 Saxonhouse, op. cit., pp. 72-80.

69 Philip H. Tresize and Yukio Suzuki, “Politics, Governmen4and Economic Growth in Japu” inAsz”a’sNew Giant, Hugh Patrick andHenry Rosovs~ (da.) (Washington, DC: The Brookings InstitutiorL1976), pp. 798-799.

70 Akio Morita, Made in Japan (New York NY: E.P. Duttom1986), pp. 65-66.

71 Tresize and S- op. cit.

72 Mori@ op. cit., pp. 65-66.

73 This overview of the color television case draws heavily onKozo Yamam ura and Jau Mndenberg, “Japan’s Rapid-Growth Policyon Trial: The ‘Rdevision Case, ” in Gary Saxonhouse and KozoYamamura (eds.), Z.uw and Trade Issues of the Japanese Economy(Seattle, WA: University of Washington Press, 1986), pp. 238-283.

74 Yamamura and ~denberg, op. ck, pp. 256-257.75 Komiya Ryutaro, Takeuchi Hiroshi, and Kitahara Masao,

“Kaden Denki” (The Consum er Electric Goods Industry) in Nihon noSangyo Soshiki Ron vol. I, Kumagai Hisao (cd.) (Tokyo: Chuo KoronS@ 1973), p. 28.

76 Komiyaetal. (eds.), Zndustrz”aZPolicy ofJapan, op. cit., p. 162.

77 Denshi Kogyo Nenkan, 1973, p. 752.

7 8 Yamam ura and Jhndenburg, op. cit., p. 259.

79 Toyokeizai, Jan. 23, 1971, p. 12; Komiya et al., “KadenDerQ” op. cit., pp. 66-67.

80 Yamamura and Mmdenberg, op. cit., p. 257.

81 Yarnamura and Wndenberg, op. cit., p. 261; Toyokeizui, Jan.26, 1980, p. 84; Time, June 13, 1977, p. 63.

82 Asahi Shimbun, Apr. 27, 1%7, p. 7; and Toyokeizai, July 27,1%8, pp. 42-43.

83 Andy Zipser, Stephen Kreider Yoder, and Jacob M. Schlesin-ger, “’IkxasInstruments Obtains Japan Patent for Its Chips,” Asian WallStreet Journal Weekly, Nov. 27, 1989, p. 5.

84 Toyokeizai, July 27, 1968, p. 43; and Asahi Shimbun, Apr. 27,1%7, p. 7.

85 Interview with former MITI official Tokyo, Apr. 11, 1989.

86 Interview with former MITI oflicial involved in the negotia-tions, Apr. 11, 1989.

87 Toyokeizai, Feb. 26, 1972, p. 8Q and June 10, 1972, p. 81.

88 Toyokeizai, June 10, 1972, p. 81.

89 For Motoroh the partner was Alps Electric, a parts maker; forFairchild, the partner was TDK (Tokyo Denki Kagaku), a maker of tapesand parts. Source: Toyokeizai, June 10, 1972, p. 81.

90 Toyokeizai, Oct. 22, 1966, p. 26.

91 Toyokeizai, June 10, 1972, p. 81.

92 Nihon Keizai Shimbun, Sept. 26, 1971.

93 MIT Commission on Industrial I%oductivity, “The U.S.Semiconductor, Computcz, and Copier Industries,” in Workz”ng Papersof the MIT Commission on Indusm”al Productivity, Volume 2 (Cam-bridge, MA: The MIT Press, 1989), p. 14.

94 ‘lhrui Yasuo, “Japan Seeks Its Own Route to Improve IC‘IkcImiques,” Electronics, Dec. 13, 1965, pp. 90-91.

95 MiChiyUki tknoharaj ‘hkUO Sugano, John G. Linvillj andFranklin B. Weinsteiq “Background” in Daniel I. Okimoto, TakuoSugano, and Frarddin B. Weinstein (eds.), Competitive Edge: TheSenu”conductorIndustry in the U.S. and Japan (Staufort CA: StanfordUniversity Press, 1984), pp. 20-21.

% Edward J. LincohL Japan’s Industrial Policies (WashingtonDC: Japan Economic Institute of America, 1984), p. 35.

97 Saiyama llkum, “A Radical Interpretation of Postwar Eco-nomic Policies,” in lkssa Morris-Suzuki and Saiyama ‘fhkuro (eds.),Japanese Capitalism Since 1945 (Armonk, NY: M.E. Sharpe, Inc.,1989), p. 49.

98 Anchordoguy, Contputers Inc.: Japan’s Challenge to ZBM, op.cit., pp. 49-53, 125-132.

99 “Firms Curb Spending as Cost of Capital Climbs,” JapanEconomic Journal, Mar. 2, 1991.

100 Leslie Heti “Big Hopes for Tiny Machines,” The &M

Angeles Times, Jan. 6, 1991, p. 1.

101 Nihon Keizai Shimbun, Jan. 12, 1991, p. 10.

102 Ibid.

103 Forexample, MITI’sreportontrade andindustrypolicy forthe1990s states, ‘There will be demands on Japan to continuously strive forhigh levels of freedom and fairness.. . Japan’s efforts to attain theseideals within its own borders are becoming extremely important for thecontinuation and improvement of the reliability of the international freetrade system.” See MITI, “90 Nendai no Tsusho Sangyo Seisaku no

284 ● Competing Economies: America, Europe, and the Pacific Rim

Arikata,” (International Trade and Industrial Policy in the 1990s), July5, 1990.

104 KennethW. Neves, “Superc.omputers: The Next Generatio@”Scientific Information Bulletin, U.S. OffIce of Naval Research Far Eastvol. 14, no.4, 1989, p. 77.

105 Business Week, Apr. 30, 1990, p. 83.

106 Interview with Marie Anchordoguy, Sept. 19, 1990.

107 Nihon Keizai Shimbun, Apr. 23, 1989, p. 4.

108 Interview, December 1990.

109 Kenneth Flarnm, Creating the Computer: Government, Zndus-try and High l?lwhnology (Washingto~ DC: The Brookings Institution1988), p. 103.

110 Minisupercomputers refer to machines with roughly l/10th to1/2 the performance of a supercomputer at roughly l/10th the price; theyare not a focus of this study.

111 In pq that is because the R&D intensity (R&D expendituresas a percent of sales) is higher in the computer business than in any other.The Japanese companies may spend the same percentage (or even more)on R&D ifordy computer R&D and computer sales figwes are counted.

112 Interview, Dec. 12, 1990.

113 Interviews of supercomputer specialists, one who recentlyretired from Boeing,. Nov. 19, 1990; one who works at the U.S. C)fIlceof Naval Research Sept. 27, 199Q one at Lawrence Livermore NationalLaboratory, Dec. 12, 1990; and one at a U.S. aerospace company, Dec.12, 1990.

114 Interview of several supercomputer specialists, one formerlyof Boeing, Nov. 19, 1990; one at Lawrence Livermore Lab, Dec. 12,1990. Also James Browne, professor of computer science and physics atthe University of lxts at Aus~ cited in “Parallel ProcessingCompukm Attract Crowd of Investors Despite Limited Uses,” John R.Wilke, The Wall Street Journal, Oct. 5, 1990, pp. Bl, B4.

115 Interview of supercomputer specialists: one formerly ofBoeing, Nov. 19, 199@ three other scientists currently at or recentlyEtired from U.S. National Labs, Nov. 30, 1990.

116 Supercomputer speeds are measured in megaflops and gi-gaflops, which are one million and one billion floating-point operationsper second, respectively. A floating-point operation is one additiomsubtractio~ multiplicatio~ or division of two numbers, where thenumbers can have fi-actional components and can have as many digits asthe computer memory accommodates. Cray’s most sophisticated Y-MPmachines come out on top of all Japanese supercomputers on the market(not including the one processor SX-3 of NBC, of which three have beenshipped), in: 1) ONR Benchmark-LANS3D and ONR Benchmark-LANS3D-UP, Kozo Fujii and Yoshiaki ‘lhmur~ ‘ ‘Capability of CurrentSupercomputers for Computational Fluid Dynamics,’ Institute of Spaceand Astromutical Science, Kanagaw~ Japaq U.S. OftIce of NavalResearch, Bulletin no.1, Feb. 14, 1989; 2) Perfect Benchmarks done inDecember 1989 by the Center for Supercomputing Research andDevelopment at the University of Illinois; 3) LINPACK Using allFortran 100X 100 MFLOPS Benchmark Jack J. Dongmr~ “Perform-ance of Wrious Computers Using Standard Linear Equations Soft-ware,” Oct. 12, 1989, Computer Science Department University oflkrmessee, and ‘lkchnical Memo No. 23, Argonne National Laboratory,Feb. 9, 1990. See Cray Research Inc., “The Japanese Public Sector:Problems and Prospects for U.S. SuperComputer Vendors,” May 1990,ch. 3.

117 David E. Sanger, “A Tough Sell for ‘Made in Jap~’ “ TheNew York Times, Nov. 30, 1990, pp. Cl, C16.

118 Hideo Yoshihara, “Perfo rmance of Japanese Supercomputersvis-a-vis Cray Computers,” Scienttj?c Information Bulletin, U.S.Department of Navy, Offke of Naval Research, Far East, vol. 15, no. 3,July to September, 1990.

119 Ibid.

120 Gartner Group, Inc., High Pe#onnance Computing andCommunications: Investment in American Competitiveness, reportprepared for the U.S. Department of Energy and Los Alamos NationalLibrary, Mar. 15, 1991, pp. 89,205.

121 Nikkei Uotcha, IBM-Ban, May 1, 1989, p. 19.

122 Gartner Oroup, Inc., op. cit., pp. 210-211.

123 Gartner Group, Inc., op. cit., p. 210. Cray Research says itsmachines now average 2,000 to 3,000 hours MTBF. Interview ofSuzanne Tichenor and David Frasch of Cmy Research by OTA staff,May 1, 1991.

124 Kawabata Naohisa, Kompyuta Gyokai ga Abunai (The Com-puter Industry is in Danger) (Tokyo: Eiru Publishers, 1990), p. 122.

125 Nihon Keizai Shimbun, Aug. 29, 1990, p. 1.

126 David Kahanerand H.T. Kung, “Aspects of Parallel Comput-ing Reswch in Japan-Hitachi, Matsushita, and Japan ElectronicsShow 1990,” a report of the U.S. Ofilce of Naval Research Far EastNov. 6, 1990, Intemiew of Hideo Aiso, Dean and Professor, Faculty ofEnvironmental Information, Keio University, who heads both the ftithgeneration and supercomputer projects, Sept. 25, 1990.

127 Interview, Nov. 27, 1987.

128 Interviews of ‘Ihkeuchi H.iroshi, Managing Director of theImng ‘km Credit Bank of Japaq Dec. 8, 1987; of TMa Iwao, head ofNTI”s Communications and Information Processing Laboratory inYokosuka, Dec. 5, 1987; and of Okazaki Kotaro, a Director and sectionchief of the Operations Departznen~ the Industrial Bank of Japan (IBJ),Dec. 4, 1987.

129 See discussion of the history of IBM’s activities in Japan inAnchordoguy, ComputersInc.:Japan’s Challenge tolBM, op. cit., p. 23.

130 Interview of Yoshioka Tadashi, a former MITI oftlcialinvolved in the promotion of the industry in the late 1950s through early1970s and later the director of the Japan Electronics Industry Develop-ment Association (JEIDA), Nov. 27, 1987.

131 Kompyutopia, December 1973, p. 23.

132 Ibid., p. 24; “JECC Monogatari,” segment 4, in KokusanDenshikeisankz” Nyusu, no. 120, Jan. 1, 1980, p. 6.

133 Ekonomisuto Editorial Board (cd.), Sengo ~angyo Shi e noShogen (Interviews towards a history of postwar industry) ~kyo:h@hiChi Shimbuns@ 1977), vol. 1, pp.142-143.

134 Kompyutopia, October 1974, pp. 29-30.

135 Despite regulations restricting large transfem of foreignexchange, MITI allowed IBM Japan to repatriate 10 percent of sales asroyalty in exchange for know-how and patents traoferredfrom the parentfirm to the subsidiary. Kokusan Denshikeisanki Nyusu, “JECC Monoga-tari,” segment 5, no. 121, Feb. 1, 1980, p. 3.

136 Uozumi Toru, Kompyuta Senso (The Computer War) (lbkyo:Aoya Shoteq 1979), p. 57.

137 Denshi Kogyo Nenkan, 1976, p. 683.

138 Uozumi, op. cit., pp. 78-79. Toshiba and Daiichi Bussan(today’s Mitsui Bussan) made the joint venture that is today’s NihonUNIVAC.

139 Uozumi, op. cit., pp. 78-79.

140 Anchordoguy, ComputersZnc.:Japan’ sChallenge tolBM, op.cit., pp.168-170.

141 “Foreign Computer Manufacturer Participation in the Japa-nese Government Sector,” IDC Jap% Ltd., prepared for the AmexicanElectronics Association and the American Chamber of Commerce inJapaq March 1990.

142 Interview, Dec. 8, 1987.

143 “Nihon IBM”, in Dokusen Bunseki Kenkyukai (cd.), Nihonno Dokusen Kigyo (Japan’s Monopolistic Enterprises) (’1’bkyo: ShinNihon Shuppansha, 1971), vol. 5, p. 275.

Chapter &Japanese Industrial Policy: The Postwar Record and the Case of Supercomputers .285

144 Imai KenicM “Japanese Business Groups and the StructuralImpediments Initiative,” Japan’s Econonu”c Structure: Should ItChange? Kozo Yamamura (cd.) (Seattle, WA: Society for JapaneseStudies, 1990), p. 191. Fujitsu is the primary computer company in theDaiichi-Kangyo group but Hitachi has relations with this group as wellas with the Sanwa and Fuyo groups. Data are not available on the percentof Daiichi Kangyo group machines that are Fujitsu or Hitachi; the onlydata is on the percent of both firms’ machines-70 percent.

145 JECC Kompyuta Noto (JECC Computer Notes), 1979, pp.10-11.

146 Share of installed base, Kompyutopia, October 1989, p. 13.Foreign companies’ market share in tams of sales was 25 percent as of1988. Kompyutopia, April 1990, p. 63.

147 Interviews of Tajiri Yasushi, Deputy SectionChief, MarketingDepartmen~ Computer Systems, International Operations, Fujitsu Inc.,Dec. 1, 1987; lhkeuchi Hiro~ Managing Director of the Long lkrmCredit Baukof Jap~ Dec. 8, 1987; Inaba Masahixo, Assistant Manager,Business Coordination Department of the I.ndustzial Bank of Jap~ Dec.4, 1987; and Ishiguro Ryuji, Director of the Japan Development Bank’sCenter for Research in Plant and li?quipmen~ Nov. 12, 1984.

148 JECC IO Nenshi (’Ikn Year History of JECC) (Tokyo: JECC,1973), pp. 50-51; JECC Kompyuta Noto, annual. For a detailed analysisof JECC see Chapter 3 of Anchordoguy, Computers Znc.: Japan’sChallenge to ZlM4, op. cit., pp. 59-91; Anchordoguy, “Report onJapanese Policies for the SuperComputer Industry,” op. cit., Appendix1.

149 Aftera 15 month period, theusercould return the computer atno penalty and the maker had to repurchase it from J13CC at theremaining book vrdue. This up-tint cash was thus in part returned toJE!CC when a machine was returned to the maker. This forced the firmsto make better machines in order to encourage users to keep them longerand thereby increase the benefit of the up-front cash.

150 Anchordoguy, Computers, Znc., op. cit., p. 61.

151 Append% total of entries in line 10 under “subsidies.” Thesubsidy computed is the difference betsveen the interest JECC paid onJDB loans and the interest it would have had to pay if it had borrowedmoney from commercial banks at prevailing interest rates. Thecalculation horn 1961 to 1981 is shown in Anchordoguy, ComputersZnc.: Japan’s Challenge to LBM, op. cit., pp. 228-230 (Appendix C).

152 Interview, Dec. 1, 1987.

153 Denshi Kogyo Nenkan, 1970-71, p. 180; JECC KompyutaNoto, 1979, pp. 10-11.

154 Denshi Kogyo Nenkan, 1974, p. 419.

155 Anchordoguy, “Japanese Policies for the SupercomputerIndustry,” op. cit., Appendix 1.

156 Sales &ta are from JECC Kompyuta Noto, 1979, pp. 1011;Kompyutopia, January 1981, 1983, and other January issues; Fujitsu noGaikyo, 1987, p. 18, and Ministry of Finauce annual customs statisticsfor data on exports, Sales in the period from 1961-1%9 were Y367.67billiorq Y1,550.50 billion for 1970-1975; Y5,441.12 billion for 19761981; and Y26.76 trillion for 1982-1989. This estimate of governmentaid as a percentage of sales is conservative in that sales &ta for1982-1986 come in the form of domestic sales and exports, but exportdata also include exports of foreign companies, espwially IBM Japan.

157 Dokusen Bunseki Kenkyukai (cd.), “Nihon Denshin DenwaKosha” (NIT’), in Nihon no Kokigyo (Tokyo: Shin Nihon Shuppans@1973), pp. 134-135; also discussions with Professor Uekusa Masu ofl’b~o University and Professor Nanbu Tsuruhiko of GakushuinUniversity.

158 Interview with Tajiri Yasusm Deputy [email protected] Chief of theMarketing Department Computer Systems, International Operations,~kyO, Dec. 1, 1987.

159 Nihon Denshin Denwa Kosha 25 Nenshi Iinkai (cd.), NihonDenshin Denwa Kosha 25 Nenshi (Twenty-five year history of NIT),

vol. 3, p. 249.

160 Y2,980.1 billion at Y220 to the dollar. Total governmentprocurement (including NIT’) of telecom products during this periodwas about $17 billion (V3,728.7 billion at Y220 to the dollar). Data for1980-1984 from Denshi Kogyo Nenkun (E!Iectronics industry yearbook)(Tokyo: Dempa Shimb~ 1986), p. 449; data for 1985-6 from Fu~itsuno Gai@o (Fujitsu’s outlook) (To@o: Fujitsu, Ltd., 1987), p. 11.

161 Shimoda Hirotsugu, IBM to no 10 Nen Senso (The l(kyearWaz with IBM) (Kyoto: PHP Kenkyujo, 1984), p.158; interviews ofYamamoto Kinko, Managing Director of the Japan InformationProcessing Development Center (JIPDEC), Feb. 28, 1986; and Ku-wahara Yuti@ head of the R&D AdmmI“ “stration Ofllce, Hitachi’sCentral Research Lalwratory, Dec. 9, 1987.

162 Interview withHitachi’s Kuwaha.raYutaka. The timing of theNew Series Project was of particular importance: IBM had introduceda far more advanced series of computers, the 370 series; the UnitedStates was pressuring Japan to liberalize its computer markec and twosharp devaluations of the dollar were rapidly eroding the competitiv-ness of Japanese products. lb help the f- respond to IBM’s new seriesof computers, the project gave subsidies to Fujitsu and Hitachi todevelop large-scale computers, NEC and ‘Ibshiba to develop medium-scale machines, and Mitsubishi and Oki, small computers. No singleJapanese firm had the resources to develop a full line to compete withIBM’s, series which ranged ffom small to Iargescale machines; the ideawas that through the project the industry as a whole could respond asrapidly as possible.

163 Kenneth _ Targeting the Computer (Washington DC:The Brookings Institution 1987), p. 134.

164 Letter in Fujitsu Nyusu, Fujitsu’s internal magazine, Novem-ber 1971, reprinted inl%jitsu Shashi, vol. 2, pp. 134-136.

165 Raul Mendez, “Japanese Supercomputers,” in Vector Regis-ter (’Iokyo: The Institute for Supercomputing Research), vol. 3, no. 1,October 1989, p. 4; Dempa Shimbun, July 1, 1987, p. 1, and Sept. 8,1986, p. 4.

166 Interview in Bungeishunju, September 1982, p. 101.

167 Toyokeizai, July 5, 1975, p. 72.

168 JECCKompyuta Noto, 1979, p. 232 and 1981, p.283; Denshi,vol. 19, no. 1, p. 9, January 1979, and vol. 18, no. 5, p. 37, May 1978.

169 Interview, Dec. 9, 1987.

170 Denshi(Electronics) (lMcyo: Nihon Denshi Kikai Kogyokai),Jtdy 1976, pp. 9, 14.

171 Interview, Feb. 3, 1986.

172 Shimura Yukio, IC Sangyo Daisenso (The IC Industry’s BigWar) (lbkyo: Daiyamondo@ 1979), p. 3..

173 Uozurni, op. cit., p. 156.

174 The Econonu”st, Apr. 5, 1980, p. 75.

175 See, forexample, Raul MendeL “JapaneseSupercomputers,”op. cit., p. 4.

176 Uozumi, op. cit., pp. 128-129, 169-170; Interview of KoezukaMasahim, Deputy Director of MITI’s Electronics Policy Divisio@ May26, 1984; interview of Yoshioka ‘I&la@ former MITI official, Nov. 27,1987. Oki ultimately got access to the patenta of the VLSI project(though not the know-how) through ~ to whom it had close ties ontelecommunications equipment.

177 This project was part of a series of projects done under theumbrella ‘‘Large Scale Project” of MITI’s AgeQcy for IndustrialScience and lkchnology. The umbrella project has funded reseamh onvarious topics including computers, pollution problems, and energy.

178 JECC Nyusu, Feb. 1, 1981, p. 1.

179 SaisentanGijutsu noDoko (Trends inLeading-Edge’Ikchnolo-gies), MITI’s Gyosei Shiryo Chosakai, 1983, p. 748.

180 Interviews of Nishikawa l?+izo, Deputy Director, Industrial

286 ● Competing Economies: America, Europe, and the Pacific Rim

Electronics Division, Machinery and Information Industries Bureau,MITI, and Furutani ‘Pakesti Deputy Director, Electronics PolicyDivisiou Machinery and Information Industries Bureau, MH’1, both onSept. 25, 1990.

181 Xnter{iew of top Japanese computer scientist who is closelyinvolved with several government-sponsored R&D projects, Sept. 25,1990.

1 8 2 Kagaku Gijutsuyo Kosoku Keisan Shisutemu no KenkyuKaihatsu ni kan suru Hyoka Hokokusho (The Evaluation Report of theResearch and Development Done in the High Speed System forScienttilc and lkchnological Uses), MIIT’s Sangyo Gijutsu Shing&ai;Ogata Gijutsu Kaihatsubu Hyoka Bunkakai; and the Kosoku KeisanSystem I-Iyoka Koiinkai, August 1990, p. 8. (calculated at Y150 to thedollar).

183 Denshi Kogyo Geppo vol. 24, no. 9, pp. 42-47. JECCKompyuta ZVoto, 1982, pp. 196-199.

184 Interview of Hideo Aiso, head of the projec~ Sept. 25, 1990.

185 NEC and Toshiba did research on gallium arsenide memorydevices, Hitachi and Mitsubishi on gallium arsenide logic devices.

186 Electronics, Jan. 13, 1982, p. 71. Most of the research done inthis project was done separately by the firms; there was no common labexcept for the dataflow machine that MITI’s Electroteclmic.al Labora-tory (ETL) led. To make the parts compatible, the f- cooperated.

187 Koichiro Tarnura, “General Remarks on the Achievements ofthe National R&D Program, High Speed Computing System forScient.Mc and lkchnological Uses,” Vector Register (Tokyo: Institutefor Supercomputing Research), vol. 3, no. 4, fall 1990, pp. 5-6; Kahanerand Kung, op. cit.

188 The processor used was the one from Fujitsu’s VP-2600machine. David Kahaner, “Japanese Government Science Structure andComputer Related Projects,” a Report of the U.S. Office of NavalResearch, Far East, July 30, 19W, JECC Nyusu, Aug. 1, 1990, p. 5, no.247. Also in Nikkei Sangyo Shimbun, Mar. 30, 1989, p. 1; Interview ofa U.S. scientist who works at the ClffIce of Naval RescarclL Far EastSept. 27, 1990; Interview of Nishikawa Taizo, Deputy Director,Industrial Electronics Divisio~ Machinery and Information IndustriesBureau, MITI, Sept. 25, 1990.

189 Fujitsu’ sM-380mainframe and Hitachi’s M-280Hmainfmmewere used as the starting point for the development of their Fujitsu VPseries of supercomputers and Hitachi S-810 supercomputers respec-tively; this architecture was originally developed during MtTI’s “NewSeries Project” from 1972-1976. Raul MendeL “Japanese Supercom-puters,” Vector Register, vol. 3, no. 1, October 1989, p. 4; DempaShimbun, July 1, 1987, p. 1 and Sept. 8, 1986, p. 4.

190 JECCNyusu, Aug. 1, 1990, p. 5, no. 247.191 JECCNyusu, Aug. 1, 1990, no. 247, p. 4-5. This is now being

followed up with the ‘‘EM-4” project to improve the Sigma-1 machine,u it bto a 1,024 processor machine. The idea is to improve u~xlthe Sigma-1 machine by simplifying its architecture, putting severalprocessing elements onto a single chip with a simplitled networkstructure. ~ahaner, Report of the U.S. Office of Naval Research FarEas4 July 2, IW, Nihon Keizai Shimbun, July 16, 1988, p. 11.].

192 Kahaner and Kung, op. cit.

193 Olaf LubeclG a resea.mher in the Computer Reserach andApplications Division of I-m Alamos National Laboratory. OlafLubeck’s notes in a report from the U.S. Ofilce of Naval Research FarEas4 Tokyo Oftlce entitled ‘‘ETL Dataflow Project’ written up by Dr.David Kahaner, July 2, 1990.

194 JECC Nyusu, Aug. 1, 1990, p. 5, no. 247.

195 Interview of Hideo Aiso, head of the project, Sept. 25, 1990;JECC Nyusu, Aug. 1, 1990, no. 247, p. 5; Koichiro lhnmr~ “GeneralRemarks on the Achievements of the National R&D progr~ ‘HighSpeed Computing System for Scientilc and ‘lkchnological Uses,’ “Vector Register, fall 1990, pp. 7-8.

196 Interviews of Kitagawa Noriyoshi of NIX’s !lccmnd LSIDivisio~ Feb. 3, 1986; and discussion with Hiyaguri ‘Ibshio, Directorand General Manager of Fujitsu’s Computer Group after he gave a talkon Fujitsu’s Supercomputer efforts at the To@o Foreign Correspon-dent’s press Club, Dec. 4, 1985; Yamam oto Kinko, Managing Directorof JIPDEC, Dec. 3, 1987; Denshi Kogyo Nenkan, 1986, p. 186.

197 Koichiro’llu.n~ aMITI’s ETL scientis4 “GeneralRemarkson the Achievements of the National R&D Program: High SpeedComputing System for ScientMc and lkchnological Uses,” VectorRegister, vol. 3, no. 4, fall 1990, p. 8.

198 Interview of Hideo Aiso, head of the projec~ Sept. 25, 199Qalso, David Kahaner, “Japanese Government Science Structure andComputer Related Projects,” Report of U.S. Oflice of Naval ResearchFar Eas~ July 30, 1990. According to an interview with YoshioShimamoto, a retired scientist at Brookhaven National Laboratory,Hitachi only did the progmmming @pge, while Fujitsu wrote theoperating system.

199 JECC Nyusu, Aug. 1, 1990, p. 5, no. 247; Koichim llm~“General Remarks on the Achievements of the NationaI R&D ProgranL‘High Speed Computing System for Scientific and ‘IkdmologictdUses,’ “ Vector Register, fall 1990, pp. 3-8.

200 Nihon Keizai Shimbun, Feb. 3, 1991, evening editio~ p. 1.

201 Kagaku Gijutsuyo Kosoku Keisan Shisutemu n o KenkyuKaihatsu ni kan suru Hyoku Hokokusho (The Evaluation Report of theResearch and Development done in the High Speed System for Scientii3cand lkchnological Uses), MITT’s Sangyo Gijutsu Shingikai; OgataGijutsu Kaihatsubu Hyoka Bunkah.; and the Kosoku Keisan SystemHyoka Koiinkai, August 1990, op. cit., p. 15.

202 Interview of Fuchi ~o, project director of the 5thgeneration projec~ who is also familiar with the supercomputer projec~Aug. 2, 1985, and Yamamoto Kinko, Managing Director of JIPDEC,Dec. 3, 1987.

203 Interiew of Oketani Kisaburo of Fujitsu, Dec. 1, 1987.

204 Interview of Oketani Kisaburo of Fujitsu, Dec. 1, 1987.

205 The Oriental Economist, January 1980, p. 29.

206 Interview, Sept. 25, 1990.

207 The Japanese Public Sector: Problems and Prospects for U.S.Supercomputer Vendors, Cray Research Inc., May 1990, pp. 2-3.

208 Interview with Yamarn oto Kinko, Managing Director ofJIPDEC, Feb. 28, 1986; Electronics, Feb. 25, 1985, p. 31.

209 Electronics, Sept. 2, 1985, p. 11 and Feb. 25, 1985, p. 31.

210 Kurita Shohei, 90 Nenaizi no Kompyuta Uoozu (ComputerWars of the 1990s) (Tokyo: Nikkan Kogyo Shimb- 1988), p. 221.

211 Interview of Yamarnoto Kinko, Managing Director ofJIPDEC, Feb. 28, 1986. Unfortunately, it is impossible to get additionalinformation about this project.

212 Interview of Fuchi Kazuhu.0, director of the ftith generationcomputer projec~ Aug. 2, 1985, and Yamamoto Kinko,Director of JIPDEC, Dec. 3, 1987.

213 JT.ECH Report on Advanced Computing in Japan, Japanlkchnology Evaluation Center (McLeiq VA: Science ApplicationsInternational Corp., Dewmber 1987).

214 Interview, Dec. 5, 1990.

215 Interview of Shimizu Sakae, Toshiba Senior MaMgingDirector, Feb. 3, 1986.

216

217

218

219

220

221

Shimoda Hirotsugu, IBM to no 10 Nen Sense, pp. 60-61.

Interview, Feb. 28, 1986.

Electronics Week, June 10, 1985, p. 30.

Interview of Hideo Aiso, head of the project Sept. 25, 1990.

Kahaner and Kung, op. cit.

Kahaner and Kung, op. cit.; and Report of the Research

Chapter tLJapanese Industrial Policy: The Postwar Record and the Case of Supercomputers . 287

Comnu”ttee on the New Information Processing Technology, AbstractApril 1990, MCTI’s Machinery and Information Industries Bureau,Industrial Electronics Division.

222 Kahaner and Kung, op. cit.

223 Kahaner and Kung, op. cit.

224 Dempa Shimbun, Apr. 22, 1989, p. 5; JECC Nyusu, July 1,1989, p. 7, no. 234.

225

226

227

228

229

230

231

232

233

JECC Nyusu, July 1, 1989, p. 7, no. 234.

Kabaner, op. cit.

Interview, Dec. 9, 1987.

Business Tokyo, May 1990, p. 8.

Kawabata Naohisaj Kompyuta Gyokai gaAbunai, p. 120.

“Supercomputer Bou6° Business Tokyo, April 1990, p. 33.

Kawaba@ op. cit., p. 121.

Kawaba@ op. cit., pp. 120-121.

Interviews of former Cray employees involve& U.S. Embassyofficials, and former USTR offlc~, Septe-mber and October 1990. U.S.government and Cray employees also eonfiied that there have beenother cases in which university professors, especially those that haveused Cray machines while working in the United States, have calledCray Research or the Embassy or botlL with the idea of getting theUnited States to put pressure on Japan to give them a large enoughbudget for a Cray.

234 Kawabata, op. cit., p. 121; Nikkei Sangyo Shimbun, Dec. 21,1988, p. 8 and May 1, 1989, p. 12.

235 Cited in “SupercomputerB ou6” Business Tokyo, April 1990,p. 33.

236 Nikkei Sangyo Shimbun, Dec. 21, 1988, p. 8.; Nihon KeizaiShimbun, Apr. 21, 1988.

237 Dempa Shimbun, Sept. 26, 1989.

238 These include keiretsu-related purchases, auto fm’ pur-chases of domestic machines despite Cray’s clear superiority in this araand all purchases of domestic machines by private institutiona upthrough 1986. (Eight are automobile companies: Nissan Diese4 1987,?muki, 1986, 1989, 1989; Maz@ 1987 and 1989; TOyOt& 1985 and1988. The reruining 12 of the 20 initial purchases are by TokaiUniversity, 1986 and 1989; Matsushi@ 1985 and 1987; Fuji Electric,1985; Sony, 1985 and 1988; Ishikawaj@ Kawasaki Steel, Sharp,ShimizW Mitsubishi, Olympus, Recruit andchiyoda Manufacturing, all1986. The three upgrades are those of Tokai University, Mataushi@ andSony.)

239 T’hkexcludes thetwopurchases of Craymachinesby NTTthatwere immediately sold to Recruit Co.

240 Nihon Keizai Shimbun, Dec. 4,1989, p. 5.

241 Kawabata, op. cit., p. 115.

242 Nikkei Sangyo Shimbun, Aug. 24, 1988, p. 1.

243 Nikkei Sangyo Shimbun, May 16, 1989, p. 1.

244 Asahi Shimbun, Apr. 29, 1987.

245 Utsumi Ichiro, San Nen go no Kompyuta Gyokai, Gekihen noSeiryoku Chizu (The Computer Industry in Three Years, A Map of theRapidly Changing [Corporate] Strength) (Tokyo: Besto Bukku, 1989),p. 24.

246 Nihon Keizai Shimbun, Mar. 11, 1989, p. 31.

247 Kompyutopia, January 1989, pp .12-19. Thia Cray wastransferred to Recruit in December, 1986. Nihon Keizai Shimbun, Mar.6, 1989, p. 1.

“Supercomputez Bou4° Business Tokyo, April 1990, p. 34.Interview of a former USTR oflkial, Sept. 18, 1990.

249 Nihon Keizai Shimbun, Mar. 27, 1987, p. 3.

250 For example, it is discussed in: Kawabata Naohiq KompyutaGyokai ga Abunai, pp. 123-128; Asahi Shimbun, Apr. 29, 1987; NikkeiSangyo Shimbun, Sept. 8, 1989, p. 8; interview of a General Manager ofFujitsu’s Marketing Department Jan. 11, 1991.

251 Nihon Keizai Shimbun, Mar. 27, 1987, p. 3.

252 Nihon Keizai Shimbun, Mar. 2, 1989, p. 31. It was sold toRecruit in December, 1987. Recruit paid a 5 percent premium on bothof these machines over what NTT had paid Cray, according to NihonKeizai Shimbun, Nov. 2, 1988, p. 19.

253 Nihon Keizai Shimbun, Nov. 2, 1988, p. 19.

254 Ibid.

255 An emergency budget was necessmy because the fiscal 1987budget had already been set. Nihon Keizai Shimbun, Mar. 29, 1987,p. 1.

256 Ibid.

257 Interview, Sept. 18, 1990.

258 Utsumi Ichiro, San Nen go no Kompyuta Gyokai, Gekihen noSeiryoku Chizu, pp. 20-21.

259 Nikkei Computer, Mar. 26,1990, p. 98; NihonKeizai Shimbun,Mar. 8, 1988, p. 13.

260 Nikkei Sangyo Shimbun, Oct. 20, 1987, p. 3.

261 Utsumi, op. cit., p. 21.

262 NikkeiSangyoShimbun, Apr.27, 1988, p.7andDec.21, 1988,p. 8; Nikkei Computer, Mar. 26, 1990, pp. 98-99.

263 Citedin “SupercomputerB ouC” Business To@o, April 1990,p. 30.

264 Nikkei Sangyo Shimbun, Apr. 15, 1987, p. 24. For example,complaints wexe made that while a domestic system could be gotten forabout Y3 billion a U.S. system, including peripherals, etc., would costsome Y5-6 billion.

265 Nikkei Sangyo Shimbun, Apr. 15, 1987, p. 24.

266 Nikkei Sangyo Shimbun, Apr. 27, 1988, p. 7. Interview of aU.S. Department of Commeme offieim Oct. 22, 1990.

267

268

269

270p. 34.

271

272273

Utsumi, op. cit., pp. 26-27.

Nikkei Computer, Mar. 26, 1990, p. 96.

Jnterview, Oct. 22, 1990.

Cited in “Supercomputer Bou$” Business Tokyo, April 1990,

Nikkei Computer, Mar. 26, 1990, p. 96.

Business Tokyo, “Supereomputer Bc.ut,” April 1990, p. 30.

This announcement was quite premature. NJ3C still baa notshipped any 4 processor SX-3 maclii.nea. -

274 Nihon Keizai Shimbun, Apr. 23, 1989, p. 4. Also in NikkeiSangyo Shhnbun, Apr. 19, 1989, p. 3.

275 Nihon Keizai Shintbun, Apr. 28, 1989, p. 11.

276 Asahi Shimbun, June 2, 1989 and July 9, 1989; NikkeiComputer, Mar. 26, 1990, p. 98.

277p. 98.

278

279

280281

282

283

p. 11.

AsahiShimbun, June 2, 1989. Nikkei Computer, Mar. 26,1990,

Nihon Keizai Shimbun, Dec. 14, 1989, p. 1.

Nihon Keizai Shimbun, (let. 21, 1989, p. 8.

Nikkei Uotcha, IBM-Ban, Oct. 2, 1989, p. 3.

Dempa Shimbun, Dec. 6, 1989, p. 2.

Nikkei Uotcha, IBM-Ban, Feb. 5, 1990, p. 4.

Asahi Shimbun, Dec. 5, 1989, p. 1.

Nihon Keizai Shimbun, Feb. 3, 1990, p. 1, and July 24, 1990,

288 ● Competing Economies: America, Europe, and the Paci@c Rim

285 Intervkw of Ministry of Foreign At%lirs OfflCkd, Sept. 18,1990.

286 Interview of Ministry of Foreign Affairs official, Sept. 18,1990. This same sentiment was strongly expressed in an article onsupercomputers and the agreement in one of Japan’s major computerindustry magazines, Nikkei Computer, Mar. 26, 1990, p. 97.

287 Utsumi, op. cit., p. 37.

288 Citedin “SupercomputmBout’ ’BusinessTokyo, April 1990,p. 32.

289 In an article Fujitsu Chakmrm Yamamoto lhkuma wrote forNikkei Computer, Jan. 1, 1990, p. 103.

290 Utsumi, op. cit., p. 39.

291 Interview, Oct. 22, 1990.

292 Nikkei Computer, Mar. 26, p. 99. The six labs are: the ‘Ibhoku,Nagoya, and Kyushu University Large Scale Computer Labs; the OsakaUniversity Laser Fusion Research Lab, the Fusion Science Lab, and theMeteorological Research Institute.

293 Interview, Sept. 18, 1990.

294 Interview, Sept. 18, 1990.

295 TheJapanese Public Sector: Problems andProspectsfor U.S.Supercomputer Vendors, Cray Researcb Inc., May 1990, pp. 2-3.

2% This estimate does not include all supercomputerpurchases inJap~ but all those that were made while the performance of Craymachines was unquestionably superior. The private sector companiesinclude keiretsu-related purchases, auto f-’ purchases of domesticmachines despite Cray’s clear superiority in this ar% and all purchasesof domestic machines by private institutions up through 1986. (NissanDiesel, 1987, Suzuki, 1986, 1989, 1989; -1987 and 1989; TokaiUniversity, 1986; Matsushi@ 1985; Toyota, 1985 and 1988; FujiElectric, 1985; Sony, 1985; Ishi.kawajimq Kawasaki Stee~ Sharp,Shim.@ Mitsubishi Olympus, all 1986; Recruit, 1986, tiyOdi3

Manufacturing, 1986.)Thegovernmentprocurements are the 21 domestic machines procured

up through 1986, after which the Japanese makers started to come outwith better, though still not technologically competitive, machines.

297 In current dollars, the estimate would be even higher.

298 For more detail on some of these issues, especially Japan’sway of fmcing long-term investments and links between fms andindustries, see M&”ng Things Better, Competing in Manufacturing,CMice of Technology Assessmen6 Congress of the United States(w_ow DC: U.S. Government printing tilce, 1990.)

299 The most comprehensive and insightful work on the institu-tions of Japanese capitalism is Johnson’s MZTZ and The JapaneseMirac2e, op. cit. The information in this section draws in part onAnchordoguy, “A Challenge to Free Trade? Japanese Industrial‘llrgeting in the Computer and Semiconductor Industries,” Japan’sEconom”c Structure: Shouki it Change?, Kozo Yamam ura (cd.) (Seattle,WA: Society for Japanese Studies, 1990), pp. 301-332.

300 Interview, Apr. 7, 1989.

301 The importance of industry and corporate structure is dis-cussed in Charles Ferguso~ “Sources and Implications of StrategicDecline: The Case of JapaneseAmericanC ompetition in Microelectron-ics,” working paper, m June 30, 1987. Also see David J. ‘Ikece,“Capturing Wlue from lkchnological Innovation: Integratio~ Strate-gic Partnering, and Licensing Decisions,” in Bruce R. Guile and HarveyBrooks (da.) Technology and Global Indus~: Companies and Nationsin the World Economy, National Academy of Engineering Series on‘lkchnology and Social Priorities (Washington DC: National AcademyRess, 1987), pp. 65-95.

302 Interview, Nov. 30, 1990.

303 Electronics, Mar. 27, 1980, p. 122.

304 Michael Gerlac@ “Keiretsu Organiza tion in the Japanese

Economy: Analysis and Trade Implications,” in Politics and Productiv-ity, Johusoq et al. (eds.), op. cit., p. 158.

305 “Nihon IBM” (JaparI IBM), Dokusen Bunseki Kenlqukai(ed.)Nihon no Dokusen Kigyo (’Ibkyo: Shin Nihon Shuppansm 1971),vol. 5, p. 275.

306 As of 1984, Japan’s six major industrial groups earned some18 percent of the total net profits of all Japanese business, had nearly 17percent of total sales, held over 14 percent of paid-up capital, andemployed almost 5 percent of Japan’s labor force. -e Wassmannand Kom Yamamura, “Do Japanese Firms Behave Differently? TheEffects of Keiretsu in the United States,” in Kozo Yamarnura (cd.)Japanese Investment in the United States: Should We Be Concerned?(Seattle, WA: Society for Japanese Studies, 1989), pp. 121-122.] Thesesix groups are the blue chips of Japanese industry today. Though the 182companies that make up the core of the 6 groups account for only about10 percent of the companies on the Tokyo Stock Exchange, more thanhalf of Japan’s largest 100 companies are group members and virtuallyall Japan’s top city banks, trust banks, insurance companies, andelectronics conglomerates including all the supercomputer makers, aregroup members.

307 GerlaclL “Keiretsu Organization in the Japanese Economy:Analysis and Trade Implications,“ in Politics and Productivity, Johnsonet al. (eds.), op. cit., pp. 141-174. It should be noted that this help duringhard times is frequently unpleasan~ banks often send bank oflicers totroubled companies, replacing company mauagers.

308 A Research and Development Strategy for High PerformanceComputing, Executive Office of the President, Office of Science and~h.uology policy, NOV. 20, 1987, p. 26.

DARPA backing in several projects helped Intel recently come outwith a custom-designed supercomputer-the Delta System-which isbased on an array of 528 Intel i860 microprocessors. A consortium of 14U.S. research institutions, led by the California Institute of ‘lkchnology,recently announced a planned pudmse of a Delta System. Intel hasannounced that the machine would have peak perfo rmance of 32gigaflops, but this has not yet been tested. [John Markoff, “Consortiumto Buy Intel Computer,” The New York Times, November 13, 1990,p.Cl.] For an overview of U.S. policies towards supercomputers seeSupercomputers: Government Plans and Policies, Background Paper,Office of ‘Ikchnology Assessment, U.S. Congress, March 1986.

309 Interview, Oct. 22, 1990.

310 The Federal High Pe#ormance Computing Program, Execu-tive Office of the President, Office of Science and lkchnology Policy,Sept. 8, 1989, p. 46. Sidney Fernbach “A U.S. High-Pcxformancecomputing Program,” The International Journal of SupercomputerApplications, vol. 4, no. 1, spring 1990, p. 3.

311 Thisdescription of the HighPerfo rmance Computing Programis taken from Executive ~lce of the President, OffIce of Science andlkchnology Policy, The Federal High Pe~ormance Computing Pro-gram, op. cit., passim.

312 DARPA the NationaJ Science Foundation Department ofEnergy, NASA the Department of Health and Human Services(National Library of Medicine), EI?~ NISZ and the National Oceanicand Atmospheric Administration.

313 CMlce of Management and Budget, Budget of the UnitedStates Government, Fiscal Year 1992 (Washir@o% DC: U.S. GPO,1991), Part Two, pp. 4849.

314 Electronic Engineering Times, Jan. 21, 1991, p. 2.

315 Ruder FiruL “The Influence of U.S. Prestige on JapaneseSupercomputer Makers, “ Perspective, Japan Deslq vol. 1, no. 3, August1989, p. 2.

316 Interview of a supervomputer specialist at the San DiegoSuperComputer Center, Nov. 30, 1990.

317 Fti op. cit., pp. 2-3.

Chapter 6--Japanese Industrial Policy: The Postwar Record and the Case of Supercomputers .289

q‘1

a

~1

mmlqv.10.

FC9-CN. .-0

L o c oCOT*O

OtoU)o70

I I

I I. .. .. .. .. .. .

I

I

I

I

I

I

I

I

I

I

I

I

I

I

o0b10

*.

I

I

I

I

I

I

I

I

I

I

I

I

I

I

o*o

0

0

I

I

I

I

I

I

I

I

I

I

I

I

I

I

I

I

I

I

I

I

I

I

I

I

I

I

o0

I

I

I

I

I

I

6

c 9 m . l -0 0 0 00 0 0 0

oqFi-0

Cvol~LQ0 0 I

Ulmmi?lmmalmT-ooooo~ o %OOOOOOOOG

N

U)C9...*-*.*0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0Oooooooob

I

I

I

I.......................

I

I

I

I.....

I

IOu)U)oco.m

03

-i

I

I.....

CNomlolqmolo* 4 0 0

Ob~cqb.F*

%8G16. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. ..“.“. :. .. .. .. ,. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. .

II

II. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. .

I

I......

I

I......

I

I......

c

I l l

Ill. . .. . .. . .. . .. . .. . .

I

I......

111 Ill I

I

......

..

Ill II

II. .. .. .. .. .

I

IIll Ill Ill II I..........................

. . .. . .. . .. . .. . .. . .. . .. . .. . .. . .. . .. . .

. . .. . . . . .. . .. . .. . .. . .

.....

.........

. . .. . .. . .. :0 . . .. . . . . .. . .. . .L . . . . .. . .. . .. . .. . .. . .. . .

. . .. . .. . .. . .. . .

. . . .. . .. ... . .. . .. . .. . ..... . .

:(Z0. .-.-

290 ● Competing Economies: America, Europe, and the Pacific Rim

3k

00.

F

I

I

I

I

I

I

.....:U).C. 0.“s:2. .-: E:$!:?

: J.... z:C# .-:U. a:2.: E:g“(u

8000-

((

II

I

I

I

I

I

I

I

I

I

I

I

I

I

I

I

.

I

I

I

I

I

I

....

I I

I

mcoNCQcyoC9CD0 I

o +

I

I

I

I.....

I

I

I

I.....

I

I

I

I

.....

Iu

OcoOcq*COb

I

m02C#I I

I.......................

II

II

. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. ..;%:3’:0

:5.-

111

Ill. . .. . .. . .. . .. . .. . .. . .. . .

I........................

.................

.............................................. .

....

..................

..

..

.....................

.

...

....

.:0

............................

............................

......

.....

.

.....

.

...

....

...

............

.....(n

. . ..................

..........

............................

. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. .,:0.=

;!..U:C.m:3.-.+;g:0.-:x:s

. .

.

c.-

jj

...

........

...... ........

Appendix 6-A--Government Financial Assistance to the Computer Industry and Its Size Relative to Private Sector Investment, 1961-89(billions of yen, millions of dollars)-Continued

1961-69 1970-75 1976-81 1982-89$1=360 Yen $1=330 Yen $1=200 Yen $1=160 Yen

Yen Dollars Yen Dollars Yen Dollars Yen Dollars

IV. Private sector investment in computer-related R&Dand plant and equipment

1. Computer industry investment in plant and equipment(private sector) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 41.78 116.06 129.40 392.12 153.60 768.00 1,338.80 8,340.00

2. Computer industry investment in R&D (private sector) . . . . . . 62.10 172.50 238.50 722.73 663.10 3,315.50 3,756.15 f 23,480.00Total private sector investment: . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 103.90 288.60 367.90 1,114.85 816.70 4,083.50 5,089.95 31,820.00

V. Subsidies and tax benefits as percent of investment(in percent) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 37.8% 55.O% 24.2?! 8.2%

V1. Subsidies, tax benefits, and loans as percent of investment(in percent) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 86.6% 147.8% 83.5% 23.O%

fData for 1989 not yet available. Estimated at 25% growth based on previous years’ growth rates.

SOURCE: JECCKompyuta Noto, DenshiKogyo Nenkan;Kompy.da Hakusho; various issues of the monthly magazine Kompyutopia:Zeisei Chosa KaI: Zen Shityo Shu, andZeisa”Chosa KaiKankeiShiryo Shu; Internal JDB and MITI downents without titles; Nihon Kaihatsu Ginko no Genkyo; JECC 10 Nensht JECC annual financial reports; Shuyo Sangyo no Setsubi ToshiKeikakqSorifu Tokeikyoku, Kagaku Gijutsu Kenkyu Chosa Hokoku; Denshi Kogyo 30 Nenshi, p. 82; Waga Kuni Denshikeisankt” Sangyo nohfonti” TM to Sono Tdsaku, 1970, p. 72.

This table is taken from Appendix 1 of the contractor document prepared by Marie Anchordoguy, “Japanese Policies for the Supercomputer Industry,” February 1991, pp. 117-122(Appendix 1) (OTA Contract No. N3-4955), modified as described below.

Subsidy No. 10 and loan No. 1 in the table give the subsidy value and loan value, respectively, of low-interest loans given by the Japan Development Bank (JDB), an agency of theJapanese Government, to the Japan Electronic Computer Co. (JECC). JECC is a nonprofit joint venture of six (originally seven) Japanese computer firms; the Japanese Governmenthas no equity in JECC. See Marie Anchordoguy, Cornputers Inc.:Japan’s Challenge to I/BM(Cambridge MA: Harvard University Press, 1989), p. 61.

Professor Anchordoguy’s original calculations also included subsidy and loan values based on up-front payments by JECC to computer firms for machines that JECC rented out tousers. Anchordoguy calculated that this program constituted a subsidy in the following amounts: 1961-1969, 8.10 billion yen, 22.50 million dollars; 1970-1975,6.22 billion yen, 18.85million dollars; 1976-1981, 6,51 billion yen, 32.55 million dollars; 1982-1989, 8.6 billion yen, 53.75 million dollars. Anchordoguy also calculated that this program constituted a loan inthe following amounts: 1961-1969, 97.01 billion yen, 269.47 million dollars; 1970-1975, 69.30 billion yen, 210.00 million dollars; 1976-1981, 72.60 billion yen, 363.00 million dollars;1982-1989, 122.13 billion yen, 763.31 million dollars. For these calculations, she noted that “JECC data on computer trade-ins is not available from 1984-1989; it was estimated at 42percent of annual JECC purchases as the average in the seventies and early eighties was 42 percent. This trade-in data is used to calculate benefits from the JECC system.” The logicbehind the calculations is explained in more detail in chapter 3 of her book (cited above).

OTA does not believe that these up-front payments represent a loan and subsidy beyond the loan and subsidy already conferred by the JDB loan to JECC, and eliminated thesevalues from the table. The only way money flowed into or out of the Japanese treasury was through loans from JDB (the governnmnt) to JECC (the pr!vate sector).

The elimination of JECC up-front payments to firms makes a difference in the total loan, tax benefit, and subsidy values, especially in the late 1960s, but the conclusion is still thesame. The value of government assistance to computer firms was and is substantial.