‘irrational exuberance’ and capital flows for the us new economy: a simple global model

17
INTERNATIONAL JOURNAL OF FINANCE AND ECONOMICS Int. J. Fin. Econ. 12: 89–105 (2007) Published online in Wiley InterScience (www.interscience.wiley.com) DOI: 10.1002/ijfe.307 ‘IRRATIONAL EXUBERANCE’ AND CAPITAL FLOWS FOR THE US NEW ECONOMY: A SIMPLE GLOBAL MODEL MARCUS MILLER a,b,c, * ,y , OLLI CASTRE ´ N d and LEI ZHANG a,b a Warwick University, UK b CSGR, UK c CEPR, UK d European Central Bank, Germany ABSTRACT In a stylized and analytically tractable model of the global economy, we first calculate the Pareto improvement when a country experiencing a favourable supply side shock consumes more against expected future output and spreads the risk by selling shares. With capital inflows to finance the ‘New Economy’ significantly exceeding the current account deficit, we then show that selling shares globally at inflated prices}due to ‘irrational exuberance’ and/or distorted corporate incentives}can generate significant international transfers when the asset bubble bursts. Our analysis complements econometric studies showing how much the European economy was affected when the US asset boom ended. Copyright # 2007 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. JEL CODE: F41; F32; G15 KEY WORDS: Capital flows; international transmission of shocks; ‘irrational exuberance’; truth-telling incentives; dynamic stochastic general equilibrium 1. INTRODUCTION The role of risk-sharing in the financial system is a central element in Alan Greenspan’s view of ‘World Finance and Risk Management’. In an address to the UK Treasury, he illustrated the importance of risk- spreading by noting the steadiness of the US economy despite ‘the draining impact of a loss of 8 trillion dollars of stock market wealth’, and other adverse shocks throughout 2001–2002 (Greenspan, 2002). As the US productivity boom in the 1990s was largely equity-financed, the decline in asset valuations was mainly absorbed by shareholders, avoiding the concentration of risks in the corporate sector and banking associated with highly-leveraged financing. The international dimensions of risk-sharing were not stressed by Mr Greenspan. They are the focus of this paper which examines the welfare benefits offered by international financial markets for consumption- smoothing and risk-spreading; and the transfers that may occur when a stock-price bubble finally bursts. The methodology used is that of dynamic stochastic general equilibrium (DSGE), greatly simplified by considering only two time periods and two states of nature in a two-bloc endowment model of the global economy. Rational expectations are not assumed: the asset bubble arises from an upward bias in the subjective distribution of payoffs from the New Economy. *Correspondence to: Marcus Miller, Department of Economics, University of Warwick, Coventry CV47AL, UK. y E-mail: [email protected] Copyright # 2007 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.

Upload: marcus-miller

Post on 11-Jun-2016

213 views

Category:

Documents


1 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: ‘Irrational exuberance’ and capital flows for the US New Economy: a simple global model

INTERNATIONAL JOURNAL OF FINANCE AND ECONOMICS

Int. J. Fin. Econ. 12: 89–105 (2007)

Published online in Wiley InterScience

(www.interscience.wiley.com) DOI: 10.1002/ijfe.307

‘IRRATIONAL EXUBERANCE’ AND CAPITAL FLOWS FOR THEUS NEW ECONOMY: A SIMPLE GLOBAL MODEL

MARCUS MILLERa,b,c,*,y, OLLI CASTRENd and LEI ZHANGa,b

aWarwick University, UKbCSGR, UKcCEPR, UK

dEuropean Central Bank, Germany

ABSTRACT

In a stylized and analytically tractable model of the global economy, we first calculate the Pareto improvement when acountry experiencing a favourable supply side shock consumes more against expected future output and spreads the riskby selling shares. With capital inflows to finance the ‘New Economy’ significantly exceeding the current account deficit,we then show that selling shares globally at inflated prices}due to ‘irrational exuberance’ and/or distorted corporateincentives}can generate significant international transfers when the asset bubble bursts. Our analysis complementseconometric studies showing how much the European economy was affected when the US asset boom ended. Copyright# 2007 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.

JEL CODE: F41; F32; G15

KEYWORDS: Capital flows; international transmission of shocks; ‘irrational exuberance’; truth-telling incentives; dynamicstochastic general equilibrium

1. INTRODUCTION

The role of risk-sharing in the financial system is a central element in Alan Greenspan’s view of ‘WorldFinance and Risk Management’. In an address to the UK Treasury, he illustrated the importance of risk-spreading by noting the steadiness of the US economy despite ‘the draining impact of a loss of 8 trilliondollars of stock market wealth’, and other adverse shocks throughout 2001–2002 (Greenspan, 2002). As theUS productivity boom in the 1990s was largely equity-financed, the decline in asset valuations was mainlyabsorbed by shareholders, avoiding the concentration of risks in the corporate sector and bankingassociated with highly-leveraged financing.

The international dimensions of risk-sharing were not stressed by Mr Greenspan. They are the focus ofthis paper which examines the welfare benefits offered by international financial markets for consumption-smoothing and risk-spreading; and the transfers that may occur when a stock-price bubble finally bursts.The methodology used is that of dynamic stochastic general equilibrium (DSGE), greatly simplified byconsidering only two time periods and two states of nature in a two-bloc endowment model of the globaleconomy. Rational expectations are not assumed: the asset bubble arises from an upward bias in thesubjective distribution of payoffs from the New Economy.

*Correspondence to: Marcus Miller, Department of Economics, University of Warwick, Coventry CV47AL, UK.yE-mail: [email protected]

Copyright # 2007 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.

Page 2: ‘Irrational exuberance’ and capital flows for the US New Economy: a simple global model

Ex ante support for the view that asset prices in the US were far higher than could be justified byeconomic fundamentals was provided by Shiller (2000), who appealed to history, sample surveys andpsychology to identify ‘irrational exuberance’ on the part of investors.1 Kaplan (2003) argues that CEOscontributed to the irrational exuberance with forecasts that seriously underestimated the effects thatcompetition would have on their profits as ‘first movers’. In addition, it has been argued, ‘stock optionsdistorted managerial incentives, [and] consulting distorted auditors incentives’, with the case of Enron2

showing that ‘shareholders didn’t have the information with which to judge what was going on, and therewere incentives not to provide that information but to provide distorted information’, Stiglitz (2003, pp.139 and 248). Evidence subsequently emerging in US bankruptcy courts}where corporate officials havebeen indicted for misappropriation of funds and for fraud}confirms that some corporate insiders didindeed have incentives to distort investor perceptions. Note that in the US, unlike the UK, controllingshareholders are severely restricted from coordinating and communicating among themselves to overseecompany management (Black and Coffee, 1994).

Much of the blame for these corporate excesses is attributed by Stiglitz to the zeal for deregulation thatbegan with President Reagan.3 Academic evidence of distorted incentives prior to re-regulation issummarized in a survey relating to corporate ‘excesses’ and financial market dynamics circulated by theECB (Maddaloni and Pain, 2004, p.13). Subsequently, however, there has been a substantial shift to re-regulation under President Bush: the Sarbanes-Oxley Act, for example, seeks to reinforce truth-telling byCEOs and CFOs who are required to certify corporate financial reports subject to criminal penalties formiscertification. (Later, in Section 3, a game involving the CEO and the auditor is used to show howderegulation can transform a situation where ‘truth-telling’ is a unique Nash equilibrium to one where theplayers can collude to raise their payoffs by cheating.)

What of the international implications? Coincident with the ‘New Economy’ productivity boom, theUnited States ran a significant current account deficit in the second half of the 1990s, and it also acted as amagnet for global capital flows. In an inter-temporal analysis, Bailey, Millard and Wells (2001, p.12),henceforth BMW, observe that ‘the productivity shock in the United States has appeared to lead to largecapital inflows as US residents have borrowed against expected future income’.4 They highlight the strongincrease in both equity and FDI flows since 1995, and note the IMF’s suggestion that these net equitycapital inflows may have helped explain the strength of the dollar against euro.

Further detail of bilateral flows between Europe and the US are provided in Table 1 5, where the inflowof risk capital from the EU (excluding the UK) totals about half a trillion dollars from 1996 to 2002, muchgreater than the cumulated bilateral deficit on current account over that period ($62 billion).6 The annualfigures over that period also reveal that, while risk capital inflows increased, flows into fixed income bondsfirst declined and then turned to outflows.

The dynamic theory of the balance of payments under certainty focuses on the role of financial marketsin smoothing consumption; and risk-sharing provides an additional motive for capital flows in a stochasticenvironment (Obstfeld and Rogoff, Chapter 5, 1996). Our use of a stylized DSGE model with ananticipated, stochastic productivity boom in one country (the US) is designed to capture both motives forUS capital inflows.

When Hunt and Rebucci (2003) used the IMF’s new Global Economic Model to see how a permanentasymmetric productivity shock in the tradable sector can affect US real exchange rates and trade balance in

Table1. Net inflows of direct and portfolio investment to the US from the EU (excl. UK)

US$ billion 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002

US treasury bonds and notes 7.82 42.88 43.05 5.54 �15.72 �6.09 �18.52 �18.61US equities �1.65 �1.75 28.79 36.31 46.04 84.86 39.42 12.53Net direct investment �13.7 16.89 19.0 71.74 121.8 165.5 18.71 �36.04Memo item: current account 12.26 5.84 �0.90 �10.21 �21.63 �35.1 �32.88 �53.58

Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis and US Treasury.

M. MILLER ET AL.90

Copyright # 2007 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Int. J. Fin. Econ. 12: 89–105 (2007)

DOI: 10.1002/ijfe

Page 3: ‘Irrational exuberance’ and capital flows for the US New Economy: a simple global model

the second half of the 1990s, they found that a reduction in the perceived riskiness of US assets is needed tofit the data; and Ventura (2001) suggests that the US current account deficit could have been magnified bythe appearance of the dot-com bubble. So as in Debreu’s original formulation7, we do not impose rationalexpectations although we assume expectations are homogeneous. Thus the stochastic distribution perceivedby all investors can differ from the true distribution, be this due to ‘investor psychology’ (Shiller, 2000) or to‘corporate moral hazard’ where distorted incentives led to false accounting (Stiglitz, 2003).

How significant was the latter effect? Though it is impossible to tell with any accuracy how muchdistorted corporate incentives contributed to the asset price overvaluation in the US, the jump in junk bondrates in 2001/2002 may provide a clue. According to Mishkin and White (2003, p.72) ‘This development didnot reflect any change in the stock market but rather the effects of the Enron scandal. The revelation offraud and misleading accounting indicated that the quality of information about corporations was weakerthan the markets had supposed.’ The increase in the US high-yield corporate bond spread over treasuriesshown by those authors is the spike of about 50 basis points in late 2001. If this 0.5% increase in the riskspread is added to the historical equity risk premium of about 5%, stock prices would be over-valued byabout 10%. (This is about a third of the over-valuation we assume in the simulations that follow.) Note,however, that Calvo and Talvi (2002), who assert that ‘Enron revealed that informational distortions reignhigh in the US’, associate the increase of 350 basis points from April to October 2002 with these‘informational distortions’. In this case, distorted incentives could have pushed share prices about two-thirds above their true value.

Efficient risk sharing implies that consumers in the faster-growing region sell equity and buy fixed incomeassets that provide the same consumption in all states of the world; and this has clear implications for the expost distribution of losses. Where the ending of the asset price boom involves a payoff below the mean}anda fortiori below the expected value after distortions due to irrationality and moral hazard}wealth transfersacross the world can be very different from those associated with debt finance.

Our expected welfare calculations show that, in the absence of distortions, the gains from trade in globalfinancial markets are positive, but small: in terms of consumption flows, they are worth only about one-fiftieth of one percent of GDP to each country}a finding which is robust to parameter variations.

The implications of mispricing are more striking. Since overvaluation involves a transfer from investorsworldwide to US producers, the US enjoys a gain which rises in proportion to the distortion in asset prices(with corresponding losses to foreign investors). In the case examined below, where}with no change infundamentals}irrational exuberance increases the mean value of the New Economy by just over onepercent of GDP, the US enjoys an international transfer of almost half of that. Taking account of homebias in investors’ portfolios would reduce the ratio of this unintended transfer to the efficiency gains; buteven if the transfer were scaled down by a factor of 10, transfer losses would still dominate efficiency gainsfor the rest of the world. We suggest finally that this analysis complements econometric studies of thetransmission mechanism which find that financial factors are needed to explain ‘why the Europeaneconomy was strongly affected by the downturn in the US’ (Artis et al. 2003).

The paper proceeds as follows. In Section 2 we introduce the model for consumption and optimalportfolio choice between equity and debt. In Section 3 we derive the key welfare results for case of the logutility; and report a check on robustness. In Section 4 the model is numerically calibrated to fit the stylizedfacts of the US equity valuations over the 1990s and the early 2000s. Section 5 concludes with qualificationsand possible extensions.

2. GROWTH EXPECTATIONS AND INTERNATIONAL FINANCIAL MARKETS:A GLOBAL MODEL

To develop our analysis, we specify a two-period DSGE model in the tradition of Weil (1990), Mas-Colellet al. (1995) and Obstfeld and Rogoff (1996). Assuming representative consumers in both countries shareidentical preferences given by expected logarithmic utilities, we obtain equilibrium consumption allocation,asset holding, and current account positions with and without the presence of ex ante misperception as to

‘IRRATIONAL EXUBERANCE’ AND CAPITAL FLOWS 91

Copyright # 2007 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Int. J. Fin. Econ. 12: 89–105 (2007)

DOI: 10.1002/ijfe

Page 4: ‘Irrational exuberance’ and capital flows for the US New Economy: a simple global model

probabilities. We compare the welfare outcomes under autarky; with complete markets; and withmisperceived probabilities. As a check on robustness, we report results from assuming more generalizedpreferences which allow for differences between the elasticity of inter-temporal substitution and of cross-state substitution (risk aversion).

2.1. Consumption allocation in a two-country model

Consider a global economy with two-countries (Home and Foreign) consuming one tradable good. Theeconomy exists for two periods. There is no uncertainty in the first period, and the endowments for bothhome and foreign countries are given by Y1 ¼ Yn

1 ; wheren denotes foreign variables. In the second period,

both countries expect a (non-stochastic) trend growth in output at the same rate of g; but the Home countryin addition anticipates the development of the ‘New Economy’, a positive supply shock which increasesperiod-to-period growth by a higher rate h or by a lower rate of l. The Home country’s date 2 endowmentsare given, respectively by Y2ð1Þ ¼ Y1ð1þ gþ hÞ and Y2ð2Þ ¼ Y1ð1þ gþ lÞ; with ex ante subjectiveprobability of p and 1� p: The date 2 endowments for the foreign country are the same in both states, soYn

2 ð1Þ ¼ Yn2 ð2Þ ¼ Yn

1 ð1þ gÞ:For simplicity, the payoffs and probabilities associated with the New Economy (h, l and p) are specified

independently of the provision of the finance. In fact, our assumption that producers can issue Arrow-Debreu securities8 means that optimal financing is available: effectively they have unrestricted access toequity finance.9

Representative consumers in both countries share identical preferences. Home country’s lifetime utility isgiven by

UðC1;C2ð*ÞÞ ¼ lnðC1Þ þ b½plnðC2ð1ÞÞ þ ð1� pÞlnðC2ð2ÞÞ� ð1Þ

where b is time preference, C1 and C2ð*Þ are date 1 and date 2 consumption, respectively.Assume complete asset markets with two Arrow–Debreu securities. Their prices are given by

qðsÞ40 ðs ¼ 1; 2Þ measured in date 1 sure consumption. No-arbitrage requiresXs

qðsÞ ¼ 1=ð1þ rÞ ð2Þ

where 1þ r is the gross real interest rate measuring date 1 consumption in units of date 2 sure consumption.The budget constraint of the home country is given by

C1 þ qð1ÞC2ð1Þ þ qð2ÞC2ð2Þ ¼ Y1 þ qð1ÞY2ð1Þ þ qð2ÞY2ð2Þ �W1 ð3Þ

where W1 is the present value of Home country’s total wealth.The partial equilibrium allocation is obtained when the home country is maximizing (1) subject to budget

constraint (3) given Arrow-Debreu prices and real interest rate. Specifically, substitution of C1 from (3) into(1) and differentiating the expected utilities with respect to C2ð1Þ and C2ð2Þ, yields the following two first-order conditions:

@UðC1;C2ð*ÞÞ@C2ð1Þ

¼1

C1

@C1

@C2ð1Þþ

bpC2ð1Þ

¼ 0 ð4Þ

@UðC1;C2ð*ÞÞ@C2ð2Þ

¼1

C1

@C1

@C2ð2Þþ

bð1� pÞC2ð2Þ

¼ 0 ð5Þ

where @C1=@C2ð1Þ ¼ �qð1Þ and @C1=@C2ð2Þ ¼ �qð2Þ:Simple rearrangement of (4) and (5) yields

C2ð1Þ ¼bpqð1Þ

C1 ð6Þ

C2ð2Þ ¼bð1� pÞqð2Þ

C1 ð7Þ

M. MILLER ET AL.92

Copyright # 2007 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Int. J. Fin. Econ. 12: 89–105 (2007)

DOI: 10.1002/ijfe

Page 5: ‘Irrational exuberance’ and capital flows for the US New Economy: a simple global model

After substitution of (6) and (7) into budget constraint (3), one can obtain date 1 consumption as

C1 ¼1

1þ bY1 þ qð1ÞY2ð1Þ þ qð2ÞY2ð2Þ½ � �

W1

1þ bð8Þ

So (6)–(8) characterize partial equilibrium consumption allocations for the home country; those for theforeign country take a similar form.

To obtain equilibrium prices and consumption allocation, we use the market clearing conditions

C1 þ Cn

1 ¼ Y1 þ Yn

1 ð9Þ

C2ðsÞ þ Cn

2 ðsÞ ¼ Y2ðsÞ þ Yn

2 ðsÞ; s ¼ 1; 2 ð10Þ

Denote YW1 ¼ Y1 þ Yn

1 ; and YW2 ðsÞ ¼ Y2ðsÞ þ Yn

2 ðsÞ; (9) and (10) imply equilibrium Arrow–Debreu prices

qð1Þ ¼ pbYW1 =Y

W2 ð1Þ ð11Þ

qð2Þ ¼ ð1� pÞbYW1 =Y

W2 ð2Þ ð12Þ

These Arrow–Debreu prices are proportional to their corresponding state probabilities, but they alsodepend on the aggregate endowments in different states relative to that of date 1.

Substitution of (11) and (12) into the no-arbitrage condition (2) gives the equilibrium real interest rate

bð1þ rÞ ¼1=YW

1

p=YW2 ð1Þ þ ð1� pÞ=YW

2 ð2Þ¼

YW2 ð1ÞY

W2 ð2Þ

YW1 ½pY

W2 ð2Þ þ ð1� pÞYW

2 ð1Þ�ð13Þ

The real interest rate reflects the relative scarcity of aggregate endowments across time (as it is the ratio ofdate 1 marginal utility of consumption of aggregate endowment to the expected present value of date 2marginal utilities of aggregate state consumption); equation (13) shows that an increase in p increases thereal interest rate.

The general equilibrium consumption allocation for the Home country can be derived by substituting(11)–(13) into (6)–(8). This yields

C1 ¼ mYW1 ð14Þ

C2ðsÞ ¼ mYW2 ðsÞ; s ¼ 1; 2 ð15Þ

where

m ¼Y1=YW

1 þ b½pY2ð1Þ=YW2 ð1Þ þ ð1� pÞY2ð2Þ=YW

2 ð2Þ1þ b

ð16Þ

Although both Home and Foreign countries can smooth consumption and share risk with the aid ofArrow–Debreu securities, aggregate uncertainty remains.

From (15), one findsC2ð1Þ=C2ð2Þ ¼ YW

2 ð1Þ=YW2 ð2Þ

As the same is true for the Foreign country, this implies the linear second-period ‘contract curve’discussed in Section 2.5 below. Even with aggregate risk, the Pareto set of points of common marginal rateof substitution is a straight line because consumers have identical probability assessments and (stateindependent) utility functions.

To see how a change in ex ante probability can affect equilibrium consumption, we need only look at howm changes with p. It is straightforward to show that

@m@p¼

b½Y2ð1Þ � Y2ð2Þ�Yn2 ð1Þ

ð1þ bÞYW2 ð1ÞY

W2 ð2Þ

40 ð17Þ

as Yn2 ð1Þ ¼ Yn

2 ð2Þ and Y2ð1Þ � Y2ð2Þ40: Given endowments, an increase in the subjective probability of thehigh growth state, p, increases home country’s consumption in all states and times.

‘IRRATIONAL EXUBERANCE’ AND CAPITAL FLOWS 93

Copyright # 2007 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Int. J. Fin. Econ. 12: 89–105 (2007)

DOI: 10.1002/ijfe

Page 6: ‘Irrational exuberance’ and capital flows for the US New Economy: a simple global model

2.2. Asset allocation and the current account

Assume there are two assets traded in the market: one is a share of date 2 Home country’s‘New Economy’ (Home country’s date 2 excess output relative to the rest of the world), the other is ariskless bond which has the return the same as the real interest rate. Note that the total date 2 payoffs onNew Economy stocks amount to Y2ðsÞ � Yn

2 ðsÞ (for states s ¼ 1; 2); and the gross return on riskless bonds is1þ r: Given Y2ð1Þ � Yn

2 ð1Þ 6¼ Y2ð2Þ � Yn2 ð2Þ; these two assets (each as a linear combination of the Arrow-

Debreu securities) span the date 2 state space.To implement the equilibrium consumption allocation, let Home country’s demand for stocks and

bonds be given by x and z respectively. (Note x denotes a fraction of the New Economy while z denotes thenumber of bonds.) Date 2 budget constraints require

C2ðsÞ � Y2ðsÞ ¼ zð1þ rÞ þ x½Y2ðsÞ � Yn

2 ðsÞ�; s ¼ 1; 2 ð18Þ

Solving (18) for x and z, and incorporating (15), yields

x ¼ m� 1 ð19Þ

zð1þ rÞ ¼ ð2m� 1ÞYn

2 ð1Þ ð20Þ

Foreign country’s asset holdings are determined in a similar fashion. Let Foreign country’s demand forstocks and bonds be given by xn and zn; since the net demand for each class of assets has to be zero, thenxn ¼ �x and zn ¼ �z: For the parameter values chosen in this model, it is clear that 1=25m51; so toexecute its optimal consumption plan the Home country sells equity to, and buys bonds from, the Foreigncountry. With an increase in p, (19) and (20) imply that both x and zð1þ rÞ increase (as they vary positivelywith m), i.e. the Home country sells a smaller fraction of its equity in date 1 while the returns on bonds goup. Equation (15) indicates that higher p leads to higher date 2 state-contingent Home consumption: (18)confirms that this consumption is financed from the higher interest on bonds and the reduced fraction ofequity sold in date 1.

To see how date 1 asset positions vary with p, note first that the number of bonds purchased by the Homecountry is simply z, and using (20), one can show

@z@p¼

2b1þ b

½Yn2 ð1Þ�

2½Y2ð1Þ � Y2ð2Þ�

YW1 ½pY

W2 ð2Þ þ ð1� pÞYW

2 ð1Þ�2½ð2� pÞY2ð1Þ þ pY2ð2Þ þ 2Yn

2 ð1Þ�40

So a higher p means an increase in the number of bonds sold by the Foreign country. Using (19), the date 1value of equity sold by the Home country can be written as

E ¼ �xXs

qðsÞ½Y2ðsÞ � Yn

2 ðsÞ� ¼ ð1� mÞYW1 1� 2

pYn2 ð1ÞY

W2 ð2Þ þ ð1� pÞYn

2 ð2ÞYW2 ð1Þ

YW2 ð1ÞY

W2 ð2Þ

� �

whereP

S qðsÞ½Y2ðsÞ � Yn2 ðsÞ� is the date 1 value of the New Economy. Given Y1=YW

1 ¼ 1=2 andYn

2 ð1Þ ¼ Yn2 ð2Þ; one can show that

@E

@p¼½Y2ð1Þ � Y2ð2Þ�Yn

2 ð1ÞYW1

ð1þ bÞYW2 ð1ÞY

W2 ð2Þ

1� bþ 4bpYn

2 ð1ÞYW2 ð2Þ þ ð1� pÞYn

2 ð2ÞYW2 ð1Þ

YW2 ð1ÞY

W2 ð2Þ

� �40

So a higher p implies that Foreign country buys more equity (by value) from the Home country in date 1.Given the equilibrium consumption allocation outlined in Section 2.1, one can easily obtain the Home

country’s current account position. Specifically, the Home country’s current account deficits are

CA ¼ C1 � Y1 ¼ mYw1 � Y140

M. MILLER ET AL.94

Copyright # 2007 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Int. J. Fin. Econ. 12: 89–105 (2007)

DOI: 10.1002/ijfe

Page 7: ‘Irrational exuberance’ and capital flows for the US New Economy: a simple global model

So an increase in p increases Home’s current account deficit. Using budget constraint (3) andasset allocations (18)–(20), one can show how current account deficits are financed

CA ¼ C1 � Y1 ¼ �z� xXs

qðsÞ½Y2ðsÞ � Yn

2 ðsÞ� ð21Þ

Equation (21) simply states that the Home country sells equity to finance both current account deficitsand the purchase of bonds in period 1. With an increase in ex ante subjective probability, Home sellsa smaller share of the New Economy but at a sufficiently higher price to finance an increased currentaccount deficits and larger purchases of foreign bonds.

2.3. Welfare measures

For the equilibrium consumption given in Section 2.1, what will be the utility gain for the Home countrywhen markets are complete? Under autarky, the Home country simply consumes its endowments, so itslifetime utility is given by

UAðY1;Y2ð*ÞÞ ¼ lnðY1Þ þ b½plnðY2ð1ÞÞ þ ð1� pÞlnðY2ð2ÞÞ� ð22Þ

Given autarky welfare above, we specify the gain from consumption-smoothing and risk-sharing as

DUT ¼ UðC1;C2ð*ÞÞ �UAðY1;Y2ð*ÞÞ ð23Þ

where UðC1;C2ð*ÞÞ is the Home country’s life time utility under complete markets.To see how such a utility gain can be translated into consumption, we provide the following two

measures in Section 3. First we assume that all the utility gain is accorded to an increase in the first periodconsumption (the ‘potlatch’ measure used in the next section), i.e.

UðC1;C2ð*ÞÞ ¼ UAðY1 þ DCP;Y2ð*ÞÞ ð24Þ

The second is to accord the utility gain to a ‘flow’ of consumption in both periods

UðC1;C2ð*ÞÞ ¼ UAðY1 þ DCF ;Y2ð*Þ þ DCF Þ ð25Þ

2.4. Effects of misperception and welfare transfer

Let corporate moral hazard and/or investor psychology be characterized as misperception where thedistribution perceived by investors differs from the true distribution, and in particular where the perceived(subjective) probability, p, of higher growth in period 2 is greater than its true (objective) probability, p0.Denote the consumption allocation under perceived distribution by Ctðs; pÞ; the lifetime utility for such anallocation evaluated under the true distribution is

UMðC1ðpÞ;C2ð*;pÞÞ ¼ lnðC1ðpÞÞ þ b½pOlnðC2ð1;pÞÞ þ ð1� pOÞlnðC2ð2; pÞÞ�

The welfare ‘transfer’ due to misperception is defined as

DUM ¼ UMðC1ðpÞ;C2ð*;pÞÞ �UðC1;C2ð*ÞÞ ð26Þ

where UðC1;C2ð*ÞÞ is given by (3) with p ¼ pO:

PropositionHigher misperception (larger p� pO) increases the welfare transfer from Foreign to Home country, i.e.@DUH

M=@p40 and @DUFM=@p50:

ProofSubstitution of (14) and (15) into (26) for the Home country yields DUH

M ¼ ð1þ bÞln½mðpÞ=mðpoÞ�From (17), mðpÞ is increasing in p. So given po; we have @DUH

M=@p40: Similarly, one can show

DUFM ¼ ð1þ bÞln½ð1� mðpÞÞ=ð1� mðpoÞÞ�

So, @DUFM=@p50:

‘IRRATIONAL EXUBERANCE’ AND CAPITAL FLOWS 95

Copyright # 2007 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Int. J. Fin. Econ. 12: 89–105 (2007)

DOI: 10.1002/ijfe

Page 8: ‘Irrational exuberance’ and capital flows for the US New Economy: a simple global model

2.5. Risk-spreading: a diagrammatic exposition

Risk-sharing in this model is illustrated in Figure 1, an Edgeworth box diagram as in Mas-Colell et al(1995, p.593), where for simplicity we begin by ignoring the effect of the first period savings. Outcomes forthe high payoff state are measured on the horizontal and for the low payoff state on the vertical, and utilityfor the Home is measured from the lower left corner while that for the Foreign is measured from the upperright. As indicated above, identical probability assessments and utility functions imply the linear contractcurve UHUF.

10 The autarky endowment point is at A, where the Foreign country endowment lies on a 45-degree line UFA whereas for the Home country it is a combination of the riskless ‘Old Economy’ (vectorUHA

0) and the ‘New Economy’ (vector A0A). Note that, given p ¼ 1=2; the indifference curve I n for theForeign country has a slope of �1 at point A. If we ignore the effect of the first period savings onreallocating entitlements, general equilibrium consumption is shown at point E (lying on the contract curve)where the trading vector has a slope of �qð1Þ=qð2Þ4� 1; a reflection of the relative abundance of goods inhigh state.

How does taking intertemporal trades into account change entitlements relative to these autarchyendowments? Note that the effect of the anticipated New Economy is to raise first period interest rates, asthe Home country increases consumption and the Foreign country saves more. These current accountimbalances in period one help to equalize entitlements in period two as is indicated by the shift from pointA to point B in Figure 2, where period 2 budget line BE 0 lies ‘below’ the autarky point A and the distanceAB reflects the first-period current account deficit which the Home country has to repay with interest inperiod 2. With rational expectations (i.e. with subjective probabilities matching objective reality),equilibrium consumption is at point E 0.11

Contract curve

New Economy

-q(1) /q(2)

I*

UF

UH

AE

Low State

High State45

ο

A’

Figure 1. State-contingent consumption allocation.

UF

UH

A

Low State

High State

45ο

BC

E’’

E’

Figure 2. Equilibrium effects of distorted probabilities.

M. MILLER ET AL.96

Copyright # 2007 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Int. J. Fin. Econ. 12: 89–105 (2007)

DOI: 10.1002/ijfe

Page 9: ‘Irrational exuberance’ and capital flows for the US New Economy: a simple global model

But what of the effect of distorted perceptions as to payoff probabilities? In this Edgeworth box diagram,state preferences reflect perceived probabilities, so irrational exuberance (an increase in p) will rotateindifference curves clockwise as shown in the diagram. The increase in p will of course raise the relativeprice of consumption in the high state, an improvement in Home country’s inter-state ‘terms of trade’.Anticipations of this will further raise first period consumption by the Home country, shifting its secondperiod budget line to CE 00, and push world interest rates up a notch. The Home country clearly gains fromthe movement of equilibrium from E 0 to E 00 along the contract curve induced by irrational exuberance: it isas if the Foreign country has sold insurance at too low a price. What are the returns to the Foreign countrywhich has boosted its saving in period one and bought assets to support the consumption plan at point E 00?In the low state it consumes less than its autarchy endowment}which is not promising. The loss of welfarethat this represents (no return on its saving) would be more than balanced by the fact that consumption willexceed the autarchy endowment in the high state, if the high state occurs with the distorted high probability.But if consumers have been significantly misled, this need not be true: the good times can occur so seldomthat the Foreign country loses all the benefits of trade in assets, and is worse off than in Autarchy. It is clearthat distorted probabilities can have significant effect on the global allocation of consumption, with welfareeffects we calibrate below.12

The state-space approach immediately shows what asset holdings are needed to implement thechosen consumption plans: the appropriate holdings of Arrow securities are indicated by the coordinatesof the consumption points in Figure 2. It may, however, be more useful to work with combinations of Arrowsecurities which also span the space of consumption, namely bonds and shares in the neweconomy. In Figure 3, the non-contingent payouts of the former are represented by the vectors OHA

0 andOFA (with unit slope) and the state-contingent payouts of the latter by the vector A0A, assuming for conveniencethat all the value added in the New Economy accrues in the form of profits paid out to shareholders.

To support consumption at point E0 for example, the Home country would need to sell shares in theNew Economy as indicated by the vector BB0 and buy bonds from the Foreign country as indicated bythe vector B0E0. These bond sales indicate that the Foreign country levers up its position in theNew Economy above what it earns by running a current account surplus. (In the calibrationswhich follow, leverage roughly doubles holdings attributable to the current account.) With irrationalexuberance, equilibrium shifts up the contract curve to E00, as the Foreign country increases in leverage (aswell as its current account surplus as shown in Figure 2). That its share of second period profits inNew Economy can nevertheless fall is because of the adverse shift in its ‘terms of trade’ in assets.

3. WELFARE EFFECTS

Using this model, we consider the US ‘New Economy’ boom of the late 1990s and the early 2000s andanalyse its impact on expected welfare both at home (US) and elsewhere. For the baseline, expected welfare

OF

OH

A

Low State

High State

45ο

B

E’’E’

A’ B’

Bonds BoughtShares Sold

New Economy

Figure 3. Asset holdings to implement consumption plans.

‘IRRATIONAL EXUBERANCE’ AND CAPITAL FLOWS 97

Copyright # 2007 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Int. J. Fin. Econ. 12: 89–105 (2007)

DOI: 10.1002/ijfe

Page 10: ‘Irrational exuberance’ and capital flows for the US New Economy: a simple global model

is calculated based on the assumption that there is a complete set of markets for smoothing consumptionover time and for diversifying risk, using key parameters from the Bank of England study, BMW (2001)13.This is followed by a scenario where investors are overly optimistic about the probability of high payoffsfrom the ‘New Economy’.

3.1. Three ‘New Economy’ scenarios

For the numerical results, we specify three scenarios:‘Autarky’: In both periods and both states, each country consumes its endowment: there is no

international finance.‘Base-Line’ (Arrow–Debreu): As in BMW (2001), we assume that the expected boom in the US is a once-

and-for-all 5.0% increase in the level of the US GDP, leaving trend growth unchanged at 2.4%. Given thestylized stochastic nature of our model, and setting the standard deviation of consumption to be consistentwith that reported by Obstfeld and Rogoff (1996) for the US between 1950 and 1990, this expected payoff isthe mean of two equi-probable outcomes, a low pay-off Y2ð2Þ which adds 2.5% to second period growthand a high pay-off Y2ð1Þ which adds 7.5%. Note that even though the ‘New Economy’ succeeded in liftingthe Home economy above its trend growth path, the market will still fall if it is the low payoff that isrealized (falling about a half, see Table 4 below): but this downside risk (‘bad luck’) will have been foreseenand balanced by the upside prospect of the market rising on realizing the high payoff.

‘Irrational Exuberance’ (a stock-market bubble): This is the scenario when the probability weightattached to the high payoff is greater than warranted. Note that we use the term ‘irrational exuberance’ toindicate misperception of probabilities whether due to investor psychology (Shiller, 2000) or to mis-information, where accountants and Chief Executive Officers (CEOs) have private incentives to misreportactual and expected profits. Under normal circumstances, the professional incentives for auditing firmspresumably make truth-telling a dominant strategy, so shareholders can rely on them to help stop CEOsfrom cheating. With the financial de-regulation during the 1980s and 1990s, however, auditors were able tooffer consulting services to companies whose books they were supposed to check; so, if there aresupernormal profits in consulting, CEOs could effectively bribe auditors by awarding consultingcontracts14.

The implications for truth-telling can be illustrated in a simple game between CEO and the auditor,where the former wishes to cheat}by misclassifying operating expenses as profit invested in R&D, forexample. Assume, as indicated in Table 2, that both players can either tell the truth or cheat, and thatpayoffs are normalized so both players get 1 if both tell the truth. Suppose that the CEO gets more, 1þ g; ifhe cheats and the auditor colludes; but he is fired (with a payoff of 0) if the auditor blows the whistle. As forthe auditor, her payoff is 1 if she acts truthfully; but there is a potential loss of reputation, with a reducedpayoff of 1� e; for miscertification; so truth-telling is a dominant strategy for the auditor}unless she isawarded a sufficiently attractive consulting contract, k4e; by a CEO who cheats.

Note that, in the absence of consulting contracts (i.e. k ¼ 0), the game has a unique Nash equilibriumwhere both tell the truth. But when the auditor is allowed to take consulting contracts from the firm sheaudits, then for k4e another possible equilibrium exists where both cheat and the payoffs to collusionPareto dominate those for truth-telling.15

Regulations to ban the use of such contracts are the obvious way of protecting shareholders fromcollusion between the agents appointed to look after their interests. In addition, imprisonment for

Table 2. Truth-telling and collusion as equilibria

Auditor tells truth Auditor cheats

CEO tells truth 1, 1 1, 1�eCEO cheats 0, 1 1þ g, 1�eþ k

Note: Figures in bold indicate equilibrium.

M. MILLER ET AL.98

Copyright # 2007 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Int. J. Fin. Econ. 12: 89–105 (2007)

DOI: 10.1002/ijfe

Page 11: ‘Irrational exuberance’ and capital flows for the US New Economy: a simple global model

miscertifying accounts, could}with a sufficiently high probability of detection}even make truth-telling adominant strategy for the CEO too. As an alternative, it might seem tempting to model a ‘moral hazardequilibrium’ where these incentives to misreport are held in check, not by regulation but by the actionstaken by suspicious investors: (we do not do this on the grounds that the degree of misreporting emerged asan unforeseen surprise16, whose true dimensions only later became apparent to investors, partly as a resultof proceedings in the criminal courts.) In simulations below, we assume, for simplicity, that such moralhazard has effectively disappeared with re-regulation, e.g. the Sarbanes-Oxley Act.

To capture ‘irrational exuberance’ in a DSGE model, we simply increase the perceived probability of thehigh payoff of the ‘New Economy’.17 Specifically it is increased to 0.75, although the true probability stillremains at 0.5; so the expected supply side shock rises from 5 to 6.25 percent of GDP. In this case, if the lowstate payoff materializes, the market fall should be greater (closer to 60%, see Table 5), i.e. more in line withthe observed fall of the NASDAQ index (from its peak of about 5000 to less than 2000). In the meantime,consumption and portfolio decisions will have been distorted by excessively bullish expectations.

3.2. Welfare results

Welfare measures are shown in Table 3. In the top row are the lifetime welfare outcomes for the ‘OldEconomy’, where there is no gain from trading financial assets and each country simply consumes its ownendowment, which grows non-stochastically by 2.4%. Next are calibrations of three scenarios for the ‘NewEconomy’. With Autarky, each country continues to consume its own endowment, despite the potential gainsfrom trade in financial assets to spread the effects of the asymmetric shock. When these market opportunitiesare exploited, however, this yields the welfare outcomes for the Arrow–Debreu equilibrium shown next. In thethird scenario, labelled ‘Irrational Exuberance’, the utility of consumption plans made using distortedprobabilities of the New Economy is assessed (but the welfare evaluation is made using the true probabilities).

Two measures are used to translate the welfare changes into consumption flows. The first, labelled‘Potlatch’18, indicates the percentage increase in consumption in the first period which would deliver anequivalent welfare change. The second, roughly half the size, labelled ‘Flow’, indicates the welfare-equivalent extra consumption flow in both periods. Although the Flow measure might seem the morerelevant, the figures in the second row showing the consumption gains from the New Economy withoutinternational trade in financial assets suggest that the Potlatch measure may be more appropriate when‘permanent’ changes are being considered in the context of a two period model. The figure of 4.67%representing the increase in current consumption corresponding to the gains from stochastic increases insecond period output whose mean value is 5%, seems a better measure of what is in reality a permanentproductivity change than the ‘flow’ figure of 2.43%. Hence the focus on the Potlatch measure in whatfollows (Table 3).

Table 3. Expected lifetime welfare, by country

HOME FOREIGN

LifetimeWelfare

‘Potlatch’%Cons’n

‘Flow’ %Cons’n

LifetimeWelfare

‘Potlatch’ %Cons’n

‘Flow’ %Cons’n

‘Old Economy’ 9.16462 9.16462DU0 þ 0.0467 þ 4.67 þ 2.43 0 0 0

Autarky Equilibrium 9.21132 9.16462DU1 þ 0.00020 þ 0.02 þ 0.01 þ 0.00021 þ 0.02 þ 0.01

Arrow–Debreu Equilibrium 9.21151 9.16484DU2 þ 0.0057 þ 0.57 þ 0.29 �0.0058 �0.58 �0.30‘Irrational Exuberance’ 9.21717 9.15903DU1þDU2 þ 0.0059 þ 0.59 þ 0.31 �0.0056 �0.56 �0.29

Note: Figures in bold signify changes.

‘IRRATIONAL EXUBERANCE’ AND CAPITAL FLOWS 99

Copyright # 2007 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Int. J. Fin. Econ. 12: 89–105 (2007)

DOI: 10.1002/ijfe

Page 12: ‘Irrational exuberance’ and capital flows for the US New Economy: a simple global model

Clearly there are additional gains to be achieved by using global financial markets to smoothconsumption over time and to spread risk of the asymmetric supply side shock internationally. How big arethey? In terms of immediate consumption, the answer for the Home country is a gain of only 1/50 of 1%,see nU1 in the table (of which, approximately 2/3 is attributable to inter-temporal consumption-smoothing). With similar results for the Foreign country, the gains from international trade in financialassets are clearly positive, but rather small.

This may be disappointing}but not too surprising if one recalls that Lucas (1987) calculated the welfaregain to the US from eliminating all consumption fluctuations to be less than one-hundredth of one percentof consumption on a flow basis when preferences are logarithmic. Updating Lucas’s exercise to cover theperiod 1950–1990, Obstfeld and Rogoff (1996, p.330) calculate a welfare gain of r Var(e)/2¼ r 0.0007/2¼ r0.00035, where e is the annual shock to consumption, and r is the measure of risk aversion; for logutility, this implies a flow gain 0.035 of 1% of consumption. While the variance we choose matches that ofObstfeld and Rogoff, the potlatch gain from international risk-sharing should only be about a quarter ofthis figure}as risk only occurs in the second period and it is only partially eliminated. But the potlatch gainshown in the table also includes the gains from inter-temporal consumption-smoothing.

What are the welfare implications of asset price overvaluation stemming, perhaps, from distortedincentives in the corporate sector? Since these involve transfers from investors worldwide to producers inthe US, there are winners and losers. On balance, US enjoys a potlatch gain of almost half a percent ofGDP, i.e. more than 20 times the gains from completing financial markets: and the losses to foreigninvestors are of a similar magnitude, see nU2 in the table. It is not difficult to see why: if corporate moralhazard has lifted the expected size of the New Economy by one percentage point and foreigners acquirealmost half of the shares on offer19, then they will lose half of one percent in the final denoument.

Summing these changes gives the bottom line: relative to autarky, international financial markets tradingwith distorted probabilities deliver a gain of 0.59 of one percent of period 1 consumption in the Homecountry, but foreigners lose the equivalent of 0.56 of one percent of period 1 consumption, as theunanticipated transfer offsets their welfare gains from financial markets.20

3.3. Checking the robustness of the welfare results

How robust are these welfare conclusions? As they depend crucially on the degree of asset mispricing, wecheck first to see how varying perceived p changes the size of the transfer. Observe that the ratio of Homecountry transfer gains (0.57) to its efficiency gains from consumption stabilisation (0.02) shown in Table 3is 28.5; and this roughly matches the excess percentage probability attached to the high outcome,100(0.75–0.5) ¼ 25. In fact, for our global model with log utility, this proportionality holds for widevariations in expected p; so we can say that the ratio of transfer gains to the Home country relative to theefficiency gains offered by complete markets approximately matches the excess probability of the highoutcome. If, for example, ‘irrational exuberance’ was to add a quarter to the asset price overvaluation dueto corporate moral hazard (lifting the perceived probability of the high outcome rises to 81.25% and theexcess probability to 31.25%), then the transfer gains would be about 35 times welfare gains of 1/50 of onepercent of US consumption, i.e. a little over 2/3 of a percent of GDP. As an important qualification, itshould be emphasized that}aside from the New Economy shock}this global model is one of perfectsymmetry, with only one good and no ‘home bias’ in portfolios: so foreigners are far more exposed to assetmispricing than one would expect in reality.

The figures shown in Table 3 are robust with respect to variations in risk aversion and intertemporal rateof substitution. Neither varying the parameter for risk aversion over the range indicated by Corsetti et al.(2004), nor lowering the rate of inter-temporal rate of substitution as suggested by Bayoumi et al. (2004)and Juillard et al. (2004) produced significant changes, see Miller and Zhang (2005).

In the view of Kaplan (2003), CEOs invested heavily in the New Economy believing that first moverswould enjoy significant monopoly profits. If investment goods were distinguished from consumption goodsin a model of production, irrational exuberance could then generate significant distortion in the Homeeconomy as resources are misallocated to producing ex-post useless capital inputs (e.g. excess volumes of

M. MILLER ET AL.100

Copyright # 2007 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Int. J. Fin. Econ. 12: 89–105 (2007)

DOI: 10.1002/ijfe

Page 13: ‘Irrational exuberance’ and capital flows for the US New Economy: a simple global model

fibre optic cables)21: this would qualify the transfer gains analysed in this paper. The need to treat thefavourable supply-side shock as endogenous is discussed further in the concluding section.

4. ECONOMIC OUTCOMES

Leaving aside the Autarky case, we consider two scenarios, the Baseline and the ‘Irrational Exuberance’then we capitalize permanent flows to assess what these might imply in terms of losses as percentage ofUS GDP.

4.1. State contingent plans and their financing (see Table 4)

Baseline case: With a real interest rate of 6.5% and a US current account deficit of 1.2%, these outcomesclosely match the results in BMW. What these simulations also provide are state-contingent consumptionplans, and the asset positions taken to implement them. Instead of the US absorbing all the risk of the NewEconomy while the foreign economy enjoys consumption stability, both countries share the aggregateconsumption risk. Details of the asset positions in the middle of the table reveal that, in addition toinvesting the current account surplus of 1.2% of GDP in risky US assets, the foreign country levers thisposition by borrowing 1.1% of its GDP and acquiring almost half of the value of shares in the US ‘NewEconomy’, as illustrated in Figure 1 above.

With a high payoff, consumption grows by about 6% in both countries; but with the low payoff, homeconsumption is slightly less than its endowment (104.9), while the foreign consumption is roughly equal toits own endowment (102.4).

‘Irrational Exuberance’: Encouraged by high subjective probabilities attached to high payoffs, foreigninvestors provide the funding for increased US consumption in period one in exchange for shares in the‘New Economy’ which they continue to leverage with borrowing that doubles their stock holding. Interestrates rise to seven percent. When leveraged bets go bad, foreign residents suffer strikingly from theirexposure to US markets. As the results for the low payoff in the last two columns show, foreigners consumeslightly less than their own endowment in period two: i.e. they get less than nothing on their savings inperiod one!

4.2. Losses in the US stock markets and their international transmission (see Table 5)

Greenspan (2002) reported that, by late 2002, the losses on the US equity market from its peak two yearsearlier amounted to US dollar 8 trillion. By capitalizing the flows discussed above, we can check to see the

Table 4. State contingent plans and their financing

qH qL R Shareholding

Debtholding

Currentaccount deficit

C2H C2

L

Baseline(p ¼ 0:5)Global 0.464 0.475 6.5% 4.7 0 212.3 207.3Home 2.4 1.1 þ 1.2 107.4 104.9Foreign 2.3 �1.1 �1.2 104.9 102.4‘Irrational Exuberance’(p ¼ 0:75)Global 0.696 0.238 7.1% 5.8 0 212.3 207.3Home 3.0 1.4 þ 1.5 107.7 105.2Foreign 2.9 �1.4 �1.5 104.6 102.1

Notes: Deficit denotes home current account deficit in period 1, as % of GDP.

Figures in bold show how the Foreign acquisition of shares is financed (approximately half by issuing debt).

‘IRRATIONAL EXUBERANCE’ AND CAPITAL FLOWS 101

Copyright # 2007 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Int. J. Fin. Econ. 12: 89–105 (2007)

DOI: 10.1002/ijfe

Page 14: ‘Irrational exuberance’ and capital flows for the US New Economy: a simple global model

size of the market fall}and the relative contribution of ‘bad luck’ and excess upside probability to suchlosses.

Note however that the calibrations reported above assume complete asset markets with bonds and value-added securities being traded to achieve optimal state-contingent consumption. This implies that the valueof all US output associated with the New Economy can be traded in these markets, along the linesrecommended by Shiller (1993) in his advocacy for the issue of GDP securities. In practice, however, twofactors substantially restrict international risk-spreading: first only a fraction of output, namely profits, aretraded in the form of equities; and second there is a ‘home bias’ in that most such equities are helddomestically. Given the first restriction, the implementation of the optimal consumption plan wouldinvolve the US short-selling its equities to hedge against non-diversifiable labour income risk (Baxter andJermann, 1997). As short-sales are not usually allowed, however, we assume, in Tables 4 and 5 that only40% of the US New Economy is traded in terms of equities.

The baseline ‘bad luck’ scenario takes no account of any asset bubble. Discounted Arrow–Debreu pricesare used to value the market ex ante; and these are applied to the flows after they have been capitalized. Thefirst two rows of Table 5 show high and low income flows in period two and the capitalization of profitsobtained using a price earnings ratio of almost 30, see footnotes, applied to 40% of the New EconomyGDP effects (allowing for a higher share of profits in this sector than in GDP as a whole). The marketvaluation of 55% of GDP for the Baseline case in the third row comes from summing these discountedcapital values. Since US GDP in 2002 was approximately $10 trillion, this implies a perceived ex antenominal valuation of the US New Economy at $5.5 trillion. But if nature selects the lower of the twopossible outturns, with a capitalized value of $2.9 trillion, then losses due to ‘bad luck’ amount to about aquarter of US GDP.

The market fall naturally gets bigger if excess probability is assigned to the high outturn}the way in whichwe have chosen to represent an asset price bubble. If the perceived probability of the high payoff of the ‘NewEconomy’ increases from 0.5 to 0.75, the ex ante stock valuation rises to $6.8 trillion; and the fall when the lowpayoff is realized becomes $3.9 trillion, over a third of US GDP (see last line of Table 5). This loss is about halfthe figure given by Greenspan for the whole market and corresponds broadly to the fall in the marketcapitalization of the NASDAQ, as the index fell from its peak of 5000 in March 2000 to below 2000 in 2002. (If$2.6 trillion is attributable to ‘bad luck’, this leaves $1.3 trillion, i.e. 20% of market peak, due to an assetbubble.22)

Table 5. Stock market values and estimated losses (Mean expected New Economy effect¼ 5.0% of US GDP)

Income flows(period 2%GDP)

Cap’nn

(period 2%GDP)

Arrow/Debreuprices

Valuation(period 1%GDP)

Dollarvalues$trillion

Non-USlosses$trillion

Baseline1 High payoff 7.5 88.2 0.464 412 Low payoff 2.5 29.4 0.475 143 Expected payoff 5.0 55 $5.54 Actual Payoff 2.5 29.4 29 $2.95 ¼ 3-4 Losses (‘‘Bad luck’’) $2.6 $1.3‘Irrational Exuberance’1B High payoff 7.5 88.2 0.696 612B Low payoff 2.5 29.4 0.238 73B Expected payoff 6.25 68 $6.84B Actual Payoff 2.5 29.4 29 $2.95B¼ 3B-4B Losses $3.9 $1.9

Notes:nThe discount rate used for capitalization of profits (40% of income) is 3.4¼ 1.5 þ 4.3-2.4 in percentage points, where 1.5% is the rate

of pure time preference and 2.4% the trend growth rate}as for BMW}and 4.3% is the risk premium in US stock market estimated by

Cechetti et al. (2000).

All numbers as % of US GDP, unless otherwise specified. US nominal GDP in 2000 was approximately US$ 10 trillion.

M. MILLER ET AL.102

Copyright # 2007 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Int. J. Fin. Econ. 12: 89–105 (2007)

DOI: 10.1002/ijfe

Page 15: ‘Irrational exuberance’ and capital flows for the US New Economy: a simple global model

The figure of $1.9 trillion appearing at the foot of the last column indicates that, in a one-good model oftwo symmetric blocs and no home bias, almost half of the total loss would be absorbed by shareholdersoutside the US. But allowing for home bias would substantially reduce this transfer, as is suggested by theestimated losses of half a trillion dollars on EU investments in the US reported in Castren et al. (2003).

The historical pattern of US investment abroad has been to issue liabilities in liquid form (seigniorage)and to acquire foreign equity in exchange (Hausmann and Sturzenegger, 2005). This would suggestsubstantial US exposure to global co-movements in stock prices. In analysing the effect of an idiosyncraticasset price boom in the US, the exercise in this paper ignores both the seigniorage gains associated with theUS issue of liquid dollar liabilities and the capital losses on US-owned foreign equity affected by a globaldecline of stock markets. One interpretation of our results is that by issuing equity to finance the NewEconomy, the US effectively hedged its historical position. This is consistent with the macroeconomicbalance sheet evidence presented in Lane and Milesi-Ferretti (2003, Figure 7) who show that US capitalgains and losses over the period from 1995 to 2002 on its external position were approximately the same.23

5. CONCLUSIONS

In an optimizing model of the open economy, an expected supply side increase of 5% could lead to capitalinflows of something over 1% of GDP to finance consumption-smoothing (BMW, 2001). When stochasticelements are added, capital flows reflect global risk-spreading as well as the financing of inter-temporaltrades. In our DSGE model, for example, it is optimal for foreigners to leverage their share-holdings to buytwice as much as needed to finance the current account deficit}and to absorb half the market losses.Calculations of the welfare gains to be obtained from such extensive cross border position-taking are,however, distinctly modest: a flow gain of only one fiftieth of one percent of consumption to eachcountry}broadly in line with Lucas’s well-known estimate of the benefits of consumption stabilization. Incomparison, the transfers attributable to mispricing this idiosyncratic shock are large. Artis et al. (2003)find that financial factors play a role in their econometric account of why ‘despite some anticipations to thecontrary . . . the European economy was strongly affected by the downturn in the US’}a synchronizationwhich they note ‘may be temporary and a result of common shocks affecting these economies’. Thoughhighly stylized, our model of an asset bubble offers a theoretical rationale for these econometric results.

Several qualifications need to be borne in mind when interpreting the figures. The size of the pricedistortion is exogenously specified, for example24; and shareholdings do not exhibit the ‘home bias’characteristic of actual portfolios. Even if one reduces the transfers by a factor of 10, however, they are stilllarger than the market efficiency gains estimated earlier. More generally, the substantial seigniorage flows tothe US as Asian countries have accumulated dollars for precautionary motives have not been considered,nor have the substantial US holdings of foreign risk assets; but see Hausmann and Sturzenegger (2005) foran analysis of the role of the US in providing global insurance using a similar framework.

Another important caveat is that we have taken the development (and risk characteristics) of the NewEconomy to be given regardless of what is assumed about the provision of finance. What if the supply sideshock was endogenous to the operation of financial markets? Without the ready availability of equityfinance and venture capital, the New Economy would surely have been much slower to develop}and mighthave been still-born.25 So, broadly considered, the gains to providing adequate financial markets, bothdomestically and across international frontiers, could include all the profits from the New Economyitself}which bulk much larger than the fractions of a percentage point of GDP considered in the paper.The potential gains to be had from developing financial markets are discussed in general terms in SavingCapitalism from the Capitalists (Rajan and Zingales, 2003); and some of the potential risks in Rajan (2005).A challenging extension would be to make the New Economy endogenous; and to include an explicitaccount of the production side of the economy.

Financial development offers benefits in smoothing consumption and in spreading risk: but asset pricedistortions can generate substantial unintended wealth ‘transfers’. As Hunter et al. (2003, p.xxv) suggest,

‘IRRATIONAL EXUBERANCE’ AND CAPITAL FLOWS 103

Copyright # 2007 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Int. J. Fin. Econ. 12: 89–105 (2007)

DOI: 10.1002/ijfe

Page 16: ‘Irrational exuberance’ and capital flows for the US New Economy: a simple global model

these can be mitigated by the ‘(d)evelopment and enforcement of accounting and auditing standards,including the quality of disclosure and the frequency and means of dissemination’.

ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS

For valuable discussion and comment, we thank Kern Alexander, Mike Artis, Sayantan Goshal, Filippo diMauro, Herakles Polemarchakis, Neil Rankin, Roger Stiegert, Alan Sutherland and Jonathan Thomas.Marcus Miller gratefully acknowledges the financial support of the ESRC under Grant Nos. R000239216and RES-051-27-0125, and Lei Zhang their support under ESRC Grant No. RES-156-25-0032. The paperhas benefited substantially from suggestions by the anonymous referees, but we are responsible for anyremaining errors. The views expressed are those of the authors and not of the European Central Bank orthe European System of Central Banks.

NOTES

1. Others have argued that the conduct of monetary policy may have encouraged investors to believe they were insured against amarket crash, Miller et al. (2002).

2. ‘One could argue that Enron put into question the reliability of corporate America.’ (Calvo and Talvi, 2002).3. He also criticizes the Chairman of the Fed for failing to follow up his ‘ irrational exuberance’ speech in 1996 by acting on interest

rates or margin requirements (Stiglitz, 2003, Chapter 3).4. Using a two-country, two-good general equilibrium model, BMW (2001) show that the productivity shock has to be mostly in the

tradable sector in order to generate the US dollar appreciation in the second half of the 1990s.5. The overall US current account deficit and multilateral patterns of finance were greatly affected by the East Asian crisis, where the

flight to safety by countries in the region increased US deficit and financed by substantial accumulation of reserve assets in Asia,IMF (2003). Such seigniorage flows are not considered by BMW nor in this paper.

6. Some of the increase in equity flows to the US towards the end of 1990s may reflect trans-Atlantic M&A activity.7. In the ‘Theory of Value’, Debreu (1959, Chapter 7.5, 7.7) solves for general equilibrium using subjective, not objective,

probabilities. See also Mas-Colell et al. (Chapter 19.C, 1995).8. A claim on one unit of output in any given time and state.9. A possible extension of the model, showing explicitly how the evolution of the supply side depended on the appropriate provision

of finance, is discussed in conclusion.10. The assumption of identical utility is more restrictive than Mas-Colell et al. (1995, p.693) where the contract curve is non-linear.11. Note that, despite the contraction of the second period consumption by the Home country compared to autarky, the relative price

of consumption in two states remains unchanged because of the assumption of logarithmic utility.12. If a country can distort its terms of trade to extract gains from the rest of the world, could this}as suggested by a referee}lead to

a war of misleading expectations, analogous to a tariff war?13. So their results can be obtained as a special case of our stochastic framework.14. In the terminology of Prendergast (1993), the auditor becomes a ‘yes man’.15. For a formal model of collusion between manager and auditor, see Peyrache and Quesada (2005).16. It is worth recalling that, in 1996/7 East Asian economies were being described as dens of ‘Crony Capitalism’ in contrast to the US,

whose Anglo-Saxon procedures for accounting and corporate governance were widely commended as a global benchmark.17. We do not discuss up-dating of misperception of true probabilities. This stylised modelling strategy could doubtless be improved

upon by incorporating Bayesian learning.18. An American word denoting an Indian winter festival, or the gift-giving at that time.19. See details in next section. Note there is no home bias in the model, and there is perfect symmetry between the two countries.20. The finding that international transfers can more than offset efficiency gains to opening markets was also a feature of the general

equilibrium model of UK entry into the European Community of Miller and Spencer (1977). In practice, however, Mrs Thatcherrenegotiated the transfers!

21. We are grateful to an anonymous referee for this example.22. This is far smaller than the estimates of market irrationality reported by DeLong and Magin (2005); using ex post data they

attribute around 60% of the fall in the stock market to a bubble.23. For US external liabilities}which include US equity held abroad}capital gains (excluding exchange rate effects) total 26% of US

GDP cumulated over the years of the stock market boom, i.e. from 1995 to 1999; and cumulative losses over the next three years(from 2000 to 2002), when markets fell, are estimated to be 18% of GDP (i.e., about $1.8 trillion when scaled by GDP in 2003,broadly consistent with the calculations in Table 4 above), a net gain of 8% of GDP. For US external assets}which are essentiallyignored in our model}they indicate estimates of capital gains and losses over the same sub-periods of about 25% and 17% of USGDP, respectively.

24. As the size of the international ‘transfer’ (relative to the efficiency gains) is proportionate to the distortion of probabilities, one canscale the transfers up or down to fit one’s priors as to the degree of distortion.

25. In 1999, the European Commission circulated a report arguing that efficient risk capital markets have a significant impact on jobcreation, noting that NASDAQ companies created half a million new jobs in the US between 1990–1995.

M. MILLER ET AL.104

Copyright # 2007 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Int. J. Fin. Econ. 12: 89–105 (2007)

DOI: 10.1002/ijfe

Page 17: ‘Irrational exuberance’ and capital flows for the US New Economy: a simple global model

REFERENCES

Artis MJ, Galvao AB, Marcellino M. 2003. The transmission mechanism in a changing world. CEPR Discussion Paper: No. 4014.Bailey A, Millard S, Wells S. 2001. Capital flows and exchange rates. Bank of England Quarterly Bulletin Autumn: 310–318.Bayoumi T, Laxton D, Pesenti P. 2004. Benefits and spillovers of greater competition in Europe: a macroeconomic assessment. NBER

Working Paper: No. 10416.Baxter M, Jermann U. 1997. The international diversification puzzle is worse than you think. American Economic Review 87(1):

170–180.Black B, Coffee J. 1994. Institutional shareholders and Corporate Governance}Hail Britannia. Michigan Law Review 92: 197.Calvo GA, Talvi E. 2002. Lula effect? Look again! Mimeo, IADB.Castren O, Stiegert R, Miller M. 2003. Growth expectations, capital flows and international risk sharing. ECBWorking Paper: No 237.Cechetti S, Genberg H, Lipsky J, Wadhwani S. 2000. Asset Prices and Central Bank Policy. Centre for Economic Policy Research:

London.Corsetti G, Dedola L, Leduc S. 2004. International risk-sharing and the transition of productivity shocks. ECB Working Paper:

No. 308.Debreu G. 1959. Theory of Value. Yale University Press: New Haven, CT.DeLong B, Magin K. 2005. The last bubble was brief, but it was still irrational. Financial Times 19 April, p. 19.European Commission. 1999. Risk capital market, a key to job creation in Europe. Euro Papers, No. 32. DGII: Brussels.Greenspan A. 2002. World Finance and Risk Management. Speech at Lancaster House, London, September. Available at www.

hm-treasury.gov.ukHausmann R, Sturzenegger F. 2005. Global imbalances or bad accounting? The missing dark matter in the wealth of nations. Mimeo,

Harvard University.Hunt B, Rebucci A. 2003. The US dollar and the trade deficit: what accounts for the late 1990s. IMF Working Paper: No. 03-194.Hunter WC, Kaufman GG, Pomerleano M. 2003. Asset Price Bubbles. MIT Press: London.IMF. 2003. Are foreign exchange reserves in Asia too high? In World Economic Outlook, Chapter 2. IMF: Washington DC; 78–92.Juillard M, Karam P. Laxtom D, Pesenti P. 2004. Welfare-based monetary policy rules in an estimated dynamic stochastic general

equilibrium model of the US economy. Mimeo, Federal Reserve Bank of New York.Kaplan SN. 2003. Valuation and New Economy Firms. In Asset Price Bubbles. Hunter et al. (eds). Chapter 27, MIT Press: London.Lane PR, Milesi-Ferretti GM. 2004. Financial globalization and exchange rates. CEPR DP: No. 4745.Lucas Jr RE. 1987. Models of Business Cycles. Basil Blackwell: New York.Maddaloni A, Pain D. 2004. Corporate ‘excesses’ and financial market dynamics. ECB Occasional Paper: No. 17 (July).Mas-Colell AM, Whinston D, Green JR. 1995. Microeconomic Theory. OUP: New York.Miller M, Spencer J. 1977. The static economic effects of the UK joining the EEC: a general equilibrium approach. The Review of

Economic Studies 44(1): 71–93.Miller M, Weller P, Zhang L. 2002. Moral hazard and the US stock market: analysing the ‘Greenspan Put’. Economic Journal 112(478):

171–186.Miller M, Zhang L. 2005. World Finance and the US ‘New Economy’: risk-sharing and risk exposure. CEPR DP: No. 4855.Mishkin FS, White EN. 2003. US stock market crashes and their aftermath: implications for monetary policy. In Asset Price Bubbles,

Hunter et al. (eds). Chapter 6, MIT Press: London.Obstfeld M, Rogoff K. 1996. Foundations of International Macroeconomics. MIT Press: Cambridge, MA.Peyrache E, Quesada L. 2005. Intermediaries, credibility and incentives to collude, Mimeo, Universidad Torcuato di Tella, Buenos

Aires.Prendergast C. 1993. A theory of yes men. American Economic Review 83(4): 757–770.Rajan R. 2005. Has financial development made world riskier? In The Greenspan Era: Lessons for the Future, Federal Reserve Bank of

Kansas City.Rajan R, Zingales L. 2003. Saving Capitalism from the Capitalists. Princeton University Press: Princeton, NJ.Shiller R. 1993. Macro markets. Creating institutions for managing society’s largest risks. Clarendon Lectures in Economics. Clarendon

Press: Oxford.Shiller R. 2000. Irrational Exuberance. Princeton University Press: Princeton, NJ.Stiglitz J. 2003. The Roaring Nineties. Penguin Books: London.Ventura J. 2001. A portfolio view of the US current account deficit. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1: 241–258.Weil P. 1990. Non-expected utility in macroeconomics. Quarterly Journal of Economics 105(1): 29–42.

‘IRRATIONAL EXUBERANCE’ AND CAPITAL FLOWS 105

Copyright # 2007 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Int. J. Fin. Econ. 12: 89–105 (2007)

DOI: 10.1002/ijfe