informational lobbying strategies and interest group access in …€¦ · informational lobbying...

26
Informational Lobbying Strategies and Interest Group Access in the European Union Adam William Chalmers Leiden University Institute of Political Science Pieter de la Court gebouw, room 5B15 2333 AK Leiden Paper prepared for the ECPR General Conference, University of Iceland, Reykjavik, 25-27 August 2011.

Upload: others

Post on 09-Jun-2020

2 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Informational Lobbying Strategies and Interest Group Access in …€¦ · Informational Lobbying Strategies and Interest Group Access in the European Union Adam William Chalmers

Informational Lobbying Strategies and Interest Group Access in the

European Union

Adam William Chalmers

Leiden University

Institute of Political Science

Pieter de la Court gebouw, room 5B15

2333 AK Leiden

Paper prepared for the ECPR General Conference, University of Iceland,

Reykjavik, 25-27 August 2011.

Page 2: Informational Lobbying Strategies and Interest Group Access in …€¦ · Informational Lobbying Strategies and Interest Group Access in the European Union Adam William Chalmers

1

Abstract

Lobbying in the EU is defined by an exchange of information: well-informed interest groups

supply understaffed and pressed-for-time decision-makers with policy-relevant

information for legitimate “access” to the EU policymaking process. While we know quite a

bit about the informational needs of decision-makers, an interest group’s capacity to meet

these needs remains relatively uncharted territory. This analysis examines the

informational determinants of interest group access to the EU. I assess an interest group’s

informational lobbying capacity in terms both of the types of information supplied to

decision-makers and the tactics used to convey this information. Which information types

and which information tactics buy the most access to the EU? Results from an empirical

analysis indicate that information tactics are, on balance, more significant determinants of

access than information types. The medium, in other words, is more important than the

actual message. I also find that largely discredited “outside” tactics, like organising public

events and launching media campaigns, are very important in granting interest groups

access to EU decision-makers.

Page 3: Informational Lobbying Strategies and Interest Group Access in …€¦ · Informational Lobbying Strategies and Interest Group Access in the European Union Adam William Chalmers

2

The currency of lobbying in the European Union is information. Information plays an

important role in shaping an interest group’s organisation and behaviour, its day-to-day

activities, and even the extent to which it can affect decisions in its own favour. At root,

information defines how interest groups interact with EU decision-makers. Groups are

relative experts on the policy issues affecting their interests most and have access to

considerable technical, specialist and politically salient information on these topics. EU

decision-makers, woefully understaffed and pressed-for-time, find it helpful, if not

necessary, to draw on this information in order to reduce uncertainties about potential

policy outcomes. Importantly, interest groups find themselves in a good position to take

advantage of this informational asymmetry. They thus supply information in exchange for

legitimate access to the policy-making process with the goal of having their voices heard at

the EU level and, ultimately, steering the EU policymaking process.

Lobbying as information exchange has long found considerable support in the

existing literature (Crawford and Sobel 1982; Austen-Smith 1993; Bouwen 2002; Hall and

Deardorff 2006). But while formal models predict when and at which stage of the

policymaking process interest groups are likely to provide information (Crombez 2002;

Hojnacki and Kimball 1998) and large-scale stocktaking research has provided insight into

the vast informational repertories of interest groups (Mahoney 2008; Schlozman and

Tierney 1986; Baumgartner et al., 2009), how informational lobbying ultimately relates to

access remains relatively uncharted territory. The scant work that has addressed the issue

does so almost exclusively with reference to demand-side factors.1 Access, in other words,

is understood as a function of the informational needs of decision-makers. The actual

capacity of interest groups to meet these needs, however, is largely ignored. Instead, this

capacity is arrived at entirely via assumptions about a group’s interests and organisational

structure. Private interest groups, like businesses and professional associations, are

assumed to “naturally” have recourse to technical and expert information because their

interests revolve around issues related to the market and production. Diffuse interests, like

NGOs and religious groups, are assumed to naturally have recourse to political salient

information or information about public opinion because they represent large subsections

1 The one exception, to my knowledge, is Eising (2007b). Eising, however, does not distinguish between

information types and does not consider how the way that information is conveyed is also related to access. I

will discuss Eising’s contribution in further detail below.

Page 4: Informational Lobbying Strategies and Interest Group Access in …€¦ · Informational Lobbying Strategies and Interest Group Access in the European Union Adam William Chalmers

3

of the population and are more politically engaged. Given these assumptions, informational

exchange becomes an altogether mechanical process: those groups naturally predisposed to

having a certain type of information will gain access to those decision-makers who value

that type of information most.

Clearly these demand-side explanations of access only tell us part of the story. We

know a great deal about the informational needs of decision-makers, but very little about an

interest group’s actual capacity to meet these needs. Missing from the literature is a supply-

side account of the informational determinants of access. Such an account is important not

only because it will give us a more accurate picture of interest group access to the EU, but it

will also allow us to empirically examine the informational determinants of access and test

the demand-side assumptions noted above. I argue that an interest group’s capacity to

supply information to decision-makers begins with a consideration of the full range of

strategic choices groups make with regard to information provision. Specifically, I examine

two supply-side factors: the type of information being sent to decision-makers and the

tactics used to do so. Information type can range from technical data and expert knowledge,

to legal information, to information about the economic and social impact of a proposed

policy, to information about public opinion. Information tactics can include so-called

“outside” tactics like mobilizing citizen support behind a policy as well as old-fashioned

shoe-leather strategies like writing a letter, making a phone call or meeting over dinner or

drinks. Examining these supply-side factors provides insight into the information types and

tactics that ultimately grant interest groups the most access to EU decision-makers.

This analysis draws on data gathered in 64 elite interviews and an online survey of

308 interest group representatives active in lobbying at the European level. Survey

questions are used to systematically tap the full repertory of information types and tactics

used by a broad range of interest groups in the EU as well as the frequency with which

these groups have access to EU decision-makers. This data is then used in regression

analyses of the informational determinants of interest group access to the main EU

decision-making bodies (European Commission, European Parliament, Council of

Ministers) as well as the Coreper and the EU’s two consultative bodies, the Committee of

Regions (CoR) and the European Economic and Social Committee (EESC). Interview data is

used to help explain the regression results. Three central findings are presented. First, some

Page 5: Informational Lobbying Strategies and Interest Group Access in …€¦ · Informational Lobbying Strategies and Interest Group Access in the European Union Adam William Chalmers

4

evidence is found to support the assumption that meeting the presumed informational

needs of decision-makes results in greater access. Second, I find evidence that the type of

information sent is far less important in determining access than the tactics used to send

the information. Groups use certain tactics to increase the salience of the information type.

To turn a phrase, the medium is more important than the message. Lastly, evidence

suggests outside tactics are not inferior to inside tactics in terms of gaining access. Instead,

while the use of inside tactics have been institutionalized through the EU’s various

intermediation efforts, outside tactics provide groups with a unique tool for increasing the

salience of lobbying efforts.

The remainder of this analysis proceeds as follows. First, I present a brief overview

of the existing literature on the informational determinants of access. I organise this

literature in terms of information types and information tactics. Next I present my supply-

side approach to access. I discuss how survey questions were used to measure an interest

group’s capacity to provide information to decision-makers. I then present results from

regression analyses using survey data. Results are explained with reference to the existing

literature and interview data. Lastly, I conclude with a short summary of my main findings

and a brief discussion of the relevance of this analysis to future research.

Informational Lobbying and Access

Lobbying is inherently interactive. Relationships and even just face-time with

decision-makers are key prerequisites to influencing policies and steering the policy-

making process. What counts, then, is interest group “access” to the right people in the right

places at the right time. In his seminal 1951 work, Truman already pointed out the

importance of access to interest group lobbying. “Power of any kind,” Truman notes,

“cannot be reached by a political interest group (…) without access to one or more key

points of decision in the government. Access, then, becomes the facilitating intermediate

objective of political interest groups.” (quoted in Bouwen 2004a: 338). Scholars are keen to

stress that access is a sufficient but not a necessary condition of influence (Eising 2008;

Mahoney 2008). However, given a series of (perhaps intractable) methodological issues

with measuring influence directly – not least of all, the difficulty associated with

Page 6: Informational Lobbying Strategies and Interest Group Access in …€¦ · Informational Lobbying Strategies and Interest Group Access in the European Union Adam William Chalmers

5

categorically linking specific lobbying efforts to specific policy outcomes -- access has come

to be seen as a useful proxy for influence (Dür and de Bièvre 2007a; Eising 2008).

As something inherently interactive, access tends to be understood in terms of an

exchange between interest groups and decision-makers. While the larger interest group

literature has a long history of modelling this exchange in terms “pressure and purchase”

tactics, in the EU context lobbying is best understood in terms of informational exchange.

“In Brussels”, as Broscheid and Coen put it, “the key to lobbying success is not political

patronage or campaign contributions, but the provision of information” (2002: 170). There

is simply a huge demand for policy-relevant information in the EU resulting from the fact

that EU decision-makers are grossly understaffed, under-resourced and pressed for time,

especially compared to the extent of their tasks (van Schendelen 2005; Crombez 2002). The

literature assessing how interest groups meet these informational needs and exchange

information for access is rather limited. Scholars tend to approach the question in one of

two ways: either in terms of the types of information interest group exchange for access or

in terms of the information tactics used during the exchange process.

Information types

Bouwen has provided an elegant and influential exchange model of interest groups

access focusing on information types (2002; 2004a; 2004b). Access patterns, for Bouwen,

are determined the by type of information certain EU decision-maker tend to require. This

informational need is a function of a decision-maker’s unique role in the EU policymaking

process. The Commission serves a largely apolitical and technocratic function and thus

requires a large amount of technical, operational and expert information. The Parliament, as

the EU’s only elected supranational assembly, requires information that allows it to

evaluate the Commission’s proposals from a “European perspective”. Finally, the Council is

a wholly intergovernmental institution and carries out executive policymaking functions. As

such, according to Bouwen, it requires information that can facilitate bargaining between

member states. From these demand-side factors Bouwen deduces the types of interest

groups we can expect to have the most access to the various institutions. His logic of

matching an interest group’s informational capacity to the informational needs of decision-

makers is rather mechanical and is based on assumptions about the types of information

Page 7: Informational Lobbying Strategies and Interest Group Access in …€¦ · Informational Lobbying Strategies and Interest Group Access in the European Union Adam William Chalmers

6

various interest groups can be expected to have. First, companies have frequent access to

the Commission because they are assumed to naturally have recourse to “technical and

expert knowledge” derived from the fact that they are active in the market and concerned

with issues of production and profit maximization. European associations (essentially

groups of companies working at the EU level) have the most access to Parliament because

they are assumed to have information about the “European encompassing interest”. Finally,

national associations (groups of companies working at the national level) exchange

information about the “national encompassing interest” to the Council.

Bouwen’s basic exchange model of access has been quite influential. Michalowitz

(2004) expanded Bouwen’s logic to an examination of several private interest groups

(multi-national firms, large national firms, and small and medium sized enterprises (SMEs))

as well as “public interest groups”. Mirroring Bouwen’s assumptions, technical information

is assumed to grant multi-national firms access to the Commission, and “expertise with

regard to the national situation” is assumed to be translated as more access to the Council

for national firms (89). SME’s, however, are relatively disadvantaged because they have

almost no natural ability to supply information. Public interest groups, possessing

information about “public support” are hard pressed to find an audience outside the

Parliament. Dür and de Biévre also consider the informational exchange potential of public

interest groups (in particular NGOs). Their estimation, however, is even less optimistic.

NGOs are distinctly disadvantaged in that they cannot generate technical and expert

information. As such, these groups are invariably “compelled to constantly appeal to

general principles like equity, social justice, and environmental protection” making their

informational contribution of “little value” to EU decision-makers (Dür and de Biévre

2007b: 82).

Eising (2007b) addresses the fact that the evidence presented in these demand-side

studies in only piecemeal and calls attention to the need for a consideration of the supply-

side factors of access. Eising tests informational lobbying alongside institutional context,

organisational structure, and a group’s choice of “national or EU strategies” as determinants

of access. Importantly, Eising does find evidence that information provision “improves

access” to EU decision-makers (352). However, Eising’s model is limited in the sense that he

uses a very vague “information” variable that lumps together a broad range of information

Page 8: Informational Lobbying Strategies and Interest Group Access in …€¦ · Informational Lobbying Strategies and Interest Group Access in the European Union Adam William Chalmers

7

types: political, legal, technical and economic information. Despite providing evidence that

information buys access, Eising does not tell us which types of information grant interest

groups the most access and in which EU institutions.

Information tactics

Informational lobbying is not only about the type of information being sent to

decision-makers, but also the tactics used to convey this information. How does the use of

various tactics relate to more or less access? The main distinction here is between outside

tactics and inside tactics (Walker 1991; Gerber 1999; Kollman 1998). Outside tactics refer

to interest groups “mobiliz(ing) citizens outside the policymaking community to contact or

pressure officials inside the policymaking community” (Kollman 1998: 3). These tactics

centre on using the media, launching public campaigns and even organising public events

(ranging from rallies to conferences to cocktail parties). Inside tactics, by contrast, involve a

more direct form of contact between interest groups and decision-makers and usually

refers to old-fashioned shoe-leather strategies like writing letters, making phone calls and

having face-to-face meetings.

On balance, inside tactics are considered more effective than outside tactics. Beyers

(2004) provides three main reasons explaining why. First, inside tactic are direct and thus

allow for the transmission of very technical, detailed and complex policy-relevant

information. Outside tactics are indirect and, by virtue of their nature and scale, are limited

in the type of information they can convey. Cost also explains the superiority of inside

tactics. Simply put, making a phone call or having a face-to-face meeting is far less costly

than organising a public event or launching a media campaign. Finally, there is also a

detrimental political cost unique to outside tactics. Using these tactics has a tendency to

damage an interest group’s reputation with decision-makers.

Empirical research, while finding an important link between tactics and access, is

more equivocal in terms of which tactics are most effective. Eising’s analysis found

considerable support linking inside tactics (like personal contacts and writing position

papers) to access. He also found that outside tactics tend to ruin a group’s chances of access

(2007b). Beyers (2004) as well as Binderkrantz (2005), however, are less categorical about

writing-off outside tactics. Both studies show that the complementary use of both strategies

Page 9: Informational Lobbying Strategies and Interest Group Access in …€¦ · Informational Lobbying Strategies and Interest Group Access in the European Union Adam William Chalmers

8

is rather common and question whether outside tactics are inherently inferior to inside

tactics. Part of the confusion relates to how outside tactics are defined. “Protest politics”,

according to Beyers, and “disruptive tactics” according to Binderkrantz, are used

infrequently and only by a minority of groups. Other forms of traditional outside tactics, like

the use of different media strategies, however, are used very frequently by a broad range of

interest groups. Both studies give purchase to Baumgartner and Leech’s observation that

“the most effective groups may not be those that are the best at a given strategy but rather

those that have the greatest repertory of strategies available to them” (1998: 148).

The Informational Determinants of Access

As Eising points out, “no coherent picture has yet emerged as to what determines the

access of interest groups to the EU” (2007b: 330). Bouwen’s exchange model is elegant but

“piecemeal”, focusing entirely on demand-side factors and assumptions about a group’s

capacity to provide information. Information types and tactics have rarely (if ever) been

considered together as complementing aspects of informational lobbying. Both theoretical

and empirical work has a distinct bias toward private and (to far lesser extent) diffuse

interest groups and rarely considers the broader EU interest group population.

This analysis seeks to addresses these shortcomings. To this end I propose a supply-side

approach to testing the informational determinants of access in the EU. I bring together six

different information types and seven different information tactics in a single framework of

analysis that is based on evidence collected from eleven different types of interest groups

active in lobbying at the EU level. The interest groups I consider are: professional

associations, companies, law firms, public affairs consultancies, chambers of commerce,

academic organisations, trade unions, NGOs and associations of NGOs, religious groups,

think-tanks, and, lastly, public authorities (regions, cities and municipalities).2 This supply-

side examination of access is meant to serve two purposes. First, it will provide insight into

the information types and information tactics that grant the most access to EU decision-

makers in the different EU institutions. Second, it will help us evaluate some of the (largely

untested) assumptions regarding types and tactics posited in literature.

2 In the context of the online survey, respondents were asked to identify which type of group they belong to.

While this list is by no means exhaustive, its does include certain groups, like public authorities, think tanks,

consultancies, and academic organisations, which are rarely studied in the interest group literature.

Page 10: Informational Lobbying Strategies and Interest Group Access in …€¦ · Informational Lobbying Strategies and Interest Group Access in the European Union Adam William Chalmers

9

Data for this analysis was collected in 64 elite interviews and a large-scale online

survey of 308 interest group representatives. For the online survey, a list of 2,500 interest

groups was generated using three sources: the “European Commission’s Register of Interest

Representatives,” the 2008 edition of Landmarks’ “European Public Affairs Directory,” and

the “Brussels-Europe Liaison Office” list.3 This last source was crucial for the inclusion of

public authorities in the sample. A sampling frame of 1,000 interest groups was established

using a simple proportional sampling technique. 308 responses were collected, putting the

response rate at about 30%. Assessing how representative this sample is vis-à-vis the EU

interest group population is very difficult. There is no definitive list of interest groups in the

EU and there are only loose approximations of the number of groups that actively lobby at

the European level (Berkhout and Lowery 2008). Table 1 below details the distribution of

survey responses by group type. There appears to be adequate coverage for quite a few

interest group types – namely, companies, trade unions, professional associations, NGOs,

public authorities, and consultancies. However, one potential limitation of this study is the

low response rates for law firms, think tanks, chambers of commerce, academic

organisations and religious organisations. A truly representative sample would include

satisfactory response rates for these interest groups as well.

(Table 1 about here)

The three main variables tested in this analysis are information types, information

tactics and interest group access to EU decision-makers. In what follows I will detail how

each of these variables is operationalized and measured by survey questions.

The type of information interest groups supply to decision-makers has been

variously described as “expert information” about the technical details of policy (Ainsworth

1993: 44; Esterling 2004; Crombez 2002), as “private information” that only certain

interest groups possess (Crawford and Sobel 1982: 1431), as well as “specialist

information” related to the “consequences of some policy” (Austen-Smith 1993: 799). It can

also be information that conveys “political intelligence” necessary to anticipate another

3 The Brussels-Europe Liaison Office list is available online at: http://www.blbe.be/directory/find.asp. This

web-site was accessed in September 2009.

Page 11: Informational Lobbying Strategies and Interest Group Access in …€¦ · Informational Lobbying Strategies and Interest Group Access in the European Union Adam William Chalmers

10

actor’s reactions or details about procedure (Hall and Deardorff 2006) as well as

information about the “political salience” and “public support” of a policy proposal (Pappi

and Hennig 1999: 259). For this analysis I have established a manageable list of information

types by coupling insights from the literature with data collected in interviews. In all, I

examine six information types: legal information; information about the feasibility of

implementing a proposal; information that makes technical or scientific data

understandable / relevant; information about public opinion; information about the

economic impact of a proposal; and information about the social impact of a proposal. Data

was collected on all six information types by asking respondents to identify how frequently

(on a scale of 1 to 5, with 1 being “never” and 5 being “very often”) their organisation

provides these types of information to EU decision-makers.

Information tactics have been subject to considerable stocktaking research detailing

the large strategic toolkits available to many interest groups. Scholzman and Tierney’s 1986

seminal work on American interest groups identifies twenty-three such tactics, ranging

from direct and informal contact with legislators, presenting research results, talking to

journalists, advertising, writing letters, giving testimony, organising protests, helping draft

legislation, agenda setting, to campaign work. Similar surveys conducted by Knoke (1990),

Walker (1991), Heinz et al., (1993), and more recently Baumgartner et al. (2009) find

“remarkably robust” support for Scholzman and Tierney’s study despite “using different

questions, different sampling frames, and (going) to the field in different years”

(Baumgartner and Leech 1998: 149). For this analysis, insights from the literature and from

interviews were used to generate a list of information tactics. Five inside strategies and

two outside strategies were examined. Inside tactics include: face-to-face meetings; write a

letter; write an email; make a phone call; and participate in the ‘open consultation’ process.4

Outside tactics include: start a media campaign; and organise a public event. Data was

collected on information tactics by asking respondents to identify how frequently (on the

same 1 to 5 scale) their organisation provides information to EU decision-makers using

these different tactics.

4 Open consultation is an invitation for interest groups to provide information to the European Commission at

the agenda-setting stage of the policymaking process.

Page 12: Informational Lobbying Strategies and Interest Group Access in …€¦ · Informational Lobbying Strategies and Interest Group Access in the European Union Adam William Chalmers

11

Measuring types and tactics in terms of frequency of use (as opposed to importance,

for instance) is based on the simple idea that “more is better”. In other words, sending

information more frequently will result in more access. There is support for this approach

in the literature. Potters and van Winden (1992) provide compelling evidence that “more

letters and more personal visits produce a more favourable response by legislators” (285;

see also Schneider and Naumann 1982; Zeigler and Baer 1969). In the EU context, Eising’s

2007 study of interest group access also measured information supply in terms of

frequency. Empirical analysis in this study found some support for the hypothesis that “the

more policy information that (interest groups) can deliver, the better their access” (2007b:

336). It seems that rather than straining interest group relations with decision-makers, a

“frappez, frappez toujours” logic, as Potters and van Winden call it, is both “rational and

effective” (1992: 285).

Access was measured by asking respondents how frequently, on the same 1 to 5

scale, their organisation is in contact with the EU’s different decision-making institutions.

Six institutions were included: European Commission, European Parliament, Council of

Ministers, Committee of Permanent Representatives (Coreper), Committee of the Regions

(CoR) and the European Economic and Social Committee (EESC). The inclusion of these last

three bodies is meant to give a more complete picture of access in the EU. Coreper performs

a set of functions separate from Council and have their only specific informational needs.

CoR and EESC, while admittedly only playing a consultative role in the EU policymaking,

provide important access points for a whole host of diverse interest group types. For

instance, CoR is mandated to represent the interests of regions, cities and municipalities,

while EESC represents the interests of trade unions and civil society more broadly speaking.

Interest groups would necessary take these consultative bodies quite seriously and would

seek to affect legislation through their access with them.

Measuring access in terms of interaction frequency is consistent with other empirical

research on access in the EU (Eising 2008; Eising 2007a; Bouwen 2004a & 2004b; Beyers

2002). Measuring access in terms of frequency also highlights the inner logic of lobbying as

information exchange. As Carpenter, Lazer and Estering (1998) explain, decision-makers

are in the market for policy-relevant information, if only because it reduces uncertainties

about potential policy outcomes. In order to maximize their chances of receiving

Page 13: Informational Lobbying Strategies and Interest Group Access in …€¦ · Informational Lobbying Strategies and Interest Group Access in the European Union Adam William Chalmers

12

information, decision-making would necessarily seek to interact most frequently with those

groups that are best able to provide information.

Empirical Analysis

Table 2 presents the results of an empirical analysis of survey data using ordered

logistic regression. The informational determinants of access (corresponding to six

information types and seven information tactics) are tested in six models, each

corresponding to different EU decision-making institutions. I discuss the results for

information type and tactics in turn.

(Table 2 about here)

Information Types

When it comes to information types, access patterns do seem to roughly match the

presumed informational needs of EU decision-makers. As Bouwen and others predict,

supplying the Commission with “technical information”, or in this case information

detailing the feasibility of a proposed policy, leads to more frequent access. This technical

information serves the Commission’s largely apolitical and technocratic functions and

reduces the complexity and policy uncertainties that tend to define the Commission’s

agenda setting and legislative tasks (Bouwen 2009). For the Council, access results from the

provision of legal information. Despite being notoriously “opaque, closed, elusive and

inscrutable, secretive, and intractable” (Hayes-Renshaw 2009: 73), the Council’s executive

tasks at the vote state of the legislative process can be revealing. With the technical details

already taken care of in the earlier policy-making stages, the Council would find itself

tasked with ironing out the legislative language of EU regulations and directives. Access to

the Parliament is granted by supplying information about the social impact of a policy

proposal. The informational needs of the Parliament follow its internal bifurcation as an

effective branch of the legislative process and as a public arena for wider political debate

(Lehmann 2009: 55). For this reason, the Parliament relies somewhat on the supply of

technical details and scientific expertise but also on information about “wide ranging”

issues, “like a cleaner environment, higher employment” that are “known to be of interest to

Page 14: Informational Lobbying Strategies and Interest Group Access in …€¦ · Informational Lobbying Strategies and Interest Group Access in the European Union Adam William Chalmers

13

a large number of citizens” (Lehmann 2009: 52). Information about social impact seems to

serve both purposes, combining substantive, technical details with a specific public or social

dimension. Importantly, regression results found no support for the expectation that

information about “public opinion” would grant the most access to the Parliament.

Coreper and the two consultative bodies are less straightforward cases. For Coreper,

legal information as well as information that makes sense of technical / expert data lead to

the most frequent interest group access. It stands to reason that Coreper, acting as a

gatekeeper to the Council by sending along only those pieces of proposed legislation that

require further debate, would be well served by information that is meant to make overly

technical information understandable.5 Access to CoR seems to be predicated on supplying

information about public opinion. As a channel for local authorities, regions, cities and

municipalities, CoR effectively serves as a hub for sub-state governmental actors. Thus, the

importance of information about public opinion might reflect the fact that this institution

ultimately represents sub-state level constituents. An electoral logic would make

information about public opinion valuable to members of CoR. Finally, there is no clear

information type that affords interest groups more or less access to EESC. This might be

indicative of the EESC dual mandate to represent both trade unions and civil society.

Importantly, the results for CoR and EESC should be used with greater caution that the

other results. Indeed, the amount of variance actually explained in these two models (as

expressed in the pseudo R2 scores) is very limited. This might be an indication that these

two consultative bodies only play a marginal role in the larger EU legislative process.

While lending some support to the assumptions in the literature, the regression

results for information type also reveal an interesting trend in informational lobbying in the

EU– namely, the preponderance, to speak with one interest group representative

interviewed for this study, “of evidence-based policymaking in the EU”.6 To understand this

trend it is useful to consider not only which types of information grant groups the most

access, but also simply which information types groups use most frequently. Graph 1

organises data to this end.

5 As Lewis (2006) explains, Coreper is responsible for preparing the Council’s agenda by dividing the work

into three categories: points where no ministerial decision is needed, points where decisions can be made

without debate and points where debate is need. Importantly, members of Coreper are more like political

generalists, at least when compared to ministers, and are “experts in the substantive questions” of each issue. 6 Interview, Paul Voss, Manger for Energy and Environment Policy, AEGPL Europe, Brussels, 16/11/2010

Page 15: Informational Lobbying Strategies and Interest Group Access in …€¦ · Informational Lobbying Strategies and Interest Group Access in the European Union Adam William Chalmers

14

(Graph 1 about here)

We can see that there is a stark difference between information about public opinion and

legal information and the remaining four information types. The point here is that evidence-

based policymaking in the EU has created a demand for data driven, technical information.

As one interest group representative explained: “It is no longer good enough to go to the

Commission or anyone else with a position that isn’t scientific in nature and that isn’t

reinforced by data.”7 As another interest group representative explained, “serious lobbying

has to be based on facts and figures. Just to say, ‘we want this’ and ‘we don’t want that’

amounts to nothing. The basis always has to be science.”8 In short, evidence-based

policymaking requires evidence-based lobbying. Hall and Deardorff’s explanation of US

interest groups serving more as “service bureaus” than as pressure and purchase lobbyists

seems to also apply to the EU context (2006). Indeed, under the conditions of information

exchange in the EU, where information is valuable only insofar as it is couched in “scientific

terms”, interest groups do appear to be providing a type of professionalized informational

service to decision-makers. What is more, the highly institutionalized nature of lobbying in

the EU seems to reinforce this trend. Interest groups lobbying through the online

consultation process, ad hoc committees or even Social Dialogue would find that evidence-

based lobbying is the more efficient way to secure access.

Evidence-based information is not only technical information. Clearly, legal

information and information about public opinion might also be loosely classified as

information that conveys technical details. Instead, information that decision-makers find

most useful has an explicit cause-effect logic highlighting the consequences of some

proposal. “We try to assess what would happen if such a proposal passed”9 according to one

interest group representative. “In very few cases,” to speak with another, “do we send just

raw data. We are always analyzing the possible consequences.”10 There are clear

advantages to transmitting this kind of information. Namely, by highlighting the feasibility

7 Interview, Paul Voss, Manger for Energy and Environment Policy, AEGPL Europe, Brussels, 16/11/2010. 8 Interview, Dr. Marlene Wartenberg, Director, Vier Pfoten, Brussels, 19/11/2010. 9 Interview, official, Bureau of Nordic Family Forestry, Brussels, 7/12/2009. 10 Interview, official, Ferrovie dello Stata, Brussel, 10/12/2009.

Page 16: Informational Lobbying Strategies and Interest Group Access in …€¦ · Informational Lobbying Strategies and Interest Group Access in the European Union Adam William Chalmers

15

of a proposal or its social and economic impact, an interest group is able to reduce the

perceived uncertainty of various policy outcomes. It is precisely this same uncertainty that

compels decision-makers to seek out interest group expertise in the first place. By contrast,

information about public opinion and legal information naturally place less stress on

assessing potential policy consequences. In particular, information about public opinion can

tell decision-makers where the political support lies but cannot help them realize the policy

outcome that will speak to this support. Without sound and more certain policy outcomes,

information about public opinion does not matter. This not only accounts for the infrequent

use of legal information and information about public opinion, but the fact that these

information types afford only very limited access to EU decision-makers.

Information Tactics

Regression results indicate that the tactics used to supply information to decision-

makers are more important, on balance, than information types. Tactics appear to be doing

most of the explanatory in all six models. In other words, and to turn a phrase, the medium

is more important than the message. Rasmusen, in a 1993 study of American lobbying,

already noted that the way that information is sent is linked to the persuasiveness and

perceived importance of the actual informational content. For instance, certain tactics have

a particular “attention-getting” value and can even be used to effectively transmit otherwise

content-less information. Similarly, tactics can be used to enhance the message contained in

the information. The frequent use of costly tactics, according to Potters and van Winden

(1992), increases the persuasiveness, political salience, importance and even reliability of

information. Lobbyists interviewed for this project admitted to using “a whole range of

strategies” to convey a single message. In many cases, the same basic informational content

is supplied using open consultation, writing position papers, emails, and public events.11

Part of the logic is, again, “frappez, frappez toujours”. Even more important, perhaps, is the

idea that sending the same information very frequently using different tactics says

something implicit about the seriousness and commitment of the interest group as well as

the urgency and importance of the message.

11 Interview, Illona Kish, Secretary General, Culture Action Europe, Brussels, 15/11/2009.

Page 17: Informational Lobbying Strategies and Interest Group Access in …€¦ · Informational Lobbying Strategies and Interest Group Access in the European Union Adam William Chalmers

16

One of the central findings of this analysis is that outside tactics are not nearly as

marginalized as the literature predicts. Indeed, the regression results indicate that

launching media campaigns and organising public events, despite being costly, are key

determinants of interest group access to all six EU decision-making bodies. This is not to

say, however, that inside strategies are somehow less important. In fact, many inside

strategies considered here are important determinants of access as well. Clearly, the results

provide support for the notion that using a large repertory of tactics is always better than

using just one tactic (Baumgartner and Leech 1998; Beyers 2004). What still needs to be

explained, however, is why outside strategies, in addition to inside strategies, are so

important for gaining access.

To answer this question, first consider which tactics interest groups in the EU tend

to use most frequently (graph 2).

(Graph 2 about here)

We can see that, while outside tactics might be important determinants of access, they are

used only very infrequently when compared to inside tactics. Typical inside tactics, like

writing emails and letters, participating in open consultation, and face-to-face meetings are

simply used far more frequently than launching media campaigns or organising public

events. Interest groups tend to turn to these inside tactics more frequently not because they

are less costly than outside tactics, but because they are more expedient. According to

lobbyists interviewed for this project, there is an important premium on providing timely

information in the EU. Information that is too late loses all of its value. The idea, according

to one lobbyist, is to be in the policy-making process “right from the start at the earliest

possible stage because when you have a written proposal it is always more difficult to

change it.”12 Thus, emails, phone calls and simple letters are favoured over tactics that

require organisation, planning and, in some case, the raising of funds.

But the fact that outside strategies are use sparingly does not explain their impact on

access patterns. I argue that the costliness and infrequent use of outside tactics explain

their relevance for access. In fact, outside tactics have become the main way of EU interest

12 Interview, Martin Romer, General Secretary, ETUCE (European Trade Union Committee for Education), Brussels, 17/11/2010.

Page 18: Informational Lobbying Strategies and Interest Group Access in …€¦ · Informational Lobbying Strategies and Interest Group Access in the European Union Adam William Chalmers

17

groups to add value to or otherwise increase the salience of a single message. Part of the

issue is the relative devaluation of inside tactics. EU decision-makers, fully aware of the

informational asymmetry that defines their relationship with interest groups, seek to

ensure a steady and reliable stream of policy-relevant information. Social Dialogue, many

formal and ad hoc committees, the online open consultation process as well as the

Commission’s legal mandate to “consult widely” with interest groups during the agenda

setting stage of the policy process serve this function (European Commission 2007). These

mechanisms necessarily require the exclusive use of inside tactics. In a sense, inside tactics

have also been institutionalized and their use has lost its potential to add value to

informational content. The result is that outside tactics like media campaigns and public

events become the primarily way for certain interest groups to get the upper-hand on other

groups, to ensure that their voices are heard the loudest and that the importance and

urgency of their message is most effectively conveyed.

Outside tactics are not outsider tactics. They are not, as assumed in some of the

literature, reserved for “those associations on the periphery of the political system” and

which are “disadvantaged in the policy process” (Beyers 2004: 216). Outside tactics are just

as feasible as inside tactics, and when it comes to access, perhaps even more so. All of this

reflects a larger trend towards the professionalization of lobbying in the EU (Lahusen 2002;

Maloney 2009). Lobbying in the EU is less and less about shouting slogans and waving

banners. Instead, it is about approaching the policymaking process as policy experts and

speaking the language of decision-makers.

Conclusion

The following has sought to shed some light on the informational determinants of

interest group access to the EU. It has addressed the “piecemeal” nature of the existing

literature, which focuses almost exclusively on demand-side factors, by examining the

supply-side factors of informational lobbying. Understanding a group’s capacity to meet the

informational needs of EU decision-makers is crucial for assessing interest group access to

the EU policymaking process.

An empirical analysis based on interview and survey data turn up three main

findings. First, regression results show that access is largely related to meeting the specific

Page 19: Informational Lobbying Strategies and Interest Group Access in …€¦ · Informational Lobbying Strategies and Interest Group Access in the European Union Adam William Chalmers

18

informational needs of decision-makers, thus bearing out some of the central assumptions

in the existing literature. The most important distinction to make with regard to

information type is not whether it is technical in nature as opposed to politically salient, but

whether or not it is couched in a specific cause-effect logic. Second, regression results also

suggest that how information is conveyed to decision-makers is more important than the

actual content of the information. The medium is more important than the message. Groups

can increase access to the various EU decision-making bodies by sending the same

information using multiple tactics and increasing the salience and urgency of information

by frequently using specific tactics. Finally, this analysis has provided evidence that both

inside and outside tactics relate to greater access to the EU. While inside tactics are used

very frequently and outside tactics very sparingly, both can be used by groups to increase

frequency of access to EU decision-makers. This result suggests that, contrary to much of

the existing literature, outside tactics are not inherently less effective than inside tactics.

Outside tactics, in other words, are not necessarily outsider tactics.

This analysis marks a first attempt to provide a supply-side analysis of the

informational determinants of access. Its central findings must be measured against its

limitations. First, and perhaps most important, is the fact that there is missing data on

several important interest group types. A complete picture of supply-side factors would

need to include data on these missing groups. A second limitation is related to the restricted

scope of this analysis: namely, the informational determinants of access. This could be a

point for future research. How, for instance, do non-informational determinants of access

factor in? Finally, a study of access and access patterns is necessarily limited in what it can

say about interest group influence or success in the policymaking process. Access might be

essential to getting what you want, but it not a guarantee that preferences get translated

into policy outcomes. This last point, however, is representative of the larger problem of

measuring interest group influence.

Page 20: Informational Lobbying Strategies and Interest Group Access in …€¦ · Informational Lobbying Strategies and Interest Group Access in the European Union Adam William Chalmers

19

TABLES AND GRAPHS

Table 1

Distribution of Online Survey Responses by Interest Group Type

Interest Group Type Frequency Percent

Companies 44 14.29

Professional Associations 73 23.70

Public Affairs Consultancies 30 9.74

Trade Unions 28 9.08

Chambers of Commerce 4 1.30

Law Firms 0 0

Academic organisations 2 0.65

NGOs/Association of NGOs 78 25.32

Think-Tanks 4 1.30

Representatives of religions, churches and communities of conviction 1 0.32

Public Authorities (regions, cities, municipalities) 34 11.04

Other 10 3.25

Total 308 100.00

Page 21: Informational Lobbying Strategies and Interest Group Access in …€¦ · Informational Lobbying Strategies and Interest Group Access in the European Union Adam William Chalmers

20

Table 2

The Informational Determinants of Interest Group Access to the EU

EC EP Council Coreper CoR EESC

Types public opinion 1 (.13) .95 (.12) .94 (.11) .89 (.11) 1.41

(.17)**

1.1 (.13)

economic

impact

1 (.18) 1 (.16) 1.06 (.16) .92 (.15) .88 (.14) 1.1 (.18)

social impact 1 (.15) 1.45

(.19)**

1.09 (.14) 1.16 (.15) .99 (.13) .97 (.12)

legal

information

.85 (.11) 1.2 (.15) 1.4 (.17)** 1.5 (.19)** 1.2 (.15) 1.1 (.13)

feasibility

information

1.5 (.27)** 1 (.16) .76 (.12) 1 (.16) .8 (.12) .76 (.12)

information

making sense of

technical/expert

data

1 (.14) .96 (.11) 1.06( .12) 1.48

(.18)**

1.08 (.13) .92 (.1)

Tactics face-to-face 1.39 (.24)* 1.5

(.25)**

2.9 (.55)** 1.42

(.25)*

.79 (.14) .94 (.16)

open

consultation

1.49 (.22)** 1.35

(.19)*

1.09 (.16) 1.05 (.16) 1 (.14) 1.17 (.16)

write letter 1.3 (.19) 1.37

(.19)*

1.5 (.22)** 1.1 (.15) 1.1 (.15) .96 (.13)

write email 1.03 (.19) .96 (.16) .62 (.11)** .52 (.1)** .9 (.16) 1.49

(.28)*

phone call 1.22 (.19) 1.45

(.21)**

1.19 (.17) 1.45 (.1)** 1.3 (.2) .8 (.12)

media campaign .73 (.09)** .96 (.12) 1.35

(.16)**

1.2 (.15)* .79 (.1) 1.46

(.17)**

public event 1.5 (.22)** 1.6

(.23)**

.85 (.11) .96 (.14) 1.5

(.22)**

1.17 (.16)

Log likelihood -248.15 -290.53 -312.99 -303.81 -310.7 -335.06

LR chi2 (13) 134.70 173.55 140.44 91.9 34.58 39.24

Pseudo R2 .21 .23 .18 .13 .052 .055

N 256 256 252 250 252 255

Note: entries are ordered logistic coefficients with standard errors in parentheses.

*p<0.05; **p<0.01.

Page 22: Informational Lobbying Strategies and Interest Group Access in …€¦ · Informational Lobbying Strategies and Interest Group Access in the European Union Adam William Chalmers

21

Graph 1

Graph 2

Page 23: Informational Lobbying Strategies and Interest Group Access in …€¦ · Informational Lobbying Strategies and Interest Group Access in the European Union Adam William Chalmers

22

REFERENCES

Ainsworth, Scott (1993) ‘Regulating Lobbyists and Interest Group Influence’, The Journal of

Politics 55(1): 41-56.

Austen-Smith, David (1993) ‘Information and Influence: Lobbying for Agendas and Votes’,

American Journal of Political Science, 34(3): 799-833.

Baumgartner, Frank R. and Leech, Beth L. (1998) Basic Interests. The Importance of Groups

in Politics and in Political Science, Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University Press.

Baumgartner, Frank R. et al., (2009) Lobbying and Policy Change: Who Wins, Who Loses, and

Why, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

Berkhout, Joost and Lowery, David (2008) ‘Counting organized interests in the European

Union: A comparison of data sources’, Journal of European Public Policy, 15(4): 489- 513.

Beyers, Jan (2002) ‘Gaining and Seeking Access: The European Adaptation of Domestic

Interest Associations’, European Journal of Political Research, 41: 585-612.

Beyers, Jan (2004) ‘Voice and Access. Political Practices of European Interest Associations’,

European Union Politics, 5(2): 211-240.

Binderkrantz, Anne (2005) ‘Interest Group Strategies: Navigating between Privileged

Access and Strategies of Pressure’, Political Studies, 53: 694-715.

Bouwen, Pieter (2002) ‘Corporate lobbying in the European Union: the logic of access’,

Journal of European Public Policy, 9(3): 365-390.

Bouwen, Pieter (2004a) ‘Exchanging access goods for access: A comparative study of

business lobbying in the European Union institutions’, European Journal of Political

Research, 43: 337-369.

Bouwen, Pieter (2004b) ‘The Logic of Access to the European Parliament: Business

Lobbying in the Committee on Economic and Monetary Affairs’, Journal of Common Market

Studies, 42(3): 473-95.

Bouwen, Pieter (2009) ‘The European Commission’, in D. Coen and J. Richardson (eds.),

Lobbying the European Union: Institutions, Actors, and Issues, Oxford: Oxford University

Press, pp. 19-38.

Broscheid, Andreas and David Coen (2002) Insider and Outsider Lobbying of the European

Commission. An Informational Model of Forum Politics, European Union Politics, 4(2), pp.

165-189.

Carpenter, Daniel, Kevin Esterling and David Lazer (1998) ‘The Strength of Weak ties in

Lobbying Networks’, Journal of Theoretical Politics, 10(4): 417-444.

Page 24: Informational Lobbying Strategies and Interest Group Access in …€¦ · Informational Lobbying Strategies and Interest Group Access in the European Union Adam William Chalmers

23

Chalmers, Adam W. (2011) ‘Interests, Information and Influence: A Comparative Analysis of

Interest Group Influence in the European Union’, Journal of European Integration, 33(4),

forthcoming.

European Commission (2007) Treaty of Lisbon, Official Journal of the European Union, 50.

Available online: http://eur-lex.europa.eu/JOHtml.do?uri=OJ:C:2007:306:SOM:EN:HTML

Crawford, Vincent P. and Sobel, Joel (1982) ‘Strategic Information Transmission’,

Econometrica, 50(6): 1431-1451.

Crombez, Christophe (2002) ‘Information, Lobbying and the Legislative Process in the

European Union’, European Union Politics, 3(1): 7-32

Dür, Andreas and Dirk De Bièvre (2007a) The Question of Interest Group Influence, Journal

of Public Policy, 21(1), pp. 1-12.

Dür, Andreas and De Bièvre, Dirk (2007b) ‘Inclusion without influence? NGOs in European

Trade Policy’, Journal of Public Policy, 27(1): 79-101.

Eising, Rainer (2007a) ‘The access of business interests in to EU institutions: toward élite

pluralism’, Journal of European Public Policy, 14(3): 384-403.

Eising, Rainer (2007b) ‘Institutional Context, Organizational Resources and Strategic

Choices’, European Union Politics, 8(3): 329-362.

Eising, Rainer (2008) Interest groups in EU policy-making, Living Rev. Euro. Gov. 3(4),

online article: cited June 2010, http://www.livingreviews.org/lreg-2008-4

Esterling, Kevin M., (2004) The Political Economy of Expertise. Information and Efficiency in

American National Politics, Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

Gerber, Elizabeth (1999) The Populist Paradox: Interest Group Influence and the Promise of

Direct Legislation, Princeton: Princeton University Press.

Grossman, Gene M. and Elhanan Helpman (2001) Special Interest Politics (Cambridge, M.A.:

MIT Press).

Hall, Richard A. and Deardorff, Alan V. (2006) ‘Lobbying as Legislative Subsidy’, American

Political Science Review, 100(1): 69-84.

Hayes-Renshaw, Fiona (2009) ‘Least Accessible but not Inaccessible: Lobbying the Council

and the European Council’, in D. Coen and J. Richardson (eds.), Lobbying the European

Union: Institutions, Actors, and Issues, Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp.70-88.

Heinz, John P. et al., (1993) The Hollow Core: Private Interests in National Policy Making,

Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

Page 25: Informational Lobbying Strategies and Interest Group Access in …€¦ · Informational Lobbying Strategies and Interest Group Access in the European Union Adam William Chalmers

24

Hojnacki, Marie and Kimball, David C. (1998) ‘Organized Interests and the Decision of

Whom to Lobby in Congress’, American Political Science Review, 92 (4): 775-790.

Knoke, David (1990) Organizing Collective Action: The Political Economies of Associations,

New York: Aldine de Gruyter.

Kollman, Ken (1998) Outside Lobbying. Public Opinion and Interest Group Strategies,

Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University Press.

Lahusen, Christian (2002) Commercial Consultancies in the European Union: the shape and

structure of professional interest intermediation, Journal of European Public Policy, 9(5), pp.

695-714.

Landmarks (2008) The European Public Affairs Directory, Brussels: Landmarks Publishing.

Lehmann, Wilhelm (2009) ‘The European Parliament’, in D. Coen and J. Richardson (eds.),

Lobbying the European Union: Institutions, Actors, and Issues, Oxford: Oxford University

Press, pp. 39-69.

Lewis, Jeffrey (2006) ‘National Interests. Coreper’, in John Peterson and Michael Shackelton

(eds.), The Institutions of the European Union, second edition, Oxford: Oxford University

Press, pp. 272-292.

Mahoney, Christine (2008) Brussels versus the Beltway. Advocacy in the United States and the

European Union, Washington: Georgetown University Press.

Maloney, William (2009) Interest Groups and the Revitalisation of Democracy: Are We

Expecting too Much?, Representation, 45(3), pp.277-287.

Michalowitz, Irina (2004) EU Lobbying – Principals, Agents and Targets. Strategic Interest

Intermediation in EU Policy-Making, Münster, Germany: LIT Verlag.

Pappi, Franz U and Henning, Christian H.C.A (1999) ‘The organization of influence on the

EC’s common agricultural policy: A network approach’, European Journal of Political

Research, 36: 257-281.

Potters, Jan and Frans van Winden (1990) Modelling Political Pressure as Transmission of

Information, European Journal of Political Economy, 6, pp. 61-88.

Potters, Jan and Frans van Winden (1992) Lobbying and Asymmetric Information, Public

Choice, 74, pp. 269-292.

Rasmusen, Eric (1993) Lobbying when the decisionmaker can acquire independent

information, Public Choice, 77, pp. 899-913.

Page 26: Informational Lobbying Strategies and Interest Group Access in …€¦ · Informational Lobbying Strategies and Interest Group Access in the European Union Adam William Chalmers

25

Schlozman, Kay Lehman, and Tierney, John (1986) Organized Interests and American

Democracy, New York: Harper and Row.

Schneider, F. and Naumann, J. (1982) ‘Interest groups in democracies - How influential are

they?: An empirical examination for Switzerland’, Public Choice, 42:281-303.

Van Schendelen, Rinus (2005) Machiavelli in Brussels. The Art of Lobbying the EU

(Amsterdam: Amsterdam University Press.

Walker, Jack (1991) Mobilizing Interest Groups in America, Ann Arbor: University of

Michigan Press.

Zeigler, H. and Baer, M. (1969) Lobbying: Interaction and influence in American State

Legislatures. Belmont: Wadsworth.