information asymmetry, accounting standards, and

219
Information Asymmetry, Accounting Standards, and Accounting Conservatism A thesis submitted to The University of Manchester for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy in the Faculty of Humanities. 2017 Mostafa Harakeh Alliance Manchester Business School

Upload: others

Post on 09-Jan-2022

2 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Information Asymmetry, Accounting Standards,

and Accounting Conservatism

A thesis submitted to The University of Manchester for the degree of

Doctor of Philosophy

in the Faculty of Humanities.

2017

Mostafa Harakeh

Alliance Manchester Business School

2

Table of Contents

ABSTRACT .......................................................................................................................... 5

DECLARATION .................................................................................................................. 6

COPYRIGHT STATEMENT ............................................................................................. 6

DEDICATION ...................................................................................................................... 7

ACKNOWLEDGMENTS ................................................................................................... 8

CHAPTER 1. INTRODUCTION ....................................................................................... 9

CHAPTER 2. DOES CHANGING ACCOUNTING STANDARDS AFFECT

DIVIDEND POLICY? ....................................................................................................... 14

2.1. Introduction ............................................................................................................. 15

2.2. Motivation & Literature Review ........................................................................... 18

2.2.1. IFRS, Legal Systems and Accounting Quality .................................................. 18

2.2.2. Dividend Payout Policy and the Information Environment ............................... 21

2.2.3. Dividend Value Relevance and the Information Environment .......................... 22

2.3. Hypothesis Development ........................................................................................ 23

2.4. Research Methodology............................................................................................ 27

2.4.1. Dividend Payout Regression Model .................................................................. 27

2.4.2. Dividend Payout Regressions among Code-law Firms ...................................... 29

2.4.3. Dividend Value Relevance Regression Model .................................................. 31

2.5. Data & Descriptive Statistics.................................................................................. 32

2.5.1. Sample Construction .......................................................................................... 32

2.5.2. Descriptive Statistics .......................................................................................... 33

2.6. Empirical Results .................................................................................................... 36

2.6.1. Dividend Payout following IFRS ....................................................................... 36

2.6.2. Dividend Payout among Code-Law Firms ......................................................... 40

2.6.3. Dividend Value Relevance following IFRS ....................................................... 43

2.7. Conclusion ................................................................................................................ 44

References: ...................................................................................................................... 46

Appendix A: Variable Definitions (sorted alphabetically) ......................................... 50

Appendix B: Accounting Quality Metrics ................................................................... 52

CHAPTER 3. DOES CHANGING ACCOUNTING STANDARDS AFFECT

EQUITY FINANCING? .................................................................................................... 80

3.1. Introduction ............................................................................................................. 81

3.2. Motivation & Literature Review ........................................................................... 84

3.2.1. IFRS and Information Asymmetry in the SEO Setting ...................................... 84

3.2.2. Earnings Management around SEOs ................................................................. 85

3.2.3. The Market Reaction and the Propensity to Issue SEOs.................................... 86

3

3.3. Hypothesis Development ........................................................................................ 88

3.4. Research Methodology............................................................................................ 91

3.4.1. Test of Earnings Management ........................................................................... 91

3.4.2. Test of SEO Market Reaction ............................................................................ 94

3.4.3. Test of Propensity to Issue Equity ..................................................................... 96

3.5. Data & Descriptive Statistics.................................................................................. 97

3.5.1. Sample Construction .......................................................................................... 97

3.5.2. Descriptive Statistics .......................................................................................... 98

3.6. Empirical Results .................................................................................................. 102

3.6.1. Earnings Management around SEOs ............................................................... 102

3.6.2. Market Reaction to SEOs ................................................................................. 104

3.6.3. Propensity to Issue New Equity ....................................................................... 107

3.6.4. Robustness Checks ........................................................................................... 108

3.7. Conclusion .............................................................................................................. 110

References: .................................................................................................................... 112

Appendix A: Variable Definitions (sorted alphabetically) ....................................... 116

Appendix B: Calculation of DACC and REM ........................................................... 118

Appendix C: Sample Construction ............................................................................. 120

CHAPTER 4. THE BIAS IN MEASURING CONDITIONAL CONSERVATISM . 151

4.1. Introduction ........................................................................................................... 152

4.2. Motivation & Literature Review ......................................................................... 155

4.2.1. Accounting Conservatism ................................................................................ 155

4.2.2. Asymmetric Timeliness Measures of Conditional Conservatism .................... 156

4.2.3. The Source of Bias in the AT Measure ............................................................ 158

4.2.4. An Alternative Measure of Conditional Conservatism .................................... 162

4.3. Hypothesis Development ...................................................................................... 164

4.3.1. The Bias in the AT Measure ............................................................................ 164

4.3.2. Assessing the Potential Bias in the C_Score Measure ..................................... 165

4.3.3. The AT Measure in an Interrupted Time-series Research Design ................... 166

4.3.4. The AT Measure in a Cross-sectional Research Design .................................. 167

4.4. Data & Descriptive Statistics................................................................................ 168

4.5. Research Designs and Results .............................................................................. 170

4.5.1. The Unconditional Relation between AT and VR ........................................... 170

4.5.2. Test Statistics for Comparing AT and VR Measures ....................................... 171

4.5.3. Examination of Conservatism Measures .......................................................... 172

4.5.3.1. Comparing the Scale Effect in AT and VR – (H1) ................................... 172

4.5.3.2. Comparing AT and VR across the Constituents of CSCORE – (H2-H5) 173

4.5.4. Comparing AT and VR in Interrupted Time-series Settings – (H6) ................ 177

4

4.5.4.1. André, Filip and Paugam (2015) – (H6) ................................................... 177

4.5.4.2. Lobo & Zhou (2006) – (H6)...................................................................... 179

4.5.5. Comparing AT and VR in Cross-sectional Settings – (H7a & H7b) ............... 181

4.5.5.1. Ball, Sadka and Robin (2008) – (H7a) ...................................................... 181

4.5.5.2. Gassen, Fulbier and Sellhorn (2006) – (H7a & H7b) ............................... 184

4.6. Conclusion .............................................................................................................. 188

References: .................................................................................................................... 189

Appendix A: Variable Definitions (sorted alphabetically by section) ..................... 192

CHAPTER 5. SUMMARY AND SUGGESTIONS FOR FUTURE RESEARCH .... 217

This thesis contains 53,040 including title page, tables, and footnotes.

5

Abstract

The University of Manchester

Mostafa Harakeh

Doctor of Philosophy (PhD)

Information Asymmetry, Accounting Standards, and Accounting Conservatism

2 April 2017

This thesis consists of three self-contained essays, each assessing the interaction between

financial accounting and information asymmetry from a different aspect. In the first two

essays, I examine how a change in the information environment affects the behavior of

market participants. In the third essay, I evaluate the empirical measurement of conditional

conservatism in accounting data. Together, these studies contribute to the understanding of

the role of financial reporting in mitigating the information gap between stakeholders.

In the first essay, I explore the impact of the mandatory adoption of the International

Financial Reporting Standards (IFRS) on dividend payout policy and the value relevance

of dividends in two Western European economies. I select the UK as a major common-law

country (control group) and France as a code-law country (treatment group) in order to

implement a difference-in-differences methodology. My findings suggest that IFRS

adoption is a major contributor in increasing dividend payouts among code-law firms,

compared to common-law firms, due to a greater reduction in information asymmetry

following the IFRS mandate. This makes investors in code-law firms more willing to rely

on accounting measures of firm performance, thereby causing a significant and material

decrease in dividend value relevance among code-law firms relative to common-law firms.

In the second essay, I examine the potential for IFRS to influence the market for SEOs. I

utilize a difference-in-differences methodology, where the UK (i.e. common-law firms) is

the control group and France (i.e. code-law firms) is the treatment group. I argue that IFRS

adoption serves to mitigate information asymmetry and improve accounting quality.

Accordingly, I find that, following IFRS adoption, earnings management activities

decrease among code-law firms prior to issuing SEOs. As a result of the lower levels of

earnings management and information asymmetry, I predict and find that the market

reaction to issuing SEOs improves significantly for code-law firms following IFRS. Given

that equity financing becomes less costly, I find that the propensity to issue new SEOs

increases among code-law firms after IFRS adoption.

In the third and final essay, I examine the empirical measurement of conditional

conservatism (CC) in accounting data. Prior studies have raised serious concerns about the

bias in the asymmetric timeliness (AT) measure of CC. This measure, along with the

C_Score measure, underpins a large body of empirical research on CC. Thus I endeavor to

assess the extent to which prior literature may need to be revised because of its reliance on

these measures. In exploring this issue, I replicate prior studies that rely on the AT or the

C_Score measure, and then compare the replicated results with those generated by

applying the variance ratio (VR) measure of CC, proposed by Dutta & Patatoukas (2017). I

show that the AT and the VR measures are associated unconditionally. Furthermore, my

findings suggest that the observed variation in the C_Score measure is driven by variation

in the bias implicit in the AT measure rather than variation in CC. I also provide evidence

showing that the AT measure yields similar conclusions to the VR measure in research

designs that model the change in CC following an exogenous change in accounting policy;

however, I find that using the AT measure to document cross-sectional differences in CC is

highly likely to have given rise to invalid conclusions in a large number of studies.

6

Declaration

No portion of the work referred to in the thesis has been submitted in support of an

application for another degree or qualification of this or any other university or other

institute of learning.

Copyright Statement

i. The author of this thesis (including any appendices and/or schedules to this thesis) owns

certain copyright or related rights in it (the “Copyright”) and s/he has given The University

of Manchester certain rights to use such Copyright, including for administrative purposes.

ii. Copies of this thesis, either in full or in extracts and whether in hard or electronic copy,

may be made only in accordance with the Copyright, Designs and Patents Act 1988 (as

amended) and regulations issued under it or, where appropriate, in accordance with

licensing agreements which the University has from time to time. This page must form part

of any such copies made.

iii. The ownership of certain Copyright, patents, designs, trademarks and other intellectual

property (the “Intellectual Property”) and any reproductions of copyright works in the

thesis, for example graphs and tables (“Reproductions”), which may be described in this

thesis, may not be owned by the author and may be owned by third parties. Such

Intellectual Property and Reproductions cannot and must not be made available for use

without the prior written permission of the owner(s) of the relevant Intellectual Property

and/or Reproductions.

iv. Further information on the conditions under which disclosure, publication and

commercialisation of this thesis, the Copyright and any Intellectual Property and/or

Reproductions described in it may take place is available in the University IP Policy (see

http://documents.manchester.ac.uk/DocuInfo.aspx?DocID=487), in any relevant Thesis

restriction declarations deposited in the University Library, The University Library’s

regulations (see http://www.manchester.ac.uk/library/aboutus/regulations) and in The

University’s policy on Presentation of Theses.

7

Dedication

I dedicate this work to my wife, who has faithfully loved me and supported me unconditionally,

Ghida

8

Acknowledgments

Writing this section was as difficult as writing a full chapter of this thesis. In what follows,

I express my indebtedness to everyone who helped and supported me, directly or

indirectly, to successfully complete my PhD. I love you all from the bottom of my heart.

First and foremost, I shall express my heartfelt gratitude to the holy God, Allah. I know

that you have granted me more than I deserve because you are generous and gracious, not

because I am worthy of your countless blessings. I promise you that I will employ the

graces you have endued me with to serve only righteous deeds.

To my great supervisors, Prof. Martin Walker and Prof. Edward Lee, you are just

awesome. I learned a lot from you, more than you can imagine. You made me believe that

the value of any PhD is derived from its supervisors in the first place. Your wisdom,

guidance, intelligence, and support have made my PhD journey one of the most

overwhelming experiences in my life. On top of that, I admire the humane attitude you

have always shown in several incidents. This only makes me respect you more and

appreciate how lucky I was when you accepted me to pursue my doctoral degree under

your supervision. I must also thank my internal and external examiners, respectively, Prof.

Norman Strong and Prof. Colin Clubb, for agreeing to examine my thesis. Indeed, being

examined by such reputable professors gives my PhD more value and credibility.

To my good friend Nikos, no words can express how grateful I am for your presence in

my life during my stay in the UK. You are a true friend that one can count on. I am proud

to have such a loyal and smart friend, with whom I can share my personal matters and

collaborate throughout my academic career. Also, to my friends in Lebanon, to the best

friends a man can have, our WhatsApp chats and Skype calls have made my journey away

from home much easier. Thank you for your support and prayers; I love you guys.

To my brother Maytham, thank you for being a good friend and a loving brother at

once. I will always be there for you when you need me, just like you have always been to

me. To my nerdy sister, Mira, you are the joy of our family. You will always have my full

support in fulfilling your promising academic ambitions. And to my kind-hearted father,

thank you for shaping my personality and for giving me your bright mind.

The famous poet William Ross Wallace says “The hand that rocks the cradle is the hand

that rules the world”; my mother is indeed one of those mothers who Mr. Wallace was

referring to. To the most caring, affectionate, and loving mother, no words can express

how much I love and admire you. The best years of your life went by while holding my

hand and doing all it takes to make that kid become a man – a man you can be proud of. I

hope that one day I will be able to compensate for a small part of your unlimited sacrifice.

Last but definitely not least, to the only girl I have ever loved, to the girl who has stood

by my side at all times, to the blessing of my life, to my best friend, to Ghida, thank you

for believing in me and for patiently spending four years waiting for me to come back. It is

said that outstanding accomplishments start with a dream. Ghida had this dream for me and

she made all it takes to make this dream come true. Without Ghida’s motivation and

support in getting this PhD, I wouldn’t have been writing these words now.

Mostafa Harakeh

Manchester, April 2017

9

Chapter 1

Introduction

In his famous paper “The Market for Lemons”, the Nobel Prize Laureate George

Akerlof started in 1970 a long standing literature on the economic consequences of

information asymmetry (Akerlof, 1970). Since its introduction to the field of financial

economics, the concept of information asymmetry has played a major role in accounting

and finance research (see the surveys of Biais, Glosten, & Spatt, 2005; Healy & Palepu,

2001). Scott (2015, p. 137) states that information asymmetry is undoubtedly the most

important concept of financial accounting theory. Information asymmetry derives its

critical role in financial markets from the fact that severe levels of asymmetric

information might lead to a complete collapse of markets. A recent example is the so-

called subprime crisis in 2008 (Ryan, 2008, p. 1626). Given these tragic consequences,

regulators and accounting standard setters strive to mitigate information asymmetry

through enforcing policies and financial reporting standards which aim to diminish the

information gap between market participants.

As far as the financial accounting research is concerned, financial reporting and

disclosure affect information asymmetry, which in turn influences economic decisions

made by market participants. In general, there are two kinds of market participants in an

information asymmetry setting: insiders and outsiders. I refer to managers and informed

(institutional) investors as insiders and to less informed (individual) investors as

outsiders. In capital markets, information asymmetry exists because of two main

problems: moral hazard and adverse selection. Moral hazard problems arise when

insiders misuse the firm resources to serve personal interests rather than maximizing the

firm value (i.e., hidden action). Such problems are exacerbated when outsiders do not

have enough information to monitor the economic decisions taken by insiders. Adverse

selection problems arise when one side of a potential economic transaction has relevant

information that the other side does not have (i.e., hidden information). Such problems

10

negatively affect investment efficiency and capital allocation and, accordingly, increase

the deadweight loss in the society.

A fundamental role of financial reporting is to mitigate moral hazard and adverse

selection problems through diminishing the informational gap between insiders and

outsiders (Mora & Walker, 2015). This brings the existing firm value closer to its

fundamental value (Scott, 2015, p. 141). In the same context, my thesis examines the

interaction between financial accounting and information asymmetry from three

different aspects. This thesis is structured around three self-contained essays in Chapters

2, 3, and 4. These essays examine original and different research questions, have

separate literature reviews, and exploit different datasets. While I recommend reading

each chapter independently, yet the concept of information asymmetry keeps a coherent

theme across all chapters. Chapters 2 and 3 examine how the behavior of market

participants changes following a positive information shock caused by the mandatory

adoption of the International Financial Reporting Standards (IFRS). This exogenous

improvement in the supplied information mitigates information asymmetry and reduces

the frictional costs of financial transactions between insiders and outsiders. In Chapter

4, I assess the measurement of a major feature of financial reporting: conditional

accounting conservatism. Conditional conservatism is a financial reporting attribute that

is meant to mitigate information asymmetry arising from adverse selection and moral

hazard problems. Specifically, investors (i.e. shareholders and bondholders) need to

assess their investment payoffs based on conservative estimations of firms’ net assets

due to their incomplete information (Balakrishnan, Watts, & Zuo, 2016). I re-examine

the empirical measurement of conditional conservatism in accounting data, which was

initially introduced in Basu (1997), in light of a contemporary study by Dutta &

Patatoukas (2017). I briefly discuss the three essays below.

In the first essay, I examine the effect of the mandatory adoption of IFRS on aspects

of dividend policy. Myers & Majluf (1984) theorize that, under information asymmetry,

11

firms pay less dividends due to high costs associated with external financing. I test

whether the reduction in information asymmetry, following the mandatory adoption of

IFRS, encourages managers to pay more dividends due to a reduction in financing costs.

At the same time, the mandatory adoption of IFRS is expected to improve accounting

quality especially in situations where accounting standards are of low quality. This

improvement in the quality of accounting numbers is expected to decrease dividend

value relevance while increasing accounting value relevance. That is, the signaling

power of dividends decreases following IFRS adoption. The empirical results I report

are consistent with the previous hypotheses. Specifically, I find an increase in the level

of dividend payout following IFRS adoption, especially among firms that had lower

accounting quality in the pre-IFRS period. In addition, I find a simultaneous change in

the value relevance of accounting line items and dividends following IFRS adoption,

where accounting value relevance increases while dividend value relevance decreases.

The second essay is sequel to the first, where I examine the effect of mandatory

adoption of IFRS on aspects of equity financing. As mentioned earlier, Myers & Majluf

(1984) theorize that external financing is costly under asymmetric information. I

examine whether the frictional costs associated with equity financing becomes less

pervasive following the IFRS mandate. Specifically, previous studies document that

managers engage in aggressive earnings management activities prior to issuing equity in

an attempt to elevate the value of the offered stocks (e.g., Teoh, Welch, & Wong, 1998).

I first examine whether the level of earnings management activities prior to issuing

equity decreases following IFRS adoption. Then I examine if the change in the levels of

earnings management and information asymmetry improves the market reaction to

issuing new equity. Finally, the change in the market reaction to equity financing is

expected to affect firms’ propensity to issue new equity. Consistent with the preceding

hypotheses, I find that the level of earnings management prior to issuing equity

decreases following IFRS adoption. This finding is significant in situations where the

12

accounting quality was relatively low before IFRS adoption. Then, I provide evidence

suggesting that the market reaction to issuing new equity improves significantly

following IFRS adoption due to the reduction in levels of information asymmetry and

earnings management. Finally, the improved market reaction indicates a reduction in the

cost associated with equity financing and, accordingly, I provide evidence showing an

increase in the propensity to issue new equity following IFRS.

In the third essay, I re-examine the empirical estimation of conditional conservatism

in accounting data. The accounting conservatism literature relies mainly on the

asymmetric timeliness (AT) measure of conditional conservatism, proposed by Basu

(1997), and on the derivative measure of Khan & Watts (2009), the C_Score measure.

Recent studies show a considerable bias in the AT measure (Dietrich, Muller, & Riedl,

2007; Patatoukas & Thomas, 2011, 2016). I extend these studies and use the variance

ratio (VR) measure, proposed by Dutta & Patatoukas (2017), to show that the bias in the

AT measure also applies to the C_Score measure. In addition, I re-examine prior studies

and find that the AT and the VR measures yield similar conclusions when used in time-

series settings that model the change in conditional conservatism for the same sample

following an exogenous change in accounting policy. On the other hand, I provide

evidence suggesting that the use of the AT measure to document cross-sectional

differences in conditional conservatism is highly likely to have given rise to invalid

conclusions about the role of accounting conservatism in capital markets. In conclusion

to this chapter, I find that a large number of prior studies that model cross-sectional

variations in conditional conservatism using the AT measure needs to be revised in light

of the VR measure.

Overall, the three empirical studies in this thesis contribute to the market-based

accounting research literature by improving our understanding of how financial

reporting affects the information gap between insiders and outsiders in capital markets.

13

References:

Akerlof, G. (1970). The Market for "Lemons": Quality Uncertainty and the

Market Mechanism. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 84(3), 488–500.

Balakrishnan, K., Watts, R., & Zuo, L. (2016). The effect of accounting conservatism on

corporate investment during the Global Financial Crisis. Journal of Business Finance

& Accounting, 43(5–6), 513–542.

Basu, S. (1997). The conservatism principle and the asymmetric timeliness of earnings.

Journal of Accounting and Economics, 24(1), 3–37.

Biais, B., Glosten, L., & Spatt, C. (2005). Market microstructure: A survey of

microfoundations, empirical results, and policy implications. Journal of Financial

Markets, 8(2), 217–264.

Dietrich, D., Muller, K., & Riedl, E. (2007). Asymmetric timeliness tests of accounting

conservatism. Review of Accounting Studies, 12(1), 95–124.

Dutta, S., & Patatoukas, P. (2017). Identifying conditional conservatism in financial

accounting data: theory and evidence. The Accounting Review, Forthcoming.

Healy, P., & Palepu, K. (2001). Information asymmetry, corporate disclosure, and the

capital markets: A review of the empirical disclosure literature. Journal of Accounting

and Economics, 31(1), 405–440.

Khan, M., & Watts, R. (2009). Estimation and empirical properties of a firm-year measure

of accounting conservatism. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 48(2–3), 132–

150.

Mora, A., & Walker, M. (2015). The implications of research on accounting conservatism

for accounting standard setting. Accounting and Business Research, 45(5), 620–650.

Myers, S., & Majluf, N. (1984). Corporate financing and investment decisions when firms

have information that investors do not have’. Journal of Financial Economics, 12,

187–221.

Patatoukas, P., & Thomas, J. (2011). More Evidence of Bias in the Differential Timeliness

Measure of Conditional Conservatism. The Accounting Review, 86(5), 1765–1793.

Patatoukas, P., & Thomas, J. (2016). Placebo tests of conditional conservatism. The

Accounting Review, 91(2), 625–648.

Ryan, S. (2008). Accounting in and for the Subprime Crisis. The Accounting Review,

83(6), 1605–1638.

Scott, W. (2015). Financial Accounting Theory (7th ed.). Pearson.

Teoh, S. H., Welch, I., & Wong, T. J. (1998). Earnings management and the

underperformance of seasoned equity offerings. Journal of Financial Economics,

50(1), 63–99.

14

Chapter 2

Does Changing Accounting Standards Affect Dividend Policy?

ABSTRACT: This study explores the impact of the mandatory adoption of International

Financial Reporting Standards (IFRS) on dividend payout policy and the value relevance

of dividends in two of the largest Western European economies. We1 select the United

Kingdom as a major common-law country and France as a code-law country. These two

countries are highly comparable economically, which allows us to implement a difference-

in-differences methodology. The genesis of our theoretical argument is that IFRS adoption

is expected to mitigate information asymmetry, a major reason behind corporate

underinvestment and cash over-retention (Myers & Majluf, 1984). Our findings thus

suggest that IFRS adoption is a major contributor in increasing dividend payouts among

code-law firms through enhancing the corporate financial information environment and

reducing asymmetric information. The reduction in information asymmetry helps investors

become more confident about using accounting measures in assessing firm financial

performance, which causes a significant reduction in dividend value relevance among

code-law firms. On the other hand, common-law firms witness no significant change in

dividend payouts and a lower reduction in dividend value relevance relative to code-law

firms.

Keywords: Information Shocks; IFRS; Dividend Payout; Dividend Value Relevance.

1 I use “we” hereafter because the three essays (chapters 2, 3 and 4) are co-authored with my supervisors,

Prof. Martin Walker and Prof. Edward Lee.

15

2.1. Introduction

Publicly listed companies in the European Union were required to report their financial

statements in compliance with the International Financial Reporting Standards (IFRS) as of

the beginning of January 2005 (European Union, 2002). The purpose of this paper is to

examine the effect of the introduction of IFRS on dividend payout policy and dividend value

relevance. Specifically, we study the change in the level of dividend payout and the change in

dividend value relevance following IFRS adoption, after controlling for the differences in

accounting and legal systems between the selected control and treatment group.

Hail, Tahoun, & Wang (2014) use an international sample in testing the effect of IFRS on

dividend policy. They find that IFRS adoption decreases dividend payouts because it mitigates

information asymmetry and consequently mitigates the problem of free cash flow (Jensen,

1986). We believe that their results are over generalized due to their non-comparable control

and treatment groups. We select two comparable countries in Western Europe (the United

Kingdom and France) with different legal and accounting systems.2 Our sample selection

criterion enables a geographic regression discontinuity research design, where the geographic

boundaries assign firms into treatment and control groups (Keele, Titiunik, & Zubizarreta,

2015). In our setting, the geographic boundary splits the two groups based on their distinctive

accounting and legal systems. Specifically, the UK is a common-law country with an

accounting system similar to IFRS (Ball, Kothari, & Robin, 2000), while France is a code-law

country with an accounting system that differs materially from a common-law based

accounting system (Joos & Lang, 1994). In contrast to Hail et al. (2014), we find that IFRS

adoption increases dividend payouts in the code-law country relative to the common-law

2 We provide a detailed explanation for the sample selection in section 3.5.

16

country due to the improved information environment relating to assets in place (Myers &

Majluf, 1984).

In general, the accounting and finance literature concludes that the introduction of IFRS has

been broadly beneficial (see the surveys by Ball, Li, & Shivakumar, 2015; Brüggemann, Hitz,

& Sellhorn, 2013; Singleton-Green, 2015). The present paper contributes further evidence on

the effects of IFRS by focusing specifically on the possibility that IFRS may have served to

reduce information asymmetry in situations where asymmetry was relatively high. We

compare France with the UK because these two economies are similar in terms of political

institutions, industrial composition, size, and enforcement of accounting standards. In

addition, our focus on mandatory adoption in two very similar economies with different

accounting standards pre-IFRS helps mitigate potential issues of selection bias and omitted

correlated variables in voluntary adoption studies (Leuz & Wysocki, 2016). This makes

implementing a difference-in-differences research design a feasible identification strategy,

after ensuring the high comparability between the treatment and the control groups. This

allows us to observe whether the effect of IFRS depends on the nature of the accounting

system prior to IFRS implementation.

We focus on the level of dividend payout and on dividend value relevance because prior

theory and empirical findings suggest that these variables are driven by information

asymmetry relating to assets in place (Hand & Landsman, 2005; Myers & Majluf, 1984;

William Rees, 1997). In this paper we argue that a potentially important feature of IFRS is that

it serves to reduce the level of information asymmetry relating to assets in place. We anticipate

that the reduction in asymmetric information would make external financing less costly and,

consequently, encourages managers to pay more dividends. Moreover, as a result of the

improved information environment, investors would rely more on accounting measures, rather

than on dividends, in assessing firms’ financial performance. Thus, we anticipate a significant

17

reduction in dividend value relevance under IFRS. We expect the reduction in information

asymmetry to be greater for the economy which has the greater difference between its pre-

IFRS financial reporting system and the IFRS reporting system, i.e., the code-law country.

First, we examine the difference in the change in the dividend payout level between

common-law and code-law firms. Then we test the difference in the change in the dividend

payout level between high- and low-accounting quality firms in the code-law country, where

lower accounting quality firms are expected to be more affected by IFRS. Finally, we examine

the change in the value relevance of dividends. We believe that this triangulation strategy

gives more credibility and reliability to our study.

Consistent with our hypotheses, our findings suggest that IFRS adoption had a significantly

larger effect on code-law firms than on common-law firms. The level of dividend payouts

increases in the code-law country. This increase in dividend payouts is more significant for

code-law firms who had a lower accounting quality prior to IFRS, compared to code-law firms

who had a higher accounting quality. In addition, we find that the reduction in the level of

information asymmetry and the enhancement in the financial reporting environment improve

investors’ confidence in accounting numbers. This results in a significant reduction in the

value relevance of dividends among the treatment firms relative to the control firms.

The remainder of the paper is structured as follows: section 2.2 provides the motivation and

literature review; section 2.3 includes hypotheses development; section 2.4 discusses the

research design; section 2.5 describes the data sample; section 2.6 discusses the results; and

section 2.7 concludes the study.

18

2.2. Motivation & Literature Review

2.2.1. IFRS, Legal Systems and Accounting Quality

In 2005, the European Union (EU) imposed IFRS as obligatory reporting standards on

publicly listed companies in all countries that fall under its authority (European Union, 2002).3

IASB’s initial objectives were to develop a set of global accounting standards that are relevant

to economic decisions made by capital market participants (Choi, Peasnell, & Toniato, 2013;

Pope & McLeay, 2011). In a recent survey on IFRS adoption, De George, Li, & Shivakumar

(2016) discuss the differences between the code-law and the common-law financial reporting

systems. They show how crucial it is to differentiate between legal systems when studying the

effect of IFRS adoption across countries because IFRS are developed in the spirit of the

common-law system (Ball et al., 2000). To be more specific, the demand for financial

reporting is higher in common-law countries because firms are more financially dependent on

capital markets, whereas firms in code-law countries are mainly reliant on banks for raising

money. Accordingly, relying on capital markets in raising funds requires firms to maintain

transparent and decision-relevant financial statements. In addition, the common-law financial

reporting system tends to be less regulated by laws than the code-law financial reporting

system. In code-law countries, accounting regulations are incorporated in national laws. On

the other hand, national laws in common-law countries are less detailed regarding financial

reporting, which allows managerial judgment and permits accounting standards to play a

major role in financial reporting. Similar to the common-law financial reporting system, IFRS

are principles-based accounting standards that specify more general rules, where firms are

responsible for presenting credible financial statements. Finally, on top of that, firms in code-

3 Some publicly listed companies were exempted from reporting under IFRS. For example, Alternative

Investment Market (AIM) companies were not required to adopt IFRS in the UK until 2007.

19

law countries resolve information asymmetry conflicts through private communication;

however, firms in common-law countries use public disclosure in resolving such conflicts.4

In light of the aforementioned points, we expect a minor change in the financial reporting

system in the common-law country following IFRS adoption. On the other hand, the code-law

country is expected to experience a more substantial change in the financial reporting system

after adopting IFRS (Armstrong, Barth, Jagolinzer, & Riedl, 2010; Barth, Landsman, Lang, &

Williams, 2012).

Another determinant of the effectiveness of IFRS adoption is the enforcement of these

standards (Leuz & Wysocki, 2016). IFRS might enhance accounting quality given that it is

accompanied with a rigid enforcement and a robust institutional infrastructure (Hail & Leuz,

2006). Christensen, Hail, & Leuz (2013) find that European countries that have improved their

accounting enforcement have experienced a greater effect for IFRS on their capital markets.

Thus, it is important for our study to make sure that the improvement in the financial reporting

environment in the code-law country, following IFRS adoption, is not due to a change in the

enforcement of accounting standards. Prior studies document that the enforcement of laws and

the institutional infrastructure are similar in the UK and France (La Porta, Lopez-De-Silanes,

Shleifer, & Vishny, 1998). Yet, Brown, Preiato, & Tarca (2014) argue that using legal systems

as a proxy for measuring the enforcement of accounting standards is general rather than

specific to financial accounting. Specifically, the authors argue that accounting standards

would not promote the supply of sufficient financial information without a regulatory

intervention. For instance, the experience of the Security and Exchange Commission (SEC) in

the US points out that juristic penalties and adverse stock price reaction form the main

incentives for firms’ compliance with accounting standards (Dechow, Sloan, & Sweeney,

4 For example, Gajewski & Quéré (2013) find that earnings announcements in France do not significantly reduce

information asymmetry compared to earnings announcements in the U.S.

20

1996). This motivates the importance of independent enforcement bodies (by governments or

private institutions) since their existence is essential for achieving high quality financial

reporting (SEC, 2002). Accordingly, we must consider any changes in the enforcement of

accounting standards in the UK and France around IFRS.

Brown et al. (2014) construct a comprehensive index that measures the enforcement of

accounting standards in 51 countries before, during, and after IFRS adoption.5 Their index of

enforcement of accounting standards in France shows a score of 19 in 2002, 19 in 2005, and

16 in 2008. This shows that the enforcement of accounting standards in France stayed stable

before and around IFRS adoption, and then it fell slightly after IFRS adoption in 2008.6 The

same index in the UK shows a score of 14 in 2002, 22 in 2005, and 22 in 2008. This slight

increase in the enforcement of accounting standards in the UK around IFRS would have a

counter effect on our findings, if present. Therefore, we rule out the possibility that changes in

the enforcement of accounting standards in both countries might drive the obtained results.

This facilitates the implementation of the difference-in-differences methodology because the

only changing factor in this case is accounting standards.

Generally, the financial accounting literature documents that accounting standards directly

affect information asymmetry through determining the quality of financial reporting and

disclosure (Armstrong et al., 2010; Ball, 2008; Barth, Landsman, & Lang, 2008; Charitou,

Karamanou, & Lambertides, 2015; Daske, Hail, Leuz, & Verdi, 2008; Leuz & Verrecchia,

2000; Leuz & Wysocki, 2016; Muller, Riedl, & Sellhorn, 2011; Panaretou, Shackleton, &

Taylor, 2013; Ramalingegowda, Wang, & Yu, 2013; Wang & Welker, 2011). Brüggemann et

al. (2013) argue that financial reporting under IFRS should produce positive economic

5 The index constructed by Brown et al. (2014) consists of an ‘auditing’ index and an ‘enforcement’ index. We

are particularly interested in the enforcement of accounting standards index. The maximum score for the

aforementioned index is ‘24’ and it is measured in 2002, 2005 and 2008. 6 This decrease of the enforcement index in 2008 might be due to the global financial crisis. We run all the

regressions while excluding year 2008 from the sample period and the results persist.

21

consequences for investors through providing enhanced transparency and comparability. Leuz

& Verrecchia (2000) and Leuz & Wysocki (2016) conclude that International Accounting

Standards (represented by IFRS) are able to decrease adverse selection among investors

through imposing an increased level of accounting disclosure on adopting firms. Their

analyses show that this increased disclosure reduces the cost of capital among firms.

Therefore, we treat IFRS as a positive shock to the corporate financial reporting environment

(Hail et al., 2014).

2.2.2. Dividend Payout Policy and the Information Environment

The relationship between IFRS adoption and dividend payout policy is characterized by the

change in the level of information asymmetry (DeAngelo, DeAngelo, & Skinner, 2008). In

their survey of the corporate payout policy literature, DeAngelo et al. (2008) propose a

theoretical framework which develops the pioneering theory of Miller & Modigliani (1961) in

determining the optimal payout policy through introducing information asymmetry in light of

Myers & Majluf (1984) and Jensen (1986). Miller & Modigliani (1961) theorize that dividend

payout policy is irrelevant under certain assumptions.7 However, these assumptions do not

hold in a corporate world that suffers from asymmetric information. This suggests that the

dividend payout policy is a relevant financial decision to the firm under information

asymmetry. The surveys by Allen & Michaely (2003) and DeAngelo et al. (2008) document

that the finance literature selects information asymmetry as a major factor in determining the

behavior of dividend policy.

In the presence of asymmetric information, the firm might experience corporate

underinvestment, especially when the firm is reliant on external financing (Myers & Majluf,

1984). The possibility of underinvestment comes from the ‘lemons problem’. This problem

7 The assumptions that support Miller and Modigliani (1961) are: (a) no friction costs and no taxes, (b) investors

are rational and securities are fairly priced, and (c) firms are price takers and not price makers and all investors

are equally informed.

22

occurs when the firm issues new equity or new debt and investors undervalue equity or

overprice debt due to high uncertainty. The framework of Myers & Majluf (1984) suggests

that the higher the level of information asymmetry relating to assets in place, the higher the

likelihood of underinvestment. The authors argue that the firm may limit the underinvestment

problem through increasing cash retention, which means a lower dividend payout. Thus, a

higher level of asymmetric information leads to a lower dividend payout in order to lessen the

underinvestment problem.

We build on the theory of Myers & Majluf (1984) and argue that we expect dividend

payouts to increase after the adoption of IFRS due to the improved information environment

induced by the new reporting regime, after ruling out the argument of the improved

enforcement of accounting standards in section 2.2.1. Less asymmetric information enables

investors to better evaluate assets in place and growth potential. This encourages managers to

pay dividends because a reduction in asymmetric information is expected to decrease the

likelihood of encountering underinvestment problems.

2.2.3. Dividend Value Relevance and the Information Environment

Under perfectly symmetric information, dividends should be irrelevant in determining the

market value of the firm (Miller & Modigliani, 1961). However, when insiders possess more

valuable information than outsiders, dividends become value relevant as they convey signals

about the firm’s future (Bhattacharya, 1979; Miller & Rock, 1985). Fama & French (1998)

provide evidence suggesting that, under information asymmetry, dividends are highly value

relevant and have a positive effect on the market value of the firm. Rees (1997) argues that,

under information asymmetry, the positive significant association between dividends and

market value is attributed to the role of dividends in conveying credible information relating

the firm’s future. This information-carrying role of dividends is more prominent when

23

earnings quality is low (Rees, 2005). Hand & Landsman (2005) use the Ohlson (1995) model

in order to test four explanations for the high value relevance of dividends. They propose four

possible explanations for the positive pricing of dividends: (1) dividends proxy for public

information that help predict future earnings, (2) managers use dividends as a signaling tool

for their private information, (3) managers pay dividends in order to signal their good

intentions about maximizing shareholders value, and (4) dividends are positively priced

because of analysts’ mis-forecasting or investors’ mispricing of earnings and book equity.

Their results are mostly consistent with the fourth proposition. After controlling for one-year-

ahead analysts’ forecast errors, Hand and Landsman (2005) rule out the possibility of analysts’

mis-forecasting. Thus, they conclude that the positive value relevance of dividends is caused

by investors’ mispricing of current earnings and book equity. We exploit the information

shock caused by IFRS, which is expected to decrease information asymmetry and improve

financial reporting, in order to argue that investors are more willing to rely on accounting

measures of financial performance post-IFRS. This is expected to reduce the value relevance

of dividends, especially where IFRS have a higher impact.

2.3. Hypothesis Development

In our setting, the common-law accounting system (i.e., UK GAAP) does not materially differ

from IFRS (Ball et al., 2000). However, the code-law accounting system (i.e., French GAAP)

differs materially from IFRS in several aspects (Hong, Hung, & Lobo, 2014; Joos & Lang,

1994; Kaufmann, Kraay, & Mastruzzi, 2007; Soderstrom & Sun, 2007). Specifically,

accounting standards in common-law countries are set by private organizations (FASB in the

US and IASB in the UK) and not by governments. The rationale for setting accounting

standards in common-law countries is derived from the information demands of investors;

therefore, the purpose of standard setters in these countries is to satisfy the information needs

24

of investors (Soderstrom & Sun, 2007). On the other hand, accounting standards in code-law

countries are a part of commercial laws, set by governments and instituted by courts.

Accounting standards in code-law countries are influenced and developed by governments,

according to governments’ priorities and not directly related to investors’ needs (Ball et al.,

2000). Given that IFRS are developed to provide investors with the relevant information for

making economic decisions (Brüggemann et al., 2013; Pope & McLeay, 2011), we expect a

greater improvement in the financial reporting environment in the code-law country than in

the common-law country following IFRS adoption.

The UK and France are both developed countries with good implementation of laws

(Kaufmann et al., 2007), which proxy for the enforcement of accounting standards. Yet, a

viable argument might be that the improvement in the financial reporting environment in

France after IFRS adoption might be due to a stricter enforcement of accounting standards. As

described in section 2.2.1, the enforcement of accounting standards did not improve in France

after IFRS adoption (Brown et al., 2014). This means that the financial reporting environment

did not improve because of the improvement in the enforcement of accounting standards, but

it improved due to imposing a set of a higher quality accounting standards. In addition, Brown

et al.'s (2014) index of accounting standards’ enforcement show a score of 19 for France and a

score of 22 for the UK (out of 24) in 2005; therefore, IFRS are properly enforced in both

countries, which increases the comparability of the selected countries.

After explaining the assumptions relating to accounting standards and legal systems,8 we

hypothesize that code-law firms might increase their dividend payouts as a result of the

reduction in asymmetric information following IFRS adoption (DeAngelo et al., 2008; Myers

8 The first assumption is that the accounting standards in code-law countries differ significantly from IFRS

whereas the accounting standards in common-law countries are similar to IFRS. The second assumption is that

the enforcement of accounting standards did not improve in France after the adoption of IFRS and, therefore, the

differences in accounting quality are due to the change in accounting standards and not to the change in the

enforcement of these standards.

25

& Majluf, 1984). When financial information becomes less asymmetric, firms will be able to

finance their investments more easily through issuing public debt and/or new equity. Under

high financial reporting quality, uncertainty is lessened and, consequently, issued bonds and

shares are expected to be more fairly priced (a lower interest rate for bonds and a better market

reaction for shares). As such, managers of code-law firms will have no need to maintain a

strict cash retention policy and, thus, will be able to pay more dividends.

Hypothesis (1):

H1: Following IFRS, there is a greater increase in the average dividend payout among code-

law firms than among common-law firms.

If IFRS are expected to improve the financial reporting environment where accounting

quality is relatively low, then firms with lower accounting quality are expected to be more

affected by IFRS than those with higher accounting quality. Given that we expect IFRS to

induce a greater change in accounting quality among code-law firms, we also believe that

IFRS will have a greater influence on code-law firms with lower accounting quality. That is,

we predict that the level of dividend payout will increase among code-law firms with low

accounting quality more than it will among code-law firms with high accounting quality.

Hypothesis (2):

H2: IFRS adoption affects the average dividend payout for low accounting quality firms more

significantly than it does for high accounting quality firms in the code-law country.

When the quality of reported earnings and book value of equity is low, the value relevance

of dividends is expected to be high because it provides a source of information to investors

26

(Rees, 2005). In this case, dividends will have a higher impact on the market value of the firm.

Rees & Valentincic (2013) study the association between the market value of equity and

dividends. They find a strong association between market value and dividends among UK

firms. They explain their findings by reference to the study of Clubb (2013) who concludes

that dividends exert a strong positive effect on market value from their role as a proxy for

financial expectations. In the same vein, Hand and Landsman (2005) conclude that dividends

are value relevant because investors are unwilling to rely entirely on accounting numbers and,

therefore, place some weight on dividends as an alternative proxy for financial expectations.

Another source for financial expectations is analysts’ forecasts. Choi et al. (2013) find that

forecasted earnings become less value relevant under IFRS whereas reported earnings become

more value relevant to investors. This suggests that IFRS were successful in improving the

decision usefulness of reported numbers through reducing information asymmetry.

We hypothesize that investors become more confident about using accounting measures in

assessing the financial performance of the firm after IFRS adoption in code law countries.

This is due to lower information asymmetry and enhanced financial reporting. As a result,

dividends are expected to lose some of their signaling power and convey less information (i.e.,

become less value relevant).

Hypothesis (3):

H3: Dividend value relevance decreases by a significantly greater magnitude among code-law

firms than it does among common-law firms.

27

2.4. Research Methodology

We test our hypotheses using a difference-in-differences research design. The common-law

sample (UK firms) serves as the control group and the code-law sample (French firms) serves

as the treatment group. A detailed discussion of sample selection is available in section 2.5.

The sample period starts in 2001 and ends in 2008 (Hail et al., 2014).9 We argue that IFRS

adoption serves as a proxy for the change in the level of information asymmetry because it is a

positive exogenous information shock to the information environment (Florou & Kosi, 2015).

We denote the IFRS adoption period using the dummy variable POST that takes the value 1 if

the year is 2005 or beyond, and 0 otherwise. It is important to point out that we do not claim

that IFRS is the only driving factor to our findings; however, we develop a research design

and perform additional tests which make us confident of attributing our findings to the change

in the information environment following IFRS adoption (after showing that the enforcement

of accounting standards did not improve in the code-law country).

Finally, we differentiate the code-law sample from the common-law sample using the

dummy variable CODE that takes the value 1 if the firm is listed in France (i.e. treated firm),

and 0 otherwise. We identify the difference-in-differences estimator as the interaction of

POST and CODE. The variable POST*CODE takes the value 1 if the firm is listed in the code-

law country between 2005 and 2008, and 0 otherwise.

2.4.1. Dividend Payout Regression Model

In order to model the behavior of dividend payouts, we mainly follow (Fama & French

2001;2002) in modelling dividends. Their model includes four economic characteristics of the

9 As a robustness check, we run the regressions after excluding year 2008, the beginning of the world financial

crisis. In addition, we run the regressions after excluding year 2005 as it is considered a transitionary period with

high level of asymmetric information (Wang and Welker, 2011). The results remain unchanged when excluding

year 2008/2005 from the sample period.

28

firm that determine its dividend payout: profitability, investment opportunities, leverage and

size. These determinants are consistent with the DeAngelo et al. (2008) literature survey.

Denis & Osobov (2008) find that dividend payers tend to be more profitable firms as they

can maintain their dividend payout level whilst keeping some reserve funds for unseen

circumstances. We proxy profitability using three variables: earnings before interest and after

tax (EBI), net income available to common stock holders (NI), and income taxes (TAX).10

Firms with high investment opportunities usually pay fewer dividends because they need to

finance their ongoing projects (Fama & French, 2001). We proxy the firm’s investment

opportunities using three variables: the percentage change in total assets (%∆TA), research and

development expenses (RND), and a proxy for Tobin’s Q using the market-to-book ratio

(TOBINQ).

The level of debt should be taken into consideration since it is one of the obstacles that

delay dividend payments (DeAngelo, DeAngelo, & Stulz, 2006; Eije & Megginson, 2008).

We proxy the level of debt using the variable LEV, the ratio of total liabilities to the average of

total assets in years prior to IFRS.11

A major determinant of dividend payout is the firm’s maturity. DeAngelo et al. (2008) state

that prior literature finds a positive association between the firm’s maturity and dividend

payouts. Fama & French (2001) proxy the firm’s maturity by its size since a more mature firm

is expected to have a bigger size. We measure the firm’s size using the natural logarithm of

total assets (LOGTA).

10

Income taxes proxy profitability because higher taxes are paid by more profitable firms. In addition, Mills,

Nutter, & Schwab (2013) find that firms with higher political cost pay higher taxes, in general, as they experience

higher scrutiny. Therefore, the inclusion of taxes in the model might capture some of the political cost which put

more pressure on firms to pay dividends in order to silence investors. 11

We deflate the variables by the firm’s average of total assets in years 2001, 2002, 2003 and 2004 in order to

isolate the fair value adjustment effect on total assets after IFRS. Yet, our results remain unchanged when

deflating by lagged total assets. An alternative deflator is market value; however, we cannot use market value

because it is the dependent variable in equation (2).

29

Finally, following Ramalingegowda et al. (2013), we add the tangibility ratio TANG, the

liquidity ratio LIQDT, and share repurchases REPUR – an alternative method of distributing

profits to shareholders. All variables are defined in Appendix A.

In the light of these ideas, the initial regression model is given in equation (1) where the

dependent variable TDVD is total dividend payout deflated by to the average of total assets in

years prior to IFRS.

TDVD = α0 + α1 POST + α2 CODE + α3 POST*CODE

+ ∑ αi Controlsi + ∑ αj Year FEj + ∑ αk Industry FEk + ε (1)

The coefficients of interest are α1, α2, and α3. When running this regression equation for

each country separately, we are especially interested in the coefficient on POST. We expect

this coefficient to be insignificant (significantly positive) when using the common-law (code-

law) sample. On the other hand, when running the regression using the full sample, α1 captures

the change in total dividends after IFRS adoption among common-law firms, α2 captures the

difference in the level of dividend payout between both groups prior to IFRS adoption, and α3

captures the difference-in-differences effect (i.e. the difference in the effect of IFRS adoption

on the level of dividend payouts between common-law and code-law firms).

2.4.2. Dividend Payout Regressions among Code-law Firms

We run the subsample analysis by splitting the code-law sample into two groups: low

accounting quality firms and high accounting quality firms. We use three proxies for

accounting quality in partitioning the code-law sample. All the proxies are calculated in years

prior to IFRS. The first proxy is the average absolute value of discretionary accruals. We

calculate discretionary accruals for the first proxy following Dechow, Sloan, & Sweeney

30

(1995) and we control for idiosyncratic economic shocks following Owens, Wu, &

Zimmerman (2016), as shown in Appendix B.1.12

The dummy variable ACCDUM1 takes the

value 1 if the firm’s average absolute value of discretionary accruals is greater than the median

value of the code-law sample, and 0 otherwise. That is, firms with an average absolute value

of discretionary accruals greater than the median value of the code-law sample are assigned to

the low accounting quality group. With respect to the second proxy for accounting quality, we

calculate discretionary accruals based on the cross-sectional version of the Dechow & Dichev

(2002) model, as shown in Appendix B.2. Then, for each firm, we calculate the variance of

discretionary accruals prior to IFRS adoption, because high volatility of discretionary accruals

implies low accounting quality (Chen, Chin, Wang, & Yao, 2015). The dummy variable

ACCDUM2 takes the value 1 if the variance of the firm’s discretionary accruals is greater than

the median value of the code-law sample, and 0 otherwise. That is, firms with a variance of

discretionary accruals greater than the median variance of the code-law sample are assigned to

the low accounting quality group. Finally, the third proxy for accounting quality is calculated

as the average annualized return volatility of the firm in years prior to IFRS. We calculate the

firm’s annualized return volatility as the annualized variance of daily stock returns. Firms with

highly volatile returns tend to have a lower level of innate earnings quality (Rajgopal &

Venkatachalam, 2011). The dummy variable RETDUM takes the value 1 if the firm’s average

annualized return volatility is greater than the median value of the code-law sample, and 0

otherwise. That is, firms with an average annualized stock volatility greater than the median

value of the code-law sample are assigned to the low accounting quality group.

12

Owens et al. (2016) find that big shifts in unsigned (absolute) abnormal accruals are caused by changes in the

firm’s economics. We follow their study and proxy idiosyncratic economic shocks using the variable ECON, as

defined in Appendix B.1.

31

2.4.3. Dividend Value Relevance Regression Model

In order to model the change in dividend value relevance following IFRS adoption, we use an

accounting-based valuation model that includes a number of variables from various prior

studies. Given that the data sample consists of Western European companies, we mainly

follow Shen & Stark (2013). We also include other variables relevant to the valuation of loss

firms (Darrough & Ye, 2007; Jiang & Stark, 2013). Finally, we add the variable OINFO as a

proxy for other information which cannot be captured in accounting-based models (Ohlson,

1995). This variable is the estimated residuals from year (t-1) regression, as performed in

Akbar & Stark (2003). We deflate both sides of the equation by the average of total assets in

years prior to IFRS. This step requires supressing the constant term and including the

reciprocal of the deflator (1/TA) among the covariates. The definition of the variables in the

regression equation below is given in Appendix A.

MV = 1/TA + β1 POST + β2TDVD + β3POST*TDVD

+ ∑ βi Controlsi + ∑ βj Year FEj + ∑ βk Industry FEk + ε (2)

The main coefficient of interest in this model is β3, which represents the change in the value

relevance of dividends after IFRS adoption. We run three models/versions of the above

regression equation using both samples (code-law and common-law). We compare the

estimates of β3, for both samples, using the Chi2 statistic. We expect β3 to be more negative for

the code-law sample regression, suggesting that the value relevance of dividends drops more

significantly among code-law firms than among common-law firms following the introduction

of IFRS. We are also interested in the change in the value relevance of accounting measures as

we expect the value relevance of accounting variables to increase after IFRS adoption.

32

2.5. Data & Descriptive Statistics

2.5.1. Sample Construction

As mentioned earlier, we select the UK as a major common-law country and France as a code-

law country in Western Europe. Our sample selection follows a geographic regression

discontinuity research design, where the geographic boundary assigns firms into treatment and

control groups (Keele et al., 2015). In our setting, the geographic boundary partitions both

groups based on accounting and legal systems. We believe that France is a suitable treatment

group because of several characteristics. First, the French economy is very similar in size to

the economy of the UK.13

Second, as discussed in section 2.2.1, the enforcement of accounting

standards around IFRS in France is similar to that in the UK (Brown et al., 2014; Hong et al.,

2014). Third, Enriques & Volpin (2007) compare public firms’ corporate governance and

ownership dispersion in France, Germany and Italy, relative to the UK. They conclude that

France is the most similar country to the UK when it comes to the characteristics of corporate

governance and ownership dispersion in Europe. Finally, our focus on the mandatory adoption

mitigates potential issues of selection bias and omitted variables in voluntary adoption studies

(Ahmed, Chalmers, & Khlif, 2013; Leuz & Wysocki, 2016). Following Hail et al. (2014), the

sample period starts in 2001 and ends by the end of 2008. We avoid extending the sample

period beyond year 2008 because the global financial crisis struck around 2008.14

The data source of financial variables is WorldScope and for stock returns is DataStream.

We apply two sets of sample restrictions. In the first set of restrictions, after we download all

publicly listed companies in the UK and France between 2001 and 2008, we exclude financial

13

The selected countries are highly comparable economically. The GDP growth from 2001 till 2008 in the UK

was 2.7%, 2.5%, 4.3%, 2.5%, 2.8%, 3%, 2.6% and 0.3%. On the other hand, the GDP growth in France during

the same period was 2%, 1.1%, 0.8%, 2.8%, 1.6%, 2.4%, 2.4% and 0.2%. The GDP growth numbers show that

the UK economy was performing similar to the French economy, especially during the adoption period (World

Bank, 2014). This evidence rules out potential critiques arguing that French firms have increased their dividend

payouts because of an economic boost. 14

As mentioned before, our results are robust to excluding the financial crisis year (2008), as well as excluding

the transitionary year (2005), from the sample period.

33

companies, unquoted equities, and unspecified industries. In the second set of restrictions, we

require each firm to have at least one observation in the pre-IFRS period and at least one

observation in the post-IFRS period. Then, we drop all firms with total assets below one

million Euros. Finally, we drop all firms that did not adopt IFRS in 2005.15

The final sample

consists of 673 common-law firms and 476 code-law firms. This is equivalent to 4,340 firm-

year common-law observations and 3,075 firm-year code-law observations.

2.5.2. Descriptive Statistics

We begin the descriptive statistics with Figure 1 that shows the trend of dividend payouts for

an average common-law firm versus an average code-law firm between 2001 and 2008. The

graph shows how dividend payouts have significantly increased on average after 2005 (IFRS

adoption) among code-law firms. However, no similar change in dividend payouts occurred

among common-law firms.

[Insert Figure 1 Here]

Table 1 reports summary statistics for the variables used in the dividend payout model for

the full sample, the common-law sample and the code-law sample. The percentage of

common-law dividend payers is higher than that of code-law dividend payers (74.84% vs

65.56%). Both groups have very similar ratios for the profitability proxies (EBI, NI and TAX).

Common-law firms have, on average, slightly higher investment and growth opportunities

than code-law firms. This can be deduced from comparing the ratios on investment

opportunity proxies (RND, TOBINQ and %∆TA). The average size of the firm is similar

between both groups; however, the leverage ratio shows that code-law firms are more

15

The name of the variable in DataStream is “Accounting Standards Followed”; Code: WC07536.

34

dependent on debt than common-law firms. Finally, common-law firms repurchase more

stocks and have higher tangibility and liquidity ratios than code-law firms.

[Insert Table 1 here]

Panel A of Table 2 shows that, in 2005, 78 code-law firms increased their dividend payouts

whereas only 53 firms from the common-law sample increased their payouts. Panel B of Table

2 reports the average dividend payout for each sample before and after IFRS adoption. It

shows that the average dividend payout among code-law firms increases by 27.59% after IFRS

implementation, whereas the same figure increases by 0.07% for common-law firms.

[Insert Table 2 Here]

Finally, Table 3 reports the summary statistics for the variables used in the dividend value

relevance model. On average, common-law firms have a higher market value (MV) than code-

law firms. The summary statistics for the variable BVE show that the financial structure of an

average common-law firm is more reliant on equity than an average code-law firm. The

summary statistics for the variable NIBX show that code-law firms report slightly higher

profits than common-law firms do. This might be due to the higher capital expenditure

(CAPX) and higher research and development expenses (RND) incurred by common-law

firms. Furthermore, common-law firms have on average a greater change in sales over the

years (∆SALES), and this might be one of the reasons why common-law firms are more

solvent (LIQDT) than code-law firms. As for equity movements, the summary statistics show

that common-law firms buy and sell equity more frequently than code-law firms do (REPUR

35

and PROCD, respectively). Finally, as also shown in Table 3, an average common-law firm

pays more dividends than an average code-law firm does.

[Insert Table 3 Here]

The Pearson correlation coefficients between variables are similar for common-law and

code-law samples; thus, we only report the correlation matrices of the dividend payout model

as well as the dividend value relevance model based on the full sample. The univariate

analysis of the dividend payout model shows that the correlation between the total dividend

payout and the profitability proxies is positive and significant for common-law and code-law

samples. The correlation between the total dividend payout and the investment proxies is

negative and significant, which means that firms with higher investment opportunities pay

fewer dividends. Loss-making firms pay fewer dividends in both samples than profitable

firms. The only notable difference between both samples is that the leverage ratio is positively

correlated with dividend payouts for common-law firms, while the same correlation is

negative for code-law firms. This can be explained by the argument of La Porta, Lopez-de-

Silanes, Shleifer, & Vishny (2000) that firms operating in countries with high investors’

protection (i.e., common-law countries) tend to raise more debt in order to maintain their

dividends.

[Insert Table 4 Here]

Regarding the dividend value relevance model, the univariate analysis shows that the book

value of equity is positively correlated with market value. The correlation coefficient on net

income (NIBX) shows a negative correlation with market value and this is more prominent for

36

loss firms (LOSS*NIBX). Nevertheless, we obtain a significantly positive coefficient when we

test the correlation between the non-deflated market value and non-deflated net income.

Furthermore, the statistics show that capital expenditure, research and development expenses,

change in sales, the liquidity ratio, proceeds, repurchases and dividends are positively

correlated with the market value.

[Insert Table 5 Here]

2.6. Empirical Results

2.6.1. Dividend Payout following IFRS

We estimate equation (1) using OLS regression with industry and year fixed effects as shown

in Table 6. We run three regressions using the common-law sample, the code-law sample and

the full sample. The profitability proxies have a positive and statistically significant effect on

the dependent variable TDVD, except for NI which has an insignificant coefficient in all three

regressions (probably because it is the only variable being deflated by the book value of

equity). The variables RND and %∆TA, that proxy for investment opportunities, have a

significantly negative effect on dividend payouts in all regressions. This indicates that firms

with higher investments pay fewer dividends due to their need for cash. Yet, the coefficient on

TOBINQ (the third proxy for investment opportunities) is positive and significant. One

possible explanation for this result might be that TOBINQ captures the firm’s profitability,

which is positively correlated with dividend payout, since more profitable firms have a higher

stock price. Moreover, the coefficient on LOGTA is positive and statistically significant,

suggesting that larger firms and more mature firms pay more dividends. Also, the coefficient

on TANG is positively significant in all regressions, suggesting that more tangible firms pay

37

higher dividends. The coefficients on LEV have different signs in both groups, with statistical

significance. Myers (1984) theorizes that debt can be either positively or negatively associated

with dividends. Myers (1984) elaborates that in some cases firms might raise safe debt in order

to maintain their payout level, while in other cases firms might cut on dividends because of

high debt. Having said that, the results suggest that common-law firms tend to raise debt in

order to maintain dividends; however, code-law firms tend to cut on dividends in the presence

of high debt obligations.

More importantly, the coefficient on POST in the first regression (common-law sample) is

negative and statistically insignificant (t-statistic = −0.17). On the other hand, the

corresponding coefficient in the second regression (code-law sample) is positive and highly

significant (t-statistic = 5.29). This suggests that IFRS adoption has a significantly positive

effect on dividend payouts in the code-law country and has an insignificant effect in the

common-law country. Moreover, the third regression using the full sample shows that the

coefficient on CODE is negative and highly significant, suggesting that code-law firms used to

pay significantly lower dividends than common-law firms in the pre-IFRS period. This is

consistent with La Porta et al. (2000), who find that firms operating in code-law countries pay

fewer dividends to their investors than firms operating in common-law countries. Finally, the

coefficient on the difference-in-differences dummy is positive with a value of 0.0021 and a t-

statistic of 4.15. This suggests that code-law firms significantly increased their dividend

payouts in the post-IFRS period compared to common-law firms. The results in Table 6 lead

us to reject the null hypothesis of H1 in favor of the alternative.

[Insert Table 6 Here]

38

Another variant of the difference-in-differences methodology allows for heterogeneous

impact of control variables (Angrist & Pischke, 2015). This requires interacting all control

variables with the three dummy variables of the difference-in-differences methodology: POST,

CODE, and POST*CODE.16

We report the results of this regression in Table 7. For brevity,

we do not report the full set of interactions. We report the estimates of the control variables

along with the three main variables of interest.17

The main results hold and the general

interpretation does not change. This means that heterogeneous attributes between groups do

not affect the treatment effect of IFRS over time. This also supports our claim regarding the

high comparability between the control and the treatment groups. The results in Table 7

confirm the rejection of the null hypothesis of H1 in favor of the alternative.

[Insert Table 7 Here]

Furthermore, we run a Logistic regression using the same set of covariates in order to test

for the change in the propensity to pay dividends among firms. The dependent variable

DIVDUM is a dummy variable that takes the value 1 if the firm pays dividends in that year,

and 0 otherwise. Table 8 reports the estimates from three Logistic regressions using the

common-law sample, the code-law sample, and the full sample. The coefficients on the control

variables have the same signs and similar significance to those obtained from the OLS

regressions. More importantly, the coefficient on POST in the first two columns remains

insignificant for common-law firms and significantly positive for code-law firms. The

coefficient on POST*CODE in the third column, which captures the difference-in-differences

effect, also remains significantly positive. This suggests that the propensity to pay dividends

16

Christensen, Lee, & Walker (2007) find that IFRS adoption does not affect all firms equally and the

effectiveness of IFRS is conditional on the firm’s perceived benefit. Therefore, allowing for heterogeneous

impact of firms’ characteristics would control for the variation in the effectiveness of IFRS adoption. 17

We obtain the estimates of the fully interacted linear model using the “film” command in Stata.

39

increases among code-law firms in comparison to that of common-law firms following IFRS

adoption. Thus, we also reject the null hypothesis of H1 in favor of the alternative.

[Insert Table 8 Here]

It is possible that our dividend payout results (Table 6, Table 7, and Table 8) are driven by

some unobserved factors that were not captured in equation (1). If these unobservable factors

remain constant over time, then we can control for the source of endogeneity using a firm

fixed effects regression (Wooldridge, 2010, p. 285). In this case, firm fixed effects control for

the unobserved differences between the treatment group and the control group as long as these

differences are time invariant (Baltagi, 2013; Bertrand, Duflo, & Mullainathan, 2004). Table 9

reports regression results for the dividend payout model using firm fixed effects. Our main

result remains unchanged after controlling for time-invariant unobservable factors. The firm

fixed effects regressions confirm the rejection of the null hypothesis of H1 in favor of the

alternative.

[Insert Table 9 Here]

Finally, we attempt to control for the change in the economics among code-law firms. If

this change in the economics was in favor of increasing dividend payout, then our finding may

not be caused by IFRS adoption. We control for the change in the underlying economics

among code-law firms by constructing a one-to-one matched sample. In particular, we match

code-law observations to common-law observations using the Coarsened Exact Matching

(CEM) technique (Iacus, King, & Porro, 2012). We use the CEM procedure to create the

treatment and the control samples with balanced characteristics in terms of several covariates

40

(Duygan-Bump, Parkinson, Rosengren, Suarez, & Willen, 2013). We match based on firm

performance (ROA), firm size (total assets), industry and IFRS. We believe that matching on

these variables would capture some of the effects, caused by changes in the underlying

economics among code-law firms, which might drive an increase in the level of dividend

payout.

Table 10 shows that our results hold, and become more economically significant, when we

run a matched difference-in-differences analysis. The estimate on POST remains statistically

insignificant for common-law firms and statistically significant for code-law firms.

Interestingly, the difference-in-differences estimate increase from 0.0021 in Table 6 to 0.0028

in Table 10.

[Insert Table 10 Here]

In conclusion to this section, after we perform a set of difference-in-differences regressions

and after controlling for several potential driving factors, we attribute the increase in dividend

payouts among code-law firms to the adoption of IFRS.18

2.6.2. Dividend Payout among Code-Law Firms

We enrich our examination of the change in the level of dividend payout by examining

heterogeneous effects of IFRS on code-law firms. IFRS are expected to affect firms with low

accounting quality; therefore, the increase in dividend payouts among code-law firms should

be more prominent among low accounting quality firms, compared to high accounting quality

firms. For this reason, we split the code-law sample into high- and low- accounting quality

18

André, Filip, & Paugam (2015) find that conditional conservatism decreases in Europe after IFRS adoption.

This implies that the reported earnings might have increased after IFRS and, as a result, managers might have

increased their dividend payout. Therefore, we run an additional test where we control for the change in net

income. There is no material impact on our findings.

41

firms using three proxies (calculated pre-IFRS): the average absolute value of discretionary

accruals, the variance of discretionary accruals and the average annualized return volatility.

Firms that fall above the median of each proxy are considered as low accounting quality firms.

Tables 11, 12 and 13 report regression results for the dividend payout model using three

samples in each table: code-law firms with high accounting quality, code-law firms with low

accounting quality and the full code-law sample. The first and the second columns of Tables

11, 12 and 13 report the regressions results for the high accounting quality subsample and the

low accounting quality subsample, respectively. The last column of Tables 11, 12 and 13

report the regression results for the full code-law sample including the difference-in-

differences estimators POST*ACCDUM1, POST*ACCDUM2 and POST*RETDUM,

respectively.

Table 11 shows that the level of dividend payouts for firms with average absolute

discretionary accruals below the median is less affected by IFRS adoption. This is shown by

the lower coefficient and significance on POST for the high accounting quality firms. The

coefficient on POST for the high accounting quality subsample is 0.0016 with a t-statistic of

2.14, while the same coefficient for the low accounting quality subsample is 0.003 with a t-

statistic of 4.79. The difference-in-differences estimator (POST*ACCDUM1) has a

significantly positive coefficient, indicating that the level of dividend payout among code-law

firms with lower accounting quality is more affected by IFRS adoption. Therefore, we reject

the null hypothesis of H2 in favor of the alternative.

[Insert Table 11 Here]

Table 12 confirms the results of Table 11 where IFRS affect the level of dividend payouts

for low accounting quality firms significantly more than it does for high accounting quality

42

firms. The dividend payout level increases more among code-law firms who have an average

variance of discretionary accruals above the median, compared to code-law firms who fall

below the median. The coefficient on POST for the high accounting quality subsample is

0.0009 with a t-statistic of 1.26, while the same coefficient for the low accounting quality

subsample is 0.0035 with a t-statistic of 5.23. The difference-in-differences estimator

(POST*ACCDUM2) has a significantly positive coefficient, indicating that the level of

dividend payout among code-law firms with lower accounting quality is more affected by the

IFRS mandate. Based on this result, we reject the null hypothesis of H2 in favor of the

alternative.

[Insert Table 12 Here]

Finally, the results in Table 13 are also consistent with those in Tables 11 and 12. The

dividend payout level increases more among code-law firms who have an average annualized

variance of daily stock returns above the median of the code-law sample, compared to those

who fall below the median. The coefficient on POST for the high accounting quality

subsample is 0.0015 with a t-statistic of 2.43, while the same coefficient for the low

accounting quality subsample is 0.0028 with a t-statistic of 4.12. The difference-in-differences

estimator (POST*RETDUM2) has a significantly positive coefficient, indicating that the level

of dividend payout among code-law firms with lower accounting quality is more affected by

IFRS implementation. This reinforces the rejection of the null hypothesis of H2 in favor of the

alternative.

[Insert Table 13 Here]

43

2.6.3. Dividend Value Relevance following IFRS

In the final set of regressions, we test the change in the value relevance of dividends following

IFRS adoption. We estimate three versions of equation (2), using the common-law and the

code-law samples, as shown in Table 13. In the first model, we interact the IFRS dummy with

total dividend payout and stock repurchases. In the second model, we interact the IFRS

dummy with total dividend payout, stock repurchases and the main accounting variables. The

purpose of interacting the accounting variables with the IFRS dummy is to test whether the

value relevance of the accounting numbers has increased after IFRS adoption. In the third

model, we interact all the variables with the IFRS dummy in order to capture other unobserved

factors which might affect these variables over time.

In order to differentiate profitable firms from loss firms, we interact the loss dummy LOSS

with the book value of equity BVE and net income before extraordinary items NIBX. After

performing this step, the coefficients on BVE and NIBX become closer to the conventional

Ohlson (1995) model’s estimates. Other covariates, like, CAPX, ∆SALES, LIQDT, and RND

have significantly positive effects on the market value in both regressions. This indicates that

an increase in investments (CAPX and RND) and/or profitability (∆SALES and LIQDT) sends

positive signals to investors, and in return this elevates the market value of the firm.

As for the value relevance of dividends, the coefficient on POST*TDVD in Model 1 of

Table 13, which captures the change in the value relevance of dividends after IFRS adoption,

equals −1.2652 for the common-law sample with a t-statistic of −1.23. This implies that the

value relevance of dividends among common-law firms does not significantly change after

IFRS adoption. On the other hand, the same coefficient for the code-law sample is −5.1882

with a t-statistic of −3.68. This indicates that the value relevance of dividends significantly

falls by almost half of its original magnitude before IFRS. The Chi2 statistic that tests the

44

statistical difference between the coefficients on POST*TDVD in both countries is 2.83 (p-

value = 0.0925).

After we include the interaction between the IFRS dummy and the accounting variables in

Model 2 of Table 13, we find that the reduction in the value relevance of dividends for the

code-law sample becomes more prominent with an estimate of −7.5324 and a t-statistic of

−4.55. On the other hand, the change in the value relevance of dividends stays statistically

insignificant for the common-law sample. After including the interactions between the IFRS

dummy and the accounting variables, the difference between the estimates on POST*TDVD

for the common-law and code-law firms becomes statistically significant at the 5% level with

a Chi2 statistic of 4.37 (p-value = 0.036). The additional reduction in the dividend value

relevance is due to the increase in the value relevance of the accounting measures. That is, the

value relevance of book value of equity increases only among code-law firms while the value

relevance of net income increases for both samples. This confirms that the effect of IFRS is

more significant and observable in the code-law country due to the improvement in the

financial reporting system and the reduction in the level of information asymmetry. Finally,

the main results persist after interacting the IFRS dummy with all economic variables, as

shown the last two columns in Table 13. In light of the results in Table 13, we reject the null

hypothesis of H3 in favor of the alternative.

[Insert Table 14 Here]

2.7. Conclusion

We study how aspects of the dividend payout policy change under information shocks caused

by changing accounting and disclosure standards. We exploit the mandatory adoption of IFRS

in Europe in 2005 and treat this event as a positive shock to the information environment

45

(Florou & Kosi, 2015; Hail et al., 2014). We select the UK as a major common-law country

where we do not expect a significant effect for IFRS (i.e. control group). We select France as a

code-law country where we expect significant changes to the dividend payout policy under

IFRS (i.e. treatment group). Our selection of the two countries is based on their high

comparability in aspects like economic characteristics, corporate governance, ownership

dispersion, institutional infrastructure, the enforcement of accounting standards and the

mandatory adoption of IFRS.

We contribute to the literature of financial reporting in several ways. We provide evidence

that the aspects of the dividend payout policy change in favor of shareholders under IFRS in

code-law countries. Our results suggest that code-law firms increase their dividend payouts in

response to the reduction in asymmetric information relating to assets in place (Myers &

Majluf, 1984). The reduction in asymmetric information eases external financing, which

mitigates underinvestment risk and reduces cash over-retention, and therefore encourages

dividend payouts. Then we examine how the effect of IFRS on code-law firms varies with the

firm’s accounting quality. We find that the effect of IFRS on dividend payouts is more

prominent for code-law firms with lower accounting quality. Finally, we find that the value

relevance of dividends decreases substantially among code-law firms under IFRS whilst the

value relevance of accounting numbers increases. This is mainly caused by the reduction in

information asymmetry among code-law firms and by the fact that investors have more

confidence in the accounting measures of financial performance following the IFRS mandate.

In general, our results suggest that improved accounting standards serve to mitigate

information asymmetry between insiders and outsiders.

Last but not least, a potential research idea which complements our paper might be

studying the change in the market reaction to issuing new equity following IFRS adoption,

especially in countries with poor financial reporting regimes pre-IFRS.

46

References:

Ahmed, K., Chalmers, K., & Khlif, H. (2013). A Meta-analysis of IFRS adoption effects. The

International Journal of Accounting, 48(2), 173–217.

Akbar, S., & Stark, A. (2003). Deflators, net shareholder cash flows, dividends, capital

contributions and estimated models of corporate valuation. Journal of Business Finance

and Accounting, 30(9–10), 1211–1233.

Allen, F., & Michaely, R. (2003). Payout Policy. In G. Constantinides, M. Harris, & R. Stulz

(Eds.), Handbook of the Economics of Finance (pp. 337–429). Amsterdam: North

Holland.

André, P., Filip, A., & Paugam, L. (2015). The effect of mandatory IFRS adoption on

conditional conservatism in Europe. Journal of Business Finance & Accounting, 42((3) &

(4)), 482–514.

Angrist, J. D., & Pischke, J.-S. (2015). Mastering ’Metrics : the Path from Cause to Effect.

Princeton University Press.

Armstrong, C., Barth, M., Jagolinzer, A., & Riedl, E. (2010). Market Reaction to Events

Surrounding the Adoption of IFRS in Europe Market Reaction to Events Surrounding the

Adoption of IFRS in Europe. The Accounting Review, 85(1), 31–61.

Ball, R. (2008). What is the actual economic role of financial reporting? Accounting Horizons,

22(4), 427–432.

Ball, R., Kothari, S. P., & Robin, A. (2000). The effect of international institutional factors on

properties of accounting earnings. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 29(1), 1–51.

Ball, R., Li, X., & Shivakumar, L. (2015). Contractibility of financial statement information

prepared under IFRS : Evidence from debt contracts. Journal of Accounting Research,

53(5).

Baltagi, B. (2013). Econometric analysis of panel data. U.K.: Wiley.

Barth, M., Landsman, W., & Lang, M. (2008). International accounting standards and

accounting quality. Journal of Accounting Research, 46(3), 467–498.

Barth, M., Landsman, W., Lang, M., & Williams, C. (2012). Are International Accounting

Standards-based and US GAAP-based Accounting Amounts Comparable ? Journal of

Accounting and Economics, 54(1), 68–93.

Bertrand, M., Duflo, E., & Mullainathan, S. (2004). How Much Should We Trust Differences-

In-Differences Estimates? The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 119(1), 249–275.

Bhattacharya, S. (1979). Imperfect Information, Dividend Policy, and the “Bird in the Hand”

Fallacy. The Bell Journal of Economics, 10(1), 259–270.

Brown, P., Preiato, J., & Tarca, A. (2014). Measuring Country Differences in Enforcement of

Accounting Standards: An Audit and Enforcement Proxy. Journal of Business Finance

and Accounting, 41(1–2), 1–52.

Brüggemann, U., Hitz, J.-M., & Sellhorn, T. (2013). Intended and Unintended Consequences

of Mandatory IFRS Adoption: A Review of Extant Evidence and Suggestions for Future

Research. European Accounting Review, 22(1), 1–37.

Charitou, A., Karamanou, I., & Lambertides, N. (2015). Who Are the Losers of IFRS

Adoption in Europe? An Empirical Examination of the Cash Flow Effect of Increased

Disclosure. Journal of Accounting, Auditing & Finance, 30(2), 150–180.

Chen, T.-Y., Chin, C.-L., Wang, S., & Yao, W.-R. (2015). The Effects of Financial Reporting

on Bank Loan Contracting in Global Markets: Evidence from Mandatory IFRS Adoption.

Journal of International Accounting Research, 14(2), 45–81.

Choi, Y. S., Peasnell, K., & Toniato, J. (2013). Has the IASB been successful in making

accounting earnings more useful for prediction and valuation? UK evidence. Journal of

Business Finance and Accounting, 40(7–8), 741–768.

47

Christensen, H., Hail, L., & Leuz, C. (2013). Mandatory IFRS Reporting and Changes in

Enforcement. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 56(2), 147–177.

Christensen, H., Lee, E., & Walker, M. (2007). Cross-sectional variation in the economic

consequences of international accounting harmonization: The case of mandatory IFRS

adoption in the UK. The International Journal of Accounting, 42(4), 341–379.

Clubb, C. (2013). Information dynamics, dividend displacement, conservatism, and earnings

measurement: a development of the Ohlson (1995) valuation framework. Review of

Accounting Studies, 18(2), 360–385.

Darrough, M., & Ye, J. (2007). Valuation of loss firms in a knowledge-based economy.

Review of Accounting Studies, 12(1), 61–93.

Daske, H., Hail, L., Leuz, C., & Verdi, R. (2008). Mandatory IFRS reporting around the

world: Early evidence on the economic consequences. Journal of Accounting Research,

46(5), 1085–1142.

De George, E., Li, X., & Shivakumar, L. (2016). A review of the IFRS adoption literature.

Review of Accounting Studies, 21(3), 898–1004.

DeAngelo, H., DeAngelo, L., & Skinner, D. (2008). Corporate Payout Policy. Foundations

and Trends in Finance, 3(2–3), 95–287.

DeAngelo, H., DeAngelo, L., & Stulz, R. (2006). Dividend policy and the earned/contributed

capital mix: a test of the life-cycle theory. Journal of Financial Economics, 81(2), 227–

254.

Dechow, P., & Dichev, I. (2002). The Quality of Accruals and Earnings: The Role of Accrual

Estimation Errors. The Accounting Review, 77(1), 35–59.

Dechow, P., Sloan, R., & Sweeney, A. (1995). Detecting Earnings Management. The

Accounting Review, 70(2).

Dechow, P., Sloan, R., & Sweeney, A. (1996). Causes and Consequences of Earnings

Manipulation: An Analysis of Firms Subject to Enforcement Actions by the SEC.

Contemporary Accounting Research, 13(1), 1–36.

Denis, D., & Osobov, I. (2008). Why do firms pay dividends? International evidence on the

determinants of dividend policy. Journal of Financial Economics, 89(1), 62–82.

Duygan-Bump, B., Parkinson, P., Rosengren, E., Suarez, G. A., & Willen, P. (2013). How

effective were the federal reserve emergency liquidity facilities? Evidence from the asset-

backed commercial paper money market mutual fund liquidity facility. Journal of

Finance, 68(2), 715–737.

Eije, V., & Megginson, W. (2008). Dividends and share repurchases in the European Union.

Journal of Financial Economics, 89(2), 347–374.

Enriques, L., & Volpin, P. (2007). Corporate Governance Reforms in Continental Europe. The

Journal of Economic Perspectives, 117–140.

European Union. (2002). “Regulation (EC) No. 1606/ of the European parliament and of the

council of 19 July on the application of international accounting standards”, Official

Journal of the European Communities, 243/ 1-L. 243/4. (Vol. 11 SRC-).

Fama, E., & French, K. (1998). Taxes, Financing Decisions, and Firm Value. The Journal of

Finance, 53(3), 819–843.

Fama, E., & French, K. (2001). Disappearing Dividends: Changing Firm Characteristics or

Lower Propensity to Pay? Journal of Financial Economics, 60(1), 3–43.

Fama, E., & French, K. (2002). Testing Tradeoff and Pecking Order Predictions About

Dividends and Debt. The Review of Financial Studies, 15(1), 1–33.

Florou, A., & Kosi, U. (2015). Does mandatory IFRS adoption facilitate debt financing?

Review of Accounting Studies, 20, 1407–1456.

Gajewski, J.-F., & Quéré, B. (2013). A Comparison of the Effects of Earnings Disclosures on

48

Information Asymmetry: Evidence from France and the U.S. The International Journal

of Accounting, 48(1), 1–25.

Hail, L., & Leuz, C. (2006). International Differences in the Cost of Equity Capital: Do Legal

Institutions and Securities Regulation Matter? Journal of Accounting Research, 44(3),

485–531.

Hail, L., Tahoun, A., & Wang, C. (2014). Dividend payouts and information shocks. Journal

of Accounting Research, 52(2), 403–456.

Hand, J., & Landsman, W. (2005). The pricing of dividends in equity valuation. Journal of

Business Finance and Accounting, 32(3–4), 435–469.

Hong, H., Hung, M., & Lobo, G. (2014). The Impact of Mandatory IFRS Adoption on IPOs in

Global Capital Markets. The Accounting Review, 89(4), 1365–1397.

Hribar, P., & Collins, D. (2002). Errors in estimating accruals: implications for empirical

research. Journal of Accounting Research, 40(1), 105–134.

Iacus, S. M., King, G., & Porro, G. (2012). Causal inference without balance checking:

Coarsened exact matching. Political Analysis, 20(1), 1–24.

Jensen, M. (1986). Agency costs of free cash flow, corporate finance, and takeovers. American

Economic Review, 76(2), 323–329.

Jiang, W., & Stark, A. (2013). Dividends, research and development expenditures, and the

value relevance of book value for UK loss-making firms. British Accounting Review,

45(2), 112–124.

Jones, J. (1991). Earnings Management During IMport Relief Investigations. Journal of

Accounting Research, 29(2).

Jones, K., Krishnan, G., & Melendrez, K. (2008). Do Models of Discretionary Accruals Detect

Actual Cases of Fraudulent and Restated Earnings? An Empirical Analysis.

Contemporary Accounting Research, 25, 499–531.

Joos, P., & Lang, M. (1994). The effects of accounting diversity: evidence from the European

Union. Journal of Accounting Research, 32(Supplement), 141–168.

Kaufmann, D., Kraay, A., & Mastruzzi, M. (2007). Governance Matters VI: Aggregate and

Individual Governance Indicators 1996-2006. Washington, DC.

Keele, L., Titiunik, R., & Zubizarreta, J. (2015). Enhancing a geographic regression

discontinuity design through matching to estimate the effect of ballot initiatives on voter

turnout. Journal of the Royal Statistical Society: Series A (Statistics in Society), 178(1),

223–239.

Kim, J. B., Liu, X., & Zheng, L. (2012). The Impact of Mancdatory IFRS aDoption on Audit

Fees: Theory and Evidence. The Accounting Review, 87(6), 2061–2094.

La Porta, R., Lopez-De-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. (1998). Law and Finance.

Journal of Political Economy, 106(6), 1113–1155.

La Porta, R., Lopez-De-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. (2000). Investor Protection and

Corporate Governance. Journal of Financial Economics, 58(1), 3–27.

Leuz, C., & Verrecchia, R. (2000). The Economic Consequences of Increased Disclosure.

Journal of Accounting Research, 38, 91–124.

Leuz, C., & Wysocki, P. (2016). The Economics of Disclosure and Financial Reporting

Regulation: Evidence and Suggestions for Future Research. Journal of Accounting

Research, 54(2), 525–622.

Miller, M., & Modigliani, F. (1961). Dividend policy, growth, and the valuation of shares.

Journal of Business, 34, 411–433.

Miller, M., & Rock, K. (1985). Dividend Policy under Asymmetric Information. The Journal

of Finance, 40(4), 1031–1051.

Mills, L., Nutter, S., & Schwab, C. (2013). The Effect of Political Sensitivity and Bargaining

49

Power on Taxes: Evidence from Federal Contractors. The Accounting Review, 88(3),

977–1005.

Muller, K., Riedl, E., & Sellhorn, T. (2011). Mandatory Fair Value Accounting and

Information Asymmetry: Evidence from the European Real Estate Industry. Management

Science, 57(6), 1138–1153.

Myers, S. (1984). The Capital Structure Puzzle. The Journal of Finance, 39(3), 574–592.

Myers, S., & Majluf, N. (1984). Corporate financing and investment decisions when firms

have information that investors do not have’. Journal of Financial Economics, 12, 187–

221.

Ohlson, J. (1995). Earnings, Book Values, and Dividends in Equity Valuation. Contemporary

Accounting Research, 11(2), 661–687.

Owens, E., Wu, J. S., & Zimmerman, J. (2017). Idiosyncratic Shocks to Firm Underlying

Economics and Abnormal Accruals. The Accounting Review, 92(2), 183–219.

Panaretou, A., Shackleton, M., & Taylor, P. (2013). Corporate Risk Management and Hedge

Accounting. Contemporary Accounting Research, 30(1), 116–139.

Pope, P., & McLeay, S. (2011). The European IFRS experiment: objectives, research

challenges and some early evidence. Accounting and Business Research, 41(3), 233–266.

Rajgopal, S., & Venkatachalam, M. (2011). Financial reporting quality and idiosyncratic

return volatility. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 51(1–2), 1–20.

Ramalingegowda, S., Wang, C., & Yu, Y. (2013). The Role of Financial Reporting Quality in

Mitigating the Constraining Effect of Dividend Policy on Investment Decisions. The

Accounting Review, 88(3), 1007–1039.

Rees, W. (1997). The impact of Dividends, Debt and Investment on Valuation Models.

Journal of Business Finance and Accounting, 24(1&2), 11–40.

Rees, W. (2005). Discussion of the Pricing of Dividends in Equity Valuation. Journal of

Business Finance and Accounting, 32((3) & (4)).

Rees, W., & Valentincic, A. (2013). Dividend irrelevance and accounting models of value.

Journal of Business Finance and Accounting, 40(5–6), 646–672.

Securities Exchange Commission (SEC). (2002). SEC Concept Release on International

Accounting Standards.

Shen, Y., & Stark, A. (2013). Evaluating the effectiveness of model specifications and

estimation approaches for empirical accounting-based valuation models. Accounting and

Business Research, 43(March 2015), 660–682.

Singleton-Green, B. (2015). The Effects of Mandatory in the EU: of Empirical Research.

Information for Better Markets, ICAEW.

Soderstrom, N., & Sun, K. J. (2007). IFRS Adoption and Accounting Quality: A Review.

European Accounting Review, 16(4), 675–702.

Wang, S., & Welker, M. (2011). Timing Equity Issuance in Response to Information

Asymmetry Arising from IFRS Adoption in Australia and Europe. Journal of Accounting

Research, 49(1), 257–307.

Wooldridge, J. (2010). Econometric analysis of cross section and panel data. Massachusetts:

MIT Press.

World Bank. (2014). GDP at market prices. Retrieved from

http://data.worldbank.org/indicator/NY.GDP.MKTP.CD

50

Appendix A: Variable Definitions (sorted alphabetically)

Variable Definition

%∆TA Change in total assets from year (t−1) to year (t), deflated by the average

of total assets in years prior to IFRS adoption.

∆LTD Change in long-term debt from year (t-1) to year (t), deflated the average

of total assets in years prior to IFRS adoption.

∆SALES Change in sales from year (t-1) to year (t), deflated by the average of

total assets in years prior to IFRS adoption.

1/TA Reciprocal of the deflator (the average of total assets in years prior to

IFRS adoption).

ACCDUM1

Dummy variable that takes the value 1 if the firm is a low accounting

quality firm, and 0 otherwise. This variable is constructed based on the

firm’s average absolute value of discretionary accruals in years prior to

IFRS (see Appendix B.1 for calculation).

ACCDUM2

Dummy variable that takes the value 1 if the firm is a low accounting

quality firm, and 0 otherwise. This variable is constructed based on the

firm’s variance of discretionary accruals in years prior to IFRS (see

Appendix B.2 for calculation).

BVE Book value of shareholders’ equity, deflated by the average of total

assets in years prior to IFRS adoption.

CAPX Capital expenditure, deflated by the average of total assets in years prior

to IFRS adoption.

CODE Dummy variable that takes the value 1 if the firm is listed in France, and

0 otherwise.

DIVDUM Dummy variable that takes the value 1 if the firm pays dividends in year

t, and 0 otherwise.

EBI Earnings before interest and after tax, deflated by the average of total

assets in years prior to IFRS adoption.

LEV Total liabilities, deflated by the average of total assets in years prior to

IFRS adoption.

LIQDT Total available cash, deflated by the average of total assets in years prior

to IFRS adoption.

LOGTA Natural logarithm of total assets.

LOSS Dummy variable that takes the value 1 if the net income is less than

zero.

MV

Firm’s market value, deflated by the average of total assets in years prior

to IFRS adoption; where the market value is the sum of total liabilities

and market capitalization (retrieved directly from DataStream).

NI Net income, deflated by the book value of equity.

NIBX Net income before extraordinary items, deflated by the average of total

assets in years prior to IFRS adoption.

OINFO Lagged residuals estimated from the regression of the value relevance

model, deflated by the average of total assets in years prior to IFRS

51

adoption.

POST Dummy variable that takes the value 1 if the year is greater than or equal

to 2005, and 0 otherwise.

PROCD Net amount of proceeds a company receives from selling equity,

deflated by the average of total assets in years prior to IFRS adoption.

REPUR Total stock repurchases, deflated by the average of total assets in years

prior to IFRS adoption.

RETDUM

Dummy variable that takes the value 1 if the firm is a low accounting

quality firm, and 0 otherwise. This variable is constructed based on the

firm’s average of annualized return volatility of daily stock returns.

RND

Research and development expenses, deflated by the average of total

assets in years prior to IFRS adoption. Missing values of this variable

are replaced with zeros.

TANG Total of property, plant and equipment, deflated by the average of total

assets in years prior to IFRS adoption.

TAX Income tax, deflated by the average of total assets in years prior to IFRS

adoption.

TDVD Total amount of dividend payouts, deflated by the average of total assets

in years prior to IFRS adoption.

TOBINQ

Firm’s market value, deflated by the average of total assets in years prior

to IFRS adoption; where the market value is the sum of total liabilities

and market capitalization (retrieved directly from DataStream).

52

Appendix B: Accounting Quality Metrics

Appendix B.1: The Modified Jones Model (Dechow et al., 1995)

We employ the modified cross-sectional Jones (1991) model as described in Dechow et al.

(1995) in order to calculate discretionary accruals for the first proxy for accounting quality.

The modified Jones model is estimated for the code-law sample in years prior to IFRS. We

run the regression equation below for each industry-year cross-section, where the industry

classification is based on the DataStream variable “INDM2”.

TACCit/TAit−1 = b0 + b1(1/TAit−1) + b2(∆REVit − ∆RECit)/TAit−1 + b3PPEit/TAit−1

+ b4ECON + eit

Where:

TACCit = NIBX - OCF, where NIBX is the net income before extraordinary items and OCF

is operating cash flow (Hribar & Collins, 2002).

TAit−1 = lagged total assets,

∆REVit = change in revenues,

∆RECit = change in receivables,

PPEit = property, plant and equipment,

ECON is a proxy for idiosyncratic economic shocks, defined as the firm-specific stock

return variation in year t and year t−1 (Owens et al., 2017). It is computed as the mean

squared errors of the residuals from the regression of the firm’s monthly return on monthly

industry return and monthly market return using 2 years of monthly data (year t and year

t−1).

Discretionary accruals are the predicted residuals from the regression model above

(Jones, Krishnan, & Melendrez, 2008; Kim, Liu, & Zheng, 2012). The first proxy for

accounting quality is the average absolute value of discretionary accruals for each firm in

years prior to IFRS.

53

Appendix B.2: The Mapping of Accruals into Cash Flows (Dechow & Dichev, 2002)

We use the cross-sectional version of the Dechow and Dichev (2002) model, as described

in Jones et al. (2008) in order to estimate accruals quality. Following Jones et al. (2008),

we run the regression equation below for each industry-year cross-section, where the

industry classification is based on the DataStream variable “INDM2”.

TACCit/TAit−1 = b0 +b1OCFt−1/TAit−1 + b2OCFt/TAit−1 + b3OCFt+1/TAit−1

+ b4∆REVit/TAit−1 + b5PPEit/TAit−1 + eit

Discretionary accruals are the predicted residuals from the regression model above

(Jones et al., 2008; Kim et al., 2012). The second proxy for accounting quality is the

variance of discretionary accruals for each firm in years prior to IFRS (Chen et al., 2015).

54

Figure 1. The average dividend payout for common-law and code-law firms between 2001 and 2008

Figure 1 presents the change in the average dividend payout in the UK (common-law firms) and France (code-law

firms) between 2001 and 2008.

55

Table 1. Summary statistics of the dividend payout model variables

Full Sample Common-law Sample Code-law Sample

N Mean S.D. Median

N Mean S.D. Median

N Mean S.D. Median

DIVDUM 7415 0.7099 0.4538 1.0000

4340 0.7484 0.4340 1.0000

3075 0.6556 0.4752 1.0000

TDVD 7415 0.0180 0.0206 0.0123

4340 0.0225 0.0221 0.0182

3075 0.0117 0.0162 0.0071

EBI 7415 0.0213 0.1669 0.0520

4340 0.0192 0.1917 0.0582

3075 0.0241 0.1236 0.0458

NI 7415 0.0333 0.5338 0.0970

4340 0.0354 0.5398 0.1008

3075 0.0305 0.5253 0.0932

TAX 7415 0.0188 0.0249 0.0161

4340 0.0191 0.0261 0.0165

3075 0.0184 0.0231 0.0157

RND 7415 0.0208 0.0530 0.0000

4340 0.0236 0.0568 0.0000

3075 0.0168 0.0469 0.0000

TOBINQ 7415 1.0543 1.1176 0.7151

4340 1.1922 1.1945 0.8159

3075 0.8597 0.9662 0.5780

%∆TA 7415 0.1285 0.4512 0.0491

4340 0.1472 0.4919 0.0574

3075 0.1019 0.3852 0.0430

LOGTA 7415 12.4348 2.0837 12.1373

4340 12.2907 2.0098 12.0579

3075 12.6382 2.1678 12.2677

LEV 7415 0.5788 0.2341 0.5855

4340 0.5454 0.2387 0.5479

3075 0.6261 0.2189 0.6301

REPUR 7415 0.0383 0.2557 0.0000

4340 0.0591 0.3325 0.0000

3075 0.0089 0.0161 0.0021

LOSS 7415 0.2384 0.4262 0.0000

4340 0.2482 0.4320 0.0000

3075 0.2247 0.4175 0.0000

TANG 7415 0.2407 0.2176 0.1750

4340 0.2778 0.2421 0.2045

3075 0.1884 0.1635 0.1482

LIQDT 7415 0.0956 0.1225 0.0545 4340 0.1146 0.1442 0.0620 3075 0.0688 0.0748 0.0488

Table 1 reports summary statistics for the variables of the dividend payout model. All variables are defined in Appendix A. All continuous variables are

winsorized at the 1% level to mitigate the influence of outliers.

56

Table 2. Comparative statistics on the level of dividend payout in UK and France

Panel A: Number of dividend-paying firms by year

Common-law Sample Code-law Sample

Year

N of +∆ %∆

N of +∆ %∆

2001

87 −

51 −

2002

85 −2.29%

62 21.56%

2003

83 −2.35%

76 22.58%

2004

74 −10.84%

70 −7.89%

2005

53 −28.37%

78 11.42%

2006

59 11.32%

53 −32.05%

2007

52 −11.86%

51 −3.77%

2008

56 7.69% 58 13.72%

Panel B: Average of deflated total dividends pre- and post-IFRS

Common-law Sample Code-law Sample

N

TDVD

(mean) %∆

N

TDVD

(mean) %∆

Pre-IFRS

2043 0.0225

1490 0.0102

Post-IFRS 2297 0.0225 0.07% 1585 0.0131 27.59%

Panel A: ‘N of +∆’ is the number of firms that increased their dividend payout from year t-1 to year t; ‘N of -∆’ is

the number of firms that decreased their dividend payout from year t-1 to year t; ‘%∆’ is the percentage change in

the dividend increase (decrease) from year t-1 to year t.

Panel B: TDVD (mean) is the average of the total dividends (deflated) and %∆ is the percentage change in TDVD

(mean) after adopting IFRS.

57

Table 3. Summary statistics of the dividend value relevance model variables

Common-law Sample Code-law Sample

N Mean S.D. Median

N Mean S.D. Median

MV

3688 1.1279 1.0482 0.8056

2373 0.8161 0.8144 0.5862

BVE

3688 0.4501 0.2399 0.4486

2373 0.3793 0.2173 0.3754

NIBX

3688 0.0054 0.1986 0.0422

2373 0.0150 0.1149 0.0329

LOSS

3688 0.2402 0.4273 0.0000

2373 0.2099 0.4073 0.0000

LOSS*BVE

3688 0.1128 0.2510 0.0000

2373 0.0596 0.1728 0.0000

LOSS*NIBX

3688 −0.0485 0.1768 0.0000

2373 −0.0267 0.0953 0.0000

CAPX

3688 0.0479 0.0481 0.0344

2373 0.0453 0.0429 0.0351

∆SALES

3688 0.0571 0.2491 0.0525

2373 0.0458 0.2017 0.0443

LIQDT

3688 0.1127 0.1388 0.0630

2373 0.0715 0.0772 0.0505

∆LTD

3688 0.0103 0.0810 0.0000

2373 0.0041 0.0721 −0.0008

RND

3688 0.0240 0.0579 0.0000

2373 0.0191 0.0497 0.0000

PROCD

3688 0.0263 0.0949 0.0011

2373 0.0154 0.0581 0.0002

TDVD

3688 0.0228 0.0223 0.0186

2373 0.0123 0.0168 0.0075

REPUR

3688 0.0701 0.3618 0.0000

2373 0.0095 0.0175 0.0023

POST

3688 0.5925 0.4914 1.0000

2373 0.6018 0.4896 1.0000

POST*BVE

3688 0.2612 0.2859 0.2254

2373 0.2347 0.2507 0.2249

POST*NIBX

3688 0.0106 0.1341 0.0000

2373 0.0166 0.0726 0.0000

POST*LOSS

3688 0.1261 0.3320 0.0000

2373 0.1066 0.3087 0.0000

POST*LOSS*BVE

3688 0.0587 0.1913 0.0000

2373 0.0313 0.1285 0.0000

POST*LOSS*NIBX

3688 −0.0238 0.1168 0.0000

2373 −0.0111 0.0538 0.0000

(continued on next page)

58

Table 3. (continued)

Common-law Sample Code-law Sample

N Mean S.D. Median N Mean S.D. Median

POST*TDVD

3688 0.0136 0.0209 0.0000

2373 0.0081 0.0157 0.0000

POST*REPUR

3688 0.0699 0.3619 0.0000

2373 0.0068 0.0171 0.0000

OINFO 3688 0.0139 1.0305 −0.0902 2373 −0.0014 0.7768 −0.0902

Table 3 reports summary statistics for the variables of the dividend value relevance model. All variables are defined in Appendix A. All continuous variables are

winsorized at the 1% level to mitigate the influence of outliers.

59

Table 4. Correlation matrix of the dividend payout model for the full sample

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11) (12) (13) (14)

(1) DIVDUM 1.000

(2) TDVD 0.561* 1.000

(3) EBI 0.354* 0.297

* 1.000

(4) NI 0.212* 0.184

* 0.491

* 1.000

(5) TAX 0.375* 0.492

* 0.420

* 0.277

* 1.000

(6) RND −0.269* −0.107

* −0.314

* −0.171

* −0.194

* 1.000

(7) TOBINQ −0.098* 0.249

* −0.128

* −0.031

* 0.194

* 0.376

* 1.000

(8) %∆TA −0.013 −0.078* 0.166

* 0.111

* 0.051

* −0.058

* 0.005 1.000

(9) LOGTA 0.393* 0.137

* 0.236

* 0.132

* 0.141

* −0.223

* −0.194

* 0.014 1.000

(10) LEV 0.026* −0.062

* −0.063

* 0.023

* −0.097

* −0.171

* −0.226

* −0.078

* 0.235

* 1.000

(11) REPUR 0.070* 0.112

* 0.054

* 0.029

* 0.085

* −0.005 0.041

* 0.020 0.109

* 0.024

* 1.000

(12) LOSS −0.431* −0.281

* −0.586

* −0.393

* −0.441

* 0.233

* 0.049

* −0.130

* −0.257

* 0.031

* −0.052

* 1.000

(13) TANG 0.144* 0.113

* 0.116

* 0.055

* 0.019

−0.195

* −0.159

* −0.034

* 0.204

* −0.001 0.022 −0.087

* 1.000

(14) LIQDT −0.199* 0.009 −0.138

* −0.048

* −0.014 0.261

* 0.303

* 0.038

* −0.279

* −0.244

* −0.002 0.117

* −0.256

* 1.000

Table 4 reports the Pearson correlation coefficients between all the variables of the dividend payout model based on the full sample. All variables are defined in Appendix

A. All continuous variables are winsorized at the 1% level to mitigate the influence of outliers. * Denotes significance at the 5% level or better.

60

Table 5. Correlation matrix of the dividend value relevance model for the full sample

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11) (12) (13) (14)

(1) MV 1.000

(2) BVE 0.232* 1.000

(3) NIBX −0.088* 0.149

* 1.000

(4) LOSS 0.020 −0.065* −0.590

* 1.000

(5) LOSS*BVE 0.123* 0.438

* −0.330

* 0.695

* 1.000

(6) LOSS*NIBX −0.234* 0.117

* 0.959

* −0.493

* −0.251

* 1.000

(7) CAPX 0.031* −0.006 0.067

* −0.085

* −0.080

* 0.045

* 1.000

(8) ∆SALES 0.086* 0.047

* 0.273

* −0.291

* −0.145

* 0.215

* 0.069

* 1.000

(9)LIQDT 0.303* 0.217

* −0.118

* 0.117

* 0.224

* −0.179

* −0.094

* 0.014 1.000

(10) ∆LTD −0.011 −0.051* 0.029

* −0.070

* −0.049

* 0.041

* 0.100

* 0.145

* −0.039

* 1.000

(11) RND 0.380* 0.137

* −0.323

* 0.224

* 0.244

* −0.353

* −0.124

* −0.075

* 0.248

* −0.041

* 1.000

(12) PROCD 0.196* 0.139

* −0.285

* 0.205

* 0.268

* −0.288

* 0.012 0.015 0.262

* −0.045

* 0.180

* 1.000

(13) TDVD 0.310* 0.073

* 0.296

* −0.285

* −0.195

* 0.171

* 0.055

* 0.049

* 0.007 0.016 −0.090

* −0.166

* 1.000

(14) REPUR 0.069* −0.013 0.058

* −0.055

* −0.040

* 0.031

* 0.003 0.022 −0.006 0.040

* −0.007 −0.027

* 0.124

* 1.000

Table 5 reports the Pearson correlation coefficients between the main variables of the dividend value relevance model based on the full sample. All variables are defined in

Appendix A. All continuous variables are winsorized at the 1% level to mitigate the influence of outliers. * Denotes significance at the 5% level or better.

61

Table 6. The change in dividend payouts following IFRS adoption (H1 - OLS regressions)

Common-law Code-law All

TDVD TDVD TDVD

POST −0.0001 0.0019***

−0.0001

(−0.17) (5.29) (−0.12)

CODE −0.0108***

(−12.49)

POST*CODE 0.0021***

(4.15)

EBI 0.0162***

0.0154***

0.0165***

(6.56) (5.77) (8.65)

NI −0.0005 0.0005 −0.0001

(−0.75) (1.24) (−0.33)

TAX 0.3178***

0.2589***

0.3000***

(19.16) (14.54) (24.53)

RND −0.0001 −0.0238***

−0.0102**

(−0.01) (−3.60) (−2.07)

TOBINQ 0.0042***

0.0034***

0.0041***

(10.60) (6.67) (13.29)

%∆TA −0.0064***

−0.0038***

−0.0058***

(−9.36) (−5.38) (−11.17)

LOGTA 0.0006***

0.0005***

0.0007***

(3.84) (4.55) (6.38)

LEV 0.0034**

−0.0073***

0.0007

(2.41) (−5.05) (0.67)

REPUR 0.0030***

0.0322 0.0032***

(3.44) (1.36) (3.68)

LOSS −0.0014* 0.0004 −0.0011

*

(−1.73) (0.53) (−1.90)

TANG 0.0039***

0.0001 0.0029***

(3.10) (0.04) (2.82)

(continued on next page)

62

Table 6. (continued)

Common-law Code-law All

TDVD TDVD TDVD

LIQDT 0.0009 −0.0032 −0.0009

(0.36) (−0.75) (−0.41)

Intercept −0.0014 −0.0054* 0.0001

(−0.43) (−1.86) (0.08)

Adjusted R2 37.63% 34.82% 39.84%

N 4340 3075 7415

Table 6 presents results on the difference in the change in dividend payouts following IFRS adoption among

common-law and code-law firms using a difference-in-differences research design.

The first two columns of Table 6 report results from the OLS regressions of total dividend payout on a set of firm

characteristics and the IFRS dummy, using the common-law and code-law samples respectively. The third column

of Table 6 reports results from the OLS regression of total dividend payout on a set of firm characteristics and the

difference-in-differences dummies, using the full sample. All variables are defined in Appendix A. All continuous

variables are winsorized at the 1% level to mitigate the influence of outliers. All regressions include year and

industry fixed effects. The t-statistics, presented in parentheses below the coefficients, are corrected for

heteroscedasticity and cross-sectional and time-series correlation using a two-way cluster at the firm level. *,

**,

***

Denote significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively.

63

Table 7. The change in dividend payouts following IFRS adoption (H1 - Fully Interacted Linear Model)

Common-law Code-law All

TDVD TDVD TDVD

POST 0.0001 0.0019***

0.0001

(0.31) (5.42) (0.21)

CODE −0.0105***

(−12.18)

POST*CODE 0.0020***

(3.97)

EBI 0.0124***

0.0106***

0.0124***

(4.41) (4.06) (4.40)

NI −0.0013 −0.0002 −0.0014

(−1.32) (−0.45) (−1.34)

TAX 0.3632***

0.2332***

0.3649***

(15.58) (11.04) (15.67)

RND −0.0132 −0.0182**

−0.0129

(−1.61) (−2.06) (−1.59)

TOBINQ 0.0028***

0.0024***

0.0029***

(5.71) (4.49) (5.86)

%∆TA −0.0091***

−0.0030***

−0.0090***

(−8.06) (−3.59) (−8.05)

LOGTA 0.0001 0.0003**

0.0001

(0.10) (2.11) (0.82)

LEV 0.0090***

−0.0078***

0.0091***

(4.31) (−5.55) (4.39)

REPUR −0.0317 0.0946***

−0.0426

(−0.28) (2.61) (−0.38)

LOSS −0.0031***

−0.0016* −0.0030

***

(−2.82) (−1.93) (−2.69)

TANG 0.0066***

0.0051***

0.0068***

(4.04) (3.09) (4.19)

(continued on next page)

64

Table 7. (continued)

Common-law Code-law All

TDVD TDVD TDVD

LIQDT −0.0023 0.0065 −0.0017

(−0.69) (1.31) (−0.53)

Intercept 0.0028 0.0025 0.0046

(0.53) (0.50) (1.22)

Adjusted R2 38.90% 36.30% 41.70%

N 4340 3075 7415

Table 7 presents results on the difference in the change in dividend payouts following IFRS adoption among

common-law and code-law firms using a fully interacted linear model of the difference-in-differences research

design.

The first two columns of Table 7 report results from the OLS regressions of total dividend payout on a set of firm

characteristics and the IFRS dummy, after interacting all variables with the IFRS dummy, using the common-law

and code-law samples respectively. The third column of Table 7 reports results from the OLS regression of total

dividend payout on a set of firm characteristics and the difference-in-differences dummies, after interacting all

variables with the difference-in-differences dummies, using the full sample. We do not report the coefficients on the

interactions for the sake of brevity. All variables are defined in Appendix A. All continuous variables are winsorized

at the 1% level to mitigate the influence of outliers. All regressions include year and industry fixed effects. The t-

statistics, presented in parentheses below the coefficients, are corrected for heteroscedasticity by clustering at the

firm level. *,

**,

*** Denote significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively.

65

Table 8. The change in dividend payouts following IFRS adoption (H1 - Logistic regressions)

Common-law Code-law All

DIVDUM DIVDUM DIVDUM

POST −0.1050 0.5510***

0.0456

(−0.59) (3.13) (0.30)

CODE −1.3230***

(−7.81)

POST*CODE 0.3500**

(2.24)

EBI 1.5270***

3.5110***

1.5530***

(3.46) (4.03) (3.91)

NI −0.134 0.2040* −0.0057

(−1.00) (1.72) (−0.07)

TAX 24.6701***

34.2609***

28.0540***

(7.17) (8.00) (10.25)

RND −5.5750***

−5.1010***

−4.4030***

(−2.80) (−2.64) (−3.09)

TOBINQ 0.0376 −0.1230 −0.0055

(0.46) (−1.11) (−0.09)

%∆TA −0.5250***

−0.0760 −0.3980***

(−5.22) (−0.60) (−5.08)

LOGTA 0.3740***

0.5110***

0.4600***

(5.99) (8.36) (10.41)

LEV −0.1210 −2.4080***

−0.9470***

(−0.33) (−5.38) (−3.46)

REPUR 0.6110**

15.8800**

0.5830

(2.00) (2.22) (1.67)

LOSS −1.0920***

−0.8660***

−1.0838***

(−7.05) (−4.37) (−9.00)

TANG −0.5430 0.1406 −0.3120

(−1.18) (0.21) (−0.84)

(continued on next page)

66

Table 8. (continued)

Common-law Code-law All

DIVDUM DIVDUM DIVDUM

LIQDT −2.7770***

−0.9610 −2.1022***

(−4.03) (−0.87) (−3.55)

Intercept −2.6734**

−6.6960***

−3.2990***

(−2.27) (−5.19) (−3.45)

Pseudo R2 38.47% 37.25% 36.97%

N 4340 3075 7415

Table 8 presents results on the difference in the change in the propensity to pay dividends following IFRS adoption

among common-law and code-law firms using a difference-in-differences research design.

The first two columns of Table 8 report results from the Logistic regressions of the dividend payout dummy on a set

of firm characteristics and the IFRS dummy, using the common-law and code-law samples respectively. The third

column of Table 8 reports results from the Logistic regression of the dividend payout dummy on a set of firm

characteristics and the difference-in-differences dummies, using the full sample. All variables are defined in

Appendix A. All continuous variables are winsorized at the 1% level to mitigate the influence of outliers. All

regressions include year and industry fixed effects. The t-statistics, presented in parentheses below the coefficients,

are corrected for heteroscedasticity by clustering at the firm level. *,

**,

*** Denote significance at the 10%, 5%, and

1% levels, respectively.

67

Table 9. The change in dividend payouts following IFRS adoption (H1 - Firm Fixed Effects regressions)

Common-law Code-law All

TDVD TDVD TDVD

POST 0.0008 0.0016***

0.0005

(1.41) (3.29) (0.99)

CODE

POST*CODE 0.0016**

(2.22)

EBI 0.0011 0.0032 0.0012

(0.48) (1.31) (0.67)

NI −0.0008 0.0001 −0.0003

(−1.61) (0.93) (−1.31)

TAX 0.0855***

0.0563**

0.0746***

(5.11) (2.57) (5.74)

RND −0.0007 0.0024 −0.0007

(−0.07) (0.25) (−0.12)

TOBINQ 0.0014***

0.0025***

0.0018***

(3.71) (4.18) (5.61)

%∆TA −0.0025***

−0.0026***

−0.0025***

(−5.71) (−4.66) (−7.31)

LOGTA 0.0002 0.0018 0.0008

(0.27) (1.87) (1.37)

LEV −0.0047* −0.0028 −0.0043

**

(−1.75) (−1.22) (−2.25)

REPUR 0.0020***

0.0494**

0.0021***

(2.66) (2.03) (2.71)

LOSS −0.0007 0.0001 −0.0004

(−1.02) (0.21) (−0.78)

TANG 0.0048 −0.0001 0.0035

(1.38) (−0.04) (1.30)

(continued on next page)

68

Table 9. (continued)

Common-law Code-law All

TDVD TDVD TDVD

LIQDT 0.0018 0.0022 0.0018

(0.65) (0.41) (0.75)

Intercept 0.0177* −0.0140 0.0051

(1.83) (−1.08) (0.65)

Overall R2 22.37% 19.64% 23.20%

N 4340 3075 7415

Table 9 presents results on the difference in the change in dividend payouts following IFRS adoption among

common-law and code-law firms using a difference-in-differences research design

The first two columns of Table 9 report results from the firm Fixed Effects regressions of total dividend payout on a

set of firm characteristics and the IFRS dummy, using the common-law and code-law samples respectively. The

third column of Table 9 reports results from the firm Fixed Effect regression of total dividend payout on a set of firm

characteristics and the difference-in-differences dummies, using the full sample. All variables are defined in

Appendix A. All continuous variables are winsorized at the 1% level to mitigate the influence of outliers. All

regressions include year fixed effects. The t-statistics, presented in parentheses below the coefficients, are corrected

for heteroscedasticity by clustering at the firm level. *,

**,

*** Denote significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels,

respectively.

69

Table 10. The change in dividend payouts following IFRS based on matched OLS regressions (H1)

Common-law Code-law All

TDVD TDVD TDVD

POST −0.0003 0.0023***

−0.0004

(−0.23) (2.63) (−0.33)

CODE −0.0120***

(−13.51)

POST*CODE 0.0028**

(2.03)

EBI 0.0264***

0.0192**

0.0227***

(3.43) (2.47) (4.54)

NI 0.0001 0.0011 0.0004

(0.04) (1.03) (0.38)

TAX 0.2555***

0.2812***

0.2769***

(5.91) (8.11) (9.68)

RND 0.028 −0.0266**

0.0013

(1.55) (−2.27) (0.12)

TOBINQ 0.0047***

0.0049***

0.0050***

(3.54) (4.97) (5.79)

%∆TA −0.0083***

−0.0050***

−0.0069***

(−4.89) (−3.13) (−6.08)

LOGTA 0.0005 0.0001 0.0004

(1.42) (0.12) (1.59)

LEV 0.0054 −0.0060**

0.0006

(1.51) (−2.09) (0.24)

REPUR 0.0010 0.0136 0.0009

(0.65) (0.38) (0.58)

LOSS 0.0025 0.0008 0.0016

(1.07) (0.56) (1.11)

TANG 0.0026 −0.0027 0.0005

(1.02) (−1.18) (0.25)

(continued on next page)

70

Table 10. (continued)

Common-law Code-law All

TDVD TDVD TDVD

LIQDT −0.0037 −0.0146**

−0.0070

(−0.55) (−1.99) (−1.32)

Intercept −0.0018 0.0073 −0.0181***

(−0.24) (1.11) (−4.99)

Adjusted R2 23.82% 38.19% 33.10%

N 1024 1024 2048

Table 10 presents results on the difference in the change in dividend payouts following IFRS adoption among

common-law and code-law firms using a matched difference-in-differences research design. The regressions are

matched, using CEM matching, based on ROA, Total Assets, Industry and IFRS. The first two columns of Table 10

report results from the OLS regressions of total dividend payout on a set of firm characteristics and the IFRS

dummy, using the common-law and code-law matched observations respectively. The third column of Table 10

reports results from the OLS regression of total dividend payout on a set of firm characteristics and the difference-

in-differences dummies, using the full matched sample. All variables are defined in Appendix A. All continuous

variables are winsorized at the 1% level to mitigate the influence of outliers. All regressions include year and

industry fixed effects. The t-statistics, presented in parentheses below the coefficients, are corrected for

heteroscedasticity by clustering at the firm level. *,

**,

*** Denote significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels,

respectively.

71

Table 11. The variation in the IFRS effect on dividend payouts among code-law firms (H2 - ACCDUM1)

High Quality Low Quality All

TDVD TDVD TDVD

POST 0.0016**

0.0030***

0.0014*

(2.14) (4.79) (1.90)

ACCDUM1 −0.0002

(−0.25)

POST*ACCDUM1 0.0022**

(2.27)

EBI 0.0103***

0.0310***

0.0157***

(4.28) (3.41) (5.93)

NI 0.0003 0.0016 0.0005

(0.71) (1.63) (1.30)

TAX 0.2321***

0.2100***

0.2565***

(9.31) (8.38) (14.38)

RND −0.0234***

−0.0285***

−0.0241***

(−2.87) (−3.20) (−3.66)

TOBINQ 0.0017***

0.0066***

0.0034***

(3.09) (8.48) (6.76)

%∆TA −0.0032***

−0.0041***

−0.0037***

(−4.14) (−3.30) (−5.27)

LOGTA 0.0007***

0.0004***

0.0005***

(3.06) (2.75) (3.65)

LEV −0.0062***

−0.0116***

−0.0071***

(−4.55) (−4.28) (−4.86)

REPUR −0.0006 0.0775***

0.0325

(−0.02) (2.88) (1.39)

(continued on next page)

72

Table 11. (continued)

High Quality Low Quality All

TDVD TDVD TDVD

LOSS −0.0009 0.0017 0.0004

(−0.95) (1.54) (0.51)

TANG 0.0025 −0.003 −0.0005

(0.81) (−1.41) (−0.26)

LIQDT 0.007 −0.0142**

−0.0032

(1.26) (−2.04) (−0.74)

Intercept 0.0014 0.0130***

0.005

(0.20) (3.61) (1.51)

Adjusted R2 29.51% 44.22% 35.00%

N 1511 1564 3075

Table 11 presents results on the difference in the change in dividend payouts following IFRS adoption among high-

and low- accounting quality firms in the code-law sample using a difference-in-differences research design. In this

table we use the average absolute value of discretionary accruals, in years prior to IFRS, after controlling for

idiosyncratic economic shocks, as a proxy for accounting quality.

The first two columns of Table 11 report results from the OLS regressions of total dividend payout on a set of firm

characteristics and the IFRS dummy, using the high- and low- accounting quality firms in the code-law samples

respectively. The third column of Table 11 reports results from the OLS regression of total dividend payout on a set

of firm characteristics and the difference-in-differences dummies, using all code-law firms. The average of absolute

value of discretionary accruals is the used criterion in categorizing code-law firms as high- or low- accounting

quality firms. All variables are defined in Appendix A. All continuous variables are winsorized at the 1% level to

mitigate the influence of outliers. All regressions include year and industry fixed effects. The t-statistics, presented

in parentheses below the coefficients, are corrected for heteroscedasticity by clustering at the firm level. *,

**,

***

Denote significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively.

73

Table 12. The variation in the IFRS effect on dividend payouts among code-law firms (H2 - ACCDUM2)

High Quality Low Quality All

TDVD TDVD TDVD

POST 0.0009 0.0035***

0.0009

(1.26) (5.23) (1.39)

ACCDUM2 0.0008

(1.32)

POST*ACCDUM2 0.0032***

(3.35)

EBI 0.0099***

0.0326***

0.0157***

(4.32) (2.75) (5.97)

NI 0.0001 0.0045**

0.0005

(0.40) (1.99) (1.25)

TAX 0.2244***

0.2047***

0.2549***

(9.71) (7.17) (14.39)

RND −0.0137* −0.0486

*** −0.0244

***

(−1.75) (−4.59) (−3.72)

TOBINQ 0.0017***

0.0078***

0.0035***

(3.28) (6.82) (6.90)

%∆TA −0.0026***

−0.0046***

−0.0035***

(−3.86) (−3.60) (−5.04)

LOGTA 0.0008***

0.0001 0.0004***

(4.58) (0.43) (3.19)

LEV −0.0047***

−0.0109***

−0.0067***

(−3.84) (−3.53) (−4.73)

REPUR 0.0288 0.1021***

0.0355

(1.19) (2.98) (1.51)

(continued on next page)

74

Table 12. (continued)

High Quality Low Quality All

TDVD TDVD TDVD

LOSS −0.0007 0.0023* 0.0007

(−0.92) (1.72) (0.99)

TANG −0.002 0.0003 −0.0009

(−1.07) (0.11) (−0.53)

LIQDT −0.0012 −0.0116 −0.0036

(−0.26) (−1.57) (−0.84)

Intercept −0.0011 0.0033 0.0053

(−0.27) (0.79) (1.63)

Adjusted R2 30.97% 45.34% 35.51%

N 1592 1483 3075

Table 12 presents results on the difference in the change in dividend payouts following IFRS adoption among high-

and low- accounting quality firms in the code-law sample using a difference-in-differences research design. In this

table we use the variance of the firm’s discretionary accruals in years prior to IFRS, calculated following Dechow

and Dichev (2002), as a proxy for accounting quality.

The first two columns of Table 12 report results from the OLS regressions of total dividend payout on a set of firm

characteristics and the IFRS dummy, using the high- and low- accounting quality firms in the code-law samples

respectively. The third column of Table 12 reports results from the OLS regression of total dividend payout on a set

of firm characteristics and the difference-in-differences dummies, using all code-law firms. The variance of

discretionary accruals is the used criterion in categorizing code-law firms as high- or low- accounting quality firms.

All variables are defined in Appendix A. All continuous variables are winsorized at the 1% level to mitigate the

influence of outliers. All regressions include year and industry fixed effects. The t-statistics, presented in

parentheses below the coefficients, are corrected for heteroscedasticity by clustering at the firm level. *,

**,

***

Denote significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively.

75

Table 13. The variation in the IFRS effect on dividend payouts among code-law firms (H2 - RETDUM)

High Quality Low Quality All

TDVD TDVD TDVD

POST 0.0015**

0.0028***

0.0015**

(2.43) (4.12) (2.39)

RETDUM 0.0052***

(7.596)

POST*RETDUM 0.0024***

(2.642)

EBI 0.0104***

0.0214 0.0166***

(4.61) (1.33) (6.38)

NI 0.0000 0.0088**

0.0004

(0.03) (2.15) (1.15)

TAX 0.1984***

0.1357***

0.2400***

(7.95) (4.35) (13.46)

RND −0.0112* −0.0197

* −0.0203

***

(−1.79) (−1.76) (−3.18)

TOBINQ 0.0017***

0.0102***

0.0036***

(3.66) (9.84) (7.30)

%∆TA −0.0021***

−0.0048***

−0.0035***

(−3.64) (−3.19) (−5.17)

LOGTA 0.0005**

−0.0001 0.0001

(2.39) (−0.38) (0.81)

LEV −0.0032***

−0.0132***

−0.0054***

(−3.15) (−4.34) (−3.92)

REPUR −0.0088 0.0387 0.0252

(−0.39) (1.35) (1.12)

LOSS −0.0002 0.0037**

0.0018**

(−0.36) (1.98) (2.56)

TANG 0.0025 −0.0014 −0.0004

(1.47) (−0.53) (−0.23)

(continued on next page)

76

Table 13. (continued)

High Quality Low Quality All

TDVD TDVD TDVD

LIQDT 0.0053 −0.0031 −0.0004

(1.02) (−0.41) (−0.10)

Intercept −0.0080**

0.0170***

0.0080***

(−2.00) (3.39) (2.57)

Adjusted R2 25.35% 42.61% 37.44%

N 1483 1592 3075

Table 13 presents results on the difference in the change in dividend payouts following IFRS adoption among high-

and low- accounting quality firms in the code-law sample using a difference-in-differences research design. In this

table we use the firm’s average annualized variance of stock returns, in years prior to IFRS, as a proxy for

accounting quality.

The first two columns of Table 13 report results from the OLS regressions of total dividend payout on a set of firm

characteristics and the IFRS dummy, using the high- and low- accounting quality firms in the code-law samples

respectively. The third column of Table 13 reports results from the OLS regression of total dividend payout on a set

of firm characteristics and the difference-in-differences dummies, using all code-law firms. The average of the

annualized variance of daily stock returns is the used criterion in categorizing code-law firms as high- or low-

accounting quality firms. All variables are defined in Appendix A. All continuous variables are winsorized at the 1%

level to mitigate the influence of outliers. All regressions include year and industry fixed effects. The t-statistics,

presented in parentheses below the coefficients, are corrected for heteroscedasticity by clustering at the firm level. *,

**,

*** Denote significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively.

77

Table 14. The change in the dividend value relevance following IFRS adoption (H3 - OLS regressions)

Model 1 Model 2 Model 3

Common-law Code-law Common-law Code-law Common-law Code-law

MV MV MV MV MV MV

POST 0.2108***

0.1818***

0.0177 −0.0881 0.0022 −0.0917

(6.48) (6.42) (0.26) (−1.57) (0.03) (−1.47)

TDVD 12.4074***

11.7295***

12.7830***

13.5585***

12.6701***

13.3559***

(14.28) (8.99) (13.72) (9.22) (13.41) (9.10)

POST*TDVD −1.2652 −5.1882***

−1.8106 −7.5324***

−1.5153 −7.1761***

(−1.23) (−3.68) (−1.54) (−4.55) (−1.26) (−4.31)

REPUR 2.6458 6.8973***

3.2203 8.6480***

3.1568 8.8338***

(0.59) (4.14) (0.72) (5.22) (0.71) (5.38)

POST*REPUR −2.6483 0.5649 −3.2218 −1.6527 −3.1597 −1.8481

(−0.59) (0.32) (−0.72) (−0.93) (−0.71) (−1.05)

LOSS 0.1354**

0.2269***

0.0293 0.1841***

0.0252 0.2146***

(2.40) (4.64) (0.34) (2.61) (0.29) (3.03)

POST*LOSS 0.0529 −0.0226 0.0651 −0.0444

(0.48) (−0.24) (0.58) (−0.46)

BVE 0.0384 0.7205***

0.0556 0.4244***

0.0529 0.4531***

(0.61) (10.92) (0.56) (4.15) (0.53) (4.47)

POST*BVE −0.0152 0.4908***

−0.021 0.4455***

(−0.12) (3.75) (−0.17) (3.41)

LOSS*BVE 0.2270**

−0.1184 0.2746* −0.2646

* −5.5483

*** −4.4502

***

(2.33) (−1.12) (1.86) (−1.71) (−11.29) (−7.41)

POST*LOSS*BVE 0.0777 0.3853* 0.0165 0.3844

*

(0.41) (1.85) (0.08) (1.85)

NIBX 6.4330***

5.5672***

4.8759***

4.1648***

5.1642***

4.0943***

(21.93) (17.09) (10.55) (7.38) (10.85) (7.21)

(continued on next page)

78

Table 14. (continued)

Model 1 Model 2 Model 3

Common-law Code-law Common-law Common-law Code-law Common-law

MV MV MV MV MV MV

POST*NIBX 2.4280***

1.9504***

1.9957***

2.0793***

(4.28) (2.94) (3.35) (3.07)

LOSS*NIBX −7.3179***

−6.0923***

−5.2069***

−4.2543***

0.3163**

−0.3352**

(−23.89) (−17.00) (−10.99) (−7.17) (2.12) (−2.18)

POST*LOSS*NIBX −3.7861***

−3.3391***

−3.2574***

−3.0550***

(−6.51) (−4.64) (−5.25) (−4.15)

CAPX 1.4516***

0.6239**

1.4482***

0.6452***

1.3239***

0.5262

(5.96) (2.50) (6.03) (2.62) (3.53) (1.33)

POST*CAPX 0.1455 0.1726

(0.31) (0.35)

∆SALES 0.2610***

0.2412***

0.2647***

0.2481***

0.1901***

0.4302***

(5.44) (4.27) (5.58) (4.43) (2.74) (5.31)

POST*∆SALES 0.1338 −0.2957***

(1.41) (−2.67)

LIQDT 0.4527***

0.2547* 0.4167

*** 0.2512

* 0.3833

*** 0.3226

(4.94) (1.82) (4.61) (1.82) (2.91) (1.39)

POST*LIQDT 0.0455 −0.0617

(0.26) (−0.22)

∆LTD −0.1383 0.1770 −0.1077 0.2195 −0.1352 −0.2883

(−0.98) (1.21) (−0.78) (1.52) (−0.59) (−1.27)

POST*∆LTD 0.049 0.8365***

(0.17) (2.88)

RND 5.4741***

3.3614***

5.4418***

3.2082***

4.6215***

2.6889***

(21.84) (14.37) (22.03) (13.85) (13.88) (8.15)

(continued on next page)

79

Table 14. (continued)

Model 1 Model 2 Model 3

Common-law Code-law Common-law Common-law Code-law Common-law

MV MV MV MV MV MV

POST*RND 1.5335***

0.9219**

(3.51) (2.10)

PROCD 1.0700***

−0.1271 0.9173***

−0.1905 1.3032***

−1.2176***

(8.21) (−0.69) (7.06) (−1.03) (6.12) (−3.68)

POST*PROCD −0.5513**

1.4902***

(−2.05) (3.76)

OINFO 0.3567***

0.4401***

0.3602***

0.4537***

0.3587***

0.4679***

(33.57) (32.91) (33.68) (34.06) (33.45) (35.18)

1/TA 2117.4988***

3664.9529***

2133.2240***

3980.1302***

2111.0392***

3939.5557***

(6.24) (8.26) (6.36) (9.06) (6.19) (9.06)

H0:

POST*TDVD (UK) =

POST*TDVD (France)

Chi2 = 2.83

p-value = 0.0925

Chi2 = 4.37

p-value = 0.0360

Chi2 = 4.12

p-value = 0.0424

Adjusted R2 81.43% 82.08% 81.97% 82.65% 81.99% 83.13%

N 3688 2373 3688 2373 3688 2373

Model 1 of Table 14 reports results from the OLS regressions of market value on a set of firm characteristics, the IFRS dummy and

interactions between the IFRS dummy with total dividends and stock repurchases, using common-law and code-law samples. Model

2 of Table 14 reports results from the OLS regressions of market value on a set of firm characteristics, the IFRS dummy, and the

interaction between the IFRS dummy with accounting variables, total dividends and stock repurchases, using the common-law and

code-law samples. Model 3 of Table 14 reports results from the OLS regressions of market value on a set of firm characteristics, the

IFRS dummy and the interaction between the IFRS dummy and all other variables, using the common-law and code-law samples.

We use the Chi2 statistic in order to test the significance of the difference in the change in dividend value relevance between the

common-law and the code-law samples. All variables are defined in Appendix A. All continuous variables are winsorized at the 1%

level to mitigate the influence of outliers. All regressions include year and industry fixed effects. The t-statistics, presented in

parentheses below the coefficients, are corrected for heteroscedasticity by clustering at the firm level. *,

**,

*** Denote significance at

the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively.

80

Chapter 3

Does Changing Accounting Standards Affect Equity Financing?

ABSTRACT: Prior literature indicates that managers manipulate earnings prior to issuing

Seasoned Equity Offerings (SEOs), especially when information asymmetry is high. We

exploit the mandatory adoption of IFRS in Europe in 2005 in order to test the change in the

level of earnings management prior to issuing SEOs in the UK and France. The UK is a

common-law country with an accounting system similar to IFRS, whereas France is a

code-law country with an accounting system that differs materially from IFRS. Despite this

difference, both countries are highly comparable economically and institutionally. This

facilitates the implementation of a difference-in-differences methodology, where the UK is

the control group and France is the treatment group. Our findings suggest that, following

IFRS adoption, earnings management activities decrease among code-law firms prior to

issuing SEOs. As a result of the lower levels of earnings management and information

asymmetry, we predict and find that the market reaction to issuing SEOs improves

significantly for code-law firms following IFRS. Given that equity financing becomes less

costly, we find that the propensity to issue new SEOs increases among code-law firms after

IFRS adoption. The results persist after running a matched-sample analysis and controlling

for self-selection bias.

Keywords: IFRS; Information Asymmetry; Earnings Management; Seasoned Equity

Offerings; Equity Financing.

81

3.1. Introduction

Since the implementation of International Financial Reporting Standards (IFRS) in 2005 in

the European Union, a large number of studies have examined the consequences of the

mandatory adoption of IFRS. This paper adds to this long standing literature and examines

the effect of IFRS adoption on various aspects of seasoned equity offerings (SEOs).

Specifically, we evaluate the change in the level of earnings management prior to issuing

SEOs, the change in the market reaction to SEO announcements and the change in the

propensity to issue SEOs following the IFRS mandate.

We examine these issues using a difference-in-differences research design, after we

control for potential factors that might confound with IFRS adoption. We differentiate

between common-law and code-law legal systems since accounting standards differ

materially between both systems (La Porta, Lopez-De-Silanes, Shleifer, & Vishny, 1998).

We expect IFRS to have a greater impact in code-law countries due to the material

difference between the code-law accounting standards and IFRS (Hong, Hung, & Lobo,

2014; Joos & Lang, 1994; Kaufmann, Kraay, & Mastruzzi, 2007). Thus, code-law firms

serve as a treatment group for our test of the IFRS adoption effect. On the other hand, we

expect a nominal effect for IFRS adoption in common-law countries because IFRS were

initially developed in the spirit of common-law accounting standards (Ball, Kothari, &

Robin, 2000). As such, common-law firms serve as a control group for testing the impact

of IFRS adoption. We select the UK as a common-law country and France as a code-law

country. This selection is based on the high comparability between both economies, which

leaves the difference in accounting standards prior to mandatory IFRS adoption the main

variant factor (see section 3.5.1 for details). Based on this setting, we formulate the

following three hypotheses.

First, we hypothesize that IFRS adoption will moderate earnings management prior to

issuing SEOs among code-law firms. Warfield, Wild, & Wild (1995) find that the level of

earnings management is higher when information asymmetry is higher. In an SEO setting,

82

Teoh et al. (1998) and Shivakumar (2000) find that managers manipulate earnings prior to

SEO announcements. To the extent IFRS mitigate information asymmetry (Daske, Hail,

Leuz, & Verdi, 2008; Muller, Riedl, & Sellhorn, 2011) and improve accounting quality

(Barth, Landsman, & Lang, 2008), we expect mandatory adoption of IFRS to reduce the

level of earnings management prior to issuing SEOs.

Second, we hypothesize that the market reaction to SEO announcements will become

more favorable among code-law firms following IFRS adoption. Myers & Majluf (1984)

theorize that the main reason behind the high cost associated with equity financing is the

existence of asymmetric information, relating to assets in place, between managers and

investors. Therefore, we argue that if IFRS serve to mitigate information asymmetry

relating to assets in place, then the market should attach a lower discount rate for SEOs

after mandatory IFRS adoption.

Third, we hypothesize that the propensity to issue SEOs will increase after IFRS

adoption among code-law firms. Eckbo, Masulis, & Norli (2007) document that issuing

SEOs is a rare phenomenon among public firms because investors underprice the offered

shares due to the existence of asymmetric information and the adverse selection problem.

If IFRS serve to mitigate information asymmetry and consequently improve the market

reaction to SEO announcements, then the cost of equity financing is reduced and managers

are expected to issue SEOs more frequently.

The empirical findings are consistent with our hypotheses. First, we find that the level

of earnings management, prior to issuing SEOs, decreases after IFRS adoption among

code-law firms compared to common-law firms. This finding holds after controlling for

real earnings management (Cohen & Zarowin, 2010) and idiosyncratic economic shocks

(Owens, Wu, & Zimmerman, 2017). Next, we find that the market reaction to SEO

announcements improves after IFRS adoption among code-law firms compared to their

common-law counterparts. This finding holds after controlling for self-selection bias

(Heckman, 1979). Finally, we find that the propensity to issue SEOs increases after IFRS

83

adoption among French firms compared to UK firms. The consistency of observing IFRS

impact on the treatment group, as opposed to the control group, reduces the likelihood that

our findings are attributed to other unidentified confounding effects.

As a robustness check, we run a matched-sample analysis in order to compare firms that

fall on the common support area of the distribution. We use Coarsened Exact Matching

(Iacus, King, & Porro, 2012), where we match each code-law observation to a common-

law observation based on total assets, industry and IFRS time period. The results hold after

running the matched-sample analysis and our conclusions remain unchanged.

Our findings reconcile with Hong et al. (2014) who find that the market reaction to

IPOs has improved globally following IFRS adoption. Our study contributes further to

Hong et al. (2014) by showing that the effect of IFRS adoption on equity financing is not

only transitory around the first equity offering (IPOs), but also permanent around later

equity offerings (SEOs). Moreover, our sample selection focuses on the high comparability

between the treatment and the control groups, based on economic and institutional factors

which cannot be entirely controlled for in international studies.

We contribute to the literature of financial reporting and corporate finance by showing

how changing accounting standards affects corporate financing through SEOs. The main

findings are that IFRS adoption serves to deter earnings management prior to the issue of

SEOs, to improve the market reaction to SEO announcements and to increase the

propensity to issue SEOs. The main implication from this study is that a better financial

reporting system reduces the frictional costs associated with equity financing.

The remainder of the paper is structured as follows: section 3.2 provides the motivation

and literature review; section 3.3 presents the hypotheses development; section 3.4

discusses the research design; section 3.5 describes the data sample; section 3.6 discusses

the main results along with the robustness checks; and section 3.7 concludes.

84

3.2. Motivation & Literature Review

3.2.1. IFRS and Information Asymmetry in the SEO Setting

Myers & Majluf (1984) theorize that equity financing is costly under information

asymmetry relating to assets in place. Uninformed investors will discount the value of the

offered shares because of high ex-ante uncertainty, which increases under asymmetric

information (Akerlof, 1970). Consistent with the information asymmetry theory, Rock

(1986) states that the issuing firm must offer a higher price discount when the level of

uncertainty relating to the fundamental value of the offered shares is higher. Corwin

(2003), among others, provides evidence suggesting that the market reaction to SEOs

issued by firms with high levels of information asymmetry and uncertainty is more

negative. Therefore, theoretical models and empirical findings agree on the strong

association between information asymmetry (uncertainty) and equity under-pricing.

As mentioned before, the relation between the effect of IFRS adoption on aspects of

SEOs relies on prior findings that IFRS mitigate information asymmetry and improve

accounting quality (Armstrong, Barth, Jagolinzer, & Riedl, 2010; Barth et al., 2008; Daske

et al., 2008; Horton, Serafeim, & Serafeim, 2013). The International Accounting Standards

Board (IASB) claims that IFRS are a set of high quality financial reporting standards that

enable investors to compare financial statements across different countries, in addition to

increasing financial reporting transparency (Tweedie, 2006). Consistent with this claim,

recent studies on the consequences of IFRS adoption provide evidence suggesting a

positive impact on capital markets. Li (2010) finds that the adoption of IFRS in European

countries serves to reduce the cost of capital among adopting firms. Byard, Li, & Yu

(2011) find that analysts’ forecast errors and forecast dispersion have decreased

significantly after the mandatory adoption of IFRS in European countries with robust

enforcement of accounting standards. They conclude that IFRS serve to improve the

corporate financial information environment of the adopting firms. Finally, DeFond, Hu,

Hung, & Li (2011) predict and find that the adoption of a unified set of accounting

85

standards, represented by IFRS, increases financial statement comparability and, hence,

increases cross-border investments in Europe. We believe that the benefits associated with

IFRS adoption are expected to mitigate information asymmetry around SEOs. As a result,

we expect improvements in various aspects of equity financing following IFRS adoption.

3.2.2. Earnings Management around SEOs

The tendencies of poor stock returns and poor earnings performance, subsequent to SEOs,

have induced researchers to suspect that earnings are being managed prior to issuing new

equity (Rangan, 1998; Shivakumar, 2000; Teoh et al., 1998; DuCharme, Malatesta, &

Sefcik, 2004). Rangan (1998) finds that firms who issue SEOs have relatively high

abnormal accruals prior to the issue date. He finds that these abnormal accruals predict

poor stock returns and poor earnings performance in post-SEO years. Teoh et al. (1998)

confirm Rangan's (1998) findings and add evidence suggesting that the long-term stock

underperformance and the predictable earnings decline are more prominent among firms

that manipulate their earnings more aggressively prior to issuing SEOs. Shivakumar (2000)

finds similar results to Rangan (1998) and Teoh et al. (1998), but he reaches a different

conclusion from theirs. In contrast to Rangan (1998) and Teoh et al. (1998), who conclude

that managers manipulate their earnings prior to issuing SEOs in order to mislead

investors, Shivakumar (2000) theorizes that investors react efficiently to manipulated

earnings by undoing the manipulation effect through underpricing the issued SEOs. In

other words, Shivakumar (2000) shows that managers manipulate earnings prior to SEOs

in order to increase the stock price, then investors undo this effect by underpricing the

issued SEOs. Despite the difference in the conclusions of the aforementioned authors, they

all find significant evidence of accruals earnings management activities prior to SEOs.

The link between IFRS adoption and the change in the level of earnings management is

based on the findings that IFRS adoption mitigates information asymmetry (Daske et al.,

2008; Muller et al., 2011) and improves accounting quality (Barth et al., 2008). Warfield et

86

al. (1995) document that the level of earnings management is higher under higher levels of

information asymmetry. If IFRS adoption is expected to increase the level of disclosure

and improve accounting quality (Brüggemann, Hitz, & Sellhorn, 2013), which is expected

to mitigate information asymmetry (Daske et al., 2008), then we anticipate a reduction in

the level of earnings management prior to SEOs.

An alternative method for manipulating earnings, other than accruals earnings

management, is real earnings management (Cohen & Zarowin, 2010), where the latter has

a real economic effect on cash flows. Graham, Harvey, & Rajgopal (2005) survey top

executive managers and find that managers prefer to engage in real earnings management

rather than accruals earnings management. According to the surveyed managers, the reason

for this preference is that accruals earnings management is more scrutinized by auditors

and regulators than real earnings management. Consistently, Cohen & Zarowin (2010) find

that firms engage in both types of earnings management prior to issuing SEOs. Therefore,

it is important to take real earnings management activities into account when testing the

change in accruals earnings management following IFRS adoption.

3.2.3. The Market Reaction and the Propensity to Issue SEOs

The finance literature documents strong evidence showing a negative reaction to issuing

new SEOs (Denis, 1994; Eckbo & Masulis, 1995; Jung, Kim, & Stulz, 1996; Masulis &

Korwar, 1986; Mikkelson & Partch, 1986). These studies attribute this common finding to

the existence of asymmetric information, relating to the firm value, between managers and

investors. Eckbo et al. (2007) document in their security offerings’ survey that only one-

quarter of public firms issue SEOs after their initial public offering. According to the

authors, this rare issuance phenomenon is caused by the adverse selection costs associated

with raising external cash.

Prior studies show that firms with a better financial information environment can raise

equity at a lower cost. McLean, Pontiff, & Watanabe (2009) state that equity issuance is

87

more costly in countries with poor financial reporting incentives. Lee & Masulis (2009)

find robust evidence that firms with poor accounting quality encounter higher floatation

costs, higher underwriting costs, a more negative equity issuance reaction, and a higher

probability of withdrawing SEOs. Moreover, Lang & Lundholm (2000) examine the

market reaction to SEO announcements for high-disclosure versus low-disclosure firms.

Their results suggest that high disclosure firms, who maintain a consistent level of

disclosure, experience a hike in their share prices prior to SEO announcements and a minor

decline on the announcement day, compared to low-disclosure firms. The aforementioned

characteristics about financial reporting incentives, accounting quality and disclosure apply

to code-law countries (La Porta et al., 2000; Lee & Masulis, 2009; Singleton-Green, 2015).

This suggests that an improvement in these characteristics should serve to improve the

market reaction to equity financing.

Moreover, Leone, Rock, & Willenborg (2007) document that underpricing of IPOs

increases with the ex-ante uncertainty about the value of the offered stocks; however,

underpricing of IPOs decreases with greater disclosure and better information

environment. Hong et al. (2014) build on Leone et al. (2007) and conduct an international

study with a sample of 29 countries, where they tackle the effect of mandatory IFRS on the

market reaction to IPOs. They implement a difference-in-differences methodology, where

the treatment group consists of 20 adopting countries while the control group consists of 9

non-adopting countries. Their findings suggest that mandatory IFRS adoption reduces

information asymmetry and, consequently, helps firms raise capital at a lower cost, in

addition to facilitating global equity issuance. Accordingly, we predict that the adoption of

IFRS will enhance financial disclosure and improve accounting quality, which is expected

to mitigate information asymmetry, and consequently improve the market reaction to SEO

announcements (Myers & Majluf, 1984).

Finally, Hovakimian & Hutton (2010) find that firms who enjoy a better market reaction

to the first SEO and a better ex-post stock performance, have a higher probability of

88

issuing another SEO. Similarly, if the market reaction to SEOs improves after IFRS

adoption, which reduces the cost of equity financing, then we would expect the propensity

to issue new equity to increase following IFRS adoption.

3.3. Hypothesis Development

Accounting standards in common-law countries are constructed by independent

professional bodies, like the FASB in the US, in order to meet the information needs of

capital market participants (Soderstrom & Sun, 2007). This is similar to the development

of IFRS (Ball et al., 2000), which aims to provide capital market participants with relevant

information for making economic decisions (Brüggemann et al., 2013; Pope & McLeay,

2011). In contrast, accounting standards in code-law countries are constructed by

governments in order to meet their own demands regarding commercial laws and taxation

(Soderstrom & Sun, 2007). This is the main reason why the code-law accounting system

differs materially from IFRS (Hong et al., 2014; Joos & Lang, 1994; Kaufmann et al.,

2007). In light of the preceding argument, we assume that IFRS adoption in code-law

countries will have a greater impact on aspects of SEOs than in common-law countries

(Hong et al., 2014). Furthermore, we discuss potential confounding factors that might drive

our findings at the end of this section.

We hypothesize that the mandatory adoption of IFRS serves to reduce the level of

earnings management prior to issuing SEOs among code-law firms. As mentioned earlier,

prior studies find that firms manage their earnings upwardly before issuing SEOs (Rangan,

1998; Shivakumar, 2000; Teoh et al., 1998), keeping in mind that earnings management

activities increase under higher levels of asymmetric information (Schipper, 1989;

Warfield et al., 1995). If IFRS mitigate information asymmetry (Daske et al., 2008) and

improve accounting quality (Barth et al., 2008), then we expect IFRS adoption to deter

earnings management prior to issuing SEOs, where managerial incentives to inflate

89

earnings are high (Teoh et al., 1998). As such, we formulate the following testable

hypothesis:

Hypothesis (1):

H1: Following IFRS, there is a greater reduction in the level of earnings management prior

to issuing SEOs among code-law firms than common-law firms.

The information shock caused by IFRS adoption is expected to increase financial

statements informative-ness due to the following: (1) mandated increase in disclosure

volume (Ball, Li, & Shivakumar, 2015), (2) improved timeliness and transparency

(Brüggemann et al., 2013), (3) enhanced financial reporting quality (Barth et al., 2008),

and (4) improved financial statement comparability (DeFond et al., 2011). Hence, the main

relationship between IFRS and SEOs arises from the assumption that IFRS are expected to

mitigate information asymmetry relating to assets in place and, therefore, improve the

market reaction to SEOs (Myers & Majluf, 1984). Based on the preceding arguments, we

establish the hypothesis below:

Hypothesis (2):

H2: Following IFRS, there is a greater improvement in the market reaction to SEO

announcements among code-law firms than common-law firms.

Finally, Eckbo et al. (2007) document that the rarity of SEOs is attributed to the high

costs associated with this kind of corporate financing. Supportive evidence is provided by

Hovakimian & Hutton (2010) who find that firms who receive a better market reaction to

their first SEO are more likely to issue a subsequent SEO. If the market reaction to SEO

announcements improves following IFRS adoption, then the associated cost with equity

90

financing is reduced and, accordingly, we expect managers to issue SEOs more frequently.

Therefore, we construct the following hypothesis:

Hypothesis (3):

H3: Following IFRS, there is a greater increase in the propensity to issue SEOs among

code-law firms than common-law firms.

Nevertheless, in order to ascribe capital benefits to IFRS per se, we have to ensure that

other factors associated with accounting quality did not change at the same time. For

instance, if accounting standards were better enforced after IFRS adoption in France, then

our findings would be driven by better enforcement and not by IFRS implementation

(Christensen, Hail, & Leuz, 2013; Leuz & Wysocki, 2016). Brown, Preiato, & Tarca

(2014) construct an international index for the enforcement of accounting standards in

2002, 2005 and 2008. The index shows that the enforcement of accounting standards in

France did not increase around IFRS, and it is similar to the enforcement in the UK, which

improves the comparability between the control and the treatment groups.19

This suggests

that the improvements in the information environment among code-law firms should not be

attributed to the enforcement factor, but to the improvement in accounting standards.

Another factor that might confound our predictions about the effect of IFRS adoption is the

change in the level of corporate governance. Prior studies find that firms with a better

corporate governance enjoy a better market reaction to SEOs because investors are less

worried about ex-post moral hazards (Kim & Purnanandam, 2014). Fortunately,

Katelouzou & Siems (2015) document that the levels of corporate governance and

investor’s protection in the UK and France are similar and sticky over the time period we

cover (2001-2008).

19

The enforcement index (out of 24) for France shows a score of 19, 19 and 16 in 2002, 2005 and 2008,

respectively. For the UK, the score is 14, 22 and 22 in 2002, 2005 and 2008, respectively.

91

3.4. Research Methodology

We test our hypotheses using a difference-in-differences research design. The common-

law sample (UK firms) serves as the control group and the code-law sample (French firms)

serves as the treatment group. As mentioned earlier, the rationale behind our sample

selection is the high comparability between the treatment and the control groups in various

aspects. The selected countries have similar economic, institutional and political factors.

These factors might confound with the effect of IFRS adoption if they were different

between the treatment and the control groups. The similarity in these factors between the

selected countries is the main advantage of our restricted sample selection over

international studies. We provide a detailed discussion of sample selection in section 3.5.1.

The sample period starts in 2001 and ends in 2008 (Hail, Tahoun, & Wang, 2014).20

We

denote the IFRS adoption period using the dummy variable POST that takes the value 1 if

the year is 2005 or beyond, and 0 otherwise. We differentiate the code-law sample from

the common-law sample using the dummy variable CODE that takes the value 1 if the firm

is listed in France (i.e. treated firm), and 0 otherwise. We identify the difference-in-

differences estimator from the interaction between POST and CODE. The interaction term

POST*CODE takes the value 1 if the firm is listed in the code-law country between 2005

and 2008, and 0 otherwise.

3.4.1. Test of Earnings Management

In order to test the change in earnings management prior to issuing SEOs, we mainly

follow Lobo and Zhou (2010) and Iliev (2008) in developing the earnings management

model as shown in equation (1). The dependent variable DACC is the discretionary

accruals calculated in the most recent financial year prior to issuing an SEO. We calculate

discretionary accruals following the modified cross-sectional Jones (1991) model as

20

As a robustness check, we run the regressions after excluding the observations of year 2008 because it is

the beginning of the global financial crisis. In addition, we run the regressions after excluding the

observations of year 2005 as it is considered a transitionary year with high level of information asymmetry

(Wang & Welker, 2011). Our conclusions remain unchanged when excluding year 2008 and/or year 2005

from the sample period.

92

described in Dechow, Sloan, & Sweeney (1995). The procedure for calculating

discretionary accruals is explained in detail in Appendix B. We deflate the variables by the

average of total assets prior to IFRS.21

Initially, the time period used for this test is 2001

till 2008; however, we exclude year 2005 from this regression because SEOs that were

issued in 2005 had their discretionary accruals in 2004 (i.e. before IFRS). We also exclude

the first year from the pre-IFRS period (i.e. 2001) in order to keep a balance between pre-

and post-IFRS. As such, the time period for the earnings management regression starts in

2002 and ends in 2008, excluding 2005.

Burgstahler & Dichev (1997) find that big firms, compared to small firms, engage more

in earnings management in order to avoid losses. We control for firm size by including the

natural logarithm of total assets, LOGTA. DeFond & Jiambalvo (1994) and Sweeney

(1994) find that highly leveraged firms use discretionary accruals to satisfy debt covenant

requirements. Given that highly leveraged firms have greater incentives to manipulate

reported earnings, we include the variable LEV to account for differences in leverage.

Another factor that might trigger earnings management is investment opportunities. Firms

planning to invest in the near future need to report earnings forecasts that show low

uncertainty about their future earnings (Kasznik, 1999). These firms might engage in

earnings management (smoothing) in order to meet their forecasted earnings and, hence,

show high quality forecasts (Goodman, Neamtiu, Shroff, & White, 2014). To control for

investment opportunities, we include the variable TOBINQ which is the market-to-book

ratio (Fama & French, 2001). Herrmann, Inoue, & Thomas (2003) find that firms might

engage in selling some of their fixed assets, instead of engaging in aggressive earnings

management, in order to reduce the management’s forecast errors. Their finding is more

prominent among more tangible firms. We control for firm tangibility by including the

variable TANG, the ratio of property plant and equipment to total assets. According to

21

We deflate the variables by the firm’s average of total assets in years 2001, 2002, 2003 and 2004 in order

to isolate the fair value adjustment effect on total assets after IFRS. Yet, our findings remain unchanged

when deflating by total assets in year t-1.

93

Becker, Defond, Jiambalvo, & Subramanyam, (1998), firms with strong operating cash

flow performance are less likely to manipulate their earnings because such firms perform

well in general. Therefore, we include deflated operating cash flow OCF and deflated total

cash balance LIQDT. We also include dummy variables for income change ∆INCDUM and

losses LOSS to account for managers’ incentives to avoid earnings decreases and losses

(Burgstahler & Dichev, 1997; Lobo & Zhou, 2006). Finally, Becker et al. (1998) find that

discretionary accruals reported by firms audited by non-big auditors increase income more

than those reported by firms audited by big auditors. We include the dummy variable

BIG4DUM to proxy for audit quality.

In addition to the aforementioned covariates, we add a measure for real earnings

management, REM. Real earnings management is an alternative way for manipulating

earnings which might be utilized by firms in order to inflate earnings prior to issuing SEOs

(Cohen & Zarowin, 2010).22

We calculate the proxy for real earnings management

following Cohen, Dey, & Lys (2008) and include it in equation (1). The procedure for

calculating real earnings management is explained in detail in Appendix B. Moreover,

Owens, Wu, & Zimmerman (2016) theorize that idiosyncratic economic shocks affect the

measurement of abnormal accruals, and this effect is more prominent when considering the

absolute value of abnormal accruals. They find a strong association between the proxy for

economic shocks and absolute abnormal accruals, which is a part of our analysis. Thus, we

calculate the proxy for idiosyncratic economic shocks IDSHOCK following Owens et al.

(2016) and include it in equation (1). Finally, we add dummy variables in order to control

for the offering technique of SEOs (RIGHTDUM, PLACDUM23

& PUBLICDUM).

22

Ipino & Parbonetti (2016) find that the reduction in accrual earnings management following IFRS adoption

is offset by an increase in real earnings management. Their finding is prominent for EU countries with strong

enforcement of IFRS. Therefore, we must control for real earnings management when testing the change in

accrual earnings management following IFRS adoption. 23

The Placements dummy variable (PLACDUM) always goes to the intercept and will not appear in the

tables.

94

DACC = α0 + α1 POST + α2 CODE + α3 POST*CODE

+ ∑ αi Controlsi + ∑ αj Year FEj + ∑ αk Industry FEk + ε (1)

3.4.2. Test of SEO Market Reaction

In order to test the difference in the market reaction to issuing SEOs following IFRS, we

follow Kim & Purnanandam (2014) since their setting is similar to ours. They study the

difference in the market reaction to SEOs under different corporate governance conditions

in the US. The dependent variable in equation (2) is the cumulative abnormal returns

CAR[−2,+2] using a [-2,+2] window around the announcement date.24

We estimate normal

returns using the EVENTUS default market model regression over a [-11, -261] window

(Dissanaike, Faasse, & Jayasekera, 2014).25

For common-law firms, we use FTSE All-

Share and Dow Jones STOXX600 market indices as a benchmark for market returns.26

For

code-law firms, we use SBF120 and Dow Jones STOXX600 market indices as a

benchmark for market returns.

Kraser (1986) finds that managers increase the volume of the issued equity when they

know it is overpriced. This suggests that the size of the issue might hold some insider

information. We control for the size of the issued equity by including LOGISSUE, the

natural logarithm of the whole issue (Clinton, White, & Woidtke, 2014). Another major

determinant of issuing equity is the growth opportunity of the firm. Denis (1994) finds that

high growth opportunity firms were subject to less negative market reaction to issuing

equity because such firms are expected to generate profits in the future. We include the

market-to-book ratio, TOBINQ, as a proxy for growth opportunities (DeAngelo, DeAngelo,

& Stulz, 2010). Moreover, Eckbo & Masulis (1995) document that investment

24

Our results hold when changing the event window to [-1, +1] or to [0, +1]. 25

The significance of our results persists when using the adjusted market model estimates. 26

The STOXX Europe 600 Index is derived from the STOXX Europe Total Market Index (TMI) and is a

subset of the STOXX Global 1800 Index. With a fixed number of 600 components, the STOXX Europe 600

Index represents large, mid and small capitalization companies across 18 countries of the European region:

Austria, Belgium, Czech Republic, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Ireland, Italy, Luxembourg,

the Netherlands, Norway, Portugal, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland and the United Kingdom.

95

opportunities signal a growth potential, which encourages investors to invest in the issued

equity. We proxy for investment opportunities using research and development expenses

RND, following Kim & Purnanandam (2014). Barnes & Walker (2006) state that firm size

reflects some of the SEO characteristics through analysts’ coverage because bigger firms

have higher analysts’ coverage. This conveys some information to the market about the

offering quality. We include LOGTA as a proxy for firm size. In addition, Lee & Masulis

(2009) find that leverage is negatively associated with the market reaction to issuing new

equity. They state that investors are cautious about investing in highly leveraged firms. We

control for the difference in leverage among firms by including LEV. Teoh et al. (1998)

find that investors react less negatively to SEOs issued by more profitable firms. We

follow Qian et al. (2012) and control for profitability using the return on assets ratio, ROA.

Lyandres, Sun, & Zhang (2008) document a positive relation between tangibility and the

probability of equity issuance as more tangible firms enjoy a better market reaction to

SEOs. We include TANG to control for that. DeAngelo et al. (2010) find that the major

motive for issuing SEOs is the short-term need for cash. If the firm issues equity for

investment purposes, we would expect a positive market reaction; however, if the firm

issues equity just to stay solvent, we would expect a negative market reaction. We control

for cash availability inside the firm using LIQDT. We control for the firm operating risk by

including SDEBIT, the standard deviation of deflated earnings before interest and tax over

the full period (Gaud, Jani, Hoesli, & Bender, 2005). Booth & Chang (2011) find that firms

that pay dividends experience a lower negative market reaction when issuing new equity.

We control for dividend-paying status by including the dummy variable DIVDUM that

takes the value 1 if the firm pays dividends, and 0 otherwise. Dittmar & Thakor (2007)

state that information asymmetry around SEO announcements is high when the date of the

SEO is far from the last earnings announcement. We control for the number of days

between the SEO announcement date and the date of the last earnings announcement using

96

DAYS.27

We also differentiate profitable and loss-making firms using the dummy variable

LOSS that takes the value 1 if the net income of the firm is negative. Finally, we include

dummy variables in order to control for the offering technique of the SEO (RIGHTDUM,

PLACDUM28

& PUBLICDUM).

CAR[−2,+2] = β0 + β1 POST + β2 CODE + β3 POST*CODE

+ ∑ βi Controlsi + ∑ βj Year FEj + ∑ βk Industry FEk + ε (2)

3.4.3. Test of Propensity to Issue Equity

After we test the change in earnings management prior to issuing SEOs and the change in

the market reaction to announcing these SEOs, it is intuitive to test the change in the

propensity to issue new equity following IFRS. In order to test for such a change, we

follow Hovakimian & Hutton (2010) who examine the propensity to issue new SEOs for

the second time depending on the post-issue returns after the first SEO. The dependent

variable in equation (3) is the dummy variable SEODUM that takes the value 1 in case the

firm issues one or more SEOs in a specific year, and 0 otherwise. Dittmar & Thakor (2007)

document that big firms have lower costs of debt and, therefore, such firms prefer issuing

debt rather than equity. We control for firm size using LOGTA. In addition, Dittmar &

Thakor (2007) find that firms with higher growth opportunities have a higher probability

for issuing equity. We include RND and TOBINQ as proxies for growth opportunities.

Rajan & Zingales (1995) find that more tangible firms are more likely to be highly

leveraged and, therefore, these firms have higher probability of raising external equity. We

control for the firm’s tangibility using TANG and for the firm’s leverage position using

LEV. Eckbo et al. (2007) find that firms with low profitability and good growth

27

The code of the variable that shows earnings reporting date in WorldScope is WC05905. 28

As mentioned earlier, the Placements dummy variable (PLACDUM) always goes to the intercept and will

not appear in the tables.

97

opportunities are more likely to issue new equity. We control for profitability using ROA

and control for financial slack using LIQDT (Dittmar & Thakor, 2007). Booth & Chang

(2011) find that dividend payers enjoy a better market reaction to SEO announcements

compared to non-payers, which might increase the probability of issuing SEOs. On the

contrary, other studies argue that firms who pay dividends are usually more mature and

profitable firms (DeAngelo, DeAngelo, & Skinner, 2008) and such firms have a lower

probability of issuing equity (Dittmar & Thakor, 2007). We control for the dividend-

paying status of the firm by including DIVDUM in equation (3). The covariates in equation

(3) are explained in sections 3.4.1 and 3.4.2, and mainly follow Hovakimian & Hutton

(2010).

SEODUM = γ0 + γ1 POST + γ2 CODE + γ3 POST*CODE

+ ∑ γi Controlsi + ∑ γj Year FEj + ∑ γk Industry FEk + ε (3)

3.5. Data & Descriptive Statistics

3.5.1. Sample Construction

In order to test the impact of IFRS on aspects of SEOs, we choose two comparable

European countries. Christensen et al. (2013) conduct an international study on the

consequences of IFRS and document that the impact of IFRS on capital markets is

concentrated in European countries with good enforcement of accounting standards. We

endeavor to select highly comparable capital markets in order to satisfy the assumptions of

the geographic regression discontinuity research design as described in Keele, Titiunik, &

Zubizarreta (2015). We select the UK as a common-law country and France as a code-law

country. At the country level, both markets have relatively comparable sizes (World Bank,

2014), similar enforcement of accounting standards around IFRS adoption (Brown et al.,

2014), comparable investor protection (Katelouzou & Siems, 2015), and both countries did

98

not allow voluntary adoption of IFRS (Leuz & Wysocki, 2016). At the corporate level,

both markets have relatively comparable ownership dispersion (Enriques & Volpin, 2007)

and similar scores for corporate governance (Katelouzou & Siems, 2015).29

Therefore, the

main relevant change around 2005 is the implementation of IFRS. In light of the

aforementioned points, we believe that the UK and France are suitable as control and

treatment groups in a difference-in-differences research design.

The sample period starts in 2001 and ends in 2008 (Hail et al., 2014). 30

The data source

for equity offerings is ThomsonONE (SDC Platinum), for financial variables is

WorldScope, and for stock returns is DataStream. We download all seasoned equity

offerings in the UK and France, consisting of Placements, Rights and Public Offerings.31

We apply data restrictions following Hong et al. (2014) as described in Appendix C.

Specifically, we drop financial firms, non-ordinary/secondary shares, firms that did not

adopt IFRS in 2005,32

and firms who do not appear at least once in pre- and post-IFRS

periods. The final sample consists of 645 issuing firms in the UK with 1100 SEOs and 100

issuing firms in France with 135 SEOs. Given missing financial variables, the main

regression includes 922 SEOs in the UK and 127 in France. Out of the 127 SEOs in

France, we hand-collect financial variables for 33 issues using ThomsonONE

Fundamentals.33

3.5.2. Descriptive Statistics

We begin the presentation of the descriptive statistics by including two graphs that show

the change in discretionary accruals before SEOs, and the change in the market reaction to

29

Compared to other Western European countries, like Germany, UK and France have the closest scores for

ownership dispersion and corporate governance. 30

As mentioned before, our results are robust to excluding the financial crisis year (2008), as well as

excluding the transitionary year (2005), from the sample period. 31

After applying the sample selection criteria described in Appendix C, we were left with only 4 public

offerings in France. For this reason we excluded public offerings from the code-law sample as we cannot run

our statistical analyses based on 4 observations. 32

The name of the variable in DataStream is “Accounting Standards Followed”; Code: WC07536. 33

Knowing that the hand-collection of data is very time consuming, we only hand-collect financial data for

issues in France because the code-law sample is small while the common-law sample is relatively big.

99

SEO announcements, over the sample period. Figure 1 shows the change in the level of

average discretionary accruals prior to SEO announcements for common-law and code-law

firms between 2002 and 2008, excluding 2005. Figure 1 demonstrates how discretionary

accruals significantly decrease among code-law firms after 2005. On the other hand, no

similar change in discretionary accruals takes place among common-law firms. This

suggests that the level of earnings management decreases among code-law firms,

compared to common-law firms, following IFRS adoption.

[Insert Figure 1 here]

With respect to the change in the market reaction to SEO announcements, Figure 2

shows an increase in the average market reaction to SEOs among code-law firms after

2005. However, the change in the average market reaction to SEOs among common-law

firms after 2005 is minor. The interesting point demonstrated in Figure 1 is that the average

market reaction of code-law firms becomes similar to that of common-law firms after

2005, with a similar pattern over the years.

[Insert Figure 2 here]

Table 1 reports the distribution of different types of equity offerings between 2001 and

2008. The common-law sample consists of Rights, Placements and Public Offerings,

whereas the code-law sample does not include Public Offerings.34

The distribution of

SEOs is balanced for both samples across the years except for common-law firms in years

2007 and 2008, where the number of issued placements increases remarkably. This

34

As mentioned earlier, applying the sample selection criteria described in Appendix C left us with only 4

public offerings in France. For this reason we excluded public offerings from the code-law sample as we

cannot run our statistical analyses based on 4 observations.

100

increase in the number of placements is attributed to the scarcity of financial resources

during the Global Financial Crisis around 2008.

[Insert Table 1 here]

Table 2 reports summary statistics for cumulative abnormal returns around SEO

announcements for the common-law and code-law samples, pre- and post-IFRS. The table

shows that the market reaction to SEO announcements is positive for the common-law

sample before IFRS adoption, and stays positive afterwards. On average, for the common-

law sample, CAR[−2; +2] is 0.0154 (0.0175) with a t-statistic of 5.95 (8.02) before (after)

IFRS adoption. On the other hand, for the code-law sample, the market reaction to SEO

announcements before IFRS adoption is negative and becomes positive following IFRS

adoption. On average, for the code-law sample, CAR[−2; +2] is -0.0081 (0.0174) with a t-

statistic of -2.48 (4.69) before (after) IFRS adoption. This coincides with Figure 2 that

shows that, following IFRS, the average market reaction to SEOs for the code-law sample

becomes similar to that of the common-law sample.

[Insert Table 2 here]

Panel A and Panel B in Table 3 report summary statistics for the variables used in

equation (1) and equation (2), respectively. Panel A shows that the mean of DACC is larger

for code-law firms than common-law firms (0.0462 vs 0.0385). This suggests that, on

average, code-law firms engage more in earnings management activities than common-law

firms. Panel B shows that the average market reaction to SEOs is more positive for

common-law firms over the sample period. This is because the market reaction around

SEOs for the code-law sample is negative before 2005.

101

On average, common-law firms are smaller in size (LOGTA), are less reliant on debt

(LEV), have higher investment opportunities (TOBINQ), are more tangible (TANG), have

more cash liquidity (LIQDT), spend more on research and development (RND), pay less

dividends (DIVDUM), are less profitable (LOSS and ROA) and engage more in real

earnings management activities (REM) than code-law firms.

[Insert Table 3 here]

Panels A and B in Table 4 report the correlation matrices between the variables in

equation (1) for the common-law and the code-law samples, respectively. The correlation

coefficient on POST, in Panel A, shows an insignificant effect of IFRS adoption on DACC

among common-law firms. On the other hand, the correlation coefficient on POST, in

Panel B, shows that there is a significantly negative effect of IFRS adoption on DACC

among code-law firms. This suggests that IFRS have a significantly negative effect on

earnings management prior to SEOs among code-law firms compared to common-law

firms. Another notable result is the significantly positive correlation between ABSDACC

and IDSHOCK for both samples. This is consistent with Owens et al. (2016) who find that

the measurement of the firm’s absolute value of abnormal accruals is highly affected by

idiosyncratic economic shocks.

Panels C and D in Table 4 report the correlation matrices for the common-law and the

code-law samples. The correlation coefficient on POST, in Panel C, shows an insignificant

effect of IFRS adoption on CAR[−2; +2] among common-law firms. On the other hand,

for code-law firms, Panel D shows that the univariate correlation between POST and

CAR[−2; +2] is 0.254, significant at the 5% level. This suggests that the market reaction to

SEO announcements, among code-law firms, improves by almost 25% following IFRS

adoption.

102

[Insert Table 4 here]

3.6. Empirical Results

In this section, we first describe the results of testing the three main hypotheses where

IFRS adoption contributes to: (1) reduce the level of earnings management around SEOs,

(2) improve the market reaction to SEO announcements and (3) increase the propensity to

issue new SEOs. Then, for robustness checks, we discuss how we attempt to control for the

change in the economics of the treated firms as well as for self-selection bias.

3.6.1. Earnings Management around SEOs

In Table 5, we report two sets of results where the first set has DACC as the dependent

variable and the second set has ABSDACC as the dependent variable. In each set of the

two, we run three OLS regressions using the common-law sample (control sample), the

code-law sample (treatment sample) and the full sample. The obtained results do not

represent the whole capital market in the UK and France since the selected sample only

includes firms who issue SEOs. Thus, we do not expect the coefficients on the control

variables to be perfectly consistent with the earnings management literature.

Contrary to our expectations, the coefficients on LEV are negative and significant across

all the regressions in the first set. This might be due to the fact that firms who are highly

leveraged are more scrutinized by creditors and subject to higher accountability; therefore,

such firms are hesitant to engage in earnings management activities.35

The coefficients on

LIQDT are negative for both samples, which suggests that firms who are short on cash

engage more in earnings management. In principle, firms who issue equity are either

suffering financial distress or raising funds to finance their investments. If a firm is not

short on cash but still issues equity, then probably this firm is raising external funds to

35

Another possible explanation could be that highly leveraged firms might engage in earnings smoothing in

order to maintain their reported earning over financial cycles. This might produce negative discretionary

accruals, which explains the negative effect of LEV on DACC.

103

finance a profitable project. This explains the negative coefficient on TOBINQ, which

indicates that firms with a better growth opportunity do not need to engage in earnings

management prior to raising external equity. As expected, the coefficients on ∆INCDUM

are positive and significant across all the regressions in the first set. This is consistent with

Lobo & Zhou (2010) who find a strong association between positive changes in net income

and earnings management. Finally, the dummy variables which control for the SEO

offering technique show that firms engage less in earnings management prior to Right

issues compared to Placement issues.36

With respect to our main result, the first column in Table 5 shows that the coefficient on

POST for the control group is insignificant. This supports our claim that IFRS adoption is

not expected to have a major effect on the financial reporting system in the UK. On the

other hand, the second column in Table 5 shows a significantly negative coefficient on

POST for the treatment group. This suggests that IFRS adoption serves to mitigate the

level of earnings management activities prior to issuing SEOs among code-law firms. This

conclusion holds when replacing the signed discretionary accruals with the absolute value

of discretionary accruals, ABSDACC. As shown in the second set of the regressions (the

last three columns of Table 5), the coefficient on POST is insignificant for the common-

law sample while it is significantly negative for the code-law sample, with a significant

difference-in-differences coefficient. Therefore, we reject the null hypothesis of H1 in

favor of the alternative. It is noteworthy that these results hold when controlling for real

earnings management, an alternative way for manipulating earnings prior to issuing SEOs

(Cohen & Zarowin, 2010).

[Insert Table 5 Here]

36

The estimates for PLACDUM go to the constant and the negative coefficients on RIGHTDUM suggest that

firms manage earnings more (less) before issuing Placements (Rights). In addition, the coefficients on

PUBLICDUM are insignificant.

104

In Table 6, we follow Owens et al. (2016) and control for idiosyncratic economic

shocks. Owens et al. (2016) state that accrual models wrongly assume firm stationarity and

intra-industry homogeneity. They argue that the accruals generating process differs

between firms operating in the same industry, and also differs for the same firm over time,

due to changes in the firm’s economics. Therefore, when calculating the firm’s

discretionary accruals as the abnormal accruals relative to the average industry-year

accruals, we should account for idiosyncratic economic shocks. They conclude that

idiosyncratic economic shocks affect the measurement of abnormal accruals, where this

effect becomes a serious concern when considering the absolute value of abnormal

accruals. Our results in Table 6 confirm the conclusion of Owens et al. (2016) because the

difference-in-differences coefficient for the unsigned discretionary accruals regression

(ABSDACC) becomes insignificant after including the proxy for idiosyncratic economic

shock (IDSHOCK). Yet, the difference-in-differences coefficient for the signed

discretionary accruals regression (DACC) remains significant when including the proxy for

idiosyncratic economic shocks (IDSHOCK). Therefore, our conclusion regarding the effect

of IFRS adoption on the level of earnings management remains unchanged after

controlling for the change in the firm’s economics.37

[Insert Table 6 Here]

3.6.2. Market Reaction to SEOs

Table 7 reports regression results for the market reaction model as shown in equation (2).

The three columns include the regression results for the common-law sample, the code-law

37

Although our time period is relatively short, yet we run an additional test to check for the effect of a time

trend. Specifically, we run the same regression of equation (1) while excluding all years after IFRS adoption

and replacing the dummy variable POST with a new dummy variable (call it Pseudo) that takes the value 1

for years 2003/2004 and the value of zero for the year 2002. We repeat the same test while assigning the new

dummy Pseudo the value 1 for the year 2004 and the value of zero for years 2002/2003. The coefficient on

Pseudo is insignificant in both regressions, meaning that our results are not attributed to the time trend effect.

105

sample and the full sample, respectively. The coefficients on LOGTA in all regressions

show that investors react more negatively to SEOs by larger firms, probably because such

firms are more scrutinized by the public. The coefficients on ROA in all regressions show

that more profitable firms experience a better market reaction to their issued equity. The

coefficients on LIQDT show that firms with higher cash liquidity receive a more negative

market reaction to their SEOs since more cash availability increases the probability of

moral hazard. The coefficients on LEV in all regressions show that more leveraged firms

receive a better market reaction to their equity issues. Yet, the coefficients mentioned so

far are statistically insignificant. In contrast to our expectations, the coefficients on TANG

show a significantly negative impact on cumulative abnormal returns in all regressions.

That is, more tangible firms receive a significantly more negative market reaction.

Regarding offering techniques, Public Offerings receive a significantly higher market

reaction among common-law firms.

The main variable of interest, POST, shows that there is no significant effect for IFRS

adoption among common-law firms (t-statistic = 0.41). On the other hand, the coefficient

on POST in the second column shows that IFRS adoption has a significantly positive effect

on CAR[−2; +2] among code-law firms. The estimate on POST shows that the market

reaction has improved by an average of 2.6% after the implementation of IFRS in the code-

law country. Moreover, the interaction term, POST*CODE, shows that the difference-in-

differences estimate is 2.34% and is statistically significant at the 1% level. That is, the

change in the market reaction among code-law firms improves by 2.34% relative to the

change in the market reaction among common-law firms, following IFRS adoption.

Therefore, we reject the null hypothesis of H2 in favor of the alternative.38

38

We also test for the time trend effect through running the regression of equation (2) for years prior to IFRS.

We include the Post dummy variable which takes the value 1 for years 2003/2004 and zero for years

2001/2002. The coefficient on Post is insignificant, meaning that our results are not attributed to the time

trend effect.

106

[Insert Table 7 Here]

In Table 8 we test the effect of IFRS on the market reaction for each offering technique,

in each country, separately. The coefficients on POST in the first three columns show that

common-law firms do not witness a significant improvement in the market reaction around

issuing Rights, Placements or Public Offerings. On the other hand, the coefficients on

POST in the last two columns show an increase in the market reaction to issuing Rights

and Placements among code-law firms. For the code-law sample, the market reaction to

issuing Rights and Placements significantly increases by 2.97% and 2.64%, respectively.

[Insert Table 8 Here]

In Table 9 we test the significance of the difference-in-differences estimates for Rights

and Placements issues. The coefficient on POST in Table 9 shows that the change in the

market reaction among code-law firms, for Rights and Placements respectively, improves

significantly by 3% and 1.84% compared to the change in the market reaction among

common-law firms. In relation to information asymmetry, Placements are usually issued to

existing investors who are better informed about the firm (Cronqvist & Nilsson, 2005),

unlike Rights that are issued to both new and existing investors. Therefore, if IFRS were to

mitigate information asymmetry, and consequently diminish the gap between informed and

uninformed investors, then we would expect a greater effect for IFRS where the

information gap is bigger. This expectation is verified by the higher impact of IFRS on the

market reaction to Rights compared to Placements. In the same vein, Ginglinger,

Matsoukis, & Riva (2013) find that the market reaction to Rights issues in France is

remarkably negative due to their higher illiquidity. The coefficient on CODE in Table 9

shows that, prior to IFRS adoption, code-law firms received a more negative market

reaction to Rights when compared to Placements. Also, the improvement in the market

107

reaction among code-law firms is greater for Rights compared to Placements. This

supports our argument that IFRS have a greater effect where information asymmetry is

higher.

In conclusion, we find support for our hypothesis that IFRS adoption serves to mitigate

information asymmetry and to improve the market reaction to issuing SEOs in the code-

law country. This finding applies to Rights and Placements issues, which reinforce our

rejection of the null hypothesis of H2 in favor of the alternative.

[Insert Table 9 Here]

3.6.3. Propensity to Issue New Equity

After we find that IFRS adoption improves the market reaction to SEO announcements

and, therefore, facilitates equity financing, we test the change in the propensity to issue

new equity. We first examine the change in the propensity to issue SEOs using the full

time period (2001-2008) as shown in the first three columns in Table 10. The results from

the Logistic regressions show that the propensity to issue SEOs increases after IFRS

adoption among common-law and code-law firms; yet, the increase among code-law firms

is double the increase among common-law firms. This results in an insignificant

difference-in-differences estimate. Nevertheless, the summary statistics in Table 1 show

that the number of Placements issued by common-law firms increase remarkably in

2007/2008. This is when the Global Financial Crisis (GFC) struck. Thus, we repeat our test

while excluding years 2007/2008 to eliminate the GFC effect and years 2001/2002 to keep

the dataset balanced. The fourth column in Table 10 shows that, for the common-law

sample, the significance of IFRS adoption disappears after excluding years 2007/2008. On

the other hand, the fifth column in the same table shows that, for the code-law sample, the

significance of IFRS adoption remains after excluding years 2007/2008. The last column

108

of Table 10 shows that the difference-in-differences estimate (POST*CODE) is statistically

significant at the 1% level. This suggests that IFRS adoption serves to facilitate equity

financing and to increase the propensity to issue new equity among code-law firms

compared to common-law firms. Therefore, we reject the null hypothesis of H3 in favor of

the alternative.

[Insert Table 10 Here]

3.6.4. Robustness Checks

The robustness checks we perform aim to control for: (1) probable changes in the

underlying economics of the treated firms and (2) self-selection bias. We control for the

change in the economics of treated firms through assigning each code-law observation a

matching common-law observation. We use Coarsened Exact Matching (Iacus et al., 2012)

based on total assets, industry and the IFRS period.39

Tables 11, 12 and 13 report results

for regression equations (1), (2) and (3), respectively, based on matched samples.

Table 11 shows that the coefficient on the difference-in-differences estimator,

POST*CODE, is still significantly negative after performing the matched-sample analysis.

This supports our initial finding that IFRS adoption serves to reduce earnings management

activities prior to SEOs in the code-law country. Similarly, the difference-in-differences

estimate in Table 12 shows that the change in the market reaction to issuing SEOs among

code-law firms significantly improves after IFRS, compared to the change in the market

reaction to SEOs among common-law firms. This offers a sensitivity check to our finding

that IFRS adoption contributes to improving the market reaction to issuing SEOs in the

code-law country.

39

Ideally, we would match based on years; however, given that SEOs are not frequent enough, we match

code-law observations pre/post IFRS to common-law observations in the same period. In this way, we make

sure that we are not matching an observation that received the treatment to another observation that did not.

109

[Insert Table 11 Here]

[Insert Table 12 Here]

Table 13 reports results from logistic regressions that test the change in the propensity

to issue new equity among common-law and code-law firms based on a matched-sample

analysis. Interestingly, after we match the observations from both samples and use the full

time period, we find that the coefficient on POST for the common-law sample loses its

significance, whereas the same coefficient for the code-law sample retains its significance.

This is in addition to a significant difference-in-differences estimate in the third column of

Table 13. These results suggest that, when comparing similar sized firms, operating in the

same industry, the propensity to issue new equity significantly increases among code-law

firms compared to common-law firms. Hence, we reinforce the rejection of the null

hypothesis of H3 in favor of the alternative.

[Insert Table 13 Here]

Finally, the last robustness test controls for self-selection bias in the market reaction

model where firms issue SEOs voluntarily and, therefore, select themselves into the sample

(Booth & Chang, 2011; Lennox, Francis, & Wang, 2012). We control for self-selection

bias through using the Heckman (1979) two-step model. First, we run a probit model,

using issuing and non-issuing firms in the UK and France, with a dependent dummy

variable that takes the value 1 if the firm has announced an SEO (and 0 otherwise). We

follow Kim & Purnanandam (2014) and select SALES as the exclusion restriction

(instrument), because sales are more likely to affect the decision of announcing SEOs

(selection equation) but less likely to affect the cumulative abnormal returns (observation

equation). Then, we calculate the Inverse Mills Ratio (IMR) from the Probit regression.

110

Finally, we run an OLS regression for equation (2) while including IMR. Table 14 shows

that the significance of the coefficients on POST and POST*CODE still holds in the

second and the third regressions, respectively. Thus, we show that our findings are robust

to controlling for potential self-selection bias.

[Insert Table 14 Here]

3.7. Conclusion

We study whether and how changes in accounting standards affect corporate financing

through SEOs. The mandatory adoption of IFRS in Europe in 2005 generates a positive

shock to the corporate financial information environment, which is expected to mitigate

information asymmetry (Hail et al., 2014). We employ a difference-in-differences research

design where we select UK firms as the control group and French firms as the treatment

group. The reason for this selection is that we do not expect a significant effect of IFRS

adoption on the financial reporting system in a common-law country such as the UK. In

contrast, IFRS adoption is expected to bring significant changes to the financial reporting

system in a code-law country like France. Despite this difference in their financial

reporting systems, both countries have similar economic and institutional characteristics.

This provides some assurance that our findings are mainly attributable to the change in the

financial reporting system following the IFRS mandate.

The cornerstone of our theoretical argument is that the adoption of IFRS serves to

mitigate information asymmetry. Given lower asymmetric information and enhanced

accounting quality, we predict and find that, following IFRS, the level of earnings

management activities decreases among code-law firms compared to common-law firms.

As a result of lower levels of earnings management and information asymmetry, we

provide evidence indicating that the market reaction to issuing SEOs improves

111

significantly among code-law firms following IFRS. The improved market reaction means

that equity financing becomes less costly and, accordingly, we find that the propensity to

issue new SEOs increases among code-law firms following IFRS. As a sensitivity analysis,

we run a matched-sample analysis by matching code-law and common-law observations

using Coarsened Exact Matching (CEM). In addition, we control for self-selection bias by

using the Heckman (1979) two-step model. The results are not sensitive either to CEM

matching or to controlling for self-selection bias.

We contribute to the literature through showing how changing accounting standards can

affect aspects of equity financing. Our findings suggest that when investors are better

informed about the underlying value of the firm, the equity financing process becomes less

costly. The main implication of our study is that a better financial reporting system reduces

the frictional costs associated with equity financing.

112

References:

Akerlof, G. (1970). The Market for "Lemons": Quality Uncertainty and the

Market Mechanism. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 84(3), 488–500.

Armstrong, C., Barth, M., Jagolinzer, A., & Riedl, E. (2010). Market Reaction to Events

Surrounding the Adoption of IFRS in Europe Market Reaction to Events Surrounding

the Adoption of IFRS in Europe. The Accounting Review, 85(1), 31–61.

Ball, R., Kothari, S. P., & Robin, A. (2000). The effect of international institutional factors

on properties of accounting earnings. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 29(1), 1–

51.

Ball, R., Li, X., & Shivakumar, L. (2015). Contractibility of financial statement

information prepared under IFRS : Evidence from debt contracts. Journal of

Accounting Research, 53(5).

Barnes, E., & Walker, M. (2006). The seasoned-equity issues of UK firms: Market reaction

and issuance method choice. Journal of Business Finance and Accounting, 33(1–2),

45–78.

Barth, M., Landsman, W., & Lang, M. (2008). International accounting standards and

accounting quality. Journal of Accounting Research, 46(3), 467–498.

Becker, C., Defond, M., Jiambalvo, J., & Subramanyam, K. R. (1998). The Effect of Audit

Quality on Earnings Management. Contemporary Accounting Research, 15(1).

Booth, L., & Chang, B. (2011). Information asymmetry, dividend status, and seo

announcement-day returns. The Journal of Financial Research, XXXIV(1), 155–177.

Brown, P., Preiato, J., & Tarca, A. (2014). Measuring Country Differences in Enforcement

of Accounting Standards: An Audit and Enforcement Proxy. Journal of Business

Finance and Accounting, 41(1–2), 1–52.

Brüggemann, U., Hitz, J.-M., & Sellhorn, T. (2013). Intended and Unintended

Consequences of Mandatory IFRS Adoption: A Review of Extant Evidence and

Suggestions for Future Research. European Accounting Review, 22(1), 1–37.

Burgstahler, D., & Dichev, I. (1997). Earnings management to avoid earnings decreases

and losses. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 24, 99–126.

Byard, D., Li, Y., & Yu, Y. (2011). The effect of mandatory IFRS adoption on financial

analysts’ information environment. Journal of Accounting Research, 49(1), 69–96.

Christensen, H., Hail, L., & Leuz, C. (2013). Mandatory IFRS Reporting and Changes in

Enforcement. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 56(2), 147–177.

Clinton, S., White, J., & Woidtke, T. (2014). Differences in the Information Environment

Prior to SEOs under Relaxed Disclosure Regulation. Journal of Accounting and

Economics, 58(1), 59–78.

Cohen, D., Dey, A., & Lys, T. (2008). Real and accrual-based earnings management in the

pre- and post-Sarbanes-Oxley periods. The Accounting Review, 83, 757–787.

Cohen, D., & Zarowin, P. (2010). Accrual-based and real earnings management activities

around seasoned equity offerings. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 50(1), 2–19.

Corwin, S. (2003). The Determinants of Underpricing for Seasoned Equity Offers. Journal

of Finance, LVIII(5), 2249–2279.

Cronqvist, H., & Nilsson, M. (2005). The choice between rights offerings and private

equity placements. Journal of Financial Economics, 78(2), 375–407.

Daske, H., Hail, L., Leuz, C., & Verdi, R. (2008). Mandatory IFRS reporting around the

world: Early evidence on the economic consequences. Journal of Accounting

Research, 46(5), 1085–1142.

DeAngelo, H., DeAngelo, L., & Skinner, D. (2008). Corporate Payout Policy. Foundations

and Trends in Finance, 3(2–3), 95–287.

DeAngelo, H., DeAngelo, L., & Stulz, R. (2010). Seasoned equity offerings, market

timing, and the corporate lifecycle. Journal of Financial Economics, 95(3), 275–295.

Dechow, P., Sloan, R., & Sweeney, A. (1995). Detecting Earnings Management. The

Accounting Review, 70(2).

113

DeFond, M., Hu, X., Hung, M., & Li, S. (2011). The impact of mandatory IFRS adoption

on foreign mutual fund ownership: The role of comparability. Journal of Accounting

and Economics, 51(3), 240–258.

DeFond, M., & Jiambalvo, J. (1994). Debt Convenant Effects and the Manipulation of

Accruals. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 17, 145–176.

Denis, D. (1994). Investment Opportunities and the Market Reaction to Equity Offerings.

Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 29(2), 159–177.

Dissanaike, G., Faasse, J., & Jayasekera, R. (2014). What do equity issuances signal? A

study of equity issuances in the UK before and during the financial crisis. Journal of

International Money and Finance, 49(PB), 358–385.

Dittmar, A., & Thakor, A. (2007). Why Do Firms Issue Equity ? The Journal of Finance,

LXII(1–54).

DuCharme, L., Malatesta, P., & Sefcik, S. (2004). Earnings management, stockissues, and

shareholder lawsuits. Journal of Financial Economics, 71(1), 27–49.

Eckbo, E., & Masulis, R. (1995). Seasoned Equity Offerings : A Survey 1. Handbook in

Operations Research and Management Science, 1017–1072.

Eckbo, E., Masulis, R., & Norli, Ø. (2007). Security Offerings. Handbook of Empirical

Corporate Finance SET, 2, 233–373.

Enriques, L., & Volpin, P. (2007). Corporate Governance Reforms in Continental Europe.

The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 117–140.

Fama, E., & French, K. (2001). Disappearing Dividends: Changing Firm Characteristics or

Lower Propensity to Pay? Journal of Financial Economics, 60(1), 3–43.

Gaud, P., Jani, E., Hoesli, M., & Bender, A. (2005). The Capital Structure of Swiss

Companies: an Empirical Analysis Using Dynamic Panel Data. European Financial

Management, 11(1), 51–69.

Ginglinger, E., Matsoukis, L., & Riva, F. (2013). Seasoned Equity Offerings: Stock Market

Liquidity and the Rights Offer Paradox. Journal of Business Finance and Accounting,

40(1–2), 215–238.

Goodman, T., Neamtiu, M., Shroff, N., & White, H. (2014). Management Forecast Quality

and Capital Investment Decisions. The Accounting Review, 89(1), 331–365.

Graham, J., Harvey, C., & Rajgopal, S. (2005). The economic implications of corporate

financial reporting. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 40(1), 3–73.

Hail, L., Tahoun, A., & Wang, C. (2014). Dividend payouts and information shocks.

Journal of Accounting Research, 52(2), 403–456.

Heckman, J. (1979). Sample Selection Bias as a Specification Error. Econometrica, 47(1),

153–161.

Herrmann, D., Inoue, T., & Thomas, W. (2003). The Sale of Assets to Manage Earnings in

Japan. Journal of Accounting Research, 41(1).

Hong, H., Hung, M., & Lobo, G. (2014). The Impact of Mandatory IFRS Adoption on

IPOs in Global Capital Markets. The Accounting Review, 89(4), 1365–1397.

Horton, J., Serafeim, G., & Serafeim, I. (2013). Does mandatory IFRS adoption improve

the information environment? Contemporary Accounting Research, 30(1), 388–423.

Hovakimian, A., & Hutton, I. (2010). Market Feedback and Equity Issuance: Evidence

from Repeat Equity Issues. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 45(3),

739–762.

Hribar, P., & Collins, D. (2002). Errors in estimating accruals: implications for empirical

research. Journal of Accounting Research, 40(1), 105–134.

Iacus, S. M., King, G., & Porro, G. (2012). Causal inference without balance checking:

Coarsened exact matching. Political Analysis, 20(1), 1–24.

Iliev, P. (2010). The Effect of SOX Section 404 Compliance on Audit Fees , Earnings

Quality and Stock Prices ∗. The Journal of Finance, LXV(3), 1163–1196.

Ipino, E., & Parbonetti, A. (2016). Mandatory IFRS adoption: the trade-off between

accrual-based and real earnings management. Accounting and Business Research,

114

46(8), 1–31.

Jones, J. (1991). Earnings Management During IMport Relief Investigations. Journal of

Accounting Research, 29(2).

Joos, P., & Lang, M. (1994). The effects of accounting diversity: evidence from the

European Union. Journal of Accounting Research, 32(Supplement), 141–168.

Jung, K., Kim, Y.-C., & Stulz, R. (1996). Timing, investment opportunities, managerial

discretion, and the security issue decision. Journal of Financial Economics, 42(2),

159–186.

Kasznik, R. (1999). On the association between voluntary disclosure and earnings

management. Journal of Accounting Research, 37, 57–81.

Katelouzou, D., & Siems, M. (2015). Disappearing Paradigms in Shareholder Protection:

Leximetric Evidence for 30 Countries. Journal of Corporate Law Studies, 15(1), 127–

160.

Kaufmann, D., Kraay, A., & Mastruzzi, M. (2007). Governance Matters VI: Aggregate

and Individual Governance Indicators 1996-2006. Washington, DC.

Keele, L., Titiunik, R., & Zubizarreta, J. (2015). Enhancing a geographic regression

discontinuity design through matching to estimate the effect of ballot initiatives on

voter turnout. Journal of the Royal Statistical Society: Series A (Statistics in Society),

178(1), 223–239.

Kim, E. H., & Purnanandam, A. (2014). Seasoned equity offerings, corporate governance,

and investments. Review of Finance, 18(3), 1023–1057.

Kraser, W. (1986). Stock price movements in response to stock issues under asymmetric

information. The Journal of Finance, 41, 93–106.

La Porta, R., Lopez-De-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. (1998). Law and Finance.

Journal of Political Economy, 106(6), 1113–1155.

La Porta, R., Lopez-De-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. (2000). Investor Protection

and Corporate Governance. Journal of Financial Economics, 58(1), 3–27.

Lang, M., & Lundholm, R. (2000). Voluntary Disclosure and Equity Offerings: Reducing

Information Asymmetry or Hyping the Stock? Contemporary Accounting Research,

17(4), 623–662.

Lee, G., & Masulis, R. (2009). Seasoned Equity Offerings: Quality of Accounting

Information and Expected Flotation Costs. Journal of Financial Economics, 92(3),

443–469.

Lennox, C., Francis, J., & Wang, Z. (2012). Selection Models in Accounting Research. The

Accounting Review, 87(2).

Leone, A., Rock, S., & Willenborg, M. (2007). Disclosure of intended use-of-proceeds and

underpricing in initial public offering. Journal of Accounting Research, 45(1), 111–

153.

Leuz, C., & Wysocki, P. (2016). The Economics of Disclosure and Financial Reporting

Regulation: Evidence and Suggestions for Future Research. Journal of Accounting

Research, 54(2), 525–622.

Li, S. (2010). Does mandatory adoption of international financial reporting standards in the

European Union Reduce the cost of equity capital? The Accounting Review, 85(2),

607–636.

Lobo, G., & Zhou, J. (2006). Did Conservatism in Financial Reporting Increase after the

Sarbanes-Oxley Act and CEO/CFO Certification of Financial Statements? Accounting

Horizons, 20(1), 57–73.

Lobo, G., & Zhou, J. (2010). Changes in Discretionary Financial Reporting Behavior

Following the Sarbanes-Oxley Act. Journal of Accounting, Auditing {&} Finance,

25(1), 1–26.

Lyandres, E., Sun, L., & Zhang, L. (2008). The New Issues Puzzle : Testing the

Investment-Based Explanation. The Review of Financial Studies, 21(6), 2825–2855.

Masulis, R., & Korwar, A. (1986). Seasoned Equity Offerings: An Empirical Investigation.

115

Journal of Financial Economics, 15, 91–118.

McLean, D., Pontiff, J., & Watanabe, A. (2009). Share issuance and cross-sectional

returns: International evidence. Journal of Financial Economics, 94(1), 1–17.

Mikkelson, W., & Partch, M. (1986). Valuation effects of security offerings and the

issuance process. Journal of Financial Economics, 15(1–2), 31–60.

Muller, K., Riedl, E., & Sellhorn, T. (2011). Mandatory Fair Value Accounting and

Information Asymmetry: Evidence from the European Real Estate Industry.

Management Science, 57(6), 1138–1153.

Myers, S., & Majluf, N. (1984). Corporate financing and investment decisions when firms

have information that investors do not have’. Journal of Financial Economics, 12,

187–221.

Owens, E., Wu, J. S., & Zimmerman, J. (2017). Idiosyncratic Shocks to Firm Underlying

Economics and Abnormal Accruals. The Accounting Review, 92(2), 183–219.

Pope, P., & McLeay, S. (2011). The European IFRS experiment: objectives, research

challenges and some early evidence. Accounting and Business Research, 41(3), 233–

266.

Qian, H., Zhong, K., & Zhong, Z. (2012). Seasoned Equity Issuers’ R & D Investments :

Signaling or Over-Optimism. The Journal of Financial Research, XXXV(4), 553–580.

Rajan, R., & Zingales, L. (1995). What do we know about capital structure? Some

evidence from international data. The Journal of Finance, 50, 1421–1460.

Rangan, S. (1998). Earnings management and the performance of seasoned equity

offerings. Journal of Financial Economics, 50(1), 101–122.

Rock, K. (1986). Why new issues are underpriced. Journal of Financial Economics, 15,

187–212.

Roychowdhury, S. (2006). Earnings management through real activities manipulation.

Journal of Accounting and Economics, 42, 335–370.

Schipper, K. (1989). Commentary on Earnings Management. Accounting Horizons, 3(4),

91–102.

Shivakumar, L. (2000). Do firms mislead investors by overstating earnings before

seasoned equity offerings? Journal of Accounting and Economics, 29(3), 339–371.

Singleton-Green, B. (2015). The Effects of Mandatory in the EU: of Empirical Research.

Information for Better Markets, ICAEW.

Soderstrom, N., & Sun, K. J. (2007). IFRS Adoption and Accounting Quality: A Review.

European Accounting Review, 16(4), 675–702.

Sweeney, A. (1994). Debt Convenant Violations and Managers’ Accounting Resposes.

Journal of Accounting and Economics, 17, 281–308.

Teoh, S. H., Welch, I., & Wong, T. J. (1998). Earnings management and the

underperformance of seasoned equity offerings. Journal of Financial Economics,

50(1), 63–99.

Tweedie, D. (2006). Prepared statement of Sir David Tweedie, Chairman of the

International Accounting Standards Board before the Economic and Monetary Affairs

Committee of the European Parliament.

Wang, S., & Welker, M. (2011). Timing Equity Issuance in Response to Information

Asymmetry Arising from IFRS Adoption in Australia and Europe. Journal of

Accounting Research, 49(1), 257–307.

Warfield, T., Wild, J., & Wild, K. (1995). Managerial ownership, accounting choices, and

informativeness of earnings. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 20(1), 61–91.

White, H. (1980). A Heteroskedasticity-Consistent Covariance Matrix Estimator and a

Direct Test for Heteroskedasticity. Econometrica, 48(4).

World Bank. (2014). GDP at market prices. Retrieved from

http://data.worldbank.org/indicator/NY.GDP.MKTP.CD

116

Appendix A: Variable Definitions (sorted alphabetically)

Variable Definition

ABSDACC

Absolute value of discretionary accruals in the most recent financial year

prior to the offering, deflated by the average of total assets in years prior

to IFRS adoption. Discretionary accruals are calculated following the

modified cross-sectional Jones (1991) model as described in Dechow et al

(1995). See Appendix B for details.

∆INCDUM Dummy variable that equals one if the change in net income is positive,

and 0 otherwise.

BIG4DUM Dummy variable that takes the value 1 if the firm is being audited by one

of the big four auditors, and 0 otherwise.

CAR[−2,+2]

Cumulative abnormal return over a [-2;+2] window around the

announcement day. The variable is calculated using the default market

model used by EVENTUS over a [-11, -261] window. We use two market

indices for each country. For common-law firms we use the FTSE All-

Share and the STOXX EUROPE 600 E-PRICE INDEX indices. For

code-law firms we use the SBF120 (Société des Bourses Françaises 120

Index) and the STOXX EUROPE 600 E-PRICE INDEX indices.

CODE Dummy variable that takes the value 1 if the firm is listed in France, and

0 otherwise.

DACC

Discretionary accruals in the most recent financial year prior to the

offering, deflated by the average of total assets in years prior to IFRS

adoption. Discretionary accruals are calculated following the modified

cross-sectional Jones (1991) model as described in Dechow et al (1995).

See Appendix B for details.

DAYS Number of days between the SEO announcement date and the end of the

most recent earnings announcement.

DIVDUM Dummy variable that takes the value 1 if the firm pays dividends, and 0

otherwise.

IDSHOCK

Proxy for idiosyncratic economic shocks, defined as the firm-specific

stock return variation in year t and year t-1. It is computed as the mean

squared errors of the residuals from the regression of the firm’s monthly

return on monthly industry return and monthly market return using 2

years of monthly data (year t and year t-1).

POST Dummy variable that takes the value 1 if the year is greater than or equal

2005, and 0 otherwise.

LEV Total liabilities in the most recent financial year prior to the offering,

deflated by the average of total assets in years prior to IFRS adoption.

LIQDT

Total available cash balance in the most recent financial year prior to the

offering deflated by the average of total assets in years prior to IFRS

adoption.

LOGISSUE Natural logarithm of the total amount of the equity issued using seasoned

equity offerings.

LOGTA Natural logarithm of total assets in the most recent financial year prior to

the offering.

LOSS Dummy variable that takes the value 1 if the firm reports a loss in the

most recent financial year prior to the offering, and 0 otherwise.

OCF Operating cash flow in the most recent financial year prior to the offering

deflated by the average of total assets in years prior to IFRS adoption.

117

PUBLICDUM Dummy variable that takes the value 1 if the offering technique is a

public offering, and 0 otherwise.

PLACDUM Dummy variable that takes the value 1 if the offering technique is a

placement issue, and 0 otherwise.

REM

Proxy for real earnings management in the most recent financial year

prior to the offering, deflated by the average of total assets in years prior

to IFRS adoption. Real earnings management is calculated as described in

(Cohen & Zarowin, 2010). See Appendix B for details.

RIGHTDUM Dummy variable that takes the value 1 if the offering technique is a right

issue, and 0 otherwise.

RND

Research and development expenses in the most recent financial year

prior to the offering, deflated by the average of total assets in years prior

to IFRS adoption. Missing values of this variable are replaced with zeros.

ROA

Net income before extraordinary items reported in the most recent

financial year prior to the offering, deflated by the average of total assets

in years prior to IFRS adoption.

SALES Total sales, scaled by the average of total assets in years prior to IFRS

adoption.

SDEBIT Standard deviation of earnings before interest and tax (EBIT), scaled by

the average of total assets in years prior to IFRS adoption.

SEODUM Dummy variable that takes the value 1 if the firm issues an SEO in a

particular year, and zero in other years.

TANG

Total of property, plant and equipment in the most recent financial year

prior to the offering deflated by the average of total assets in years prior

to IFRS adoption.

TOBINQ

Firm’s market value in the most recent financial year prior to the offering,

deflated by the average of total assets in years prior to IFRS adoption;

where market value is the sum of total liabilities and market capitalization

(stock price*outstanding shares). Market value is retrieved directly from

DataStream.

118

Appendix B: Calculation of DACC and REM

Appendix B.1: Discretionary Accruals (DACC)

In order to estimate discretionary accruals, we use the modified cross-sectional Jones

(1991) model as described in Dechow et al. (1995). The modified Jones model is estimated

by each country-industry-year separately, where the industry classification is based on the

DataStream variable “INDM2”. First, we run the regression model below:

TACCit/TAi = b1 (1/TAi) + b2 ∆SALESit/TAi + b3 PPEit/TAi + eit

Where:

TACCit = NIBX - OCF, where NIBX is net income before extraordinary items and OCF is

operating cash flow (Hribar & Collins, 2002).

TAi = average of total assets in years prior to IFRS adoption,

∆SALESit = change in revenues,

PPEit = property, plant and equipment.

Then, the estimates of b1, b2, and b3 obtained from the cross-sectional regressions are

used to estimate discretionary accruals as follows:

DACCit = TACCit/TAi – [b̂1 (1/TAi) + b̂2 (∆SALESit - ∆RECit)/TAi + b̂3 PPEit/TAi]

Where:

∆REC = change in receivables.

Appendix B.2: Real Earnings Management (REM)

We follow Cohen and Zarowin (2010) in constructing the proxy for real earnings

management since they study accrual and real earnings management around SEOs. The

proxy comprises three components: (a) abnormal level of operating cash flow, (b)

abnormal level of production costs, and (3) abnormal level of discretionary expenses.

We first generate the normal levels of operating cash flow, production costs, and

discretionary expenses using the equations below (Roychowdhury, 2006). We run the

119

regressions by each country-industry-year separately, where the industry classification is

based on the DataStream variable “INDM2”.

Operating cash flow (OCF) is a linear function of sales (SALES) and change in sales

(∆SALES). In order to estimate the normal level of operating cash flow, we run the model

below:

OCFit/TAi = b1 (1/TAi) + b2 SALESit/TAi + b3 ∆SALESit/TAi + eit

The firm’s abnormal OCF is the actual OCF minus the estimated normal OCF.

Production cost (PROD) is the sum of cost of goods sold (COGS) plus change in

inventory (∆INV). Cost of goods sold (COGS) is a linear function of sales (SALES).

Change in inventory (∆INV) is a linear function of lagged and current change in sales

(∆SALES). In order to estimate the normal level of production cost, we run the model

below:

PRODit/TAi = b1 (1/TAi) + b2 SALESit/TAi + b3 ∆SALESit/TAi + b4 ∆SALESit-1/TAi + eit

The firm’s abnormal PROD is the actual PROD minus the estimated normal PROD.

Finally, discretionary expenses (DISX) are defined as the sum of (1) research and

development expenses (RND) and (2) general, selling and administrative expenses (SGA).40

Discretionary expenses are a linear function of lagged sales. In order to estimate the

normal level of discretionary expenses, we run the model below:

DISXit/TAi = b1 (1/TAi) + b2 SALESit-1/TAi + eit

The firm’s abnormal DISX is the actual DISX minus the estimated normal DISX.

40

Selling, general and administrative expenses (SGA) include advertising expenses, which are a part of

discretionary expenses according to Roychowdhury (2006) and Cohen and Zarowin (2010). The variable

code in WorldScope is WC01101.

120

Appendix C: Sample Construction

The construction of the SEO sample in the UK and France between 2001 and 2008. The data

is retrieved from SDC Platinum (ThomsonONE). All exclusions are detailed below.

UK France All

Initial sample 1609 185 1794

Exclude financial firms (383) (34) (417)

Exclude non-ordinary/secondary shares (32) (4) (36)

Exclude firms that did not adopt IFRS in 2005 (71) (9) (81)

Exclude firms that do not appear pre- and post-IFRS (23) (3) (26)

Final sample 1100 135 1235

121

Figure 1. The change in the average discretionary accruals prior to SEO announcements

Figure 1 shows the change in the average discretionary accruals prior to SEO announcements for common-law and

code-law firms between 2002 and 2008, excluding 2005.

122

Figure 2. The change in the average cumulative abnormal returns around SEO announcements

Figure 2 shows the change in the average cumulative abnormal returns around SEO announcements for common-

law and code-law firms between 2001 and 2008.

123

Table 1. The annual distribution of SEOs

Common-law

Code-law

Year

Rights Placements Public Offerings

Rights Placements

2001

13 127 15

8 12

2002

12 26 14

7 2

2003

9 33 20

8 2

2004

15 29 15

5 2

2005

21 33 3

13 2

2006

10 74 2

9 7

2007

2 195 6

15 9

2008

2 243 3

13 13

Sub-total

84 760 78

78 49

Grand-total 922

127

Table 1 reports summary statistics for SEOs issued by common-law and code-law firms between 2001 and 2008. The table shows the annual distribution of SEOs, by

offering techniques.

124

Table 2. Cumulative abnormal returns around SEOs pre- and post-IFRS

Common-law

Code-law

Offering Type:

Rights Placements Public Offerings All

Rights Placements All

Pre−IFRS

N

49 215 64 328

28 18 46

CAR [−2;+2]

0.0078 0.0127 0.0304 0.0154

−0.0088 −0.0070 −0.0081

t-stat

1.92 4.48 3.56 5.95

−2.16 −1.25 −2.48

Post−IFRS

N

35 545 14 594

50 31 81

CAR [−2;+2]

0.0050 0.0180 0.0258 0.0175

0.0178 0.0169 0.0174

t-stat 1.2 7.83 1.33 8.02

4.4 2.33 4.69

Table 2 reports summary statistics for cumulative abnormal returns around issuing SEOs among common-law and code-law firms during pre- and post-IFRS periods. The

table shows cumulative abnormal returns for each offering technique, and for the total issues, in both groups.

125

Table 3. Summary statistics of the variables in equations (1) and (2)

Panel A: Summary statistics of variables used in equation (1).

Common-law

Code-law

N Mean S.D. p25 p50 p75

N Mean S.D. p25 p50 p75

DACC

645 0.0385 0.1507 −0.0638 0.0739 0.1290

75 0.0462 0.0728 −0.0032 0.0432 0.0930

ABSDACC

645 0.1278 0.0885 0.0713 0.1164 0.1602

75 0.0683 0.0524 0.0259 0.0572 0.0947

LOGTA

645 9.8293 2.0621 8.4425 9.3902 11.0461

75 12.8936 2.3921 11.1462 12.4434 14.4064

LEV

645 0.4760 0.3748 0.2153 0.3798 0.6293

75 0.6661 0.2120 0.5310 0.6796 0.8314

TOBINQ

645 2.1571 2.7265 0.5320 1.1013 2.7265

75 0.8397 0.9820 0.3037 0.6038 0.9658

TANG

645 0.1858 0.2355 0.0213 0.0749 0.2553

75 0.2144 0.2235 0.0482 0.1160 0.3344

LIQDT

645 0.1664 0.1940 0.0273 0.0920 0.2447

75 0.0579 0.0425 0.0319 0.0543 0.0700

∆INCDUM

645 0.2899 0.4541 0.0000 0.0000 1.0000

75 0.3200 0.4696 0.0000 0.0000 1.0000

OCF

645 −0.2132 0.3720 −0.3389 −0.0940 0.0226

75 −0.0134 0.1290 −0.0460 0.0289 0.0665

LOSS

645 0.7132 0.4526 0.0000 1.0000 1.0000

75 0.4800 0.5030 0.0000 0.0000 1.0000

BIG4DUM

645 0.4124 0.4926 0.0000 0.0000 1.0000

75 0.7067 0.4584 0.0000 1.0000 1.0000

REM

645 0.0511 0.3593 −0.0649 0.0483 0.1642

75 −0.0236 0.2401 −0.0915 −0.0170 0.0735

IDSHOCK 645 0.3637 0.5553 0.0264 0.1685 0.3951

75 0.4377 0.7170 0.0050 0.1229 0.4840

(continued on next page)

126

Table 3. (continued)

Panel B: Summary statistics of variables used in equation (2).

Common-law

Code-law

N Mean S.D. p25 p50 p75

N Mean S.D. p25 p50 p75

CAR [-2;+2]

922 0.0162 0.0491 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000

127 0.0073 0.0316 0.0000 0.0000 0.0084

LOGISSUE

922 8.4337 2.2137 6.8459 8.4322 10.0344

127 10.6260 2.1774 9.0967 10.5000 12.1264

LOGTA

922 9.9126 2.0595 8.4591 9.5178 11.1163

127 12.6705 2.6057 10.9800 12.1382 14.3901

LEV

922 0.4620 0.3555 0.1980 0.3875 0.6347

127 0.6304 0.2343 0.5112 0.6653 0.7791

ROA

922 −0.2827 0.6356 −0.4582 −0.1169 0.0130

127 −0.0613 0.2648 −0.0705 0.0104 0.0358

TOBINQ

922 2.3082 3.3230 0.5371 1.1454 2.8352

127 0.9678 1.2844 0.3031 0.6317 0.9658

TANG

922 0.1987 0.2529 0.0225 0.0772 0.2727

127 0.2232 0.2511 0.0428 0.1065 0.3164

LIQDT

922 0.1634 0.1978 0.0257 0.0838 0.2282

127 0.0848 0.1328 0.0336 0.0616 0.0700

RND

922 0.0463 0.1177 0.0000 0.0000 0.0077

127 0.0265 0.0781 0.0000 0.0000 0.0095

SDEBIT

922 0.3994 2.2833 0.0611 0.1466 0.3197

127 0.2470 1.6831 0.0285 0.0595 0.1131

DIVDUM

922 0.2049 0.4039 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000

127 0.4015 0.4921 0.0000 0.0000 1.0000

DAYS

922 191.4111 106 101 194 290

127 195.1575 98 107 193 278

LOSS

922 0.7072 0.4553 0.0000 1.0000 1.0000

127 0.4173 0.4951 0.0000 0.0000 1.0000

Panel A and Panel B of Table 3 report summary statistics for the variables used in equations (1) and (2), respectively. The time period for Panel A starts in 2002 and

ends in 2008 (excluding 2005) whereas the time period for Panel B starts in 2001 and ends in 2008. All variables are defined in Appendix A. All continuous variables

are winsorized at the 1% level to mitigate the influence of outliers.

127

Table 4. Correlation matrixes

Panel A: The correlation between variables of equation (1) based on the common-law sample.

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11) (12) (13) (14)

(1) DACC 1.000

(2) ABSDACC −0.101* 1.000

(3) LOGTA 0.161* −0.111

* 1.000

(4) LEV −0.181* 0.124

* −0.021 1.000

(5) TOBINQ −0.262* 0.112

* −0.469

* 0.049 1.000

(6) TANG 0.081* 0.007 0.394

* 0.135

* −0.176

* 1.000

(7) LIQDT −0.099* 0.061 −0.247

* −0.190

* 0.251

* −0.193

* 1.000

(8) ∆INCDUM 0.262* 0.049 0.051 0.027 −0.045 0.028 −0.006 1.000

(9) OCF 0.184* −0.079

* 0.556

* −0.266

* −0.586

* 0.161

* −0.286

* 0.035 1.000

(10) LOSS −0.196* 0.040 −0.484

* 0.015 0.260

* −0.197

* 0.157

* 0.028 −0.414

* 1.000

(11) BIG4DUM −0.083* −0.084

* 0.414

* 0.068 0.091

* 0.143

* −0.045 −0.015 0.130

* −0.172

* 1.000

(12) REM 0.075 −0.006 0.005 −0.018 −0.079* −0.084

* 0.156

* 0.028 0.021 −0.032 −0.045 1.000

(13) IDSHOCK −0.134* 0.156

* −0.128

* 0.179

* 0.005 −0.011 0.062 −0.051 −0.136

* 0.168

* −0.043 −0.073 1.000

(14) POST −0.011 0.009 −0.215* −0.133

* 0.148

* −0.166

* 0.113

* −0.069 −0.107

* 0.105

* −0.223

* 0.045 −0.039 1.000

Panel A of Table 4 presents the Pearson correlation coefficients between all the variables of equation (1) based on the common-law sample. All variables are defined in Appendix

A. All continuous variables are winsorized at the 1% level to mitigate the influence of outliers. * Denotes significance at the 5% level or better.

(continued on next page)

128

Table 4. (continued)

Panel B: The correlation between variables of equation (1) based on the code-law sample.

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11) (12) (13) (14)

(1) DACC 1.000

(2) ABSDACC 0.718* 1.000

(3) LOGTA −0.077 −0.188 1.000

(4) LEV −0.020 0.110 0.226 1.000

(5) TOBINQ −0.303* −0.052 −0.449

* −0.298

* 1.000

(6) TANG −0.013 0.061 0.060 0.331* −0.137 1.000

(7) LIQDT −0.011 0.222 −0.078 0.104 −0.022 −0.070 1.000

(8) ∆INCDUM 0.103 0.194 0.080 −0.027 0.148 −0.063 0.107 1.000

(9) OCF −0.002 −0.143 0.460* 0.128 −0.561

* −0.012 −0.109 −0.070 1.000

(10) LOSS 0.158 0.317* −0.304

* 0.139 0.221 −0.015 0.037 −0.030 −0.517

* 1.000

(11) BIG4DUM −0.076 −0.121 0.516* −0.004 −0.273

* −0.065 0.004 −0.060 0.220 −0.026 1.000

(12) REM −0.042 −0.112 0.009 −0.379* 0.117 −0.275

* 0.122 −0.031 0.234

* −0.238

* −0.064 1.000

(13) IDSHOCK 0.300* 0.279

* −0.181 0.055 −0.018 −0.066 0.251

* −0.158 −0.151 0.284

* 0.152 0.002 1.000

(14) POST −0.274* −0.264

* −0.177 −0.321

* 0.307

* 0.024 −0.064 0.364

* −0.151 −0.113 −0.207 0.144 −0.516 1.000

Panel B of Table 4 presents the Pearson correlation coefficients between all the variables of equation (1) based on the code-law sample. All variables are defined in Appendix A.

All continuous variables are winsorized at the 1% level to mitigate the influence of outliers. * Denotes significance at the 5% level or better.

(continued on next page)

129

Table 4. (continued)

Panel C: The correlation between variables of equation (2) based on the common-law sample.

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11) (12) (13) (14)

(1) CAR[−2;+2] 1.000

(2) LOGISSUE −0.066* 1.000

(3) LOGTA −0.100* 0.693* 1.000

(4) LEV 0.059 −0.007 0.044 1.000

(5) ROA −0.048 0.346* 0.493* −0.236* 1.000

(6) TOBINQ 0.003 −0.198* −0.399* −0.039 −0.446* 1.000

(7) TANG −0.086* 0.244* 0.362* 0.188* 0.157* −0.190* 1.000

(8) LIQDT 0.019 0.040 −0.254* −0.252* −0.147* 0.263* −0.229* 1.000

(9) RND 0.060 −0.016 −0.208* −0.043 −0.259* 0.385* −0.162* 0.340* 1.000

(10) SDEBIT −0.008 −0.018 −0.213* 0.114* −0.174* 0.314* −0.062 0.072* 0.028 1.000

(11) DIVDUM −0.099* 0.349* 0.553* 0.141* 0.301* −0.216* 0.157* −0.245* −0.176* −0.069* 1.000

(12) DAYS 0.042 −0.111* −0.043 −0.052 0.008 −0.039 −0.033 0.006 −0.008 0.011 −0.046 1.000

(13) LOSS 0.098* −0.330* −0.490* −0.060 −0.429* 0.245* −0.191* 0.185* 0.193* 0.077* −0.458* 0.058 1.000

(14) POST 0.019 −0.110* −0.167* −0.096* −0.082* 0.001 −0.138* 0.096* −0.001 −0.088* −0.089* 0.051 0.065* 1.000

Panel C of Table 4 presents the Pearson correlation coefficients between all the variables of equation (2) based on the common-law sample. All variables are defined in Appendix

A. All continuous variables are winsorized at the 1% level to mitigate the influence of outliers. * Denotes significance at the 5% level or better.

(continued on next page)

130

Table 4. (continued)

Panel D: The correlation between variables of equation (2) based on the code-law sample.

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11) (12) (13) (14)

(1) CAR[−2;+2] 1.000

(2) LOGISSUE −0.086 1.000

(3) LOGTA −0.122 0.826* 1.000

(4) LEV −0.070 0.146 0.276* 1.000

(5) ROA 0.031 0.183* 0.389* 0.164 1.000

(6) TOBINQ 0.060 −0.203* −0.387* −0.375* −0.287* 1.000

(7) TANG −0.018 0.087 0.167 0.255* 0.110 −0.255* 1.000

(8) LIQDT −0.056 −0.120 −0.239* −0.339* −0.457* 0.226* −0.166 1.000

(9) RND −0.108 −0.097 −0.165 −0.231* −0.202* 0.304* −0.232* −0.050 1.000

(10) SDEBIT −0.028 −0.090 −0.247* −0.155 −0.807* 0.117 −0.076 0.554* −0.020 1.000

(11) DIVDUM −0.008 0.413* 0.536* 0.045 0.270* −0.191* 0.120 −0.196* −0.201* −0.095 1.000

(12) DAYS 0.065 −0.341* −0.265* −0.048 0.020 −0.034 0.131 0.027 −0.074 −0.117 −0.231* 1.000

(13) LOSS 0.004 −0.176* −0.332* −0.010 −0.457* 0.267* −0.080 0.153 0.324* 0.116 −0.402* 0.085 1.000

(14) POST 0.254* −0.057 −0.102 −0.171 0.083 −0.016 0.196* −0.124 0.024 −0.113 0.139 0.273* 0.028 1.000

Panel D of Table 4 presents the Pearson correlation coefficients between all the variables of equation (2) based on the code-law sample. All variables are defined in Appendix A.

All continuous variables are winsorized at the 1% level to mitigate the influence of outliers. * Denotes significance at the 5% level or better.

131

Table 5. The change in the signed/absolute discretionary accruals before issuing SEOs following IFRS adoption (H1)

Common-law Code-law All Common-law Code-law All

DACC DACC DACC ABSDACC ABSDACC ABSDACC

POST 0.0004 −0.0667***

−0.0006 −0.0015 −0.0496***

−0.0028

(0.03) (−3.54) (−0.04) (−0.16) (−3.39) (−0.30)

CODE 0.0824***

−0.0219

(3.29) (−1.16)

POST*CODE −0.0961***

−0.0351**

(−3.80) (−2.07)

LOGTA 0.0048 −0.0043 0.0034 −0.0043 −0.0051 −0.0043*

(1.18) (−0.85) (0.97) (−1.56) (−1.25) (−1.82)

LEV −0.0881***

−0.0984* −0.0845

*** 0.0389

*** −0.0299 0.0377

***

(−4.20) (−2.00) (−4.13) (2.89) (−0.75) (2.89)

TOBINQ −0.0097**

−0.0383***

−0.0107***

0.0040 −0.0070 0.0037

(−2.51) (−4.38) (−2.78) (1.16) (−1.10) (1.09)

TANG 0.0311 0.0023 0.0370* 0.0127 0.0087 0.0114

(1.44) (0.07) (1.86) (0.96) (0.35) (0.95)

LIQDT −0.0870**

−0.1668 −0.0834**

0.0426 0.2054 0.0412

(−2.23) (−0.78) (−2.16) (1.52) (1.67) (1.49)

∆INCDUM 0.0863***

0.0464**

0.0834***

0.0102 0.0320**

0.0124*

(7.52) (2.62) (7.89) (1.27) (2.45) (1.67)

OCF −0.0392 −0.0487 −0.0327 0.0245 0.0233 0.0238

(−1.55) (−0.65) (−1.33) (1.61) (0.48) (1.63)

LOSS −0.0563***

0.0258 −0.0449***

−0.0044 0.0241 −0.0011

(−4.18) (1.19) (−3.78) (−0.52) (1.50) (−0.15)

BIG4DUM −0.0144 −0.0186 −0.0160 −0.0143 −0.0115 −0.0135*

(−1.03) (−0.89) (−1.29) (−1.64) (−0.77) (−1.73)

RIGHTDUM −0.0520**

−0.0344**

−0.0479**

0.0045 −0.0102 −0.0004

(−2.06) (−2.41) (−2.53) (0.23) (−0.98) (−0.03)

(continued on next page)

132

Table 5. (continued)

Common-law Code-law All Common-law Code-law All

DACC DACC DACC ABSDACC ABSDACC ABSDACC

PUBLICDUM −0.0129

−0.0157 0.0086

0.0066

(−0.53)

(−0.65) (0.59)

(0.47)

REM 0.0166 0.0356 0.0162 0.0006 0.0205 0.0017

(0.74) (0.84) (0.75) (0.04) (0.70) (0.11)

Intercept 0.0953* 0.3362

*** 0.1036

* 0.1263

*** 0.2111

*** 0.1771

***

(1.96) (5.63) (1.95) (3.76) (4.13) (5.45)

N 645 75 720 645 75 720

Adjusted-R2 20.61% 25.17% 19.50% 7.28% 24.05% 8.91%

Table 5 presents results on the change in the signed/absolute discretionary accruals before issuing SEOs following IFRS adoption

among common-law and code-law firms between 2002 and 2008, excluding 2005, using a difference-in-differences research design.

The first two columns of Table 5 report results from the OLS regressions of signed discretionary accruals on a set of firm

characteristics and the IFRS dummy, using the common-law and the code-law samples respectively, between 2002 and 2008,

excluding 2005. The third column of Table 5 reports results from the OLS regression of signed discretionary accruals on a set of firm

characteristics and the difference-in-differences dummies, using the full sample between 2002 and 2008, excluding 2005. Column 4

and column 5 Table 5 report results from the OLS regressions of absolute discretionary accruals on a set of firm characteristics and the

IFRS dummy, using the common-law and the code-law samples respectively, between 2002 and 2008, excluding 2005. The third

column of Table 5 reports results from the OLS regression of absolute discretionary accruals on a set of firm characteristics and the

difference-in-differences dummies, using the full sample between 2002 and 2008, excluding 2005. All variables are defined in

Appendix A. All continuous variables are winsorized at the 1% level to mitigate the influence of outliers. All regressions include year

and industry fixed effects. The t-statistics, presented in parentheses below the coefficients, are calculated using White (1980) standard

errors. *,

**,

*** Denote significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively.

133

Table 6. The change in discretionary accruals after controlling for Idiosyncratic Economic Shocks (H1)

Common-law Code-law All Common-law Code-law All

DACC DACC DACC ABSDACC ABSDACC ABSDACC

POST −0.0006 −0.0520**

−0.0016 −0.0004 −0.0465***

−0.0015

(−0.04) (−2.35) (−0.11) (−0.04) (−2.98) (−0.15)

CODE 0.0909***

−0.0331*

(3.42) (−1.80)

POST*CODE −0.1046***

−0.024

(−3.86) (−1.40)

LOGTA 0.0044 −0.0033 0.0029 −0.0039 −0.0049 −0.0037

(1.10) (−0.61) (0.86) (−1.45) (−1.18) (−1.61)

LEV −0.0833***

−0.0873 −0.0812***

0.0340**

−0.0275 0.0334**

(−3.97) (−1.66) (−3.98) (2.49) (−0.66) (2.55)

TOBINQ −0.0102**

−0.0384***

−0.0111***

0.0045 −0.0070 0.0042

(−2.56) (−4.05) (−2.80) (1.27) (−1.09) (1.21)

TANG 0.0325 −0.0037 0.0380* 0.0112 0.0074 0.0101

(1.51) (−0.11) (1.92) (0.86) (0.29) (0.85)

LIQDT −0.0810**

−0.2287 −0.0792**

0.0364 0.1921 0.0357

(−2.23) (−1.14) (−2.18) (1.43) (1.42) (1.41)

∆INCDUM 0.0846***

0.0448**

0.0823***

0.0120 0.0316**

0.0138*

(7.34) (2.66) (7.79) (1.52) (2.38) (1.90)

OCF −0.0398 −0.0389 −0.0332 0.0252* 0.0254 0.0246

*

(−1.59) (−0.51) (−1.36) (1.69) (0.50) (1.71)

LOSS −0.0527***

0.0214 −0.0420***

−0.0083 0.0231 −0.0049

(−3.79) (0.99) (−3.44) (−0.94) (1.46) (−0.64)

BIG4DUM −0.0137 −0.0265 −0.0148 −0.0150* −0.0132 −0.0150

*

(−0.97) (−1.17) (−1.17) (−1.71) (−0.86) (−1.89)

RIGHTDUM −0.0532**

−0.0309**

−0.0496**

0.0058 −0.0095 0.0019

(−2.08) (−2.07) (−2.58) (0.30) (−0.85) (0.13)

(continued on next page)

134

Table 6. (continued)

Common-law Code-law All Common-law Code-law All

DACC DACC DACC ABSDACC ABSDACC ABSDACC

PUBLICDUM −0.0152 −0.0178 0.011 0.0093

(−0.63) (−0.74) (0.76) (0.66)

REM 0.0140 0.0265 0.0145 0.0034 0.0185 0.0040

(0.60) (0.63) (0.66) (0.21) (0.63) (0.26)

IDSHOCK −0.0208 0.0199 −0.0161 0.0217* 0.0042 0.0211

**

(−1.25) (1.17) (−1.10) (1.78) (0.30) (1.98)

Intercept 0.1073* 0.2053

*** 0.1134

*** 0.1701

*** 0.1154

* 0.1184

***

(1.82) (2.79) (2.68) (4.51) (1.98) (3.99)

N 645 75 720 645 75 720

Adjusted-R2 25.05% 29.64% 24.32% 7.88% 27.76% 10.40%

Table 6 presents results on the change in the signed/absolute discretionary accruals before issuing SEOs following IFRS adoption

among common-law and code-law firms between 2002 and 2008, excluding 2005, using a difference-in-differences research design.

These regressions include a proxy for Idiosyncratic Economic Shocks as computed in Owens, Wu and Zimmerman (2016).

The first two columns of Table 6 report results from the OLS regressions of signed discretionary accruals on a set of firm

characteristics and the IFRS dummy, while including a proxy for business model shock, using the common-law and the code-law

samples respectively, between 2002 and 2008, excluding 2005. The third column of Table 6 reports results from the OLS regression

of signed discretionary accruals on a set of firm characteristics and the difference-in-differences dummies, while including a proxy

for idiosyncratic business model shock, using the full sample between 2002 and 2008, excluding 2005. Column 4 and column 5 in

Table 6 report results from the OLS regressions of absolute discretionary accruals on a set of firm characteristics and the IFRS

dummy, while including a proxy for business model shock, using the common-law and the code-law samples respectively, between

2002 and 2008, excluding 2005. The third column of Table 6 reports results from the OLS regression of absolute discretionary

accruals on a set of firm characteristics and the difference-in-differences dummies, while including a proxy for idiosyncratic

business model shock, using the full sample between 2002 and 2008, excluding 2005. All variables are defined in Appendix A. All

continuous variables are winsorized at the 1% level to mitigate the influence of outliers. All regressions include year and industry

fixed effects. The t-statistics, presented in parentheses below the coefficients, are calculated using White (1980) standard errors. *,

**,

*** Denote significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively.

135

Table 7. The change in the market reaction to issuing SEOs following IFRS adoption (H2)

Common-law Code-law All

CAR[−2,+2] CAR[−2,+2] CAR[−2,+2]

POST 0.0014 0.0260***

0.0014

(0.41) (4.23) (0.42)

CODE −0.0175***

(−3.28)

POST*CODE 0.0234***

(3.60)

LOGISSUE 0.0006 −0.0017 0.0005

(0.55) (−0.97) (0.46)

LOGTA −0.0012 −0.0013 −0.0013

(−0.84) (−0.69) (−1.02)

LEV 0.0082 0.0082 0.0083

(1.21) (0.63) (1.31)

ROA 0.0016 0.0042 0.0013

(0.49) (0.13) (0.43)

TOBINQ −0.0005 0.0029 −0.0004

(−0.70) (1.28) (−0.59)

TANG −0.0155***

−0.0305**

−0.0161***

(−2.62) (−2.04) (−2.91)

LIQDT −0.0038 −0.0197 −0.0024

(−0.40) (−0.88) (−0.27)

RND 0.0340 −0.0742* 0.0282

(1.41) (−1.81) (1.25)

SDEBIT −0.0004 0.0007 −0.0004

(−0.81) (0.15) (−0.96)

DIVDUM −0.0091* 0.0004 −0.0069

(−1.68) (0.09) (−1.53)

(continued on next page)

136

Table 7. (continued)

Common-law Code-law All

CAR[−2,+2] CAR[−2,+2] CAR[−2,+2]

DAYS 0.0002 −0.0031 0.0001

(1.32) (−1.55) (1.07)

LOSS 0.0037 0.0001 0.0029

(0.78) (0.01) (0.71)

RIGHTDUM −0.0036 0.0004 −0.0027

(−0.85) (0.06) (−0.79)

PUBLICDUM 0.0152*

0.0156*

(1.89)

(1.95)

Intercept 0.0131 0.0303 0.0114

(0.70) (1.06) (1.06)

N 922 127 1049

Adjusted-R2 6.05% 12.69% 6.52%

Table 7 presents results on the change in the market reaction to issuing SEOs following IFRS adoption among common-law and

code-law firms between 2001 and 2008 using a difference-in-differences research design.

The first two columns of Table 7 report results from the OLS regressions of cumulative abnormal returns on a set of firm

characteristics and the IFRS dummy, using the common-law and the code-law samples respectively, between 2001 and 2008. The

third column of Table 7 reports results from the OLS regression of cumulative abnormal returns on a set of firm characteristics and

the difference-in-differences dummies using the full sample between 2001 and 2008. All variables are defined in Appendix A. All

continuous variables are winsorized at the 1% level to mitigate the influence of outliers. All regressions include year and industry

fixed effects. The t-statistics, presented in parentheses below the coefficients, are calculated using White (1980) standard errors. *,

**,

*** Denote significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively.

137

Table 8. The change in the market reaction to issuing different types of SEOs following IFRS adoption (H2)

Common-law Code-law

Rights Placements Public Offerings Rights Placements

CAR[−2,+2] CAR[−2,+2] CAR[−2,+2] CAR[−2,+2] CAR[−2,+2]

POST −0.0008 0.0017 0.0065 0.0297***

0.0264**

(−0.11) (0.44) (0.28) (3.09) (2.69)

LOGISSUE 0.0032 0.0006 0.0020 −0.0015 −0.0030*

(0.93) (0.47) (0.38) (−0.46) (−1.82)

LOGTA 0.0005 −0.0027* 0.0068 −0.0003 0.0036

*

(0.20) (−1.77) (1.26) (−0.10) (1.96)

LEV −0.0325 0.0077 0.0011 0.0117 0.0435*

(−1.49) (1.04) (0.03) (0.85) (1.94)

ROA −0.0167 0.0025 0.0090 −0.1076 −0.0353

(−1.66) (0.70) (0.56) (−1.62) (−1.44)

TOBINQ 0.0004 −0.0006 0.0035 0.0087* 0.0084

**

(0.11) (−0.82) (0.37) (1.69) (2.60)

TANG −0.0150 −0.0151**

0.0081 −0.0241 −0.0055

(−1.08) (−2.55) (0.21) (−1.02) (−0.30)

LIQDT −0.0487 −0.0001 0.0095 −0.0453 −0.0239

(−1.37) (−0.01) (0.19) (−1.16) (−0.75)

RND −0.0250 0.0363 0.0387 −0.0502 −0.0981*

(−0.56) (1.34) (0.43) (−0.93) (−2.06)

SDEBIT −0.0099 −0.0004 −0.0002 −0.0445 −0.0011

(−1.53) (−0.80) (−0.02) (−0.95) (−0.34)

DIVDUM −0.0237**

−0.0051 −0.0032 −0.0096 0.0084

(−2.01) (−0.80) (−0.15) (−0.91) (1.11)

DAYS 0.0018 0.0006 −0.0009 −0.0023 0.0004

(0.64) (1.10) (−0.14) (−2.32) (1.26)

(continued on next page)

138

Table 8. (continued)

Common-law Code-law

Rights Placements Public Offerings Rights Placements

CAR[−2,+2] CAR[−2,+2] CAR[−2,+2] CAR[−2,+2] CAR[−2,+2]

LOSS −0.0126 0.0025 0.0541* −0.0224 −0.0075

(−1.27) (0.46) (1.81) (−1.63) (−0.68)

Intercept 0.0125 0.0233 −0.0043 0.0355 −0.0770**

(0.32) (1.61) (−0.03) (0.97) (−2.65)

N 84 760 78 78 49

Adjusted-R2 8.14% 5.27% 12.40% 21.51% 24.61%

Table 8 presents results on the change in the market reaction to issuing different types of SEO offerings following IFRS adoption

among common-law and code-law firms between 2001 and 2008.

The first three columns of Table 8 report results from the OLS regressions of cumulative abnormal returns on a set of firm

characteristics and the IFRS dummy for each offering technique in the common-law sample, between 2001 and 2008. The last two

columns of Table 8 report results from the OLS regression of cumulative abnormal returns on a set of firm characteristics and the

IFRS dummy for each offering technique in the code-law sample, between 2001 and 2008. All variables are defined in Appendix A.

All continuous variables are winsorized at the 1% level to mitigate the influence of outliers. All regressions include year and

industry fixed effects. The t-statistics, presented in parentheses below the coefficients, are calculated using White (1980) standard

errors. *,

**,

*** Denote significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively.

139

Table 9. The change in the market reaction to Rights and Placements following IFRS adoption (H2)

Rights Placements

CAR[-2,+2] CAR[-2,+2]

POST −0.0025 0.0013

(−0.35) (0.32)

CODE −0.0191**

−0.0160**

(−2.59) (−2.24)

POST*CODE 0.0300***

0.0184*

(3.27) (1.82)

LOGISSUE 0.0025 0.0003

(1.00) (0.22)

LOGTA −0.0012 −0.0024*

(−0.65) (−1.77)

LEV −0.0172 0.0125**

(−1.30) (2.08)

ROA −0.0221***

0.0036

(−2.96) (1.04)

TOBINQ 0.0019 −0.0006

(0.65) (−0.86)

TANG −0.0103 −0.0167***

(−1.16) (−3.34)

LIQDT −0.0378**

0.0001

(−2.45) (0.01)

RND −0.0068 0.0177

(−0.32) (0.81)

SDEBIT −0.0137***

−0.0005

(−3.10) (−1.42)

DIVDUM −0.0166**

−0.0034

(−2.31) (−0.61)

(continued on next page)

140

Table 9. (continued)

Rights Placements

CAR[-2,+2] CAR[-2,+2]

DAYS −0.0001 0.0026

(−0.42) (1.02)

LOSS −0.0126**

0.0040

(−2.02) (0.76)

Intercept 0.0249 0.0304**

(1.03) (2.11)

N 162 809

Adjusted-R2 3.70% 4.24%

Table 9 presents results on the change in the market reaction to issuing different types of SEO offerings following IFRS adoption

among common-law and code-law firms between 2001 and 2008 using a difference-in-differences research design (OLS

regressions).

The first column of Table 9 reports results from the OLS regression of cumulative abnormal returns on a set of firm characteristics

and the IFRS dummy for the Rights offering technique, using the common-law and the code-law samples, between 2001 and 2008.

The last column of Table 9 reports results from the OLS regression of cumulative abnormal returns on a set of firm characteristics

and the IFRS dummy for the Placements offering technique, using the common-law and the code-law samples, between 2001 and

2008. All variables are defined in Appendix A. All continuous variables are winsorized at the 1% level to mitigate the influence of

outliers. All regressions include year and industry fixed effects. The t-statistics, presented in parentheses below the coefficients, are

calculated using White (1980) standard errors. *,

**,

*** Denote significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively.

141

Table 10. The change in the propensity to issue SEOs following IFRS adoption (H3)

Time period: 2001 - 2008 Time period: 2003 - 2006

Common-law Code-law All Common-law Code-law All

SEODUM SEODUM SEODUM SEODUM SEODUM SEODUM

POST 0.2317***

0.6145***

0.2391***

−0.0559 1.1209***

−0.0508

(2.65) (2.96) (2.74) (−0.40) (3.23) (−0.36)

CODE −0.2686 −0.9683***

(−1.45) (−3.27)

POST*CODE 0.3460 0.9655***

(1.57) (2.70)

LOGTA 0.0150 0.1014**

0.0363 0.1102**

0.2914***

0.1452***

(0.56) (2.22) (1.63) (2.53) (3.39) (4.00)

LEV −0.4549***

−0.6083 −0.4453***

−0.7649***

0.2733 −0.5857***

(−3.67) (−1.20) (−3.82) (−3.33) (0.37) (−2.85)

ROA −0.2678**

−0.5367 −0.2859***

0.0071 0.0628 0.0185

(−2.48) (−1.08) (−2.76) (0.03) (0.05) (0.08)

TOBINQ −0.0171 0.0443 −0.0115 0.0117 −0.2146 0.0126

(−0.83) (0.86) (−0.60) (0.28) (−0.58) (0.32)

TANG 0.0278 0.6651 0.0676 0.0066 0.3720 0.0279

(0.14) (1.20) (0.37) (0.02) (0.48) (0.10)

LIQDT −0.5253**

−0.0585 −0.4285* −0.3654 −1.2259 −0.2536

(−2.24) (−0.06) (−1.90) (−0.93) (−0.71) (−0.67)

RND 0.4213 −2.9503* 0.0817 1.3394

** −0.4405 1.0718

*

(1.03) (−1.92) (0.21) (2.21) (−0.22) (1.90)

DIVDUM −0.1805 −0.4984* −0.2370

** −0.0399 −0.4147 −0.1028

(−1.38) (−1.80) (−2.03) (−0.19) (−0.97) (−0.53)

LOSS 0.2704**

0.3472 0.2890***

0.2885 0.9201* 0.4164

**

(2.33) (1.34) (2.77) (1.47) (1.79) (2.34)

RIGHTDUM −0.3398**

−0.0099 −0.2747**

0.2763 0.1674 0.2666

(−2.24) (−0.04) (−2.27) (1.26) (0.37) (1.45)

(continued on next page)

142

Table 10. (continued)

Time period: 2001 - 2008 Time period: 2003 - 2006

Common-law Code-law All Common-law Code-law All

SEODUM SEODUM SEODUM SEODUM SEODUM SEODUM

PUBLICDUM −0.1541

−0.1545 0.2602

0.2527

(−1.06)

(−1.07) (1.20)

(1.17)

Intercept −0.8263**

−2.1648**

−1.0560***

−1.8955***

−5.3204***

−2.3404***

(−2.07) (−2.51) (−3.02) (−2.79) (−3.07) (−3.98)

N 3101 673 3774 1567 328 1895

Pseudo-R2 4.52% 6.70% 4.96% 5.23% 17.74% 5.02%

Number of Issues 765 125 890 253 48 301

Marginal Effects

POST 4.19%***

9.05%***

4.2%***

-0.72% 10.67%***

-0.63%

CODE

-4.54%

-9.67%***

POST*CODE

6.59%

15.49%**

Table 10 presents results on the change in the propensity to issue SEOs following IFRS adoption among common-law and code-

law firms between 2001 and 2008 and between 2003 and 2006 using a difference-in-differences research design.

The first two columns of Table 10 report results from the Logistic regressions of the SEO dummy on a set of firm characteristics

and the IFRS dummy, using the common-law and the code-law samples respectively, between 2001 and 2008. The third column of

Table 10 reports results from the Logistic regression of the SEO dummy on a set of firm characteristics and the difference-in-

differences dummies, using the full sample between 2001 and 2008. Column 4 and Column 5 of Table 10 report results from the

Logistic regressions of the SEO dummy on a set of firm characteristics and the IFRS dummy, using the common-law and the code-

law samples respectively, between 2003 and 2006. The last column of Table 10 reports results from the Logistic regression of the

SEO dummy on a set of firm characteristics and the difference-in-differences dummies, using the full sample between 2003 and

2006. The table reports the marginal effects for the difference-in-differences dummies at the bottom. All variables are defined in

Appendix A. All continuous variables are winsorized at the 1% level to mitigate the influence of outliers. All regressions include

year and industry fixed effects. The z-statistics, presented in parentheses below the coefficients, are calculated using White (1980)

standard errors. *,

**,

*** Denote significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively.

143

Table 11. The change in the discretionary accruals prior to SEOs based on matched sample regressions (H1)

Common-law Code-law All

DACC DACC DACC

POST 0.0003 −0.0639***

−0.0027

(0.01) (−2.97) (−0.10)

CODE 0.0819**

(2.52)

POST*CODE −0.0806**

(−2.43)

LOGTA 0.0001 −0.0052 −0.0004

(0.01) (−0.64) (−0.07)

LEV −0.0518 −0.0576 −0.066

(−0.84) (−0.95) (−1.47)

TOBINQ 0.0024 −0.0418***

−0.0066

(0.28) (−4.38) (−0.74)

TANG 0.0829 −0.0272 0.032

(1.52) (−0.62) (0.92)

LIQDT 0.0147 −0.1914 0.0773

(0.07) (−0.85) (0.53)

∆INCDUM 0.0635**

0.0477**

0.0601***

(2.06) (2.43) (3.67)

OCF 0.0991 −0.0758 0.0617

(1.06) (−0.88) (0.93)

LOSS −0.0442 0.0140 −0.0210

(−0.91) (0.59) (−0.94)

BIG4DUM 0.0035 −0.0196 −0.0003

(0.08) (−0.92) (−0.01)

RIGHTDUM −0.0606 −0.0389**

−0.0531***

(−1.34) (−2.37) (−2.78)

(continued on next page)

144

Table 11. (continued)

Common-law Code-law All

DACC DACC DACC

PUBLICDUM −0.1722***

−0.1410***

(−2.77)

(−2.98)

REM 0.0177 0.0102 0.0036

(0.26) (0.21) (0.11)

Intercept 0.0531 0.3402***

0.1014

(0.44) (3.84) (1.28)

N 65 65 130

Adjusted-R2 23.47% 17.84% 23.21%

Table 11 presents results on the change in the signed discretionary accruals before issuing SEOs around IFRS adoption among

common-law and code-law firms between 2002 and 2008, excluding 2005, using a matched difference-in-differences research

design. The regressions are matched (using CEM matching) based on Total Assets, Industry and IFRS.

The first two columns of Table 11 report results from the OLS regressions of signed discretionary accruals on a set of firm

characteristics and the IFRS dummy, using a matched sample of common-law and code-law firms respectively, between 2002 and

2008, excluding 2005. The third column of Table 11 reports results from the OLS regression of signed discretionary accruals on a

set of firm characteristics and the difference-in-differences dummies, using the full matched sample between 2002 and 2008,

excluding 2005. All variables are defined in Appendix A. All continuous variables are winsorized at the 1% level to mitigate the

influence of outliers. All regressions include year and industry fixed effects. The t-statistics, presented in parentheses below the

coefficients, are calculated using White (1980) standard errors. *,

**,

*** Denote significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels,

respectively.

145

Table 12. The change in market reaction to SEOs based on matched sample regressions (H2)

Common-law Code-law All

CAR[-2,+2] CAR[-2,+2] CAR[-2,+2]

POST 0.0179 0.0298***

0.0047

(1.43) (3.94) (0.59)

CODE −0.0223***

(−2.65)

POST*CODE 0.0227**

(2.12)

LOGISSUE 0.0007 −0.0008 0.0015

(0.52) (−0.37) (0.86)

LOGTA −0.0006 −0.0019 −0.0023

(−0.27) (−0.67) (−1.03)

LEV −0.0013 0.0139 0.0053

(−0.11) (0.99) (0.52)

ROA 0.0030 0.0032 0.0057

(0.22) (0.10) (0.66)

TOBINQ −0.0050 0.0030 −0.0010

(−1.54) (1.35) (−0.54)

TANG 0.0036 −0.0295 −0.0067

(0.37) (−1.62) (−0.61)

LIQDT −0.0184 −0.0129 −0.0070

(−0.62) (−0.54) (−0.36)

RND 0.1552 −0.0722 −0.0115

(0.96) (−1.63) (−0.29)

SDEBIT 0.0209 0.0005 0.0013

(0.45) (0.11) (0.57)

DIVDUM −0.0151 −0.0018 −0.0067

(−1.61) (−0.23) (−1.03)

(continued on next page)

146

Table 12. (continued)

Common-law Code-law All

CAR[-2,+2] CAR[-2,+2] CAR[-2,+2]

DAYS −0.0012 −0.0023 0.0019

(−0.23) (−1.24) (−0.74)

LOSS 0.0013 −0.0027 0.0001

(0.14) (−0.32) (0.01)

RIGHTDUM 0.0115 0.0014 0.0029

(0.89) (0.19) (0.48)

PUBLICDUM 0.0074

−0.0045

(0.68)

(−0.37)

Intercept 0.0524 0.0203 0.0153

(1.61) (0.59) (0.65)

N 107 107 214

Adjusted-R2 6.64% 11.07% 7.78%

Table 12 presents results on the change in the market reaction to issuing SEOs around IFRS adoption among common-law and

code-law firms between 2001 and 2008 using a matched difference-in-differences research design. The regressions are matched

(using CEM matching) based on Total Assets, Industry and IFRS.

The first two columns of Table 12 report results from the OLS regressions of cumulative abnormal returns on a set of firm

characteristics and the IFRS dummy, using a matched sample of common-law and code-law firms respectively, between 2001 and

2008. The third column of Table 12 reports results from the OLS regression of cumulative abnormal returns on a set of firm

characteristics and the difference-in-differences dummies using the full matched sample between 2001 and 2008. All variables are

defined in Appendix A. All continuous variables are winsorized at the 1% level to mitigate the influence of outliers. All regressions

include year and industry fixed effects. The t-statistics, presented in parentheses below the coefficients, are calculated using White

(1980) standard errors. *,

**,

*** Denote significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively.

147

Table 13. The change in the propensity to issue SEOs based on matched sample regressions (H3)

Common-law Code-law All

SEODUM SEODUM SEODUM

POST −0.2016 0.6771***

−0.2044

(−1.00) (3.01) (−1.02)

CODE −0.4218*

(−1.69)

POST*CODE 0.8545***

(2.74)

LOGTA −0.0945 0.0684 0.0011

(−1.56) (1.43) (0.03)

LEV −0.6127* −0.5791 −0.4892

*

(−1.76) (−1.12) (−1.92)

ROA −0.1847 −0.4869 −0.2166

(−0.56) (−0.97) (−0.85)

TOBINQ −0.0882 0.0582 −0.0303

(−1.50) (1.13) (−0.80)

TANG 0.4513 0.8758 0.464

(0.91) (1.51) (1.29)

LIQDT 0.0661 0.0427 0.3253

(0.09) (0.05) (0.60)

RND 0.9103 −2.9778* −0.821

(0.63) (−1.90) (−0.85)

DIVDUM 0.0185 −0.4312 −0.1944

(0.07) (−1.46) (−0.99)

LOSS 0.2936 0.3768 0.3522*

(1.08) (1.36) (1.87)

RIGHTDUM −0.0805 0.0858 −0.0308

(−0.28) (0.34) (−0.18)

(continued on next page)

148

Table 13. (continued)

Common-law Code-law All

SEODUM SEODUM SEODUM

PUBLICDUM −0.1379 −0.1423

(−0.40) (−0.42)

Intercept 0.5106 −1.6637* −0.7079

(0.54) (−1.79) (−1.11)

N 602 602 1204

Pseudo-R2 5.25% 7.32% 5.09%

Number of Issues 125 110 235

Marginal Effects

POST −3.19% 9.73%*** −3.18%

CODE

−6.55%*

POST*CODE

14.87%***

Table 13 presents results on the change in the propensity to issue SEOs around IFRS adoption among common-law and code-law

firms between 2001 and 2008 using a matched difference-in-differences research design. The regressions are matched (using CEM

matching) based on Total Assets, Industry and IFRS.

The first two columns of Table 13 report results from the Logistic regressions of the SEO dummy on a set of firm characteristics and

the IFRS dummy, using matched samples from common-law and code-law firms respectively, between 2001 and 2008. The third

column of Table 13 reports results from the Logistic regression of the SEO dummy on a set of firm characteristics and the

difference-in-differences dummies, using the full matched sample between 2001 and 2008. The table reports the marginal effects for

the difference-in-differences dummies at the bottom. All variables are defined in Appendix A. All continuous variables are

winsorized at the 1% level to mitigate the influence of outliers. All regressions include year and industry fixed effects. The z-

statistics, presented in parentheses below the coefficients, are calculated using White (1980) standard errors. *,

**,

*** Denote

significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively.

149

Table 14. The change in market reaction to SEOs based on Heckman two-step model (H2)

Common-law Code-law All

CAR[-2,+2] CAR[-2,+2] CAR[-2,+2]

POST 0.0051 0.0257***

0.0045

(1.34) (4.36) (1.20)

CODE −0.0157***

(−2.85)

POST*CODE 0.0220***

(3.32)

IMR 0.0224* −0.0052 0.0168

(1.67) (−0.25) (1.42)

LOGISSUE 0.0008 −0.0017 0.0006

(0.63) (−0.96) (0.51)

LOGTA −0.0012 −0.0014 −0.0013

(−0.77) (−0.70) (−0.98)

LEV 0.0085 0.0090 0.0084

(1.19) (0.64) (1.27)

ROA 0.0015 0.0038 0.0013

(0.43) (0.11) (0.39)

TOBINQ −0.0004 0.0028 −0.0004

(−0.57) (1.24) (−0.52)

TANG −0.0189***

−0.0309**

−0.0184***

(−2.95) (−2.02) (−3.12)

LIQDT −0.0022 −0.0196 −0.0012

(−0.22) (−0.87) (−0.13)

RND 0.0436* −0.0765

* 0.0359

(1.73) (−1.77) (1.52)

SDEBIT −0.0005 0.0006 −0.0005

(−1.05) (0.14) (−1.13)

(continued on next page)

150

Table 14. (continued)

Common-law Code-law All

CAR[-2,+2] CAR[-2,+2] CAR[-2,+2]

DIVDUM −0.0126**

0.0006 −0.0094*

(−2.02) (0.09) (−1.82)

DAYS 0.0003 −0.0061 0.0001

(1.23) (−1.45) (1.01)

LOSS 0.0086 −0.0009 0.0065

(1.43) (−0.09) (1.26)

RIGHTDUM −0.0040 0.0005 −0.0032

(−0.92) (0.08) (−0.89)

PUBLICDUM 0.0152*

0.0155*

(1.87)

(1.93)

Intercept −0.0195 0.0371 −0.0279

(−0.76) (0.97) (−0.94)

N 922 127 1049

Adjusted-R2 6.26% 12.36% 6.67%

Table 14 presents results on the change in the market reaction to issuing SEOs around IFRS adoption among common-law and

code-law firms between 2001 and 2008, using a difference-in-differences research design, after controlling for self-selection bias

using the Heckman two-step estimator. The variable SALES is used as the exclusion restriction in the first stage.

The first two columns of Table 14 report results from the Heckman two-step regressions of cumulative abnormal returns on a set of

firm characteristics and the IFRS dummy, using the common-law and the code-law samples respectively, between 2001 and 2008.

The third column of Table 14 reports results from the Heckman two-step regression of cumulative abnormal returns on a set of firm

characteristics and the difference-in-differences dummies using the full sample between 2001 and 2008. The Inverse Mills Ratio

(IMR) is calculated using SALES as the exclusion restriction (Kim and Purnandum, 2014). All variables are defined in Appendix A.

All continuous variables are winsorized at the 1% level to mitigate the influence of outliers. All regressions include year and

industry fixed effects. The t-statistics, presented in parentheses below the coefficients, are calculated using White (1980) standard

errors. *,

**,

*** Denote significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively.

151

Chapter 4

The Bias in Measuring Conditional Conservatism

ABSTRACT: Prior studies have raised concerns about the bias in the asymmetric

timeliness (AT) measure of conditional conservatism (CC) proposed by Basu (1997). This

measure, along with the C_Score measure of Khan & Watts (2009), underpins a large body

of empirical research on CC. Thus, this paper assesses the extent to which the prior

literature needs to be revised because of its reliance on these measures. In exploring this

issue, we replicate prior studies that rely on the AT or the C_Score measures, and then

compare the replicated results with those generated by applying the variance ratio (VR)

measure of CC, proposed by Dutta & Patatoukas (2017). We draw four main conclusions.

First, the AT measure is to some extent associated with the VR measure unconditionally.

Second, the observed variation in the C_Score measure seems more likely to be driven by

the variation in the bias in the AT measure rather than variation in CC. Third, the AT

measure yields similar results to the VR measure in interrupted time-series research

designs that model the change in CC following an exogenous change in accounting policy.

Fourth, the results of prior studies using the AT measure to document cross-sectional

differences in CC are unreliable.

Keywords: Financial Reporting; Conditional Conservatism; Measurement Bias;

Asymmetric Timeliness; Research Design.

152

4.1. Introduction

The literature on conditional conservatism (henceforth CC) is large and still growing (see

the surveys of Mora & Walker, 2015 and Ruch & Taylor, 2015). Most of the empirical

literature on CC relies on the Basu (1997) asymmetric timeliness (hereafter AT) measure

or the Khan & Watts (2009) C_Score measure – a development of the AT measure used to

produce a firm-year measure of CC. Researchers have drawn several important conclusions

about the role of accounting conservatism in capital markets based on the asymmetric

timeliness measures of CC. For instance, prior studies find that CC mitigates bondholder-

shareholder agency problems (Ahmed, Billings, Morton, & Stanford-Harris, 2002), CC is

associated with a lower cost of equity capital (García Lara, García Osma, & Penalva,

2011), and CC is used to resolve ramifications arising from information asymmetry

(LaFond & Watts, 2008). However, recent literature raises serious concerns about potential

bias in the AT measure arising from non-accounting (economic) factors (Dietrich, Muller,

& Riedl, 2007; Givoly, Hayn, & Natarajan, 2007; Patatoukas & Thomas, 2011, 2016). The

main purpose of our study is to help assess the likelihood that prior literature on CC may

need to be revised based on a more appropriate measure. In investigating this matter, we

heed the call of Ball (2016) to revisit previous studies and verify their conclusions using

new methodologies and data. Our findings have particular implications for researchers

interested in testing theories about the costs and benefits of CC.

Dutta & Patatoukas (2017) develop a novel measure for estimating CC, the variance

ratio (hereafter VR), which is the spread between the conditional variance of bad news

accruals and the conditional variance of good news accruals. They show that their measure

does not suffer from the bias implicit in the AT measure. Specifically, whilst the AT

coefficient estimate is biased due to price-scale irregularities, expected component of

returns, cashflow persistence and asymmetric returns distribution, the VR measure proves

to be orthogonal to these confounding factors. That is, the VR measure is not driven by the

153

non-accounting factors that yield spurious evidence of CC when using the AT measure.

Thus, we believe that the VR measure provides an appropriate measure to compare with

the long-standing AT measure.

We start our analysis by reporting new evidence showing that the AT and the VR

measures are associated unconditionally. The unconditional association establishes a level

playing field between both measures in a sense that AT and VR arguably estimate the same

feature of financial reporting. This initial analysis is important because it shows that,

although the AT measure is biased, yet it is likely to indicate the presence of CC when it

exists. The problem with the AT measure is that it is biased towards recognising CC when

it does not exist. In statistical terms, the AT measure gives rise to numerous type 1 errors.

Having shown an unconditional association between the AT and the VR measures, we then

move on to investigate the possibility that the bias in the AT measure, which is not present

in the VR measure, may have led to systematic incorrect conclusions in the CC literature.

We achieve this research objective by conducting two sets of empirical tests. Firstly, we

reconstruct the C_Score measure of Khan & Watts (2009) using the VR measure as the

proxy for CC instead of the AT measure. Secondly, we replicate four influential prior

studies that rely on the AT measure (or the C_Score measure), and then compare the

results of our replications with the results generated by applying the VR measure of CC.

Our first set of tests, relating to the C_Score measure, shows that, whilst AT is strongly

related to the decile ranks of stock price, market-to-book ratio, firm size, leverage and the

C_Score measure, such relations either do not exist or are much weaker for the VR

measure. These findings in turn suggest that the bias in the AT measure also applies to the

C_Score measure because of the similar behavior of AT and C_Score across the decile

ranks of the aforementioned financial variables. In other words, the C_Score measure

arguably captures variations in the bias in the AT measure rather actual variations in CC.

In the second set of tests, we first replicate four well known journal articles on CC that

employ the AT measure (or the C_Score measure): André, Filip, & Paugam (2015), Lobo

154

& Zhou (2006), Ball, Robin, & Sadka (2008) and Gassen, Fulbier, & Sellhorn (2006).

Then we re-examine the evidence provided in these articles using VR instead of AT (or

C_Score). The intuition behind selecting these articles is that they cover different

applications of the AT measure using US and international datasets, which allows us to

generalize our findings. The first two articles use an interrupted time-series research design

that models the change in CC for the same sample following an exogenous change in

accounting policy, whereas the last two articles utilize a cross-sectional research design.

Our findings indicate that AT and VR lead to the same conclusion in an interrupted time-

series setting that uses the same sample and involves an exogenous change in accounting

policy; however, AT and VR yield different conclusions when applied in a cross-sectional

setting. Furthermore, even when we find a weak consistency between AT and VR in cross-

sectional settings, placebo tests refute the reliability of AT but not that of VR (Patatoukas

& Thomas, 2011).

This paper makes three main contributions. First, we draw on the work of prior studies

(Dietrich et al., 2007; Givoly et al.; Patatoukas & Thomas, 2011, 2016) and consider an

alternative measure of CC instead of the AT measure. Our evidence suggests a high

likelihood that a considerable amount of prior studies on CC should be revised and their

conclusions reassessed. Second, we provide evidence suggesting that VR is a more reliable

measure of CC than AT. Our findings complement those of Dutta & Patatoukas (2017)

who claim that their VR measure is not driven by non-accounting factors. Third, we

identify research designs where one can use the asymmetric timeliness measures (i.e., AT

and C_Score) with a low probability of drawing false conclusions; yet, in such cases, we

highly recommend using the VR measure as a robustness check.

The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. Section 4.2 outlines the literature

related to our study. Section 4.3 motivates and states our hypotheses. Section 4.4 describes

the data and the sample selection. Section 4.5 presents the research methods and the

corresponding empirical results. Section 4.6 concludes the paper.

155

4.2. Motivation & Literature Review

4.2.1. Accounting Conservatism

Accounting conservatism is one of the oldest concepts in the history of accounting

(Sterling, 1976). Theoretically, conservatism is the accounting practice that anticipates

economic losses before being realized and recognizes economic gains only when realized

(Beaver & Ryan, 2005; Watts, 2003a). Empirical studies define conservatism as the

requirement of a lower degree of verification to recognize economic losses compared to

the degree of verification required to recognize economic gains (Basu, 1997; Pope &

Walker, 1999). Since its introduction, the concept of conservatism was criticized for

understating earnings in current financial cycles and overstating them in future cycles

(Watts, 2003a). Nevertheless, the importance of the conservatism (prudence) concept in

financial reporting stems from its role in mitigating adverse selection and moral hazard

(Mora & Walker, 2015). The International Accounting Standards Board (IASB) removed

the prudence (conservatism) concept from its conceptual framework in 2010 as it

contradicts with the value relevance of financial statements. A few years later, and due to

the informational demands of stakeholders, the IASB decided to reintroduce the prudence

concept in the coming conceptual framework in a way that does not conflict with the value

relevance objective (Cooper, 2015). This incident shows that accounting conservatism

remains as a controversial issue with respect to the setting of accounting standards in

general and the construction of the conceptual framework in particular.

Accounting conservatism can be either conditional or unconditional. Conditional

conservatism (CC) is news dependent since it involves the timely recognition of bad news

in earnings to a larger extent than good news, whereas unconditional conservatism is news

independent because it understates the book value of net assets regardless of news (Ryan,

2006). Examples of CC include inventory write-downs and intangible asset impairments

(Dutta & Patatoukas, 2017). Examples of unconditional conservatism include using

historical cost accounting for positive net present value projects or accelerating the

156

depreciation of property plant and equipment (Beaver & Ryan, 2005). In the present study

we are mainly interested in CC, yet we allow for unconditional conservatism, to some

extent, through examining the behavior of AT and VR across the decile ranks of the

market-to-book ratio – a widely adopted proxy for unconditional conservatism (Beaver &

Ryan, 2005; Feltham & Ohlson, 1995; Pae, Thornton, & Welker, 2005; Roychowdhury &

Watts, 2007).41

4.2.2. Asymmetric Timeliness Measures of Conditional Conservatism

Among all measures of CC, the Basu (1997) AT measure is by far the most frequently used

measure in the literature (Wang, Hógartaigh, & Zijl, 2009). However, a problem with the

AT measure is that it cannot be estimated at the firm-year level. Khan & Watts (2009)

overcome this weakness and propose a firm-year measure of CC, the C_Score. In what

follows, we briefly explain the estimation process of the AT and the C_Score measures.42

Essentially, the AT measure is the differential timeliness in reflecting bad news relative

to good news in earnings. Basu (1997) uses the sign of stock returns as a proxy for

bad/good news as shown in the earnings-returns piecewise linear regression below.

Xit = β0 + β1 RDit + β2 RETit + β3 RD*RETit + ɛit (1)

Where, for firm i in year t, X is earnings deflated by lagged market value of equity, RD is a

dummy variable that equals 1 if RET is negative and 0 otherwise, and RET is the

(abnormal) stock return over the fiscal year (see Appendix A for complete definitions). The

41

Other news-independent measures of conservatism include the negative accruals measure and the relative

skewness of earnings to that of operating cash flow (Givoly & Hayn, 2000) as well as the hidden reserves

measure (Penman & Zhang, 2002). A material disadvantage of the first two measures is that their calculation

requires a long time period per firm. Similarly, the last measure is barely used because it requires data for a

large number of variables, which in turn leads to a high level of missing observations in the final sample even

when using US data. 42

Ball & Shivakumar (2005) propose a measure of CC for private firms, where stock returns are unavailable.

The authors use the sign of operating cash flow instead of the sign of stock return as a proxy for bad/good

news. We do not include this measure in our study as it is not commonly used in papers that study public

companies.

157

coefficient on the interaction term (β3) captures the asymmetric timeliness in news

reflected in earnings (i.e., the AT measure). A significantly positive β3 indicates that, on

average, economic losses are reflected in earnings in a timelier manner than economic

gains, i.e., conditionally conservative reporting. Basu (1997) also introduces another CC

measure based on the explanatory power of the earnings-returns regression for the bad

news and the good news subsamples, separately. The measure is the ratio of the obtained

R2 from the bad news earnings-returns regression to that obtained from the good news

earnings-returns regression. However, this measure is considered inferior to the AT

measure and is less popular in conservatism studies (Ruch & Taylor, 2015).

In regards to the C_Score measure, Khan & Watts (2009) combine the theory of

conservatism in Watts (2003a) with the empirical model in Basu (1997) in order to

construct their measure of CC. Specifically, Khan & Watts (2009) show that the C_Score

measure is strongly correlated with market-to-book, firm size and leverage. They argue

that these variables implicitly proxy for the four driving factors of conservatism –

contracting, litigation, taxation and regulation – as explained in (Watts, 2003a, 2003b).

The calculation of the C_Score measure is a two-stage process. As shown below, the

first stage is based on equation (1) while interactively adding the three financial variables

(market-to-book, size and leverage) with the independent variables in (1).

Xit = β0 + β1 RDit + β2 RETit + β3 RD*RETit

+ β4 MTBit + β5 MTBit*RDit + β6 MTBit*RETit + β7 MTBit*RD*RETit

+ β8 SIZEit + β9 SIZEit*RDit + β10 SIZEit*RETit + β11 SIZEit*RD*RETit

+ β12 LEVit + β13 LEVit*RDit + β14 LEVit*RETit + β15 LEVit*RD*RETit + ɛit (2)

Where, for firm i in year t, MTB is the market-to-book ratio of equity, SIZE is the natural

logarithm of the market value of equity, and LEV is the ratio of total debt to the market

value of equity (see Appendix A for complete definitions).

158

In the second stage, the coefficient estimates from the regression equation (2) are used

to calculate the C_Score measure for each firm-year as shown below.

CSCOREit = β3 + β7* MTBit + β11*SIZEit + β15* LEVit (3)

It is crucial to mention that β3, β7, β11 and β15 are constant across firms but vary over time

because they are estimated from annual cross-sectional regressions. That is, the estimates

from each annual cross-sectional regression are multiplied by the corresponding firm-year

financial variable. For the purpose of the present paper, the important point to note from

equation (2) is that the C_Score measure is essentially a development of the AT measure,

which opens up the possibility that the bias implicit in the AT measure could also lead to

bias in the C_Score measure.

4.2.3. The Source of Bias in the AT Measure

Despite the fact that prior studies provide considerable evidence showing bias in the AT

measure (Dietrich et al., 2007; Givoly et al., 2007; Patatoukas & Thomas, 2011),

researchers keep relying on this measure for estimating CC and draw inferences based on

these estimations. We believe there are several reasons behind this reliance. First, until

recently, there was no alternative measure that could replace the AT measure (or its

variants). Second, several studies improved the original AT measure and tried to eliminate

the associated bias through adding relevant control variables or through changing the

estimation method (Ball, Kothari, & Nikolaev, 2013b; Collins, Hribar, & Tian, 2014; Khan

& Watts, 2009). Third, giving up on the AT measure will put a twenty-year old literature

on stake and question the conclusions drawn from this literature. Nonetheless, we believe

that the documented bias in the AT measure should be taken seriously in re-evaluating

existing conclusions. In this section, we discuss the bias in the AT measure as documented

in prior studies.

159

We start with Gigler & Hemmer (2001) who develop a theoretical model showing that

the AT coefficient might be significantly positive in the absence of CC. This is caused by

an omitted variable bias, where researchers fail to control for the firm’s voluntary

disclosure policy which jointly affects stock returns and reporting conservatism. Voluntary

disclosures in less conservative firms aim to pre-empt the market reaction around earnings

announcements, which asymmetrically affects stock returns among firms, depending on the

frequency of the firms’ (voluntary) disclosure policy. Givoly et al. (2007) show that the AT

measure suffer from an implicit bias due to the “aggregation effect”, which is mainly the

difference between how information is assumed to be reflected at once in the AT

regression model whereas in reality this information arrives gradually over time. This bias

is more prominent among big firms that receive news at a higher frequency than small

firms. Cano-Rodríguez & Núñez-Nickel (2015) extend the study by Givoly et al. (2007)

and show that the “aggregation effect” applies to proxies of good and bad news other than

raw stock returns.

Dietrich et al. (2007) address the bias in the AT coefficient from an econometric

perspective. They use a simulated dataset that should not exhibit CC; yet, the earnings-

returns regression still indicates CC due to test specification bias. They argue that there are

two reasons for this spurious result: sample-variance-ratio bias and sample truncation bias.

These biases arise from the fact that earnings cause returns and not vice versa, where the

returns variable is endogenous to the firm (i.e., determined by firm-related news other than

earnings news). Thus, according to Dietrich et al. (2007), reversing the returns-earnings

regression (Beaver, Lambert, & Ryan, 1987) and truncating the sample based on the

returns variable (Basu, 1997) will induce bias in the regression estimates.43

Ryan (2006)

questions the severity of the concerns raised by Dietrich et al. (2007). He argues that, given

the low R2 observed from the returns-earnings regression (i.e., weak causality), and given

43

At a more fundamental level, both sources of bias arise due to the fact that stock returns comprise non-

earnings information as well as earnings information. This causes test misspecification and renders the Basu

(1997) regression results non-interpretable (Givoly et al., 2007).

160

that a large literature documents that returns reflect information on a timelier basis than

earnings, then the biases introduced in Dietrich et al. (2007) are small in magnitude. Ball,

Kothari, & Nikolaev (2013a) discuss the econometrics of the AT measure and argue that

the sample-variance-ratio bias, introduced in Dietrich et al. (2007), is irrelevant because

the covariance between returns and earnings, conditional on returns, is equal for good and

bad news when CC is absent (i.e., when the AT coefficient equals zero). However, the

argument is disputed by Patatoukas & Thomas (2011) who show that the covariance

between abnormal returns and earnings differs significantly between the good and bad

news subsamples when CC is absent. Patatoukas & Thomas (2011) attribute this anomaly

to two empirical irregularities discussed below.

Patatoukas & Thomas (2011) reflect on the evidence provided by Dietrich et al. (2007)

and identify two scale-driven empirical irregularities in the AT measure: the loss effect and

the return variance effect. The authors argue that firms with a small stock price report

losses more frequently than firms with a high stock price. This causes firms with a small

stock price to frequently have highly negative values for the dependent variable in the

earnings-returns piecewise regression (i.e., the loss effect). At the same time, firms with a

small stock price have higher fluctuations in share price, which results in a higher variance

in stock returns (i.e., the return variance effect). According to Patatoukas & Thomas

(2011), due to the negative association between the loss effect and the return variance

effect with stock prices (i.e., both effects increase as stock prices decrease), scaling

earnings by lagged stock price causes an upward bias in the AT measure, where this bias is

more pronounced among firms with small stock prices.44

Given that small firms usually

have smaller stock prices than big firms, prior studies find that the AT measure decreases

with firm size (Khan & Watts, 2009; LaFond & Watts, 2008). These studies argue that, due

to the fact that small firms suffer higher levels of information asymmetry (Easley,

44

Patatoukas & Thomas (2011) find that the AT coefficient induces high significance for lagged earnings

with respect to current returns, which cannot be attributed to CC. They conclude that this spurious effect is

driven by the two scale-driven empirical irregularities discussed above.

161

Hvidkjaer, & O’Hara, 2002), such firms report more conservatively in order to mitigate the

consequences of asymmetric information. However, the evidence they report relies on the

validity of the AT measure, so the inferences that have been drawn from these studies may

be incorrect. It is possible that, rather than detecting differences in CC, they were actually

detecting differences in the bias in CC induced by the AT measure.

The upward bias in AT discussed in Patatoukas & Thomas (2011) motivated Ball et al.

(2013b) and Collins et al. (2014) to apply modifications to the AT measure, where these

modifications were meant to correct for the upward bias. Ball et al. (2013b) argue that the

bias documented in Patatoukas & Thomas (2011) emerges due to the expected component

of earnings and returns. Ball et al. (2013b) suggest using abnormal returns through

adjusting raw returns for the portfolio average return.45

As for earnings, Ball et al. (2013b)

offer three empirical approaches to remove the expected component of earnings and,

accordingly, mitigate the upward bias: (1) include firm characteristics in the Basu (1997)

regression model in order to control for the expected component of earnings, (2) use an

industry-year autoregressive model where the residuals are used as a proxy for the

expected component of earnings for each industry-year cross-section,46

and (3) use firm

fixed effects regressions instead of OLS in order to demean the time-invariant expected

earnings component. Alternatively, Collins et al. (2014) find that replacing the dependent

variable of the AT regression (i.e., deflated earnings) with an accrual-based dependent

variable would correct for the bias raised by Patatoukas & Thomas (2011) because the

spurious asymmetric timeliness in the AT measure is caused by the asymmetry in the

operating cash flow component of earnings.47

45

Ball et al. (2013b) measure expected returns using the average returns of 5×5 portfolios constructed each

year by sorting firms based on the opening market value of equity and then based on the opening book-to-

market ratio. 46

A similar evidence is provided in Pae (2007) who find that CC reflected in accruals is mainly due to the

unexpected component of accruals rather than the expected component. 47

Hsu, O’Hanlon, & Peasnell (2012) report evidence consistent with Patatoukas & Thomas (2011) showing

that the scale-effect bias exists in the cash flow and accrual component of earnings; however, they argue that

the scale-effect bias is heavily concentrated in the cash flow component and largely absent from the accrual

162

Several studies in the literature use the modified AT measures proposed by Ball et al.

(2013b) and Collins et al. (2014).48

However, Patatoukas & Thomas (2016) show that the

modified AT measures, proposed by Ball et al. (2013b) and Collins et al. (2014), are still

subject to substantial upward bias. Patatoukas & Thomas (2016) use a placebo test to show

that AT remains significantly positive even when the dependent variable is the reciprocal

of lagged stock price (i.e., the deflator of earnings per share). This shows that the AT

measure is substantially driven by the scale effect that was originally introduced in

Patatoukas & Thomas (2011). Patatoukas & Thomas (2016) conclude that the Basu (1997)

piecewise regression model yields a spurious asymmetric timeliness regardless of the

dependent variable used or the econometric method utilized.49

4.2.4. An Alternative Measure of Conditional Conservatism

The literature reviewed thus far suggests that the AT and related measures are severely

biased, but without providing an alternative measure that is unbiased and amenable to

application in the large samples used in the research contexts in which AT has been

applied. Dutta & Patatoukas (2017) contribute to the literature by proposing a novel

measure of CC that is orthogonal to the sources of bias in the AT measure. According to

Dutta & Patatoukas (2017), CC can be estimated by calculating the spread between the

variance of bad news accruals and the variance of good news accruals. As an elaborative

example, consider a high-tech firm that decides to write-down outdated inventories due to

a technological breakthrough in the market (i.e., bad news). This will definitely affect

component. In conclusion, they recommend excluding the cash flow component from the Basu (1997)

piecewise regression as a robustness check. 48

For example, Dhaliwal, Huang, Khurana, & Pereira (2014), Erkens, Subramanyam, & Zhang (2014) and

Ramalingegowda & Yu (2012) use firm fixed effects - the third empirical approach suggested by Ball et al.

(2013b). Jayaraman & Shivakumar (2013) use the AT measure and assume that there is no need to control for

the bias documented in Patatoukas & Thomas (2011) because Ball et al. (2013b) demonstrate that AT is a

well specified measure of CC. 49

In addition to Patatoukas & Thomas (2016), Cano-Rodríguez & Núñez-Nickel (2015) document that the

modified AT measure in Ball et al. (2013b) is biased due to the “aggregation effect” introduced by Givoly et

al. (2007). Cano-Rodríguez & Núñez-Nickel (2015) use separate proxies of good and bad news and show that

good and bad news timeliness coefficients are larger in magnitude for the negative-abnormal-returns sample

than for positive-abnormal-returns sample. This shows that the aggregation bias in the Basu (1997) model

also applies to Ball et al. (2013b) models, where these models underestimate good-news timeliness and

overestimate bad-news timeliness and, consequently, overestimate differential timeliness.

163

accruals and will increase the variance of bad news accruals relative to the variance of

good news accruals. Dutta & Patatoukas (2017) use the sign of unexpected returns as a

proxy for good/bad news and deflate accruals with the lagged stock price. Therefore, the

VR measure of CC is Variance (ACCit | RETit < 0) − Variance (ACCit | RETit≥ 0), where

ACC is deflated accruals and RET is unexpected returns. We use a modified version of the

original VR measure in order to fit our research setting. Specifically, we use the difference

in the conditional variances of earnings instead of accruals, which is also proposed by

Dutta & Patatoukas (2017) and yields very similar results.50

We use earnings instead of

accruals for two reasons: (1) using accruals creates a problem of missing data in the non-

US sample, and (2) using earnings in calculating the AT and the VR measures keeps a

level playing field. Furthermore, we use the ratio, rather than the spread, of the variance of

bad news earnings to the variance of good news earnings in order to be able to compare

different cross-sections (Givoly et al., 2007; Pope & Walker, 1999, Figure 1). In light of

the preceding points, the VR measure we use in our study is calculated as shown in

equation (4) below (where all variables are defined previously and in Appendix A).

VR = Variance (Xit | RETit < 0) / Variance (Xit | RETit ≥ 0) (4)

Theoretically, Dutta & Patatoukas (2017) claim that their proposed measure exists if,

and only if, accounting is conditionally conservative and it only increases by increasing the

degree of CC. Moreover, they claim that, unlike the AT measure, their proposed measure is

unaffected by the asymmetric distribution of returns and does not rely on the market

efficiency assumption where investors incorporate all information in a timely and efficient

manner.

50

Dutta & Patatoukas (2017) state the following: “While evidence of asymmetry extends to the distribution

of total earnings, we argue that focusing on asymmetry in the distribution of the accrual component of

earnings provides a cleaner path towards identifying the effect of CC in accounting data.” All of our

inferences for the US sample remain unchanged when using accruals instead of earnings.

164

The construct validity tests in Dutta & Patatoukas (2017) start by examining the

modified AT measures proposed by Ball et al. (2013b) and Collins et al. (2014), where

they find that these measures remain upwardly biased due to non-accounting factors.

Specifically, Dutta & Patatoukas (2017) show that the modified AT measures are sensitive

to three non-accounting factors: (i) expected returns (ii) asymmetry in the conditional

variances of positive and negative unexpected returns, and (iii) cash flow persistence. They

also show that the AT coefficient estimate becomes statistically and economically

insignificant after controlling for the variation in the aforementioned non-accounting

factors. On the other hand, the VR measure proves to be insensitive to these factors. Given

this evidence, we argue that the measure proposed by Dutta & Patatoukas (2017) is a

convenient measure of CC that we can use to reassess the validity of prior literature.

4.3. Hypothesis Development

4.3.1. The Bias in the AT Measure

Since the bias in the AT measure arises from two scale-driven empirical irregularities, we

start our analysis by comparing the behavior of the AT and the VR measures across the

decile ranks of the opening stock price, i.e., the deflator of the dependent variable in the

Basu (1997) AT model. Consistent with Patatoukas & Thomas (2011), we expect to find a

strong negative relation between the AT measure and the opening stock price. On the other

hand, the VR measure is insensitive to non-accounting factors by construction (Dutta &

Patatoukas, 2017); therefore, we do not predict any relation between the VR measure and

the opening stock price. In light of the preceding arguments, we formulate the hypothesis

below.

Hypothesis (1):

H1: Stock price is negatively related to the AT measure but not to the VR measure.

165

4.3.2. Assessing the Potential Bias in the C_Score Measure

Khan & Watts (2009) construct the C_Score measure by incorporating interactively MTB,

SIZE and LEV in the Basu (1997) AT model. Firms with low book value of equity,

compared to their market value of equity, have fewer items to write-down and, therefore,

CC is expected to decrease as the market-to-book ratio increases (i.e., when book equity

decreases). With respect to firm size, big firms enjoy a lower level of information

asymmetry than small firms because big firms are followed by a higher number of

analysts, covered more by the media and scrutinized more by the public and the

government (Easley et al., 2002). Accordingly, small firms are required to report more

conservatively than big firms in order to mitigate higher levels of information asymmetry

(LaFond & Watts, 2008). Finally, firms with higher financial leverage suffer from higher

agency conflicts between shareholders and bondholders over dividend policy. Therefore,

bondholders demand more conservative reporting of earnings because dividend payments

are directly linked to reported earnings (Ahmed et al., 2002). As a result, firms with higher

LEV are expected to report more conservatively.

Overall, Khan & Watts (2009) theorize and find that market-to-book and firm size are

negatively related to the C_Score measure whereas leverage is positively related to it.

However, the authors did not consider the possibility that the C_Score measure could be

affected by bias in the underlying AT measure. Thus, in order to assess whether the bias in

the AT measure also applies to the C_Score and the VR measures, we revisit the construct

of the C_Score measure using the VR measure instead of the AT measure. We test whether

the quasi-monotonic relation between the AT coefficient estimates and the decile ranks of

the constituents of the C_Score measure exists for the VR measure. If the variation in the

VR measure is only affected by the variation in CC, and not by the variation in non-

accounting factors, then we should not observe a direct relation between the VR measure

and the three financial variables (MTB, SIZE and LEV). Our hypotheses below predict

166

whether the VR measure has a similar relation to that of the AT measure with the

constituents of the C_Score measure.

Hypothesis (2)

H2: Market-to-book is negatively related to the AT measure but not to the VR measure.

Hypothesis (3)

H3: Firm size is negatively related to the AT measure but not to the VR measure.

Hypothesis (4)

H4: Leverage is positively related to the AT measure but not to the VR measure.

Hypothesis (5)

H5: The C_Score measure is positively related to the AT measure but not to the VR

measure.

4.3.3. The AT Measure in an Interrupted Time-series Research Design

Dietrich et al. (2007) show in their equations (1.7a) and (1.7b) how the AT coefficient

estimate is biased for good and bad news, respectively. Each equation has two

components: the CC component and the associated bias component. We endeavor to

disentangle both components. Knowing that the associated bias arises from non-accounting

(economic) factors (Patatoukas & Thomas, 2011), this bias is not expected to change when

the accounting practice changes. Accordingly, we argue that an exogenous change in

accounting policy is expected to affect the CC component in the AT coefficient estimate

but not the bias component. Therefore, the difference in the AT coefficient estimate

following an exogenous change in accounting policy, for the same sample, is more likely

to capture the difference in CC and to offset the bias. In order to test this argument, we first

replicate two papers that examine the change in CC following an exogenous change in

accounting policy that is not meant to affect the underlying economics of firms. We then

167

compare the results of our replications with the results generated by applying the VR

measure, as stated in the following hypothesis.

Hypothesis (6)

H6: Holding the economic characteristics of the sample constant, the AT and the VR

measures will change in the same direction following an exogenous change in accounting

policy.

4.3.4. The AT Measure in a Cross-sectional Research Design

Cross-sectional research designs involve comparing AT coefficient estimates across

different samples with different underlying economics. As a result, the cross-sectional

differences in the AT coefficient estimates are determined not only by differences in CC

but also by differences in the scale-driven economic bias. In this case, we cannot

disentangle the variation in the CC and the variation in the associated bias. That is, the

cross-sectional comparison of the AT coefficient estimates for different samples might be

driven by the difference in the bias magnitude in each sample, which depends on the

economic heterogeneity in samples. In order to test this argument, we replicate another two

influential papers that examine cross-sectional differences in CC and then re-examine the

replicated results using the VR measure. In addition, we test the robustness of the AT and

the VR measures using a placebo that should not exhibit CC (Patatoukas & Thomas, 2016).

Specifically, the placebo test examines whether using lagged earnings and current returns

indicates the presence of CC when estimated by AT and VR, where lagged earnings should

not reflect CC based on current returns. In light of the preceding arguments, we formulate

the following hypotheses.

168

Hypothesis (7)

H7a: Using the AT measure to model the cross-sectional variation in CC yields a different

inference than that using the VR measure.

H7b: The placebo test shows that the economic bias implicit in the AT measure does not

affect the VR measure.

4.4. Data & Descriptive Statistics

In this section we discuss variable definitions, sample construction and summary statistics.

Appendix A includes detailed definitions for the variables used in all the tests in five

panels. Panel A includes definitions for variables used in testing the unconditional

association between AT and VR, the scale effect in AT and VR, and the hypotheses

relating to the Khan & Watts (2009) replication. We define X as income before

extraordinary items divided by the lagged market value of equity. We use abnormal stock

returns RET at the end of the fiscal year in order to remove the effect of annual earnings

announcement on stock prices, where this effect takes place approximately three months

later (García Lara, García Osma, & Penalva, 2009).51

We define MTB and SIZE following

Khan & Watts (2009). We define LEV following Fama & French (2002) because the

definition used in Khan & Watts (2009) hinders the decile rank test of leverage.

Specifically, Khan & Watts (2009) define leverage as the ratio of the sum of long term

debt and short term debt to the market value of equity. When using this definition, around

15% of the observations have a leverage ratio of zero. Thus, 15% of the observations will

be sorted into the first decile and only 5% into the second decile (deciles 3-10 are not

affected). This makes testing CC across the decile ranks of leverage inaccurate.

Nevertheless, our results are qualitatively similar when using the Khan & Watts (2009)

definition of financial leverage. With respect to the measures of CC, the AT measure and

51

Our conclusions remain unchanged when using stock returns calculated three months after the closing date.

169

the C_Score measure (CSCORE) are created as described in section 4.2.2 and the VR

measure is created as described in section 4.2.4. Panels B to E in Appendix A define the

variables used in replicating the results of the four prior studies. We discuss these

definitions in sections 4.5.4.1, 4.5.4.2, 4.5.5.1 and 4.5.5.2.

In order to generalize our findings, we construct an international sample that comprises

22 countries with developed capital markets and sufficient data over the period 1990-2015.

Panel A of Table 1 reports the selected countries along with the number of observations for

each country in the full sample. The sample is constructed following prior papers (e.g.,

Ball et al., 2008; Gassen et al., 2006) as follows. First, we drop cross-listed firms by

keeping firms who are listed on stock exchanges in the same country as their headquarters

(Li, 2015). Second, we drop all financial firms (SIC code 6000-6999). Third, we drop

observations with negative book value of equity. Fourth, we drop the top and bottom

percentiles of X and RET and winsorize MTB, SIZE and LEV at the top and bottom 1%. We

run all analyses for the US sample and the full sample separately. The final US sample

consists of 7,004 firms and the final full sample consists of 22,254 firms. This is equivalent

to 70,033 firm-year observations for the US sample and 215,903 firm-year observations for

the full sample. For the US and Canada, we use accounting data from the Compustat

fundamental annual file and stock return data from the Compustat security file.52

For the

remaining countries, we use accounting data from the Compustat global fundamental

annual file and stock return data from the Compustat global security file.

Panels B and C of Table 1 report summary statistics for the variables used in testing

hypotheses H1-H5 for the US and the full samples, respectively. On average, both samples

have abnormal returns around zero, US firms have a higher MTB, and non-US firms have a

higher LEV. The summary statistics for the US and the full samples show high

52

In order to calculate annual stock returns for US and non-US firms following the same procedure, we use

the Compustat security file instead of CRSP to collect stock return data for US firms. Nevertheless, our

results are almost identical when using CRSP instead of the Compustat security file to calculate annual stock

returns for US firms.

170

comparability with prior studies. For example, the mean and standard deviation of

CSCORE for the US sample are 0.0946 and 0.1074, respectively, while the corresponding

statistics reported in Khan & Watts (2009) are 0.105 and 0.139. Moreover, the statistics on

X, RET and MTB for the full sample are similar to those reported in Gassen et al. (2006).

[Insert Table 1 Here]

4.5. Research Designs and Results

In this section we discuss the research designs used in testing all the hypotheses and

explain how the findings should be interpreted. We begin with establishing an

unconditional relation between the AT and the VR measures in section 4.5.1. Then, in

section 4.5.2, we explain how we test for a difference between two AT or two VR values.

Next, in section 4.5.3.1, we compare the scale effect in the AT and the VR measures (H1),

followed by the comparison of the behavior of both measures across the constituents of the

C_Score measure in section 4.5.3.2 (H2-H5). Finally, in sections 4.5.4 and 4.5.5, we

replicate the results of prior studies that use interrupted time-series and cross-sectional

research designs, respectively, and re-examine their evidence by applying the VR measure

of CC (H6, H7a and H7b). For consistency, we use abnormal returns for all tests and

replications, defined as raw returns minus the country-year returns average. Yet, our

inferences remain unchanged when using raw returns or other definitions of abnormal

returns.

4.5.1. The Unconditional Relation between AT and VR

Before testing our hypotheses, we examine the unconditional association between the AT

and the VR measures as follows. We first calculate the AT coefficient estimate for each

171

industry-year based on the Fama and French twelve-industry classification.53

Then we sort

the AT coefficient estimates into deciles and calculate the corresponding VR measure for

each decile. Finally, we plot the values of the VR measure across the deciles of the AT

measure for the US and the full samples as shown in Table 2. This graphical evidence

shows that, despite the fact that the AT coefficient is upwardly biased, nevertheless it

indicates the presence of CC when it exists. After demonstrating this unconditional

relation, we start adding conditions to the association between AT and VR to empirically

examine whether it holds or not, as discussed in section 4.5.3.

[Insert Table 2 Here]

4.5.2. Test Statistics for Comparing AT and VR Measures

We use the following approaches to test for a difference between two AT or two VR

values. With respect to AT, we use the Chi2 statistic to test the statistical significance of the

difference between two regression estimates. Regarding the VR measure, calculating the

variance ratio of bad news earnings to good news earnings is a simple mathematical

operation. However, testing the statistical significance of the difference between two VR

values requires some statistical programming because the VR measure is non-linear.54

For

example, in order to calculate the VR measure for the first decile and the tenth decile, we

fit a mixed linear regression model that estimates the variance of bad news and good news

earnings in the first and the tenth decile.55

Then, we calculate the variance ratios (for the

53

Using a more specific industry classification (such as SIC two-digit) will leave many industry-year groups

with a small number of observations, which will affect the accuracy of regression estimates. 54

All programming is done in Stata and the code is available on request. 55

The mixed linear model regresses the dependent variable X on the news dummy, the deciles dummy, and

their interaction. The news dummy takes the value 1 for bad news and zero for good news. The deciles

dummy takes the value 1 for observations in the tenth decile and zero for observations in the first decile of X.

This purpose of this regression is to partition the dependent variable X into 4 subsamples and then calculate

the VR measures for the first and the tenth deciles. The same procedure applies when testing the difference in

the VR measure between two time periods, but instead of having a dummy variable for the first and the tenth

deciles, we use a dummy variable for time periods (e.g., pre- and post-policy).

172

first and the tenth deciles) and test the statistical significance of their difference through

utilising a non-linear combination of estimators that uses the delta method (Casella &

Berger, 2002; Feiveson, 1999).

4.5.3. Examination of Conservatism Measures

As mentioned earlier, we compare the behavior AT and the VR measures across the

opening stock price and across the constituents of the C_Score measure in order to assess

whether the bias that drives AT also drives VR and C_Score. We report results based on

pooled cross-sectional estimations because the earnings-returns regression parameters are

nonstationary (García Lara et al., 2009, Footnote 16). Hence, using average coefficients

from annual cross-sectional regressions gives an equal weight to each year, which might

affect the precision of the parameters in each cross-section (Basu, 1999). Nonetheless,

using Fama & MacBeth (1973) annual cross-sectional estimations yields qualitatively

similar results to ours.

4.5.3.1. Comparing the Scale Effect in AT and VR – (H1)

We start the empirical analysis by testing hypothesis H1 that examines the behavior of AT

and VR across the opening stock price deciles, i.e., deciles of the deflator of the AT model.

Patatoukas & Thomas (2011) document that the bias that drives the AT measure is more

prominent among firms with small stock prices. As mentioned in section 4.2.3, this bias

arises due to the fact that firms with small stock prices are usually small firms that

encounter losses more frequently than large firms (i.e., the loss effect) and, at the same

time, such firms experience greater fluctuations in their stock prices (i.e., the return-

variance effect), which yields more extreme RET values. Thus, the joint impact of the loss

effect and the return-variance effect leads to inflating the AT measure for samples

dominated by firms with small stock prices. We find results consistent with Patatoukas &

Thomas (2011) as shown in Table 3, where the AT measure decreases across deciles of the

opening stock price (i.e., the deflator of the AT regression). This finding holds in both the

173

US and the full sample. The difference in the AT coefficient estimates between the tenth

decile and the first decile of the opening stock price for the US sample is −0.1263,

significant at the 1% level. Similarly, the equivalent difference in the AT coefficient

estimates for the full sample is −0.1124, significant at the 1% level. On the other hand, we

find contradictory evidence when using the VR measure. Specifically, the difference in the

VR values between the tenth decile and the first decile of the opening stock price is 0.5042

for the US sample, significant at the 1% level. Moreover, the full sample shows that the

equivalent difference in the VR values is 0.3954, significant at the 1% level. This

demonstrates that the correlations of AT and VR with the decile rank of the opening stock

price have different directions. Therefore, we reject the null hypothesis of H1 in favor of

its alternative.

[Insert Table 3 Here]

4.5.3.2. Comparing AT and VR across the Constituents of CSCORE – (H2-H5)

In order to test hypotheses H2-H5, we first sort all variables annually into deciles by MTB,

SIZE, LEV and CSCORE. The variable CSCORE is sorted annually into deciles based on

its closing values in order to be contemporaneous with AT and VR, whereas the other

variables (i.e., MTB, SIZE and LEV) are sorted annually into deciles based on their opening

values (Gassen et al., 2006). We then calculate the AT and the VR measures by decile for

each variable.

Table 4 reports results consistent with prior studies that document a negative relation

between AT and MTB (e.g., Roychowdhury & Watts, 2007). Specifically, the difference in

the AT coefficient estimates between the tenth decile and the first decile of the opening

MTB is −0.3521 for the US sample, significant at the 1% level. Likewise, the

corresponding difference in the AT coefficient estimates for the full sample is −0.4111,

significant at the 1% level. On the other hand, the VR measure shows a much weaker

174

negative difference in the VR values between the tenth and the first opening MTB deciles

for the US sample, where the difference is −0.09 with a p-value of 0.037. However, this

result seems to be economically insignificant because the VR values for the first and the

tenth deciles of the opening MTB are less than 1, indicating no presence of CC for the

extreme deciles of MTB. This weak finding of consistency between AT and VR disappears

when using the full sample. The difference in the VR values between the tenth decile and

the first decile of the opening MTB is statistically insignificant for the full sample,

indicating no relation between VR and MTB. The joint results from the US and the full

samples lead us to reject the null hypothesis of H2 in favor of its alternative. In other

words, using the VR measure to estimate CC shows no direct relation with unconditional

conservatism when proxied by MTB.

[Insert Table 4 Here]

Table 5 examines the behavior of AT and VR across deciles of SIZE. LaFond & Watts

(2008) report evidence consistent with the information asymmetry hypothesis of CC, where

smaller firms report more conservatively than larger firms in order to mitigate higher levels

of information asymmetry. We find results consistent with LaFond & Watts (2008) where

the degree of CC, estimated by the AT measure, decreases as the SIZE decile increases.

Specifically, the difference in the AT coefficient estimates between the tenth decile and the

first decile of the opening SIZE is −0.1366 for the US sample, significant at the 1% level.

Similarly, the equivalent difference in the AT coefficient estimates for the full sample is

−0.1422, significant at the 1% level. However, estimating CC using the VR measure shows

a rather weak positive trend in CC across deciles of SIZE. In contrast to the result for AT,

the difference in the VR values between the tenth decile and the first decile of the opening

SIZE for the US sample is 0.7645, significant at the 1% level. The corresponding

difference in the VR values for the full sample is 0.1793, also significant at the 1% level.

175

This shows that the correlations of AT and VR with the decile rank of firm size have

different signs, which leads us to reject the null hypothesis of H3 in favor of its alternative.

[Insert Table 5 Here]

Consistent with prior studies, we find LEV to have a positive relation with the AT

measure of CC. Ahmed et al. (2002) find that firms with higher leverage ratios have more

severe bondholder-shareholder agency problems and, thus, such firms need to report more

conservatively in order to mitigate this agency conflict. As shown in Table 6, we find

results consistent with Ahmed et al. (2002) where the degree of CC, estimated by the AT

measure, increases as the LEV decile increases. The difference in the AT coefficient

estimates between the tenth decile and the first decile of the opening LEV is 0.3091 for the

US sample, significant at the 1% level. Likewise, the corresponding difference in the AT

coefficient estimates for the full sample is 0.2633, significant at the 1% level. On the other

hand, estimating CC using the VR measure shows a noisy relation between CC and LEV.

The difference in the VR values between the tenth decile and the first decile of the opening

LEV is statistically insignificant for the US sample, indicating no relation between VR and

LEV. As for the full sample, the difference in the VR values between the tenth decile and

the first decile of the opening LEV is −0.2618, significant at the 1% level. Yet, we do not

draw any conclusions based on this significance because the trend of VR across LEV

deciles is highly noisy with no clear direction. This indicates that the correlations of AT

and VR with the decile rank of leverage have opposite signs and, hence, we reject the null

hypothesis of H4 in favor of its alternative.

[Insert Table 6 Here]

176

Finally, in order to examine whether the bias implicit in the AT measure also applies to

the C_Score measure, we test the behavior of the AT and the VR measures across deciles

of CSCORE. Our results in Table 7 are consistent with those of Khan & Watts (2009) who

find that the AT measure increases across CSCORE deciles. The difference in the AT

coefficient estimates between the tenth decile and the first decile of CSCORE is 0.2640 for

the US sample, significant at the 1% level. The equivalent difference in the AT coefficient

estimates for the full sample is 0.1800, significant at the 1% level as well. The positive

linear relation between the AT coefficient estimates and the decile ranks of CSCORE

suggests that the C_Score measure is likely to be affected by the same factors that drive the

AT measure. In contrast, the relation between VR and CSCORE shows no clear

association. Specifically, the difference in the VR values between the tenth decile and the

first decile of CSCORE is −0.0937 for the US sample, significant at the 5% level.

Nevertheless, this statistical significance is economically trivial given the flat trend of the

VR measure across CSCORE deciles. This is consistent with the results from the full

sample that show a highly noisy relation between the VR measure and CSCORE. Despite

the statistically significant positive difference in the VR values between the tenth and the

first CSCORE deciles for the full sample, we cannot draw any inference from this result.

For example, the VR values for the fourth and the fifth CSCORE deciles are the highest

VR values across all CSCORE deciles, indicating no direct relation between VR and

CSCORE. In conclusion, we find no support for a positive association between the VR and

the C_Score measures. Accordingly, we reject the null hypothesis of H5 in favor of its

alternative.

[Insert Table 7 Here]

177

4.5.4. Comparing AT and VR in Interrupted Time-series Settings – (H6)

We now reconsider prior studies that test the change in CC in an interrupted time-series

context. Specifically, we first replicate two influential studies on CC that use the AT

measure (or the C_Score measure) and then examine if the results of these studies still hold

when AT is substituted with VR. As mentioned in section 4.3.3, Dietrich et al. (2007) show

that the AT coefficient estimate is composed of two components, the CC component and

the associated bias component, where the bias component arises from economic factors

(Patatoukas & Thomas, 2011). We argue that, holding the economic characteristics of the

sample constant, the difference in the AT coefficient estimate, following an exogenous

change in accounting policy, will measure the change in CC.

4.5.4.1. André, Filip and Paugam (2015) – (H6)

André et al. (2015) examine the change in CC following the mandatory adoption of

International Financial Reporting Standards (IFRS) in the European Union. The mandatory

adoption of IFRS is an exogenous change in accounting policy that is meant to affect

various aspects of the financial reporting system (see the survey of De George, Li, &

Shivakumar, 2016). Using a sample of 16 European countries over the 2000-2010 period,

André et al. (2015) find a significant reduction in the degree of CC following IFRS

adoption. They use a modified version of the C_Score measure (CSCORE_A) in order to

estimate CC.

André et al. (2015) use Thomson Reuters for accounting and return data and

DataStream for firm-level beta coefficients and stock price volatility. We replicate their

main findings using Compustat Global and we calculate firm-level beta coefficients and

stock price volatility as described in the DataStream manual.56

We generally adopt to the

data management procedure described in André et al. (2015) when constructing the sample

56

André et al. (2015) retrieve firms’ beta coefficients from DataStream and use this variable as a proxy for

the cost of capital. We follow the DataStream manual and estimate firms’ beta coefficients over the last 36

months with a minimum of 23 consecutive monthly returns. We also calculate the stock price volatility,

which is used in estimating unconditional conservatism, as the annualized variance of daily stock returns.

178

used for replication. We download all accounting data from the Compustat global

fundamental annual file and stock return data from the Compustat global security file. We

first drop cross-listed firms and financial institutions. Next, we delete observations with

negative book value of equity. Then, we keep only mandatory adopters and delete firms

that did not adopt IFRS in 2005.57

Finally, we keep firms that have at least one observation

before and one observation after IFRS adoption. This leaves us with 5,520 (7,211) firm-

year observations in the pre-IFRS (post-IFRS) period. We winsorize all continuous

variables at the 1% level.

With respect to modelling the change in CC following IFRS adoption, André et al.

(2015) regress CSCORE_A on IFRS and a set of firm characteristics, where they expect a

significantly negative coefficient on IFRS. The regression equation below is equivalent to

equation (6) in André et al. (2015).

CSCORE_Ait = α0 + α1IFRS + α2SIZEit + α3MTBit + α4LEV_Ait + α5BETAit

+ α6UCCit + ɛit (5)

Where, for firm i in year t, CSCORE_A is their modified C_Score measure, IFRS is a

dummy variable that takes the value 1 if the year is 2005 or later and 0 otherwise, SIZE is

firm size, MTB is the market-to-book ratio, LEV_A is the leverage ratio, BETA is a proxy

for cost of equity and UCC is a proxy for unconditional conservatism. All variables are

described in detail in Appendix A.

Panel A of Table 8 reports summary statistics for the variables used in replicating the

main findings in André et al. (2015). The reported statistics are roughly similar to those

reported in Panel C of Table 1 in André et al. (2015).58

For example, the mean values for

57

We follow the accounting standards classification in Daske, Hail, Leuz, & Verdi (2013) in order to identify

firms who adopted IFRS in 2005. 58

Obtaining differences in summary statistics and regression results is inevitable as we use a different

database. Yet we reach the same conclusion from our replication.

179

MTB and BETA are 2.3350 and 0.9967, respectively, while the corresponding statistics

reported in André et al. (2015) are 2.263 and 0.885. Panel B of Table 8 reports regression

results that replicate column (1) of Table 2 in André et al. (2015). The negative and

significant coefficient on IFRS indicates a significant reduction in the degree of CC when

estimated using CSCORE_A. Specifically, the coefficient estimate on IFRS is −0.0256

significant at the 1% level. This finding is supported using the VR measure as shown in

Panel C. The VR measure decreases from 1.25 in the pre-IFRS period to 0.91 in the post-

IFRS period. The reduction in the VR measure is statistically significant at the 1% level.

These results indicate that the direction of the change in CC following the IFRS mandate is

identical when using the AT and the VR measures. Therefore, we reject the null hypothesis

of H6 in favor of its alternative.

[Insert Table 8 Here]

4.5.4.2. Lobo & Zhou (2006) – (H6)

Lobo & Zhou (2006) examine the change in the level of CC following the Sarbanes-Oxley

(SOX) Act in 2002 in the US. The main purpose of SOX is to protect investors by

improving the accuracy and reliability of corporate disclosures and to restore shareholders’

and lenders’ confidence in the reliability of corporate financial reporting among US firms

(see the survey of Coates & Srinivasan, 2014). Using a short time period, Lobo & Zhou

(2006) find that the passage of SOX leads to an increase in the degree of CC due to the

high litigation risk imposed on firms’ executives. The authors use the basic version of the

Basu (1997) AT model in order to model the change in CC.

Lobo & Zhou (2006) use the Compustat fundamentals annual file for accounting data

and CRSP for stock return data. We follow their data management procedure using the

same databases to retrieve accounting and return data between 2000 and 2004. We first

180

drop firms with stock prices less than $1 and observations with negative book value of

equity. We then require an equal number of observations per firm pre- and post-SOX.

Finally, we delete the upper and bottom percentiles of earnings and returns distributions.

The final sample consists of 5,622 (5,622) firm-year observations in the pre-SOX (post-

SOX) period.

The regression model utilized in Lobo & Zhou (2006) is very straight forward. The

authors add to the Basu (1997) AT model a dummy variable that takes the value 1 for the

post-SOX period, and 0 otherwise. The regression equation below is equivalent to equation

(6b) in Lobo & Zhou (2006).

Xit = δ0 + δ1RDit + δ2RETit + δ3RDit*RETit + δ4SOX + δ5SOX*RDit + δ6SOX*RETit

+ δ7SOX*RDit*RETit + ɛit (6)

Where SOX is a dummy variable that takes the value 1 if the firm’s fiscal year ends in

August 2002 or after, and 0 otherwise. All other variables are defined in section 4.2.2 and

in Appendix A.

Panel A of Table 9 reports summary statistics for the main variables used in replicating

Table 4 in Lobo & Zhou (2006). The mean values of X and RET are close to 0.01, and RET

has a higher standard deviation than X. Panel B of Table 9 reports the replication results of

model (6b) in Table 4 in Lobo & Zhou (2006). The coefficient on the interaction term

SOX*RDit*RETit is 0.0436, significant at the 1% level, which indicates a positive change in

the AT coefficient estimate.59

This suggests that the degree of CC increases after the

passage of the SOX act, consistent with the finding of Lobo & Zhou (2006). Finally, Panel

C of Table 9 reports the VR values pre- and post-SOX, where VR increases from 1.16 in

59

The magnitude of the coefficient on the interaction term is smaller than that in Lobo & Zhou (2006)

because we use abnormal returns, whereas Lobo & Zhou (2006) use raw returns. Yet, we obtain a very close

coefficient on the interaction term when using raw returns.

181

the pre-SOX period to 1.34 in the post-SOX period. This statistically significant increase

suggests that the inference drawn from the change in the AT measure is similar to the

inference drawn from the change in the VR measure in an interrupted time-series research

design. In light of these results, we confirm the rejection of the null hypothesis of H6 in

favor of its alternative.

[Insert Table 9 Here]

4.5.5. Comparing AT and VR in Cross-sectional Settings – (H7a & H7b)

In this subsection, we replicate the results of two studies that use the AT measure to model

the cross-sectional variation in CC among two samples and then look to see if the results

change materially when we substitute AT with VR. As discussed in section 4.3.4, a

potential research design issue in testing for cross-sectional differences in the AT measure

is that the observed variation in AT could be driven by the economic bias rather than

genuine differences in accounting conservatism. If this is the case, then using VR instead

of AT could lead to materially different inferences.

4.5.5.1. Ball, Sadka and Robin (2008) – (H7a)

In a highly influential paper, Ball et al. (2008) study whether debt markets or equity

markets constitute the primary source of demand for timely financial reporting. Given that

timely financial reporting is costly, and the supply of this activity is dependent on demand,

the authors argue that debt markets have a higher demand for timely financial reporting

than equity markets. Specifically, debt contracts are covenanted by financial ratios where

the violation of these covenants gives the right to debtholders to veto managerial financial

decisions, such as paying dividends or raising more debt. On the other hand, equity

investors are less concerned about timely recognition per se as they usually invest in

portfolios. Moreover, equity investors are more concerned about managerial disclosure

182

related to future outcomes, unlike debt holders who mainly monitor current financial

performance. In sum, Ball et al. (2008) show that debt markets form the main source of

demand for timely accounting recognition.

Ball et al. (2008) examine the association between the importance of debt and equity

markets with metrics of timely accounting recognition (such as timely loss and gain

recognition, conditional and unconditional conservatism, and overall timeliness). We re-

examine their test of the association between the importance of debt and equity markets

with CC. The authors aggregate data in 22 countries over the 1992-2003 period and

estimate the AT coefficient for each country. Then they run a regression with 22

observations of the AT coefficient estimate on a proxy for the importance of debt markets,

a proxy for the importance of equity markets, and a set of country characteristics. They

find a significantly positive coefficient on the proxy for the importance of debt markets and

significantly negative coefficient on the proxy for the importance of equity markets,

indicating a positive (negative) demand of CC by debt (equity) markets.

In order to replicate their results, we use accounting data from the Compustat global

fundamental annual file and stock return data from the Compustat global security file for

the selected 22 countries.60

We delete cross-listed firms, financial and utility firms, and the

upper and bottom 1% of the deflated earnings and returns distribution. The final sample

comprises 96,379 firm-year observations. Then, we run the Basu (1997) piecewise

regression of deflated earnings on abnormal returns for each country in order to estimate its

AT coefficient.

Panel A of Table 10 reports summary statistics for X and RET used in the Basu (1997)

AT regressions for the full sample. Panel B of Table 10 reports the extracted estimates

from the country-level Basu (1997) regressions. The variables B0, B1, B2, and B3 are the

Basu (1997) regression estimates for each country, where B0 is the coefficient on the

intercept, B1 is the coefficient on the returns dummy variable, B2 is the coefficient on the

60

Ball et al. (2008) use Global Vantage database, which is succeeded by Compustat Global.

183

returns variable, and B3 is the coefficient on the bad news returns (i.e., the AT coefficient).

In addition, Panel B reports other country characteristics identical to those in Ball et al.

(2008), where these characteristics were initially introduced in La Porta, Lopez-De-

Silanes, Shleifer, & Vishny (1997, 1998). All variables are listed below and fully defined

in Appendix A.

[Insert Table 10 Here]

The cross-sectional model used in testing the association between debt and equity

markets with CC is stated below.

B3i = λ0 + λ1DEBTi + λ2EQUITYi + λ3ENGLISHi + λ4FRENCHi + λ5SCANDi

+ λ6LAWi + λ7CORRUPTi + λ8CREDITi + λ9BTMi + ɛi (7)

Where, for each country i, B3 is the AT coefficient estimate, DEBT is a proxy for the debt

market importance, EQUITY is a proxy for the equity market importance, ENGLISH,

FRENCH and SCAND are dummy variables for legal origins61

, LAW is a proxy for the rule

of law, CORRUPT is an index of corruption, CREDIT is a proxy for creditors’ rights, and

BTM is the book-to-market ratio.

Table 11 reports the replication results of Table 5 in Ball et al. (2008), where CC is

estimated using the AT measure (B3). The main result we are interested in is the effect of

the debt market importance proxy, DEBT, on the AT coefficient estimate B3. In all the

columns of Table 11, the coefficient on DEBT is significantly positive, indicating a

positive association between the importance of debt markets and CC. On the other hand,

the proxy for the importance of equity markets EQUITY shows a (significantly) negative

61

The GERMAN dummy variable (that takes 1 for countries with German legal origins and 0 otherwise) goes

to the constant to avoid the dummy variable trap.

184

association with CC. These results replicate the findings reported in Table 5 in Ball et al.

(2008).

[Insert Table 11 Here]

We now consider what happens when we use VR instead of AT in the Ball et al. (2008)

research design. As reported in Table 12, substituting AT with VR renders the coefficient

on DEBT insignificant in all regressions. In addition, the sign of the coefficient on EQUITY

becomes insignificantly positive in all columns of Table 12 apart from the first column

which shows a negatively insignificant coefficient. These results indicate that neither debt

markets nor equity markets determine the supply of timely financial reporting. More

importantly, our re-examination test suggests that using AT and VR to estimate CC in a

cross-sectional setting yields very different inferences. Therefore, we reject the null

hypothesis of H7a in favor of its alternative.

[Insert Table 12 Here]

4.5.5.2. Gassen, Fulbier and Sellhorn (2006) – (H7a & H7b)

Using an international sample comprising 23 countries between 1990 and 2003, Gassen et

al. (2006) find that common-law countries exhibit a higher degree of CC than code-law

countries. In addition, they show that CC decreases with the degree of unconditional

conservatism when proxied by MTB. We first replicate their results and then use a placebo

test, employed by Patatoukas & Thomas (2016), to examine whether the AT measure leads

to spurious inferences about the cross-sectional variation in CC. Finally, we use the same

placebo test to assess the robustness of the VR measure in modelling the cross-sectional

variation in CC. This placebo is based on using lagged earnings instead of current earnings

185

as a dependent variable, where the regression of lagged earnings on current returns should

not exhibit conditionally conservative reporting.

Gassen et al. (2006) use accounting data from WorldScope for their non-US sample and

Compustat for their US sample. They use return data from DataStream for their non-US

sample and CRSP for their US sample. To construct the replication sample, we first

download all accounting data for the 23 countries from the Compustat global fundamental

annual file and stock return data from the Compustat global security file. Then, we delete

cross-listed firms and require each firm to have five years of consecutive earnings and

returns. Finally, we winsorize all continuous variables at the upper and bottom 1%. The

final sample consists of 84,436 firm-year in the 23 selected countries spanning the period

1990-2003.

The regression models used in testing the variation of CC across legal regimes (i.e.,

common-law and code-law) and across the decile ranks of unconditional conservatism

(MTB) are stated respectively below.62

Xit = η0 + η1RDit + η2RETit + η3RDit*RETit + η4COMMON + η5COMMON*RDit

+ η6COMMON*RETit + η7COMMON*RDit*RETit + ɛit (8)

Xit = θ0 + θ1RDit + θ2RETit + θ3RDit*RETit + θ4RMTB + θ5RMTB*RDit + θ6RMTB*RETit

+ θ7RMTB*RDit*RETit + ɛit (9)

Where COMMON is a dummy variable that takes 1 for common-law countries and 0

otherwise, and RMTB is the annual decile rank of MTB. The rest of the variables are

defined in section 4.2.2 and in Appendix A.

62

The authors estimate CC using a trigonometric version of the Basu (1997) AT measure, which yields

qualitatively similar results to the basic AT measure we employ.

186

Panel A of Table 13 reports summary statistics for the variables used in equations (8)

and (9). Despite the fact that we use a different database to replicate the results in Gassen

et al. (2006), our summary statistics are close to those reported in the original paper.

Notably, common-law observations constitute two-thirds of the sample and X has a mean

value of 0.0202. Panel B of Table 13 reports two sets of regressions, where the first set

refers to the replication of the original test and the other set refers to the placebo test. In the

first three columns (i.e., the first set), we replicate the results of Table 2 in Gassen et al.

(2006). In the last three columns we report results from the placebo test, where we use

deflated lagged earnings LAGX as the dependent variable instead of X (Patatoukas &

Thomas, 2016).

The results in the first set of regressions confirm the findings of Gassen et al. (2006,

Table 2), where the coefficient on the interaction term RD*RET (i.e., the AT coefficient

estimate) is significantly positive for code-law and common-law samples. In addition, the

AT coefficient estimate for the common-law sample is significantly higher than that for the

code-law sample. These results are roughly consistent with the results from the VR

measure, as shown in the original test section of Panel C. Specifically, the AT values for

the common-law and code-law samples are 0.1352 and 0.2172, respectively, whereas the

corresponding VR values are 1.09 and 1.21, respectively. This weak consistency could be

due the fact that the bias component in the AT coefficient is similar between the common-

law and code-law samples. Nevertheless, the proportional difference in CC between both

samples is much higher when using AT compared to that when using VR.

With respect to the placebo test, the last three columns of Panel B shows significant

estimates for the AT coefficient for the common-law and code-law samples when using

LAGX as the dependent variable. This indicates that the AT measure exhibits the presence

of CC when it is absent. On the other hand, the corresponding VR values for the common-

law and the code-law samples are significantly lower than 1, indicating that the VR

measure exhibits no presence of CC when using the placebo. The results from the placebo

187

test suggest that the economic factors that cause bias in the AT measure do not affect the

VR measure. Accordingly, we reject the null hypothesis of H7b in favor of its alternative.

[Insert Table 13 Here]

In another analysis, Gassen et al. (2006) use the decile ranks of the market-to-book ratio

(RMTB) as a proxy for unconditional conservatism in order to test the association between

conditional and unconditional conservatism. Panel A of Table 14 reports three regressions

that show a negative association between unconditional conservatism and CC (estimated

by AT). The coefficient on RMTB, which is the proxy for the decile rank of unconditional

conservatism, is significantly negative for the code-law sample, the common-law sample,

and the full sample. These negative coefficients are consistent with the results reported in

Panel B, where the AT coefficient estimates decrease monotonically across the deciles of

MTB using the full sample. Specifically, the difference in the AT coefficient estimates

between the tenth and the first deciles of MTB is −0.308 with a Chi2 statistic of 144.93. On

the other hand, this is not the case with VR as the corresponding difference in the VR

values is −0.09 with a Chi2 statistic of 3.94, suggesting a rather weak relation with MTB.

Despite the “knife edge” significance of the negative difference in the VR values between

the tenth and the first MTB deciles, yet we cannot infer that CC is decreasing across the

decile ranks of unconditional conservatism because the VR value for the tenth decile of

MTB is below 1 (i.e., no presence for CC). In light of the inconsistency in the inferences

drawn from using AT and VR to model cross-sectional variation in CC across the decile

ranks of MTB, we confirm the rejection of the null hypothesis of H7a in favor of its

alternative.

[Insert Table 14 Here]

188

4.6. Conclusion

The vast majority of conclusions about the role of accounting conservatism in capital

markets were drawn using the AT measure of CC. Yet, prior studies show that the AT

measure is upwardly biased. Recently, Dutta & Patatoukas (2017) proposed the VR

measure for estimating CC and showed that VR is not driven by the bias in AT. The

present study is designed to assess the extent to which prior studies may need to be

revisited in the light of bias in the AT and the C_Score measures, using the VR as an

alternative, arguably unbiased, measure.

Our analysis compares the performance of the AT and the VR measures of CC in

different research settings. We first find that both measures are associated unconditionally.

We then confirm that the AT measure is biased due to its strong association with non-

accounting (economic) factors. Moreover, our results suggest that the variation in the

C_Score measure is attributed to the variation in the AT bias rather than to the variation in

CC. However, we find that this bias does not apply to the VR measure of CC. Furthermore,

we find that using the AT and the VR measures yield consistent inferences in research

designs that model the change in CC following an exogenous change in accounting policy.

On the other hand, our findings suggest that using the AT measure to model the cross-

sectional variation in CC will probably lead to invalid conclusions due to different

economic characteristics between samples (i.e., different magnitude of bias between

samples).

Returning to the question posed at the beginning of this study, our analysis reveals a

high probability that a large number of cross-sectional studies on the determinants and

effects of CC in capital markets, that rely on the AT or the C_Score measures, need to be

reassessed. Moreover, whilst we do not claim that the VR is a bias-free measure, we show

that factors that drive the bias in the AT measure do not seem to drive the VR measure.

189

References:

Ahmed, A., Billings, B., Morton, R., & Stanford-Harris, M. (2002). The role of accounting

conservatism in mitigating bondholder-shareholder conflicts over dividend policy and

in reducing debt costs. The Accounting Review, 77(4), 867–890.

André, P., Filip, A., & Paugam, L. (2015). The effect of mandatory IFRS adoption on

conditional conservatism in Europe. Journal of Business Finance & Accounting,

42((3) & (4)), 482–514.

Ball, R. (2016). Why we do international accounting research. Journal of International

Accounting Research, 15(2), 1–6.

Ball, R., Kothari, S. P., & Nikolaev, V. (2013a). Econometrics of the Basu asymmetric

timeliness coefficient and accounting conservatism. Journal of Accounting Research,

51(5), 1071–1097.

Ball, R., Kothari, S. P., & Nikolaev, V. (2013b). On estimating conditional conservatism.

The Accounting Review, 88(3), 755–787.

Ball, R., Robin, A., & Sadka, G. (2008). Is financial reporting shaped by equity markets?

An international study of timeliness and conservatism. Review of Accounting Studiesi,

13, 168–205.

Ball, R., & Shivakumar, L. (2005). Earnings quality in UK private firms: Comparative loss

recognition timeliness. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 39(1), 83–128.

Basu, S. (1997). The conservatism principle and the asymmetric timeliness of earnings.

Journal of Accounting and Economics, 24(1), 3–37.

Basu, S. (1999). Discussion of International differences in the timeliness, conservatism,

and classification of earnings. Journal of Accounting Research, 37(Supplement), 89–

99.

Beaver, W., Lambert, R., & Ryan, S. (1987). The information content of security prices: A

second look. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 9(2), 139–157.

Beaver, W., & Ryan, S. (2005). Conditional and Unconditional Conservatism:Concepts

and Modeling. Review of Accounting Studies, 10(2–3), 269–309.

Cano-Rodríguez, M., & Núñez-Nickel, M. (2015). Aggregation bias in estimates of

conditional conservatism: Theory and evidence. Journal of Business Finance &

Accounting, 42((1) & (2)), 51–78.

Casella, G., & Berger, R. (2002). Statistical Inference (2nd ed.). Duxbury.

Coates, J., & Srinivasan, S. (2014). SOX after Ten Years: A Multidisciplinary Review.

Accounting Horizons, 28(3), 627–671.

Collins, D., Hribar, P., & Tian, X. (2014). Cash flow asymmetry: Causes and implications

for conditional conservatism research. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 58(2),

173–200.

Cooper, S. (2015). A tale of “prudence.” Retrieved from http://www.ifrs.org/Investor-

resources/Investor-perspectives-2/Documents/Prudence_Investor-

Perspective_Conceptual-FW.PDF

Daske, H., Hail, L., Leuz, C., & Verdi, R. (2013). Adopting a label: Heterogeneity in the

economic consequences around IAS/IFRS adoptions. Journal of Accounting

Research, 51(3), 495–547.

De George, E., Li, X., & Shivakumar, L. (2016). A review of the IFRS adoption literature.

Review of Accounting Studies, 21(3), 898–1004.

Dhaliwal, D., Huang, S., Khurana, I., & Pereira, R. (2014). Product market competition

and conditional conservatism. Review of Accounting Studies, 19(4), 1309–1345.

Dietrich, D., Muller, K., & Riedl, E. (2007). Asymmetric timeliness tests of accounting

conservatism. Review of Accounting Studies, 12(1), 95–124.

Dutta, S., & Patatoukas, P. (2017). Identifying conditional conservatism in financial

accounting data: theory and evidence. The Accounting Review, (Forthcoming).

Easley, D., Hvidkjaer, S., & O’Hara, M. (2002). Is Information Risk a Determinant of

Asset Returns? The Journal of Finance, 57(5), 2185–2221.

190

Erkens, D., Subramanyam, K. R., & Zhang, J. (2014). Affiliated Banker on Board and

Conservative Accounting. The Accounting Review, 89(5), 1703–1728.

Fama, E., & French, K. (2002). Testing Tradeoff and Pecking Order Predictions About

Dividends and Debt. The Review of Financial Studies, 15(1), 1–33.

Fama, E., & MacBeth, J. (1973). Risk, return, and equilibrium: Empirical tests. Journal of

Political Economy, 81(3), 607–636.

Feiveson, A. (1999). FAQ: What is the delta method and how is it used to estimate the

standard error of a transformed parameter? Retrieved from

http://www.stata.com/support/faqs/stat/deltam.html

Feltham, G., & Ohlson, J. (1995). Valuation and clean surplus accounting for operating

and financial activities. Contemporary Accounting Research, 11(2), 689–731.

García Lara, J. M., García Osma, B., & Penalva, F. (2009). Accounting conservatism and

corporate governance. Review of Accounting Studies, 14, 161–201.

García Lara, J. M., García Osma, B., & Penalva, F. (2011). Conditional conservatism and

cost of capital. Review of Accounting Studies, 16(2), 247–271.

Gassen, J., Fulbier, R. U., & Sellhorn, T. (2006). International differences in conditional

conservatism – the role of unconditional conservatism and income smoothing.

European Accounting Review, 15(4), 527–564.

Gigler, F., & Hemmer, T. (2001). Conservatism, optimal disclosure policy, and the

timeliness of financial reports. The Accounting Review, 76(4), 471–493.

Givoly, D., & Hayn, C. (2000). The changing time-series properties of earnings, cash flows

and accruals: Has financial reporting become more conservative? Journal of

Accounting and Economics, 29(3), 287–320.

Givoly, D., Hayn, C. K., & Natarajan, A. (2007). Measuring Reporting Conservatism. The

Accounting Review, 82(1), 65–106.

Hsu, A., O’Hanlon, J., & Peasnell, K. (2012). The Basu measure as an indicator of

conditional conservatism: Evidence from UK earnings components. European

Accounting Review, 21(1), 87–113.

Jayaraman, S., & Shivakumar, L. (2013). Agency-based demand for conservatism:

evidence from state adoption of antitakeover laws. Review of Accounting Studies,

18(1), 95–134.

Khan, M., & Watts, R. (2009). Estimation and empirical properties of a firm-year measure

of accounting conservatism. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 48(2–3), 132–

150.

La Porta, R., Lopez-De-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. (1997). Legal Determinants

of External Financing. The Journal of Finance, LII(3).

La Porta, R., Lopez-De-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. (1998). Law and Finance.

Journal of Political Economy, 106(6), 1113–1155.

LaFond, R., & Watts, R. (2008). The information role of conservatism. The Accounting

Review, 83(2), 447–478.

Li, X. (2015). Accounting conservatism and the cost of capital: An international study.

Journal of Business Finance & Accounting, 42((5) & (6)), 555–582.

Lobo, G., & Zhou, J. (2006). Did Conservatism in Financial Reporting Increase after the

Sarbanes-Oxley Act and CEO/CFO Certification of Financial Statements? Accounting

Horizons, 20(1), 57–73.

Mora, A., & Walker, M. (2015). The implications of research on accounting conservatism

for accounting standard setting. Accounting and Business Research, 45(5), 620–650.

Pae, J. (2007). Unexpected Accruals and Conditional Accounting Conservatism. Journal of

Business Finance & Accounting, 34(5–6), 681–704.

Pae, J., Thornton, D., & Welker, M. (2005). The Link between Earnings Conservatism and

the Price-to-Book Ratio. Contemporary Accounting Research, 22(3), 693–717.

Patatoukas, P., & Thomas, J. (2011). More Evidence of Bias in the Differential Timeliness

Measure of Conditional Conservatism. The Accounting Review, 86(5), 1765–1793.

191

Patatoukas, P., & Thomas, J. (2016). Placebo tests of conditional conservatism. The

Accounting Review, 91(2), 625–648.

Penman, S., & Zhang, X.-J. (2002). Accounting conservatism, the quality of earnings, and

stock returns. The Accounting Review, 77(2), 237–264.

Pope, P., & Walker, M. (1999). International differences in the timeliness, conservatism,

and classification of earnings. Journal of Accounting Research, 37, 53–87.

Ramalingegowda, S., & Yu, Y. (2012). Institutional ownership and conservatism. Journal

of Accounting and Economics, 53(1), 98–114.

Roychowdhury, S., & Watts, R. (2007). Asymmetric timeliness of earnings, market-to-

book and conservatism in financial reporting. Journal of Accounting and Economics,

44(1), 2–31.

Ruch, G., & Taylor, G. (2015). Accounting conservatism: A review of the literature.

Journal of Accounting Literature, 34, 17–38.

Ryan, S. (2006). Identifying Conditional Conservatism. European Accounting Review,

15(4), 511–525.

Sterling, R. (1976). Conservatism: The fundamental principle of valuation in traditional

accounting. ABACUS, 3(2), 109–122.

Wang, R. Z., Hógartaigh, C. Ó., & Zijl, T. V. (2009). Measures of accounting

conservatism: A construct validity perspective. Journal of Accounting Literature, 28,

165–203.

Watts, R. (2003a). Conservatism in accounting, Part I: explanations and implications.

Accounting Horizons, 7(3), 207–221.

Watts, R. (2003b). Conservatism in accounting, Part II: evidence and research

opportunities. Accounting Horizons, 7(4), 287–301.

192

Appendix A: Variable Definitions (sorted alphabetically by section)

Variable Definition

Panel A: Examination of Conservatism Measures

CSCORE Measure of conditional conservatism following Khan and Watts (2009). It is

calculated as shown in equations (2) and (3) in section 4.2.2.

LEV Ratio of total liabilities to the sum of market value of equity and total

liabilities.

MTB Ratio of market value of equity to book value of equity.

RD Dummy variable that takes the value 1 if RET is negative, and 0 otherwise.

RET Abnormal stock return calculated at the end of the fiscal year, compounded

monthly, and adjusted for the country-year average of returns.

SIZE Firm size calculated as the natural logarithm of market value of equity.

X Income before extraordinary items deflated by lagged market value of equity.

Panel B: André, Filip and Paugam (2015)

BETA

Firm’s Beta, calculated over the last 36 months with a minimum of 23

consecutive monthly returns, and estimated from the regressions of monthly

stock returns on monthly market returns.

CSCORE_A Modified version of CSCORE, calculated following Andre et al. (2015). In

addition to MTB, SIZE and LEV, the measure incorporates BETA and UCC.

IFRS Dummy variable that takes the value 1 if the year is 2005 or later, and 0

otherwise.

LEV_A Ratio of the sum of long-term and short-term debt to market value of equity.

MTB Ratio of market value of equity to book value of equity.

RET Abnormal stock return calculated at the end of the fiscal year, compounded

monthly, and adjusted for the country-year average of returns.

SIZE Firm size calculated as the natural logarithm of market value of equity.

UCC

Measure of unconditional conservatism calculated following Andre et al.

(2015, Footnote 12). It is estimated using the residual of annual cross-

sectional regressions of MTB on raw returns, intangibles assets (scaled by

total assets), property plant and equipment (scaled by total assets), capital

expenditures (scaled by total assets), percentage change in sales, return on

equity, price volatility, leverage ratio and firm size.

Panel C: Lobo & Zhou (2006)

RD Dummy variable that takes the value 1 if RET is negative, and 0 otherwise.

RET Abnormal stock return calculated at the end of the fiscal year, compounded

monthly, and adjusted for the country-year average of returns.

SOX Dummy variable that takes the value 1 if the firm fiscal year ends in August

2002 or later, and 0 otherwise.

X Income before extraordinary items deflated by lagged market value of equity.

Panel D: Ball, Sadka and Robin (2008)

B0 Constant term in the Basu (1997) piecewise linear regression. It is the

coefficient on the intercept (β0) in equation (1).

B1

Coefficient on the return dummy variable in the Basu (1997) piecewise linear

regression. It is the coefficient on the return dummy variable (β1) in equation

(1).

B2

Coefficient on the return variable in the Basu (1997) piecewise linear

regression. It is the coefficient on the return continuous variable (β2) in

equation (1).

B3 Coefficient on the interaction term in the Basu (1997) piecewise linear

193

regression. It is the coefficient on the interaction term (β3) in equation (1).

BTM Ratio of book value of equity to market value of equity, calculated following

Ball et al. (2008) as the median value for all firms and years in each country.

CORRUPT

ICR’s assessment of the corruption in government. Scale from zero to 10,

with lower scores for higher levels of corruption. See La Porta et al. (1997,

1998) for full details.

CREDIT An index aggregating creditor rights. The index ranges from 0 to 4. See La

Porta et al. (1997, 1998) for full details.

DEBT

Ratio of the sum of bank debt of the private sector and outstanding non-

financial bonds to GNP in 1994, or last available. See La Porta et al. (1997,

1998) for full details.

ENGLISH Dummy variable that takes the value 1 if the country’s legal origin is

English, and 0 otherwise.

EQUITY Ratio of the stock market capitalization held by minorities to gross national

product for 1994. See La Porta et al. (1997, 1998) for full details.

FRENCH Dummy variable that takes the value 1 if the country’s legal origin is French,

and 0 otherwise.

LAW

Assessment of the law and order tradition in the country. Scale from 0 to 10,

with lower scores for less tradition for law and order. See La Porta et al.

(1997, 1998) for full details.

SCAND Dummy variable that takes the value 1 if the country’s legal origin is

Scandinavian, and 0 otherwise.

Panel E: Gassen, Fulbier and Sellhorn (2006)

COMMON Dummy variable that takes the value 1 if the country’s legal system is a

common-law system, and 0 otherwise.

LAGX Lagged income before extraordinary items deflated by lagged market value

of equity.

MTB Ratio of market value of equity to book value of equity.

RD Dummy variable that takes the value 1 if RET is negative, and 0 otherwise.

RET Abnormal stock return calculated at the end of the fiscal year, compounded

monthly, and adjusted for the country-year average of returns.

RMTB With-in year decile rank of the opening market-to-book ratio.

X Income before extraordinary items deflated by lagged market value of equity.

194

Table 1. Summary Composition and Summary Statistics for the Examination of Conservatism Measures Section

Panel A: Number of Firm-Year for each Country in the Full Sample

Australia 15,291 France 8,978 Netherlands 2,269 Sweden 4,145

Austria 1,026 Germany 8,868 New Zealand 1,295 Switzerland 2,855

Belgium 1,451 Greece 2,159 Norway 2,277 UK 20,986

Canada 4,574 Ireland 605 Singapore 6,655 USA 70,033

Denmark 1,809 Italy 2,898 South Africa 3,297

Finland 1,824 Japan 50,815 Spain 1,793

Panel B: Summary Statistics for the US Sample

N Mean S.D. Q1 Median Q3

X 70,033 0.0107 0.1346 −0.0074 0.0409 0.0714

RET 70,033 −0.0067 0.5649 −0.3392 −0.0857 0.1931

MTB 70,033 3.1855 4.0001 1.3118 2.0742 3.4985

SIZE 70,033 5.8650 2.0503 4.3644 5.8200 7.2620

LEV 70,033 0.3276 0.2181 0.1421 0.2934 0.4872

CSCORE 70,033 0.0946 0.1074 0.0348 0.0842 0.1397

(continued on next page)

195

Table 1. (continued)

Panel C: Summary Statistics for the Full Sample

N Mean S.D. Q1 Median Q3

X 215,903 0.0123 0.2822 −0.0105 0.0406 0.0792

RET 215,903 0.0004 0.4450 −0.2497 −0.0105 0.2276

MTB 215,903 2.4499 3.2104 0.8991 1.5506 2.7089

SIZE 215,903 6.4456 2.9050 4.1851 6.1918 8.5714

LEV 215,903 0.4129 0.2451 0.2068 0.4009 0.6046

CSCORE 215,903 0.0569 0.1320 −0.0194 0.0553 0.1271

Panel A of Table 1 reports the number of firm-year observations for each country in the final sample. Panels B and C of Table 1

report summary statistics for the variables used in hypotheses H1-H5 for the US and the full samples, respectively. X and RET are

trimmed at the top and bottom 1%. MTB, SIZE and LEV are winsorized at the top and bottom 1%. All variables are defined in

Appendix A.

196

Table 2. The Unconditional Association between AT and VR

US Sample Full Sample

AT Decile VR AT VR AT

1 1.1724 0.0137 1.2247 −0.0187

2 1.2289 0.0847 1.1734 0.0495

3 1.1744 0.1102 1.4303 0.0734

4 1.7283 0.1321 1.3889 0.1049

5 1.4783 0.1571 1.4023 0.1343

6 1.5774 0.1842 1.3040 0.1663

7 2.8953 0.2135 1.7732 0.2007

8 2.5770 0.2484 1.8199 0.2423

9 3.1620 0.3146 1.8303 0.3112

10 2.1389 0.4363 1.8938 1.2566

Table 2 reports pooled cross-sectional values of AT and VR across AT deciles for the US and the full samples. AT and VR are

calculated for each industry-year using the Fama and French 12-industry classification, excluding financial firms, between

1990 and 2015. The industry-year values of AT are sorted into deciles and then the corresponding VR value is calculated for

each AT decile. All variables are defined in Appendix A.

197

Table 3. The Behavior of AT and VR across Price Deciles (H1)

US Sample Full Sample US Sample Full Sample

Price Decile AT AT VR VR

1 0.2090 0.1973 0.7586 0.8193

2 0.2118 0.179 0.9581 0.7616

3 0.1770 0.2135 1.3921 0.9013

4 0.1533 0.1974 1.3704 0.512

5 0.1344 0.1833 1.5202 0.2943

6 0.1077 0.1374 1.5894 1.3643

7 0.1002 0.1296 1.5939 0.6444

8 0.1131 0.1592 1.8577 1.3322

9 0.0766 0.1046 1.3795 1.0515

10 0.0827 0.0849 1.2628 1.2147

Dec.10 – Dec.1 −0.1263 −0.1124 0.5042 0.3954

Chi2 (p-value) 47.21 (0.000) 67.54 (0.000) 100.06 (0.000) 194.80 (0.000)

Table 3 reports pooled cross-sectional values of AT and VR across price deciles for the US and the full samples. Opening stock

price values are sorted annually into deciles between 1990 and 2015. All variables are sorted by opening stock price deciles and

then AT and VR are calculated for each decile. Dec.10 – Dec.1 is the difference between the values of the variable for the 10th

and 1st deciles of price. All variables are defined in Appendix A.

198

Table 4. The Behavior of AT and VR across MTB Deciles (H2)

US Sample Full Sample US Sample Full Sample

MTB Decile AT AT VR VR

1 0.4309 0.4990 0.9403 0.8473

2 0.2813 0.3778 1.3595 1.5902

3 0.2713 0.3213 1.7630 1.6932

4 0.2210 0.2517 1.3351 1.5711

5 0.1670 0.2379 1.5568 1.6721

6 0.1601 0.1958 1.1210 0.5558

7 0.1440 0.1680 1.2502 0.9618

8 0.1257 0.1383 1.0610 1.2157

9 0.1105 0.1317 0.9039 1.0533

10 0.0788 0.0879 0.8503 0.8630

Dec.10 – Dec.1 −0.3521 −0.4111 −0.0900 0.0157

Chi2 (p-value) 215.14 (0.000) 163.14 (0.000) 4.33 (0.037) 0.44 (0.504)

Table 4 reports pooled cross-sectional values of AT and VR across MTB deciles for the US and the full samples. Opening MTB

values are sorted annually into deciles between 1990 and 2015. All variables are sorted by opening MTB deciles and then AT

and VR are calculated for each decile. Dec.10 – Dec.1 is the difference between the values of the variable for the 10th

and 1st

deciles of MTB. All variables are defined in Appendix A.

199

Table 5. The Behavior of AT and VR across SIZE Deciles (H3)

US Sample Full Sample US Sample Full Sample

SIZE Decile AT AT VR VR

1 0.2429 0.2116 0.7567 0.8795

2 0.2350 0.2068 1.0715 0.6700

3 0.1912 0.2249 1.1877 1.6717

4 0.1917 0.1935 1.3474 0.6334

5 0.1620 0.1573 1.1904 0.4786

6 0.1273 0.1384 1.3026 0.2994

7 0.1041 0.1474 1.5989 0.4232

8 0.1075 0.1162 1.3701 2.2036

9 0.1165 0.0918 2.0371 0.4302

10 0.1063 0.0694 1.5212 1.0588

Dec.10 – Dec.1 −0.1366 −0.1422 0.7645 0.1793

Chi2 (p-value) 52.65 (0.000) 80.86 (0.000) 171.88 (0.000) 45.50 (0.000)

Table 5 reports pooled cross-sectional values of AT and VR across SIZE deciles for the US and the full samples. Opening SIZE

values are sorted annually into deciles between 1990 and 2015. All variables are sorted by opening SIZE deciles and then AT

and VR are calculated for each decile. Dec.10 – Dec.1 is the difference between the values of the variable for the 10th

and 1st

deciles of SIZE. All variables are defined in Appendix A.

200

Table 6. The Behavior of AT and VR across LEV Deciles (H4)

US Sample Full Sample US Sample Full Sample

LEV Decile AT AT VR VR

1 0.1068 0.0767 0.9523 1.0090

2 0.1871 0.1304 1.2489 1.3221

3 0.1792 0.1546 1.2389 1.3229

4 0.1868 0.1882 1.2520 1.4861

5 0.1858 0.1910 1.2293 1.2135

6 0.1676 0.1927 1.3208 0.7714

7 0.1997 0.1933 1.5452 1.5223

8 0.2076 0.2237 1.4394 1.4331

9 0.2390 0.2547 1.2307 1.3789

10 0.4159 0.3400 0.9120 0.7472

Dec.10 – Dec.1 0.3091 0.2633 −0.0403 −0.2618

Chi2 (p-value) 133.47 (0.000) 92.37 (0.000) 0.78 (0.376) 113.57 (0.000)

Table 6 reports pooled cross-sectional values of AT and VR across LEV deciles for the US and the full samples. Opening LEV

values are sorted annually into deciles between 1990 and 2015. All variables are sorted by opening LEV deciles and then AT

and VR are calculated for each decile. Dec.10 – Dec.1 is the difference between the values of the variable for the 10th

and 1st

deciles of LEV. All variables are defined in Appendix A.

201

Table 7. The Behavior of AT and VR across CSCORE Deciles (H5)

US Sample Full Sample US Sample Full Sample

CSCORE Decile AT AT VR VR

1 0.0795 0.0827 0.9024 0.2261

2 0.0892 0.0545 0.7211 1.4496

3 0.0899 0.0883 0.7648 0.6760

4 0.1001 0.1393 0.6259 1.8187

5 0.1071 0.1440 0.7139 1.8823

6 0.1342 0.1402 0.7565 0.9727

7 0.1454 0.1789 0.7683 0.4984

8 0.1413 0.1876 0.7628 1.1041

9 0.1817 0.2035 0.8669 1.0650

10 0.3435 0.2627 0.8087 1.0910

Dec.10 – Dec.1 0.2640 0.1800 −0.0937 0.8649

Chi2 (p-value) 132.00 (0.000) 53.91 (0.000) 4.88 (0.027) 1561.41 (0.000)

Table 7 reports pooled cross-sectional values of AT and VR across CSCORE deciles for the US and the full samples. Closing

CSCORE values are sorted annually into deciles between 1990 and 2015. All variables are sorted by closing CSCORE deciles

and then AT and VR are calculated for each decile. Dec.10 – Dec.1 is the difference between the values of the variable for the

10th

and 1st deciles of CSCORE. All variables are defined in Appendix A.

202

Table 8. André et al. (2015): The Change in Conditional Conservatism around IFRS (H6)

Panel A: Summary Statistics

N Mean S.D. Q1 Median Q3

RET 12,731 0.0252 0.4474 −0.1925 0.0429 0.2786

CSCORE 12,731 0.0595 0.0876 0.0109 0.0606 0.1150

SIZE 12,731 6.4201 2.0122 4.9541 6.2554 7.6563

MTB 12,731 2.3350 2.8101 0.9536 1.6106 2.6521

LEV 12,731 0.1207 0.1239 0.0146 0.0874 0.1844

BETA 12,731 0.9967 0.8531 0.4488 0.9071 1.4557

UCC 12,731 −0.5921 2.6226 −2.1991 -0.7703 0.7368

Panel B: The Change in Conditional Conservatism around IFRS using CSCORE_A

CSCORE_A

IFRS −0.0256***

(−24.16)

SIZE −0.0300***

(−81.17)

MTB 0.0090***

(25.03)

LEV_A 0.2219***

(35.20)

BETA −0.0175***

(−24.14)

UCC −0.0249***

(−73.04)

(continued on next page)

203

Table 8. (continued)

Panel B: (continued)

CSCORE_A

Intercept 0.2211***

(132.47)

Adjusted R2 51.95%

N 12,731

Panel C: Change in Conditional Conservatism around IFRS using VR

IFRS RD Mean (X) S.D. N

IFRS = 0 RD = 0 0.0921 0.2064 3,089

IFRS = 0 RD = 1 −0.0006 0.2309 2,431

IFRS = 1 RD = 0 0.0897 0.1866 3,929

IFRS = 1 RD = 1 0.0104 0.1774 3,282

H0: VR | (IFRS=0) = VR | (IFRS=1) VR | (IFRS=0) = 1.25 Chi

2 = 35.2

VR | (IFRS=1) = 0.91 p-value = 0.000

Panel A of Table 8 reports summary statistics for the variables used in the replication of Andre et al. (2015). The sample period is 2000-2010.

Panel B of Table 8 reports results from the pooled cross-sectional regression of CSCORE_A on a set of firm characteristics and IFRS. All variables are defined in Appendix A.

All continuous variables are winsorized at the top and bottom 1%. The t-statistics, presented in parentheses below the coefficients, are calculated based on clustered standard

errors at the firm level. *,

**,

*** Denote significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively.

Panel C of Table 8 reports detailed summary statistics for X conditional on RD pre- and post-IFRS adoption, along with the Chi2 statistic that tests the statistical significance of

the change in VR.

204

Table 9. Lobo and Zhou (2006): The Change in Conditional Conservatism around SOX (H6)

Panel A: Summary Statistics

N Mean S.D. Q1 Median Q3

X 11,244 0.0150 0.1602 −0.0054 0.0472 0.0856

RET 11,244 0.0128 0.6170 −0.3398 −0.0738 0.2119

Panel B: The Change in Conditional Conservatism around SOX using AT

X

RD 0.0176***

(2.94)

RET −0.0043

(−0.94)

RD*RET 0.2289***

(20.75)

SOX −0.0115**

(−2.11)

RD*SOX −0.0014

(−0.17)

RET*SOX 0.0028

(0.41)

RD*RET* SOX 0.0436***

(2.63)

Intercept 0.0605***

(15.42)

Adjusted R2 12.93%

N 11,244

(continued on next page)

205

Table 9. (continued)

Panel C: The Change in Conditional Conservatism around SOX using VR

SOX RD Mean (X) S.D. N

SOX = 0 RD = 0 0.0582 0.1509 2,380

SOX = 0 RD = 1 −0.0050 0.1628 3,242

SOX = 1 RD = 0 0.0483 0.1424 2,459

SOX = 1 RD = 1 −0.0230 0.1647 3,163

H0: VR | (SOX=0) = VR | (SOX=1) VR | (SOX=0) = 1.16 Chi

2 = 6.54

VR | (SOX=1) = 1.34 p-value = 0.010

Panel A of Table 9 reports summary statistics for the variables used in the replication of Lobo and Zhou (2006). The sample period is 2000-2004.

Panel B of Table 9 reports results from the pooled cross-sectional regression of the Basu (1997) piecewise linear model while interactively including SOX. All variables are

defined in Appendix A. X and RET are trimmed at the top and bottom 1%. The t-statistics, presented in parentheses below the coefficients, are calculated based on clustered

standard errors at the firm level. *,

**,

*** Denote significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively.

Panel C of Table 9 reports detailed summary statistics for X conditional on RD pre- and post-SOX passage, along with the Chi2 statistic that tests the statistical significance of

the change in VR.

206

Table 10. Ball et al. (2008): The Effect of Debt and Equity Markets in Shaping Financial Reporting (H7a)

Panel A: Summary Statistics

N Mean S.D. Q1 Median Q3

X 96,379 −0.0071 0.2625 −0.0093 0.0321 0.0728

RET 96,379 −0.0076 0.5528 −0.3023 −0.0282 0.2327

Panel B: Extract from the Full Dataset Used to Replicate Ball et al. (2008)

Country B0 B1 B2 B3 VR DEBT EQUITY LAW CORRUPT CREDIT BTM

Australia 0.017 −0.027 0.004 0.272 1.90 0.76 0.49 10.00 8.52 1 0.638

Canada 0.051 0.002 −0.001 0.293 1.64 0.72 0.39 10.00 10.00 1 0.682

Malaysia −0.012 −0.010 −0.023 0.160 1.19 0.84 1.48 6.78 7.38 4 0.789

Singapore 0.016 0.004 0.087 0.013 1.00 0.60 1.18 8.57 8.22 3 0.817

South Africa 0.101 −0.001 0.147 −0.017 0.70 0.93 1.45 4.42 8.92 4 0.738

Thailand 0.030 −0.016 0.003 0.365 0.86 0.93 0.56 6.25 5.18 3 0.944

UK 0.041 −0.018 −0.026 0.193 1.48 1.13 1.00 8.57 9.10 4 0.514

USA 0.035 0.012 −0.026 0.228 1.51 0.81 0.58 10.00 8.63 1 0.475

Brazil 0.043 −0.061 −0.019 0.027 0.61 0.39 0.18 6.32 6.32 1 0.004

Chile 0.061 0.002 0.098 0.116 1.29 0.63 0.80 7.02 5.30 2 0.815

France 0.043 −0.007 0.022 0.216 2.33 0.96 0.23 8.98 9.05 0 0.702

Indonesia −0.021 −0.006 0.045 −0.025 1.09 0.42 0.15 3.98 2.15 4 0.775

Italy 0.054 0.000 −0.019 0.129 1.04 0.55 0.08 8.33 6.13 2 1.052

Netherlands 0.079 −0.005 −0.036 0.221 1.82 1.08 0.52 10.00 10.00 2 0.566

Spain 0.119 −0.018 −0.046 0.132 0.61 0.75 0.17 7.80 7.38 2 0.787

Germany 0.012 −0.039 0.023 0.212 1.72 1.12 0.13 9.23 8.93 3 0.628

Japan 0.009 −0.010 0.045 0.081 2.00 1.22 0.62 8.98 8.52 2 0.793

(continued on next page)

207

Table 10. (continued)

Panel B: (continued)

Country B0 B1 B2 B3 VR DEBT EQUITY LAW CORRUPT CREDIT BTM

South Korea 0.056 −0.039 0.239 0.032 1.25 0.74 0.44 5.35 5.30 3 1.810

Denmark 0.088 −0.028 0.048 0.127 1.36 0.34 0.21 10.00 10.00 3 0.848

Finland 0.093 −0.024 0.075 0.071 0.78 0.75 0.25 10.00 10.00 1 0.811

Norway 0.052 −0.011 −0.016 0.230 1.81 0.64 0.22 10.00 10.00 2 0.650

Sweden 0.022 0.011 0.078 0.270 4.16 0.55 0.51 10.00 10.00 2 0.657

Mean 0.045 −0.013 0.032 0.152 1.462 0.766 0.529 8.208 7.956 2.273 0.750

Median 0.043 −0.010 0.013 0.146 1.325 0.750 0.465 8.775 8.575 2.000 0.757

S.D. 0.036 0.018 0.069 0.108 0.770 0.245 0.416 1.947 2.102 1.162 0.313

Panel A of Table 10 reports summary statistics for the variables used in replicating Ball et al. (2008). The sample period is 1992-

2003.

Panel B of Table 10 reports the estimates obtained from the Basu (1997) pooled cross-sectional regression in each country, the

VR value for each country and a set of country-level variables. X and RET are trimmed at the top and bottom 1%. All variables

are defined in Appendix A.

208

Table 11. The Effect of Debt and Equity Markets on Conditional Conservatism using AT (H7a)

B3 B3 B3 B3 B3 B3 B3 B3 B3

DEBT 0.2656**

0.1987* 0.2592

* 0.2518

** 0.2550

** 0.1978

* 0.2686

* 0.2568

** 0.2569

*

(2.81) (1.87) (2.13) (2.53) (2.25) (1.80) (2.14) (2.16) (2.08)

EQUITY −0.1875***

−0.1472**

−0.1869***

−0.1661**

−0.1174 −0.1501* −0.1626

* −0.1145 −0.117

(−3.08) (−2.18) (−2.96) (−2.29) (−1.67) (−2.05) (−2.13) (−1.47) (−1.44)

ENGLISH 0.2223***

0.1863**

0.2200**

0.2087**

0.1939**

0.1874**

0.2125**

0.1931**

0.2010**

(3.27) (2.58) (2.94) (2.84) (2.72) (2.49) (2.74) (2.60) (2.44)

FRENCH 0.0823 0.0689 0.0813 0.0702 0.0745 0.0712 0.0703 0.0727 0.0823

(1.25) (1.05) (1.18) (0.99) (1.16) (1.02) (0.96) (1.05) (1.03)

SCAND 0.1688**

0.1071 0.163 0.1569* 0.1564 0.106 0.1722 0.1582 0.1614

(2.20) (1.20) (1.58) (1.93) (1.63) (1.14) (1.62) (1.57) (1.53)

LAW

0.0163

0.0331* 0.0175

0.0325 0.0323

(1.29)

(1.82) (1.11)

(1.63) (1.57)

CORRUPT

0.0012

−0.0234

−0.0038 −0.0238 −0.0223

(0.09)

(−1.26)

(−0.23) (−1.21) (−1.05)

CREDIT

−0.0115

0.0031 −0.0144 −0.0025 −0.0026

(−0.58)

(0.13) (−0.60) (−0.10) (−0.10)

BTM

0.0206

(0.27)

Intercept −0.09 −0.1657 −0.0928 −0.0537 −0.1894 −0.1807 −0.0358 −0.1776 −0.2095

(−0.84) (−1.38) (−0.81) (−0.42) (−1.58) (−1.06) (−0.24) (−1.06) (−1.00)

(continued on next page)

209

Table 11. (continued)

B3 B3 B3 B3 B3 B3 B3 B3 B3

Adjusted R2 53.77% 58.35% 53.79% 54.77% 62.59% 58.40% 54.94% 62.63% 62.86%

N 22 22 22 22 22 22 22 22 22

Table 11 reports pooled cross-sectional regression results that use the AT coefficient estimates (B3) reported in Table 10 in order

to replicate Ball et al. (2008). All variables are defined in Appendix A. The t-statistics, presented in parentheses below the

coefficients, are calculated based on White (1980) standard errors. *,

**,

*** Denote significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels,

respectively.

210

Table 12. The Effect of Debt and Equity Markets on Conditional Conservatism using VR (H7a)

VR VR VR VR VR VR VR VR VR

DEBT 0.9134 0.1215 0.3079 0.6631 0.2778 0.1423 0.4169 0.3372 0.336

(1.03) (0.13) (0.28) (0.74) (0.26) (0.14) (0.37) (0.30) (0.29)

EQUITY −0.0393 0.4385 0.0175 0.3491 0.521 0.5033 0.2981 0.6208 0.6427

(−0.07) (0.72) (0.03) (0.53) (0.78) (0.76) (0.43) (0.85) (0.84)

ENGLISH −0.1817 −0.6085 −0.3978 −0.4292 −0.5874 −0.634 −0.485 −0.6154 −0.6876

(−0.29) (−0.93) (−0.58) (−0.65) (−0.87) (−0.93) (−0.69) (−0.88) (−0.88)

FRENCH −0.0905 −0.2484 −0.1839 −0.3093 −0.2328 −0.2992 −0.3107 −0.2942 −0.3811

(−0.15) (−0.42) (−0.29) (−0.48) (−0.38) (−0.47) (−0.47) (−0.45) (−0.51)

SCAND 0.7841 0.0544 0.2388 0.5694 0.1912 0.0788 0.3455 0.2511 0.2218

(1.09) (0.07) (0.26) (0.78) (0.21) (0.09) (0.36) (0.26) (0.22)

LAW

0.1935

0.2401 0.1685

0.2181 0.2197

(1.68)

(1.39) (1.18)

(1.16) (1.13)

CORRUPT

0.1135

−0.065

0.0557 −0.0788 −0.0931

(0.91)

(−0.37)

(0.38) (−0.42) (−0.47)

CREDIT

−0.2082

−0.0678 −0.166 −0.0862 −0.0858

(−1.15)

(−0.32) (−0.77) (−0.38) (−0.37)

BTM

−0.1863

(−0.26)

Intercept 0.7345 −0.1616 0.4726 1.3927 −0.2273 0.1684 1.1307 0.1786 0.4673

(0.73) (−0.15) (0.45) (1.22) (−0.20) (0.11) (0.83) (0.11) (0.24)

(continued on next page)

211

Table 12. (continued)

VR VR VR VR VR VR VR VR VR

Adjusted R2 21.00% 33.57% 25.16% 27.43% 34.21% 34.04% 28.17% 34.94% 35.31%

N 22 22 22 22 22 22 22 22 22

Table 12 reports pooled cross-sectional regression results that use the VR values reported in Table 10 in order to re-examine

the finding of Ball et al. (2008). All variables are defined in Appendix A. The t-statistics, presented in parentheses below the

coefficients, are calculated based on White (1980) standard errors. *,

**,

*** Denote significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels,

respectively.

212

Table 13. Gassen et al. (2006): The Difference in Conditional Conservatism across Legal Origins (H7b)

Panel A: Summary Statistics

N Mean S.D. Q1 Median Q3

X 84,436 0.0202 0.2120 0.0024 0.0414 0.0810

RET 84,436 0.0003 0.4890 −0.2803 −0.0310 0.2149

COMMON 84,436 0.6792 0.4668 0 1 1

MTB 84,436 2.5678 2.8855 0.9870 1.7024 2.9499

Panel B: Original and Placebo Tests of Conditional Conservatism across Legal Regimes using AT

Original Test Placebo Test

Code-law Common-law All Code-law Common-law All

X X X LAGX LAGX LAGX

RD −0.0125 0.0102***

−0.0125 −0.0145 0.0081 −0.0145

(−1.31) (6.81) (−1.31) (−1.40) (1.73) (−1.40)

COMMON −0.0044 −0.0388

(−0.20) (−1.16)

COMMON*RD 0.0227**

0.0227**

(2.27) (2.20)

RET 0.0355* 0.0045 0.0355

* −0.0695

* −0.0825

*** −0.0695

*

(1.92) (0.54) (1.92) (−1.94) (−5.77) (−1.94)

COMMON*RET −0.031 −0.0129

(−1.61) (−0.46)

RD*RET 0.1352

*** 0.2172

*** 0.1352

*** 0.2098

*** 0.2451

*** 0.2098

***

(3.62) (18.21) (3.62) (3.21) (6.92) (3.21)

COMMON*RD*RET 0.0820**

0.0353

(2.22) (0.63)

(continued on next page)

213

Table 13. (continued)

Panel B: (continued)

Original Test Placebo Test

Code-law Common-law All Code-law Common-law All

X X X LAGX LAGX LAGX

Intercept 0.0563**

0.0519***

0.0563**

0.0775**

0.0388***

0.0775**

(2.45) (10.78) (2.45) (2.30) (5.80) (2.30)

Average R2 7.86% 12.74% 12.09% 2.12% 4.60% 4.74%

N 27,083 57,353 84,436 27,083 57,353 84,436

(continued on next page)

214

Table 13. (Continued)

Panel C: Original and Placebo Tests of Conditional Conservatism across Legal Regimes using VR

Original Test Placebo Test

Code-law Sample Code-law Sample

RD Mean(X) S.D. N RD Mean (LAGX) S.D. N

RD = 0 0.0680 0.2560 13,790 RD = 0 0.0687 0.4527 13,790

RD = 1 −0.0004 0.2671 13,293 RD = 1 0.0307 0.4400 13,293

VR = 1.09

VR = 0.94

H0: VR = 1 F-stat (p-value): 22.91 (0.000) H0: VR = 1 F-stat (p-value): 3.31 (0.068)

Common-law Sample Common-law Sample

RD Mean(X) S.D. N RD Mean (LAGX) S.D. N

RD = 0 0.0508 0.1695 25,475 RD = 0 −0.0014 0.2637 25,475

RD = 1 −0.0164 0.1864 31,878 RD = 1 −0.0134 0.2494 31,878

VR = 1.21

VR = 0.89

H0: VR = 1 F-stat (p-value): 287.91 (0.000) H0: VR = 1 F-stat (p-value): 7.86 (0.005)

Panel A of Table 13 reports summary statistics for the variables used in the replication of Gassen et al. (2006). The sample period is 1990-2003.

Panel B of Table 13 reports results from the annual cross-sectional regressions of the Basu (1997) model while interactively including COMMON. The first three

columns are the original test where the dependent variable is X while the last three columns are the placebo test where the dependent variable is LAGX. All variables

are defined in Appendix A. X, RET and LAGX are winsorized at the upper and bottom 1%. The t-statistics, presented in parentheses below the coefficients, are

calculated based on Fama-MacBeth standard errors. *,

**,

*** Denote significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively.

Panel C of Table 13 reports detailed summary statistics for X and LAGX conditional on RD, for Common-law and Code-law samples, from the original and the

placebo tests. The reported F-statistics test the significance of the null hypothesis that VR equals 1.

215

Table 14. Gassen et al. (2006): The Difference in Conditional Conservatism across MTB Deciles (H7a)

Panel A: The Change in AT across MTB Deciles

Code-law Common-law All

X X X

RD −0.0328* −0.0008 −0.0185

(−1.89) (−0.13) (−1.65)

RMTB −0.0118 0.0007 −0.0053

(−1.47) (0.45) (−1.14)

RMTB*RD 0.0053**

0.0017* 0.0035

**

(2.32) (1.77) (2.41)

RET 0.0221 0.0325**

0.0135

(0.71) (2.34) (0.68)

RMTB*RET 0.0042 −0.0050***

−0.0012

(0.98) (−3.99) (−0.52)

RD*RET 0.3272***

0.3579***

0.3853***

(4.04) (13.43) (7.22)

RMTB*RD*RET −0.0355***

−0.0232***

−0.0312***

(−3.17) (−7.47) (−4.56)

Intercept 0.1104* 0.0482

*** 0.0851

**

(2.01) (3.72) (2.43)

Average R2 12.88% 17.13% 15.35%

N 27,083 57,353 84,436

(continued on next page)

216

Panel B: The Behavior of Conditional Conservatism across MTB Deciles using AT and VR

MTB Decile AT VR

1 0.417 1.06

2 0.307 1.44

3 0.248 1.93

4 0.212 1.82

5 0.196 1.68

6 0.162 1.29

7 0.131 1.84

8 0.130 1.32

9 0.113 1.25

10 0.101 0.97

Dec.10 – Dec.1 −0.308 −0.09

Chi2 (p-value) 144.93 (0.000) 3.94 (0.047)

Panel A of Table 14 reports results from the annual cross-sectional regressions of the Basu (1997) model while interactively including RMTB. All variables are defined in

Appendix A. X and RET are winsorized at the top and bottom 1%. The t-statistics, presented in parentheses below the coefficients, are calculated based on Fama-MacBeth

standard errors. *,

**,

*** Denote significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively.

Panel B of Table 13 reports the mean values of AT and VR across MTB deciles for the full sample. Dec.10 – Dec.1 is the difference between the values of the variable for the

10th

and 1st deciles of MTB.

217

Chapter 5

Summary and Suggestions for Future Research

This thesis examines the interaction between financial reporting and information

asymmetry in relation to their effect on the behavior of market participants. I first assess

the impact of changes in accounting standards on corporate payout and equity financing

choices. The overall inference is that imposing higher quality financial reporting standards

serves to mitigate information asymmetry and, accordingly, reduce frictions affecting

corporate financial decisions. I then evaluate the empirical measurement of conditional

conservatism, a feature of financial reporting meant to mitigate information asymmetry.

My findings imply that the literature has drawn several conclusions about the role of

accounting conservatism in capital markets based on a biased measure of conditional

conservatism. Accordingly, a considerable number of prior studies need to be revisited in

light of a more appropriate measure of conditional conservatism.

Chapter 2 examines the change in dividend payout policy and dividend value relevance

following the mandatory adoption of IFRS. The first main hypothesis is based on prior

findings that the mandatory adoption of IFRS serves to mitigate information asymmetry,

due to better accounting quality and increased financial disclosure, and accordingly eases

external financing. As a result, managers are expected to retain less cash and pay more

dividends to shareholders since raising external funds becomes less costly. Concurrently,

the other main hypothesis predicts that improving accounting standards increases

accounting value relevance and decreases dividend value relevance. That is, investors are

expected to have more confidence in accounting numbers and, thus, dividends would lose

from their signaling power. The empirical findings confirm the aforementioned

hypotheses.

Chapter 3 examines whether imposing higher quality accounting standards serves to

mitigate earnings management activities in situations where such activities are found to be

218

high. In particular, the first hypothesis examines the change in the level of earnings

management prior to issuing new equity following the mandatory adoption of IFRS. The

reduction in earnings management and information asymmetry following the IFRS

mandate is expected to improve the market reaction to SEOs, which is the second

hypothesis. Accordingly, an improved market reaction to equity offerings implies a

reduction in the costs associated with equity financing. Therefore, the final hypothesis

predicts that the propensity to issue new equity would increase following IFRS adoption.

The reported results indicate that the formulated hypotheses are in the right direction.

Extending Chapters 2 and 3 would include the addition of more countries to the sample

in order to generalize the findings. A bigger sample would also allow for a tighter

matching based on several firm-level variables that might drive the results in the current

chapters, such as corporate governance and underlying economic characteristics. However,

this would come at the cost of compromising the high comparability between the control

and treatment groups in my study, that is, the UK and France. This is because the effect of

IFRS adoption is determined to a large extent by several country characteristics that drive

the effect of IFRS per se. A plausible solution might be the addition of some country-level

variables that control for variations in financial reporting incentives, enforcement changes,

institutional infrastructures, legal systems, and corruption.

Chapter 4 evaluates the empirical estimation of conditional conservatism in accounting

data. As mentioned in the introduction of the chapter, several important conclusions were

drawn about the role of accounting conservatism in capital markets based on the

asymmetric timeliness measures (i.e., the AT and the C_Score measures). Yet, recent

studies provide evidence showing a substantial upward bias in the original asymmetric

timeliness measure (i.e., the AT measure) arising from non-accounting (economic) factors.

Therefore, this chapter aims to evaluate prior studies in light of a new alternative measure

of conditional conservatism, the VR measure. The first part of the analysis shows that the

economic bias implicit in the AT measure also drives the C_Score measure; however, the

219

VR measure seems unaffected by this bias. The other part of the analysis replicates four

prior studies that use the AT measure (or the C_Score measure), and then re-examines the

replicated results using the VR measure. The findings show that the AT and the VR

measures yield similar conclusions when used to model the change in conditional

conservatism for the same sample following an exogenous change in accounting policy.

The intuition here is that the economic bias for the same group of firms is expected to

cancel out when the regression model measures the change in the AT coefficient estimate.

On the other hand, the AT and the VR measures yield inconsistent conclusions when used

to model the cross-sectional variation in conditional conservatism. This is attributed to the

different underlying economic characteristics across different cross-sections, which results

in a different magnitude of the AT bias between samples.

Chapter 4 opens the door to re-examining prior studies on conditional conservatism and

to reaching more reliable conclusions about the costs and benefits of conditional

conservatism. Despite the fact that I praise the VR measure in light of my findings, yet this

measure suffers from some limitations. Specifically, the VR measure cannot be estimated

at the firm-year level. This should motivate researchers to develop a new firm-year

measure in spirit of the VR measure in a similar way that the C_Score measure was

developed based on the AT measure. In addition, the VR measure is sensitive to outliers

and becomes more sensitive when estimating conditional conservatism for a small number

of observations. Thus, it might be helpful to check if the results hold after dropping the top

and bottom 5%, or perhaps 10%, of the main variable used in the VR measure (i.e.,

deflated earnings or deflated accruals).