household bargaining over fertility: theory and evidence ...uctpimr/research/fertility_jde.pdf ·...

27
Household bargaining over fertility: Theory and evidence from Malaysia Imran Rasul Department of Economics, University College London, Drayton House, 30 Gordon Street, London WC1E 6BT, United Kingdom CEPR¸ United Kingdom Received 14 November 2005; received in revised form 24 April 2006; accepted 28 February 2007 Abstract We develop and test a model of household bargaining over fertility when transfers between spouses are possible. The model makes precise how the fertility preferences of each spouse translate into fertility outcomes. We show this depends on whether or not spouses can commit to their future actions within marriage. If couples bargain with commitment, fertility outcomes take account of both spouses' fertility preferences and do not depend on the threat point in marital bargaining. If couples bargain without commitment, the influence of each spouse's fertility preference on fertility outcomes depends on the relevant threat point in marital bargaining, and the distribution of bargaining power. We test the models using household data from the Malaysia Family Life Survey. This data set contains information on each spouse's desired fertility level, as well as fertility outcomes. We exploit differences in threat points in marital bargaining across ethnic groups to help identify the underlying bargaining model. The evidence suggests couples bargain without commitment. © 2007 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved. JEL classification: J12; J13; O12 Keywords: Commitment; Fertility; Household bargaining 1. Introduction This paper develops and tests a model of household bargaining over fertility when transfers between spouses are possible. The aim of the analysis is to make precise how the fertility preferences of each spouse translate into fertility outcomes. This sheds light both on how conflicts between spouses over fertility are resolved, and the subsequent distribution of household resources. 1 Journal of Development Economics 86 (2008) 215 241 www.elsevier.com/locate/econbase I thank the editor, Mark Rosenzweig, and an anonymous referee for comments that have helped improve the paper. I have also benefited from discussions with Oriana Bandiera, Tim Besley, Richard Blundell, Robin Burgess, Anne Case, Andrew Chesher, Markus Goldstein, Valentino Larcinese, Alan Manning, Michele Piccione, Andrea Prat, Yoram Weiss and seminar participants at Bocconi, Bonn, Brown, Chicago GSB, Essex, IFS, IIES, LSE, Mannheim, Maryland, Michigan, Northwestern, Stanford GSB, Warwick, the World Bank, and Yale SOM. I thank Marcia Schafgans and Charles Hirschman for help with obtaining the data. All errors remain my own. Department of Economics, University College London, Drayton House, 30 Gordon Street, London WC1E 6BT, United Kingdom. Tel.: +44 20 7679 5853; fax: +44 20 7916 2775. E-mail address: [email protected]. 1 It is well documented that there are significant differences in men and women's fertility preferences in many developing countries including Malaysia, which is our empirical setting (Leung, 1987; Mason and Taj, 1987). 0304-3878/$ - see front matter © 2007 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved. doi:10.1016/j.jdeveco.2007.02.005

Upload: others

Post on 24-Jun-2020

3 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Household bargaining over fertility: Theory and evidence ...uctpimr/research/fertility_JDE.pdf · Household bargaining over fertility: Theory and ... This standard hold-up problem

omics 86 (2008) 215–241www.elsevier.com/locate/econbase

Journal of Development Econ

Household bargaining over fertility: Theory andevidence from Malaysia☆

Imran Rasul ⁎

Department of Economics, University College London, Drayton House, 30 Gordon Street, London WC1E 6BT, United KingdomCEPR¸ United Kingdom

Received 14 November 2005; received in revised form 24 April 2006; accepted 28 February 2007

Abstract

We develop and test a model of household bargaining over fertility when transfers between spouses are possible. The modelmakes precise how the fertility preferences of each spouse translate into fertility outcomes. We show this depends on whether or notspouses can commit to their future actions within marriage. If couples bargain with commitment, fertility outcomes take account ofboth spouses' fertility preferences and do not depend on the threat point in marital bargaining. If couples bargain withoutcommitment, the influence of each spouse's fertility preference on fertility outcomes depends on the relevant threat point in maritalbargaining, and the distribution of bargaining power. We test the models using household data from the Malaysia Family LifeSurvey. This data set contains information on each spouse's desired fertility level, as well as fertility outcomes. We exploitdifferences in threat points in marital bargaining across ethnic groups to help identify the underlying bargaining model. Theevidence suggests couples bargain without commitment.© 2007 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.

JEL classification: J12; J13; O12Keywords: Commitment; Fertility; Household bargaining

☆ I thank the editor, Mark Rosenzweig, and an anonymous refereefor comments that have helped improve the paper. I have also benefitedfrom discussions with Oriana Bandiera, Tim Besley, Richard Blundell,Robin Burgess, Anne Case, Andrew Chesher, Markus Goldstein,Valentino Larcinese, Alan Manning, Michele Piccione, Andrea Prat,Yoram Weiss and seminar participants at Bocconi, Bonn, Brown,Chicago GSB, Essex, IFS, IIES, LSE, Mannheim, Maryland,Michigan, Northwestern, Stanford GSB, Warwick, the World Bank,and Yale SOM. I thank Marcia Schafgans and Charles Hirschman forhelp with obtaining the data. All errors remain my own.⁎ Department of Economics, University College London, Drayton

House, 30 Gordon Street, London WC1E 6BT, United Kingdom.Tel.: +44 20 7679 5853; fax: +44 20 7916 2775.

E-mail address: [email protected].

0304-3878/$ - see front matter © 2007 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.doi:10.1016/j.jdeveco.2007.02.005

1. Introduction

This paper develops and tests a model of householdbargaining over fertility when transfers between spousesare possible. The aim of the analysis is to make precisehow the fertility preferences of each spouse translateinto fertility outcomes. This sheds light both on howconflicts between spouses over fertility are resolved, andthe subsequent distribution of household resources.1

1 It is well documented that there are significant differences in menand women's fertility preferences in many developing countriesincluding Malaysia, which is our empirical setting (Leung, 1987;Mason and Taj, 1987).

Page 2: Household bargaining over fertility: Theory and evidence ...uctpimr/research/fertility_JDE.pdf · Household bargaining over fertility: Theory and ... This standard hold-up problem

216 I. Rasul / Journal of Development Economics 86 (2008) 215–241

Key to the analysis is whether spouses can commit totheir future actions in marriage once they have chosen afertility level. Suppose first that spouses are able tocommit to ex ante agreements on their behavior withinmarriage. The future actions of either spouse can then beagreed to at any time, including in a pre-marital contract.With commitment, this agreement is assumed enforce-able at any stage of marriage. We show fertility outcomesare then efficient and take account of both spouse'sdesired fertility level.

Now suppose couples are unable to commit ex anteto their future actions within marriage. Such actions mayfor example include their investments into child quality.While such future actions can be discussed, they cannotbe committed to ex ante. Non-commitment may stemfrom actions being non-observable or non-verifiable. Itwill not then be possible to write an agreement based onthese actions because such contracts are not enforceableby third parties.

The key insight for household decision making whenactions cannot be committed to is that marital bargainsare subject to ex post renegotiation after fertility invest-ments are sunk, and this alters spouses' ex ante invest-ment incentives. This standard hold-up problem hasconsequences both for the efficiency of fertility out-comes, and the allocation of household resources.

With non-commitment, both spouses' preferences areweighted in determining the equilibrium number ofchildren, although these weights are in general different,and may even be zero. In particular, the influence ofeach spouse's fertility preference on fertility outcomesdepends on the relevant threat point in marital bargain-ing, and the distribution of bargaining power.

We take the models to the data using the MalaysiaFamily Life Survey (MFLS). This is two-wave house-hold panel where both spouses are interviewed on eachoccasion. Importantly, the survey collects detailedinformation on each spouse's fertility preferences. Werelate fertility outcomes at the end of women's fertilityperiod in the second wave of data, to the fertility prefe-rences of both spouses as expressed 12 years earlier, inthe first wave of data.2

In line with the existing evidence (Leung, 1987;Mason and Taj, 1987), we find significant differencesbetween spouses in their desired fertility. On average,

2 In contrast, much of the existing literature has exploited data suchas the World Fertility Survey, that only contains the wife's fertilitypreference. Furthermore, nearly all the previous literature has useddata with a time span of between three and seven years from whenpreferences are expressed until fertility outcomes are observed(Freedman et al., 1980; Thomson et al., 1990).

husbands prefer significantly more children than theirwives.

Malaysia is an ethnically diverse country and weexploit important differences in how marriage marketsoperate across ethnic groups, and hence the relevantthreat point in marital bargaining, to help identify theunderlying model of bargaining. As documented inmore detail later, among Malays, divorce rates over thestudy period are among the highest in the world. Forthese couples, the relevant threat point in maritalbargaining is divorce. In contrast, for the Chinese inMalaysia, divorce is rare and the relevant threat pointrelates more closely to some non-cooperative outcomewithin marriage (Lundberg and Pollak, 1993; Chen andWoolley, 2001).3

If couples bargain with commitment, theory predictsthese different threat points in marital bargaining acrossethnic groups, should have no effect on how fertilitypreferences translate into fertility outcomes. If couplesbargain without commitment, then the outside option inmarital bargaining shapes how the fertility preferencesof each spouse translate into fertility outcomes.

The central empirical results are that in Malayhouseholds, both spouse's fertility preferences have anequal, positive, and significant effect on fertility out-comes. In contrast, in Chinese households, only thewife's preference determines fertility outcomes. Theresults are robust to controlling for other individual andhousehold determinants of fertility, and to using anestimation technique that accounts for the discreteness offertility outcomes. However, a number of econometricconcerns remain.

First, there may be unobserved time invarianthousehold determinants of fertility preferences and fer-tility outcomes. To address this concern we apply atransformation analogous to first-differencing fertilityoutcomes between the two waves of data. We thenestimate how each spouse's desired number of addi-tional children relates to the additional number ofchildren born between the two waves of data.

Second, preferences may be endogenously deter-mined by unobserved factors that also drive fertilityoutcomes. Alternatively, preferences may be measuredwith error. We address these concerns using an in-strumental variables approach that exploits informationon the characteristics of each spouse's own parent, toinstrument for preferences.

These econometric concerns obviously apply equallyto all couples. However due to limited sample sizes in

3 Intermarriage across ethnic groups is almost non existent in thetime period we study.

Page 3: Household bargaining over fertility: Theory and evidence ...uctpimr/research/fertility_JDE.pdf · Household bargaining over fertility: Theory and ... This standard hold-up problem

217I. Rasul / Journal of Development Economics 86 (2008) 215–241

the MFLS data, we are only able to address them forMalays. When doing so, we continue to find that amongMalay couples, both spouse's fertility preferences havean equal, positive, and significant effect on fertilityoutcomes.

Mapping the results back to theory, behavioramong Malay couples is consistent with thembargaining with or without commitment. In contrast,for Chinese couples, as only the wife's preferencedetermines fertility outcomes, their behavior can onlybe reconciled with a model of bargaining withoutcommitment.

This leads to one of two conclusions. First, it may bethat Malay couples can bargain with commitment andChinese couples cannot. This interpretation lacks intui-tive appeal if we view the ability of couples to commitor not as a fundamental characteristic underlying house-hold behavior, and not something some couples can do,and others cannot. A second interpretation is that allcouples bargain without commitment. The variation inoutcomes across couples is then explained by differ-ences in threat points in marital bargaining across ethnicgroups. To distinguish between these interpretations, weprovide evidence that within each ethnic group, howeach spouse's preference translates into outcomesdepends on the distribution of household bargainingpower. This is consistent with households bargainingwithout commitment.

The balance of evidence therefore suggests that allhouseholds bargain without commitment.

The paper makes three contributions to the literature.First, we develop and test a general model of householddecision making over fertility. The model makes precisehow spousal conflicts over desired fertility are resolved,and the role of commitment in marital bargaining. Non-commitment leads to marital bargains being subject toex post renegotiation which has both efficiency anddistributional consequences.

A second contribution is the explicit inclusion ofpreferences in a model of decision making over fertility.While many papers in the demographic literature haveshown a correlation between reported fertility prefer-ences and subsequent fertility outcomes, the interpreta-tion of those correlations has hitherto been far fromobvious. Moreover, by exploiting a data set containinginformation on each spouse's desired fertility we areable to perform direct tests of household bargainingmodels, rather than having to follow an inferentialapproach that has been previously used in the literature(Thomas, 1990).

Finally, we contribute to the literature on householddecision making. The benchmark model of household

behavior has been the unitary model (Becker, 1981).While this generates a rich set of predictions for priceand income effects on fertility, it remains silent onhow conflicts between spouses over fertility areresolved. Modelling fertility as the outcome of a bar-gaining process provides a natural way in which tointroduce conflicts. However, in contrast to existinghousehold bargaining models (Manser and Brown,1980; McElroy and Horney, 1981; Chiappori, 1988),we move away from the implicit assumption thathouseholds bargain with commitment, and do nottherefore assume households necessarily make effi-cient fertility decisions.

The paper is organized into five sections. Section 2develops the model of bargaining over fertility.Section 3 documents differences in marriage marketsacross ethnic groups in Malaysia, and describes theMFLS data. Section 4 presents the main results,additional evidence exploring further implications oftheory, and addresses econometric concerns. Section 5concludes.

2. A model of bargaining over fertility

We present a model of bargaining in marriage overfertility. This makes precise that the ability ofspouses to commit to ex ante agreements on fertility,affects how the fertility preferences of each spousetranslate into actual fertility outcomes. The mainintuitions can be grasped in the general frameworkpresented in Section 2.1. To then bring the theory tothe data, we move to specific functional forms inSection 2.2.

2.1. General payoffs

The household comprises a married husband (h) andwife (w). Spouse i's payoff in marriage, Ui, depends onthe following factors. First, there are some private gainsfrom marriage, vi. Second, there are other benefits frommarriage that depend both on the number of children, q,and the desired number of children, πi⁎, V

i(q, πi⁎). Bothspouses are therefore assumed to care about fertility,and in line with earlier literature, children are assumedto be a public good within marriage (Weiss and Willis,1985). Both spouses fertility preferences and privategains from marriage are assumed to be commonknowledge. The private gain is assumed transferableacross spouses. As a result, all divisions of the maritalsurplus are feasible.

We make a simplifying assumption that only thewife makes a sunk investment, q, to produce children.

Page 4: Household bargaining over fertility: Theory and evidence ...uctpimr/research/fertility_JDE.pdf · Household bargaining over fertility: Theory and ... This standard hold-up problem

6 Allowing husbands to also invest into producing children wouldalso force us to make additional assumptions on the production functionfor children. This raises further complications without providingadditional insights on the nature of marital bargaining. In the model

218 I. Rasul / Journal of Development Economics 86 (2008) 215–241

This leads to exactly q children being born ex post.Wives bear the cost of investing, c(q), where c(q) isnon-negative and convex. These costs include thosearising from the biology of child rearing, such as thetime devoted to pregnancy, childbirth, and lactationover the fertility period. Husband and wife's payoffs inmarriage are then given by;

Uh ¼h þVhðq; p⁎h Þ

Uw ¼w þVwðq; p⁎wÞ � cðqÞ:ð1Þ

If the marriage breaks up, the partners no longerobtain any private benefits from marriage. We alsoassume there is no childbearing outside of marriageso that women no longer incur the costs of pro-ducing children.4 Hence spouse i's payoff in single-hood is;

PU i ¼ P

V iðq; p⁎i Þ; ð2Þ

where q is the number of children, if any, producedduring marriage. There is assumed to be some gainto being married over being single, so there is apositive surplus to be bargained over.5

Although this framework generates a rich set ofpredictions on behavior, this comes at the cost of someconsiderable simplifications on real world aspects ofthe fertility process. It is important to be clear from theoutset on the robustness of the results to these sim-plifying assumptions.

First and foremost, husbands surely also makeinvestments into producing children. The aim of theanalysis is to understand how spouses' fertilitypreferences relate to fertility outcomes, and how therole of preferences changes depending on the abilityof spouses to commit to their actions within marriage.As detailed throughout, the qualitative nature of thesekey results is largely unchanged if both spouses caninvest. Moreover, as we assume all divisions of themarital surplus are feasible, the results are also robustto allowing spouses to share the costs of investinginto fertility. Indeed, with commitment in marriage,we show that the wife is fully compensated for

4 Births out-of-wedlock are almost non-existent in Malaysia overthe period of study.5 By revealed preference, these gains from marriage must exist. They

may arise from specialization in home andmarket production, economiesof scale, the provision of insurance, and risk sharing, among others.

her investment costs through transfers from herhusband.6

Second, deciding the number of children to have isan inherently dynamic decision making process. Wecapture such dynamics by considering two periods inmarriage — one at the start of marriage when fertilityinvestments are chosen, and one after these invest-ments are sunk, and bargaining takes place. Thepayoffs in marriage, U i, should therefore be thoughtof as the present value of benefits from marriage, andthe payoffs in singlehood,

PU i, should be thought of as

the present value of returning to the pool of singles andpotentially remarrying.

While this allows a direct mapping between the twoperiods in the theoretical analysis to the two periodsavailable in the data, this simplification raises otherissues such as the potential endogeneity of fertilitypreferences. This arises if for example parents updatetheir fertility preferences as they learn the true costsand benefits of children during marriage. We addressconcerns on the endogenous formation of preferencesin the empirical analysis.

Third, inevitably some aspects of household decisionmaking – such as the trade-off between child quantityand quality – are ignored altogether, both to maketractable the theoretical analysis, and because of datalimitations. Such extensions remain open for futureresearch.

With these caveats and concerns in mind, we nowturn to the analysis. We focus on highlighting the keyaspect of marital bargaining the model brings to the fore.Namely, the ability of spouses to commit to ex anteagreements on behavior within marriage affects howeach spouse's fertility preference translates into fertilityoutcomes.

2.1.1. Marriage with commitmentSuppose spouses are able to commit ex ante on their

behavior within marriage. Any future actions withinmarriage of either spouse can then be specified at anytime, including in a pre-marital contract. This implicit

of marriage developed here, it is as if the wife always retains access tosome hidden action, such as contraceptive use, that allows her touniquely control her fertility level. The husband can then only provideincentives to his wife to change her fertility level through the use oftransfers in marital bargaining, not physical coercion. This justificationalso fits the relevant empirical facts — contraceptives have beenavailable in Malaysia since the 1960s, and a quarter of women in oursample report having used them.

Page 5: Household bargaining over fertility: Theory and evidence ...uctpimr/research/fertility_JDE.pdf · Household bargaining over fertility: Theory and ... This standard hold-up problem

219I. Rasul / Journal of Development Economics 86 (2008) 215–241

contract specifies investments into fertility, and transfersacross spouses in marriage once fertility investments aresunk. In a world of commitment, this agreement isassumed enforceable at any stage of marriage.

The relevant outside option for couples at the time ofagreeing on such a marital contract, is to separate beforeinvestments into fertility are undertaken and children areborn. The payoff to spouse i in the case of a breakdownin marital bargaining is then

PV ið0; p⁎i Þ. This outside

option may depend on opportunities for remarriage, butis independent of the number of children in the currentmarriage as these investments have not yet beenundertaken.

We can now determine the equilibrium fertility andtransfers. To first pin down the transfers across partners,we assume spouses Nash bargain over the division of themarital surplus. We denote the bargaining power ofhusbands as θ and the transfer as t. The transfer isdefined to be positive if it is from husband to wife. Theequilibrium Nash bargained transfer, when ex anteagreements can be committed to, tC, is therefore givenby;

tC ¼ ð1� hÞ½th þ Vhðq; p⁎h Þ �PV

hð0; p⁎h Þ�� h½tw þ Vwðq; p⁎wÞ �

PV wð0; p⁎wÞ � cðqÞ�: ð3Þ

The transfer a spouse receives increases in their ownbargaining power. If one spouse retains all thebargaining power, they appropriate the entire maritalsurplus and their partner remains indifferent betweenhaving q children in marriage and remaining single withno children. Note that the transfer fully compensates thewife for her costs of investing.7

The spouse that, for a given fertility preference, gainsmore from having children in marriage relative toremaining single without children, transfers more totheir partner, other things equal. Hence the pre-maritalcontract accounts for differences in fertility preferencesacross spouses.

The wife chooses her investment to maximize herex ante payoff, taking account of the transfers shereceives;

maxq

tw þ Vwðq; p⁎wÞ þ tC � cðqÞ: ð4Þ

7 A woman's bargaining power will depend on her attractivenessin the marriage market. This in turn depends partly on her futurefecundity and quality as a mother. As transfers to the wife increasein her bargaining power, this captures the intuition that withcommitment, women that are more attractive in the marriage marketare able to negotiate pre-marital contracts that are more attractive tothem.

Husbands' fertility preferences therefore influencefertility outcomes through their effect on transferswithin marriage. Substituting in for tC, it is straight-forward to show the equilibrium number of childrenwhen ex ante agreements can be committed to, qC,satisfies the standard Lindahl–Samuelson conditionfor public goods;8

Vhq ðqC; p⁎h Þ þ Vw

q ðqC; p⁎wÞ ¼ c VðqCÞ: ð5Þ

This result that marital bargaining leads to anefficient outcome is a straightforward application ofthe Coase theorem. To summarize;

Result 1. With commitment in marriage, investmentsinto fertility are efficient. Both spouses' preferences areweighted in determining the equilibrium number ofchildren.

Spousal preferences determine the fertility out-comes through their effect on the payoff withinmarriage, Vi(.). The relationship between preferencesand payoffs in the case of a breakdown in maritalbargaining,

PV ið:Þ, is irrelevant in determining the

equilibrium fertility level when ex ante agreementscan be committed to. Note finally that the equilibriumfertility level is independent of the distribution ofbargaining shares across spouses. All of these featuresof the model will be exploited later in the empiricalanalysis.9

2.1.2. Marriage without commitmentWe now consider a world in which ex ante agree-

ments on behavior in marriage cannot be committedto. Such future actions may relate to investments intochild quality for example. While these future actionscan certainly be discussed, they cannot be committedto ex ante. Non-commitment may stem from actionsbeing neither observable nor verifiable. It will not thenbe possible to write an agreement based on thembecause such contracts are not enforceable by thirdparties outside the household. Alternatively, some

8 Hence when there is commitment in marriage, it is as if thewife chooses her investment to maximize the total marital surplus,Uh+Uw−U– h−U–w. This is in line with a unitary model of householddecision making.9 This is an application of the results in Bergstrom and Cornes

(1983). They show the Pareto optimal level of public goods provisionis independent of the distribution of resources for the class of utilityfunctions Ui(.) considered here.

Page 6: Household bargaining over fertility: Theory and evidence ...uctpimr/research/fertility_JDE.pdf · Household bargaining over fertility: Theory and ... This standard hold-up problem

220 I. Rasul / Journal of Development Economics 86 (2008) 215–241

actions may be time inconsistent, or not credible inlight of unanticipated shocks.10

The main insight for household decision makingover fertility when actions cannot be committed to, isthat marital bargains are then subject to ex postrenegotiation after fertility investments are sunk.Spouses cannot credibly commit not to renegotiate.Ex post renegotiation over the marital surplusprevents the wife from appropriating the full marginalbenefit of her ex ante fertility investment. This altersthe wife's investment incentives. This has conse-quences both for the efficiency of household deci-sions, as well as the distribution of resources acrossspouses.

The household therefore faces a standard hold-upproblem (Grossman and Hart, 1986; Hart and Moore,1990). As is well recognized, these general implicationsof non-commitment would remain if we modelled bothspouses as making fertility investments.11

To see the implications for household outcomeswhen couples bargain without commitment, we need tospecify spousal payoffs if bargaining breaks down.Given that bargaining takes place after investments aremade, spouse i's payoff in this case is

PV

iðq; p⁎i Þ. Theinterpretation of this payoff depends on the relevantthreat point in marriage.

It is standard in the literature on household bargain-ing to assume the threat point in marriage is divorce. Ifso, Vi(q, πi⁎) captures the present value of returning tothe pool of singles and potentially remarrying. Thisvalue depends on both the number of children from thecurrent marriage and fertility preferences. If divorce isnot a credible threat, an alternative interpretation is thatVi(q, πi⁎) captures the value of some non-cooperativeoutcome within marriage. Again this will in generaldepend on the number of children from the currentmarriage and fertility preferences. As discussed in moredetail later, both cases will be relevant in the Malaysiancontext.12

10 Unanticipated shocks to bargaining power may be relevant forMalaysia during the period of study, when the economy experiencedrapid economic growth that led to rising female wages relative to malewages for example.11 A case in which renegotiation would have no affect on ex anteinvestments would be if one partner could make take-it-or-leave-itoffers during the renegotiation period. This is unlikely to be the casein marital bargaining where both spouses retain some bargainingpower in marriage.12 In either case the properties of Vi(q, πi⁎) may depend on whetherthe number of children q is greater than or less than the spouse'sdesired fertility, πi⁎.

We are now able to solve for the equilibrium transfersand fertility level. We solve the model backwards,considering first transfers in marriage. These aredetermined in a similar fashion as in the model of mar-riage with commitment. The key difference with non-commitment is that the relevant threat point in bargainingis Vi(q, πi⁎), and the wife no longer recovers her sunkcosts of investment. The equilibrium Nash bargainedtransfer with non-commitment, tNC, then is;

tNC ¼ ð1� hÞ½th þ Vhðq; p⁎h Þ �PV

hðq; p⁎h Þ�� h½tw þ Vwðq; p⁎wÞ �

PV

wðq; p⁎wÞ�: ð6Þ

As in a world of commitment, the division of themarital surplus depends both on the distribution ofbargaining power across spouses, and on how fertilitypreferences determine each spouse's gains from mar-riage. We now solve for the equilibrium fertilityoutcome.

With non-commitment, the wife anticipates renego-tiation later in marriage. She therefore chooses herinvestment to maximize her ex ante payoff;

maxq

tw þ Vwðq; p⁎wÞ þ tNC � cðqÞ: ð7Þ

Substituting Eq. (6) into Eq. (7) and maximizing withrespect to q, the equilibrium fertility level with non-commitment, qNC, then satisfies the following firstorder condition;13

ð1� hÞ½Vhq ðqNC; p⁎h Þ þ Vw

q ðqNC; p⁎wÞ� þ ½hPV wq ðqNC; p⁎wÞ

�ð1� hÞPV hqðqNC; p⁎h Þ� ¼ c VðqNCÞ: ð8Þ

This highlights two incentives the wife has to investinto fertility. First, she seeks to maximize the totalpayoff in marriage as in the case of commitment inmarriage. This is captured in the first term on the LHS.Second, if on the margin, the wife's payoff whenbargaining breaks down, is increasing relative to herhusbands, so that

PV

wq ð:Þ >

PV

hqð:Þ, this increases the

share of the marital surplus the wife appropriates inrenegotiation. This increases her incentives to invest,

13 If the wife were able to recover some fraction τ of her investmentcosts, this would add a −τθc′(q) term to the RHS of Eq. (8). Thiswould not alter the main insights of the model.

Page 7: Household bargaining over fertility: Theory and evidence ...uctpimr/research/fertility_JDE.pdf · Household bargaining over fertility: Theory and ... This standard hold-up problem

14 If both partners can invest, then it can either be the case thath V w

q ðq; p⁎wÞzð1� hÞ V hqðq;p⁎hÞ; or; h V w

q ðq; p⁎wÞVð1� hÞ V hqðq;p⁎hÞ.

Hence it remains possible that one spouse invests more than in aworld with commitment, and the other invests less. Whether this leadsto overinvestment depends on the assumptions made on thetechnology with which children are produced. By focusing on thecase with one investor we avoid such complications without losing thefundamental insight of the bargaining model. Namely that with non-commitment, fertility levels can be inefficiently high if by havingmore children, one spouse is able to obtain a sufficiently greater shareof the marital surplus in renegotiation, other things equal.

221I. Rasul / Journal of Development Economics 86 (2008) 215–241

other things equal. This is captured in the second termon the LHS.

As in the case where spouses can commit to ex anteagreements, both spouses' fertility preferences determinethe equilibrium number of children with non-commit-ment. However, in contrast to the case of commitment, theweight placed on each spouses preferences depends ontheir payoff if bargaining breaks down, and on theirbargaining power. Hence even if spouses have identicalpreferences, and derive the same benefits from children inmarriage and when bargaining breaks down, the effecteach spouse's preference has on the fertility outcome stillneed not be the same. This result occurs despite the factthat only the wife is modelled to make fertilityinvestments. The result stems from non-commitment inmarriage, and this insight would be retained even if bothpartners are allowed to invest.

Comparison of the first order conditions (5) and (8)further reveals that fertility levels with non-commitmentgenerally diverge from the efficient levels achieved withcommitment.

Result 2. With non-commitment in marriage, invest-ments into fertility are inefficient. Both spouses'preferences are weighted in determining the equilibriumnumber of children. The weight placed on eachspouse's preference is partly determined by their payoffif bargaining breaks down and their bargaining power.

Results 1 and 2 highlight the different determinantsof fertility outcomes depending on whether householdscan or cannot bargain with commitment. In addition, acomparison of the maximization problems (4) and (7)also reveals when non-commitment leads to over-investment in fertility. This is so if the transfer to thewife increases more quickly as she invests, than does thehusband's benefits from children in marriage, so thatAtNCAq > Vh

q ð:Þ. In other words;

Result 3. With non-commitment, overinvestment intofertility occurs if;

½hPV wq ðq; p⁎wÞ � ð1� hÞPV h

qðq; p⁎h Þ� > h½Vhq ðq; p⁎h Þ

þVwq ðq; p⁎wÞ�: ð9Þ

The LHS of Eq. (9) captures the investmentincentives of the wife arising from her capturing agreater share of the marital surplus during renegotiation.The RHS captures the marginal change in total gainsfrom children in marriage. Hence overinvestment occursif the investing partner appropriates a sufficientlygreater share of the marital surplus as a result. Allowing

spouses to share investment costs would not reverse theresult, and may make overinvestment more likely.14

2.2. Specific payoffs

We now specify function forms for payoffs inmarriage and if marital bargaining breaks down. Thisallows us to move towards an empirical specificationthat nests within it, both models of marital bargaining,and to tailor the model to capture some importantfeatures across ethnic groups in Malaysia that we exploitempirically.

Assumption 1. The payoff to spouses in marriage are;

Uh ¼h þ/ðqÞ � 12ðq� p⁎h Þ2

Uw ¼w þ/ðqÞ � 12ð1� p⁎wÞ2 � cðqÞ

ð10Þ

The first term υi, denotes the private benefit to i frommarriage. The second term ϕ(q), captures in reducedform, the present value of the benefits from children,with ϕ(q) assumed concave. The third term captureshow fertility preferences enter spousal payoffs inmarriage. We consider an intuitive case in whichspouses suffer a loss in utility if they do not achievetheir preferred fertility level, all else equal. The utilityloss increases in the divergence between fertilityoutcomes and preferences. The final term for the wifec(q), captures the costs she incurs of having children.

Assumption 2. The payoff to spouse i if marital bar-gaining breaks down is;

PUi ¼ di/ðqÞ � gi

2ðq� p⁎h Þ2 ð11Þ

If bargaining breaks down, spouses lose the privatebenefits of marriage. The benefits from children areassumed (weakly) lower if marital bargaining breaksdown. The precise interpretation of the (δi, ηi) param-eters depends on what the relevant threat point in maritalbargaining is.

Page 8: Household bargaining over fertility: Theory and evidence ...uctpimr/research/fertility_JDE.pdf · Household bargaining over fertility: Theory and ... This standard hold-up problem

222 I. Rasul / Journal of Development Economics 86 (2008) 215–241

Suppose couples divorce if marital bargaining breaksdown. The δi parameters can then be interpreted asrelating to the share of child custody enjoyed by spousei, so that δi≤1.15 Having divorced, partners are free toremarry. Partners no longer suffer disutility from anydivergence between their fertility preference and thenumber of children in the previous marriage, as they arefree to pursue their fertility goals with future marriagepartners. Hence with divorce as the relevant threat pointto marital bargaining, ηi=0.

Suppose divorce is not a credible threat, so the relevantthreat point in marital bargaining is for couples to reachsome non-cooperative outcome within marriage. The δiparameters then capture the fact that the value of benefitsfrom children may be lower if they are brought up in ahousehold where parents conflict but do not divorce, sothat δi≤1.Moreover, as partners are unable to pursue theirfertility goals with other marriage partners, they continueto suffer a loss from not having achieved their desiredfertility level in the current marriage, so that ηi=1.

16

We now use these specific payoffs to make precisehow the ability of spouses to commit to ex ante agree-ments on fertility, affects how each spouse's fertilitypreference translates both into fertility outcomes, andtransfers across spouses in marriage.

2.2.1. Marriage with commitmentSuppose spouses bargain with commitment. Sub-

stituting the specific payoffs into Eq. (5), the equili-brium fertility level with commitment, qC, then satisfiesthe following first order condition;

qC ¼ 12ðp⁎h þ p⁎wÞ þ / VðqCÞ � 1

2c VðqCÞ ð12Þ

A number of implications follow. First, spousalpreferences have equal weight in determining fertilityoutcomes. The divergence in preferences plays no rolein determining the fertility outcome. Even if spousesconflict over desired fertility levels, it is the average of

15 This functional form captures a number of different ways to viewthe benefits from children in divorce. First, if children are a pureprivate good in divorce, δi relates to the fraction of the children's timeendowment that is spent with spouse i, so that δh+δw=1. Second, ifchildren are an impure public good in divorce, then δi captures boththe time spent with spouse i as well as the benefits obtained fromchildren per se, so that δi≤1. Third, if children are a pure public goodin marriage and divorce, then δh=δw=1.16 In general, there is no reason to suppose these are the only threatpoints or interpretations that can be given. However, these twoscenarios are found to be empirically relevant, and so we focus onthem primarily to keep clear the exposition. In general, the ηi

parameters merely capture the extent to which preferences over thedesired number of children still matter ex post.

these preferences that will, in part, determine the fertilityoutcome. Hence in line with a unitary model of thehousehold, it is as if the household has a unique fertilitypreference given by the average of spouse's preferences.However, whether the equilibrium number of childrenactually lies above or below the average of spousalpreferences, is ambiguous and depends on the sign of/ Vð:Þ � 1

2c V :ð Þ.17

Second, spouses' payoffs if bargaining breaks downdo not affect how each spouse's preference translatesinto fertility outcomes, so qC is independent of the(δi, ηi) parameters. The fertility outcome is alsoindependent of the distribution of bargaining power.The Nash bargained transfer across spouses is derivedby substituting the specific payoffs into Eq. (3);

tC ¼ ð1� hÞth � htw þ 12hðqC � p⁎wÞ2

� 12ð1� hÞðqC � p⁎hÞ2 þ

gh2ð1� hÞp⁎2h

� gw2hp⁎2w þ ðhdw � ð1� hÞdhÞ/ð0Þ

þ ð1� 2hÞ/ðqCÞ þ hcðqCÞ ð13Þ

The transfer depends on the private gains inmarriage, the divergences between fertility outcomesand preferences, preferences themselves, and the costand benefits of children in marriage.18

2.2.2. Marriage without commitmentSuppose spouses bargain without commitment.The

equilibrium fertility level without commitment, qNC,then satisfies the following first order condition;

c VðqNCÞ ¼ ½1� hð1� gwÞ�p⁎w þ ½ð1� hÞð1� ghÞ�p⁎hþ ½ð1� hÞgh � hgw � 2ð1� hÞ�qNCþ ½2ð1� hÞ þ hdw � ð1� hÞdh�/ VðqNCÞ

ð14Þ

The equilibrium fertility level depends on bothspouses' preferences, although not necessarily with the

17 The bargaining framework therefore implies deviations betweenfertility outcomes and the average of spousal preferences need notarise because of mistakes, or unmet demand for contraception. Thefact that fertility outcomes diverge from average spousal desires is anempirical regularity that holds in both developed and developingcountries (Bongaarts, 2001).18 The reason why fertility preferences matter directly is becausewith commitment, the relevant outside option that couples face at thetime of agreeing on the marital contract, is to separate beforeinvestments into fertility are undertaken and children are born. HenceU

i ¼ di/ð0Þ � gi2 ð0� p⁎i Þ2.

Page 9: Household bargaining over fertility: Theory and evidence ...uctpimr/research/fertility_JDE.pdf · Household bargaining over fertility: Theory and ... This standard hold-up problem

19 There are an insufficient number of Indian households in theMFLS data to use them for the analysis.

223I. Rasul / Journal of Development Economics 86 (2008) 215–241

same weight. In particular, spouses' payoffs if bargain-ing breaks down affect how each spouse's preferencetranslates into fertility outcomes, so qNC depends on the(δi, ηi) parameters, as well as on the distribution ofbargaining power.

Suppose first the relevant threat point in maritalbargaining is to divorce so that ηh=ηw=0. In this case,and only in this case, both spouse's preferences haveequalweight in determining fertility outcomes. The actualweight attached to each spouse's preference is determinedby the distribution of bargaining power in marriage.

Now suppose the relevant threat point in maritalbargaining is some non-cooperative outcome withinmarriage so that ηh=ηw=1. In this case, and only in thiscase, the wife's preference alone has some positiveweight attached to it in determining the fertility outcome.The husband's preference does not determine the fertilityoutcome. Moreover, the effect of the wife's fertilitypreference is independent of her bargaining power. In amore general settingwhen both spouses invest, as long asthe wife's investment into fertility is relatively moreimportant than her husbands, her preference will alwaysmatter more than her husband's for fertility outcomes.

Finally, the Nash bargained transfers are;

tNC ¼ ð1� hÞth � htw þ ðð1� hÞð1� dhÞ� hð1� dwÞÞ/ðqNCÞ� 12ð1� hÞð1� ghÞðqNC � p⁎h Þ2

þ 12hð1� gwÞðqNC � p⁎wÞ2 ð15Þ

These transfers depend on the private gains inmarriage, the benefits from children in marriage, andthe divergence between fertility outcomes and prefer-ences. If the relevant threat point in marital bargaining isto divorce so ηh=ηw=0, the transfer from husband towife decreases as the divergence between fertilityoutcomes and his preference increases. Similarly, thetransfer increases as the divergence between fertilityoutcomes and his wife's preference increases.

Intuitively, when divorce is the relevant threat point,the surplus to be bargained over itself depends on thedivergence between fertility outcomes and both spouses'preferences. Hence the transfer across spouses takesaccount of these divergences, and this in turn ensuresboth spousal preferences influence fertility outcomes.

If the relevant threat point is some non-cooperativeoutcome, the surplus to be bargained over is not determinedby the divergence in fertility outcomes and preferences.These divergences do not then influence ex post transfers,and only the wife's preference drives fertility outcomes.

Note finally that by substituting the specific payoffsinto the condition for overinvestment, Eq. (9), we cannotrule out that with non-commitment, there is over-investment into fertility relative to the benchmark caseof commitment in marriage.

2.3. Summary

Table 1 summarizes the predictions from theory. Wedo this both for the case when spouses can commit to exante agreements on fertility, and when they cannot, andhow each of these change depending on the threat pointin marital bargaining. In each case we highlight how —(i) fertility outcomes relate to the fertility preferences ofeach spouse, and if this depends on the distribution ofbargaining power; (ii) transfers from husband to wifedepend on the divergence between fertility outcomesand the preferences of each spouse, and again if thisdepends on the distribution of bargaining power; (iii)transfers depend directly on fertility preferences.

The model provides a rich set of testable predictionsto take to data. In the remainder of the paper, we focuson the empirical relation between fertility preferencesand fertility outcomes, using the set of predictionssummarized in the top half of Table 1 to shed light on theunderlying nature of household bargaining. Reliabledata on transfers between spouses however remainsrelatively scarce in nearly all household surveys. Hencewe do not take this aspect of the theory to the data, andas such, this awaits future research.

3. Empirical analysis

3.1. Background and data

Malaysia is an ethnically diverse society — Malaysaccount for 58% of the population, Chinese 26%,Indians 7%, and others 9%. We exploit differencesbetween the marriage markets of the Malay and Chineseethnic groups to help identify the underlying model ofmarital bargaining.19

We first present evidence on two aggregate demo-graphic trends. Fig. 1 shows for Malaysia, the timeseries for the fertility rate, defined as the number of livebirths per female, and the infant mortality rate, definedas the number of infant deaths per 1000 births. Toprovide some context for these figures, we also show thesame series for Indonesia and the US.

Page 10: Household bargaining over fertility: Theory and evidence ...uctpimr/research/fertility_JDE.pdf · Household bargaining over fertility: Theory and ... This standard hold-up problem

224I.Rasul

/Journal

ofDevelopm

entEconom

ics86

(2008)215–241

Table 1Predictions of the Bargaining Model on Fertility Outcomes and Transfers Across Spouses

Variable Marriage with commitment Marriage without commitment

Threat point in marital bargaining: V i(0, πi⁎) Threat point in marital bargaining: V i(q, πi

⁎)

Divorce(Malays)

Non-cooperation within marriage(Chinese)

Divorce(Malays)

Non-cooperation within marriage(Chinese)

Fertility outcomes ηi=0 ηi=1 ηi=0 ηi=1

Wife's fertility preference πw⁎ 1/2 1/2 1Husband's fertility preference πh⁎ 1/2 1/2 1−θ 0

Transfers across spousesDivergence between fertility outcome and wife's fertility preference (q−πw⁎)2 1/2θ 1/2θ 1/2θ 0Divergence between fertility outcome and husband's fertility preference (q−πh⁎)2 −1/2 (1−θ) −1 /2 (1−θ) −1/2 (1−θ) 0Wife's fertility preference squared πh⁎

2 0 −1/2 0 0Husband's fertility preference squared πh⁎

2 0

Using the specific payoffs in Eqs. (10) and (11) in the main text, the general first order conditions for fertility outcomes, and transfers across spouses, are as follows.Marriage with commitmentFertility outcome, qC, satisfies thefirst order condition: qC ¼ 1

2ðp⁎h þ p⁎wÞ þ u VðqCÞ � 1

2c VðqCÞ

Transfer, tC:tC ¼ ð1� hÞth � htw þ ðhdw � ð1� hÞdhÞuð0Þ þ 1

2hðqC � p⁎wÞ2 �

12ð1� hÞðqC � p⁎h Þ2 þ

gh2ð1� hÞp⁎2h � gw

2hp⁎2w þ ð1� 2hÞuðqCÞ þ hcðqÞ

Marriage without commitmentFertility outcome, qNC, satisfies thefirst order condition:

c VðqNCÞ ¼ ð2ð1� hÞ þ hdw � ð1� hÞdhÞu VðqNCÞ þ ð1� hÞð1� ghÞp⁎h þ ð1� hð1� gwÞÞp⁎w þ ðð1� hÞgh � hgw � 2ð1� hÞÞqNC

Transfer, tNC:tNC ¼ ð1� hÞth � htw þ ðð1� hÞð1� dhÞ � hdwÞuðqNCÞ � ð1� ghÞ

2ð1� hÞðqNC � p⁎wÞ2 þ

ð1� gwÞ2

hðqNC � p⁎wÞ2

For the fertility equation, the table reports the coefficients on each spouse's fertility preference in each model of bargaining.For the transfers equation, we report the coefficients on the divergence between fertility outcomes and fertility preferences of each spouses, and on fertility preferences directly.On the threat points in marital bargaining, if the relevant outside option is to divorce, ηh=ηw=0. This characterizes marriage markets among Malays in Malaysia. If the relevant threat point is somenon-cooperative outcome within marriage, ηh=ηw=0. This characterizes marriage markets for the Chinese in Malaysia.

1−θ

1/2 (1−θ ) 0 0

Page 11: Household bargaining over fertility: Theory and evidence ...uctpimr/research/fertility_JDE.pdf · Household bargaining over fertility: Theory and ... This standard hold-up problem

Fig. 1. Aggregate demographic trends.

21 The divorce rate is defined as the number of divorcees per thousandpopulation aged 15 and over. This measure understates the true divorcerate in the US as individuals marry at an older age compared to inMalaysia. Similarly, the measure understates the true divorce rate inPeninsular Malaysia in later periods relative to early periods because

225I. Rasul / Journal of Development Economics 86 (2008) 215–241

Malaysia's fertility rate has been in decline since the1960s, although during the period we focus on between1976 and 1988, it was relatively stable at around 4 birthsper female. Within ethnic groups, the fertility rate forMalays fell from 5.9 to 4.5 between 1958 and 1983. Thisis a smaller fall than for other ethnic groups over thesame period, and one that is largely attributed to risingage at marriage for Malay women, from 17 in 1950 to 22in 1985. For example for the Chinese over the sameperiod, the decline in fertility rates was from 6.5 to 2.7(Jones, 1994).

An implicit assumption made in the bargainingmodels in Section 2 is that spouses face no uncertaintyover how many of their children survive into adulthood.In support of this note that infant mortality has been inlong run decline in Malaysia, and historically, it has alsobeen lower than in many comparable developingcountries. For example infant mortality rates inIndonesia have typically been more than double thosein Malaysia. Indeed, by the late 1980s, infant mortalityin Malaysia was at levels comparable to those in the USin the early 1960s.20

20 Jones (1994) also documents the sharp reduction in child mortalityrates thatMalaysia experienced during the 1960s. In our data, the numberof children ever born has a correlation coefficient of .95 with the numberof pregnancies, further suggesting parents face little uncertainty over thelikelihood of survival for their children.

3.1.1. Ethnicity and marriage marketsA key difference between Malays and Chinese in

Malaysia lies in how their marriage markets operate.Since the 1940s, Malays have had one of the highestdivorce rates in the world (Jones, 1981, 1994). Table 2compares divorce rates over the period 1965–1985 forMalays in PeninsularMalaysia, forMuslims in Indonesia,and for the United States.21

Two points are of note. First, the divorce rate inMalaysia in the 1960s and 1970s is comparable to thedivorce rate in the US today. Clearly, divorce is a crediblethreat among married Malay couples. Second, highdivorce rates appear to be a characteristic particular tothe ethnic group of Malays, and not a feature of theeconomic environment faced by Malays in Malaysia.Muslims in Indonesia –who are predominantly ethnically

the median age at marriage for Malays has been rising. However, asshown in Fig. 2, the comparison across countries remains unchanged ifthe number of currentlymarried is used as the denominator. The declinein divorce rates amongMalays from 1965 to 1985 may be explained bythe rise in educational attainment for bothmen and women inMalaysia,coupled with rising ages at first marriage.

Page 12: Household bargaining over fertility: Theory and evidence ...uctpimr/research/fertility_JDE.pdf · Household bargaining over fertility: Theory and ... This standard hold-up problem

Table 2Divorce rates 1965–1985

Malays in peninsularMalaysia

IndonesianMuslims

UnitedStates

1965 7.4 11 3.51970 6.1 5.2 4.81975 5.6 4.6 6.31980 3.9 2.6 6.71985 2.8 1.5 6.3

Notes: The source for this table is Jones (1994). The divorce rate isdefined as the number of divorcees per thousand of the populationaged 15 and over.

24 The Malaysian Marriage Survey (1984) reports that 55% ofchildren involved in divorce reside with their mothers, 19% stay withtheir fathers, and 13% reside with both parents in some form of joint

226 I. Rasul / Journal of Development Economics 86 (2008) 215–241

Malay – have divorce rates comparable to Malays inPeninsular Malaysia.

Fig. 2 sheds light on the levels of turnover in theMalay marriage market, and how this varies by region.This shows the ratio of divorces to marriages forMalays, by state, for 1950–7 and 1972–6. This divorcepropensities in the Malay marriage market increasedbetween the 1950s and 1970s. By the 1970s, these levelsof turnover in marriage markets are higher than thoseever witnessed in the United States over the pastgeneration.

Two other features of the bargaining models devel-oped also closely approximate how Malay marriagemarkets operate in practice. First, despite high divorcerates, first marriages are not just trial relationships —children are typically born into these marriages. Hencethe marital surplus to be bargained over ex post dependson ex ante fertility choices.22 Second, ethnographicevidence suggests that both spouses are able to dissolvea marriage.23

The fact that divorce is a credible threat amongMalays further implies that the allocation of childcustody determines spousal payoffs if marital bargain-ing breaks down. If couples bargain without commit-ment, the allocation of child custody will therefore inpart, determine investments into fertility. A concern forthe empirical analysis is that the allocation of childcustody varies across households and may be correlated

22 Hirschman and Teerawichitchainan (2003) provide evidence onthe determinants of marital dissolution in Malay households using1970 census data. They show that the timing of first births is asignificant determinant of marital dissolution so that the allocation ofcustody is relevant for divorcing Malay couples.23 While official records show that men initiate the majority ofdivorces, ethnographic evidence suggests that in practice, womentypically instigate divorce (Rudie, 1983; Jones, 1981). Malay womenhave historically had considerable autonomy with regards to marriagepartner, household decisions within marriage, and the decision todivorce (Swift, 1965; Kuchiba et al., 1979).

with parental fertility preferences. However, in practice,children tend to reside with their mothers, regardless ofage or gender (Jones, 1981, 1994).24

In contrast toMalays, divorce is extremely rare amongthe Chinese in Malaysia. As documented by Hirschmanand Teerawichitchainan (2003), the probability of divorcein the first 5 years of marriage among Chinese has beenless than 2% for all cohorts married since the 1940s. Notonly is this orders of magnitude smaller than amongMalays, but also smaller than for any other ethnic groupin South East Asia.25

3.1.2. Data and key variablesWe use the Malaysian Family Life Survey (MFLS)

for the empirical analysis. This is two-wave householdpanel, collected in 1976/7 (MFLS-1) and 1988/9(MFLS-2). The MFLS-1 sample consists of householdswith an ever-married woman aged 50 or below, and isrepresentative of Peninsular Malaysia in 1976. Bothspouses are interviewed in each wave. The surveycollects detailed current and retrospective informationon fertility preferences, fertility outcomes, individualand household characteristics. The key variables for theanalysis are as follows.

3.1.3. Fertility preferencesIn MFLS-1 both spouses were asked, “suppose you

could start your married life all over again and youcould decide what children to have. How many child-ren would you want?” We use the response to measureeach spouses' desired number of children, πi⁎. How-ever, as we discuss in detail later, there are concerns asto whether this is a reliable measure of innate pref-erences. This is however perhaps the most accuratemeasure of innate preferences that can ever be expectedfrom survey data.26

custody (Tan and Jones, 1990). Fathers are required by Islamic law topay maintenance in divorce. In practice, the incidence of fatherspaying is less than universal. Tan and Jones (1990) report 59% ofhusbands never pay maintenance.25 Similar evidence for later periods on these differences in divorcerates across ethnic groups is presented using alternative data sourcesin Tan (1988) and Jones (1994).26 If the intent of the question was understood and followed byrespondents, they should report the number of wanted children, andnot the number of expected children. Furthermore, the questionnairewas administered in one of ten languages, further reducing thepossibility of misinterpretation. Less than 1% of households did notrespond to the question.

Page 13: Household bargaining over fertility: Theory and evidence ...uctpimr/research/fertility_JDE.pdf · Household bargaining over fertility: Theory and ... This standard hold-up problem

Fig. 2. Ratio of Malay divorces (net of revocations) to marriages, by State in Peninsular Malaysia. Source: Jones (1994).

227I.Rasul

/Journal

ofDevelopm

entEconom

ics86

(2008)215–241

Page 14: Household bargaining over fertility: Theory and evidence ...uctpimr/research/fertility_JDE.pdf · Household bargaining over fertility: Theory and ... This standard hold-up problem

Table 3Descriptive statistics on fertility preferences and fertility outcomes

Malay households Chinese households

Husband Wife Test ofequality(p-value)

Husband Wife Test ofEquality(p-value)

Fertility preferences by ethnicity and gender (mean and 95% confidence interval)Number of children desired in total 4.97 4.60 .0161 4.33 4.05 .0249

[4.72, 5.22] [4.42, 4.77] [4.16, 4.52] [3.88, 4.22]Number of boys desired 2.48 2.25 .0114 2.27 2.14 .1219

[2.37, 2.63] [2.24, 2.43] [2.15, 2.39] [2.03, 2.26]Number of girls desired 2.16 2.20 .7068 1.96 1.83 .0713

[2.03, 2.28] [2.10, 2.31] [1.85, 2.07] [1.73, 1.92]

Fertility outcomes by ethnicity (mean and 95% confidence interval)Fertility outcome (MFLS-2) 6.38 5.79

[6.11, 6.64] [5.41, 6.16]Number of childrenever born in MFLS-1

3.46 4.15[3.25, 3.67] [3.85, 4.45]

Notes: Sample households are those used for the fertility regressions. Tests of equality are across gender, within ethnicity. Tests of equality of meansand proportions all have two-sided alternative hypotheses. For all tests, we do not impose the restriction that the samples have the same variance or arepaired. All fertility preferences are expressed in MFLS-1. The desired number of boys and girls does not sum to the total number of children desiredbecause spouses were also asked the number of children they wanted whose gender was undecided.

228 I. Rasul / Journal of Development Economics 86 (2008) 215–241

3.1.4. Fertility outcomesWe use the number of children alive in MFLS-2 as a

measure of the fertility outcome. Hence fertility out-comes are measured 12 years after fertility preferencesare expressed. The average age of women in MFLS-2 is47 years. Census data confirms that 98% of women thisage have completed their fertility period, so thatcensoring of fertility outcomes is not a major concern.27

Amore substantive worry is that at the time ofMFLS-1, women were in the middle of their fertility period.Hence fertility preferences may be endogenous to thestage of the fertility period the couple are at. This occursfor example if spouses learn the true costs and benefits ofchildren over time. We later address econometricconcerns arising from the endogeneity of preferences.

On the other hand, because in the MFLS-1 samplewomen are already some way into their fertility period,then in line with the model of marital bargaining, someinvestments into fertility have been sunk, and there isscope for renegotiation over the division of the maritalsurplus.

The sample of households used for the main analysisare husband and wife pairs that satisfy three criteria —(i) both fertility preferences, fertility outcomes, andother variables used in the main analysis are reported;

27 The majority of women in the sample also considered theirfertility period over by MFLS-2, either because of menopause orsterilization.

(ii) both report being fertile and resident in thehousehold in MFLS-1; (iii) were continuously marriedbetween the two waves. This last restriction appliesbecause in the models developed, all couples remainmarried in equilibrium. Although threat points in maritalbargaining influence household outcomes, the theorypredicts that no couples actually experience a break-down in bargaining in equilibrium. Hence it is exactlythose households in the data that bargain and allocate themarriage surplus so as to remain married, that the theoryapplies to. There are 472 Malay couples, and 220Chinese couples that satisfy these criteria.

3.2. Descriptives

3.2.1. Fertility preferencesTable 3 presents descriptive statistics on fertility

preferences, split by spouse and ethnicity. A strikingresult that emerges is the degree of conflict over pref-erences over fertility within couples. Among Malays,husband's desire significantly more children than theirwives. This difference is largely driven by husbandsdesiring more sons than their wives. Overall, aroundtwo thirds of Malay couples report disagreements onfertility preferences.

Although Chinese households desire slightly fewerchildren than do Malays, there remain significantdifferences in the fertility preferences of husbands andtheir wives. Unlike for Malays, this difference is driven

Page 15: Household bargaining over fertility: Theory and evidence ...uctpimr/research/fertility_JDE.pdf · Household bargaining over fertility: Theory and ... This standard hold-up problem

229I. Rasul / Journal of Development Economics 86 (2008) 215–241

largely by husbands desiring more daughters than theirwives. Overall, just over half the Chinese couples reportdisagreements on fertility preferences.

These significant differences in preferences withinhouseholds occur despite the fact that these householdsremain married over the two MFLS waves, and thesample sizes are relatively small.28

To see more clearly the extent of conflict overfertility within each household, Fig. 3 graphs for eachethnic group, a two-way frequency distribution forhusband and wife's preferences, in couples where thereis some disagreement over fertility.

Among Malay households, 44% differ by at least twochildren, and 10% differ by more than four. In Chinesehouseholds, although the majority of couples stilldisagree, the extent of these differences is smaller thanin Malay households. Around one third of Chinesehouseholds disagree by one child in their preference,one fifth differ by two or more.

3.2.2. Fertility outcomesThe remainder of Table 3 presents information on

fertility outcomes. Unsurprisingly, the number ofchildren ever born in MFLS-2 is significantly greaterthan that in MFLS-1, suggesting the fertility period isincomplete at MFLS-1. However, as measured inMFLS-2, fertility outcomes for both ethnic groups aresignificantly higher than the largest preferences ofeither spouse. In both Malay and Chinese households,around 1.5 more children are born on average than eitherspouse reports to be their preferred number 12 yearsearlier in MFLS-1. This may be indicative of householdsbargaining without commitment, which under theconditions identified in Result 3, leads to overinvest-ment into fertility. Alternatively, this may reflect thatparents learn the true costs and benefits of children overtime, and on average, revise their desires upwards.

However, Table 3 provides two further pieces ofevidence that suggest reported preferences do relate tospouses' innate preferences over fertility. First, as spouseshave significantly different preferences, they are unlikelyto be reporting the expected number of children unlessthere is a significant degree of asymmetric information inthe household.

28 To shed more light on how representative these households are ofthe total population, we also checked these reported preferences againstthose from other surveys. The World Fertility Survey was administeredto over 6000 households in Malaysia in 1974. Only women were askedto report their fertility preferences however. Malay women reporteddesiring 4.70 children, Chinese women reported 4.03 children. Theseare not significantly different from the reports given in MFLS-1.

Second, spouses' reports bear little relation to theactual number of children present in the household at thetime of the report. For example among Malay house-holds, around two thirds of husbands and wives report apreference greater than the number of children they haveat the time, around one fifth report desiring strictlyfewer children than they have at the time. AmongChinese households, around two fifths of spouses reportdesiring more children than they have at the time, andone third report desiring strictly fewer children.

3.3. Empirical method

The first order conditions for fertility when spousesbargain with commitment, (Eq. (12)), and withoutcommitment, (Eq. (14)), both reduce to the followingform;

qðh; dh; dw; gh; gw; qÞ ¼ bhðh; dh; dw; gh; gwÞp⁎hþ bwðh; dh; dw; gh; gwÞp⁎w:

ð16Þ

This separates out the determinants of fertility intothose relating to each spouse's desired fertility, πi⁎, andthose arising from other costs and benefits of children,captured in g(.). We estimate the following linearregression for the fertility outcome in household n anddistrict d;

qnd ¼ ad þ bhp⁎hnd þ bwp

⁎wnd þ ghXhnd

þ gwXwnd þ gXnd þ und; ð17Þ

where qnd is the equilibrium fertility outcome measuredin MFLS-2, and πind⁎ is the fertility preference ofspouse i in household n in district d expressed inMFLS-1. Xhnd, Xwnd and Xnd are characteristics of thehusband, wife, and household respectively, measured inMFLS-1, that capture the costs and benefits of children.αd is a district fixed effect. There are 70 districts inPeninsular Malaysia and it is important to control forsuch regional differences as these may in part capturevariations in access to family planning clinics and otherresources that stem from public policy, and that drivefertility outcomes.

The parameters of interest are βh and βw. A necessarycondition for these to be consistently estimated is thatspousal preferences are uncorrelated to the error term,und. We maintain this assumption for now, and lateraddress econometric concerns arising from there beingomitted determinants of fertility that are correlated tofertility preferences, and from preferences being endo-genously determined or measured with error.

Page 16: Household bargaining over fertility: Theory and evidence ...uctpimr/research/fertility_JDE.pdf · Household bargaining over fertility: Theory and ... This standard hold-up problem

Fig. 3. Disagreements on fertility preferences.

230 I. Rasul / Journal of Development Economics 86 (2008) 215–241

If spouses bargain with commitment, theory suggeststhat— (i) both spouses' preferences have some weight indetermining fertility outcomes; (ii) the outside option inmarital bargaining has no affect on fertility outcomes, andso how fertility preferences translate into fertilityoutcomes should be the same across Malay and Chinesehouseholds; (iii) the distribution of bargaining powerwithin marriage should have no affect on fertilityoutcomes.

If spouses bargain without commitment, then asemphasized in Section 2 — (i) the pattern of (βh, βw)

coefficients depend on the relevant threat point inmarital bargaining, and therefore will vary across ethnicgroups; (ii) the distribution of bargaining power withinmarriage affects fertility outcomes.

For Malay households, as the threat point in bar-gaining for Malays is to divorce, both fertility prefer-ences determine the surplus to be bargained over, andthrough this channel, both preferences determine thefertility outcome. Hence we would expect βh=βw so bothspouses' preferences have equal weight in determiningfertility outcomes.

Page 17: Household bargaining over fertility: Theory and evidence ...uctpimr/research/fertility_JDE.pdf · Household bargaining over fertility: Theory and ... This standard hold-up problem

Table 4Means and standard deviations for other controls, by ethnicity and gender

Malay households Chinese households Test of equality withingender, across ethnicities

Husband Wife Husband Wife Husbands(p-value)

Wives(p-value)

Age 41.32 35.25 40.29 35.45 .2114 .7755(10.57) (8.68) (9.14) (7.78)

Age at marriage 25.67 16.51 27.05 20.69 .0615 .0000(9.54) (3.09) (6.97) (3.57)

Age menstruation 13.44 14.31 .0000(1.53) (1.74)

Years of schooling 4.49 3.00 5.93 3.92 .0000 .0015(3.27) (3.21) (4.04) (4.15)

No schooling .19 .42 .08 .33 .0000 .0333(.39) (.49) (.27) (.48)

Some primary schooling .42 .31 .40 .34 .7041 .3811(.49) (.46) (.49) (.48)

Completed primary school .40 .28 .52 .33 .0019 .1894(.49) (.45) (.50) (.47)

Non-earned income (monthly) 297 219 227 902 .5296 .0000(1464) (1174) (1178) (160)

Employed (yes=1) .96 .60 .98 .60 .3157 .9854(.19) (.49) (.15) (.49)

Water supply (yes=1) .26 .65 .0000(.44) (.48)

Electric supply (yes=1) .34 .72 .0000(.47) (.49)

Notes: Sample sizes are the same as those used for the fertility regressions. Two outliers are dropped when calculating the non earned income of wivesin Chinese households. Tests of equality are across ethnicity, within gender. Tests of equality of means and proportions all have two-sided alternativehypotheses. For all tests, we do not impose the restriction that the samples have the same variance or are paired. Completed primary schoolcorresponds to 6 or more years of schooling. All monetary variables are measured in 1986 Malaysian Ringgit.

231I. Rasul / Journal of Development Economics 86 (2008) 215–241

For Chinese households, as the threat point inbargaining is non-cooperation within marriage, neitherfertility preference determines the surplus to be bar-gained over. As only the wife contributes to invest-ments into fertility, only her preference then determinesthe fertility outcome. Hence we expect βh=0 andβw>0.

29

The characteristics controlled for in Xwnd includethe wife's age, her age at marriage, and the age at whichmenstruation started. These capture the stage of thefertility period the wife is at. We also control for thewife's schooling and monthly non-earned income.These capture her opportunity cost of having children.Other things equal, womens' education reduces fertilitythrough a number of channels — by raising theopportunity cost of time, reducing infant mortality,increasing knowledge and use of contraception, or by

29 In a more general setting, as long as the wife's investment intofertility is relatively more important than her husbands, theimplication is that her preference matters more than her husband'sfor fertility outcomes, so that βw≥βh>0.

reducing the desired number of children. The empiricalresults will shed some light on the interplay betweenwomen's education, fertility preferences, and fertilityoutcomes.

Characteristics of the husband controlled for, Xhnd,include his schooling, non-earned income, and employ-ment status. These capture the husband's opportunitycosts of raising children. Finally we control for house-hold wealth using information on whether the householdhas its own supply of running water and electricity. Apriori, wealth has ambiguous effects on fertility asincome and substitution effects move in oppositedirections when children are a normal good.

Table 4 presents summary statistics for these controls,by ethnicity and gender. Consistent with earlier litera-ture, Malays tend to marry earlier than Chinese, havefewer years of schooling and are less wealthy. Malay andChinese women are equally likely to participate in thelabor force, although Chinese women have significantlygreater amounts of non-earned income.

Both ethnic groups use similar forms of contra-ception as reported in MFLS1. Among Malays, 74%

Page 18: Household bargaining over fertility: Theory and evidence ...uctpimr/research/fertility_JDE.pdf · Household bargaining over fertility: Theory and ... This standard hold-up problem

232 I. Rasul / Journal of Development Economics 86 (2008) 215–241

report using no form of contraception, and 9% reportusing the contraceptive pill. The corresponding figuresamong Chinese households are 49% and 17% respec-tively. These forms of birth control are more likely tolead to problems of non-commitment and renegotiationthan other forms of control, such as injectibles andsterilization, that can be committed to.

In Sections 4.1 and 4.2 we present estimates of thebaseline specification (Eq. (17)) for each ethnic group.We then explore some other implications of the theoryon the relation between fertility preferences and fertilityoutcomes in Section 4.3. In Section 4.4 we addresseconometric concerns.

4. Results

4.1. Malay households

Table 5 presents OLS estimates of the baselinespecification (Eq. (17)) for Malay households. We lateralso estimate (Eq. (17)) using ordered probit andnegative binomial models to account for the discretenature of fertility outcomes. Throughout we reportrobust standard errors, and to ease exposition, we reportonly the parameters of interest, (βh, βw) for eachspecification. In Table A1 we provide the coefficientson the full set of controls.

Column 1 of Table 5 estimates Eq. (17) only control-ling for spouses' fertility preferences, πind⁎ , and district

Table 5Fertility regressions, Malay households

Malay Households

(1) Baseline (2) FertilityPeriod

Husband's desired number of children .145⁎⁎⁎ .140⁎⁎⁎

(.055) (.057)Wife's desired number of children .164⁎⁎ .135⁎⁎

(.066) (.068)Control for Fertility period No YesControl for Wife's Characteristics No NoControl for Husband's Characteriscticsand Household Wealth

No No

District Fixed Effects Yes YesTest (p_value): βh=βw .8428 .9598Adjusted R_squared .1263 .2012Observations 472 472

Dependent variable =Fertility outcome (number of children ever born, measNotes: ⁎⁎⁎ denotes significance at 1%, ⁎⁎ at 5%, and ⁎ at 10%. Robust staColumns 1 to 4. Controls in Column 1 are both spouses' desired number of chwife's age, her age at marriage, and the age at which menstruation started. Ceducation, whether she has completed primary education, and her monthlyhusbands education, non-earned income, employment status, and whether thschool corresponds to 6 or more years of schooling. The omitted education

fixed effects. Both preferences have a positive andsignificant effect on the fertility outcome. At the foot ofthe table we report the p-value on the test of thehypothesis βh=βw. We cannot reject the hypothesis thathusband and wife's preferences have an equal effect onfertility outcomes for Malay households.

Column 2 introduces controls for the stage of thefertility period the wife is at. Both spouse's preferencescontinue to have positive, significant, and equal effectson fertility outcomes. In Column 3 we control for thecharacteristics of the wife that capture her opportunitycost of having children. The effect of each spouses'preferences on fertility outcomes remains unchanged.The next column introduces the same characteristics forthe husband, and also controls for measures of house-hold wealth. The previous results are robust tocontrolling for this full set of characteristics.

The pattern of coefficients on these other controls isalso informative, and reported in full in Column 1 ofTable A1. Malay households in which women are older,married earlier, and started menstruating later, havesignificantly more children as expected. Wives withonly some primary education have fewer children,although this effect is somewhat weak, being significantonly at the 10% level. There is a negative andinsignificant relationship between fertility and educationfor women that have completed primary education.These results are broadly in line with the existingliterature that documents a negative correlation between

(3) Wife'sCharacteristics

(4) AllControls

(5) OrderedProbit

(6) NegativeBinomial

.140⁎⁎⁎ .123⁎⁎ .053⁎⁎⁎ .023⁎⁎⁎

(.057) (.058) (.023) (.008).131⁎⁎ .155⁎⁎ .069⁎⁎⁎ .022⁎⁎

(.068) (.066) (.027) (.010)Yes Yes Yes YesYes Yes Yes YesNo Yes Yes Yes

Yes Yes Yes Yes.9298 .7584 .7139 .9574.1973 .2593 _ _472 472 472 472

ured in MFLS-2) Robust standard errors reported in parentheses.ndard errors are reported throughout. OLS estimates are presented inildren and district fixed effects. Column 2 additionally controls for theolumn 3 additionally controls for whether the wife has some primarynon-earned income. Columns 4 to 6 all additionally control for thee household has a supply of electricity and water. Completed primarycategory is no schooling.

Page 19: Household bargaining over fertility: Theory and evidence ...uctpimr/research/fertility_JDE.pdf · Household bargaining over fertility: Theory and ... This standard hold-up problem

233I. Rasul / Journal of Development Economics 86 (2008) 215–241

education and fertility for women with little educationand the weaker relationship among more educatedwomen.30

However, a concern remains that fertility preferencesare themselves determined by education. As a check onthis, we re-estimated the specification in Column 4without controlling for preferences. The estimated coef-ficients on whether the wife has some primary edu-cation, or whether she has completed primary education,remain almost identical to those when preferences arecontrolled for, as reported in Column 2 of Table A1. Theresults suggest that in this sample of households, fertilitypreferences and education are not much correlated.31

Households in which husbands have higher non-earned income and are employed, have significantlyhigher levels of fertility. More educated husbands havesignificantly more children, although this is likely to bepicking up an effect of household income on fertility.32

Finally, the wife's non-earned income and whether thehousehold has its own supply of running water do notpredict fertility outcomes. If these controls capturewealth effects, they may be insignificant because ofoffsetting income and substitution effects.

We also estimated the baseline specification andadditionally control for the employment status and non-earned income of husbands in MFLS-2.33 Column 3 ofTable A1 shows that among Malay households, those inwhich husbands are employed in MFLS-2 havesignificantly higher fertility levels, although there isno effect of the husband's non-earned income. Theeffects of husband and wives preferences continue to bethe same as in the baseline specification.

The remaining Columns in Table 5 use estimationtechniques that take account of the discrete nature of thedependent variable. We first estimate Eq. (17) using anordered probit model. This model assumes fertilityoutcomes are driven by some underlying continuousprocess so that as each threshold in the continuous

30 DaVanzo et al. (2003) also report a weak relation betweenwomen's education and fertility in the MFLS data.31 In fact the sample correlation between female years of schoolingand fertility preferences is only − .1270.32 If husband's earnings are also controlled for, the effect ofhusband's education becomes insignificant. Both preferences con-tinue to have positive, significant, and equal effects on fertility in thisspecification (not reported).33 Among Malays, 77% of husbands are employed over the twowaves, and 56% of wives are. The corresponding figures for theChinese are 78% and 57%. The simple correlation coefficientsbetween husband and wives non-earned income, earned income (bothin MFLS-1 and MFLS-2), fertility preferences, and fertility outcomesare all less than .3 in absolute value. This is true for both Malay andChinese households.

process is crossed, an additional child is born. A secondapproach is to use a negative binomial model. This treatsfertility outcomes as being the result of an underlyingpoint process.34 Columns 5 and 6 show the main resultson the effects of spousal fertility preferences on fertilityoutcomes, to be robust to these alternative models. Asexpected, once the discreteness of the dependent variableis accounted for, the t-ratios on the estimated coefficientsare larger than when the model is estimated using OLS.

To summarize, in Malay households the fertilitypreferences of husband's and wives have positive, sig-nificant, and equal effects on fertility outcomes. Theeffects of preferences are quantitatively large.The specification in Column 4 implies a one standarddeviation in a wife's fertility preference leads to .25 morechildren being ever born, other things equal. The mag-nitude of this effect is for example just under half as largeas the effect of the wife having some primary education.

4.2. Chinese households

An analogous set of specifications for Chinesehouseholds are presented in Table 6. In Column 1only each spouse's fertility preference and district fixedeffects are controlled for. Both preferences have asignificant and positive effect on fertility outcomes.However, this result is not robust. In Column 2, once weadd controls for the stage of the fertility period the wifeis at, husbands preferences no longer have any effect onfertility outcomes. In contrast, wives preferences arepositively and significantly related to fertility outcomes.This result remains robust to introducing additionalcontrols into the fertility equation.

In particular, adding controls for the wife's char-acteristics, husband's characteristics, and householdwealth, it remains the case that only the wife's fertilitypreference has any significant effect on fertility out-comes. Moreover, the magnitude of the estimated effectof wives preferences remains relatively stable across theOLS specifications in Columns 2 to 4. Again this effectis quantitatively large. The specification in Column 4implies a one standard deviation in a wife's fertilitypreference leads to .39 more children being ever born,other things equal. As in Malay households, themagnitude of this effect is just under half as large asthe effect of the wife having some primary education.

34 The negative binomial model accounts for overdispersion in thedependent and is typically interpreted as allowing for heterogeneityacross households (Cameron and Trivedi, 1998). In this data over-dispersion does not arise because of excess zeroes — less than 1% ofhouseholds have zero children.

Page 20: Household bargaining over fertility: Theory and evidence ...uctpimr/research/fertility_JDE.pdf · Household bargaining over fertility: Theory and ... This standard hold-up problem

Table 6Fertility regressions, Chinese households

Chinese households

(1)Baseline

(2) Fertilityperiod

(3) Wife'scharacteristics

(4) Allcontrols

(5) Orderedprobit

(6) Negativebinomial

Husband's desirednumber of children

.361⁎⁎⁎ .051 − .010 .000 .019 .000(.143) (.134) (.131) (.137) (.080) (.019)

Wife's desired numberof children

.721⁎⁎⁎ .388⁎⁎⁎ .350⁎⁎⁎ .298⁎⁎ .225⁎⁎⁎ .051⁎⁎⁎

(.1500) (.115) (.116) (.123) (0.70) (0.17)Control for fertility period No Yes Yes Yes Yes YesControl for wife's characteristics No No Yes Yes Yes YesControl for husbandscharacteristics andhousehold wealth

No No No Yes Yes Yes

District fixed effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes YesTest (p-value): βh=βw .1479 .1009 .0726 .1558 .0847 .0691Adjusted R-squared .3750 .5809 .5936 .5995 – –Observations 220 220 220 220 220 220

Dependent variable = Fertility outcome (number of children ever born, measured in MFLS-2) Robust standard errors reported in parentheses.Notes: ⁎⁎⁎ denotes significance at 1%, ⁎⁎ at 5%, and ⁎ at 10%. Robust standard errors are reported throughout. OLS estimates are presented inColumns 1 to 4. Controls in Column 1 are both spouses' desired number of children and district fixed effects. Column 2 additionally controls for thewife's age, her age at marriage, and the age at which menstruation started. Column 3 additionally controls for whether the wife has some primaryeducation, whether she has completed primary education, and her monthly non-earned income. Columns 4 to 6 all additionally control for thehusbands education, non-earned income, employment status, and whether the household has a supply of electricity and water. Completed primaryschool corresponds to 6 or more years of schooling. The omitted education category is no schooling.

35 When husband's earned income, which is potentially endogenous, isincluded in the full specification, the coefficient on husband's preferencesremains insignificant. The coefficient on the wife's preference risesto .34. The p-value on the null hypothesis that these are equal is .07.36 We also estimated the baseline specification including the husband'searned income both at MFLS-1 andMFLS-2. This captures both incomeand substitution effects of earned income on fertility outcomes. ForMalay households, those in which the husband has higher income inMFLS-2 have significantly lower fertility outcomes. Husband's incomein MFLS-1 is not significant. Among Chinese households, MFLS-1income significantly reduces fertility outcomes and MFLS-2 income ispositive but not significant at conventional levels. The results suggest themagnitude of the income and substitution effects of husband's earnedincome are different in Malay and Chinese households.

234 I. Rasul / Journal of Development Economics 86 (2008) 215–241

The results in Columns 5 and 6 show that whenexplicit account is taken of the discrete nature of thedependent variable, it is again only the wife's fertilitypreference that determines fertility outcomes in Chinesehouseholds.

The conclusion that husbands matter less for fertilityoutcomes in Chinese than Malay households isreinforced by the pattern of other coefficients, asreported in Column 4 of Table A1. While the wife'scharacteristics such as her age, age at marriage, and non-earned income, affect fertility in the expected direction,husband's education, non-earned income and employ-ment status are not significant determinants of fertility inChinese households.

The relation between wives' education and fertilityoutcomes is also stronger among Chinese than Malayhouseholds. Among Chinese couples, if the wife hassome primary education, fertility is predicted to besignificantly lower. The magnitude of this effect is largerin absolute value than for Malays and estimated withgreater precision. Moreover, if the wife has completedprimary education, the couple is predicted to have oneless child than if the wife has no years of schooling.

To shed light on the relation between fertility pref-erences and education, we re-estimate the specificationin Column 4 of Table 6, excluding fertility preferences.As reported in Column 5 of Table A1, the effects ofwife's education then become marginally stronger.

However, husband's characteristics continue to haveno effect on fertility outcomes.35

When we additionally control for the employmentstatus and non-earned income of husbands in MFLS-2,the result in Column 6 of Table A1 is consistent with theearlier findings that husband's characteristics are notsignificant predictors of fertility outcomes. Again, onlythe fertility preferences of wives determine fertilityoutcomes. Husband's fertility preferences are notsignificant, and the point estimate is close to zero.36

To summarize, in Chinese households, only the fertilitypreferences of wives have any effect on fertility outcomes.The effect of wives' preferences is quantitatively large.Husbands' fertility preferences, and characteristics in

Page 21: Household bargaining over fertility: Theory and evidence ...uctpimr/research/fertility_JDE.pdf · Household bargaining over fertility: Theory and ... This standard hold-up problem

Table 7Further implications

Malayhouseholds

Chinesehouseholds

(1a) (1b)

Husband's desirednumber of children

.055 − .060(.065) (.147)

Interaction with whetherhusband inherits any land

.317⁎⁎⁎ .718(.130) (.484)

Wife's desirednumber of children

.214⁎⁎⁎ .328⁎⁎⁎

(.071) (.121)Interaction with whether

husband inherits any land− .508⁎⁎ .305(.216) (.472)

All baseline controls Yes YesDistrict fixed effects Yes YesAdjusted R-squared .2481 .5988Observations 472 220

Dependent variable = Fertility outcome (number of children everborn, measured in MFLS-2) Robust standard errors reported inparentheses.Notes: ⁎⁎⁎ denotes significance at 1%, ⁎⁎ at 5%, and ⁎ at 10%. Robuststandard errors are calculated throughout. The full set of controls as inTables 5 and 6 are included throughout.

37 AmongMalay households there is no direct effect on fertility of thehusband inheriting land. AmongChinese households, the inheritance ofland by husbands reduces fertility outcomes, other things equal.

235I. Rasul / Journal of Development Economics 86 (2008) 215–241

general, have little or no predictive power in explainingfertility outcomes among Chinese households.

In all specifications, the point estimate on husband'spreferences is itself close to zero, so that part of the reasonwhy husband's preferences have no significant effect isbecause the magnitude of any true effect is small.Although βh is not estimated with the same precision asin Malay households, this is partly a result, as shown inTable 3, of there being less variation in preferencesamong Chinese than Malay households. This lack ofvariation is not however driving the results — wives'preferences in Chinese households have a positive androbust effect on fertility outcomes across all thespecifications estimated. What makes the Chinese resultsmore remarkable is that, as reported in the descriptiveevidence in Table 3, there is relatively less conflict overfertility in Chinese households than Malay households.This may have led to the false expectation that bothspouses influence fertility outcomes. In fact, only thepreferences of wives have an effect.

4.3. Further implications

The fact that in Malay households, both spouses'fertility preferences have an equal, positive, andsignificant effect on fertility outcomes, is consistentwith both models of household bargaining developed inSection 2. In contrast, for Chinese households, as onlywife's preferences determine fertility outcomes, thisbehavior can only be reconciled with a model of

bargaining without commitment. This leads to one oftwo conclusions.

First, it may be that Malay households can bargain withcommitment and Chinese households cannot. This inter-pretation lacks intuitive appeal if we view the ability ofhouseholds to commit or not in marital bargains as afundamental characteristic underlying household behavior,and not something that some households can do, andotherscannot. A second interpretation is that all householdsbargain without commitment. The variation in outcomesacross households is then explained by differences in threatpoints in marital bargaining across ethnic groups.

To explore these interpretations further, we note that ifcouples bargain with commitment, the effect of spousalpreferences should not vary with the distribution ofbargaining power. To proxy the distribution of bargain-ing power we use information on inheritance. Inparticular we define a dummy equal to one if thehusband has inherited any land from his family, and zerootherwise. Unlike other potential proxies for bargainingpower, such as education, this is plausibly less correlatedwith fertility preferences themselves. In Malay house-holds, just over 20% of husbands have inherited someland. This figure is 10% in Chinese households. Weinteract the dummy for the husband having inherited anyland, with each spouse's fertility preference in specifica-tion (17). We continue to control for the full set ofcovariates and district fixed effects.

The results for Malay households are reported inColumn 1a of Table 7. The husband's fertilitypreference is a significant determinant of fertility out-comes when he has greater bargaining power within thehousehold, all else equal. The wife's fertility preferencestill has a significant effect on fertility outcomes, but theeffect of her preference is significantly lower if thehusband has more bargaining power, other things equal.

Column 1b reports the results for Chinese house-holds. Among those couples, the distribution ofbargaining power appears to play no role in determininghow spouses' fertility preferences translate into fertilityoutcomes. In line with the baseline results in Table 6, itremains true that only the wife's fertility preference is asignificant predictor of fertility outcomes.37

4.4. Econometric concerns

We now address econometric concerns arising fromthe estimation of (17). These concerns obviously apply

Page 22: Household bargaining over fertility: Theory and evidence ...uctpimr/research/fertility_JDE.pdf · Household bargaining over fertility: Theory and ... This standard hold-up problem

Table 8Descriptive Statistics on Preferences for Additional Children

Malay households Chinese households

Husband Wife Test of equality(p-value)

Husband Wife Test of equality(p-value)

Fertility preferences by ethnicity and gender (mean and 95% confidence interval)Desire more children? (yes=1) .517 .483 .1409 .255 .286 .2094

[.472, .562] [.438, .528] [.197, .313] [.226, .347]Number of additional children desired 3.31 3.05 .1280 2.09 1.75 .1062

[3.06, 3.57] [2.81, 3.28] [1.73, 2.45] [1.52, 1.97]

Additional number of children born between MFLS-1 and MFLS-2 (mean and 95% confidence interval)Both spouses desire additional children 2.84 1.57

[2.58, 3.10] [1.25, 1.88]One spouse desires additional children 2.90 1.77

[2.68, 3.12] [1.40, 2.15]Neither spouse desires additional children 2.98 2.34

[2.62, 3.33] [1.81, 2.87]

Notes: Sample households are those used for the fertility regressions. Tests of equality are across gender, within ethnicity. Tests of equality of meansand proportions all have two-sided alternative hypotheses. For all tests, we do not impose the restriction that the samples have the same variance or arepaired. All fertility preferences are expressed in MFLS-1. Only those spouses that said they desired additional children were asked to report thenumber of additional children they desired. For all others, no additional children were desired.

38 In MFLS-1 respondents were asked, “would you personally like tohave any more children than the number you have now?”, and if yes,“how many more children do you want?”.39 Only 44 Chinese couples have both spouses desiring additionalchildren.

236 I. Rasul / Journal of Development Economics 86 (2008) 215–241

equally to Malay and Chinese households. However dueto limited sample sizes in the MFLS data, and becausesome of the concerns are addressed exploiting additionalinformation in the data, we are able to only focus onMalay households.

4.4.1. Omitted variablesThere may be unobserved (to the econometrician)

household specific characteristics that determine bothfertility preferences and outcomes. Thesemay for examplerelate to the costs of having children such as local prices ofchild related goods, the support network available to thehousehold, or the household's permanent income.

The error term in Eq. (17) can then be written asund=εn+εnd, where εn is the unobserved householddeterminant of fertility and is correlated to spouses' pref-erences, and εnd is a classical disturbance term. Omittingεn in Eq. (17) then leads to inconsistent estimates of(βh, βw).

If εn is time invariant, consistent estimates may berecovered by applying a transformation to Eq. (17)analogous to first-differencing. Denote those variablesmeasured in the first wave of data, MFLS-1, with asuperscript of one, and those measured in MFLS-2 witha superscript of two. Hence Δqnd=(qnd

2 −qnd1 ) denotesthe additional number of children produced between thetwo waves. Consistent estimates can then be recoveredby estimating the following specification;

Dqnd ¼ bhDp⁎hnd þ bwDp

⁎wnd þ ghDXhnd

þ gwDXhnd þ gDXnd þ Dund ð18Þ

where the error term Δund=Δεnd is uncorrelated tofertility preferences. To implement this approach, wetake the following steps. We use information on eachspouses desired number of additional children, toproxy for Δπind⁎ , the change in the desired number ofchildren over the two waves of data.38 We continue tocontrol for the same characteristics as in Eq. (17), asthese are correlated to changes in household determi-nants of fertility. We also include district fixed effectsto control for spacial variation in infrastructure andpublic services that drive fertility. Finally, we reportOLS estimates for Eq. (18). The results are howeverqualitatively unchanged if an ordered probit ornegative binomial model is estimated instead.

Only those spouses that said they wanted additionalchildren in MFLS-1 were asked to report the number ofadditional children they desired. For all others, noadditional children were desired. Of the 472 Malayhouseholds in our sample, 177 have both spousesdesiring additional children.39

Table 8 presents descriptive evidence by ethnicityand spouse on whether more children are desired, theadditional number of children desired conditional onwanting more children, and the actual number ofadditional children born between the two waves. On

Page 23: Household bargaining over fertility: Theory and evidence ...uctpimr/research/fertility_JDE.pdf · Household bargaining over fertility: Theory and ... This standard hold-up problem

Table 9Econometric concerns, Malay households

Additional number of children bornbetween MFLS-1 and MFLS-2

Instrumental variables

First stage Second stage

Both want morechildren

At least one wantsmore children

Husband's desirednumber of children

Wife's desirednumber of children

Fertility Outcome(MFLS-2)

(1) (2) (3a) (3b) (4)

Husband's desired number ofadditional children

.106⁎ .110⁎

(.064) (.062)Wife's desired number of

additional children.186⁎⁎ .141⁎⁎

(.086) (.073)Husband wants more

children (yes=1).034(.375)

Wife wants more children(yes=1)

−1.45⁎⁎⁎(.426)

Husband's desirednumber of children

.573⁎

(.328)Wife's desired

number of children1.51⁎⁎⁎

(.484)Husband's father's age

at husband's birth.037⁎⁎⁎ − .010(.015) (.012)

Husband's mother's ageat husband's birth

− .027⁎ .040⁎⁎⁎

(.015) (.012)Wife's father's age

at wife's birth− .057⁎⁎⁎ .004(.017) (.014)

Wife's mother's ageat wife's birth

.053⁎⁎ − .007(.022) (.018)

All baseline controls Yes Yes Yes Yes YesTest (p-value): βh=βw .4968 .7613 .0619Adjusted R-squared .1677 .2211 .1848 .2402 –Observations 177 295 378 378 378

Dependent variable is reported in the heading of each column.Robust standard errors reported in parentheses.Notes: ⁎⁎⁎ denotes significance at 1%, ⁎⁎ at 5%, and ⁎ at 10%. Robust standard errors are calculated throughout. The full set of controls as in Tables 5and 6 is included in all Columns. In Column 1 the sample is restricted to those households in which both spouses reported wanting additional childrenin MFLS-1. The sample is Column 2 is restricted to those households in which at least one spouse reported wanting additional children in MFLS-1.Columns 3a and 3b report the first stage regressions from the IV regression. The second stage is reported in Column 4.

40 Among couples in which neither spouse wanted more children,there is no variation in the desired number of additional children —they are both set to zero. Hence these couples cannot be used toidentify βh and βw.

237I. Rasul / Journal of Development Economics 86 (2008) 215–241

average, both spouses want to double their family sizefrom that in MFLS-1. Two further points are of note.

First, there is much less conflict within householdsover the additional number of children desired than overthe total number desired. Second, the additional numberof children born after MFLS-1 bears little relation towhether spouses actually wanted more children or not.For example in Malay households, the number ofadditional children born does not significantly differbetween households in which both spouses reportwanting more children, only one spouse wants morechildren, and neither spouse wants more children. Thissuggests there remains scope for bargaining even if onespouse would prefer not to have any more children.

Table 9 reports estimates of Eq. (18).We first considerthose households in which both spouses actually desireadditional children. The result in Column 1 suggests thatin Malay households, both spouse's fertility preferences

have positive, significant, and equal effects on fertilityoutcomes. The results are qualitatively similar to those inthe baseline specification in Table 4. However theestimated effect of husband's preferences on outcomes isnow slightly smaller in magnitude than in the baselinespecification, and the effect of the wife's preferences isslightly larger. This suggests unobserved householdlevel determinants of fertility, εn, are positively related tohusbands' preferences and negatively related to wives'preferences.

In Column 2 we also use information from house-holds in which at least one spouse wants additionalchildren.40 Among these couples, we continue to find the

Page 24: Household bargaining over fertility: Theory and evidence ...uctpimr/research/fertility_JDE.pdf · Household bargaining over fertility: Theory and ... This standard hold-up problem

238 I. Rasul / Journal of Development Economics 86 (2008) 215–241

effect of both spouse's preferences on fertility outcomesto be positive, significant, and equal to each other.

The direct effect of the husband wanting morechildren per se, is not significantly different from zero.In contrast, if the wife wants more children, this leadsto significantly fewer additional being born, otherthings equal. This may capture that in householdswhere the wife wants additional children, her fertilitypreference is relatively higher than her husbands. Ashighlighted by theory, if on the margin, by having morechildren the husband's share of the marital surplus thenfalls, he will be less willing to contribute to investmentsinto fertility, all else equal.41

4.4.2. Endogenous preferencesA second concern is that fertility preferences

are endogenous to fertility outcomes. Specifically,there may be unobserved individual characteristicsthat drive both fertility outcomes and fertility pref-erences. The error term in Eq. (17) then is such thatund=εhnd+εwnd+εnd, where εind determines the fertilityoutcome, and the fertility preference of spouse i, πind⁎ .Estimates of (βh, βw) in Eq. (17) are then inconsistent.

The endogeneity of preferences could for exam-ple arise for example from the private informationeach spouse has on their health status, knowledge ofchild rearing practices, fecundity, or use of contra-ception, that drive fertility outcomes and prefer-ences. These concerns are exacerbated by the factthat at the time preferences are expressed, house-holds are some way into the fertility period. Hencethese preferences may also reflect parent's currentattitudes towards children based on information re-vealed over time, such as the true costs and benefitsof children.42,43

To address this concern we seek instruments for eachspouses' fertility preference. These must be correlatedwith fertility preferences, πind⁎ , and uncorrelated withunobserved individual determinants of fertility outcomes,εind. These are stringent criterion to meet. However, we

41 In line with this interpretation, wives that wanted more childrenreport desiring 5.04 children in total, significantly higher than the 4.3children desired bywomen that do not want additional children. Similarresults using the same data are also reported in DaVanzo et al. (2003).42 For 90 Malay women, information is available on their desirednumber of additional children inMFLS-2. The majority of women revisetheir preferences downwards. These revisions are significantly andnegatively related to the number of children in the household inMFLS-1,but are unrelated to either spouses' education, age, non-earned income oryears married.43 In a similar spirit, Rosenzweig and Wolpin (1993) presentevidence from the US that mothers use information on their sibling'sbirth outcomes in evaluating the wantedness of their own children.

are able to exploit information on the characteristics ofeach spouses' parents as potential instruments. Themotivation for this instrumentation strategy is that anindividual's fertility preference stems partly from theirown experiences as a child. In particular, their preferencemay relate to their own birth order, or number and gendercomposition of their own siblings.44

We do not however directly use the birth order,number or gender composition of each spouse's siblingsas instruments. These may be correlated to the supportnetworks available to spouses outside of marriage, andthus may influence behavior within marriage. Rather, weuse the age of the husband and wife's own mother andfather, at the time when the husband, or wife, were born,as instruments for spouses fertility preferences. The ageof spouse i's parents at the time when he or she was bornwill be correlated to the birth order of each spouse, andhence may influence their fertility preferences. To bevalid, these instruments should have no direct effect onfertility outcomes within the household.45

We report the IVestimates in Table 9. Columns 3a and3b report the relevant coefficients from the first stage.Husbands desire significantly more children if at the timethey were born, their father was older or mother wasyounger. Husbands' preferences are also predicted by theage of the wife's parents, at the time she was born. Inparticular, husbands desire significantly more children ifat the time their wife was born, her father was younger ormother was older. These effects move in the oppositedirection to those of the husband's own parents.

The wife's preference is significantly higher, the olderwas her husband's mother, at the time her husband wasborn. The fact that each spouses' preference is in partpredicted by the age of their partner's parents, makes itless likely that the predicted preferences from the firststage are correlated to spouses' own support networks offamily that may drive behavior within marriage.

The second stage is reported in Column 4.46 Bothspouses' preferences continue to have positive andsignificant effects on fertility outcomes. Note that thestandard errors on both estimates are larger than in thebaseline estimates as expected. However, the magnitude

44 This motivation stems from two fields of research. First, demo-graphers have long been interested in whether birth order affects fertilitybehavior. Johnson and Stokes (1976) present evidence in favor of this.Second, in psychology, some socialization studies have suggested thatchildren brought up in small families, themselves prefer small families.Kahn and Anderson (1992) provide an overview of these studies.45 The instruments are not highly correlated with each other. Thepairwise correlation coefficients between them are less than .5.46 The instruments pass a Sargan test of overidentification. Thep-value on the test is .65.

Page 25: Household bargaining over fertility: Theory and evidence ...uctpimr/research/fertility_JDE.pdf · Household bargaining over fertility: Theory and ... This standard hold-up problem

239I. Rasul / Journal of Development Economics 86 (2008) 215–241

of the effects of each spouse's preferences on fertilityoutcome are also larger than in the baseline estimates, sothat the effect both spouses' fertility preferences onoutcomes are underestimated if these preferences aretaken to be exogenous to fertility outcomes.

4.4.3. Measurement ErrorA third concern is that preferences may be reported

with error. Suppose that spouse i's reported preferenceis equal to πind⁎ =Πind+ωind where πind is their truepreference, and ωind is some measurement error. Theimplications for the estimated coefficients are thensimilar to when fertility preferences are endogenous. Ifthe measurement error is white noise, the parameters ofinterest are subject to attenuation bias. This would implythe true effect of each spouse's preference in Malayhouseholds is larger than that reported in Table 5.However, the error term ωind may not be white noise forat least four reasons.

First, couples may be unwilling to report true levelsof conflict to interviewers, thus biasing their reporttowards that of their spouse. Second, spouses facingthe threat of divorce or a shift in bargaining power maybe more likely to agree with their partner. Third, theremay be a tendency for individuals to centralize theirreports around some acceptable norm. Fourth, errorsmay arise from misinterpretation of the survey questionon fertility preferences, such as if respondents reportedtheir immediate plans rather than their ultimate fertilitygoals.47

This concern is then addressed using the instru-mental variables strategy detailed above and reportedin Table 9. The evidence suggests the effects of bothspouses' fertility preferences on outcomes are under-estimated if measurement error in preferences is notaccounted for.

5. Conclusions

This paper develops and tests a model of householdbargaining that sheds light on how fertility outcomesrelate to the fertility preferences of spouses. Key to theanalysis is whether spouses can commit to their futureactions within marriage, such as those relating toinvestments into child quality. If couples bargain withcommitment, fertility outcomes take account of both

47 Around 80% of spouses were interviewed in the absence of theirpartner. There are no significant differences in reported fertilitypreferences, nor in the difference between reports of spouses,depending on the presence of others.

spouses' fertility preferences. Hence even if there isconflict, couples behave as if there is a unitary decisionmaking process, and fertility outcomes are efficient. Ifcouples bargain without commitment, the effect of eachspouse's preference depends on the threat point inmarital bargaining and the distribution of bargainingpower. In contrast to standard models of householdbargaining, fertility outcomes are inefficient despitecouples bargaining efficiently over the distribution ofthe marital surplus. The Coase theorem breaks downbecause spouses are unable to commit to ex anteagreements on behavior within marriage.

We test the models using household data fromMalaysia. This is an excellent testing ground in which tounderstand household bargaining, because exogenousdifferences in threat points in marital bargaining acrossethnic groups can be used to help identify the underlyingbargaining model. The balance of evidence suggestscouples bargain without commitment. The analysishowever leaves unresolved the issue of whether couplesactually overinvest in fertility relative to the efficientlevels that would be achieved if they could bargain withcommitment, although the descriptive evidence cer-tainly points in this direction.

Finally, while we have developed and testeda framework for thinking through how non-commitmentin marriage determines how conflicts over desiredfertility are resolved, these intuitions can be applied tomany actions in the household, not just those related tofertility. This offers a broad agenda for future work onthe economics of household behavior.48

6. Data sources

The MFLS comprises a pair of surveys with partiallyoverlapping samples, designed by RAND and adminis-tered in Peninsular Malaysia in 1976/7 (MFLS-1) and1988/9 (MFLS-2). Each survey collected detailedcurrent and retrospective information on family struc-ture, fertility, economic status, and many other topics.Data and documentation for both surveys are availableat www.rand.org/labor/FLS. The MFLS-1 sample con-sists of 1262 households with an ever-married woman,selected to be representative of Peninsular Malaysia in1976. MFLS-2 reinterviewed 926 of those MFLS-1households. DaVanzo et al. (2003) report that attrition

48 Pollak (1985) first discussed the role of such transactions costs inmarriage. More recently, Lundberg and Pollak (2001) and Aura (2002)have formally considered the implications of such non-commitmentfor household outcomes.

Page 26: Household bargaining over fertility: Theory and evidence ...uctpimr/research/fertility_JDE.pdf · Household bargaining over fertility: Theory and ... This standard hold-up problem

240 I. Rasul / Journal of Development Economics 86 (2008) 215–241

was not random. Women who had not moved or hadnot moved far were more likely to be reinterviewed.Compared to those not reinterviewed, reinterviewedwomen are more likely to be older, from rural areas, andMalay rather than Chinese. However, DaVanzo et al.(2003) provide evidence that attrition was uncorrelated

to fertility preferences. We also merged the MFLS datawith 1970 and 1980 Malaysia census data, obtainedfrom the South-east Asia Fertility Project Data Archiveat the University of Washington. This is accessiblevia http://csde.washington.edu/research/seafert/n/m/malay_download.html.

Appendix A

Table A1: Fertility Regressions

Dependent variable = Fertility outcome (number of children ever born, measured in MFLS-2) Robust standard errors reported in parentheses

Malay households

Chinese households

(1)All controls

(2)No preferences

(3)MFLS-2 controls

(4)All controls

(5)No preferences

(6)MFLS-2 controls

Husband's desired number of children

.123⁎⁎ .138⁎⁎ .000 .009 (.058) (.061) (.137) (.150)

Wife's desired number of children

.155⁎⁎ .148⁎⁎ .298⁎⁎ .331⁎⁎⁎

(.066)

(.071) (.123) (.127) Age .071⁎⁎⁎ .073⁎⁎⁎ .077⁎⁎⁎ .131⁎⁎⁎ .141⁎⁎⁎ .135⁎⁎⁎

(.020)

(.020) (.023) (.021) (.021) (.022) Age at marriage − .158⁎⁎⁎ − .154⁎⁎⁎ − .165⁎⁎⁎ − .229⁎⁎⁎ − .246⁎⁎⁎ − .223⁎⁎⁎

(.041)

(0.43) (.042) (.036) (.035) (.038) Age menstruation started .188⁎⁎ .192⁎⁎ .217⁎⁎ .087 .092 .118

(.086)

(.087) (.091) (.074) (.076) (.077) Wife has some primary education − .641⁎ − .676⁎ − .466 − .821⁎⁎ − .956⁎⁎⁎ − .723⁎⁎

(.362)

(.370) (.370) (.349) (.352) (.362) Wife has completed primary education − .109 − .209 − .237 −1.16⁎⁎⁎ −1.30⁎⁎⁎ −1.04⁎⁎

(.431)

(.445) (.446) (.394) (.390) (.430) Non-earned income×10−4 − .314 − .955 − .262 .387⁎ .387⁎ .369⁎

(.880)

(.778) (.865) (.203) (.221) (.198) Husband has some primary education .587 .569 .768⁎ .451 .439 .307

(.389)

(.400) (.410) (.510) (.513) (.622) Husband has completed primary education .782⁎ .767⁎ .846⁎ .340 .215 .178

(.460)

(.468) (.471) (.533) (.700) (.626) Husband's non-earned income×10−4 3.73⁎⁎⁎ 3.96⁎⁎⁎ 3.16⁎⁎⁎ − .336 − .182 −.646

(.964)

(.891) (.911) (1.19) (1.23) (1.26) Husband employed (yes=1) 2.46⁎⁎⁎ 2.29⁎⁎⁎ 2.51⁎⁎⁎ 1.31 1.50 1.19

(.751)

(.688) (.741) (1.01) (1.03) (1.07) Husband's non-earned income MFLS-2×10−4 − .139 .287

(.608)

(.624) Husband employed in MFLS-2 (yes=1) .893⁎⁎ .200

(.382)

(.316) Water supply (yes=1) − .638 − .553 − .360 − .364 − .457 − .247

(.440)

(.443) (.450) (.343) (.353) (.399) Electric supply (yes=1) − .917⁎⁎⁎ − .967⁎⁎⁎ − .107 − .391 − .428 − .131

(.358)

(.358) (.342) (.364) (.372) (.360) District fixed effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Test (p-value): βh=βw .7584 – .9276 .1558 – .1460 Adjusted R-squared .2593 .2371 .1925 .5995 .5900 .5877 Observations 472 472 453 220 220 209

Notes: ⁎⁎⁎ denotes significance at 1%, ⁎⁎ at 5%, and ⁎ at 10%. Robust standard errors are calculated throughout. Completed primary school

corresponds to 6 or more years of schooling. Omitted education category is no schooling. The specifications in Columns 1 and 4 are the same as thosereported in Column 4 of Tables 4 and 5 respectively, except now the full set of estimated coefficients is shown. The specifications in Columns 2 and 5are identical except that both fertility preferences are dropped. The specifications in Columns 3 and 6 additionally control for the husband'semployment status and non-earned income in MFLS-2.

Page 27: Household bargaining over fertility: Theory and evidence ...uctpimr/research/fertility_JDE.pdf · Household bargaining over fertility: Theory and ... This standard hold-up problem

241I. Rasul / Journal of Development Economics 86 (2008) 215–241

References

Aura, S. (2002) Uncommitted Couples: Some Efficiency and PolicyImplications of Marital Bargaining, mimeo University of Missouri.

Becker, G.S., 1981. A Treatise on the Family. Harvard UniversityPress, Cambridge.

Bergstrom, T.C, Cornes, R.C., 1983. Independence of allocativeefficiency from distribution in the theory of public goods.Econometrica 51, 1753–1766.

Bongaarts, J., 2001. Fertility and reproductive preferences in post-transitional societies. Population and Development Review 27,261–281.

Cameron, A.C, Trivedi, P.K., 1998. Regression Analysis of CountData. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.

Chen, Z., Woolley, F., 2001. A Cournot–Nash model of familydecision making. Economic Journal 111, 722–748.

Chiappori, P.A, 1988. Rational household labor supply. Econometrica56, 63–90.

DaVanzo, J., Peterson, C.E., Jones, N.R., 2003. How well do desiredfertility measures predict subsequent fertility? Evidence FromMalaysia, DRU-3013-NICHD, RAND.

Freedman, R., Freedman, D.S., Thornton, A.D., 1980. Changes infertility expectations and preferences between 1962 and 1977: theirrelation to final parity. Demography 17, 365–378.

Grossman, S., Hart, O., 1986. The costs and benefits of ownership: atheory of vertical and lateral integration. Journal of PoliticalEconomy 94, 691–719.

Hart, O., Moore, J., 1990. Property rights and the theory of the firm.Journal of Political Economy 98, 1119–1158.

Hirschman, C., Teerawichitchainan, B., 2003. Cultural and socio-economic influences on divorce during modernization: SoutheastAsia, 1940s to 1960s. Population and Development Review 29,215–253.

Johnson, N.E, Stokes, C.S., 1976. Family size in successivegenerations: the effects of birth order, intergenerational change inlifestyle, and familial satisfaction. Demography 13, 175–187.

Jones, G.W., 1981. Malay marriage and divorce in peninsularMalaysia: three decades of change. Population and DevelopmentReview 7, 255–278.

Jones, G.W., 1994. Marriage and Divorce in Islamic South-East Asia.Oxford University Press, Kuala Lumpur.

Kahn, J.R., Anderson, K.E., 1992. Intergenerational patterns ofteenage fertility. Demography 29, 39–57.

Kuchiba, M., Tsubouchi, Y., Maeda, N., 1979. Three Malay Villages:A Sociology of Paddy Growers in West Malaysia. Monograph ofthe Center for Southeast Asian Studies, Kyoto University.

Leung, S.F (1987). ATheoretical and Empirical Analysis of the Effectsof Parental Sex Preferences on Fertility, PhD dissertation,University of Chicago.

Lundberg, S., Pollak, R.A., 1993. Separate spheres bargaining and themarriage market. Journal of Political Economy 101, 988–1010.

Lundberg, S., Pollak, R.A., 2001. Efficiency in marriage. NBERWorking Paper, vol. 8642.

Manser, M., Brown, M., 1980. Marriage and household decisiontheory — a bargaining analysis. International Economic Review21, 21–34.

Mason, K.O, Taj, A.M., 1987. Differences between women's andmen's reproductive goals in developing countries. Population andDevelopment Review 13, 611–638.

McElroy, M., Horney, M., 1981. Nash-bargained decisions: towards ageneralization of the theory of demand. International EconomicReview 22, 333–349.

Pollak, R.A., 1985. A transaction cost approach to families andhouseholds. Journal of Economic Literature 23, 581–608.

Rosenzweig, M.R., Wolpin, K.I., 1993. Maternal expectations and expost rationalizations: the usefulness of survey information on thewantedness of children. Journal of Human Resources 28, 205–229.

Rudie, I., 1983. Women in Malaysia: economic autonomy, ritualsegregation and some future possibilities. In: Utas, B. (Ed.),Women in Islamic Societies: Social Attitudes and HistoricalPerspectives. Curzon Press.

Swift, M., 1965. Malay Peasant Society in Jelebu. The Athlone Press,London.

Tan, P.C., 1988. The Study of Marriage and Marital Dissolution inPeninsular Malaysia, University of Malaya Faculty of Economicsand Administration.

Tan, P.C., Jones, G.W., 1990. Malay divorce in peninsular Malaysia:the near disappearance of an institution. Southeast Asian Journal ofSocial Science 18, 85–114.

Thomas, D., 1990. Intra-household resource allocation: an inferentialapproach. Journal of Human Resources 25, 635–664.

Thomson, E., Mcdonald, E., Bumpass, L.L., 1990. Fertility desires andfertility: his, hers, and theirs. Demography 27, 579–588.

Weiss, Y., Willis, R.J., 1985. Children as collective goods and divorcesettlements. Journal of Labor Economics 3, 268–292.