foreign direct investment in the former soviet union

21
Does FDI increases GDP per capita growth in the Former Soviet Union? By Roger Miller I. Introduction: The Soviet Union was a centrally planned economy that is unparalleled in history. It set up heavy industrial sectors without enough light industry and overpaid agriculture. When compared to structures like China’s economy before the year 1978 at which time China started to move more toward a market economy, the Soviet Union left a much more difficult problem for restructuring (Sachs and Woo 1994). The Soviet Union had greater citizen benefits all the way around, but largely connected them to the place of employment. Changing the market would mean more people would be changing jobs, some firms would be forced out of business or to lay people off. That would mean those people would lose their benefits. Fear of such changes has likely been a driving factor of the reluctance of the citizens to make the change. It is likely that they feel like the gains they will eventually get from moving to a free market economy are just too far in the future for the turmoil they will have to go through to get there. Although their history is unequalled in magnitude of a socially planned economy, its future possibility of market economic structure exists in other countries. Many great nations benefit from market economies and the specialization and profit maximizing efficiency inducing practices that go with them. That means that the Former Soviet Union (FSU) can look to other countries as examples for the market both on macro and micro aspects. Governments can learn from policies of other governments and individual firms can gain from Foreign Direct

Upload: rojeymiller

Post on 09-Jul-2015

674 views

Category:

Documents


2 download

DESCRIPTION

Slides presenting the findings of my Research Project for my Masters in Applied Economics

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Foreign Direct Investment in the former Soviet Union

Does FDI increases GDP per capita growth in the Former Soviet Union?

By Roger Miller

I. Introduction: The Soviet Union was a centrally planned economy that is unparalleled in history. It set

up heavy industrial sectors without enough light industry and overpaid agriculture. When

compared to structures like China’s economy before the year 1978 at which time China started

to move more toward a market economy, the Soviet Union left a much more difficult problem

for restructuring (Sachs and Woo 1994). The Soviet Union had greater citizen benefits all the

way around, but largely connected them to the place of employment. Changing the market

would mean more people would be changing jobs, some firms would be forced out of business

or to lay people off. That would mean those people would lose their benefits. Fear of such

changes has likely been a driving factor of the reluctance of the citizens to make the change. It

is likely that they feel like the gains they will eventually get from moving to a free market

economy are just too far in the future for the turmoil they will have to go through to get there.

Although their history is unequalled in magnitude of a socially planned economy, its

future possibility of market economic structure exists in other countries. Many great nations

benefit from market economies and the specialization and profit maximizing efficiency inducing

practices that go with them. That means that the Former Soviet Union (FSU) can look to other

countries as examples for the market both on macro and micro aspects. Governments can

learn from policies of other governments and individual firms can gain from Foreign Direct

Page 2: Foreign Direct Investment in the former Soviet Union

Page 2

Investment (FDI). The goal of this paper is to show the positive benefits the FSU is gaining in

their economic growth as a result of FDI if any may be determined or supported empirically.

Generally FDI is expected to increase growth both directly and indirectly. FDI is believed

to have positive effects such as productivity gains, technology transfers, exposure to new

processes, managerial skills, employee training, international production networks, and access

to markets (Alfaro et al. 2007). Firm level studies have not shown positive effects on economic

growth including technology spillovers (Carkovic and Levine 2002). Such benefits are difficult to

measure directly. Using GDP growth rates and FDI levels, I will attempt to determine whether

FDI has a greater effect in the FSU than in other nations.

Macroeconomic studies have shown that FDI is good for growth in an economy with

financial markets that can manage the flows, but it is argued that these analyses are not careful

enough in their calculations for things like simultaneity and country-specific effects (Carkovic

and Levine 2002). The restructuring of the economy to where the public is now responsible for

finding their niche in the marketplace, gives rise to grow to its natural market potential.

Convergence will bring the less developed nations up to speed with the other markets. If

nations with slower Gross Domestic Product (GDP) do catch up, then we should see the FSU

growing quickly (de la Fuente 1997).

A study over the period from 1994 to 1998 found that FDI in Europe’s formerly centrally

planned economies, have many determining factors to inflows of FDI including country risk, unit

labor cost, host market size and gravity factors. It also found that the announcing of a country

preparing to join the European Union (EU) caused increased faith in the economy of that

country and FDI inflows increased as a result which further improved the performance of those

Page 3: Foreign Direct Investment in the former Soviet Union

Page 3

emerging economies. Conversely countries that were not members of the EU, and did not have

plans to join would not receive as much FDI and would continue to struggle for stability and

growth progress (Bevan and Estrin 2000). Such findings support the theory that FDI can help

economies to improve their performance. The intent here is to show that it applies at a larger

level to the FSU than average.

It is also shown that multinational corporations (MNC’s) are more technologically

advanced than average, and as such are able to bring new technology into the countries in

which they invest. This follows the theory of FDI increasing production through technology

spillovers. The marginal cost of these MNC’s is lower for developing and replicating new

technologies for their production. A large limiting factor in underdeveloped nations is human

capital (Borensztein et al. 1998). The work force must be able to learn the new jobs without

excessive training in order for the corporations and economies to benefit from it.

In this paper, I aim to show the positive aspects of FDI and what the FSU nations can

hope to gain from continuing to open their borders to investment. There are other papers that

deal more with the effects of the structure set up in industry under communism and the

difficulties that come with restructuring to a market economy that no longer has to follow such

mandates as from a social planner. For further reading on that, I would recommend “Corporate

Governance in the Former Soviet Union: An Overview” by Saul Estrin and Mike Wright 1999.

I am isolating the FSU from the rest of the nations because of the history of them being

combined into the same government and economic society, and then splitting into separate

governments and economies. Any corruption or political boundaries that may come into effect

are difficult to measure and collect data on. Inferences may be made, but the issue is a difficult

Page 4: Foreign Direct Investment in the former Soviet Union

Page 4

one to resolve. Some analysis with such indicators will be attempted in this paper, but the

findings are not robust enough to be strong indicators.

I believe that while such things as governance and corruption may cause problems, it

may not be much worse than with most countries and is subjective in measurement, so that the

bulk of the benefit and difficulty with these economies comes more from their being set up by a

social planner in a less than optimal fashion, or at least one that a market structure would

support, and their ability to restructure to achieve desired economic growth to increase welfare

and utility of the general public.

Investigating the impact of FDI in the FSU has potential to aid in improving our

understanding of how to help transitioning economies. Such benefits can be from showing

corporations how to more securely enter the restructuring markets. FDI helps growth where

financial markets are in good condition which shows transitioning economies to first strengthen

their financial sector and to improve trade restrictions that promote FDI. As mentioned earlier,

it is also important to have human capital at a level comparable to the FDI it wishes to attract.

The rest of the paper is divided into five sections. The next section discusses the model

and its theory. Section three presents the variables for analysis, while section four presents the

data. Section five discusses the regression results. Section six is the conclusion.

II. Structure of the Model: The form of the model presented here is Ordinary Least Squares (OLS).

This gives a basic model that makes the affect clearer since it is the coefficient of FDI in FSU

nations. The growth rate of Gross Domestic Product is the most widely used indicators of

economic growth and development. Therefore it is used here as the dependent variable

Page 5: Foreign Direct Investment in the former Soviet Union

Page 5

explained by a series of independent variables. It is expected that FDI in the FSU will have a

positive effect since the socialist structure of their economies is not as efficient for producing

technology. It is expected that the FSU will best benefit from FDI with restructuring their

economies with more profitable organization, especially in management. The structure of the

model is:

1 2 3* * * *GDPgrowth FDI FSU FDI FSU controls

In this model I start in 1995 to allow for some of the stress of the transition to be

relieved so that economies showing promise and stabilizing are more likely to attract FDI

inflows that will be of more significance to them in their growth efforts. The data is therefore

more limited, but gives results that are a better representation of the progress the nations are

making as they become more capitalistic and is a better representation of the new growth

these transitional economies are now experiencing. It is hoped that the data is more consistent

and therefore more reliable in analysis.

I created a variable to represent FDI in just the FSU nations, which is an indicator

variable multiplied by the FDI inflows into all nations. It therefore only has values for the 12

FSU nations consistent with their FDI inflows, and is zero for all other nations.

The other variables in this analysis include Gross Fixed Capital Formation (as a

percentage of GDP) representing the industrialization that accompanies and promotes growth,

Secondary School Enrollment (as a percentage of gross student age population) to represent

human capital, Crude Birth Rate (per 1000 people) as another measure of human capital, the

natural logarithm of GDP in 1999 as a measure of initial capital stock, openness to trade,

Page 6: Foreign Direct Investment in the former Soviet Union

Page 6

inflation, and Gross Domestic Savings (as a percentage of GDP).

As noted in the introduction, when a country develops an encouraging growth trend, it

attracts more FDI. There are some concerns of endogeneity and causality in the model for such

reasons. FDI may increase because growth increases, growth may increase because FDI

increases, both could benefit each other, or there may be no direct effect from one to the

other. In an effort to avoid such causality issues, I used data for the independent variables from

a period preceding the data from the growth or dependant variable. This keeps causality clear

in that the data are not taken from the same year, but are presented as the independent

variables causing the dependent variable at a later date which does allow for causality only in

one direction.

III. Variables for analysis: The main variables of interest are Foreign Direct Investment, as well as Foreign Direct

Investment in the Former Soviet Union nations. The FDI net inflows (as a % of GDP) variable is

included for all countries, plus an additional FDI variable multiplied by an indicator of whether

the country was a member of the FSU in order to show the added benefit the FSU nations

would benefit from FDI.

Gross Domestic Savings was included in the model under the theory of it working with

FDI, instead it may be interpreted that FDI was a substitute for domestic savings. Gross Fixed

Capital Formation was included in the model in representation of industrialization which is

generally associated with economic growth.

Secondary School Enrollment rates, as a percent of the population of age for that level

of schooling, was included in the model. It is used as an indicator of human capital and labor.

Page 7: Foreign Direct Investment in the former Soviet Union

Page 7

Crude Birth Rate was also included as a measure of human capital, it was available for much

less countries, but since education levels were higher for FSU nations there may be a negative

correlation to growth and education enrollment levels.

Openness to Trade is in the model as well, which was calculated by adding exports to

imports both of which are measured as a percent of GDP for the year 1999. Openness to trade

can be quite substantial in growth as it invites more specialization and productivity in those

areas of production in which the home country has a comparative advantage. This makes the

home country more profitable and thereby increases growth. Growth is shown to be positively

correlated to trade openness (Edwards 1997). Edwards also reminds us how complicated it can

be to determine which arena to focus our attention on when discussing and considering how to

benefit growth with trade:

“The complex nature of commercial policy – international trade can be

effected by tariffs, quotas, licenses, prohibitions, and exchange controls, among

others – suggests that attempts to construct a single indicator of trade

orientation may be futile, and will tend to generate disagreements and

controversies. (Edwards 1997)”

This issue of having so many avenues to approach in order to improve international trade, and

hopefully benefit home countries with more growth is further complicated with war getting in

the way of good trade relations especially if production facilities are damaged in battle. Even at

that, the fact that these policies and restrictions and gateways are all so inter-related makes

calculating benefits of lessening controls difficult to pinpoint so as to direct one as to where to

start. The reliability and accuracy of policy and trade indicators is certainly a difficult point to

Page 8: Foreign Direct Investment in the former Soviet Union

Page 8

address as it makes conclusions drawn from such indicators a little more grey (Rodriguez and

Rodrik 1999).

Inflation is included under the idea that price levels affect trade and investment

between nations, and is calculated using consumer price levels from each country with the

standard as US$ in the year 2000=100, and calculating the percent change in prices from 1998

to 1999. Inflation can have varying effects on trade. As the price levels change within

countries, it alters the currency value in the exchange markets, and that causes price

differentials by virtue of the exchange rate. As the United States Dollar falls in value, American

goods become cheaper to other nations which may increase demand for American goods and

thereby increases American profitability. A large study covering data from 1960 to 1990

showed that when inflation is as much as ten percentage points per year, it can cause a drop in

the real growth rate of GDP per capita by as much as 0.3 percentage points annually, and also

reduce investment as a percent of GDP by as much as 0.6 percentage points annually (Barro

1995).

The logarithm of Initial GDP per capita was included in regressions as a measure of

initial capital. This was included in the model under the theory that it takes money to make

money, or some initial capital stock must be present in order for the economy to exist or grow.

I also ran another set of regressions with a governance indicator included to give

another term that may indicate a difference with other nations. The governance indicator I

used was developed by Kaufmann, Kraay, and Mastruzzi and a table of their indicators is

available on the World Bank Website. I used the Rule of Law indicator, and tried it in three

different ways: just with its own value, multiplied by FSU, and multiplied by FDI*FSU. There

Page 9: Foreign Direct Investment in the former Soviet Union

Page 9

was high correlation between the five indicators they developed, so there is little difference in

the choice of variable from the set.

IV. Data: The data was collected from the World Bank’s World Development Indicators (WDI)

2008 CD-Rom version. This was accessed through Washington State University’s subscription.

It had the variables of interest for a very large number of countries. Table one shows the

descriptive statistics of the variables in the model that were used to run regressions to test the

model (based off the Carkovic and Levine model).

Table 1: Base Year 1999 Descriptive Statistics

Mean Standard

Error

Standard

Deviation

Sample

Variance Min. Max. Count

GDPgpc (2001-2005) 2.846 0.252 3.439 11.830 -6.000 24.057 187

FDIFSU (1996-2000) 0.257 0.083 1.078 1.163 0.000 6.597 168

FDI net inflows (1996-2000) 4.533 0.469 6.073 36.886 -3.073 51.476 168

FSU - - - - 0 1 187

Gross Domestic Savings (% of GDP) 16.079 1.088 14.306 204.649 -41.225 53.231 173

Gross Fixed Capital Formation 21.464 0.554 7.290 53.146 3.087 47.993 173

Secondary School Enrollment 67.337 2.735 33.833 1144.670 5.178 159.499 153

Crude Birth Rate 14.310 0.744 6.093 37.128 7.800 41.800 67

Log of Initial Income per Capital 7.581 0.117 1.587 2.520 4.537 10.675 185

Inflation 0.138 0.032 0.408 0.166 -0.085 2.937 162

Openness to Trade 82.943 3.248 43.459 1888.670 18.969 251.372 179

Rule of Law -0.040 0.078 1.022 1.045 -2.267 1.925 170

Rule of Law *FSU -0.035 0.017 0.215 0.046 -1.404 0.590 170

Rule of Law *FSU*FDI -0.084 0.059 0.766 0.586 -5.925 3.713 170

Data from World Bank, World Development Indicators 2008 CD-Rom version. Base year of 1999 unless

otherwise specified.

The growth of the FSU nations in constant based on the year 2000 United States dollar

value of Gross Domestic Product per Capita and is shown in table two. To show the effect of

the break up, it is important to look at the available information on their economies previous to

Page 10: Foreign Direct Investment in the former Soviet Union

Page 10

the break up. Data for the former Soviet Union are limited, and likely not as accurate as hoped,

but still is able to give some clues as to the effects of the restructuring of their economies.

Table 2: GDP per capita (constant 2000 US$)

Country\Year 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995

Belarus

1410 1392 1256 1158 1024 920

Estonia 3873 3887 3993 4080 4190 3891 3598 2888 2794 2806 2986

Georgia 1986 1805 1809 1893 1749 1493 1188 665 479 438 458

Kazakhstan 1612 1425 1351 1235 1095 1023

Kyrgyz Republic

397 402 444 448 465 422 359 304 243 227

Latvia 3628 3777 3842 4014 4217 3901 3421 2349 2271 2356 2364

Lithuania

4337 4085 3220 2710 2462 2561

Moldova 751 803 806 813 849 824 690 489 483 334 331

Russian Federation

2693 2602 2465 2106 1926 1686 1618

Tajikistan 521 522 499 551 501 485 441 308 253 196 169

Ukraine

1408 1438 1487 1389 1270 1143 980 759 672

Uzbekistan 643 685 690 685 667 579 553 514 500

Country\Year 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006

Belarus 949 1062 1156 1200 1273 1338 1412 1519 1701 1871 2067

Estonia 3164 3555 3750 3790 4106 4438 4813 5174 5610 6211 6938

Georgia 517 579 604 629 648 687 733 823 880 974 1075

Kazakhstan 1044 1078 1076 1116 1229 1397 1534 1671 1819 1978 2166

Kyrgyz Republic 240 260 261 267 279 291 289 306 324 321 326

Latvia 2477 2727 2904 3065 3302 3588 3854 4154 4539 5047 5681

Lithuania 2701 2910 3144 3112 3263 3498 3753 4158 4487 4873 5277

Moldova 316 325 307 300 311 334 365 395 430 468 492

Russian Federation 1564 1591 1511 1614 1775 1870 1968 2122 2286 2444 2620

Tajikistan 139 140 145 148 159 173 186 203 222 234 247

Ukraine 610 597 591 594 636 701 745 823 930 962 1037

Uzbekistan 499 515 528 543 558 574 590 608 647 684 724

Data from World Bank, World Development Indicators 2008 CD-Rom version.

The restructuring of economies in the case of the former Soviet Union and its breaking-

up caused an immediate downturn in their economies, after which they have regained what

they had lost in terms of GDP per capita. Estonia, Latvia, Lithuania, Kazakhstan, and Russia have

Page 11: Foreign Direct Investment in the former Soviet Union

Page 11

actually gained more GDP per capita than they had at the break up. These countries were

showing good growth between 1985 and 1991, but when the Soviet Union split up, they fell

immediately. Russia did not start to progress again until about 1999, while the other former

Soviet Union nations began to return to positive growth paths around 1995.

Inflows of Foreign Direct Investment are the most interesting of the FDI variables since

the theory is that inflows are what effect growth through technology advances in production,

as well as product introduction. It is the most available variable for FDI from the World Bank as

well.

Table 3: Correlation Matrix

GDP

Growth

Rate

FDI*FSU

(1996-

2000)

FDI, net

inflows (% of

GDP) (1996-

2000)

Gross

domestic

savings (% of

GDP)

Gross fixed

capital

formation (% of

GDP)

School

enrollment,

secondary (%

gross)

Crude

Birth

Rate

Log of

Initial GDP

per capita

Inflation

FDI*FSU (1996-

2000) 0.375 1

FDI, net inflows

(% of GDP)

(1996-2000)

0.324 0.009 1

Gross domestic

savings (% of

GDP)

0.104 -0.021 0.035 1

Gross fixed

capital formation

(% of GDP)

0.026 -0.016 0.359 0.197 1

School

enrollment,

secondary (%

gross)

0.005 0.156 0.076 0.421 0.175 1

Crude Birth Rate -0.240 -0.143 -0.177 -0.097 0.027 -0.413 1

Log of Initial

GDP per capita -0.048 -0.072 0.162 0.549 0.219 0.796 -0.351 1

Inflation 0.122 0.090 -0.009 0.001 -0.118 -0.159 -0.067 -0.220 1

Openness to

Trade 0.080 0.106 0.477 0.290 0.391 0.173 -0.228 0.250 0.048

Data from World Bank, World Development Indicators 2008 CD-Rom version.

Page 12: Foreign Direct Investment in the former Soviet Union

Page 12

Table three presents the correlation matrix for the variables. There was a notable

correlation (0.477) between FDI inflows and openness to trade, which shows that it can be

beneficial to increase openness to trade to invite more FDI inflows. Another notable

correlation is that which is found between Secondary School Enrollment and the log of Initial

GDP per capita (0.796). This follows the theory of human capital supporting growth. Gross

Domestic Savings is also highly correlated (0.549) with the log of Initial GDP per capita.

Consequently, there is a correlation (0.421) between secondary school enrollment and savings.

It may be a result of better educated people making more money and thereby being able to

save more.

I use per capita GDP since family and individual welfare is at the heart of national

success. The dependent variables of Foreign Direct Investment, Gross Capital Formation, and

Gross Domestic Savings are included as percentages of GDP. This is to keep them relative to

the country’s economy size. This will show if they change relative to GDP. If it is shown that

they fall relative to GDP, especially if GDP is increasing in the meantime, shows that they are

less important to growth or possibly have a negative effect on growth. The opposite may also

be assumed.

V. Results The model tested herein was run with the data from the World Bank and returned the

results found in Table 4. The coefficients that tested to be significant to the 1%, 5%, and 10%

levels are marked with three, two, or one stars respectively. The R-squared values, as well as

the f-statistics with degrees of freedom are also listed for each regression.

Page 13: Foreign Direct Investment in the former Soviet Union

Page 13

Table 4: Regression Results with 1999 Base Year

Variable and Abbreviation 1 2 3 4 5 6 7

FDI*FSU (1996-2000) 1.177253696*** 1.020616*** 0.5989597*** 1.02424*** 0.498204 0.3875706

(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.180) (0.361)

FDI, net inflows (% of GDP)

(1996-2000)

0.099230* 0.066652 0.089695* 0.1688492*** 0.110500** 0.0586109 0.0897582*

(0.071) (0.216) (0.082) (0.005) (0.043) (0.239) (0.068)

FSU indicator 3.329632** 3.280747 4.851288***

(0.035) (0.111) (0.000)

Gross domestic savings (%

of GDP)

0.0292815

0.0650209** 0.0316734 0.024789

0.0526232***

(0.019)

(0.049) (0.270) (0.198)

(0.009)

Crude Birth Rate

-

0.2380626***

(0.000)

Gross fixed capital

formation (% of GDP)

0.035555 0.0846482**

0.1477094*** 0.035264 0.0747151** 0.0555807

(0.290) (0.019)

(0.001) (0.289) (0.030) (0.102)

School enrollment,

secondary (% gross)

0.0224695* 0.0130283

0.0153975 0.0125467

(0.056) (0.284)

(0.203) (0.284)

Openness to Trade -0.006216 -0.0062585 -0.0135856** -0.0146073** -0.007106

(0.322) (0.308) (0.046) (0.028) (0.254)

Inflation 0.3644437

(0.480)

Log of Initial GDP per capita -0.373711** -0.6998317*** -1.600056*** -0.7754999*** -0.317298* -0.543592** -0.7132263***

(0.021) (0.006) (0.000) (0.006) (0.050) (0.040) (0.009)

R-squared 0.2468 0.3341 0.7162 0.4097 0.2688 0.3419 0.3729

f-statistic F(6,152) F(6,125) F(6,54) F(8,112) F(7,151) F(6,126) F(6,125)

8.30 10.45 22.71 9.72 7.93 10.91 12.39

Data from World Bank, World Development Indicators 2008 CD-Rom version. Base year of 1999 unless otherwise specified.

(***), (**), and (*) indicate significance to the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels, respectively. Constant terms vary by regression and are

omitted.

The aim of this paper is to illustrate the effect of Foreign Direct Investment on growth

particularly in the former Soviet Union nations. As such there is an indicator FSU*FDI variable

for just those FSU nations to show the added benefit of FDI within those nations. When the

regression included FDI*FSU and FDI they were both significant to at least the 10% level. When

the indicator for FSU was also included, however, it lowered the significance of FDI*FSU.

Regression one included FDI*FSU, FDI, Gross Domestic Savings (GDS), Gross Fixed

Page 14: Foreign Direct Investment in the former Soviet Union

Page 14

Capital Formation (as a percent of GDP) [GFCF], Openness to Trade, and the log of initial GDP

per capita. FDI*FSU was significant to the 1%, FDI was significant to the 10% level, and the log

of GDP per capita was significant to the 5% level.

The second regression excluded GDS while including Secondary School Enrollment which

was significant to the 10% level. FDI fell in significance to below the 10% level and fell in value a

little bit, while GFCF grew to the 5% level and more than doubled in value, and the log of GDP

per capita grew in significance to the 1% level and doubled in value.

The third regression included Crude Birth Rate (CBR) which is not available for many of

the countries, so it cut the regression down, but as a result it greatly increased the R-squared.

The fourth regression then omits CBR again, and changes some other control variables with

minor changes in the results, although the R-squared is better than the first two regressions.

The first four regressions all found FDI*FSU to be quite significant, while the significance

of FDI over all had varying significance. Clearly there was something different about the FSU

that was being captured in the interaction term. To determine whether it was in fact FDI, I

added the indicator FSU variable in the last three regressions. It was quite large and significant

while it reduced the significance of FDI*FSU.

The fifth and sixth regressions added in an indicator variable for FSU nations. The

addition of that variable removed significance of the FDI*FSU variable with little other changes

in the results. The seventh regression excluded FDI*FSU which increased the value and

significance of the FSU indicator variable as well as GDS significance. This lends some evidence

to there being a different more influential factor. There is certainly a difference between the

FSU and other nations, evidenced by the FSU indicator.

Page 15: Foreign Direct Investment in the former Soviet Union

Page 15

It is important to note that in the seven regressions, there are some countries of the FSU

that are excluded because of missing information. Secondary School Enrollment data was not

available for the Russian Federation and Uzbekistan. Crude Birth Rates were not available for

Georgia, Moldova, and Tajikistan. Inflation was not available for Tajikistan and Uzbekistan.

Rule of Law (as well as the other 4 governance indicators) did not have data for Kyrgyz Republic

and the Russian Federation.

The interaction term of FDI*FSU was found to be significant in the first four regressions.

The values in these regressions range from 0.59 and 1.02, which shows that up to a whole

percent of the growth of GDP within FSU nations, can be account for by increasing FDI inflows

by one percent of GDP holding all else constant. It is significant to the 1% level in all six

regressions. That is quite significant considering that average growth over all nations in the

sample is about 2.5%.

The FSU indicator variable had coefficients 3.33, 3.28, and 4.85 in regressions 5, 6, and

7. It was also significant to the 5% level in regression 2, and to the 1% level in regression 7

which excluded the interaction term of FDI*FSU. This means that holding all else constant, just

the fact that a country was a member of the Soviet Union means that they are presently

growing up to almost 5% faster than average.

When the interaction term is included, it accounts for up to a whole percent of growth

above and beyond non FSU nations’ growth from FDI holding all else constant. When the

interaction term is included along with FDI and FSU separately, at least one loses significance.

The most robust of the three seems to be FDI*FSU, but since it is not significant along with FSU,

it cannot be as easily interpreted as robust and a real contributor to growth.

Page 16: Foreign Direct Investment in the former Soviet Union

Page 16

As mentioned previously, the gains from FDI may be difficult to capture in a numerical

model. Convergence may even be supported more by FDI and trade than international

progress and it is easily argued that all work together for the progress of all. We have seen

many nations increase their growth and production upon opening borders to trade and learning

from imported products and foreign investors’ new ways of efficiency and production. It is

difficult to put numbers on these influences, but noticing a correlation between trade openness

and FDI flows with the growth of a nation, give evidence of such benefits.

Once again, however, this model fails to show that especially with the openness to trade

variable giving all negative coefficients and half of those calculated were significant to the 5%

level. What this shows is that according to my model, the more open a country is to trade,

holding all else constant, the less their economy will grow, in fact it will even grow slower as a

result of openness to trade up to 1.3% slower.

These results lend a good deal of evidence to convergence theory. The coefficient of

the natural log of initial GDP per capita was always negative and always significant to at least

the 10% level. In four of the seven regressions, it was significant to the 1% level, and was

lowest in the third regression at -1.6%. So, holding all else constant, the more GDP per capita a

nation had at the start, in the year 1999, the slower they grew on average.

Gross Fixed Capital Formation was also very significant in the analysis, and was well

correlated (0.359) to FDI inflows. This supports the long-term nature of FDI in developing

capital and structure which can raise productivity in the economy as a whole as well as in the

firms directly receiving FDI (Barrell and Holland 2000). Barrell and Holland also discovered that

when research is taken into account, FDI no longer has an impact on the economy, but the

Page 17: Foreign Direct Investment in the former Soviet Union

Page 17

research does. When the research is brought to that country as a result of MNC’s production in

that country, then I believe it is still a result of FDI although maybe not as directly as the

regressions show.

There are some other variables in the model that are strongly significant in improving

growth. One such is the Crude Birth Rate, which was only available for 67 countries, but 9 of

the 12 FSU nations had that variable, and including it in the regression made the R-squared as

high as 0.71 for a greatly supported model. The coefficient for the birth rate was negative,

which follows the theory of population growth slowing as development occurs. That is a great

increase over the model with education, and not the birth rate, as the human development

indicator had R-squared value up to 0.41. This is still a reasonable model for such a large group

of such diversity since they include over a hundred nations with varying levels of development.

Inflation which would affect price levels and influencing trade did not test to be very

significant in the model. It was included to help determine robustness and to check and see if it

is significant. It actually tested to have a positive coefficient of 0.36 in regression four. It would

seem that inflation should have a negative impact on growth as higher prices would lessen

exports in theory. Openness to trade was included in that regression and it did have a negative

coefficient of -0.015 and was significant to the 5% level.

The interaction term FDI*FSU is insignificant when the FSU indicator variable is included

in the regression. This leads me to believe that there is a greater distinction between the FSU

and other nations which may be captured in governance indicators. It may be that countries

with better institutions and less corruption are able to better utilize FDI. In order to determine

the effect of governance and see if it would make a difference in the significance of the FDI*FSU

Page 18: Foreign Direct Investment in the former Soviet Union

Page 18

(or any other) variables I found some governance indicators that could be included in the

regression. The regressions and analysis thereof follow.

Table 5: Governance Indicators

Variable and Abbreviation 1 2 3 4

FDI*FSU 0.2808042 0.2890947 0.2808042 0.2921956

(0.604) (0.506) (0.604) (0.503)

FDI, net inflows (% of GDP) (1996-2000) 0.0655467 0.0658427 0.0655467 0.0655314

(0.209) (0.208) (0.209) (0.209)

FSU indicator 4.200222 4.151858* 4.200222 4.125981*

(0.165) (0.057) (0.165) (0.063)

Gross fixed capital formation (% of GDP) 0.0617689* 0.0613066* 0.0617689* 0.061822*

(0.085) (0.094) (0.085) (0.085)

School enrollment, secondary (% gross) 0.0173286 0.0171263 0.0173286 0.0172705

(0.177) (0.184) (0.177) (0.178)

Rule of Law 0.0320419

(0.944)

Rule of Law *FSU 0.0535104

(0.972)

Rule of Law *FDI*FSU 0.0003421

(0.999)

Log of Initial GDP per capita -0.6212972** -0.6329134* -0.6212972** -0.6197108**

(0.028) (0.060) (0.028) (0.028)

R-squared 0.3715 0.3715 0.3715 0.3715

f-statistic F(7,115) F(7,115) F(7,115) F(7,115)

9.71 9.71 9.71 9.71

Data from World Bank, World Development Indicators 2008 CD-Rom version. Base year of 1999 unless otherwise specified.

(***), (**), and (*) indicate significance to the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels, respectively. Constant terms vary by regression and are

omitted. This model is the same as the 6th regression in the first model plus the governance variables. Regulatory Quality

provided by the World Bank website from "Governance Matters VIII: Governance Indicators for 1996-2008" by Kaufmann et al. Breusch-Pagan test on regression 2 resulted in a chi-squared of 0.24 with probability > chi-squared of 0.6262.

The results with the governance indicator of Rule of Law are not significantly different

from the previous model and its regressions. I used the model from the sixth regression in the

first set adding in the governance variable. One difference is that the FSU indicator variable

went up by almost a whole percent from 3.28 to 4.2. The governance variable, however, never

tested to be significant.

Page 19: Foreign Direct Investment in the former Soviet Union

Page 19

VI. Conclusion: Growth of the former Soviet Union nations was analyzed in this paper in an effort to

identify the benefit they receive from foreign direct investment. An ordinary least squares

model was used to calculate growth benefits of the nations from factors commonly accepted to

affect Gross Domestic Product.

In my analysis, I found that after the breakup of the Soviet Union there was a downturn

in economic growth per capita, but within five years of the breakup most countries were

recovered and resuming growth. Because of this growth pattern, I ran some regressions to see

if FDI might have been a driving influence in the recovery of the nations that lost GDP per capita

for a few years. As such an interaction term of FDI*FSU was included in the analysis in an effort

to determine if FDI was a greater factor in the growth of FSU nations than other nations and it

was found to be significant until the FSU indicator variable was added. FDI*FSU was expected

to have more influence in the FSU than other nations because their technology and socialistic

market structures were lagging capitalist industrialized nations. However, the indicator variable

absorbed the significance, and had a much larger value than FDI*FSU. This may be because of

the difficulty of capturing all the benefits of FDI in numerical data, or it could be a result of

omitted variables.

Since the Soviet Union has only been broken up since 1991 and data collection has not

been expansive, so the results found here may later be verified or disproved as more reliable

data becomes available and especially as the more far reaching effects of the break up are

magnified with time. From the structure of my model and the numerical analysis, it is difficult

to say with much surety that there is a positive correlation between FDI inflows as a percent of

Page 20: Foreign Direct Investment in the former Soviet Union

Page 20

GDP and GDP growth rates. The more time goes on, and the more transparent the transitioning

economies become, the more reliable these analyses can be. It seems at this time, however,

that FDI should be encouraged to assist these nations especially those which have financial

structures and human capital to more effectively utilize and benefit from such.

Page 21: Foreign Direct Investment in the former Soviet Union

Page 21

References: Alfaro, Laura., Areendam Chanda, Sebnem Kalemli-Ozcan, and Selin Sayek (2004), ‘FDI and Economic Growth: The Role of Local Financial Markets.’ Journal of International Economics, Volume 64, Issue 1, Pages 89-112. Barrell, Ray and Dawn Holland (2000), ‘Foreign Direct Investment and Enterprise Restructuring in Central Europe.’ Economics of Transition, Volume 8, Issue 2, pp. 477- 504. Barro, R.J. (1995), ‘Inflation and Economic Growth.’ Bank of England Quarterly Bulletin, Volume 35 (May): pp. 166-176. Bevan, Alan A. and Saul Estrin (2000), ‘The Determinants of Foreign Direct Investment in Transition Economies.’ Working Paper Number 342. Borenstein, E., J De Gregorio, and J-W. Lee (1998), ‘How Does Foreign Direct Investment Affect Economic Growth?’ Journal of International Economics, Volume 45, pp. 115-135. Campos, Nauro F., and Yuko Kinoshita (2002), ‘Foreign Direct Investment as Technology Transferred: Some Panel Evidence from the Transition Economies.’ William Davidson Working Paper Number 438. Carkovic, Maria and Ross Levine (2002), ‘Does Foreign Direct Investment Accelerate Economic Growth?’ University of Minnesota Department of Finance Working Paper. In Does Foreign Direct Investment Promote Development? ed. Theodore H. Moran, Edward M. Graham, and Magnus Blomström. Washington, DC: Institute for International Economics, pp. 221–44. de la Fuente, A., (1997), ‘The Empirics of Growth and Convergence: A Selective Review.’ Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, Volume 2, Issue 1, pp. 23-73. Edwards, Sebastian (1997), ‘Openness, Productivity and Growth: What Do We Really Know?’ NBER Working Paper 5978. Kaufmann, Daniel., Aart Kraay and Massimo Mastruzzi (2009), ‘Governance Matters VIII: Governance Indicators for 1996-2008.’ World Bank Policy Research June Rodriguez, Francisco and Dani Rodrik (2001), ‘Trade Policy and Economic Growth: A Skeptic’s Guide to the Cross-National Evidence.’ Macroeconomics Annual 2000, eds. Ben Bernanke and Kenneth S. Rogoff, MIT Press for NBER, Cambridge, MA. Sachs, Jeffery and Wing Thye Woo (1994), ‘Structural Factors in the Economic Reforms of China, Eastern Europe, and the Former Soviet Union.’ Economic Policy, pp 102-145.