fairness in apportionment how do you decide whether a method for apportioning representatives is...

21
Fairness in Apportionment How do you decide whether a method for apportioning representatives is fair?

Upload: sybil-parrish

Post on 11-Jan-2016

221 views

Category:

Documents


1 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Fairness in Apportionment How do you decide whether a method for apportioning representatives is fair?

Fairness in Apportionment

How do you decide whether a method for apportioning representatives is fair?

Page 2: Fairness in Apportionment How do you decide whether a method for apportioning representatives is fair?

Absolute Fairness

• If a state has a certain percentage of the total population, it should have that same percentage of seats in the House.

But, this usually results in a fractional number of seats, called the ideal quota or standard quota for the state. Thus, in most cases we have to go up or down to get an integer number or representatives.

Page 3: Fairness in Apportionment How do you decide whether a method for apportioning representatives is fair?

Upper and Lower Quota

Suppose a state has an ideal quota of 8.87 representatives.

• Its upper quota will be 9.

• Its lower quota will be 8.

Page 4: Fairness in Apportionment How do you decide whether a method for apportioning representatives is fair?

Satisfying Quota

• Any apportionment system which gives each state no fewer representatives than its lower quota and no more representatives than its upper quota is said to satisfy quota.

• An apportionment system which fails to do this for even one state is said to violate quota.

Page 5: Fairness in Apportionment How do you decide whether a method for apportioning representatives is fair?

An example

A state has an ideal quota of 23.71.

If, under a particular apportionment system, the state receives less than 23 representatives or more than 24 representatives, the system will have violated quota.

Page 6: Fairness in Apportionment How do you decide whether a method for apportioning representatives is fair?

What about our methods?

• Hamilton’s method never violates quota.

• Jefferson, Adams and Webster (and, in fact, any divisor method) can violate quota, although they do not always do so. We will see an historical example of this for Jefferson’s method on the next slide.

Page 7: Fairness in Apportionment How do you decide whether a method for apportioning representatives is fair?

Jefferson ♥ NY!

• New York’s population, 1820 census, was 1,368,775 while the total population of the US was 8,969,878.

• The house size was 213 so the standard divisor was 8,969,878 ÷ 213 = 42,112. Thus, NY’s ideal quota was 1,368,775 ÷ 42,112 = 32.503.

• Jefferson’s method, using a divisor of 39,900, gave NY int[1,368,775 ÷ 39,900] = 34 seats! This violated upper quota.

Page 8: Fairness in Apportionment How do you decide whether a method for apportioning representatives is fair?

Jefferson’s woes continued

• If Jefferson’s method had been used (it wasn’t) since 1850, it would have violated quota in every apportionment!

Page 9: Fairness in Apportionment How do you decide whether a method for apportioning representatives is fair?

Paradoxes

• Consider the following data for the Dale County schools.

Population

North High 9061

South High 7179

Valley High 5259

Meadow H. 3319

Ridge High 1182

Total 26,000

Page 10: Fairness in Apportionment How do you decide whether a method for apportioning representatives is fair?

Getting the Ideal Quotas

• We want to consider how to apportion Councils of size 26, 27 and 40 using Hamilton’s method.

26

Seat

27

seat

40

seat

Standard

Divisor

1000 963 650

Page 11: Fairness in Apportionment How do you decide whether a method for apportioning representatives is fair?

Table of Ideal Quotas

26 seats 27 seats 40 seats

North 9.061 9.4095 13.94 +1

South 7.179 7.455 +1 11.045

Valley 5.259 5.4613 +1 8.0908

Meadow 3.319 +1 3.4467 5.1062

Ridge 1.182 1.2275 1.8185 +1

Page 12: Fairness in Apportionment How do you decide whether a method for apportioning representatives is fair?

The Hamilton Apportionments

26 seats 27 seats 40 seats

North 9 9 14

South 7 8 11

Valley 5 6 8

Meadow 4 3 5

Ridge 1 1 2

26 27 40

Page 13: Fairness in Apportionment How do you decide whether a method for apportioning representatives is fair?

Alabama Paradox

• Notice what happened to Meadow High when Council size went from 26 to 27 seats! There was no change in total population or in any school population and yet Meadow lost a seat when the Council size increased by 1!!

• This is called the Alabama paradox. (Alabama would have lost a seat going from a 299 member house to a 300 member house after the 1880 census.) At this point Congress ditched the Hamilton method!

Page 14: Fairness in Apportionment How do you decide whether a method for apportioning representatives is fair?

Population Paradox

• This occurs when state X loses a seat to state Y even though X’s population grew at a higher rate than Y’s population!

• From 1900 to 1910 Virginia’s population grew by 19,767 while Maine grew by only 4648. Also, Virginia’s population grew at a 60% faster rate, yet, under Hamilton’s method, Virginia lost a seat to Maine!

Page 15: Fairness in Apportionment How do you decide whether a method for apportioning representatives is fair?

Population Paradox: A simple example

• We have 5 states: A,B,C,D,E with a total population of 900 and a 50 seat assembly, making the standard divisor d = 18. Using Hamilton, this gives:

Page 16: Fairness in Apportionment How do you decide whether a method for apportioning representatives is fair?

Population Paradox (cont.)

State Population Ideal Quota Apportion

A 150 8.33 8

B 78 4.33 4

C 173 9.61 +1 10

D 204 11.33 11

E 295 16.39 +1 17

Total 900 50

Page 17: Fairness in Apportionment How do you decide whether a method for apportioning representatives is fair?

Population grows:Only C and E grow

State Population Ideal Quota Apportion

A 150 8.25 8

B 78 4.29 +1 5

C 181 9.96 +1 10

D 204 11.22 11

E 296 16.28 16

Total 909 50

Page 18: Fairness in Apportionment How do you decide whether a method for apportioning representatives is fair?

Look what happened!

• State E, which gained population, lost a seat to state B, which did not gain population!!

Page 19: Fairness in Apportionment How do you decide whether a method for apportioning representatives is fair?

New States Paradox

• The addition of a new state, with its fair share of representatives can change the apportionments of other states.

• In 1907 Oklahoma joined the Union with 5 seats. Using Hamilton’s method to reapportion the House would have NY giving a seat to Maine, even though neither state (or any other) had a population change!

Page 20: Fairness in Apportionment How do you decide whether a method for apportioning representatives is fair?

Are there any apportionment methods that do not violate quota

and avoid all paradoxes??• (Balinsky and Young, 1980) There is

no perfect apportionment method! Any method which does not violate quota must produce paradoxes, and any method that does not produce paradoxes can violate quota.

• No apportionment method is completely fair!

Page 21: Fairness in Apportionment How do you decide whether a method for apportioning representatives is fair?

What about our methods?

• Hamilton satisfies quota but produces paradoxes (Alabama, population, new states)

• Jefferson, Adams, Webster (and all divisor methods) avoid all paradoxes, but can violate quota.