estimation of tax and social insurance burden on ... · researcher, policy research institute,...

26
PRI Discussion Paper Series (No.17A-02) Estimation of Tax and Social Insurance Burden on Households: Verification of the Validity and Assessment of Actual Status Taro Ohno Associate Professor, Faculty of Economics and Law, Shinshu University Senior Visiting Scholar, Policy Research Institute, Ministry of Finance Takahiro Kodama Researcher, Policy Research Institute, Ministry of Finance January 2017 Research Department Policy Research Institute, MOF 3-1-1 Kasumigaseki, Chiyoda-ku, Tokyo 100-8940, Japan TEL 03-3581-4111 The views expressed in this paper are those of the authors and not those of the Ministry of Finance or the Policy Research Institute.

Upload: others

Post on 13-Jun-2020

0 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Estimation of Tax and Social Insurance Burden on ... · Researcher, Policy Research Institute, Ministry of Finance January 2017 Research Department Policy Research Institute, MOF

PRI Discussion Paper Series (No.17A-02)

Estimation of Tax and Social Insurance Burden on Households:

Verification of the Validity and Assessment of Actual Status

Taro Ohno

Associate Professor, Faculty of Economics and Law, Shinshu University

Senior Visiting Scholar, Policy Research Institute, Ministry of Finance

Takahiro Kodama

Researcher, Policy Research Institute, Ministry of Finance

January 2017

Research Department Policy Research Institute, MOF

3-1-1 Kasumigaseki, Chiyoda-ku, Tokyo 100-8940, Japan

TEL 03-3581-4111

The views expressed in this paper are those of the

authors and not those of the Ministry of Finance or

the Policy Research Institute.

Page 2: Estimation of Tax and Social Insurance Burden on ... · Researcher, Policy Research Institute, Ministry of Finance January 2017 Research Department Policy Research Institute, MOF

1

Estimation of Tax and Social Insurance Burden on Households:

Verification of the Validity and Assessment of Actual Status*

Taro Ohno*1

Takahiro Kodama*2

Abstract In recent years, household micro data has been streamlined in Japan. Based on this

environmental development, the number of analyses using household micro data (questionnaire

information) has increased in the fields of taxation and social securities. With the regard to taxes

and social insurance premiums for each household account in these analyses, there are two

cases: (1) using burdens reported in the questionnaire (Reported Value), and (2) using burdens

calculated by applying information, such as family unit, income, etc. reported in the

questionnaire to the actual system (Imputed Value).

We used household micro data from the National Survey of Family Income and Expenditure

(NSFIE) in 2009 by the Ministry of Internal Affairs and Communications, and estimated the

imputed values of tax and social insurance burdens (such as income tax, residence tax,

consumption tax, pension insurance premium, health insurance premium, long-term care

insurance premium and employment insurance premium) on households. On that basis, we

verify the validity of imputed value by comparing it with reported value, and assess the actual

status of fiscal burden on household.

The NSFIE is pointed out that the reported values of income tax and social insurance

premium are underestimated by the effect of seasonality. Therefore, for verifying the validity of

imputed value, we need to focus on the case of residence tax that is less affected by seasonality.

And, it was found that the mean disparity between the reported and imputed values was zero

and the dispersion was approximately 3% to income. For the implication of the examination, the

imputed value has almost no bias in relation to tallied macro values, and it results in an

estimated value with almost no error. Therefore, its accuracy can be used sufficiently for the

assessment of policies.

The underestimation of reported value may result from the possibility that tax and social

premium burdens related to bonuses out of survey period are not reflected completely in the

statistics. From the result of examination, such a hypothesis was supported.

In addition, the total fiscal burden on household including taxes and social insurance

premiums is progressive both in all samples and in each age bracket. The social insurance

premiums and consumption tax have effects to reduce the progressivity. In particular, these are

shown up strongly in the elderly generation. Therefore, the progressivity of fiscal burden is

smaller in the elderly generation, which implies that intra-generational redistributive effect is

weaker in the elderly.

Key words: tax, social insurance premium, imputed value, reported value

JEL Classification: C15, H24

* This research is supported by JSPS KAKENHI Grant Number JP26780176, and uses the information

from questionnaires of the National Survey of Family Income and Expenditure (NSFIE) by the

Ministry of Internal Affairs and Communications. This report is based on the personal opinions of the

authors and does not indicate the official opinions of the institutions to which the authors belong. *1

Associate Professor, Faculty of Economics and Law, Shinshu University; Senior Visiting Scholar,

Policy Research Institute, Ministry of Finance *2

Researcher, Policy Research Institute, Ministry of Finance

Page 3: Estimation of Tax and Social Insurance Burden on ... · Researcher, Policy Research Institute, Ministry of Finance January 2017 Research Department Policy Research Institute, MOF

2

1. Introduction

In recent years, household micro data has been streamlined in Japan. The restructure of tax and

social insurance burdens on households is desirable for maintaining the social security system,

and thus it is important to evaluate the redistribution effect of changing the tax and social

security systems. For doing this, it is necessary to estimate the sophisticatedly imputed value

with micro data which reflects heterogeneity across households. In particular, in current Japan

with the falling birth rate and the aging population, consumption tax has a critical role to fund

the social security cost. Therefore, micro data with households’ consumption information is

increasingly important to assess the whole picture of tax and social insurance burdens on

households1.

For household micro data including consumption information in Japan, there exists the

National Survey of Family Income and Expenditure (NSFIE) by the Ministry of Internal Affairs

and Communications. However, although the NSFIE surveys the burdens of workers’ and non-

workers’ households, it does not survey the burdens of self-employed households. Furthermore,

Ohno et al. (2015) show that the income tax and social insurance burdens reported in the

questionnaire (Reported Value) are underestimated by the effect of seasonality. Thus, it is difficult

to assess the whole picture of tax and social insurance burdens only by using micro data (namely,

reported value).

Under this situation, previous studies with using the NSFIE estimate the tax and social

insurance burdens by applying information, such as family unit, income, etc. reported in the

questionnaire to the actual system (Imputed Value)2. Such a method is same as micro simulation

that makes original variable virtually by applying available variable to the social system by

household, and is able to estimate the burdens of household and variable which are not covered

in the survey. However, the imputed value means estimating a variable with strong individuality,

such as tax and social insurance burdens, by using limited information, and thus is possible to

contain crucial measurement error. Therefore, it is necessary to verify the validity of the

imputed value.

The studies on the validity of the imputed value have occurred before, and have received a

certain amount of interest from analysts who have implemented microsimulation analysis. For

example, Tajika and Yashio (2006a) compares the reported and imputed values of income tax

by focusing on the mean value by each income bracket. Tanaka and Shikata (2012) compares

the imputed value and macro statistic of tax and social insurance burdens. In addition, Ohno et

al. (2015) examine the validity of reported value from the Comprehensive Survey of Living

Conditions (CSLC) by the Ministry of Health, Labour and Welfare by comparing it with other

surveys, and indicate that it is able to evaluate the validity of the imputed value by comparing it

with the reported value of CSLC. And then, they verify the validity of imputed value of income

tax and residence tax by using micro data from CSLC, and show that the mean disparity between

the reported and imputed values is zero and the dispersion was around 3% over time. Tada et al.

(2016) also verify the validity of imputed value of social insurance burdens (such as pension

insurance premium, health insurance premium, long-term care insurance premium and

employment insurance premium) by using micro data from CSLC, and show that the mean

disparity between the reported and imputed values is zero. These examinations imply that imputed

values obtained through microsimulation analysis are estimates with little bias regarding the macro

values obtained through collection of data and that there is little margin of error. In that sense, these

1 There are previous studies which estimate consumption tax burden on households with using micro data,

including Ohtake and Kohara (2005), Yashio and Hasegawa (2009), Takayama and Shiraishi (2010,

2011), Shiraishi (2011) and Tanaka (2014). 2 There are previous studies which analyze tax and social security system with using micro data from the

NSFIE, including Tanaka and Shikata (2012), Tanaka et al. (2013), Kitamura and Miyazaki (2013)

Miyazaki and Kitamura (2014), and Tanaka (2014).

Page 4: Estimation of Tax and Social Insurance Burden on ... · Researcher, Policy Research Institute, Ministry of Finance January 2017 Research Department Policy Research Institute, MOF

3

imputed values have sufficient precision to be used for the evaluation of policies (Ohno et al. 2015,

p.40). In this way, previous studies use data from CSLC for verifying the validity of imputed value

because the accuracy of reported value exists. Now, we can estimate the imputed value of tax

and social insurance burdens because there are also variables required to estimate them in

NSFIE. Sano et al. (2015) and Tada and Miyoshi (2015) show that CSLC and NSFIE are

consistent with regards to information of family unit and income. Therefore, we can apply the

method to estimate imputed value to NSFIE, and furthermore make the imputed value with

sufficient precision.

We use household micro data from NSFIE in 2009, and estimate the imputed values of tax

and social insurance burdens (such as income tax, residence tax, consumption tax, pension

insurance premium, health insurance premium, long-term care insurance premium and

employment insurance premium) on households. On that basis, we verify the validity of

imputed value by comparing it with reported value. As pointed out above, the NSFIE is shown

that the reported values of income tax and social insurance premium are underestimated by the

effect of seasonality. Therefore, we focus on the result of residence tax that is less affected by

seasonality to verify the validity of imputed value. And, we assess the actual status of the fiscal

burden on households.

The outline of this paper will be as follows. First, we confirm data in section 2. Next, we

show the method to estimate imputed values of tax and social insurance premiums in section 3.

In section 4, we verify the validity of imputed value by examining the disparity between

reported and imputed values. In section 5, we assess the actual status of tax and social insurance

burdens on households. Finally, we conclude in section 6.

2. Data

2.1. Data In this analysis, we use micro data from the NSFIE in 2009 (including Household Questionnaire,

Yearly Income and Savings Questionnaire, and Family Account Book). This survey is

conducted every five years and targets approximately 57,000 family units throughout Japan

from September (October in cases of 4,400 single-person households) to November. And, it

surveys several household types at the first month of the survey period, yearly income of the last

year and consumption expenditure and non-consumption expenditure during survey period.

Non-consumption expenditure contains income tax, residence tax, public pension insurance

premium, health insurance premium, long-term care insurance premium and other insurance

premium (namely, employment insurance premium), so detailed data can be used. One of the

aims of this paper is to estimate the imputed values of taxes and social insurance premiums by

applying the information of household type and income to real tax and social security system by

each family unit, and to verify the validity of the imputed value by comparing it to reported

value. Here, we eliminate the following family units that we cannot compare reported value and

imputed value.

-Family units which have a member without age or sex information

-Family units which have a member living away from home for business

-Family units which have a member who deviated from the family during survey period

-Family units which have no information on some important items,

such as income, consumption, taxes and social insurance premiums

Page 5: Estimation of Tax and Social Insurance Burden on ... · Researcher, Policy Research Institute, Ministry of Finance January 2017 Research Department Policy Research Institute, MOF

4

After this elimination, the sample size is 49,977 household units3.

2.2. Income data We use yearly income data from the “Yearly Income and Savings Questionnaire” (not monthly

data from the “Family Account Book”). This data includes the following 10 items.

(1) Income from employment

(2) Income from agriculture, forestry and fishery

(3) Income from business other than (2)

(4) Income through Piecework

(5) Income from house and land rents

(6) Annuities or pensions

(7) Company and private pension benefits

(8) Interest and dividends

(9) Remittance from relatives

(10) Other income

The “Yearly Income and Savings Questionnaire” of the NSFIE asks yearly income of

“household head”, “spouse”, “other household members (aged under 65)” and “other household

members (aged 65 or older)”. Thus, in case of the family unit which has more than one “other

household member” in each category, namely under-65 and 65-or-older, we can only use total

amount of income of members belong to each category. In order to divide the total amount of

income into members individually, we accept the following rule.

In the case of income items (1)(2)(3)(4)(6)(7), these income levels seem to be different by sex

and age. Therefore, first, we calculate the average income by sex (male or female) and age (15-

19, 20-29, 30-39, 40-49, 50-59, 60-69, and 70 or older) group from income data of household

heads and spouses whose individual income data are available originally. Second, we divide the

total income of “other household members (aged under 65)” and “other household members

(aged 65 of older)” into each members by applying ratio of the average income that we

calculated above. For instance, consider that one family unit which has two members belong to

“other household members (aged under 65)”, and they are “36-years-old male” and “28-years-

old female”. Then, we calculate the income from employment of the “36-years-old male” by

applying the following formula.

A = α × β1 / ( β1 + β2 )

α = Income from employment of “other household members (aged under 65)”

β1 = the average of income from employment of “male / age 30-39” group

which is calculated from the income data of household heads and spouses

β2 = the average of income from employment of “female / age 20-29” group

which is calculated from the income data of household heads and spouses

3 In the NSFIE, households are classified into “workers households”, “non-workers households”, and

“other households” (such as, self-employed workers, etc.). The NSFIE surveys consumption

expenditure including taxes and social insurance premiums (reported values) only to “workers

households” and “non-workers households”. Therefore, when we verify the validity of imputed value

of tax and social insurance burdens, the sample is restricted to “workers households” and “non-workers

households”, and thus sample size reduces to 43,391 household units.

Page 6: Estimation of Tax and Social Insurance Burden on ... · Researcher, Policy Research Institute, Ministry of Finance January 2017 Research Department Policy Research Institute, MOF

5

In the case of income items (5)(8)(10), we divide total income into each members equally by

the number of members who belong to “other household members (aged under 65)” or “other

household members (aged 65 or older)”. However, members aged under 15 are not included in

the subject for dividing total income.

2.3. Consumption data We use the consumption data from “Family Account Book”. This questionnaire asks the

following 10 items. Here, the total amount of consumption means the sum of these items.

-Food

-Housing

-Fuel, light and water charges

-Furniture and household utensils

-Clothes and footwear

-Medical care

-Transportation and communication

-Education

-Reading and recreation

-Other living expenditure

For estimating consumption tax burden on household, we need to consider the expenditure

items on which consumption tax is not imposed, namely “tax-free items”. Here, we define the

following subdivided items as “tax-free items”.

-Rents for dwelling

-Rents for land

-Fire and earthquake insurance premium

-Medicines

-Medical treatment

-Dental treatment

-Osteopathic, acupunctural and moxibustic services

-Automotive insurance premium

-School fees

-School textbooks and reference books for study

-Overseas package tours

-Nursery fees

-Nursing care services

-Others

3. Estimation Method

3.1. Direct tax

3.1.1 Income tax and residence tax We estimate the imputed values of income tax and resident tax paid by each household. Note

that despite income being separated into 10 types under Japanese Tax Act, we use limited types

of income such as employment income, employer income, miscellaneous income and real estate

income whose data are available in the NSFIE. We assume that each household chooses the

separate taxation about their interest or dividends, and thus we omit these kinds of incomes

Page 7: Estimation of Tax and Social Insurance Burden on ... · Researcher, Policy Research Institute, Ministry of Finance January 2017 Research Department Policy Research Institute, MOF

6

from the formula of the comprehensive taxation. Here, we calculate total income by the formula

as follow. (The parenthesis means item name applied in questionnaire.)

Employment income = [(1)Income from employment]-Employment income exemption

Pension income = [(6)Annuity or pensions] + [(7)Company and private pension benefits]

-Public pension, etc. exemption

Employer income = [(2) Income from agriculture, forestry and fishery]

+ [(3)Income from business other than (2)]

+ [(4)Income through Piecework]

Real estate income = [(5) Income from house and land rents]

Total income4 = Employment income + Pension income + Employer income

+ Real estate income

Next, according to Ohno et al. (2015), we apply the income exemption and estimate taxable

income by each household. The income exemption contains basic exemption, exemption for

spouse, special exemption for spouse, exemption for dependents and social insurance premiums

exemption. And, these exemptions are applied as follow.

Temporary taxable income 1 = Total income - Basic exemption

- Social insurance premiums exemption

Temporary taxable income 2 = Temporary taxable income 1 - Exemption for spouse

- Special exemption for spouse

Taxable income = Temporary taxable income 2 - Exemption for dependents

First, we calculate temporary taxable income 1 by deducting the basic exemption and social

insurance premiums exemption from total income. Second, if there is a spouse who meets the

income criteria, we calculate temporary taxable income 2 by applying exemption for spouse and

special exemption for spouse to one of a married couple who has higher temporary taxable

income 1. Third, if there are dependents, we apply the exemption for dependents to the family

member who has highest temporary taxable income 2. In this calculation, we will try two cases

in terms of applying social insurance premiums exemption; one is using the reported value of

social insurance premium, and another is using the imputed value of that. Finally, we calculate

the imputed values of income tax and residential tax by applying the real table of tax rate to

their taxable income.

3.1.2 Earned income tax Since the reported value of income tax in the NSFIE is defined as “earned income tax”, we also

need to estimate the imputed value of income tax only from “Income from employment”. We

calculate tax base on simply earned income by the formula as follow.

4 “Total income” means income after deduction for expenses here.

Page 8: Estimation of Tax and Social Insurance Burden on ... · Researcher, Policy Research Institute, Ministry of Finance January 2017 Research Department Policy Research Institute, MOF

7

Temporary taxable income 1 = Employment income - Basic exemption

- Social insurance premiums exemption

Temporary taxable income 2 = Temporary taxable income 1 - Exemption for spouse

- Special exemption for spouse

Taxable income = Temporary taxable income 2 - Exemption for dependents

Then, we estimate the imputed value of earned income tax by applying the same table of tax

rate as above.

3.2. Social insurance premiums In Japan, there are several different social insurance systems for people according to their types

of employment, therefore in order to calculate imputed values of social insurance premiums, it

must be considered which social insurance system each member of household participate in. In

this section, according to Tanaka and Shikata (2012), we estimate which system each member

participates in at first, and then imputed values of public pension insurance premium, health

insurance premium, long-term care insurance premium and employment insurance premium by

applying the real formula of these premiums. Noted that amounts of several premiums are

different by households’ residence in Japan, but enough information about their residence is not

available in NSFIE, hence we use the nationwide average to calculate them here.

3.2.1 Public pension insurance premium We regard the household members as participants in employee pensions (so-called, second

insured persons) if “Income from employments” are more than the amount of “average hourly

wage of short-time workers × 30(hours) × 52(weeks)”, the spouses of them as the third insured

persons whose annual income are less than 1.3 million yen, and the others as the participants in

national pension (so-called, first insured persons). Household members under 19 years old or

over 60 years old do not pay their premiums in principle. However, we regard the household

members who meet the above income criteria for No.2 category of insured as the participants in

employee pension even if they are under 19 or over 60.

We estimating premiums as follow. The first insured persons pay fixed amount of premium

(14,660 yen per month in 2009). But, people who meet the income criteria for reduction and

exemption always apply the deduction and exemption. Since the premium of second insured

persons is paid in equal shares by employer and employee, we estimate their premiums by

multiplying their incomes by half of nationwide average premium rate of employee pensions.

3.2.2 Health insurance premium We regard household members aged 75 or over as participants in the medical care system for

the latter-stage elderly. In the case of members aged 74 or younger, we regard the participants in

the employee pensions as participants in the employee health insurances, and others as

participants in the national health insurance. But, we regard the household members as the

dependents of participants in the employee health insurances if their annual incomes are less

than 1.3 million yen and there is other member that participates in the employee health

insurances.

We calculate premiums as follow. First, since the premium of employee health insurances is

paid in equal shares by employer and employee, we estimate participants’ premiums by

multiplying their incomes by half of nationwide average premium rate of employee health

Page 9: Estimation of Tax and Social Insurance Burden on ... · Researcher, Policy Research Institute, Ministry of Finance January 2017 Research Department Policy Research Institute, MOF

8

insurances. Next, in case of the national health insurance, we estimate the premiums by

applying nationwide average premium rate levied on income, nationwide average premium

amount levied on property, premium amount per capita and per household, and then summing

each household member’s premium up. Lastly, in case of the medical care system for the latter-

stage elderly, we estimate the premiums by applying nationwide average amount levied on

income and levied per household. Besides, we consider the levy limit and reduction in each

system.

3.2.3 Long-term care insurance premium In case of the first insured persons in long-term care insurance (65 years old or older), we

estimate the premiums by applying the weighted average premium amount between prefectures.

In the case of the second insured persons (between 40 and 64 years old), we consider two cases

in terms of participants, such as participants in the national health insurance and participants in

the employee health insurances. In the case of the national health insurance, we estimate the

premiums by applying nationwide average premium rate levied on income and nationwide

average premium amount levied on property, premium amount per capita and per household,

and then summing each household member’s premium up. In the case of the employee health

insurances, since the premium is paid in equal shares by employer and employee, we estimate

by multiplying participants’ incomes by half of nationwide average premium rate. Besides, we

consider the levy limit and reduction in national health insurance, and the upper limit of

standard monthly remuneration and bonus in employee health insurances.

3.2.4 Employment insurance premium We regard the household members as employment insurance participants if “Income from

employments” are more than the amount of “average hourly wage of short-time workers ×

20(hours) × 52(weeks)”. We estimate the premiums by multiplying their incomes by the

employee burden rate of general industries.

3.3. Consumption tax We estimate imputed value of consumption tax as follow. First, we compute the monthly

amount of taxable consumption by subtracting tax-free items from the total consumption. Next,

we multiply it by 12(month) for getting annual amount, and estimate the amount of

consumption tax burden by multiplying the annual taxable consumption by consumption tax

rate. Here, since the reported amount of consumption in the questionnaire is tax-included, we

multiply the annual taxable consumption by 5/105 (because the consumption tax rate was 5% in

2009).

4. Validity of Imputed Values

4.1. Comparison of reported and imputed values We examine the approximation and disparity between reported and imputed values of tax and

social insurance burdens. Here, we use the following disparity rate as index.

Disparity rate = ( Reported value – Imputed value ) / Income

Page 10: Estimation of Tax and Social Insurance Burden on ... · Researcher, Policy Research Institute, Ministry of Finance January 2017 Research Department Policy Research Institute, MOF

9

If the disparity rate is larger than zero, it means that reported value is larger than imputed

value. In contrast, if disparity rate is smaller than zero, it means that imputed value is larger than

reported value.

Table 1 shows descriptive statistics on the disparity rate of tax and social insurance burdens.

Figure 1 is histogram of Table 1, and then horizontal axis indicates disparity rate and vertical

axis indicates frequency5. Here, for estimating imputed values of income and residence taxes,

we use the reported values of social insurance premiums in part of the social insurance

premiums exemption.

As indicated in Table 1, mean disparity rates are negative in cases of all tax and social

insurance premium burdens. Similarly, as indicated in Figure 1, each distribution of disparity

rate stands aside to negative direction. Such a negative disparity rate means that imputed value

tends to be larger than the reported value. One of reasons is that the reported value is

underestimated. Ohno et al. (2015) indicated that the reported values of income tax and social

premium burdens are underestimated by the effect of seasonality in the NSFIE, and it may result

from the possibility that tax and social premium burdens related to regular income and bonuses

out of survey period (from September to November) are not reflected completely in the statistics.

Meanwhile, they also indicate that the reported value of residence tax is not underestimated. It

may result from the fact that residence tax is imposed on the income of the previous year and

collected in monthly installments under this system, thereby is not affected by the seasonality.

The underestimation of reported value can have two effects on the disparity rate. First, the

underestimation of reported value may lead the disparity rate to negative direction directly.

Second, for estimating imputed value of tax including both income and residence taxes, the use

of reported values of social insurance premiums may cause “social insurance premiums

exemption” to underestimate, thereby cause the imputed value of tax to overestimate. This also

may lead the disparity rate to negative direction. These are consistent to the measuring result,

and thus can be factors that help to explain the characteristic of the measuring result.

< Insert Table 1 and Figure 1 >

Next, we examine the possibility that the underestimation of reported values of social

insurance premiums causes the imputed value of tax to overestimate. For this examination, we

use the imputed values of social insurance premiums in “social insurance premiums exemption”.

Table 2 shows descriptive statistics on the disparity rate of income and residence taxes. Figure 2

is histogram of Table 2. As indicated in Table 2, compared to the case of using the reported

values of social insurance premiums (namely, Table 1), the distribution of disparity rate shifts to

positive direction in both income tax case and residence tax case. This indicates that the use of

imputed values of social insurance premiums in “social insurance premiums exemption” can

mitigate the overestimation of imputed value of tax.

The reported value of residence tax is less affected by the seasonality, and has the validity as

an object for comparison. Here, we focus on the result of residence tax in Table 2. The mean

disparity rate is 0.95% to income; the 5th percentile is negative 3.89%; the 95th percentile is

3.94%. Therefore, the mean disparity rate is almost zero and dispersion is approximately 3% to

income. This is nearly equal to the result of Ohno et al. (2015) using the micro data from the

CSLC, which indicated that the mean disparity rate is negative 0.38%; the 5th percentile is

negative 3.74%; the 95th percentile is 2.81%. The sample size of this model is approximately

5 It may be not so difficult to lead also to zero imputed value for household units for which the reported

value of the burden is zero. It is rather important as a simulation model how close the imputed value

can be led to the reported value with respect to household units for which the reported value is positive.

Here, we eliminate the household units that both reported and imputed values are zero, and show the

measuring result.

Page 11: Estimation of Tax and Social Insurance Burden on ... · Researcher, Policy Research Institute, Ministry of Finance January 2017 Research Department Policy Research Institute, MOF

10

43,000 household units, and therefore it is valued that the mean of the sample mean of disparity

rate is zero and dispersion is almost zero (=0.03/√43,000). Imputed value of microsimulation

analysis, etc. have almost no bias in relation to tallied macro values, and it results in an

estimated value with almost no errors. Therefore, its accuracy can be used sufficiently for the

assessment of policies.

< Insert Table 2 and Figure 2 >

4.2. Verification of a hypothesis on underestimation of reported value

We focus on the social insurance premium, and empirically verify the factor that causes the

underestimation of reported value. If the underestimation of reported value results from the

possibility that tax and social premium burdens related to bonuses out of survey period (from

September to November) are not reflected completely in the statistics, the distribution of

disparity rate will be different according to the difference between households with or without

bonuses.

Table 3 shows descriptive statistics on the disparity rate of social insurance premium that are

classified by householders’ income classes, such as less than 5 million yen, 5 to 10 million yen

and more than 10 million yen. Figure 3 is histogram of Table 3. As indicated in Table 3, in

lower income class of less than 5 million yen, the mean disparity rate is 0.51%; the 5th

percentile is negative 9.04%; the 95th percentile is 10.78%. This means that the mean of

distribution is almost zero and the dispersion is bilaterally symmetric. Meanwhile, in the income

class of 5 to 10 million yen, the mean disparity rate is negative 2.70%; the 5th percentile is

negative 9.88%; the 95th percentile is 3.14%. In the income class of more than 10 million yen,

the mean disparity rate is negative 3.97%; the 5th percentile is negative 9.91%; the 95th

percentile is 0.43%. In this way, the distribution of disparity rate in higher income class stands

aside to negative direction. This implies the possibility that the reported value is underestimated.

< Insert Table 3 and Figure 3 >

Next, Table 4 shows descriptive statistics on the disparity rate of social insurance premium

that are classified by householders’ occupational categories, such as regular staff, part-time

worker and albeit, and dispatched worker from temporary labor agency. Figure 4 is histogram of

Table 4. As indicated in Table 4, while the mean disparity rate is negative 2.43% in the regular

staff, the mean disparity rate is 0.43% in the part-time worker and albeit. In this way, the

distribution of disparity rate in regular staff stands aside to negative direction.

< Insert Table 4 and Figure 4 >

In addition, Table 5 shows descriptive statistics on the disparity rate of social insurance

premium that are classified by householders’ income classes in the restricted sample to regular

staff. Figure 5 is histogram of Table 5. As indicated in Table 5, in lower income class of less

than 5 million yen, the mean disparity rate is negative 0.98% and thus the mean of distribution

is almost zero. Meanwhile, the mean disparity rate is negative 2.85% in the income class of 5 to

10 million yen, and negative 4.02% in the income class of more than 10 million yen. In this way,

the distribution of disparity rate in higher income class stands aside to negative direction.

Page 12: Estimation of Tax and Social Insurance Burden on ... · Researcher, Policy Research Institute, Ministry of Finance January 2017 Research Department Policy Research Institute, MOF

11

These results support the effect of social insurance burdens related to bonuses on the

underestimation of reported value6.

< Insert Table 5 and Figure 5 >

5. Actual Status of Tax and Social Insurance Burden on Households

We examine the results of each tax and social insurance premiums (imputed value) by income

brackets7. First, we show the status of household income and consumption. Table 6 shows the

mean income and consumption of households that are classified by income brackets. Here, we

use equivalence income decile for making income class. The equivalence income is calculated

as follows.

Equivalence Income = Household Income8 / √the Number of Household Members

As indicated in Table 6, household income of lowest income bracket, namely 1st decile, is

1.391 million yen, and that of highest income bracket, namely 10th decile is 13.540 million yen.

Meanwhile, household consumption of 1st decile is 1.843 million yen, and that of 10

th decile is

5.032 million yen. In this way, the consumption is larger than income in the 1st decile, which

indicates that households in this decile spend down their wealth. Base on the life-cycle

hypothesis, household smooths their consumption with reflecting the lifetime income. Therefore,

the 1st decile contains not only poor households but also retired households that are not poor,

rather can spend down their wealth. And, when we focus on the number of household members

by income bracket, the number of members increases for higher income bracket. Therefore,

using equivalence income and consumption reduces the gap between income brackets.

< Insert Table 6 >

5.1. Fiscal burdens by income brackets

Table 7 shows the tax and social insurance burdens that are classified by income brackets.

Figure 6 is graph of Table 7. Here, we apply 5% of consumption tax rate as of 2009. Burden

rate is calculated as follows.

Burden Rate = Burden Amount (Imputed Value) / Household Income

6 We also examine the distributions of disparity rate that are classified by the number of earners in the

household, such as none, one person ,two persons, three or more persons. Table A1 shows descriptive

statistics on the disparity rate of social insurance premium that are classified by the number of earners

in household. Figure A1 is histogram of Table A1. As indicated in Table A1, the mean disparity rate is

1.04% in the case of a no earner household. Meanwhile, the mean disparity rates are negative 1.8-2.0%

in the cases of one or more earner households, and thus the distributions of disparity rate stand aside to

a negative direction. Therefore, these results also supports the effect of social insurance burdens related

to bonuses on the underestimation of reported value. 7 Here, we contain not only workers’ households and non-workers’ households but also self-employed

households in the sample. 8 “Household income” means the initial income which is the income before any deduction here.

Page 13: Estimation of Tax and Social Insurance Burden on ... · Researcher, Policy Research Institute, Ministry of Finance January 2017 Research Department Policy Research Institute, MOF

12

As indicated in Figure 6, the burden structures of income tax and residence tax are

progressive. For example, income tax is 0.10%, residence tax is 0.34% and the total burden of

direct income is 0.44% in 1st decile. Meanwhile, income tax is 6.57%, residence tax is 5.16%

and the total burden of direct income is 11.74% in 10th decile.

Public pension insurance premium of 1st decile is 1.26% and that of 10

th decile is 5.16%, and

thus implying that the burden structure of pension insurance premium is also progressive. In

Japan, households participate in different pension systems by occupations. The insurance

premium of employee pension is constant rate to income, which tends to cause proportional

burden structure. The insurance premium of national pension that self-employed workers etc.

participate in is constant amount, which tends to cause regressive burden structure. However,

the reasons for the progressive burden structure contain that there are exemptions for low

income households and that age structure of each income bracket is different. In addition, the

burden rate of 10th decile is lower than that of 9

th decile. This reason contains that the burden

rate of high income household is restricted by the ceiling of pension insurance premium.

Heath insurance premium of 1st decile is 3.63% and that of 10

th decile is 3.53%, and thus

implying that the burden structure of health insurance premium is proportional. Similar to

pension system, in Japan, households participate in different health insurances by occupations.

The insurance premium of health insurance that employees participate in is constant rate to

income, which tends to cause proportional burden structure. The insurance premium of National

Health Insurance that self-employed workers etc. participate in is mix of constant rate to income

and constant amount, which tends to cause regressive burden structure.

Long-term care insurance premium of 1st decile is 1.73% and that of 10

th decile is 0.55%, and

thus implying that the burden structure of long-term care insurance is regressive. And, the

burden structure of employment insurance premium is proportional. This reason contain that

employment insurance premium is imposed on income by constant rate.

Consumption tax of 1st decile is 5.32% and that of 10

th decile is 1.61%, and thus implying that

the burden structure of consumption tax is regressive. The burden rate of 1st decile is

considerably large, which means that low income household bears large tax burden. However,

as Yashio and Hasegawa (2009) indicated, low income bracket contains not only low income

households through lifetime but also elderly households that face to just temporally low income

in a lifecycle. In addition, when we use the burden rate to income for seeing the consumption

tax burden, the burden rate on household that spends down their wealth tends to be calculated to

become larger.

Figure 7 shows the total burden rate including income tax, residence tax, consumption tax

and social insurance premiums. As Figure 7 indicated, the burden structure of tax and social

insurance premiums is progressive.

< Insert Table 7 and Figure 6, 7 >

Finally, we compare these results using the imputed values with the case of using the reported

values. Ohno et al.(2014) estimated the tax and social insurance burdens on households with

using the reported values of the NSFIE. They showed that the burden structures of income tax,

residence tax and pension insurance premium are progressive, that the burden structures of

health insurance premium, long-term care insurance and consumption tax is regressive, and in

addition that the structure of total burden is progressive (Ohno et al. 2014, Figure 1 (2)(3))9.

These results using the reported values are same as the ones of this paper using the imputed

values in terms of the burden structures, except health insurance premium. However, the

volumes of burden rates are quite different. Basically, the burden rates of using the imputed

values are larger than the ones of using the reported values, especially in the higher income

9 They contain only workers’ households and non-workers’ households, but not self-employed households

in the sample.

Page 14: Estimation of Tax and Social Insurance Burden on ... · Researcher, Policy Research Institute, Ministry of Finance January 2017 Research Department Policy Research Institute, MOF

13

bracket. Therefore, the structure of total burden in the case of using the imputed values is more

progressive than in the case of using the reported values.

5.2. Fiscal burdens by income-age brackets The amount of tax and social insurance burdens on households are different across generations

because of the features of the tax and social security systems, and furthermore the tendencies of

income and consumption in a lifecycle. Thus, we examine the fiscal burdens by income-age

brackets, where income bracket is income 10 decile, and age bracket contains 15-29, 30-39, 40-

49, 50-59, 60-69, 70 and over.

As panel (a) of Figure 8 indicated, direct tax including income tax and residence tax is

progressive in each age bracket. But, the direct tax burdens of elderly households are smaller

than those of young households even when both households are contained in same income

bracket. One of reasons is that tax bases of elderly households are eroded by “deduction for

public pension” of income tax etc., and thus their tax burdens are reduced.

Meanwhile, as panel (b) of Figure 8 indicated, social insurance premium is proportional in

each age bracket. But, in low income bracket, the burdens of households are relatively small by

exemption for each insurance premium. In addition, the social insurance burdens of young

households are larger than those of elderly households even when both households are

contained in same income bracket. The reason is that the burdens of young households are

relatively large by pension insurance premium.

Finally, we look at total burdens on households. As panel (c) of Figure 8 indicated, the

burden structure of tax and social insurance premiums is progressive in each age bracket. The

social insurance premiums and consumption tax tend to reduce the progressivity. In particular,

this is shown up strongly in the elderly generation. Therefore, the progressivity of fiscal burdens

is smaller in the elderly generation, which implies that the redistributive effect of intra-

generation is weaker in the elderly.

< Insert Figure 8 >

6. Conclusion We used household micro data from the National Survey of Family Income and Expenditure

(NSFIE) in 2009, and estimated the imputed values of tax and social insurance burdens (such as

income tax, residence tax, consumption tax, pension insurance premium, health insurance

premium, long-term care insurance premium and employment insurance premium) on

households. On that basis, we verified the validity of imputed value by comparing it with

reported value, and assessed the actual status of fiscal burden on household.

The method that evaluates the validity of imputed value by comparing it with reported value

has been adopted in Ohno et al. (2015) and Tada et al. (2016) that use the micro data from the

Comprehensive Survey of Living Conditions (CSLC). This paper also adopts the same method

with using the micro data from the NSFIE. However, the NSFIE is pointed out that the reported

values of income tax and social insurance premiums are underestimated by the effect of

seasonality. Therefore, for verifying the validity of imputed value, we need to focus on the case

of residence tax that is less affected by seasonality. And, it was found that the mean disparity

between the reported and imputed values is zero and the dispersion was approximately 3% over

income. For the implication of the examination, the imputed value has almost no bias in relation

to tallied macro values, and it results in an estimated value with almost no errors. Therefore, its

accuracy can be used sufficiently for the assessment of policies.

The underestimation of reported value affects not only the validity for comparing with

imputed value, but also estimating the imputed value of tax. This means that when estimating

Page 15: Estimation of Tax and Social Insurance Burden on ... · Researcher, Policy Research Institute, Ministry of Finance January 2017 Research Department Policy Research Institute, MOF

14

the imputed value of tax, using reported value of social insurance premium causes

underestimation of the “deduction for public pension” of tax, and thus results in overestimation

of the imputed value of tax. From the awareness of this issue, when using the imputed value of

social insurance premium for the “deduction for public pension”, it was found that the

overestimation of the imputed value of tax can be mitigated.

The underestimation of reported value may result from the possibility that tax and social

premium burdens related to bonuses out of survey period are not reflected completely in the

statistics. From the result of examination, such a hypothesis was supported.

In addition, the total fiscal burden on household including tax and social insurance premiums

is progressive both in all samples and in each age bracket. The social insurance premiums and

consumption tax have effects to reduce the progressivity. In particular, these are shown up

strongly in the elderly generation. Therefore, the progressivity of fiscal burden is smaller in the

elderly generation, which implies that intra-generational redistributive effect is weaker in the

elderly.

Page 16: Estimation of Tax and Social Insurance Burden on ... · Researcher, Policy Research Institute, Ministry of Finance January 2017 Research Department Policy Research Institute, MOF

15

References

Kitamura, K. and Miyazaki T. (2013), Micro Empirical Analysis of Tax Reform: Income Tax

and Consumption Tax in Household Economics, Iwanami Shoten (in Japanese)

Miyazaki, T. and Y. Kitamura (2014), “Redistributive Effects of Income Tax Rates and Tax

Base 1984-2009: Evidence from Japanese Tax Reforms”, Discussion Paper Series, A

No.610, Institute of Economic Research, Hitotsubashi University

Ohno, T., M. Nakazawa, K. Kikuta, and M. Yamamoto (2015), “Comparison of Taxes and

Social Insurance Premium Burdens in Household Accounts”, Public Policy Review, No.

11(4), pp. 547-571

Ohno, T., M. Nakazawa, K. Matsuda, K. Kikuta, and T. Masuda (2014), “Tax and Social

Insurance Burden on Households: Estimating Using National Survey of Family Income

and Expediture”, Public Policy Review, No. 10(3), pp. 457-479

Ohtake, F. and M. Kohara (2005), “Is the Consumption Tax Really Regressive?: Consideration

of the Equality of Burden”, Ronza, No.127, pp.44-51 (in Japanese)

Sano, S., S. Tada, and M. Yamamoto (2015), “Method of Household Surveys and

Characteristics of Surveyed Households: Comparison regarding Household Composition,

Annual Income and Educational Attainment”, Public Policy Review, No. 11(4), pp. 505-

529

Shiraishi, K. (2011), “Consumption Tax Payment Level and Regressivity”, Report Paper of the

68th National Meeting of Japan Institute of Public Finance (in Japanese)

Tada, S. and K. Miyoshi (2015), “Verifying household incomes in Japanese statistics”, Public

Policy Review, No. 11(4), pp. 531-545

Tada, S., Ohno, T. and T. Unayama (2016), “Estimation of Social Insurance Premiums using

micro data and Verification of the Validity”, PRI Discussion Paper Series, 16A-02 (in

Japanese)

Takayama N. and K. Shiraishi (2010), “Burden Level of Consumption Tax in Family Units in

Japan”, Discussion Paper, CIS-PIE DP No.491, Institute of Economic Research,

Hitotsubashi University (in Japanese)

Takayama N. and Shiraishi K. (2011), “The VAT Credit for Mitigating Regressive Tax Burdens

in Japan”, Discussion Paper, CIS-PIE DP No.503, Institute of Economic Research,

Hitotsubashi University (in Japanese)

Tanaka S. (2014), “Analysis of Effects of Consumption Tax Measures for Low-Income

Earners”, Report Paper of the 71th National Meeting of Japan Institute of Public Finance

(in Japanese)

Tanaka S. and M. Shikata (2012), “Microsimulation of Tax and Social Insurance Premium”,

RISS Discussion Paper Series No. 25, Research Institute for Socionetwork Strategies,

Kansai University (in Japanese)

Tanaka S., M. Shikata and K. Komamura (2013), “Analysis of Tax and Social Security Burdens

on Senior Citizens: Using Individual Questionnaire Data of the National Survey of Family

Income and Expenditure”, Financial Review No. 115, pp.117-133 (in Japanese)

Yashio, H. and Y. Hasegawa (2009), “Actual Situation of Consumption Tax Burdens in

Household Accounts in Japan”, Economic Analysis No. 182, pp.25-47 (in Japanese)

Page 17: Estimation of Tax and Social Insurance Burden on ... · Researcher, Policy Research Institute, Ministry of Finance January 2017 Research Department Policy Research Institute, MOF

16

Table 1: Descriptive Statistics on Disparity Rate

(using the reported values of social insurance premiums)

Income Tax Residence Tax Earned Income

Tax

Mean -1.87% -0.66% -1.83%

5 percentile -6.11% -3.55% -6.12%

95 percentile 0.67% 3.12% 0.74%

Pension InsurancePremium

Health InsurancePremium

Long-term CareInsurance Premium

Employment InsurancePremium

Social InsurancePremium

Mean -0.74% -0.03% -0.66% -0.06% -1.08%

5 percentile -7.31% -4.17% -2.59% -0.40% -9.50%

95 percentile 4.24% 5.73% 0.63% 0.22% 7.15%

Figure 1: Histogram on Disparity Rate

(using the reported values of social insurance premiums)

(a) Income tax (b) Residence tax

(c) Earned income tax (d) Social insurance premium

Page 18: Estimation of Tax and Social Insurance Burden on ... · Researcher, Policy Research Institute, Ministry of Finance January 2017 Research Department Policy Research Institute, MOF

17

Table 2: Descriptive Statistics on Disparity Rate

(using the imputed values of social insurance premiums)

Income Tax Residence Tax Earned Income

Tax

Mean -0.83% 0.95% -0.65%

5 percentile -3.43% -3.89% -3.72%

95 percentile 1.11% 3.94% 1.46%

Figure 2: Histogram on Disparity Rate

(using the imputed values of social insurance premiums)

(a) Income tax (b) Residence tax

(c) Earned income tax

Page 19: Estimation of Tax and Social Insurance Burden on ... · Researcher, Policy Research Institute, Ministry of Finance January 2017 Research Department Policy Research Institute, MOF

18

Table 3: Descriptive Statistics on Disparity Rate of Social Insurance Premium

(by income brackets)

less than5 million yen

5 - 10 miliion yenmore than

10 million yen

Mean 0.51% -2.70% -3.97%

5 percentile -9.04% -9.88% -9.91%

95 percentile 10.78% 3.14% 0.43%

Figure 3: Histogram on Disparity Rate of Social Insurance Premium

(by income brackets)

(a) Less than 5 million yen (b) 5 – 10 million yen

(c) More than 10 million yen

Page 20: Estimation of Tax and Social Insurance Burden on ... · Researcher, Policy Research Institute, Ministry of Finance January 2017 Research Department Policy Research Institute, MOF

19

Table 4: Descriptive Statistics on Disparity Rate of Social Insurance Premium

(by occupational categories)

Regular StaffPart-time Worker

and AlbeitDispatched Worker

Mean -2.43% 0.43% -1.35%

5 percentile -11.06% -9.88% -11.82%

95 percentile 3.99% 13.22% 7.11%

Figure 4: Histogram on Disparity Rate of Social Insurance Premium

(by occupational categories)

(a) Regular staff (b) Part-time worker and albeit

(c) Dispatched worker

Page 21: Estimation of Tax and Social Insurance Burden on ... · Researcher, Policy Research Institute, Ministry of Finance January 2017 Research Department Policy Research Institute, MOF

20

Table 5: Descriptive Statistics on Disparity Rate of Social Insurance Premium

(only regular staff, by income brackets)

less than5 million yen

5 - 10 miliion yenmore than

10 million yen

Mean -0.98% -2.85% -4.02%

5 percentile -12.03% -10.64% -9.84%

95 percentile 7.98% 2.59% 0.03%

Figure 5: Histogram on Disparity Rate of Social Insurance Premium

(only regular staff, by income brackets)

(a) Less than 5 million yen (b) 5 – 10 million yen

(c) More than 10 million yen

Page 22: Estimation of Tax and Social Insurance Burden on ... · Researcher, Policy Research Institute, Ministry of Finance January 2017 Research Department Policy Research Institute, MOF

21

Table 6: Households’ Income and Consumption

Income BracketHousehold

IncomeHousehold

ConsumptionNumber

of MemberEquivalence

IncomeEquivalenceConsumption

(million yen) (million yen) (person) (million yen) (million yen)

Ⅰ 1.391 1.843 2.1 0.993 1.326

Ⅱ 2.599 2.325 2.5 1.695 1.541

Ⅲ 3.336 2.619 2.6 2.125 1.693

Ⅳ 3.860 2.836 2.6 2.485 1.863

Ⅴ 4.540 3.091 2.7 2.854 1.975

Ⅵ 5.372 3.394 2.9 3.273 2.107

Ⅶ 6.184 3.666 2.8 3.787 2.276

Ⅷ 7.287 3.943 2.8 4.459 2.463

Ⅸ 8.908 4.350 2.8 5.504 2.715

Ⅹ 13.540 5.032 2.5 8.870 3.315

Total 5.700 3.309 2.6 3.604 2.127

Table 7: Tax and Social Insurance Burden Rates

IncomeTax

ResidenceTax

PensionIns.

HealthIns.

Long-termCare Ins.

EmploymentIns.

Ⅰ 0.10% 0.34% 0.44% 1.26% 3.63% 1.73% 0.10% 6.73% 7.17% 5.32% 12.49%

Ⅱ 0.35% 1.10% 1.45% 2.89% 3.94% 1.42% 0.16% 8.41% 9.86% 3.63% 13.49%

Ⅲ 0.65% 1.77% 2.42% 3.40% 4.13% 1.46% 0.18% 9.17% 11.58% 3.24% 14.82%

Ⅳ 0.93% 2.32% 3.25% 3.59% 4.23% 1.38% 0.18% 9.37% 12.62% 3.05% 15.68%

Ⅴ 1.23% 2.86% 4.09% 4.32% 4.23% 1.11% 0.21% 9.87% 13.96% 2.82% 16.78%

Ⅵ 1.49% 3.23% 4.72% 4.79% 4.06% 0.95% 0.22% 10.03% 14.75% 2.63% 17.38%

Ⅶ 1.89% 3.67% 5.56% 5.16% 4.01% 0.83% 0.23% 10.23% 15.80% 2.49% 18.28%

Ⅷ 2.43% 4.06% 6.49% 5.58% 3.93% 0.73% 0.24% 10.48% 16.97% 2.26% 19.23%

Ⅸ 3.47% 4.56% 8.03% 5.97% 3.90% 0.64% 0.24% 10.75% 18.78% 2.06% 20.84%

Ⅹ 6.57% 5.16% 11.74% 5.16% 3.53% 0.55% 0.22% 9.45% 21.19% 1.61% 22.79%

Total 2.98% 3.71% 6.68% 4.83% 3.90% 0.88% 0.22% 9.82% 16.50% 2.43% 18.93%

ConsumptionTax

IncomeBracket

Direct Tax+ Social Ins.+ Cons. TaxSocial

Ins.

Direct Tax+ Social Ins.Direct

Tax

Page 23: Estimation of Tax and Social Insurance Burden on ... · Researcher, Policy Research Institute, Ministry of Finance January 2017 Research Department Policy Research Institute, MOF

22

Figure 6: Tax and Social Insurance Burden Rates (Each Burden)

0%

1%

2%

3%

4%

5%

6%

7%

Ⅰ Ⅱ Ⅲ Ⅳ Ⅴ Ⅵ Ⅶ Ⅷ Ⅸ Ⅹ

Income Tax

Residence Tax

Pension Ins.Premium

Health Ins.Premium

Long-term CareIns. Premium

Employment Ins.Premium

Consumption Tax

Figure 7: Tax and Social Insurance Burden Rates (Total Burden)

0%

5%

10%

15%

20%

25%

Ⅰ Ⅱ Ⅲ Ⅳ Ⅴ Ⅵ Ⅶ Ⅷ Ⅸ Ⅹ

Consumption Tax

Employment Ins.Premium

Long-term CareIns. Premium

Health Ins.Premium

Pension Ins.Premium

Residence Tax

Income Tax

Page 24: Estimation of Tax and Social Insurance Burden on ... · Researcher, Policy Research Institute, Ministry of Finance January 2017 Research Department Policy Research Institute, MOF

23

Figure 8: Tax and Social Insurance Burden Rates (By Income-Age Brackets)

(a) Direct tax (including income tax and residence tax)

0%

2%

4%

6%

8%

10%

12%

14%

Ⅰ Ⅱ Ⅲ Ⅳ Ⅴ Ⅵ Ⅶ Ⅷ Ⅸ Ⅹ

15-29

30-39

40-49

50-59

60-69

70 and older

(b) Social insurance premium

0%

2%

4%

6%

8%

10%

12%

14%

Ⅰ Ⅱ Ⅲ Ⅳ Ⅴ Ⅵ Ⅶ Ⅷ Ⅸ Ⅹ

15-29

30-39

40-49

50-59

60-69

70 and older

Page 25: Estimation of Tax and Social Insurance Burden on ... · Researcher, Policy Research Institute, Ministry of Finance January 2017 Research Department Policy Research Institute, MOF

24

Figure 8: (continued)

(c) Total burden (including direct tax, social insurance premium and cosumption tax)

0%

5%

10%

15%

20%

25%

30%

Ⅰ Ⅱ Ⅲ Ⅳ Ⅴ Ⅵ Ⅶ Ⅷ Ⅸ Ⅹ

15-29

30-39

40-49

50-59

60-69

70 and older

Page 26: Estimation of Tax and Social Insurance Burden on ... · Researcher, Policy Research Institute, Ministry of Finance January 2017 Research Department Policy Research Institute, MOF

25

Table A1: Descriptive Statistics on Disparity Rate of Social Insurance Premium

(by the number of earner)

None 1 person 2 persons 3 or more persons

Mean 1.04% -1.88% -1.95% -1.96%

5 percentile -7.31% -11.78% -9.69% -9.65%

95 percentile 10.13% 6.40% 5.39% 5.91%

the Number of Earner

Figure A1: Histogram on Disparity Rate of Social Insurance Premium

(by the number of earner)

(a) None (b) 1 person

(c) 2 persons (d) 3 or more persons