environmental sustainability as a goal tellus institute boston, … · 2017-09-19 · environmental...

35
Environmental Sustainability as a Goal in Resource Planning and Policy Stephen Bernow and Bruce Biewald Tellus Institute Boston, Massachusetts Abstract Resource planning and policy must consider impacts on the quality of our environment. Economic theory offers both a basis for environmental policy -- the allocation of resources based upon individuals' willingness to pay -- and instruments for achieving policy goals, for example emissions taxes and pollution trading systems. This paper points out some of the shortcomings of an economic-based approach, particularly when used as the basis for environmental policy. Economic approaches to valuing environmental damages treat the environment as a commodity and people as consumers with preferences regarding the disposal of their incomes. Policies based on these approaches will fail to recognize: 1) the fundamental importance of ecological systems supporting current and future life on the planet, and 2) the vital role of individuals acting as citizens shaping the values and goals of their society. Environmental sustainability, and the related issues of intergenerational and social equity, are important policy objectives that should not be subsumed within notions of economic efficiency. As instruments for implementing environmental policy, economic mechanisms such as prices and markets offer some promise for helping to achieve environmental goals. Even here, however, other approaches such as "command and control" regulation, prohibition of specific pollutants, explicit protection of certain environments via restrictions of certain habitats or ecosystems, programmatic initiatives, and the development of new institutions, have important roles to play. We call for a shift from a purely economic paradigm to one in which sustainability is emphasized. Over the longer term, new approaches that go beyond the marginalism of conventional economics, to reflect the complex interactions between economic and ecological processes, and to distinguish between the domains of individual preferences and societal values, will need to be developed, However, in the current environment and for the foreseeable future, methodological pluralism is appropriate; economists, scientists, and social theorists will each have much to offer. Bernow and Biewald 1

Upload: others

Post on 21-Apr-2020

1 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Environmental Sustainability as a Goal Tellus Institute Boston, … · 2017-09-19 · Environmental Sustainability as a Goal in Resource Planning and Policy Stephen Bernow and Bruce

Environmental Sustainability as a Goalin Resource Planning and Policy

Stephen Bernow and Bruce BiewaldTellus InstituteBoston, Massachusetts

Abstract

Resource planning and policy must consider impacts on the quality of ourenvironment. Economic theory offers both a basis for environmental policy-- the allocation of resources based upon individuals' willingness to pay --and instruments for achieving policy goals, for example emissions taxes andpollution trading systems. This paper points out some of the shortcomingsof an economic-based approach, particularly when used as the basis forenvironmental policy.

Economic approaches to valuing environmental damages treat theenvironment as a commodity and people as consumers with preferencesregarding the disposal of their incomes. Policies based on theseapproaches will fail to recognize: 1) the fundamental importance ofecological systems supporting current and future life on the planet, and 2)the vital role of individuals acting as citizens shaping the values and goalsof their society. Environmental sustainability, and the related issues ofintergenerational and social equity, are important policy objectives thatshould not be subsumed within notions of economic efficiency.

As instruments for implementing environmental policy, economicmechanisms such as prices and markets offer some promise for helping toachieve environmental goals. Even here, however, other approaches suchas "command and control" regulation, prohibition of specific pollutants,explicit protection of certain environments via restrictions of certainhabitats or ecosystems, programmatic initiatives, and the development ofnew institutions, have important roles to play.

We call for a shift from a purely economic paradigm to one in whichsustainability is emphasized. Over the longer term, new approaches that gobeyond the marginalism of conventional economics, to reflect the complexinteractions between economic and ecological processes, and to distinguishbetween the domains of individual preferences and societal values, willneed to be developed, However, in the current environment and for theforeseeable future, methodological pluralism is appropriate; economists,scientists, and social theorists will each have much to offer.

Bernow and Biewald 1

Page 2: Environmental Sustainability as a Goal Tellus Institute Boston, … · 2017-09-19 · Environmental Sustainability as a Goal in Resource Planning and Policy Stephen Bernow and Bruce

Introduction

In the evolution of resource planning methods and their application, we seea belated but quite welcome trend toward recognizing environmentalimpacts that are outside direct market costs. This may be thought of as the"internalization of environmental externalities"; that is, bringing theseexternal societal costs into the economic decisionmaking process. While weapplaud (and actively participate in) attempts to recognize environmentalexternalities in resource planning, we note that this approach has practicaland theoretical shortcomings.

As a practical matter, the internalization of environmental externalities isoften problematic owing to information gaps, uncertainties, ecologicalcomplexities, disagreements over the value of nonmarket "goods," politicalconsiderations, and jurisdictional boundaries. On a theoretical level, itmust be recognized that purely economic approaches to environmentalproblems may not adequately protect the environment, even ifimplemented perfectly, because some "costs" can never be accuratelymonetized. This failure becomes particularly acute when dealing withpotentially irreversible changes to ecological systems beyond thresholds thatmay be uncertain. Over long time periods, basing decisions on economicefficiency alone is inadequate to ensure ecological sustainability, even if theconcept of efficiency is expanded to include environmental externalities.

A sustainability target or safe minimum standard approach is required ifenvironmental, ecological and intergenerational equity goals are to berealized. Economic methods have a role within such an approach, toensure that society's goals are realized efficiently. Economic methods alonecannot, however, determine those goals. The central theme of this paper isthis shift from the economic paradigm to the sustainability paradigm as thepolicy basis for taking account of environmental impacts, particularly thosethat can have severe, long-term, and irreversible consequences.

Environmental impacts are ascribed monetary values within the economicparadigm and are incorporated into economic analyses and policies on thatbasis; environmental conditions are set as societal goals within thesustainability paradigm, and the pursuit of economic efficiency isincorporated into an environmental analyses.

Notwithstanding the limitations of the externalities monetization approach,we do not believe that planners and decisionmakers should reject attemptsto monetize damage costs and incorporate externalities into economicmodels and policy frameworks. However, there needs to be a shift towardusing sustainability targets or safe minimum standards wherever possible as

Bernow and Biewald 2

Page 3: Environmental Sustainability as a Goal Tellus Institute Boston, … · 2017-09-19 · Environmental Sustainability as a Goal in Resource Planning and Policy Stephen Bernow and Bruce

the policy basis. To be sure, a variety of market-oriented approaches --including targets with tradable permits, taxes, and other monetarytechniques -- as well as selected requirements and restrictions -- could beused as policy instruments. But the instrument itself should also be selectedto best embody sustainability policy and goals, while contributing toeconomic efficiency in meeting those goals.

In this paper, we briefly review the basis for externalities in conventionaleconomic theory, identify the techniques used to establish appropriatemonetary values or equivalent methods to internalize externalities, discussthe limitations of these approaches within the economic paradigm, explorean alternative paradigm based on intergenerational equity andsustainability, and examine the distinction between the policy bases andpolicy instruments.

The Economic Paradigm

Environmental Impacts and Externalities

The development and use of energy resources have a variety of impacts onsociety, some of which are included in the actual price for energy. Otherimpacts, however, are not fully embodied in the prices of energy products,and by extension, are not included in the price of goods or services that useenergy (virtually everything in a modern society). Most notable amongthese are damages to the environment and human health that result fromconstruction of energy facilities, extraction, processing, transport, andcombustion of fuels, and disposal of wastes. For example, fossil fuel plantsemit CO2, S02' particulates, toxics, and NOx, hydroelectric facilities canharm watershed ecosystems; and nuclear power plants produce highlyradioactive wastes.

Pollution from energy production and consumption can have significant,often severe, and sometimes irreversible, impacts on air, water, soils, biota,habitats and human health. Such impacts occur on local, regional, andglobal scales, and are often quite complex and difficult to predict. Therelease of pollutants and the use of local resources by energy relatedactivities can directly affect human health and amenity and the integrity ofnatural systems in the immediate vicinity of the facilities, thereby raisingimportant siting issues.

Some of these impacts are reflected (or "internalized") in direct costs to theextent that regulations and engineering practice respond, howeverbelatedly, to scientific research and public concern and policy. However,the impact from residual, uncontrolled pollution remains as the deleterious

Bernow and Biewald 3

Page 4: Environmental Sustainability as a Goal Tellus Institute Boston, … · 2017-09-19 · Environmental Sustainability as a Goal in Resource Planning and Policy Stephen Bernow and Bruce

side effect of satisfying society's identified energy needs. Taking accountof these impacts in energy policy, planning, and operation could alter theamount and mix of resources used to meet our energy demands, withpositive effects for the environment and public health, and for long-termecological and economic sustainability.

Expressed in economic terms and assigned monetary values, those impactsthat are not already reflected in costs and prices at the appropriate levelare called externalities. Economic theory tells us that if only direct monetarycosts are taken into account in decisionmaking, then the existence ofexternalities among competing resources may result in resource allocationthat is "inefficient" from a societal perspective. If we don't count theexternalities, then we will "produce" too many of them. The result is thatthe "wrong" types of resources will be pursued, as evaluated from astandpoint that considers environmental preservation, human health, andlongterm sustainability, along with traditional monetary costs and benefits.

In order to improve resource decisions generally, and energy decisions inparticular, economists and environmentalists have argued that theseexternal costs should be "internalized" in decisions affecting resourceplanning, development, and use. In this way, more appropriate pricesignals would be established, thereby leading to the satisfaction of resourceneeds at the lowest overall cost to society.

Internalizing Environmental Externalities: A Microeconomic Perspective

In explaining how prices are determined, Alfred Marshall constructed the"supply-demand cross" graph, as illustrated here in figure 1 (see Marshall'sPrinciples of Economics, 1890). This simple picture embodies severalfundamental micro economic concepts. The "supply curve" represents themarginal cost of production as a function of output; the "demand curve"represents the relationship between the price of the product and theamount of it that consumers will purchase. Given an idealized market(perfect competition, perfect information, no transaction costs, etc.) andprofit maximizing behavior, the "optimal" amount of production, q*, will beproduced and sold at a market price ofp*.

Bernow and Biewald 4

Page 5: Environmental Sustainability as a Goal Tellus Institute Boston, … · 2017-09-19 · Environmental Sustainability as a Goal in Resource Planning and Policy Stephen Bernow and Bruce

Figure 1Marshallian Supply-Demand Cross

p*

Marginal Cost ofProduction("Supply")

q* Output

Price

Market

1 2.i

Page 6: Environmental Sustainability as a Goal Tellus Institute Boston, … · 2017-09-19 · Environmental Sustainability as a Goal in Resource Planning and Policy Stephen Bernow and Bruce

In recent thinking about pollution reduction policies, the Marshalliansupply-demand cross has been employed in a modified form, with pollutionreduction plotted on the horizontal axis as a commodity for which there aresupply and demand curves. The supply curve for pollution reduction is themarginal cost of abatement or control options arranged in order ofincreasing cost. The demand curve for pollution reduction is the "marginaldamage cost" resulting from varying levels of pollution. These areillustrated in figure 2.

Bernow and Biewald 6

Page 7: Environmental Sustainability as a Goal Tellus Institute Boston, … · 2017-09-19 · Environmental Sustainability as a Goal in Resource Planning and Policy Stephen Bernow and Bruce

Figure 2Economic "Textbook" Approach

to Pollution Reduction

Prlc

Marginal Cost ofPollution Abatement

q* Pollution Reduction

"A~

Page 8: Environmental Sustainability as a Goal Tellus Institute Boston, … · 2017-09-19 · Environmental Sustainability as a Goal in Resource Planning and Policy Stephen Bernow and Bruce

Within this idealized framework, the "optimal" amount of pollutionreduction, q*, is determined as the point on the horizontal axis where thesupply and demand curves cross. The standard textbook policy instrumentin this situation is to implement a Pigouvian tax set at p*. The marketwould then produce q* of pollution, and the externality could be declaredinternalized.

Other policy instruments are also available for the internalization of theexternality, including "command and control" regulation embodied intechnology and facility-specific requirements. Setting an aggregate cap onemissions (at q*) with a permit trading system would have many of theeconomic efficiency advantages that would be attained with a tax (at p*).Here, the point is not the mechanism used to address the pollution, butrather, that within this economic approach, the policy is based on a notionof marginal costs and marginal benefits, and is aimed to hit the target pointat the intersection of these curves.

There are many simplifications and assumptions embodied in thisframework. For example, the graph considers just one pollutant whereaspollutants are usually both emitted and controlled in combination withothers in production processes. Another factor is the scope of theregulation; when the regulation applies only to one jurisdiction then theregulation itself can have "external effects" upon other sectors of theeconomy and other geographic regions. Also, the construction of a single,monotonically increasing curve to represent the marginal cost of abatementis an oversimplification, given uncertainties about the availability, costs andeffectiveness of pollution control options, and the pace and character oftechnological innovation. Technological change is a dynamic phenomenonthat goes beyond the static representations of such pollution reductionsupply curves. Markets for pollution reduction are generally "imperfect"owing to lack of information, high transaction costs, and lack ofcompetitive forces. Indeed, for many pollutants, markets are nonexistent.

Markets, however imperfect, can be created through political andregulatory processes. The construction of the marginal damage cost curveis a different sort of problem. It may be impossible as a practical matter inmany cases to develop this curve adequately, given the inherentcomplexities in the ecological processes and the controversies surroundingmonetary valuation. The shape of idealized marginal damage curve maybe reasonable for certain damages for small and continuous changes, butseverely simplified in many other instances. Indeed, it may beinappropriate as a theoretical and political matter for some environmentalimpacts. Some have argued that, owing to these uncertainties, recognitionof external environmental impacts in planning protocols must await thearrival of accurate and reliable marginal damage functions. But this is the

Bernow and Biewald 8

Page 9: Environmental Sustainability as a Goal Tellus Institute Boston, … · 2017-09-19 · Environmental Sustainability as a Goal in Resource Planning and Policy Stephen Bernow and Bruce

functional equivalent of saying that these environmental impacts should beignored by planners for the next few decades. Such an approach impliesthat simply because we have not yet precisely quantified the damage, weshould assume that it does not exist.

Valuation of Environmental Resources

If the theory described above is to be put into practice, then marginaldamage curves (or at least some points on the marginal damage curves)must be estimated. Various techniques are used to determine the marginaldamage cost curve.

Some of these damages are themselves market goods, for example, cattle,fish, or commercial crops affected by industrial or urban pollution. Themarket value of these damages can be estimated directly by assessing lostrevenues or remediation costs, although the estimation of the physicalimpacts, and the potential responses of economic activity and technologicaldevelopments to those impacts, can be quite complex.

Typically, many of the damage costs are associated with nonmarketresources, such as natural ecosystems, human health, and amenity. Forthese, indirect valuation techniques are available. These techniques involveeither: 1) the examination of behavioral responses that are or might beinfluenced by an externality (e.g., hedonic pricing); 2) the assumption orcreation of a fictitious market in order to elicit the value that individualsmight assign to an externality (contingent valuation); or 3) an analysis ofthe implicit value placed on pollution abatement by society through theactions of its regulatory agencies (e.g., regulators' revealed preferences).

Contingent valuation is a survey technique for estimating a value forenvironmental "goods" (i.e, different levels of environmental condition thatmight be affected by resource use) as if they were commodities in themarketplace. Quite simply, it asks people what they are willing to pay tosecure a benefit (avoided environmental damage), and/or what they arewilling to receive by way of compensation to tolerate a cost (incurredenvironmental damage) (OEeD 1989). Through the use of interviews andsurveys, contingent valuation tries to ascertain personal valuation forincreases or decreases in the quantity of a particular good, contingent upona hypothetical market. This approach can include not only identifiedphysical damages caused by pollutant emissions for example, but a valuefor the risk imposed on society for the unknown potential environmentalimpacts of those resources.

Hedonic pricing is an alternative approach that examines market behaviorsfor the environmental resource in question. Economic or policy decisions

Bernow and Biewald 9

Page 10: Environmental Sustainability as a Goal Tellus Institute Boston, … · 2017-09-19 · Environmental Sustainability as a Goal in Resource Planning and Policy Stephen Bernow and Bruce

.----

that involve an environmental good and result in market decisions can beused to infer a value for that good.

Hedonic pricing rests on the assumption that nonmarket characteristicshave values that are reflected in a good's market price. For example,property values may reflect the environmental condition of the land and itslocation. Given two properties with similar characteristics except forenvironmental surroundings, one might infer that the difference in themarket value of the properties is attributable to the willingness to pay forthe difference in environmental surroundings. Using this technique,economists have estimated environmental and social externalities usingproperty values, wages, and travel costs.

The regu1ators' reveaIedpreferences approach is an empirical means ofestablishing willingness to pay, without directly engaging in the complextask of identifying and estimating all of the various physical environmentaldamages and "polling" all of the affected parties. The approach identifiesspecific instances in which control measures have been required, in orderto determine the cost that society, as represented by its regulators, iswilling to pay to reduce emissions, thereby avoiding environmentaldamages. By requiring specific end-of-pipe equipment or otherrequirements on emissions, regulators imply a willingness to pay up to theassociated cost per unit of pollution (or damage) avoided, even thoughthere may exist opportunities for pollution reduction at lower costs. Whilecontingent valuation polls individuals regarding their willingness to pay inhypothetical decisions, regulators revealed preference examines the actualdecisions to taken by those responsible for environmental protection.Utility regulators in several States have required that externalities valuesdeveloped by this method be applied in energy planning.

Each of these techniques has practical and/or inherent limitations thatcould limit, albeit not necessarily entirely obviate, its usefulness.Contingent valuation is subject to many sources of bias, since the "accuracy"of the responses depends greatly on the technique used to elicit them(OECD, 1989). For example, there is a strategic bias: Sinceenvironmental quality is a public good (i.e., once it is provided, peoplecannot be excluded from consumption), people have an incentive tounderstate their preference (if they had to pay), counting on the fact thatother people will provide for the supply of the good. This is the free-riderproblem. Then there are several sources of bias stemming from the factthat individuals sometimes appear to respond to the starting value that isquoted to them (source for the "starting point bias").

Also, the question is whether the hypothetical markets correspond wellenough to real markets. The survey, questioner, and respondent must all

Bernow and Biewald 10

Page 11: Environmental Sustainability as a Goal Tellus Institute Boston, … · 2017-09-19 · Environmental Sustainability as a Goal in Resource Planning and Policy Stephen Bernow and Bruce

be as close as possible to a real market situation to avoid operational bias.This means the respondent must be knowledgeable about the good inquestion and aware of the hypothetical means of payment. Experts oncontingent valuation have cautioned against the belief that contingentvaluation is a sufficiently proven methodology upon which policy decisionscan be made (Mitchell and Carson, 1987). The possibility for distortedresults from inexperienced researchers is of major concern; such resultscould mislead policymakers and discredit contingent valuation before themethodology has matured.

Hedonic pricing requires considerable data and accurate use of statisticaltechniques, but even then it may be difficult to extract a value for a specificexternality, given the myriad variables involved in market decisions. Animportant limitation here is the likelihood, in many instances, that therequisite information on environmental risk is not available or apparent tothose engaged in the transactions.

The regulators' revealed preference approach has also been criticized.Those who believe that there is an independent and better way ofreckoning the value of the damages avoided by the regulation, have arguedthat what is revealed in regulatory decisions can be an inaccuraterepresentation of the "true" damage value. It could be either too high ortoo low, depending upon whether regulators are thought to have under- orovercontrolled relative to the optimal level. Thus, they argue, based on aconviction that an acceptable and superior method of valuation existsindependent of the regulators, that using a regulators' revealed preferencesvalue as the basis for further regulation is circular and inappropriate.

In addition to these difficulties, there are other challenges that may renderthe idealized marginal damage cost curve unattainable in practice, if not inprinciple. Estimating the direct physical impacts or damages ofenvironmental loadings (air emissions, water emissions, etc.) can be a largeand exceedingly complex task, fraught with uncertainty. These impactsdepend on the emissions loadings into various media (air, water, soils); thetransport of pollutants through those media, based on the physicalcharacteristics of the emissions (e.g., velocity) and climatological (windspeed/direction) and topographical conditions; the exposure of receptorarea or populations; and the dose-response relationship of thosepopulations.

Beyond the immediate environmental impacts of energy production anduse, there can be a series of subsequent nonphysical (e.g., socioeconomic)as well as physical impacts that ensue in both the near and the long term.The local, regional, and global consequences of air emissions, for example,depend upon atmospheric; biological, chemical, geophysical, ecological, and

Bemow and Biewald 11

L

Page 12: Environmental Sustainability as a Goal Tellus Institute Boston, … · 2017-09-19 · Environmental Sustainability as a Goal in Resource Planning and Policy Stephen Bernow and Bruce

physiological relationships across time, space, and socioeconomic andcultural conditions. These various pathways involve feedbacks andinteractions with one another, over differing time scales, with bothreversible and irreversible consequences. In modeling such relationships,elements of scientific uncertainty, availability of accurate data, theecological response to perturbation, including nonlinearities, threshholds,cumulative impacts, and feedback effects, among other factors, must betaken into account.'

A National Research Council report addressed the major sources ofuncertainty in our understanding of ecosystem response to stress andidentified each as either rectifiable or inherent. For rectifiable sources ofuncertainty, "it is possible to plan research that could considerably reducethe uncertainty." For inherent sources, "it is difficult even to conceive of aresearch program that could significantly reduce the associateduncertainties" (NRC, 1980). The inherent sources are reproduced here astable 1.2 A useful recent discussion of types of uncertainty in physicalmodeling of complex and poorly understood systems can be found inShllyakhter and Kamman (1992).

For example: "There are strong links between the issues of greenhouse gas induced climatic change, stratospheric ozonedepletion, ground level oxidant generation, forest and watershed degradation by acid rain and regionalair pollution, and eutrophication of coastal and inland waters". The Full Range of Responses toAnticipated Climate Change. (United Nations Environment Programme and Beijer Institute, 1989,p. xii.)

2

The list of "rectifiable sources of uncertainty" for which "research is imaginable that could reduce the uncertainty to aconsiderable extent" is much longer and is not reproduced here.

Bernow and Biewald 12

Page 13: Environmental Sustainability as a Goal Tellus Institute Boston, … · 2017-09-19 · Environmental Sustainability as a Goal in Resource Planning and Policy Stephen Bernow and Bruce

Table 1

Inherent Sources of Uncertaintyin Predicting the Response of Ecosystems to Stress

1. Lack of data on, and understanding of, effects of long-term, low-level effluents on ecosystems.

2. Difficulty in performing controlled, replicableexperiments that provide in situ information aboutecosystems.

3. Lack of models allowing the use of measurable data topredict detailed ecological responses to stress.

From Table 1-1 (NRC 1980, page 5)

Bemow and Biewald Table 1

Page 14: Environmental Sustainability as a Goal Tellus Institute Boston, … · 2017-09-19 · Environmental Sustainability as a Goal in Resource Planning and Policy Stephen Bernow and Bruce

Of course, "difficult" to conceive is not impossible to conceive, and theprogress of both theoretical and empirical research is surely helping toadvance both conception and execution of research relevant to allapproaches to the valuation of environmental resources or the setting ofenvironmental goals. Indeed, the prospect of an "ecological economics," oran economic (and institutional) basis for sustainable development, is aworthy goal, however daunting the effort may appear at this time.'Nonetheless, these complexities--particularly the threshold and cumulativeeffects and uncertainties-Iend weight to the use of target and critical loadbased approaches supported here.

The idealized economic theory of intersecting marginal cost curves,discussed earlier, generally rests on a severe lack of relevant informationwhen applied to environmental policy decisions. Neither the emissionsreduction supply curve nor the damage cost curve has been generallyaccurately established by regulators. While, in practice, it is possible toconstruct the "control cost" curve with sufficient study, the "damage cost"curve will more likely be a cloud of points at best, reflecting the inherentcomplexities, uncertainties, and variety of valuation perspectives that areentailed in such estimates.'

When reckoned against the full complexity of economic/ecologicalinteractions and social life, within which markets may operate, chasing thechimera of "actual damage values" derived from a schedule of consumerpreferences is a poignant instance of the fallacy of misplaced concreteness.Indeed, for certain environmental resources, and for the deeper and more complex interactions between ecological and economicprocesses, such valuation may be inappropriate. The validity of theeconomic paradigm embodied in the abstraction of markets and allocativeefficiency is circumscribed by ethical and political considerations regardingthe roles of individuals in society, and by the depth and complexity ofeconomic and ecological interactions.

3

The new journal Ecological Economics (Costanza, 1989-1994) and the work of Herman Daly (1990) are at the center of suchefforts.

4

Kenneth Arrow notes that " ... in assessing methods such as the CVM [contingent valuation method], the demand curveshould not be considered as some kind of 'reality' to which we should hope to aspire." (Cummings etal. 1986, p. 181)

Bernow and Biewald 14

Page 15: Environmental Sustainability as a Goal Tellus Institute Boston, … · 2017-09-19 · Environmental Sustainability as a Goal in Resource Planning and Policy Stephen Bernow and Bruce

Beyond the Economic Paradigm

Consumers and Citizens

The role of individuals in microeconomics is a typically represented by veryabstract simplifications of the complex biological and social beings that weare. Homo economicus is a species of utility-maximizing individuals,deciding how to allocate limited disposable income to various combinationsof commodities. This model emphasizes people acting as individuals andconsumers.

We are also members of a society and inhabitants of ecosystems. As socialbeings, we participate in decisions on society's goals and values. As part ofthe fabric of life on the planet, we have an interest in maintaining andenhancing the quality of the environment, and protecting it for futuregenerations.

Contingent valuation attempts to determine the value of environmentalresources, by posing questions to individuals regarding their willingness topay for different levels of environmental quality. It emphasizes theindividual as a consumer allocating his or her income, and treats theelements of environmental quality as commodities whose proper prices areappropriately determined by consumers' preferences. This approach is not asubstitute for a public discourse on society's values and goals, which have adifferent status in a polity from individual preferences. Consumers' choicesof household or recreational items should not be afforded the same status,theoretically or in practice, as society's (and its citizens') adherence to basicvalues such as freedom of speech or equal protection under the law,however these may be expressed in specific policies and legislation.

Individuals acting as citizens in such a broader political process expressvery different "values" than they do when acting as consumers.'For example, individuals may make decisions as consumers that imply atime value of money of as much as 20 percent (e.g., credit card purchases)"while the same individuals may support government policies that implydiscount rates closer to 2 percent. Recent proposals for "green pricing" ofelectricity are an interesting example. This pricing approach would offerconsumers an option to purchase "clean" power, generated by renewableresources, at a higher price. The logic of charging a premium price for a

5

A system based on targets rather than externalities may also open the door for lay people to participate in environmentaldecisionmaking in a more effective and meaningful way. The average citizen has an importantcontribution to make in deciding what a "sustainable" environment means and in deciding what type ofenvironment we want to leave for future generations.

Bernow and Biewald 15

Page 16: Environmental Sustainability as a Goal Tellus Institute Boston, … · 2017-09-19 · Environmental Sustainability as a Goal in Resource Planning and Policy Stephen Bernow and Bruce

premium product is attractive, as is the emphasis upon "individual freedomto choose." However, in recognizing the individual as a consumer, thisapproach fails to recognize the individual as a citizen in society. It wouldbe perfectly reasonable to decline "clean electricity" when offered a smallportion as an individual consumer, but to welcome a more costly approachin which all consumers of electricity participate in the "subsidization" ofclean sources of electric power.

Just as other expressions of society's values have evolved to reflect broadsocial concerns (e.g., economic/social security, civil rights, protection oflabor), so too should protection of human health, recognition of the deeperrelationships between economic and ecological processes, consideration ofthe ethical issues embodied in bequeathing sufficient natural as well asman-made "resources" to subsequent generations, and the ethical andaesthetic considerations in striving for more benign interactions with extra-human nature.

Society's goals and values regarding the environment may be expressed inmyriad forms, including pollution taxes, emission constraints, command andcontrol regulation, wilderness setasides, bans on certain materials andpollutants, legal structures, government investments and programs,education, and new institutional arrangements. Discussions about thesepolicies may itself imply a certain "willingness to pay," but this would beone constructed quite apart from markets and simulated markets.

The "tragedy of the commons" is the archetypal example of the existence ofan externality, wherein individuals maximizing their own utility cause a .suboptimal or disastrous outcome for society. In this situation, the"invisible hand" of the market fails to produce an acceptable result.

Society, then, must look for remedies. An economic incentive system (e.g.,a tax) may be used to optimize the use of the resource, perhaps based onan ecological constraint (e.g., grazing not to exceed the rate at which grasscan survive and reproduce effectively). Other "commons" may simply beset aside to be bequeathed to future generations. The conventional view ofsuch regulation appears to be that it is generally undesirable, to beimplemented and tolerated to the extent that corrections to the marketsystem may be required. One might also look at examples of protection ofecosystems and natural endowments as the best of human behavior. Thesuccessful cooperation of individuals, whether voluntary or self-imposedthrough law and regulation, should be examined, acknowledged, andcelebrated as a "glory of the commons." In sum, we need to shift our focusfrom individuals as consumers to individuals as citizens.

Bernow and Biewald 16

Page 17: Environmental Sustainability as a Goal Tellus Institute Boston, … · 2017-09-19 · Environmental Sustainability as a Goal in Resource Planning and Policy Stephen Bernow and Bruce

Economy and &ology

The separation of economy from ecology in both theory and the principlesgoverning economic life, is a radical abstraction, historically useful butintrinsically flawed." From the vantage point of that abstraction, and theassociated abstractions of the sovereign consumers acting individuallythrough markets, environmental impacts can be viewed as externalities,perturbations or marginal effects around the edges of a system ofrelationships that is to a first order independent of those interactions; thebasic system need only be adjusted to account for these effects, which arenot yet fully represented in its markets through appropriate prices. Thisperspective, and the institutions built around it, may no longer be tenablein its current form, however resonant with various human goals and valuesit has been in the past. While in the past the amount of food harvestedfrom the land and water bodies was limited by available tools, today it isincreasingly limited by the amount and condition of the resourcesthemselves.

For the most part, the scale of human economic activity has beenconstrained by the character of sociopolitical organization and the level oftechnological development. To be sure, local depletion and degradation ofthe environment can occur, and has occurred, at levels of population andproduction far below today's, and in those contexts, new social forms andtechnologies have often provided the basis for avoiding or superseding suchcrises. Today, however, the scale and range of human activity, and the roleof technology, are more problematical. The condition of the biospherecontinues to affect the opportunities for human activity generally and foreconomic development in particular. But the condition of the biospherehas in turn been affected by such activity, which today has reached amagnitude that threatens further development at local, regional, national,and global levels.

Herman Daly (1991) schematically diagrams the sets ofeconomic/ecological relationships in a matrix linking the human andnonhuman domains of the biosphere, noting that each of the pairs --conventional economics (human to human interactions), ecology(interactions within nonhuman nature), environmental economics (human tononhuman interactions), and resource economics (nonhuman to humaninteractions) -- is by itself inadequate to the full task of representing the

6

See, for example Daly and Cobb (1989), Costanza (1989), Georgescu-Roegen (1971).

Bernow and Biewald 17

Page 18: Environmental Sustainability as a Goal Tellus Institute Boston, … · 2017-09-19 · Environmental Sustainability as a Goal in Resource Planning and Policy Stephen Bernow and Bruce

complexity of the relationships.' Theemergingfieldof"ecologicaleconomics"thusbegins bytakingtheentirematrixasitsdomain,whilerecognizingthatthesecondlawofthermodynamicsandtheavailablethroughputofsolarenergycircumscribetheseprocesses,asmattersofphysicallawandphysicalphenomena,"

Thus,whileitrespects and makes use of the separate contributions of these four.discourses, it seeks to be more than their simple summation.Correspondingly, its reflections upon the social and institutional practicesappropriate to these conditions, also take as their point of departure, if notarrival, the techniques--market and others--that prevail in current practiceor consideration.

The purposes to which our economic activity and productive capabilitieshave been put--the creation of social wealth--can be undermined by thatactivity itself. Not only are the resources and means for producingcommodities for human consumption being called into question as thetwenty-first century looms, but some of the ends as well. The spatialconfiguration of society, the relationship of built environments to theirnatural surroundings, the organization of production, the fabrication of newsubstances, the forms of agriculture, water use, etc., will need to bereexamined from the perspective of ecological principles and therelationship between economics and ecology. Since so many of the world'speoples do not enjoy the living standards brought by industrialization andresource exploitation to so few, important questions regarding equity,political stability, and the preservation of democracy are posed by the linkbetween economy and ecology.

In sum, new forms of economic theory, and new institutions, may berequired to adequately reflect the realities of economic/ecologicalinteractions. These would provide the bases for formulation and executionof policies and practices designed to help realize the various individual andsocial objectives--environmental sustainability, social and individual wealthand well-being, political freedom, justice--that might otherwise conflict withone another.

Monetization, Discounting, and Intergenerational Equity

"Frank Ramsey, for instance, argued that it was ethicallyindefensible for society to discount future utilities.Individuals might do so, either because they lackimagination ...or because they are all too conscious that life is

7

See figure 1 of Costanza in this volume.

8

See, for example, Odum (1983) and Odum (1989).

Bernow and Biewald 18

Page 19: Environmental Sustainability as a Goal Tellus Institute Boston, … · 2017-09-19 · Environmental Sustainability as a Goal in Resource Planning and Policy Stephen Bernow and Bruce

short. In social decision-making, however, there is no excusefor treating generations unequally, and the time-horizon is, orshould be, very long. In solemn conclave assembled, so tospeak, we ought to act as if the social rate of time preferencewere zero ..." (Robert Solow, 1974).

Resource allocation decisions often involve tradeoffs over time. In certaincases (e.g., nuclear waste and global warming), the impacts of our decisionscan span centuries. Today's CO2 emissions will likely contribute to climatechange for decades, while some of the ecological, economic anddemographic impacts of global warming may occur over centuries. Theusual tool in cost-benefit analysis for combining economic effects spreadover time into a single measure of total cost is the "discount rate."

Ordinarily, discount rates are used to express time preference, reflectingwillingness to forgo certain consumption now by investing to achieveexpected consumption later, and the associated risk of that investmentdecision. Whether undertaken by the individual, the firm, or society,resource allocation must take this into account, because the costs andbenefits of different resource strategies will have different temporalpatterns. Discounting costs enables the comparison between costs thatoccur now and costs that occur in the future by establishing an indifferencefactor (or equivalence) between consuming/paying now orpaying/consuming in the future," Ideally, by establishing this indifferencefactor, economically efficient resource allocation over time can be ensured.

There are many important considerations in the determination of adiscount rate for any particular analysis (see, for example, Lind et al. 1982),and some analysts have questioned the compatibility of discounting and themaintenance of ecological sustainability (Howarth, 1991a; Howarth, 1991b;Norgaard and Howarth, 1992; Bernow and Marron, 1991; and Bernow etal. 1992).

It is interesting to consider that within a context where only economiclosses are considered, and with a discount rate that is higher than the rateof economic growth, the entire value of the planet (i.e., the world'seconomy) after any particular point is finite, since the annual discountedcontribution can rapidly approach zero. Thus, within this economicframework, if one were faced with the policy decision between: 1)spending a small annual percentage of GNP in the near term in order toavoid major economic collapse a century or more from now, or 2) not

9

Every consumer may have a different discount rate, expressing a different willingness to trade future expenditures and goodsfor current expenditures and goods.

Bernow and Biewald 19

Page 20: Environmental Sustainability as a Goal Tellus Institute Boston, … · 2017-09-19 · Environmental Sustainability as a Goal in Resource Planning and Policy Stephen Bernow and Bruce

investing the money and suffering the long-term economic loss, one wouldbe compelled to select the latter. This result is, prima facie, unacceptable.The limitations of discounting over very long time periods becomes evenmore problematic when human and ecological consequences areconsidered.

While the authors have routinely applied real discount rates in energyresource cost-benefit analyses and planning studies, we believe that the useof discounting applies best to relatively near-term cash flow analysis and"marginal" impacts. It may be inappropriate to apply real discount rates toimpacts of the time, magnitude, and geographic scales involved in globalwarming. Nonlinearities in the environmental damage functions, includingpossible threshold effects in the economy/ecology interactions, also raiseproblems for the discounting approach, for local and regional as well asglobal environments.

Fairness between generations is determined by comparing the welfare ofeach generation. The value of each generation's welfare is relative to itsown time period; that is, a comparison is made between the value a persontoday places on her situation now and the value a person 50 years fromnow places on his situation then. It is not the value a person today has forthe situation fifty years from now. Yet that is what is reflected inconventional discounting from today's perspective. For that reason,discounting is not sufficient, nor are variations in discount ratesappropriate, to ensure that the intergenerational equity is reflected inresource allocation decisions."

Indeed, it may be impossible to place an economic value on irreversiblechanges in certain environmental resources. Conventional economicanalysis and discounting assume a reasonable degree of continuity inunderlying conditions. The loss of a species, the elimination of a uniquehabitat, or the potential global and regional impacts of climate change, arediscontinuous changes in the environment, whether local or global, that areirrevocable. As Cline indicates with a quote from Mishan, we cannot knowthe value that future generations will place on their environmentalresources: Whenever intergenerational comparisons are involved ... it is aswell to recognize that there is no satisfactory way of determining socialworth at different points in time" (Cline, 1992, p. 239).Discount rateanalysis lies strictly in the realm of economic efficiency. The use of apositive discount rate does not necessarily result in resource allocationsthat are equitable to future generations. Instead, the issues of equity mustbe decided separately from those of efficiency. Society today must consider

oSee, for example, Dodds and Lesser (1992, p. 112) and Howarth (1991).

Bernow and Biewald 20

Page 21: Environmental Sustainability as a Goal Tellus Institute Boston, … · 2017-09-19 · Environmental Sustainability as a Goal in Resource Planning and Policy Stephen Bernow and Bruce

the legacy of its resource decisions. To the extent that the resourceallocation decisions made today include the possibility of irreversiblechanges in the environment now or in the future, society must decidewhether such change is justifiable. When such change occurs, futuregenerations will not have the option of recovering the resource in exchangefor some measure of their own consumption. As Lind observes, the toolsof economic efficiency inform the debate, but "other rules or judgementmust be evoked in deciding whether to incur the risks for the future bycreating and storing nuclear waste or by not investing heavily in energyR&D" (Lind, 1986, p. 457).

SustainabiIity Targets

While discounting aims to ensure efficiency in resource allocation overtime, the use of discounting for long time frames, over which large andirreversible impacts are possible, is problematic. Economic efficiency isnot the only societal goal, and the objectives of environmental sustainabilityand intergenerational equity are distinct from that of economicefficiency." To sustain its existence, society must take steps to guaranteethat the welfare of its future generations is not compromised by the short-term decisions of its current generations. Intergenerational equity requiresthat we bequeath sufficient human-made and natural resources so thatfuture generations are at least as well off as current generations.

This is at the center of the emerging concept of sustainable development.In its weaker sense sustainable development would require that acombination of environmental and productive conditions be maintained atsome level or exceeded; in its stronger sense, this would require thatenvironmental conditions and the conditions of production are separatelysustained at or above minimum acceptable levels. Moreover, either ofthese two senses of sustainability could be further strengthened by applyingit to local as well as more global ecological and economic systems. Finally,while sustainable development from the standpoint of productive andecological conditions is distinct from issues of social equity and politicalenfranchisement, they interact in complex ways. The preservation andinnovative expansion of democratic institutions, and a more equitabledistribution of work and wealth, may be necessary concomitants ofeconomic and ecological sustainability.

1

To a first order, so too is intragenerational equity, whether among groups within nations or among nations. If efficiency isdefmed as Pareto optimality, then certain solutions are precluded that might increase overall welfare.Improved social and economic equity could enhance the prospects for economic efficiency as well aslong-term sustainability. We do not address these issues further here.

Bernow and Biewald 21

Page 22: Environmental Sustainability as a Goal Tellus Institute Boston, … · 2017-09-19 · Environmental Sustainability as a Goal in Resource Planning and Policy Stephen Bernow and Bruce

Society may decide that certain decisions are unacceptable owing to theconsequences that affect future generations, regardless of the values thateconomic analysis might place on them. Nordhaus (1991a, p. 55)acknowledges the limitations of cost-benefit analysis in such policydecisions:

Cost-benefit analyses are a useful starting point forconsidering government policies, but they raise several issuesthat must be addressed before making policyrecommendations. To begin with, many values cannot beincorporated in a quantitative cost-benefit analysis. Forexample, climate change may threaten a society's culturalheritage in ways that are not possible to evaluate in aneconomic framework but which are nonetheless unacceptable.While being unable to put a price tag on Venice, we mightdecide that it is unacceptable to take actions that threatenVenice's existence. There is not much economic science cansay about this issue except to identify such trade-offs.

Certain environmental resources would thus not be assigned monetaryvalues within a market-like context for use in a conventional economicanalysis. While most of our argument thus far has focused on long termand/ or global impacts, the same considerations could also apply toenvironmental resources that are more local either spatially or temporally.Instead of assigning monetary values to such "resources" as Venice, theJames Bay ecosystem, the Baltic Sea, or particular forest and watershedecosystems, and adjusting discount rates and costs in an effort to addressintergenerational equity in an efficiency analysis, the alternative is toestablish constraints or targets based on sustainability considerations and toproceed with the efficiency analysis of resource allocation within thoseboundaries.

Targets could be based on aggregate loadings of particular pollutants inparticular ecological contexts (e.g., total greenhouse gases on a global scaleconsistent with climate stabilization) or they could be based on depositionlimits that take account of the impacted ecosystems and their carrying orbuffering capacities. The environmental targets approach entails variantssuch as sustainability indicators (Kuik and Verbruggen, 1991), safeminimum standards (Batie and Shugart, 1989), and critical loads (Chadwickand Kuylenstierna, 1990)

Figure 3 shows how a sustainability target approach to environmentalpolicy might be presented in the graphical form used earlier to present themicro economic approach. Here, the fictional marginal damage cost curvehas been eliminated; a target pollution level, q*, is determined based upon

Bernow and Biewald 22

Page 23: Environmental Sustainability as a Goal Tellus Institute Boston, … · 2017-09-19 · Environmental Sustainability as a Goal in Resource Planning and Policy Stephen Bernow and Bruce

physical or ecological considerations; and a marginal cost of pollutionreduction is implied by the target and the abatement cost curve.

Pursuing intergenerational equity may strictly prohibit certain resourcedecisions, or require additional investments to minimize the risk of futureimpacts if certain decisions are allowed. Policies establishing targets couldrely upon the use of market instruments such as taxes or tradable permits,as long as those instruments are effective at achieving the identified goals.

The costs that are incurred by the instruments used to achieve a particularset of goals can then be examined and used to inform the debate ofwhether society should continue to pursue those goals given their costs, orto identify alternative instruments that are more cost-effective. The propermeans of combining economic and ecological sustainability considerationsis to have a societal discourse, on its values and goals, on the uses and risksto which it subjects human and environmental "resources", and on itswillingness to pay to preserve certain resources for future generations.Environmental and health risk, ecological sustainability, economic cost, andsocial equity have important places in such a discourse.

Bernow and Biewald 23

Page 24: Environmental Sustainability as a Goal Tellus Institute Boston, … · 2017-09-19 · Environmental Sustainability as a Goal in Resource Planning and Policy Stephen Bernow and Bruce

m::s<_=t

o 0::s"'C 32..(l)c;a"- III -0-<0::s -i C:Il 2! (j)(l) <0 (..)o.(l)C •.•(') ~="'00"'0

.::l 0IIIo::r

Page 25: Environmental Sustainability as a Goal Tellus Institute Boston, … · 2017-09-19 · Environmental Sustainability as a Goal in Resource Planning and Policy Stephen Bernow and Bruce

An Example: Acid Precipitation Policy in Europe

One example of the environmental standard or target approach is ananalysis of continent-wide acid deposition abatement strategies for Europethat has been undertaken by the Stockholm Environment Institute Centerat York in the United Kingdom (Chadwick and Kuylensterna, 1990).12

Here the concept of "critical load" is used for establishing environmentaltargets based on local area characteristics. Critical loads are the maximumdeposition of a pollutant that will not cause significant adverse effects onparticular ecosystems. Taking account of emissions, transport, deposition,and area-specific responses and sensitivities to acid gas depositions,modeling exercises are being carried out to determine cost-effectiveabatement strategies for Europe. The transport modeling is performed atthe level of 150 square kilometer grid sizes, while area sensitivities andcritical loads were built up from information at a much finer grid size.

The abatement strategy analysis involves finding the least cost mix ofoptions affecting the emitters of acid gases that will satisfy the critical loadtargets or, alternatively, the minimum overall impact based on relativesensitivities of receptor areas for a given level of expenditures. Thesetechniques can be used to explore the use of environmental standards as ameans to effect acid gas abatement. They could also be used to informother policy instruments such as tax-based systems.

2

The Boston Center of SEI at Tellus is participating in the modeling efforts on this project.

Bernow and Biewald 25

Page 26: Environmental Sustainability as a Goal Tellus Institute Boston, … · 2017-09-19 · Environmental Sustainability as a Goal in Resource Planning and Policy Stephen Bernow and Bruce

Figure 4Relative Sensitivity to Acidic Depositions

.•..

1

~

-¢~<! •

Relative sensitivity to acidic depositions (Class 5·most sensitive;Class 1 • least sensitive).

I ClassS

I Class4

~ Class3

n CIass2oo Class 1

Page 27: Environmental Sustainability as a Goal Tellus Institute Boston, … · 2017-09-19 · Environmental Sustainability as a Goal in Resource Planning and Policy Stephen Bernow and Bruce

Figure 4 provides the map of relative sensitivity to acidic depositions, basedon factors including rock type, soil type, land use, and rainfall, used in theStockholm Environment Institute's CASM model for determining emissionabatement strategies to meet critical load-based spatial distributions ofdepositions." Similar maps could show critical loads, targets, anddepositions.

In March 1993, under the auspices of the United Nations EconomicCommission for Europe (EeE), negotiations began for a new "sulfurprotocol" to reduce emissions of sulfur dioxide from power plants andindustrial boilers, to meet targets based on critical loads of acid rain. Theprecise allocations to nations of the reductions needed to meet the targets,and the mechanisms for implementation, are yet to be negotiated (NewScientist, 1993).

An Example: Greenhouse Warming Policy in the UnitedStates

The global warming problem is largely a matter of addressing large anduncertain impacts, with incomplete knowledge. In such a context,developing policies to respond to the threat involves a decision that isanalogous to deciding whether or not to purchase insurance. That is, is itworthwhile to spend a relatively well defined sum in the near-term in orderto avoid possible large damages (possibly with unknown probabilities ofoccurring) in the longterm? A deterministic cost-benefit analysis thatreflects the environmental consequences of climate change in solelyeconomic terms is not a sound basis for climate change policy.

Nordhaus (1991b, p. 930) is quite candid about the uncertainties in such acost-benefit analysis:

We now move from the terra infirma of climate change to theterra incognita of the social and economic impacts of climatechange. Studies of the impacts of climate change are in theirinfancy, and at this stage we can only hope to obtain anorder-of-magnitude estimate of the impact of greenhousewarming upon the global economy.

Later in the same paper (p. 932), Nordhaus points out that:

A wide variety of non-marketed goods and services escapethe net of the national income accounts and might affect thecalculations. Among the areas of importance are human

3

The figure is reproduced from (SEI 1991, p. 12).

Bernow and Biewald 27

Page 28: Environmental Sustainability as a Goal Tellus Institute Boston, … · 2017-09-19 · Environmental Sustainability as a Goal in Resource Planning and Policy Stephen Bernow and Bruce

health, biological diversity, amenity values of everyday lifeand leisure, and environmental quality.

Of course, under conditions of uncertainty and incomplete knowledge wemight be tempted to wait for the global experiment to unfold. Even if thelikelihood of significant climate change from existing and projected futurecarbon dioxide concentrations were small, staking the future of the planetand its peoples on a role of the dice would be unwise social policy.

The observations of Nordhaus quoted earlier, about the limits of cost-benefit analysis and the appropriate role of economics, suggest that forglobal warming, as for the case of Venice given by Nordhaus in thisdiscussion, the appropriate role for economic analysis is limited to theemission reduction side of the problem, and that the damage side mightbest be left for scientists, politicians, and the public acting through politicalprocesses.

Economic analysis may be informative in estimating the costs of achievingspecified reductions in carbon emissions. It may also have a role indeveloping the least-cost combinations of measures to achieve specifiedreductions. Economic analysis in its current state of development maysimply fail, however, at any attempt to determine an "optimal" level of e02

emissions. Whether this deficiency can be overcome, or whether it is aninherent limitation in the applicability of economic methods, is a questionthat is beyond the scope of this paper.

Nevertheless, global warming policies must be evaluated and implemented.An approach that avoids the most problematic aspects of the cost-benefitapproach is the setting of targets based upon long-term sustainabilitycriteria. For example, the Stockholm Environment Institute has proposedthat "an absolute temperature limit of 2.0 degrees e can be viewed as anupper limit beyond which the risks of grave damage to ecosystems, and ofnon-linear responses, are expected to increase rapidly" (SEI, 1990).

Some believe that in order to achieve climate stabilization there wouldneed to be a reduction in emissions of greenhouse gases of about 40percent by the year 2010, and 70 percent by 2030, relative to today's levels,and seek to analyze and promote economical solutions to theseenvironmental targets (UeS, 1991; National Academy of Sciences, 1991).

If "targets" are set at these levels, then taxes, planning methods (e.g.,externality adders), tradable permit systems, equipment efficiencystandards, and other policies can be developed in order to achieve thetargets. In the case of economic instruments (e.g., a carbon tax) the level ofthe tax would not be based upon an estimate of the "marginal global

Bernow and Biewald 28

Page 29: Environmental Sustainability as a Goal Tellus Institute Boston, … · 2017-09-19 · Environmental Sustainability as a Goal in Resource Planning and Policy Stephen Bernow and Bruce

warming damages from carbon dioxide emissions." Rather, it would be aninstrument to achieve stabilization, with its magnitude based upon anestimate of the level of tax required in order that the goal be realized.With this approach, one might expect periodic adjustment of the taxdepending on the progress toward the goal and on the development oftechnologies to reduce carbon emissions.

Policy Basis and Policy Instrument

It is important to distinguish between the policy basis and the policyinstrument for internalizing externalities. The levels at which taxes ortargets are set can be established on different bases. Within the economicparadigm, damages are valued and the tax (or target) is set at the point atwhich marginal costs of pollution reduction equals marginal damages,based on consumer preferences, in order to achieve economic efficiency.Within a sustainability paradigm, physical constraints are set to ensure thatcritical loads are not exceeded (e.g., carbon dioxide limits for climatestabilization), or targets are set for restoration of degraded environmentalconditions.

As a policy basis, targets and monetary values can be seen to betheoretically equivalent within the economic paradigm. That is, if onebelieves that acceptable damage and cost curves can be established (asshown in figure 2 earlier), the optimal level of pollution occurs where themarginal cost and marginal damage curves intersect: there, theappropriate pollution target is directly related to the optimum value(willingness to pay) at the intersection of the two curves. As policyinstruments, the Pigouvian tax set at p* and the quantity constraint set atq* are theoretically equivalent if the quantity constraint is associated with apermit auction/trading system.

Whether or not one is wedded to an economic paradigm that radicallyabstracts from social reality and reduces myriad societal (andenvironmental) processes to matters of efficient resource allocation derivedfrom individual consumer preferences, it is important not to conflate theinstrument with the basis. Instruments should not become the masters ofour theoretical and policy reflections. Elevating an instrument to a matterof high principle is an instrumentalism that constricts and distorts theprocesses of theoretical, policy, and institutional response to thecomplexities and issues raised by the economy-environment nexus.

However, notwithstanding such theoretical and analytical equivalencebetween the tax and target instruments, there may be differences inpractice owing to technological, institutional, economic and behavioralfactors. Perhaps the most important practical difference is associated with

Bernow and Biewald 29

Page 30: Environmental Sustainability as a Goal Tellus Institute Boston, … · 2017-09-19 · Environmental Sustainability as a Goal in Resource Planning and Policy Stephen Bernow and Bruce

the policy response to uncertainty. If the pollution damages are potentiallyvery high and irreversible, and if there appears be a threshold beyondwhich these damages grow precipitously, policymakers may wish to adopt acap at a safe minimum standard to ensure that a disastrous, albeituncertain, outcome is avoided. The risk that would be taken instead is ofunexpectedly high costs to meet the standard. The pollution tax alternative,perhaps better suited to conditions of greater certainty and smoothness ofthe physical relationships, would ensure the cost but not the environmentaloutcome.

But environmental goals and pollution targets can be set outside theeconomic paradigm and embodied in policies that override and constraineconomic activity. Here the policy basis is sustainability, with targets,critical loads, or safe minimum standards established, based on scientificand policy discourse, and not a damage cost curve based on consumerpreferences, as represented in figure 3. To be sure, the potential costs andeconomic impacts of implementing such targets would be of interest topolicymakers, but the point of departure is the sustainability target. Theinstrument to implement such policy could be either taxes or targets withtradable permits, to ensure economically efficient realization. However,since institutional and behavioral responses to taxes may not ensure thatthe target is reached, it might be necessary to modify the tax levelperiodically. For this reason, and the arguments earlier regarding thepolicy response to uncertain and highly risky physical outcomes, targets(with trading) may be preferred for some environmental goals .

.Conclusions

None of the foregoing arguments regarding sustainability targets should betaken as a complete dismissal of attempts to quantify damages andmonetize damage costs. Indeed, research in these areas is quite important.However, the policy process should not get bogged down in complexdamage cost estimation. As we noted above, the development of suchestimates, while worthwhile, is difficult, controversial and inadequate fordealing with sustainability and intergenerational equity. For that reason,the use of externality costing for policymaking will remain problematical,and we would be wise to provide other bases for realizing ourenvironmental goals.

By applying a sustainability target or safe minimum standards perspectiveon environmental quality to resource planning, we provide such analternative or complementary basis by rearranging the basic structure ofthe problem. Rather than having to justify environmental protection basedon elusive cost-benefit analyses involving the monetization ofenvironmental conditions, we can use the planning process to identify least-

Bernow and Biewald 30

Page 31: Environmental Sustainability as a Goal Tellus Institute Boston, … · 2017-09-19 · Environmental Sustainability as a Goal in Resource Planning and Policy Stephen Bernow and Bruce

cost plans that meet environmental quality standards, especially thoseassociated with sustainability. This process--which would entail explorationof the full range of technologies, techniques and options to meetenvironmental targets--can be complemented by examination of theenvironmental damages associated with those targets, by the costs tosociety and its citizens of achieving those targets, and as desired, byvaluation of those damages that can be directly monetized.

A degree of methodological pluralism may be valuable in the comingperiod. Ascribing monetary values to pollution or environmental impactscan be an instrument for reaching targets. Conversely, the setting oftargets can provide a basis for assigning values, as society's willingness topay is established through political and institutional processes. Both can beused to develop pollution taxes or a permit system, along with other--economic, administrative, legal and institutional--mechanisms. The goalsof environmental protection and sustainable resource development remainthe same.

Bernow and Biewald 31

Page 32: Environmental Sustainability as a Goal Tellus Institute Boston, … · 2017-09-19 · Environmental Sustainability as a Goal in Resource Planning and Policy Stephen Bernow and Bruce

References

Batie, Sandra S. and Shugart, Herman H. 1989. "The BiologicalConsequences of Climate Changes: An Ecological and EconomicAssessment." Chapter 9 in Greenhouse Warming:Abatement andAdaptation. Norman Rosenberg, William Easterling, Pierre Crosson, andJoel Darmstadter, editors. Resources for the Future. Washington, D.e.

Bernow, Stephen and Donald Marron. 1991. "The Inclusion ofEnvironmental Goals in Electric Resource Evaluation: A Case Study inVermont," Chapter 13 in Energy Efficiency and the Environment: Forgingthe Link, Edward Vine, Drury Crawley and Paul Centolella, eds. AmericanCouncil for an Energy Efficient Economy, in conjunction with theUniversitywide Energy Research Group, University of California, Berkeley.

Bernow, Stephen, Bruce Biewald and David Wolcott. 1992. "ModellingFuel Cycle and Site-Dependent Environmental Impacts in ElectricResource Planning" paper presented at the OECD/IEA Expert Workshopon the Environmental Impacts of Energy Systems, Life-Cycle Analysis:Methods and Experience. Paris. May 18 and 19.

Chadwick, M.J. and Kuylenstierna, J.e. 1990. The Relative Sensitivity ofEcosystems in Europue to Acidic Depositions. A preliminary assessment ofthe sensitivity of aquatic and terrestrial ecosystems. StockholmEnvironment Institute at York, University of York, U.K.

Cline, William. 1992. The Economics of Global Warming. Institute forInternational Economics, Washington, D.e. June.

Costanza, R. Ecological Economics. 1989-1994. The Journal of theInternational Society for Ecological Economics. Elsevier. Amsterdam-Oxford-New York-Tokyo.

Cummings, R. G., Brookshire, D.S. and Schulze, W. D. 1986. ValuingEnvironmental Goods: An Assessment of the Contingent Valuation Method.Rowman and Littlefield.

Daly, H. E. and Cobb, J. B. 1989.' For the Common Good: Redirecting theEconomy Toward Community, the Environment and a Sustainable Future.Beacon Press. Boston.

Daly, H. E. 1990. "Towards an Environmental Macroeconomics."Washington, D.e.

Bernow and Biewald 32

Page 33: Environmental Sustainability as a Goal Tellus Institute Boston, … · 2017-09-19 · Environmental Sustainability as a Goal in Resource Planning and Policy Stephen Bernow and Bruce

Daly, H. E. 1991. "Ecological Economics and Sustainable Development:From Concept to Policy." World Bank Environment Department,Divisional Working Paper No. 1991-24. Washington, D.C. August.

Dodds, D. and Lesser, J. 1992. Appropriate Use of Numeric and MonetaryValues for Environmental Impacts of Energy Resource Development and UseDecisions. Washington State Energy Office. Olympia, WA.

Georgescu-Roegen, N. 1971. The Entropy Law and the Economic Process.Harvard University Press. Cambridge.

Howarth, Richard. 1991a. "Economic Efficiency, Intergenerational Equity,and Uncertainty: An Application to Climate Change," presented to thePeder Sather Symposium on Global Climate Change, Berkeley, California,October 16-18, 1991.

Howarth, Richard B. 1991b. "Intergenerational Competitive Equilibriaunder Technological Uncertainty and an Exhaustible Resource Constraint."Journal of Environmental Economics and Management. 21, 225-243.

Howarth, Richard, and Richard Norgaard. 1992. "IntergenerationalTransfers and the Social Discount Rate," presented to the SecondConference of the International Society for Ecological Economics.Stockholm, Sweden. August 3-6.

Kuik, Ono and Verbruggen, Harmen, editors. 1991. In Search ofIndicators of Sustainable Development. Kluwer Academic Publishers.Boston/Dordrecht/London,

Lind, Robert, et al. 1982. Discounting for Time and Risk in Energy Policy,Resources for the Future, Washington, D.C.

Mitchell, R. and R. Carson. 1987. How Far Along the Learning Curve is theContingent Valuation Method? (discussion paper QE87-07), Resources forthe Future, Washington, D.C.

National Research Council. 1980. Energy and the Fate of Ecosystems. TheReport of the Ecosystems Impacts Resource Group, Risk and Impact Panelof the Committee on Nuclear and Alternative Energy Systems, NationalAcademy Press.

New Scientist. 1993. "Britain faces huge bill to cut acid rain." March 13.Page 4.

Bernow and Biewald 33

Page 34: Environmental Sustainability as a Goal Tellus Institute Boston, … · 2017-09-19 · Environmental Sustainability as a Goal in Resource Planning and Policy Stephen Bernow and Bruce

Nordhaus, William. 1991a. "Economic Approaches to Global Warming"in Global-Warming: Economic Policy Responses, Rudiger Dornbush andJames Poterba, editors. MIT Press.

Nordhaus, William. 1991b. "To Slow or not to Slow: The Economics ofthe Greenhouse Effect." The Economics Journal, 101. July.

Norgaard, Richard and Richard Howarth. 1991. "Sustainability andDiscounting the Future" in Ecological Economics: The Science andManagement of Sustainability, R. Costanza, ed. New York: ColumbiaUniversity Press.

Odum, H. 1983. Systems Ecology, An Introduction. Wiley. New York.

Odum, E. 1989. Ecology and Our Endangered Life Support Systems.Sinauer.

Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development, 1989.Environmental Policy Benefits: Monetary Valuation, OECD, Paris.

Shllyakhter, Alexander I., and Daniel Kammen. 1992. "Estimating theRange of Uncertainty in Future Development From Trends in PhysicalConstants and Predictions of Global Change." Department of Physics andNortheast Regional Center for Global Environmental Change, HarvardUniversity, Cambridge, Massachusetts.

Solow, Robert. 1974. The Economics of Resources or the Resources ofEconomics. Richard T. Ely Lecture, American Economic Review 64, No.2. May.

Stockholm Environment Institute. 1990. Targets and Indicators of ClimaticChange. Edited by F.R. Rijsberman and R.J. Swart.

Stockholm Environment Institute. 1991. An Outline of the StockholmEnvironment Institute's Coordinated Abatement StrategyModel (CASM).

SEI, Stockholm, Sweden. November.

UCS. 1991. America's Energy Choices: Investing in a Strong Economy anda Clean Environment. Union of Concerned Scientists, Natural ResourcesDefense Council, American Council, American Council for an Energy-Efficient-Economy, and Alliance to Save Energy, in consultation with

Tellus Institute. Published by Union of Concerned Scientists, Cambridge,Massachusetts.

Bernow and Biewald 34

l-

Page 35: Environmental Sustainability as a Goal Tellus Institute Boston, … · 2017-09-19 · Environmental Sustainability as a Goal in Resource Planning and Policy Stephen Bernow and Bruce

United Nations Environment Programme and Beijer Institute. The FullRange of Responses to Anticipated Climate Change. Nairobi. 1989.

Bernow and Biewald

-

35