empirical education research

84
Empirical Education Research Lent Term Lecture 3 Dr. Radha Iyengar

Upload: sereno

Post on 17-Jan-2016

30 views

Category:

Documents


1 download

DESCRIPTION

Empirical Education Research. Lent Term Lecture 3 Dr. Radha Iyengar. Last Time. Model of Human Capital Acquisition Choose optimal schooling where MB=MC For some individuals, MC lower because of ability (ability bias) - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Empirical Education Research

Empirical Education Research

Lent TermLecture 3

Dr. Radha Iyengar

Page 2: Empirical Education Research

Last Time

Model of Human Capital Acquisition Choose optimal schooling where MB=MC For some individuals, MC lower because of

ability (ability bias) For some individuals, MB higher because of

group/family factors (heterogeneity) IV estimates my be “unbiased” for a given

subgroup but the returns in that subgroup may be very different than other groups

Page 3: Empirical Education Research

Topics Covered TodayBroadly 3 Major Strands of Empirical Research Returns to Education (Ability Bias)

Angrist and Krueger Ashenfelter and Rouse

Credit Constraints and Education Investment Carneiro and Heckman Dynarski

Education Production Function Hanushek Krueger Hoxby Rouse and Figlio

Page 4: Empirical Education Research

Estimating Returns to Education Generally 3 approaches:

Cross-sectional variation (Mincer Regression) Within group differences Instrumental Variables

Page 5: Empirical Education Research

Mincer Regression

log( y ) = a + bS + cX + dX2 + e

Estimated worldwide with estimates ranging from 0.05 to 0.15

Linear model fits the data well even in countries with very different economies, education system, etc.

Page 6: Empirical Education Research

Source: Angrist and Lindhal (2001) JEL

Page 7: Empirical Education Research

Issues with Mincer Regression How to interpret the coefficient on

schooling? Ability bias: Upward “bias” Heterogeneity in effects: ??? Measurement Error: Downward “bias” Signalling vs. Human Capital (next week)

In practice, OLS seems to be slightly, though not significantly smaller than the IV approaches

Page 8: Empirical Education Research

Simple Solution to Ability Bias The simplest way of dealing with this

problem is to find a measure of ability (IQ, AFQT, or similar) BUT no good reason to expect the relative ability

bias to be constant across people This is especially a problem if b differs across

ages and other groups Also the relationship between ability and

schooling varies greatly across time and individuals.

Page 9: Empirical Education Research

Instrumental Variables Basic goal: Find something that varies schooling

but is uncorrelated with unobserved factors (e.g. ability)

Estimate the component of schooling predicted by “instrument”

Use predicted schooling (rather than actual schooling) to estimate relationship between schooling and earnings

Page 10: Empirical Education Research

Various Instruments

Card: Proximity to 2-Year or 4-Year colleges + Parent’s education

Kane & Rouse: Tuition at local 2-year and 4-year colleges

Angrist & Krueger: Quarter-of-birth and compulsory schooling laws

Page 11: Empirical Education Research

Compulsory Schooling IV Angrist and Krueger (AK) use quarter of birth as

an instrument for education to determine the impact of education on earnings.

quarter of birth impacts education attainment b/c compulsory schooling laws,

this source of schooling variation is uncorrelated with other factors influencing earnings,

Page 12: Empirical Education Research

Does quarter of birth affect education?

Regress de-trended education outcomes on quarter of birth dummy variables:

(individual i, cohort c, birth quarter j, education outcome E, birth quarter Q)

This shows that Q does impact education outcomes such as total years of education and high school graduation.

ijccjicj QQQEE 332211)(

Page 13: Empirical Education Research

Is Schooling related to Quarter of Birth?

Page 14: Empirical Education Research

Is this due to compulsory schooling laws?- 1

Indirect evidence: Examine impact of birth quarter on post-

secondary outcomes that are not expected to be affected by compulsory schooling laws.

No birth quarter impact on post-secondary outcomes is consistent with a theory that compulsory schooling laws are behind the birth quarter-education relationship for secondary education.

Page 15: Empirical Education Research

Direct evidence: Construct a difference-in-difference measure of schooling law impact between high age requirement states and low age requirement states:

%Eage 16, high is the fraction of 16 year olds enrolled in high school in states where attendance in mandatory up to age 17 or 18)

)]%(%)%[(% ,15,15,16,16 lowagehighagelowagehighage EEEELaw of Impact

Is this due to compulsory schooling laws?- 2

Page 16: Empirical Education Research

How to estimate: OLS Wald estimate compares the overall

difference in education and earnings between Q1 and Q2-4 individuals

Consistency requires that the grouping variable (Q) is correlated with education (Educ), but uncorrelated with wage determinants other than education.

For instance, this assumes that ability is distributed uniformly throughout the year.

QIVQIIQI

QIVQIIQI

EducEduc

WageWageWald

loglog

Page 17: Empirical Education Research

Difference-in-Differences estimate of about 4%

Decreasing effect over time. Maybe because of increasing returns to college

Page 18: Empirical Education Research

IV Estimates

Two-Stage Least Squares (2SLS) uses quarter of birth to predict education, then regresses wage on this predicted value of education to estimate the return to education (ρ)

First stage:

Second stage:

ijcijc j icC icii QYYXE

iicC icii EYXW log

Page 19: Empirical Education Research

Correlation between QOB and Schooling

Page 20: Empirical Education Research

IV Estimates of Return to Schooling

Page 21: Empirical Education Research

Summary of AK Quarter of birth is a valid instrument: affects educational

attainment through compulsory schooling laws, not through unobserved ability First quarter individuals (who enter school at an older age and

can leave earlier too) receive about 0.1 fewer years of schooling and are 1.9% less likely to graduate from HS than those born in the fourth quarter.

Quarter of birth is found to be unrelated to post-secondary educational outcomes.

Between 10 to 33% of potential drop outs are kept in school due to compulsory attendance laws.

Returns to an additional year of schooling are remarkably similar to those estimated with OLS, approximately 7.5% depending on the specification.

Page 22: Empirical Education Research

What about variation in marginal benefits?

Think that marginal benefits different for different people

Want to see how shifts in marginal benefit curve affect investment in schooling

Need assumption on how marginal benefits vary

Page 23: Empirical Education Research

Within Family Estimates Some of the unobserved differences that

bias a cross-sectional comparison of education and earnings are based on family characteristics

Within families, these differences should be fixed. Observe multiple individuals with exactly the

same family effect, then we could difference out the group effect

Page 24: Empirical Education Research

Estimating Family Averages Can look at differences within family effect

This of this as a different CEF for each familyE[Yij -Yj | S, X, f] = a + b(Sij – Sj) + c(Xij – Xj) +

c(X2ij – X2

j)

The way we estimate this:

ˆˆˆˆˆˆ)log( 2ijjijijijij efXdXcSbay

Page 25: Empirical Education Research

What makes this believable

No within family differences

Might be a problem with siblings generally Parents invest differently Cohort related differences—influence siblings

differently Different “inherited” endowment

More believable with identical twins

Page 26: Empirical Education Research

A twins sample Ashenfelter and Rouse (AR) Collect data at

the Twins festival in Twinsburg Ohio

Survey twins: Are you identical? If both say yes—then included Ever worked in past two years Earnings, education, and other characteristics

Useful because also get two measures of shared characteristics, so can control for measurement error

Page 27: Empirical Education Research
Page 28: Empirical Education Research

Comparing twins to others Sample at Twinsburg NOT a random sample

of twins Benefit: more likely to be similar because

attendees are into their “twinness” Cost: not necessarily generalizable, even to

other twin

Attendees select segment of the population Generally Richer, Whiter, More Educated, etc. Worry about heterogeneity of effects across

some of these categories

Page 29: Empirical Education Research
Page 30: Empirical Education Research
Page 31: Empirical Education Research

Where’s the variation

Recall our estimating equation

If Sij is the same in both twins, no contribution to estimate of b

Only estimated off of twins who are different from each other in schooling investments

ˆˆˆˆˆˆ)log( 2ijjijijijij efXdXcSbay

Page 32: Empirical Education Research

Correlation Matrix for Twins

Education of twin 1, reported by twin1

Education of twin 1, reported by twin2

ALL of the identification for b comes from the 25% of twins who don’t have the same schooling

Page 33: Empirical Education Research

Summary of AR Consistent with past literature—returns

around 8-10 %

OLS estimate slight upward bias but with measurement error there’s a slight downward bias

Ability bias less of a problem than measurement error

Page 34: Empirical Education Research

General Conclusions on RTS Returns appear to be between 8-12 percent in the

US

Not much different between OLS, IV, and within family estimators Maybe ability bias not as much of problem as we

thought Maybe there’s an offsetting bias (marginal benefits,

measurement error etc.)

Maybe the estimation strategies are not eliminating the source of the bias—i.e. some other factor is affecting all these estimates.

Page 35: Empirical Education Research

Credit Constraints and Education We’re always assuming selection into education

(esp higher education) on ability but may also be on resources

Can’t borrow against future earnings so if don’t have high asset endowment, hard to afford extra schooling

ReferencesCarneiro and Heckman (2002) “The Evidence on credit constraints in Post-

Secondary Schooling” Economic Journal 112: 705-734Dynarski (2003) “Does Aid Matter: Measuring the Effect of Student Aid on

College Completion” American Economic Review 93(1)

Page 36: Empirical Education Research

% Attending College related to Parent’s Income

Page 37: Empirical Education Research

How do Credit Constraints affect RTS Estimates?

IV estimates of the wage returns to schooling (the Mincer coefficient) exceed least squares estimates (OLS) is consistent with short term credit constraints. The instruments used in the literature are invalid

because they are uncorrelated with schooling or they are correlated with omitted abilities.

Even granting the validity of the instruments, IV may exceed least squares estimates even if there are no short term credit constraints

Page 38: Empirical Education Research

The Quality Margin The OLS-IV argument neglects the choice

of quality of schooling. Constrained people may choose low quality

schools and have lower estimated Mincer coefficients (‘rates of return’) and not higher ones.

Accounting for quality, the instruments used in the literature are invalid because they are determinants of potential earnings.

Page 39: Empirical Education Research

The general issue Individuals cannot offer their future earnings as

collateral to finance current education

Individuals from poorer families with limited access to credit will have more trouble raising funds to cover college

This affects: Attendance in college Completion of college Quality/content of education

Page 40: Empirical Education Research

Two theories for the facts Higher income parents produce higher

“ability” children or invest more in their children

Access to credit means low-income individuals don’t attend college, reducing their human capital and reinforcing the relationship between schooling and earnings

Page 41: Empirical Education Research

Return to our model Let’s ignore experience (for ease) and so consider

the model

Let’s also define the wages in for two groups: College Grad and HS Grads

specific decision rule on college attendance: S = 1 if Y1 – Y0 – C > 0, and S = 0 otherwise. We can think of C as representing the costs of schooling

(e.g. tuition)

ebSaYy )log(

1111)ln( UYy 0000 )ln( UYy

Page 42: Empirical Education Research

Defining IV and OLS Estimates Suppose the true model we want to

estimate is:

Then for an instrument Z , our OLS and IV estimates are:

eAbSaY

)(

),(ˆSVar

SACovbbOLS

),(

),(ˆSZVar

ZACovbbIV

Page 43: Empirical Education Research

Why might IV be bigger than OLS Taking homogeneous returns, if we believe

γ>0, then IV > OLS if

Or rescaling and taking the case were COV(Z,S)>0

)(

),(

),(

),(

SVar

SACov

ZSCov

ZACov

SZSAZA

Page 44: Empirical Education Research

Source: Carneiro and Heckman (2002)

Page 45: Empirical Education Research

Estimating the effect of Costs Suppose the instruments are valid and b varies

across the population

Let C=0 then individuals with higher b will get more schooling

The returns to schooling are

Same true if C not to big and not too strongly correlated with Y1 – Y0

]1|[]1|[ 01 SYYESbE

Page 46: Empirical Education Research

people with characteristics that make them more likely to go to school have higher returns on average than those with characteristics that make them less likely to go to school.

High costs not so correlated with RTS

Page 47: Empirical Education Research

Negative Selection Individuals with high b also have high C

then Marginal entrants to college have higher

average returns than the population average In the extreme: dumb kids have rich parents,

smart kids have poor parents IV estimates will isolate returns of smart kids

and will exacerbate ability bias relative to OLS

Page 48: Empirical Education Research

High costs correlated with RTS

Page 49: Empirical Education Research

Does increase Aid increase College Attendance

Source: Dynarski, 2003

Page 50: Empirical Education Research

Empirical Evidence for Credit Constraints Not much to support it—some evidence of

responses to subsidies but: Mostly go to people likely to go to college anyway Hard to separate out relaxing credit constraints from

subsidizing for marginal, unconstrained individuals

Other margins of adjustment Reduce cost and reduce quality education of low-income individuals not comparable to

high-income

Page 51: Empirical Education Research

Education Production If education is valuable good (i.e. it has high

returns)—need to worry about how it is produced

If can’t get adjustments on the quantity margin—maybe we can get it at the quality margin

Usually think about education as representing some intangible thing that’s valuable Responsible people Democratic values

Page 52: Empirical Education Research

Production Function Define

Eist = f( NSist, Rist, Xist, ε)

NS: Non school inputs, not under control of school s in year t Innate ability of students Parent’s wealth

R: School inputs NOT under control of school s in year t Resources Student type (peers)

X: School inputs under control of school s in year t Class size Teacher quality curriculum

Page 53: Empirical Education Research

Estimation Usually don’t worry about function form—

just think of it linearlyEist = α+ β*NSist + γ*Rist +δ*Xist + εist

Can look at the effect of change in any of the factors on “education”

Usually looking to estimate either δ (Returns to resource investment) or γ Often end up estimate δ+ γ

Page 54: Empirical Education Research

Outcome measures Choice matters

depends on what you think the intervention/investment will effect

Depends on what makes education productive

Common choice Wages HS graduation/college attendance Test scores

Frequent Cheap Noisy but correlated with stuff we care about

Page 55: Empirical Education Research

What to estimate

Value added model Change in outcomes Eist – Eist-1

Control for what’s new to students in current yearEist = α+ λ*Eist-1 β*NSist + γ*Rist +δ*Xist + εist

These are the same if λ=1

Page 56: Empirical Education Research

What have people found?

Hanushek (1997) JEL meta-analysis Aggregate across papers No clear relationship between inputs and

schooling Krueger (2003)

Weight papers equally: systematic positive relationship

Weight papers in proportion to number of estimates, not related

Tennessee Star Experiment

Page 57: Empirical Education Research
Page 58: Empirical Education Research
Page 59: Empirical Education Research

Issues with the literature

Class size coefficient mixes up two things Resources put into teachers (e.g. salary) Teacher pupil ratio

Define log expenditures as EXP, log teacher pupil ratio at TP and log teacher salary as L, which are related as follows:

EXP= L + T

Page 60: Empirical Education Research

Model of production The true model we want to estimate is:

E( y ) = α + τ*TP + λ*L

If instead we estimate, we have a problem:

If proportionate changes in the teacher-pupil ratio and teacher pay have equal effects on achievement, ψ will be zero.

LTPEXPTPyE **)(*ˆ*ˆˆ)(

Page 61: Empirical Education Research

Why might class-size be important Lazear (1999) presents a simple model of class-

size in probability of a child disrupting a class is independent

across children, the probability of disruption is intuitively increasing in

class size. Assuming that disruptions require teachers to suspend

teaching it will tend to reduce the amount of learning for everyone in the class.

There may be other benefits to smaller classes as well such as closer supervision or better tailoring to individual students.

Page 62: Empirical Education Research

Evidence on Class Size-1

Tennessee Star Experiment: Students randomly assigned to one of 3 class-

types: Small (13-17 students) Regular(22-25 students) Regular + Teacher’s aid

Newly entering students randomly assigned to one of the class-types

Continue assignment through 3rd grade Analyzed by Krueger (QJE, 1999)

Page 63: Empirical Education Research
Page 64: Empirical Education Research

Distribution of treatment effects

Page 65: Empirical Education Research

Class size Evidence-2 Maimonides Rule (Angrist and Lavy)

Use rule in Israel to determine class-size 25 students: 1 teacher 25-49 students: 1 teacher + aide 50+ students: 2 teachers

Page 66: Empirical Education Research

Maimonides Rule

Page 67: Empirical Education Research

Using predicted class-size

Page 68: Empirical Education Research

Reduced Form Estimates

Page 69: Empirical Education Research

IV Estimates

Page 70: Empirical Education Research

General Class-size Evidence On balance probably increase test scores

Even at young ages, after first year gains from increase test scores smaller

In later years, gains smaller

Heterogeneous and about 1/3 of students may not gain in smaller classes

Page 71: Empirical Education Research

School Incentives

Broadly two types of studies Incentives from competition (vouchers,

increased number of schools in an area, etc.) Incentives from monitoring/accountability

standards (e.g. NCLB)

Other work on increases in teacher pay, but hard to separate selection from incentives in increased performance

Page 72: Empirical Education Research

School competition

Best evidence probably from Hoxby (2000): uses streams to identify school district boundary. IV estimates suggest school competition helps

Criticism from Rothstein: sensitivity to specification and definition of stream. Results might not be that robust

Page 73: Empirical Education Research
Page 74: Empirical Education Research

School Accountability Mixed Evidence:

Rouse (QJE, 1998): Wisconsin vouchers program gave students in low

performing schools vouchers to private school Gains in math, no gains in reading

Rouse (JPubEc, 2006): Look at FL program, similar to NCLB, imposes standards

and if fall below standards, close schools and issue vouchers.

Changes in raw test scores show large improvements associated with the threat of vouchers.

much of this estimated effect may be due to other factors. The relative gains in reading are largely explained by

changing student characteristics the gains in math are limited to the high-stakes grade.

Page 75: Empirical Education Research
Page 76: Empirical Education Research
Page 77: Empirical Education Research
Page 78: Empirical Education Research
Page 79: Empirical Education Research
Page 80: Empirical Education Research
Page 81: Empirical Education Research
Page 82: Empirical Education Research
Page 83: Empirical Education Research
Page 84: Empirical Education Research