electricity transmission pricing: getting the prices “good enough”?

52
Electricity transmission pricing: getting the prices “good enough”? Richard Green Institute for Energy Research and Policy

Upload: breck

Post on 15-Jan-2016

40 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

DESCRIPTION

Electricity transmission pricing: getting the prices “good enough”?. Richard Green Institute for Energy Research and Policy. Transmission pricing. Geographical differentiation in the wholesale market Prices for connecting to and using the transmission network. Six objectives. - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Electricity transmission pricing: getting the prices “good enough”?

Electricity transmission pricing: getting the prices “good enough”?

Richard Green

Institute for Energy Research and Policy

Page 2: Electricity transmission pricing: getting the prices “good enough”?

Transmission pricing

• Geographical differentiation in the wholesale market

• Prices for connecting to and using the transmission network

Page 3: Electricity transmission pricing: getting the prices “good enough”?

Six objectives

1. Promote the efficient day‑to‑day operation of the bulk power market

2. Signal locational advantages for investment in generation and demand

3. Signal the need for investment in the transmission system

Page 4: Electricity transmission pricing: getting the prices “good enough”?

Six objectives

4 Compensate the owners of existing transmission assets

5 Be simple and transparent

6 Be politically implementableGreen (Utilities Policy, 1997)

Page 5: Electricity transmission pricing: getting the prices “good enough”?

Three approaches

• Ignore transmission issues

• Ignore transmission issues, then bribe market participants to sort things out

• Integrate transmission issues into your market design(s)

Page 6: Electricity transmission pricing: getting the prices “good enough”?

Major power flows

Source: UCTE

Page 7: Electricity transmission pricing: getting the prices “good enough”?

Major power flows and congestion

Source: UCTE

Congested 26-75% 76-99% 100%

Page 8: Electricity transmission pricing: getting the prices “good enough”?

If costs differ between areas

GW

P

GW

P

PL

PHPricetrade

Xpts Mpts

Page 9: Electricity transmission pricing: getting the prices “good enough”?

If costs differ between areas

GW

P

GW

P

Pricetrade

Xpts Mpts

Page 10: Electricity transmission pricing: getting the prices “good enough”?

Pricetrade

If costs differ between areas

GW

P

GW

P

and the lines are too thin…

Xpts Mpts

Page 11: Electricity transmission pricing: getting the prices “good enough”?

If costs differ between areas

T {

GW

P

GW

P

and the lines are too thin…

Xpts Mpts

Page 12: Electricity transmission pricing: getting the prices “good enough”?

Pricetrade

If costs differ between areas

GW

P

GW

P

and the lines are too thin…you could still ignore the problem

but someone will want money to sort it out!Xpts Mpts

Page 13: Electricity transmission pricing: getting the prices “good enough”?

Zones in the NEM

• NEM runs nodal model and dispatches according to nodal conditions (prices)

• Generators / loads grouped into regions

• All generators in a region receive the regional reference price– Marginal cost at a reference node

• No compensation for constrained running

Page 14: Electricity transmission pricing: getting the prices “good enough”?

From a line to a network…

• Electricity will flow along every path between two nodes

• It “cannot” be steered

• If one line fails, the flows instantly change

• Overloading any line can be catastrophic

Page 15: Electricity transmission pricing: getting the prices “good enough”?

(for example…)

Page 16: Electricity transmission pricing: getting the prices “good enough”?

A B

C

The impact of loop flows

Page 17: Electricity transmission pricing: getting the prices “good enough”?

A B

C

The impact of loop flows

Page 18: Electricity transmission pricing: getting the prices “good enough”?

Nodal prices

• Set price of power equal to marginal cost at each point (node) on the network– Marginal cost of generation (if variable)– MC of bringing in power from elsewhere

• Centralised market uses the nodal prices

• Bilateral trades which move power pay the difference in nodal prices

Page 19: Electricity transmission pricing: getting the prices “good enough”?

Nodal trading

• Price at A = 20, Price at B = 30

• I sell at A, I receive 20

• I sell at B, I receive 30

• I generate at A and sell at B, I receive the agreed bilateral price and pay (30 – 20)

• I generate at B and sell at A, I receive the agreed bilateral price and pay (20 – 30)

AB

Page 20: Electricity transmission pricing: getting the prices “good enough”?

A B

C

6 MW at C needs3 MW from A and3 MW from B

The impact of loop flowsand constraints

Page 21: Electricity transmission pricing: getting the prices “good enough”?

Prices – constraint AB• Price at C = (Pa + Pb)/2• 1 MW extra capacity allows 1.5 MW from A to

replace 1.5 MW from B• Shadow cost of constraint = 1.5 (Pb – Pa) • If Pa = 10, Pb = 30• Pc = 20, shadow cost = 30• Pc = Pa + 1/3 shadow cost

= Pb – 1/3 shadow cost

Page 22: Electricity transmission pricing: getting the prices “good enough”?

A B

C

3 MW at C needs–3 MW from A

The impact of loop flowsand constraints

and 6 MW from B

Page 23: Electricity transmission pricing: getting the prices “good enough”?

Prices – constraint AC

• Price at C = 2Pb – Pa• 1 MW extra capacity allows 3 MW from A

to replace 3 MW from B• Shadow cost of constraint = 3 (Pb – Pa) • If Pa = 10, Pb = 30• Pc = 50, shadow cost = 60• Pc = Pa + 2/3 Shadow cost

= Pb + 1/3 Shadow cost

Page 24: Electricity transmission pricing: getting the prices “good enough”?

A B

C

and constraints

3 MW at C needs 6 MW from A

The impact of loop flows

and–3 MW from B

Page 25: Electricity transmission pricing: getting the prices “good enough”?

Prices – constraint CB• Price at C = 2 Pa – Pb • 1 MW extra capacity allows 3 MW from A to

replace 3 MW from B• Shadow cost of constraint = 3 (Pb – Pa) • If Pa = 10, Pb = 30• Pc = –10, shadow cost = 60• Pc = Pa – 1/3 shadow cost

= Pb – 2/3 shadow cost

Page 26: Electricity transmission pricing: getting the prices “good enough”?

Summary

Constraint is on line:

None AB AC BC

Price at A 10 10 10 10

Price at B 10 30 30 30

Price at C 10 20 50 -10

Page 27: Electricity transmission pricing: getting the prices “good enough”?

Implications

• Nodal prices can vary significantly– Over time– Over space

• The first creates a need for hedging

• The second makes it harder

• The prices may be counter-intuitive

Page 28: Electricity transmission pricing: getting the prices “good enough”?

How to hedge

• Transmission Congestion Contract

• Spatial contract for differences– Pays the holder the difference in nodal prices

between two specified points (from A to B)– Price at B – Price at A– Perfect hedge if you generate that amount of

power at A and sell it at B• Remember the real-time charge is (PB – PA)

Page 29: Electricity transmission pricing: getting the prices “good enough”?

Who’d sell that hedge?

• The spot market charges raise a surplus– Who gets it?

• If the Transmission Congestion Contracts allocation is feasible, Hogan (1992) shows spot market surplus ≥ TCC payments

• Organisation receiving the spot surplus can issue TCCs and find itself hedged!

Page 30: Electricity transmission pricing: getting the prices “good enough”?

Inferior ways of hedging

• Financial Transmission Rights (options)– Only pay out when value is positive– Payments may exceed spot revenues

• Physical Transmission Rights– Limited by system capacity– If line limit on AB is 100, can only issue 100– With TCCs, 100 BA “allows” an extra 100 AB

• “Smeared” share of congestion revenues

Page 31: Electricity transmission pricing: getting the prices “good enough”?

What if you get it wrong?

• Operational difficulties– PJM’s first market

• Economic operating mistakes

• Investment mistakes– At present, we don’t know much about these

Page 32: Electricity transmission pricing: getting the prices “good enough”?

How much does it cost to get it wrong?

• Compare demand and operating patterns with different pricing rules

• Model applied to England and Wales, 1996 data

• Numbers are country- and time-specific

• Approach is general

Page 33: Electricity transmission pricing: getting the prices “good enough”?

The model

• NGC system in 1996/97

• Thirteen zones (two pairs of NGC’s zones are combined, one zone split into two)

• Iso-elastic demand in every zone

• Generation in most £/MWh

GW

Gas, Coal,Nuclear Oil

Page 34: Electricity transmission pricing: getting the prices “good enough”?

North

South-West

A DC load flow model with losses (proportional to the square of flows) and constraints on the total flows across NGC’s system boundaries

Transmission system model

Page 35: Electricity transmission pricing: getting the prices “good enough”?

Three pricing rules

• One price for generation and for demand in each zone (optimal)

• One price at each node for generation, but a common national price for demand

• One national price for generation and one national price for demand (actual system)– Constraints are managed via payments for

constrained-on and constrained-off running

Page 36: Electricity transmission pricing: getting the prices “good enough”?

What is welfare?

• NGC’s operating surplus– Kept the same under each of the rules

• Generators’ operating surpluses– Energy revenues less variable fuel costs– Gas contracts assumed not to be variable

• Consumer surplus– Area under their demand curve and above the

price they actually pay

Page 37: Electricity transmission pricing: getting the prices “good enough”?

Prices – winter peak

0

10

20

30

40

50

0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 12 13

£/MWh

Optimal

G varying

Uniform

Page 38: Electricity transmission pricing: getting the prices “good enough”?

Prices – summer trough

0

2

4

6

8

0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 12 13

£/MWh

Optimal

G varying

Uniform

Page 39: Electricity transmission pricing: getting the prices “good enough”?

Basic results

Pricing System Optimal Nodal (forGenerators)

Uniform

Av. Revenue (£/MWh) 27.17 27.39 28.21

Changes (% of optimal, competitive, revenue):

Consumer surplus -0.2% -3.4%

Generators’ profits -0.9% 2.1%

Welfare -1.2% -1.3%

Page 40: Electricity transmission pricing: getting the prices “good enough”?

Intuition for the results

• Adjustments to generation for constraints have to happen, whatever the pricing rule– Here, these are in the same direction as the

economic response to marginal losses

• Cost differences at stations partially offset marginal transmission losses

Page 41: Electricity transmission pricing: getting the prices “good enough”?

Market power

• Sometimes a problem in this market– General incentive to raise prices– Particular incentive to raise prices in import-

constrained area– Uniform pricing gives incentive to reduce

prices in export-constrained area

• Model two strategic generators plus fringe– Both firms change slope of bids (by region)

Page 42: Electricity transmission pricing: getting the prices “good enough”?

Generators’ capacities

0

2

4

6

8

10

0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 9 10 8 12 13

Zone

GW OtherPowerGenNational Power

North

South-West

Page 43: Electricity transmission pricing: getting the prices “good enough”?

Prices – winter peak

0

25

50

75

100

125

150

0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 12 13

£/MWh

Optimal MP Optimal

G varying MP G varying

Page 44: Electricity transmission pricing: getting the prices “good enough”?

Prices – summer trough

0

2

4

6

8

10

0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 12 13

£/MWh

Optimal MP Optimal

G varying MP G varying

Page 45: Electricity transmission pricing: getting the prices “good enough”?

Prices – zone 12

0

25

50

75

100

125

150

Winterpeak

Trough Summerpeak

Trough

£/MWh MP Optimal

MP G varyingOptimal

G varyingUniform

Page 46: Electricity transmission pricing: getting the prices “good enough”?

Prices – zone 1

0

10

20

30

40

Winterpeak

Trough Summerpeak

Trough

£/MWh MP Optimal

MP G varyingOptimal

G varyingUniform

Page 47: Electricity transmission pricing: getting the prices “good enough”?

Market power

Pricing System Optimal Nodal (forGenerators)

Uniform

Av. Revenue (£/MWh) 44.70 46.90 45.25

Changes (% of optimal, competitive, revenue):

Consumer surplus -6.6% -1.0%

Generator profit 4.3% -2.1%

Welfare Rel. to optimal -2.3% -3.1%

Rel. to comp -5.4% -6.5% -7.2%

Page 48: Electricity transmission pricing: getting the prices “good enough”?

Conclusions of this study• Optimal pricing would create winners

(northern consumers, southern generators) and losers (northern generators, southern consumers)

• It would be less vulnerable to market power

• Welfare gains of 1% of turnover are quite large as Harberger triangles go!

Page 49: Electricity transmission pricing: getting the prices “good enough”?

Other transmission charges

• Connection assets – local costs• Capacity-based use of system

– Affect investment decision, not operating choices

• Output-based use of system– Affect operating choices and might be used to

offset consistent errors in the market rules

• Contracts for constrained running

Page 50: Electricity transmission pricing: getting the prices “good enough”?

Interactions between charges

• Investing generators should consider both spot market and transmission charges– With the right spot signals, transmission

charges should be uniform– Differentiated transmission charges needed if

spot prices send inadequate signals– Using both would over-signal, reducing

transmission costs, but raising generators’

Page 51: Electricity transmission pricing: getting the prices “good enough”?

Conclusion

• For major changes, transmission charging creates well-informed winners and losers– Gains typically small relative to transfers

• With good operators, the system is resilient to poor rules

• Better rules will create gains worth having

Page 52: Electricity transmission pricing: getting the prices “good enough”?