economics of renewable natural resources

72
Economics of Renewable Natural Resources Bioeconomics of Marine Fisheries Ashir Mehta Source : The Economics of Marine Capture Fisheries, Steven C. Hackett, Professor of Economics, Humboldt State University 1

Upload: rogan-bray

Post on 30-Dec-2015

43 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

DESCRIPTION

Economics of Renewable Natural Resources. Bioeconomics of Marine Fisheries Ashir Mehta Source : The Economics of Marine Capture Fisheries, Steven C. Hackett, Professor of Economics, Humboldt State University. Fisheries. What is a fishery?. - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Economics of Renewable Natural Resources

Economics of Renewable Natural Resources

Bioeconomics of Marine Fisheries

Ashir Mehta

Source : The Economics of Marine Capture Fisheries, Steven C. Hackett, Professor of Economics, Humboldt State University

1

Page 2: Economics of Renewable Natural Resources

Fisheries

What is a fishery?

The interaction of fish populations and human harvest activity

The economically valuable portion of a fish population is a renewable but potentially exhaustible natural resource.

2

Page 3: Economics of Renewable Natural Resources

The Bioeconomics of a FisheryBackground information on the biological mechanics of a fisheryIdentification of a steady-state bioeconomic equilibrium Harvesting under open access Socially optimal harvest

BioeconomicsBioeconomics combines the biological mechanics of a fish population with the economic activity of harvesting fish.

3

Page 4: Economics of Renewable Natural Resources

Biological MechanicsImagine a rich marine habitat for a certain species of fish. There’s lots of food and shelter and few predators and parasites.

If the number of reproductive mature fish in this habitat is low, but there is mating success, will the habitat generally allow for reproductive success?

Suppose that a breeding pair is able to produce 10 young that reach adulthood.

Then from an initial stock of 2 fish (male and female), the stock grows by 10 fish.

4

Page 5: Economics of Renewable Natural Resources

Biological Mechanics

Number of Adult Fish

Rate of Growth

2010 .

5

Page 6: Economics of Renewable Natural Resources

Biological MechanicsNext breeding season we have 12 reproductively mature fish (assume the original 2 are still alive). Suppose there is still plenty of habitat, so that again each pair produces 10 young that reach adulthood.

How many new adult fish are produced this season?6 breeding pairs x 10 = 60 new adults

6

Page 7: Economics of Renewable Natural Resources

Biological Mechanics

Number of Adult Fish

Rate of Growth

2010 .

12

60 .

7

Page 8: Economics of Renewable Natural Resources

Biological MechanicsNext breeding season we have 50 mature fish (assume mortality of 10 adult fish due to old age or predation). Suppose that the habitat now only allows each pair to produce 4 young that reach adulthood. Why might this be happening?

How many new adult fish are produced this season?

25 breeding pairs x 4 = 100 new adults

8

Page 9: Economics of Renewable Natural Resources

Biological Mechanics

Number of Adult Fish

Rate of Growth

2010 .

12

60 .

50

100 .

9

Page 10: Economics of Renewable Natural Resources

Biological MechanicsNext breeding season we have 126 mature fish (assume 24 old adults die). Suppose that the habitat only allows each pair to produce, on average, 2.3 young that reach adulthood. Why might this be happening?

How many new adult fish are produced this season?63 breeding pairs x 2.3 = 145 new adults

10

Page 11: Economics of Renewable Natural Resources

Biological Mechanics

Number of Adult Fish

Rate of Growth

2010 .

12

60 .

50

100 .

126

145 .

11

Page 12: Economics of Renewable Natural Resources

Biological MechanicsNext breeding season we have 224 mature fish (assume 47 old adults die). Suppose that now the habitat only allows each pair to produce, on average, 0.5 young that reach adulthood. Why might this be happening?

How many new adult fish are produced this season?112 breeding pairs x 0.5 = 56 new adults

12

Page 13: Economics of Renewable Natural Resources

Biological Mechanics

Number of Adult Fish

Rate of Growth

2010 .

12

60 .

50

100 .

126

145 .

224

56 .

13

Page 14: Economics of Renewable Natural Resources

Biological MechanicsEventually, the population or stock of fish will reach a biological maximum for the available habitat. At this maximum, the birth rate equals the death rate.

If conditions do not change, the population will remain at this maximum, making it an equilibrium.

14

Page 15: Economics of Renewable Natural Resources

Biological Mechanics

Number of Adult Fish

Rate of Growth

2010 .

12

60 .

50

100 .

126

145 .

224

56 .

Population growth rate curve: Describes population growth for different populations of fish

15

Page 16: Economics of Renewable Natural Resources

Biological Mechanics• Let’s suppose that X stands for the stock (population) of

economically valuable fish.

• Moreover, suppose that F(X) is the population growth

rate for the fishery (birth rates – death rates).

• F(X) reflects the rate of net recruitment (number of new fish enter a fishery, net of fish removed from the fishery).

• Note that if the fish stock is described by the usual logistic function (smoothly increasing at a decreasing rate), then the stock growth rate can be given as follows:

F(X) = aX – bX2

16

Page 17: Economics of Renewable Natural Resources

Biological Mechanics

F(X) = aX – bX2

Note that the maximum value for the fish population X equals (a/b), which we will define as k (carrying capacity) for a given habitat.

When X = k, stock growth rate F(X) = 0.

17

Page 18: Economics of Renewable Natural Resources

Biological Mechanics

Fishery Stock X

Rate of Growth

X1

Note that one can have the same fishery stock growth rate F(X) at two different sizes of the stock (X1 and X2)

k0 X2

Rate of Fishery Stock Growth F(X)

18

Page 19: Economics of Renewable Natural Resources

Introduction to BioeconomicsBasic Principles: Basic Principles:

Begin with an unexploited fishery in biological equilibrium (where X = k):

1. Suppose that the harvest rate H exceeds even the highest possible population growth rate for the fishery. Then population X eventually falls to zero. Fishers are “mining” the fishery.

19

Page 20: Economics of Renewable Natural Resources

Mining the Fishery (H > F(X))

Fishery Stock X

Rate

k0

Fishery stock growth rate F(X)

Harvest rate H

20

Page 21: Economics of Renewable Natural Resources

Example of Mining the Fishery

Fishery Stock X

Rate

k = 10,0000

Harvest rate H2,000

Year 1: Harvest 2,000 fish 8,000 left for next year.

21

Page 22: Economics of Renewable Natural Resources

Example of Mining the Fishery

Fishery Stock X

Rate

k 0

Harvest rate H2,000

Year 2: Harvest 2,000 fish, popul. grows by 700 6,700 left for next year.

X = 8,000

700

22

Page 23: Economics of Renewable Natural Resources

Example of Mining the Fishery

Fishery Stock X

Rate

k 0

Harvest rate H2,000

Year 3: Harvest 2,000 fish, popul. grows by 1,200 5,900 left for next year.

X = 6,700

1,200

23

Page 24: Economics of Renewable Natural Resources

Example of Mining the Fishery

Fishery Stock X

Rate

k 0

Harvest rate H2,000

Year 4: Harvest 2,000 fish, popul. grows by 1,400 5,300 left for next year.

X = 5,900

1,400

24

Page 25: Economics of Renewable Natural Resources

Example of Mining the Fishery

Fishery Stock X

Rate

k 0

Harvest rate H2,000

Year 5: Harvest 2,000 fish, popul. grows by 1,450 4,750 left for next year.

X = 5,300

1,450

25

Page 26: Economics of Renewable Natural Resources

Example of Mining the Fishery

Fishery Stock X

Rate

k 0

Harvest rate H2,000 Year 6: Harvest 2,000

fish, popul. grows by 1,400 4,150 left for next year.

X = 4,750

1,400

26

Page 27: Economics of Renewable Natural Resources

Example of Mining the Fishery

Fishery Stock X

Rate

k 0

Harvest rate H2,000 Year 7: Harvest 2,000

fish, popul. grows by 1,200 3,350 left for next year.

X = 4,150

1,200

27

Page 28: Economics of Renewable Natural Resources

Example of Mining the Fishery

Fishery Stock X

Rate

k 0

Harvest rate H2,000

Year 8: Harvest 2,000 fish, popul. grows by 900 2,250 left for next year.

X = 3,350

900

28

Page 29: Economics of Renewable Natural Resources

Example of Mining the Fishery

Fishery Stock X

Rate

k 0

Harvest rate H2,000

Year 9: Harvest 2,000 fish, popul. grows by 700 950 left for next year.

X = 2,250

700

29

Page 30: Economics of Renewable Natural Resources

Example of Mining the Fishery

Fishery Stock X

Rate

k 0

Harvest rate H2,000

Year 10: Try to harvest 2,000 fish, but only 950 left. Even with 400 new fish produced, stock is destroyed.

X = 950

400

30

Page 31: Economics of Renewable Natural Resources

Introduction to Bioeconomics

Basic Principles:Basic Principles:

2. The highest rate of harvest H that can be sustained by the fishery occurs where the growth rate of the fishery stock is at its maximum. This point is called maximum sustainable yield (MSY).

31

Page 32: Economics of Renewable Natural Resources

Example of Mining the Fishery

Fishery Stock X

Rate

k 0

Why is a harvest of 1,450 fish/year in this example equal to maximum sustainable yield?1,450

32

Page 33: Economics of Renewable Natural Resources

Introduction to BioeconomicsBasic Principles: MSYBasic Principles: MSY

A. If we start with the stock at X = k (the unexploited biological equilibrium), and set harvest equal to MSY, then what happens?

Hmsy > F(X), which causes X to decline. This process continues until X = Xmsy, at which point the harvest rate H equals the stock growth rate F(X) and no further reduction in biomass occurs. This is an equilibrium.

33

Page 34: Economics of Renewable Natural Resources

Biological Mechanics

Fishery Stock X

Rate

Xmsyk0

Hmsy

Stock Dynamic A

Start here

End here

34

Page 35: Economics of Renewable Natural Resources

Introduction to BioeconomicsBasic Principles: MSYBasic Principles: MSY

B. In contrast, suppose that the fishery had been over-harvested in the past and the stock is at X < Xmsy. If we start at a relatively low stock and set harvest equal to MSY, then what happens?

The population is extinguished.

35

Page 36: Economics of Renewable Natural Resources

Biological Mechanics

Fishery Stock X

Rate

Xmsyk0

Hmsy

Stock Dynamic B

Start here

End here

36

Page 37: Economics of Renewable Natural Resources

Introduction to Bioeconomics

Basic Principles:Basic Principles:

C. For harvest rates H < Hmsy there are

usually two biomass equilibria – “low biomass” and “high biomass”.

37

Page 38: Economics of Renewable Natural Resources

Biological Mechanics

Fishery Stock X

Rate

Low biomass equilibrium X1

0

H

High biomass equilibrium X2

Fishery stock growth rate F(X)

38

Page 39: Economics of Renewable Natural Resources

Introduction to Bioeconomics

Basic Principles: Basic Principles: H < Hmsy

To see this, suppose that the population is at X = k (the unexploited biological equilibrium). If H > F(X), what will happen?

The stock X will decline until it reaches the high biomass equilibrium where F(X) = H.

39

Page 40: Economics of Renewable Natural Resources

Biological Mechanics

Fishery Stock X

Rate

Xhigh k0

H Start here

End here

40

Page 41: Economics of Renewable Natural Resources

Introduction to Bioeconomics

Basic Principles: Basic Principles: H < Hmsy

Suppose now the stock X is less than the high biomass equilibrium, but is large enough that F(X) > H. What will happen?

The stock X will grow to the high biomass equilibrium where F(X) = H.

41

Page 42: Economics of Renewable Natural Resources

Biological Mechanics

Fishery Stock X

Rate

Xhigh k0

HStart here

End here

Net growth rate F(X) - H

F(X)

42

Page 43: Economics of Renewable Natural Resources

Introduction to Bioeconomics

Basic Principles: Basic Principles: H < Hmsy

Thus the high biomass equilibrium is sustainable and is locally stable (it holds “locally” for X somewhat larger or smaller).

43

Page 44: Economics of Renewable Natural Resources

Introduction to Bioeconomics

Fishery Stock X

Rate

0

H

Range of initial stock values that will result in the high biomass equilibrium X2

[ ]

Fishery stock growth rate F(X)

44

Page 45: Economics of Renewable Natural Resources

Introduction to BioeconomicsBasic Principles: Basic Principles: H < Hmsy If the stock X is at the low biomass equilibrium, then F(X) = H. This equilibrium is also sustainable.

But … if the stock X is even slightly less than the low biomass equilibrium, then F(X) < H, and X falls to zero – the population is extinguished. If X is even slightly greater than the low biomass equilibrium, then F(X) > H and X rises to the high biomass equilibrium.

Thus the low biomass equilibrium is not stable.45

Page 46: Economics of Renewable Natural Resources

Biological Mechanics

Fishery Stock X

Rate

0

H

The low biomass equilibrium is not stable

Fishery stock growth rate F(X)

X1

46

Page 47: Economics of Renewable Natural Resources

Introduction to Bioeconomics

Basic Principles: Basic Principles:

Assume that the fishing industry is competitive, and fishermen take ex-vessel price as well as input prices (e.g., fuel, bait, labor cost) as fixed parameters. In other words, individual fishers are too small to control price, and cannot form a cartel (like OPEC).

47

Page 48: Economics of Renewable Natural Resources

What Determines Harvest Rate?What factors would determine how many tons of fish per day will be harvested from a fishery?

Total effort E (number of vessels, gear, deckhands, etc).

Stock of fish X available to be caught.

The harvest function H(t) defines fishing industry output at time “t”. It is a production function production function :

H(t) = G[E(t), X(t)]

E(t) is effort, and defines the quantity of inputs (e.g., labor, capital, bait, fuel) applied to the task of fishing at time “t”.

48

Page 49: Economics of Renewable Natural Resources

Introduction to BioeconomicsBasic Principles: Basic Principles: assume that there is diminishing marginal productivity to effort, which means that each unit of additional fishing effort (e.g., a day of fishing) results in smaller and smaller landings of fish.

Effort can be measured in units that aggregate the inputs into “vessel-hours”, or “person-hours per vessel”, which are indices of inputs applied to fishing.

The other factor affecting harvest at time “t” is the existing stock of fish X(t).

Note that effort E(t) and stock X(t) interact. For example, the marginal productivity of effort is higher when X is larger. (Why?)

49

Page 50: Economics of Renewable Natural Resources

Harvest Function

Fishery Stock X

Harvest Rate

0

H = G(E,X)

X1

}H(X0)

If the stock X is larger, then for given (fixed) amount of effort E, the harvest rate will be larger. Why? (More nos. added with a larger base)

X0

}H(X1)

50

Page 51: Economics of Renewable Natural Resources

Introduction to BioeconomicsBasic Principles: Basic Principles: Without harvest activity, recall that the unexploited steady-state biological equilibrium occurs where X = k. Fishery stock growth equals zero.

With human harvest activity, the net stock growth rate equals the stock growth rate minus the harvest rate (F(X) – H(t)).

Thus a steady-state bioeconomic equilibrium a steady-state bioeconomic equilibrium occurs when the net stock growth rate equals occurs when the net stock growth rate equals zerozero F(X) – H(t) = 0 thus, when F(X) = H(t)

51

Page 52: Economics of Renewable Natural Resources

Steady-State Equilibrium Harvest

Fishery Stock X

Rate

0

H

X*

F(X)

Steady-state equilibrium harvest occurs where harvest rate H = biomass growth rate F(X).

F(X*) = H

52

Page 53: Economics of Renewable Natural Resources

Introduction to BioeconomicsBasic Principles: Basic Principles:

Note that there is a higher level of effort E that will yield the same harvest rate. This corresponds to the low biomass vs. high biomass equilibria.

53

Page 54: Economics of Renewable Natural Resources

Steady-State Equilibrium Harvest

Fishery Stock X

Rate

0

H = G(E1,X)

Xhigh

Due to low fishery stocks (Xlow), it takes a higher level of effort (E2) to generate the same harvest rate. H = G(E2,X)

Xlow

With high fishery stocks (Xhigh), it takes a lower level of effort (E1) to generate the same harvest rate.

54

Page 55: Economics of Renewable Natural Resources

Introduction to BioeconomicsBasic Principles: Basic Principles:

Since effort costs money in a fishery (fuel, bait, labor (opportunity) costs), the low biomass equilibrium is bioeconomically inefficient for the fishing industry as a whole. It generates the same harvest rate (i.e., tons per day) as the high biomass equilibrium, but involves higher effort costs.

55

Page 56: Economics of Renewable Natural Resources

Harvesting Under Open AccessDerivation of the Derivation of the open-accessopen-access equilibrium equilibrium

Assume that no private/common/govt. property rights are asserted over the fishery. Thus anyone can fish and catch as much as they want (“open access”).

Assume (for simplicity) that a unit of effort costs “c” dollars, and a unit of harvested fish generates “p” dollars.

Total revenue equals price per ton multiplied by total landings of fish TR = P x H.

Recall that in equilibrium the harvest rate H equals stock growth rate F(X). Thus the total revenue curve looks like the F(X) curve.

56

Page 57: Economics of Renewable Natural Resources

Steady-State Equilibrium Effort

Effort E

$

0

TC = cE

Ehigh

Open access means that equilibrium effort (Ehigh)

is found where fishing industry profit = 0, which occurs where total revenue equals total cost.

TR = pH(E)

57

Page 58: Economics of Renewable Natural Resources

Steady-State Equilibrium

Fishery Stock X

Rate

0

Zero profit under open access results in high levels of effort, which makes the harvest curve steeper and pushes the bioeconomic equilibrium fishery stock [found where F(X) = H(t)] below MSY.

H = G(Ehigh,X)

Xlow Xmsy

58

Page 59: Economics of Renewable Natural Resources

Harvesting Under Open AccessEfficiency of the Open Access Equilibrium:Efficiency of the Open Access Equilibrium:

Under open access, equilibrium can only occur when profit is zero (no incentive to enter or exit).

Economic efficiency occurs at the profit-maximizing level of effort where MR = MC. Yet under open access, the equilibrium level of effort is selected where profit equals zero and MC > MR.

Thus the open-access equilibrium the open-access equilibrium alwaysalways features an inefficiently large amount of effort features an inefficiently large amount of effort being deployed in the fisherybeing deployed in the fishery.

59

Page 60: Economics of Renewable Natural Resources

Group Optimum Harvest

Group optimum harvest (or “socially optimal” harvest) takes into account the stock effect, and occurs where industry-wide profits are maximized, which occurs where marginal revenue equals marginal cost.

60

Page 61: Economics of Renewable Natural Resources

Open Access v. Group Optimum Harvest

Effort E

$

0

TC = cE

E0

Open access means that equilibrium effort (E0) is found where fishing industry profit = 0 (TR=TC). Note that the group optimum level of effort (E*) is smaller than E0, generates a higher steady state level of harvest H, and results in maximum profit as indicated below:

E*

TR(H0)

TR = pH(E)}Maximum

Profit

TR(H*)

61

Page 62: Economics of Renewable Natural Resources

Open Access v. Group Optimum Harvest

Fishery stock X

Rate

0 X*

The group optimum equilibrium results in a stock X* that exceeds that of the open access equilibrium X0 and maximum sustainable yield (Xmsy).

H = G(E0,X)

X0

H(X0)

H(X*)H = G(E*,X)

Xmsy

62

Page 63: Economics of Renewable Natural Resources

Rate (H)TC’ (c*Eopen) TC (c*Esocial) MSY

H0 max. profit zero profit

H1 Eopen

Esocial

TR(P*H) 300 450 500 700 900 stock

(X) group/social optimum E = 450 (max. profit) ; open access E = 900 (zero profit)

stock size = 700 (> MSY ; H rate = H0) stock size = 300 (< MSY ; H rate = H1)

63

Page 64: Economics of Renewable Natural Resources

ExtinctionWhy is extinction more likely to occur under open access than under group-optimum harvest?

Biologically, a key characteristic of fisheries susceptible to extinction is that there is a threshold population > 0 that must exist in order to sustain the species. If the population falls below this threshold, the population declines to extinction.

64

Page 65: Economics of Renewable Natural Resources

Extinction

Threshold effects are more likely to occur in fish species with few births per fertile female.

From a marine mammal point of view, this is the case with blue whales.

Economically, extinction can occur under open access when the price of the fish rises sufficiently that the zero-profit level of effort only occurs at the origin.

65

Page 66: Economics of Renewable Natural Resources

II. Approaches to Fisheries Management

Restricting Access – Territorial Rights – sedentary v/s migratoryRegulating Fishing Practices – make fishing more costly – economically inefficientTAC – rivalry – no ind. QuotasITQs - tradeable

66

Page 67: Economics of Renewable Natural Resources

Approaches to Fisheries Management (contd……..)

A key problem with both open-access fisheries and traditional fishery management tools is that fishermen do not have any property rights to a share of the available fishery stock prior to capture.

Because fishermen do not have a property right to fish until capture, the harvest by one vessel imposes a rule of capture externality on all others by reducing the remaining stock of fish.

Individual Quotas and Other Alternative Management Systems for Marine Capture Fisheries

67

Page 68: Economics of Renewable Natural Resources

Individual Quotas and Other Alternative Management Systems for Marine Capture Fisheries

The rule of capture is old common law. It states that withdrawals from a common-property or open-access resource become private property upon “capture”. Ex: Fish in a fishery are government property (public trust resource) until legally landed by a fisherman, at which point they become private property.

When the rule of capture externality is operating, fishermen have an incentive to overcapitalize in vessel, crew, and gear.

The rule of capture externality promotes a race for fish that leads to diminished product quality and increased fishing hazards.

68

Page 69: Economics of Renewable Natural Resources

Individual Quotas and Other Alternative Management Systems for Marine Capture Fisheries

Individual quotas (IQs) have been implemented in an increasing number of fisheries around the world. IQs assign a share of the TAC to individual fishermen (IFQs), vessels (IVQs), or communities (CFQs). Those who hold quota shares own a share of the TAC. Therefore the fishing season does not end until all quota shares are filled, subject to biological constraints.

By assigning withdrawal rights to a quota share prior to capture, IQs eliminate the rule of capture externality.

69

Page 70: Economics of Renewable Natural Resources

Individual Quotas and Other Alternative Management Systems for Marine Capture Fisheries

By eliminating the rule of capture externality, IQ’s can reduce or eliminate derby (race for fish) conditions and the incentive for overcapitalization.

Reducing overcapitalization increases the economic efficiency of the fishing industry by reducing the total cost of harvesting a given quantity of fish.

70

Page 71: Economics of Renewable Natural Resources

Individual Quotas and Other Alternative Management Systems for Marine Capture Fisheries

issues that can make IQs difficult to implement?

• Establishing a TAC on the fishery may be difficult.

•Must monitor landings to prevent cheating on quota shares.

•Quota shares must be allocated to individuals, vessels, or communities, and the initial quota allocation can be contentious. Processors? Crew members? Allocation based on historical landings?

71

Page 72: Economics of Renewable Natural Resources

Individual Quotas and Other Alternative Management Systems for Marine Capture Fisheries

issues that can make IQs difficult to implement (continued)?

• A decision must be made about whether IQs are to be tradable. If IQs are to be tradable, then a determination must be made regarding who is allowed to purchase quota shares, and whether there is to be an upper limit on quota holdings by an individual, vessel, or community.

• Some see IQ systems as a giveaway of public resources to private individuals, and so a decision must be made over whether some sort of auction or tax should be used to fund monitoring and enforcement.

72