economic instruments for long-term reductions in energy-based carbon emissions

147
Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions State of the Debate

Upload: others

Post on 11-Sep-2021

1 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

Economic Instruments forLong-term Reductions inEnergy-based CarbonEmissions

S t a t e o f t h e D e b a t e

Page 2: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

© National Round Table on the Environment andthe Economy, 2005

All rights reserved. No part of this work covered bythe copyright herein may be reproduced or used inany form or by any means – graphic, electronic ormechanical, including photocopying, recording, taping or information retrieval systems – without the prior written permission of the publisher.

National Library of Canada

Cataloguing in Publication

Main entry under title: The state of the debate on the environment and the economy: economic instruments for long-term reductions in energy-basedcarbon emissions.

Report and recommendations by the National Round Table on the Environment and the Economy.

Includes bibliographical references.

ISBN 1-894737-09-1

1. Carbon dioxide mitigation–Economic aspects–Canada. 2. Carbon dioxide mitigation–Governmentpolicy–Canada. 3. Fiscal policy–Canada. 4. Renewableenergy sources–Government policy–Canada. I. National Round Table on the Environment and the Economy (Canada)

HC120.E5S833 2005363.738’746’0971C2005-903921

Issued also in French under title: L’état du débat surl’environnement et l’économie : les instrumentséconomiques au service de la réduction à long termedes émissions de carbone d’origine énergétique

This book is printed on Environmental Choice papercontaining 20 percent post-consumer fibre, usingvegetable inks.

National Round Table on the Environment and the Economy344 Slater Street, Suite 200Ottawa, OntarioCanada K1R 7Y3Tel.: (613) 992-7189Fax: (613) 992-7385E-mail: [email protected]: www.nrtee-trnee.ca

Other publications available from the NationalRound Table State of the Debate on the Environmentand the Economy Series:

1. State of the Debate on the Environment and the Economy: Water and Wastewater Services in Canada

2. State of the Debate on the Environment and the Economy: Private Woodlot Management in the Maritimes

3. State of the Debate on the Environment and theEconomy: The Road to Sustainable Transportationin Canada

4. State of the Debate on the Environment and theEconomy: Greening Canada’s Brownfield Sites

5. State of the Debate on the Environment and theEconomy: Managing Potentially Toxic Substancesin Canada

6. State of the Debate on the Environment and the Economy: Aboriginal Communities and Non-renewable Resource Development

7. State of the Debate on the Environment and the Economy: Environment and SustainableDevelopment Indicators for Canada

8. State of the Debate on the Environment and theEconomy: Environmental Quality in CanadianCities: the Federal Role

9. State of the Debate on the Environment and theEconomy: Securing Canada’s Natural Capital: AVision for Nature Conservation in the 21stCentury

Toutes les publications de la Table ronde nationalesur l’environnement et l’économie sont disponiblesen français.

To order:Renouf Publishing Co. Ltd.5369 Canotek Road, Unit 1Ottawa, ON K1J 9J3Tel.: (613) 745-2665Fax: (613) 745-7660Internet: www.renoufbooks.comE-mail: [email protected]: C$19.98 plus postage and tax

Page 3: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

Economic Instruments forLong-term Reductions inEnergy-based CarbonEmissions

Page 4: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions
Page 5: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

About UsThe National Round Table on the Environment and the Economy (NRTEE) is dedicated to exploring newopportunities to integrate environmental conservation and economic development, in order to sustain Canada’sprosperity and secure its future.

Drawing on the wealth of insight and experience represented by our diverse membership, our mission is to gen-erate and promote innovative ways to advance Canada’s environmental and economic interests in combination,rather than in isolation. In this capacity, it examines the environmental and economic implications of priorityissues and offers advice on how best to reconcile the sometimes competing interests of economic prosperity and environmental preservation.

The NRTEE was established in 1994 as an independent advisory body reporting to governments and theCanadian public. Appointed by the Prime Minister, our members are distinguished leaders in business andlabour, universities, environmental organizations, Aboriginal communities and municipalities.

How We WorkThe NRTEE is structured as a round table in order to facilitate the unfettered exchange of ideas. By offeringour members a safe haven for discussion, the NRTEE helps reconcile positions that have traditionally been at odds.

The NRTEE is also a coalition builder, reaching out to organizations that share our vision for sustainable development. We believe that affiliation with like-minded partners will spark creativity and generate themomentum needed for success.

And finally, the NRTEE acts as an advocate for positive change, raising awareness among Canadians and their governments about the challenges of sustainable development and promoting viable solutions.

We also maintain a secretariat, which commissions and analyses the research required by our members in their work. The secretariat also furnishes administrative, promotional and communications support to the NRTEE.

The NRTEE’s State of the Debate reports synthesize the results of stakeholder consultations on potentialopportunities for sustainable development. They summarize the extent of consensus and reasons for disagree-ments, review the consequences of action or inaction, and recommend steps specific stakeholders can take to promote sustainability.

iiiEconomic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

MANDATE

Page 6: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions
Page 7: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

CHAIR

Harvey L. Mead Sainte-Foy, Quebec

VICE-CHAIR

Patricia McCunn-Miller Calgary, Alberta

VICE-CHAIR

Ken Ogilvie Executive DirectorPollution Probe FoundationToronto, Ontario

Harinder P. S. Ahluwalia President and CEOInfo-Electronics Systems Inc.Dollard-des-Ormeaux, Quebec

Edwin Aquilina Special Advisor to the MayorCity of OttawaOttawa, Ontario

Louis Archambault President & CEO Groupe-conseil Entraco Inc.North Hatley, Quebec

Jean Bélanger Ottawa, Ontario

David V.J. Bell Professor EmeritusSenior Scholar and Former DeanFaculty of Environmental Studies York University Toronto, Ontario

Katherine M. Bergman Dean, Faculty of Science University of Regina Regina, Saskatchewan

William J. Borland Director, Environmental Affairs JD Irving Limited Saint John, New Brunswick

Wendy L. Carter Vancouver, British Columbia

Douglas B. Deacon Owner, Trailside Café and AdventuresMount Stewart, Prince Edward Island

The Honourable Michael Harcourt Chair Cities Advisory CommitteePrivy Council Office - PacificVancouver, British Columbia

Linda Louella Inkpen St. Phillips, Newfoundland and Labrador

Diane Frances Malley President PDK Projects Inc. Nanaimo, British Columbia

Cristina Marques Co-Owner and Developer of Dreamcoast HomesToronto, Ontario

Patrice Merrin Best President & CEO Luscar Limited Edmonton, Alberta

vEconomic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

NATIONAL ROUND TABLE ONTHE ENVIRONMENT AND THEECONOMY MEMBERS*

* List reflects NRTEE membership at time of report approval.

Page 8: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

vi National Round Table on the Environment and the Economy

Alfred Pilon Corporate Secretary Office franco-québécois pour la jeunesse Montreal, Quebec

Qussai Samak Union AdvisorConfédération des syndicats nationauxMontreal, Quebec

Keith Stoodley Vice-President OceanTalk St. John’s, Newfoundland and Labrador

John Wiebe President & CEOGLOBE Foundation of CanadaVancouver, British Columbia

Judy Williams Partner MacKenzie Fujisawa Vancouver, British Columbia

Eugene NybergActing President & CEONRTEEOttawa, Ontario

Page 9: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

Mandate . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . iii

National Round Table on the Environment and the Economy Members . . . . . . . . . . v

Preface . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . ix

Ecological Fiscal Reform and Energy Task Force Members . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . xi

Introduction: The EFR and Energy Program . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1

Part 1: General Findings and Recommendations . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 7

1. BACKGROUND . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 91.1 Purpose of the Report . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 91.2 Ecological Fiscal Reform . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 9

2. CONTEXT: THE NEW ENERGY ECONOMY—CANADA’S OPPORTUNITY . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 132.1 Global Energy Trends . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 132.2 Canada’s Opportunity . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 13

3. CONTEXT: MAXIMIZING OVERALL ADVANTAGES TO SOCIETY—LONG-TERM CARBON EMISSION REDUCTIONS WITHIN AN INTEGRATED POLICY FRAMEWORK . . . . . . 153.1 Co-benefits: Nine Reasons for an Integrated Policy Framework . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 153.2 Why Long-term Carbon Emission Reductions Cannot be an Implied

or Secondary Objective . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 20

4. ECONOMIC INSTRUMENTS FOR LONG-TERM CARBON EMISSION REDUCTIONS AND TECHNOLOGY DEVELOPMENT . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 214.1 Economic Instruments and Canada’s Climate Change Plan . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 214.2 Macroeconomic Impacts of Fiscal Policy to Promote Long-term Carbon Emission Reductions . . . 224.3 General Findings: Using Economic Instruments for Long-term

Carbon Emission Reductions and Technology Development . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 254.4 Application of Targeted Measures . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 274.5 Transition Measures . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 30

5. A COORDINATED, LONG-TERM CARBON EMISSION REDUCTIONS STRATEGY. . . . . . . . . . . . . 315.1 Staging and Considerations for a Coordinated Technology Transition Strategy . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 32

6. LESSONS: THE EXPERIENCE WITH ASSESSING FISCAL INSTRUMENTS . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 356.1 Data Reliability and Comprehensiveness. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 356.2 Sensitivities. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 356.3 Technology Paths . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 356.4 Examining Mid- to Long-term Futures: Uncertainties and Unknowns . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 366.5 Market Settings . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 366.6 Other Issues . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 37

viiEconomic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

TABLE OF CONTENTS

Page 10: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

viii National Round Table on the Environment and the Economy

7. SUMMARY OF FINDINGS . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 39

PART 2: Specific Findings from the Case Studies . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 41

8. CASE STUDY SCOPE, BOUNDARIES AND METHODOLOGIES . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 438.1 Overview of Case Study Methodologies . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 43

9. SPECIFIC FINDINGS: INDUSTRIAL ENERGY EFFICIENCY . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 499.1 Status of Industrial Energy Efficiency . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 499.2 Status of Industrial Energy Efficiency to 2030 Assuming Business as Usual . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 509.3 Industrial Energy Efficiency Scenarios to 2030 with Government Intervention . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 509.4 Macroeconomic Impact: Industrial Energy Efficiency Case Study . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 529.5 Policy Implications: Industrial Energy Efficiency . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 52

10. SPECIFIC FINDINGS: EMERGING RENEWABLE POWER TECHNOLOGIES . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 5510.1 Status of the Emerging Renewable Power Sector . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 5510.2 Status of the Emerging Renewable Power Sector to 2030 Assuming

Business as Usual . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 5610.3 Status of the Emerging Renewable Power Sector to 2030 with

Government Intervention . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 5710.4 Macroeconomic Impact: Emerging Renewables Case Study . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 6010.5 Policy Implications: Emerging Renewable Power Technologies . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 61

11. SPECIFIC FINDINGS: HYDROGEN ENERGY . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 6511.1 Status of the Hydrogen Energy Sector . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 6511.2 Status of the Hydrogen Energy Sector to 2030 Assuming Business as Usual . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 6611.3 Status of the Hydrogen Energy Sector to 2030 Assuming Government Intervention . . . . . . . . . 6611.4 Macroeconomic Impact: Hydrogen Case Study . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 6811.5 Policy Implications: Hydrogen Energy . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 68

12. MACROECONOMIC IMPACTS OF THE PROPOSED MEASURES . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 73

13. A SUPPORTING SUITE OF COORDINATED ECONOMIC INSTRUMENTS . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 75

14. SUMMARY OF RECOMMENDATIONS, PART II . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 77Industrial Energy Efficiency . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 77Emerging Renewable Power Technologies . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 77Hydrogen Case Study . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 78A Supporting Suite of Coordinated Economic Instruments . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 78

Appendices . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 79

A. EXECUTIVE SUMMARY: CASE STUDY ON ENERGY EFFICIENCY . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 81

B. EXECUTIVE SUMMARY: CASE STUDY ON RENEWABLE GRID–POWER ELECTRICITY . . . . . . 93

C. EXECUTIVE SUMMARY: CASE STUDY ON HYDROGEN TECHNOLOGIES . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 111

D. SELECTED READING . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 115

E. PROGRAM PARTICIPANTS . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 117

F. ENDNOTES . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 125

Page 11: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

This State of the Debate report marks the conclusion of the National Round Table on the Environment andthe Economy (NRTEE)’s Ecological Fiscal Reform (EFR) and Energy Program. It describes the Program’sresearch findings and details the final recommendations stemming from the stakeholder consultations.

The EFR and Energy Program represents the second phase of the NRTEE’s EFR Program. Whereas Phase 1explored the general potential of economic instruments to advance sustainable development—looking at EFR measures in Europe, the United States and Canada, as well as the use of EFR in specific sectors of theeconomy—Phase 2 has focused on the use of economic instruments in achieving long-term reductions ingreenhouse gas emissions, specifically carbon emissions.

Phase 1 of the EFR Program was launched in 2000 and concluded with the publication in 2002 of Toward a Canadian Agenda for Ecological Fiscal Reform: First Steps. Work on Phase 2, the EFR and Energy Program,began shortly afterwards, early in 2003.

The NRTEE will continue to work on the broader topic of climate change and energy. This work has beenmandated by Prime Minister Paul Martin, who requested on February 16, 2005, that the NRTEE “provideadvice and recommendations on the development of a long-term energy and climate change strategy for Canada.”

As well, in the Federal Budget 2005, the NRTEE was asked to develop options for a vehicle feebate, to consult,and to make recommendations to the government prior to the next federal budget. This request reflects the fact that the National Round Table has established capacity in the use of economic and fiscal instruments for environmental objectives.

Glen MurrayChair

ixEconomic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

PREFACE

Page 12: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions
Page 13: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

Note: This program was carried out over a number ofyears, and some participants’ titles/organizations mayhave changed during that time.

Bélanger, Jean(NRTEE Member) ChairEFR & Energy Task Force, NRTEEOttawa, ON

Archambault, Louis(NRTEE Member) Président-directeur généralGroupe-conseil Entraco Inc.Montréal, QC

Beausoleil, JerryDirector General, Strategic Policy BranchIndustry CanadaOttawa, ON(Resigned May 2004)

Bergman, Katherine M.(NRTEE Member) Dean of ScienceUniversity of ReginaRegina, SK

Dillon, JohnVice President, Environment and Legal CounselCanadian Council of Chief ExecutivesOttawa, ON

Favreau, GillesChargé d’équipe Enjeux réglementaireHydro-QuébecQuébec, QC(Resigned July 2004)

Gagnon, LucSenior Advisor, Climate ChangeHydro-QuébecQuébec, QC

Hornung, RobertPolicy DirectorPembina Institute for Appropriate DevelopmentOttawa, ON(Resigned April 2003)

Inkpen, Linda L.(NRTEE Member) Doctor of MedicineSt. Phillips, NL

Leblanc, AlfredDirector GeneralStrategic Policy BranchIndustry CanadaOttawa, ON

McClellan, StephenDirector General, Economic & Regulatory AffairsEnvironment CanadaOttawa, ON

McCuaig-Johnston, MargaretGeneral Director, EDCF – Assistant DeputyMinister’s OfficeFinance CanadaOttawa, ON

McGuinty, David J.President and CEONRTEEOttawa, ON(Resigned January 2004)

Mead, Harvey L.(NRTEE Member) Chair, NRTEEQuébec, QC

Minns, David E.Special Advisor, Sustainable Development TechnologyNational Research CouncilOttawa, ON

xiEconomic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

ECOLOGICAL FISCAL REFORM AND ENERGY TASKFORCE MEMBERS

Page 14: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

xii National Round Table on the Environment and the Economy

Nyberg, EugeneActing President and CEONRTEEOttawa, ON

Odenbach-Sutton, PhyllisDirector, Economic and Fiscal Analysis DivisionEnergy Policy BranchNatural Resources CanadaOttawa, ON

Olewiler, NancyProfessor of EconomicsSimon Fraser UniversityBurnaby, BC

Pattenden, MaryClimate Change Programme DirectorPollution ProbeToronto, ON

Robinson, GregorDirectorConservation, Energy Efficiency & Renewables OfficeOntario Ministry of EnergyToronto, ON

Samak, Qussai(NRTEE Member) Conseiller syndicalConfédération des syndicats nationauxMontréal, QC

Siegmund, MonikaSenior Tax AdvisorShell Canada LimitedCalgary, AB

Wiebe, John(NRTEE Member) President and CEOGLOBE Foundation of CanadaVancouver, BC

Staff:

Wood, AlexanderSenior Policy Advisor

Aplevich, ClaireResearch Associate

Long, AlexResearch Associate

Johnston, DeniseAdministrative Assistant

Consultants:

Cairns, StephanieConsultant/Writer

Watters, David B.Consultant

Page 15: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

Introduction: The EFR and

Energy Program

Page 16: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions
Page 17: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

Concerns about climate change will clearly beamong the many factors driving a coherentenergy strategy. The real debate is about how

much weight should be given to climate change considerations in energy policy and about the appro-priate tools for doing so. To provide more contextfor this critical issue, the National Round Table onthe Environment and the Economy (NRTEE) hasexplored a scenario in which economic instrumentsare used as a key tool to promote long-term carbonemission reductions. The operating assumption ofour Ecological Fiscal Reform (EFR) and EnergyProgram was that long-term reductions in energy-based carbon emissions will be one of the mainpriorities shaping energy strategy.

The EFR and Energy Program’s objective was “todevelop and promote fiscal policy that consistentlyand systematically reduces energy-based carbon emis-sions in Canada, both in absolute terms and as a ratioof gross domestic product, without increasing otherpollutants.” The rationale for this focus was twofold:

1Fiscal policy is one of the most powerful means atthe government’s disposal to influence outcomesin the economy, but it is not typically employedin a consistent and strategic manner to promoteobjectives that have simultaneous economic andenvironmental benefits.

2The related issues of climate change and energypresent substantial challenges and opportunitiesfor Canada, and fiscal policy—employed in a consistent and strategic manner—is a key but underutilized1 element of the government’sresponse. Although taxation and tax credits have,for example, been used to support wind powerproduction or to promote the expanded use ofethanol as a transportation fuel, these efforts have been piecemeal.

The Program examined the role of economic instru-ments in supporting technologies with the potentialto reduce energy-based carbon emissions on both thedemand and supply sides of the energy equation, as well as at three different stages of development:mature technologies, using a case study of industrialenergy efficiency; emerging technologies, using a case study of renewable power technologies in thedemonstration to market-ready stages; and longer-term new technologies, using a case study of hydrogenfuel technologies. The choice of these specific casestudies should not be interpreted as assigning anypriority to these technologies: they are understood tofit within a broad mix of supply sources and demandsectors, now and in the future, including otherequally significant low-carbon energy sources andmitigation technologies, as well as carbon fuels.

The findings and recommendations of the Programdraw not only on the specific analysis carried out inthe three case studies (and their general lessons forthe use of economic instruments), but also on theconsultation process conducted as part of theProgram’s work.

Three questions formed the starting point of inquiry:

• What role can economic instruments play inreducing energy-based carbon emissions in Canadaover the next quarter century?

• What are the constraints that will determine thedesign and application of such instruments?

• How can we undertake a coordinated transitiontoward a lower carbon emission energy system?

3Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

Page 18: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

4 National Round Table on the Environment and the Economy

A 25-year perspective was adopted, inspired by theconviction that focusing on the Kyoto timetablealone would not allow a sufficient time horizon forthe optimum, orderly development and implementa-tion of mitigation and adjustment strategies. Inadopting this time horizon, the NRTEE is in no way suggesting that Canada should ignore its currentcommitments under the Kyoto Protocol. Rather, weare recognizing that the development and deploy-ment of new technologies can take decades: theenergy system is complex and involves myriad decision makers; it is also capital-intensive and willchange most easily at the rate at which long-livedcapital stock is retired.2 Research has shown that thecost of environmental improvement can be sensitiveto timing—that policies matching the pace of tech-nological change to the rates of capital stock turnoverwill reduce compliance costs.3 Since turnover rateswill vary by sector and technology, environmentalimprovement requires a long-term agenda.

Investment decisions are being made now about capi-tal stock that may last for several decades. Without aclear, long-term direction for climate change policy,long-lived carbon-inefficient new stock will continueto be installed, complicating future mitigation efforts.Our long time horizon allows for fundamental shiftsin the energy system, reflecting the advice of bodiessuch as the NRCan Advisory Board on EnergyScience and Technology, which recommended that“to encourage the sustained and sustainable effortsrequired to meet the threat of climate change, bothreduction of emissions and response to its effects, a long term focus on the 2015-2050+ time-frame will be required, including stable and sustainablepolicies.”4

This report is organized into two parts plus appendices:

• Part 1 covers high-level themes and general findings and recommendations. Section 1 givesbackground on the purpose and context of thereport, and on EFR. Section 2 outlines Canada’sunique opportunities in an emerging, more envi-ronmentally conscious global energy economy, andSection 3 describes the connections between along-term energy-based carbon emission reductionstrategy and other societal priorities. Section 4reviews the general findings on the use of economic instruments for carbon emission reductions, including an overview of what we

know about the macroeconomic impacts of fiscalpolicies for carbon emission reductions from otherstudies. Section 5 proposes a generic strategy forcoordinating mature, emerging and longer-termtechnologies in a deliberate framework for carbonemission reduction. Section 6 describes the generallessons learned (regarding methodologies, data,etc.) while assessing economic instruments.

• Part 2 summarizes the findings, macroeconomicimpacts, policy implications and recommendationsfrom each of the three case studies.

• The appendices contain executive summaries ofthe case studies.

An executive summary of this State of the Debatereport, as well as copies of the full case study reports,can be obtained from the NRTEE website at<www.nrtee-trnee.ca>.

PROJECT SCOPE

One part of our research was based on case studiesfocusing on different stages of technology develop-ment, and some of the recommendations focus onthe specific technologies studied. The following dis-cussion is intended to clarify the project boundariesand to highlight relevant issues outside its scope:

• The technologies examined are understood to be partof a broader mix of energy sources and demand sectors: While they hold potential to change theprofile of energy demand and supply (industrialenergy efficiency through reduced pressure for newsupply, emerging renewable power as a growingsource of primary energy, and hydrogen throughfar-reaching applications as a secondary energysource), the dominant sources of primary energyin the country will remain fossil fuels, nuclear andlarge hydro well into the foreseeable future.5

• These technologies are not the only low-carbon energysources available: Low-carbon energy sourcesalready account for almost 75 percent of Canadianelectrical generation. Over 90 percent of the electricity supply comes from hydroelectricity in British Columbia, Manitoba, Quebec, andNewfoundland and Labrador, while 31 percentcomes from nuclear in Ontario. Hydroelectricityand nuclear energy continue to be the foundationof a low-carbon energy mix. Other emerging

Page 19: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

5Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

low-carbon energy sources and technologies werealso outside the scope of this study: for example,off-grid renewable energy technologies such asground-source heat pumps, solar water heaters and passive solar, and transportation technologiessuch as hybrid vehicles.

• Some of the case studies’ findings are regionally spe-cific: The electrical generation mix and associatedcarbon emissions are regionally dependent inCanada. Accordingly, some of the case studies’findings—for example, that hydrogen pathwaysusing electrolyzer technology could lead to netincreases in greenhouse gas emissions—are specificto regions where the marginal source of generationhas a higher carbon content than the base load.These findings may not be relevant to other generation mixes.

• The recommendations in this report deal with only a few of the technologies, initiatives and measuresthat will be needed in a comprehensive climatechange action plan for Canada: The intention ofthe EFR and Energy Program is not to present acomprehensive climate change plan—the com-bined magnitude of direct and indirect reductionsfrom the proposed instruments in the three casestudies is 23 to 42 Mt by 2010 and 53 to 77 Mtby 2030; these reductions pale in comparison tothe forecast emissions gap of 238 Mt by 2010.6

Rather, the intention has been to bore down onthe design of specific elements of a potential package of measures.

Page 20: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions
Page 21: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

Part I: General Findings

and Recommendations

Page 22: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions
Page 23: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

1. BACKGROUND

1.1 PURPOSE OF THE REPORT

In 2000, the NRTEE launched a program of work toexplore the role that economic instruments can playin advancing sustainable development objectives. The initial phase of this program, the Ecological FiscalReform (EFR) Program, yielded some broad lessonsabout the application of economic instruments toeconomy–environment issues. Its findings were pub-lished in Toward a Canadian Agenda for EcologicalFiscal Reform: First Steps.

The results from the first phase convinced theNRTEE to continue the project and, in particular, toexplore the use of economic instruments in reducinggreenhouse gas emissions. Thus the second phase ofthe EFR Program—the EFR and Energy Program—was launched early in 2002 with a mandate to focuson the use of economic instruments in achievinglong-term reductions in energy-based carbon emissions.

This State of the Debate report synthesizes the majorconclusions of the EFR and Energy Program, draw-ing in particular from case study experience but alsoon the broader research and consultation conductedas part of the Program’s work. The report defines the major points of agreement and disagreement,explores questions surrounding the use of fiscal policy in the specific sectors addressed by the casestudies (industrial energy efficiency, emerging renew-able power and hydrogen fuel technologies), andexamines the broader context for the use of economicinstruments in encouraging reductions in energy-based carbon emissions (including some aspects ofthe linkages between greenhouse gas emission reduc-tions, energy policy and broad societal priorities).

1.2 ECOLOGICAL FISCAL REFORM

The NRTEE has defined EFR as “a strategy that redirects a government’s taxation and expenditure programs to create an integrated set of incentives to support the shift to sustainable development.”7

Unlike the ecological tax reform or tax-shiftingapproach being implemented in many jurisdictions,the NRTEE’s approach to fiscal reform embraces abroad suite of instruments in a reinforcing package.This package includes:

• redirection or introduction of new taxes or taxincentives;

• redirection or introduction of targeted direct expenditures, such as targeted government pro-gram expenditures, government procurement, cash subsidies and grants; and

• other economic instruments, such as tradable permits, permitting charges and user fees.

1.2.1 Broad Conclusions from Phase 1 of the EFR Program

Phase 1 of the NRTEE’s EFR Program reviewedinternational experience with EFR and undertookthree case studies to assess the applicability of EFRwithin the Canadian context.8

This research indicated that, in theory, there is a rolefor EFR in Canada and that EFR can be a uniquelyappropriate tool in implementing sustainable devel-opment. EFR is an integrative tool that is easier toadapt to the complexity of sustainable developmentobjectives than are other policy tools. It is moreamenable to a continuous improvement approachthan are exclusive command-and-control models, and it allows for more flexibility because parties candetermine their own response. Analysis for the casestudies revealed the vital importance of precisely targeted instruments and clearly defined policy objec-tives, as well as a thorough understanding of Canada’sunique regulatory, market and jurisdictional profiles.The effectiveness, impacts and experience with EFR measures in some limited existing applicationsshowed these to be promising approaches. However,conclusive evidence on the efficiency and effective-ness of EFR measures in Canada will require broaderapplied experience and the passage of sufficient timeto judge their performance.9

According to the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD):

Economic instruments have been playing anincreasing role in the environmental policies ofOECD countries over the last decade, includingenvironmentally related taxes. All OECD coun-tries have introduced environmentally relatedtaxes to some extent and an increasing number areimplementing comprehensive green tax reforms.Green tax reforms have been identified as a keyframework condition for sustainable developmentin the OECD report Sustainable Development:Critical Issues and as a powerful tool in imple-menting the OECD Environmental Strategy forthe First Decade of the 21st Century adopted byOECD environment ministers in May 2001.10

9Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

Page 24: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

10 National Round Table on the Environment and the Economy

Such successes have stimulated interest in the use ofmarket-based instruments in Canada, as evidenced by the emphasis on fiscal instruments in the 2002Climate Change Plan for Canada.11 Nonetheless,regardless of our understanding of the potential ofEFR instruments, as well as international experiencein their design, these instruments have not beenwidely adopted in Canada.

This deficiency was noted in the OECD’s 2004 review of Canada’s environmental performance, which concluded:

Despite [the introduction of a number of economic instruments for environmental policypurposes, mainly at the provincial level], limiteduse has been made of economic instruments forenvironmental management at any level of gov-ernment. A number of constraints affect greateruptake of economic instruments. Industry is concerned about day-to-day competitiveness pres-sures, especially in relation to cost competitivenesswith the US. It has difficulty understanding howto implement new instruments such as trading.Within governments, economic agencies have supported economic instruments in principle, butresisted specific proposals for targeted incentives onallocative efficiency grounds. The public is waryof new fees and charges, and of the allocation of“right to pollute”. There is a general resistance toexternal pressure to change consumption patterns.Small but influential groups have blocked someproposals….

Increasing the use of economic instruments is a matter of urgency in view of the need for afford-able solutions and appropriate cost sharing toreduce environmental degradation.12

One objective of the NRTEE’s EFR Program was todetermine why these instruments are not used more.

1.2.2 Long-term Benefits of EFRUnder regulatory approaches based on command andcontrol, compliance decisions are made by the regula-tor. With fiscal instruments, however, this decisionmaking shifts to the regulated community (i.e., firms or individuals). In theory, this shift providesincreased flexibility for the targeted community,enabling it to make compliance decisions that

minimize compliance costs and thus maximize prof-its. According to environmental economic theory, the ability of fiscal instruments to enable profit-maximizing behaviour gives them a major advantageover traditional command-and-control approaches.Fiscal instruments are also more attractive because, in theory, they reduce government implementationcosts, raise government revenues and reduce budgetaryoutlays, thus reducing the costs (both to governmentand industry) of meeting societal objectives.

Of course, not all fiscal instruments accomplish this.Many of the benefits of EFR will depend on the specific design of the fiscal instrument, and badlydesigned EFR instruments, like any other badlydesigned policy instrument, can be inefficient, ineffective and administratively costly.

Building on this logic, the Government of Canadaannounced in its Budget 2005 a new set of initiativestargeting carbon emission reductions. It also indi-cated that it intends to “actively consider otheropportunities to use the tax system to support environmental objectives, in areas where it would be an appropriate instrument.”13

1.2.3 Fiscal Instruments Within a Mix of Policy Instruments

The focus on fiscal instruments in this report does not imply the exclusion of other policy instruments.Rather, the intent is to drill down on one set of thepolicy reforms necessary to enable greater deploy-ment of carbon-reducing technologies. The intent isalso to explore and highlight the possible benefits ofEFR—over other policy tools—as a cost-effective,agile and integrative means of pursuing sustainabledevelopment objectives.

A recent review of alternatives for managing environ-mental problems compared approaches emphasizingeconomic instruments with those emphasizing command and control. The researchers noted thatalmost all of the 12 policies studied were a blend of economic incentives and command-and-controlinstruments, underlining the fact that the use of economic instruments does not imply the exclusionof other policy tools.14

Page 25: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

Promoting a long-term, coordinated strategy forlong-term, energy-based carbon emission reductionswill require coherent and cohesive policy reforms onmany fronts, as well as engagement from every levelof government. For example, factors such as pricing,market access, grid access, perceived investment risk,market demand, and social and regulatory acceptanceare just some of the barriers acting as cumulative filters to these theoretically feasible projects.15 This filtering process is illustrated in Figure 1. It is confirmed by this project’s finding that, while the technical resource potential for low-impact

renewable power in Canada has been estimated at 68,500–336,600 MW capacity and 244,700–1,210,400 GWh/yr supply, the actual installed base today is only 2,300 MW capacity and 12,100 GWh/yr supply.16

In this policy field, as in others, ecological fiscalreform is a necessary but far from sufficient instrument for meeting policy objectives.

11Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

Theoretical potentialof renewables

Filter of technicalfeasibility

Filter of financial feasibility

Filter of social and environmental acceptability

Filter of greennessrecognition

Filter of NIMBY or of“Nothing anywhere”

Largehydro

Smallhydro

Landfillgas, Waste

IncinerationCo-firing

BiomassWind Tidal Solar Energyefficiency

DSM

Figure 1: Barriers to Renewable Energy Development and Their Potential Impact on Project Implementation Rates

DSM= demand-side management

Note: This illustration is an evocation of a principle. It does not pretend to represent accurately the relative importance of theoptions, nor their rate of shrinking.

Source: Y. Guérard (Hydro-Québec), Presentation at the November 3–4, 2004, Green Power Workshop in Montreal.

Page 26: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions
Page 27: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

2. CONTEXT: THE NEWENERGY ECONOMY—CANADA’S OPPORTUNITY

2.1 GLOBAL ENERGY TRENDS

The International Energy Agency (IEA) concluded in2002 that:

[30-year energy projections] raise serious concernsabout the security of energy supplies, investment inenergy infrastructure, the threat of environmentaldamage caused by energy production and use andthe unequal access of the world’s population tomodern energy. …Governments will have to takestrenuous action in many areas of energy use andsupply if these concerns are to be met.17

Spurred by population growth, increasing standardsof living and spreading industrialization, the globalenergy market is projected to increase by two-thirdsover the next three decades, equal to an annualdemand growth of 1.7 percent. Meeting this demandwill require an unprecedented investment in world-wide energy supply infrastructure: US$16 trillion of investments in new energy supply capacity andreplacement are anticipated at the global level. Power generation, transmission and distribution will account for nearly US$10 trillion of this, including US$2 trillion for power generation inOECD countries.18

Renewable energy is expected to assume a growingrole in the world’s primary energy mix under bothbusiness-as-usual and alternative environmental scenarios. In the IEA’s reference (business as usual)scenario, non-hydro renewables will grow faster thanany other primary energy source, at an average rate of3.3 percent over the 2002–2030 projection period.This growth will take place largely within theOECD. Wind power and biomass will grow mostrapidly, again especially in OECD countries.19 TheEuropean Union has set itself a target of 22.1 percentof electricity consumption and 12.0 percent of grossnational energy consumption from renewable energysources by 2010.20 The United States aims to nearlydouble energy production from renewable sources(excluding hydro) between 2000 and 2025.21

Environmental policies could lead to a dramatic shift in the pattern of energy investment and reduceoverall energy needs. Scenarios based on policies cur-rently being debated in OECD countries forecastinvestment in renewables (including large-scalehydroelectricity) to increase from $480 billion to $720 billion over the 2000–2025 period—a shift from one-third of new investment in power generation to one-half.22

The IEA’s reference scenario forecasts that hydrogenfuel cells will phase in slowly between 2020 and2030—from 4 GW global generating capacity to 100 GW.23 The IEA notes that:

[t]he total investment required in order to achievea substantially hydrogen-powered transport systemwill depend both on the rate at which costs arereduced and the timing of the development of thissystem. …With optimal learning and cost reduc-tion, a mature fuel cell vehicle market could bereached at an incremental cost of several hundredbillion dollars, but if cost reductions are slow, theincremental costs of achieving a mature marketcould be around $5 trillion.24

A PricewaterhouseCoopers study on global demandfor fuel cell products projects this market to reach $46 billion per year by 2011 (stationary: $17.9 billion;portable: $17.6 billion; early phase transportation:$10.3 billion) and $2.6 trillion per year by 2021.25

Other forecasts echo these coming shifts. TheIntergovernmental Panel on Climate Change’s peer-reviewed “IS92a” scenario, a middle path thatassumes significant technological change under abusiness-as-usual (i.e., no climate policy) scenario,assumes that the reduced costs of carbon-free tech-nologies such as wind, solar, biomass, nuclear andhydropower, relative to fossil fuels, will lead to theirsupplying 75 percent of global electricity by the endof the century, up from one-third in 1995.26

2.2 CANADA’S OPPORTUNITY

Canada is a world leader in oil and gas, hydroelectricand nuclear energy production and technologies. Ourleadership in these energy sectors has been fosteredthrough a long history of deliberately using public policy to successfully partner and contribute to thedevelopment of new energy technologies and sources

13Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

Page 28: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

14 National Round Table on the Environment and the Economy

of supply. For example, Crown corporations havebeen instrumental in the development of Canada’shydroelectricity generation; nuclear technologies havebeen supported through Crown corporations, R&Dand export subsidies, and capped liability in the event of accidents; oil and natural gas developmentshave been supported through grants and other invest-ments in numerous megaprojects and the use ofroyalty structures and tax measures tailored to thedevelopment needs of this sector; and the recentdevelopment of northern Alberta’s oil sands is beingassisted by tax treatment designed for that industry’sspecific needs.

Should Canadian governments proactively pursue asimilar advantage in the carbon emission reductiontechnologies that are defining global energy trends? Acoherent Canadian energy strategy will be driven bymany factors, such as energy security, economic andindustrial development, employment, internationalcompetitiveness, environmental protection and sus-tainability. Mitigating climate change also will be oneof these factors, but will it be one that limits or onethat enables other objectives?

The charge for policy-makers is to design a path to a lower carbon emission future that responds to theecological urgency of climate change impacts and tothe challenge of mitigation, and that does so in a waythat limits disruption to other societal priorities.

Canada enjoys unique challenges, opportunities andconstraints in finding this path.

Our challenges, as a resource-based trading nation ofmodest economic and demographic size, come fromtwo sides. On one side is a changing internationalmarket, in which energy supply preferences are diversifying and shifting and in which greenhouse gasperformance is increasingly a factor in market access,investment decisions and assessments of corporaterisk. In this market, environmental sustainabilitydrives innovation and competitiveness. On the other side are competitiveness challenges posed by countries at different stages in their policies and level of economic development.

Fortunately, Canada has unique advantages in assem-bling this response. More than any other country, wecombine a rich and varied mix of energy sources withthe knowledge capital that can enable us to maintainour global leadership in the energy economy, even asit shifts and diversifies to mitigate climate change.Untapped wind, water, solar and biomass resources of world-class calibre abound alongside the hydrocar-bon, uranium, coal and large hydro resources thathave formed the basis to date of Canada’s energywealth. We are knowledge leaders in several of thenew technologies—small hydro, biomass, hydrogen,and carbon capture and sequestration—that are critical elements of a lower-carbon energy future.And the geographic diversity of our communitiesenables experimentation with technologies for urban and remote locations, cold and moderateweather conditions. In other words, we have all theresources necessary to adapt to the coming energyrevolution, provided we advance strategically andwith a clear vision.

In contrast with these unparalleled opportunities onthe energy resources front, on the policy front thereare real constraints. Canada’s confederation modelintroduces jurisdictional limits that establish substan-tive hurdles and that often require complex andsignificant efforts in the area of federal–provincialcoordination. Unilateral federal action is possible inmany areas (e.g., transport), but federal and provin-cial governments must work in concert for effectiveaction in others (e.g., power production and buildingstandards). Our dominant trading relationship with a nation that has not ratified the Kyoto Protocol,coupled with the scale of commodity-based trade,imposes inescapable international competitivenesschallenges that shape the choice and design of poli-cies available to mitigate greenhouse gas emissions.

These circumstances compel a “smart” response: atimely, no-regrets approach that pursues opportunitywhile enhancing economic achievement and thatemploys a set of dynamic and diverse means based on knowledge and innovation.

Page 29: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

3. CONTEXT: MAXIMIZINGOVERALL ADVANTAGES TO SOCIETY—LONG-TERMCARBON EMISSIONREDUCTIONS WITHIN AN INTEGRATED POLICYFRAMEWORK

History records a gradual decline in the carbon inten-sity of energy sources over the last century. Beginningwith the transition from wood to coal, and continu-ing with sequential shifts to oil and natural gas, eachof these technology stages has resulted in less carbonbeing released per unit of energy produced. The primary reason for the shift to each new fuel was the promise of better-quality energy. Society investedenormous research, capital and infrastructure to bringeach of these new energy sources to market.

Drivers for past shifts to new energy sources have been affordable energy, quality of energy, ease of use,reliability, regional security of supply, desire fordecentralized generation and other non-ecologicalfactors. Climate change considerations have not beena main driver for energy technology change and willnot be—unless consideration of long-term carbonemission reductions is given greater priority in energypolicy than it has up to this point.

But how much priority should we accord to long-term carbon emission reductions in energy policy?Some participants in the EFR and Energy Programargued that long-term carbon emission reductionsand other objectives are complementary to a point,but that eventually there will need to be trade-offs.These participants proposed long-term carbon emis-sion reductions as the priority of energy strategy. Yetanother perspective cautioned against making long-term carbon emission reductions even the primaryenvironmental objective in an energy strategy, notingthat other environmental aspects of sustainability,such as biodiversity and toxics prevention, also needto be upheld. And, finally, some participants felt that energy policy should be primarily interested inopportunities for economic development, with anyenvironmental objectives considered secondary.

Many in the EFR and Energy Program stressed thatsocietal priorities such as quality jobs, regional andcommunity development, productivity and energysecurity animate society more than carbon reduc-tions. These participants feared that the call for asingle-minded pursuit of long-term carbon emissionsreduction, in isolation from other public priorities,will fall by the wayside, as it currently has. However,if the benefits and opportunities arising from long-term, energy-based carbon emission reductions canbe shown to align comfortably with these societal priorities, there will be more champions for andbroader interest in the agenda.

Wherever they stood on the priority of carbon emis-sions in energy strategy, participants in the EFR andEnergy Program agreed that public investments in along-term carbon emissions reduction strategy wouldyield many additional benefits, including thosedescribed below.

3.1 CO-BENEFITS: NINE REASONS FOR ANINTEGRATED POLICY FRAMEWORK

3.1.1 Energy Security

3.1.1.1 Overcoming the Supply ShortageBy 2020, approximately 15 percent of Canada’s cur-rent electrical generation capacity will be more than 40 years old. Incremental generation requirements by2020 for both plant replacement and demand growthare expected to be 42,000 MW or 40 percent of thecurrent stock of approximately 105,000 MW.27

This statistic accents the enormity of one dimensionof the nation’s looming energy security challenge; italso underscores the importance of the decisions thatwill soon have to be made for a long-term carbonemission reduction strategy.

Deep shifts in energy policy are underway in mostprovinces, which will affect the context for decisionsregarding energy and long-term carbon emissionreductions at the national level. British Columbia,Alberta, Manitoba, Ontario, Quebec, New Brunswickand Nova Scotia face changes in how they handle elec-tricity generation and supply, and some provinces arelooking to private sector, independent producers toprovide much of their new supply. For example:

15Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

Page 30: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

16 National Round Table on the Environment and the Economy

• Ontario faces a supply shortage that could becomeserious as early as 2007 and worsen over thelonger term. Driving this shortage are a combina-tion of factors: growing population and economy,aging generating infrastructure and insufficientplanned new capacity. Furthermore, for health and environmental reasons, the government has committed to shutting down five coal-firedelectricity-generation plants (which produce one-third of Ontario’s power) by 2008. As much as $5 billion in new generating capacity is needed.Aggressive conservation measures and a growth inindependent generation, including from renewablesources, are recognized as vital components ofmeeting future demand.28

• Manitoba has been emphasizing its hydropower asa competitive advantage. The province is exploringnew hydroelectric power capacity and an east–westgrid to export this power to Ontario. Moreover, it has identified hydrogen development, using acarbon-efficient hydropower feedstock, as anattractive future energy option.29

• In New Brunswick, a transition to a deregulatedelectricity market is underway. Some retail competition will be allowed: large industrial andwholesale customers will be able to choose theirproviders, and decentralized facilities will be ableto re-sell the electricity they produce back into the grid. The provincial government has recentlyintroduced a renewable portfolio standard (RPS),and in the meantime New Brunswick Power hasset its own target of 100 MW from wind by2010.30

• In British Columbia, BC Hydro forecasts thatenergy demand will increase by 1.7 percent peryear over the next decade. This demand will be met by a combination of energy efficiency(demand-side management), generation efficiencyand independent power generation, including low-impact green power. There is a voluntarycommitment to meet at least 10 percent of newelectricity demand through green energy by 2010,and 16 projects representing 1,764 GWh wererecently commissioned. A new corporation, theBC Transmission Corporation, was created in2003 to provide transmission services that willenable independent generators to sell into thegrid. BC Hydro has also targeted hydrogen, inparticular the hydrogen-fuelled transportationmarket, as a future business opportunity.

Provincial renewable portfolio standards are alsobeing discussed in Alberta and Prince Edward Islandand have been announced in Ontario and NovaScotia. British Columbia, Ontario, Nova Scotia, NewBrunswick and Prince Edward Island are consideringthe introduction of net metering. Several provinceshave also announced targets for renewable energyprocurement.31 Several provincial Crown utilitieshave also committed to targets for emerging renew-able energy technologies; for example, while Quebec’sgeneration profile is already composed of 93 percenthydro, Hydro-Québec has committed to buying1,000 MW of new wind-power capacity from independent producers by 2013.

3.1.1.2 Improving Security of SupplyThe September 11 terrorist attacks, combined withthe rolling California brownouts in the winter andspring of 2001 and the August 2003 eastern NorthAmerica blackout, have renewed public interest inthe security of energy supplies.

More diverse sources of fuels, a more responsive supply mix (including renewable energy sources) and greater energy efficiency are key ingredients of a more robust energy model:

• Hydrogen fuels can be a carrier for low-carbon primary energy sources, creating the potential toreplace the fossil fuels being used in transportation.

• Distributed generation, for which hydrogen andmany renewable energy technologies are wellsuited, increases the resilience of a system other-wise characterized by large centralized powerplants, pipelines and long transmission distances—all of which contribute to the system’svulnerability.

• Energy efficiency can also contribute to grid sta-bility through reduced loading of transmissionsystems.

• Conservation and efficiency programs can reducepressure on supply more quickly than can the construction of new facilities. The lead times formany low-impact renewable power sources areshorter than those for many traditional sources ofsupply. The McBride Lake Wind Farm in southernAlberta, for instance, was brought on-line in undera year. Large hydro projects may take 10 or moreyears to complete, due in part to federal andprovincial regulatory processes.32

Page 31: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

3.1.1.3 Improving Price StabilityStability of energy pricing has also become a priorityfollowing recent experience with rising crude oilprices and significant price volatility in the naturalgas and deregulated electricity markets. There is someconcern that the increased demand for natural gas (in part due to environmental reasons) will lead tocontinuing price volatility and that the increasedpresence of gas-fired electricity generation has led toa closer correspondence between gas and electricityprices.33 Integrating emerging renewable powersources into the supply mix can offer a buffer againstprice volatility: these sources have higher upfrontcosts but generally more stable operating costs.Improved stewardship of existing sources of supply,through increased energy efficiency, reduces overalldemand, making energy more affordable for allCanadians.

New energy sources and technologies for distributedgeneration are particularly attractive for remote communities that are currently subject to high energy prices.

3.1.2 Clean Air and Improved Quality of Life The largest sources of human-created air pollutionare energy generation, transportation and energy-intensive industries. Emissions from these sourcescontribute to increases in the concentration of particulates, smog-forming gases and acid rain pre-cursors, all factors that lead to respiratory problemsand impaired lung function as well as other healthissues. Smog alerts have become a familiar summeroccurrence in Canadian urban centres. Energy effi-ciency programs that reduce the quantity of fossilfuels burned, zero-emission renewable energy sourcesand hydrogen technologies with zero emissions at thepoint of combustion can all reduce emissions of smogprecursors in Canadian urban centres and improvethe quality of life.

3.1.3 Reduced Health Care Costs Air pollution causes respiratory ailments, exacerbatescardiovascular disease and contributes to higher mortality rates from a number of conditions. Theassociated hospital admissions, emergency room visits, doctor visits and medication costs impose alarge cost on the health care system—$600 million in2000 in Ontario alone, according to research by theOntario Medical Association.34 These costs could belowered by reducing smog.

3.1.4 Industrial and Manufacturing Capacity in New Environmental Technologies

The domestic economic benefits of large investmentsin long-term carbon emission reductions would beamplified if Canada were able to supply the requisitetechnology and expertise.

At present, however, many of the energy technologiesrequired for carbon mitigation would need to beimported. Analysis conducted by Industry Canadafor the AMG Working Group in 200235 concludedthat, given present Canadian manufacturing capaci-ties, one-third or more ($25 billion of $75 billion) of the machinery and equipment required to satisfyCanada’s Kyoto targets would need to be imported.36

The same study noted that under normal circum-stances, foreign countries provide 60 to 70 percent of Canada’s machinery and equipment requirements.The level of imports required to satisfy Canada’sKyoto targets could be as high as 95 percent if thetimeline for investment were too short for Canadianmanufacturers or if the demand were perceived to bea one-time opportunity, with declining requirementsonce the Kyoto target was achieved.

Canada already has well-developed knowledge andmanufacturing clusters in some emission reductiontechnologies such as hydro turbines and biomass andan emerging industrial cluster for fuel cells. Othervital technologies are not supported by strong manufacturing capacity in Canada. These includetechnologies such as wind turbines, solar panels,geothermal heat pumps and micro-turbines for landfill gas recovery. More aggressive Canadian com-mitments to specific technologies, such as a sizablerenewable power portfolio standard, would stimulateEuropean companies to locate manufacturing plantsin Canada—and possibly even to use this country astheir entry point into the North American market.This would create an entire ripple effect of benefitsthrough the supply chain. In Germany, for example,the wind industry now stands second only to automanufacturing as a consumer of steel. The benefitswould apply both to sectors where Canada is consid-ered a “technology taker” (such as wind turbines) and sectors where it is a “technology maker” (such as proton exchange membrane fuel cells).

17Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

Page 32: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

18 National Round Table on the Environment and the Economy

Industry participants in the EFR and EnergyProgram confirmed that manufacturing facilities for some technologies and equipment now suppliedby other countries would locate in Canada if thedomestic market passed certain demand thresholds.Leading wind industry manufacturers, for example, areactively developing North American manufacturingstrategies to take advantage of the positive long-termmarket outlook, U.S. production tax credits, emerg-ing renewable portfolio standards, competitive labour costs (25 percent lower in Canada than in Europe) and the elimination of import duties.North American production would also mitigateagainst currency risks, the high costs of shippinglarge machines (5 to 10 percent of project costs) and customer preferences for North American goods.According to the Canadian Wind Energy Association,“manufacturers regard North America as a singlemarket from a manufacturing strategy point of view.Any plants located in Canada will have significantexport potential to the U.S….”37 Locating in theUnited States would obviously yield similar benefits.

A deliberate emphasis on promoting domestic manu-facturing capacity in these emerging industrial sectorswould permit Canada to expand its share of thebooming global markets for energy management andrenewable energy technologies. It would also keep theeconomic benefits of substantial expenditures onmachinery and equipment within Canada.

3.1.5 Targeting Growing Export Markets andDeveloping Country Needs

Nearly 70 percent of the increase in world primaryenergy demand between 2001 and 2030 will be inthe developing and transition economies; half of total global energy investments during this period,US$7.9 trillion, will be directed to developing coun-tries.38 At the global level, renewable energy, andwind and biomass in particular, are projected to growfaster than any other primary energy sources, at anaverage rate of 3.3 percent a year even under busi-ness-as-usual scenarios. Environmental scenarioswould increase the investment in renewables by 50 percent to $720 billion, forming half of all investment in new power generation.

The primary energy sources and energy use efficien-cies that are used to meet this ballooning demandwill determine the ecological future of the planet, aswell as environmental and health effects at regionaland local scales. Thus a Canadian focus on assistingthe commercialization of cleaner, reduced-carbontechnologies could also benefit developing countries.

Moreover, it would be in line with the stated federalobjective of developing “a strategy specifically focusedon learning technologies, life sciences and the envi-ronment to help those in developing countries tobenefit from Canadian expertise” and the long-termplan of providing “at least 5 per cent of researchinvestment to those who are developing new ways of dealing with international problems.”39

3.1.6 Commercializing and LeveragingGovernment-funded Research

Government fiscal involvement in the developmentof new energy technologies has historically focusedmainly on the idea generation and conceptual stagesof product development. The recent establishment of the Sustainable Development Technology Fundaims to address the gap in funding at the demonstra-tion and pre-commercialization stages, just prior to venture capital investment. These stages are often characterized as the “valley of death” for new technologies.

Many experts believe that despite these efforts, thereremains a backlog of market-ready carbon mitigationtechnologies. This “innovation backlog” is cited asevidence of the need for ecological fiscal reform atnew stages of the innovation chain, to reduce finan-cial risks to investors and to create the market pullneeded to get new technologies off the shelf.40

The tax treatment of certain renewable energies (e.g., through accelerated capital cost allowances or theethanol excise tax exemption) helps support the marketentry of these technologies from the demand side.

Others also note that different technologies have different pathways to the market and that their specific context must be taken into account whendesigning fiscal instruments to encourage their adoption. Such a context might be the lack of adomestic manufacturing capacity for a low-carbonenergy technology, which would put Canada in therole of technology taker. Representatives of the windindustry, for example, argued that Canadian R&Dinvestment in wind would have little impact on costcurves since these technologies are largely manufac-tured elsewhere. The EFR focus for this technology,therefore, should be on instruments to expanddemand. A related point was made regarding break-through technologies and/or step changes in theenergy efficiency of industrial processes: these willlikely be determined in the international marketplaceand are unlikely to be stimulated by Canada in isola-tion. This consideration must inform the choice offiscal instrument for these technologies.

Page 33: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

3.1.7 New Jobs and Regional Development Other countries are achieving worthwhile employ-ment benefits from the R&D, manufacturing andservicing of carbon emission reduction technologies.In Germany, for example, 45,000 jobs have been cre-ated in the wind industry alone; the United Kingdomexpects that 20,000 jobs will be created through thedevelopment of 6,000 MW from offshore wind,much of this in rural and remote areas.41

The macroeconomic study commissioned for theEFR and Energy Program was not able to quantifyemployment impacts from the policies proposed inthe case studies, other than to conclude that theaggregate macroeconomic impacts of the proposedinstruments are insignificant from a national perspective.

Other Canadian data on employment potential fromthe three technologies studied is limited. A recentassessment of employment potential from Canadiandevelopment of low-impact, renewable electricitysources, commissioned by the Clean Air RenewableEnergy Coalition, concluded that:

Low-impact, renewable electricity sources currentlyemploy an average of six people per 10 MW ofcapacity. If the federal government were to encour-age the development of these energy sources with a 1¢ per kilowatt-hour incentive paid to power producers, they would leverage significant job creation.

The Clean Air Renewable Electricity Coalitionhas proposed that there is the potential in Canadato develop approximately 31,875 MW of low-impact renewable electricity between 2004 and 2020. Depending on the assumptions used, building and operating this capacity would createbetween 12,700 and 26,900 jobs by 2015, andwould sustain these jobs through to 2020.42

Ninety-nine percent of these jobs would be approxi-mately evenly distributed between onshore wind,run-of-river hydro and biomass facilities. Over time,the job mix would steadily shift away from manufac-turing and development and toward operations andmanagement. By 2020, 54 percent of jobs would bededicated to keeping existing facilities operational.The employment created from low-impact renewableelectricity would be comparable to or greater thanthat created by an equivalent capacity of fossil fuel–based generation.43

Renewable energy sources offer employment potentialin rural and remote locations, including First Nationcommunities, and energy efficiency–related jobs aredistributed across all regions of the country. OECDresearch confirms that conventional energy supplysectors tend to create employment at centralized sitesor regions or in banking, trade and other servicesclustered in densely populated regions. In contrast,energy efficiency investments are more often servicedby small and medium-sized enterprises, and tend tostimulate employment that is more geographicallyand sectorally dispersed, at least for a while.Therefore, the regional distribution of net employ-ment from these types of investments is moreequitable, a co-benefit for underdeveloped regions or regions with high unemployment.44

3.1.8 Innovation and Development of Value-addedand Intellectual Property–IntensiveSecondary Industries

Emerging, low-carbon energy technologies are a natural element of the innovation agenda. This wasrecognized at the National Summit on Innovationand Learning in November 2002, where specific discussions on environment, clean energy and eco-efficiency identified several strong connections.45

Canadian leadership in new, knowledge-based industries—such as hydrogen fuel cells or carbonsequestration—can supplement commodity-basedenergy sector exports to diversify our economy.

3.1.9 Maintaining Canadian Competitiveness International markets are changing. While demandfor conventional energy commodities and technolo-gies will persist and grow, markets are increasinglyinterested in the environmental impact of produc-tion, favouring new, environmentally consciousofferings that can meet the same needs. A long-termcarbon mitigation strategy is a pre-emptive responseon two fronts: to ensure the continued acceptance ofconventional Canadian commodities—heavy crudefrom oil sands, electrical power and minerals—intointernational markets; and to position Canada to participate in new growth sectors such as the produc-tion of hydrogen-fuelled vehicles. Improved energyefficiency in the industrial sector will also enhancethe productivity of Canadian firms.

19Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

Page 34: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

20 National Round Table on the Environment and the Economy

3.2 WHY LONG-TERM CARBON EMISSIONREDUCTIONS CANNOT BE AN IMPLIED OR SECONDARY OBJECTIVE

Opinions differ on where long-term carbon emissionreductions should rank in energy strategy. What isclear, though, is that we cannot simply assume thatsuch reductions will come about as an implied or secondary effect of other policies. This point is significant because the present policy debate oftentends to assume an inherent substitutability betweensustainable energy initiatives—such as energy effi-ciency, renewable energy deployment, developmentof hydrogen technologies and carbon mitigation—and this assumption may not always hold true.Findings from our case studies, which form the basis for this report, reveal that:

• attempts to improve industrial energy efficiencycan sometimes increase the greenhouse gas inten-sity of production. For instance, a coal-fired boileris more efficient than a wood-fired or even a natu-ral gas–fired boiler (depending on coal quality).Increasing energy efficiency by using a coal boilerinstead of the other options would result in highercarbon emissions. (In corollary, focusing on indus-trial carbon efficiency alone could result in the useof methods such as sequestration that wouldincrease energy consumption);

• an exclusive emphasis on maximizing the outputof emerging renewable power technologies wouldneglect the two other factors determining the carbon intensity of the electricity market: the carbon intensity of fossil fuel generation and total electricity demand; and

• the carbon intensity of hydrogen fuels depends ontheir primary energy source. Hydrogen productiontechnologies that use electricity as a fuel source,such as electrolyzers, can increase greenhouse gas emissions if the marginal electricity used to produce the hydrogen comes from a higher carbon source (e.g., natural gas) than the baseload. Therefore, an undiscriminating “diversity”approach to primary energy sources and produc-tion technologies for hydrogen fuels could lead to some pathways that increase greenhouse gasemissions. Carbon capture and sequestration tech-nologies, which are currently under development,may offer a companion technology to address this issue, but the introduction of this mitigationtechnology would come at a significant cost to the energy balance of hydrogen fuels.

Thus a major lesson arising from our case studies isthat the pursuit of other objectives of a sustainableenergy strategy, without a specific long-term carbonemission reduction objective, may lead to perverseemission impacts.

Page 35: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

4. ECONOMIC INSTRUMENTSFOR LONG-TERM CARBONEMISSION REDUCTIONSAND TECHNOLOGY DEVELOPMENT

4.1 ECONOMIC INSTRUMENTS AND CANADA’S CLIMATE CHANGE PLAN

Climate policy in this country has largely beenimplemented through voluntary programs and expenditure instruments. But experience is revealingthe weakness of this approach: voluntary methodswill not achieve Canada’s Kyoto targets, and the per-tonne reduction expenditures are proving costlysince subsidies go to actors who would have reducedemissions without a subsidy as well as to those whoneeded the incentive.

This reality underscores a perplexing question: if eco-nomic instruments are apparently so effective andefficient, why do they not have a larger presence inCanada’s national climate change strategy? And, in an environment of tight fiscal space, can we affordnot to adopt those measures that hold the greatestpromise for achieving carbon reductions?

4.1.1 A Piecemeal PlanThe November 2002 Climate Change Plan forCanada (CCPC) contains a plethora of small initia-tives—over 90 federal and provincial programs to date.These have spread both the burden and the benefitsacross regions and sectors, but they have also led topiecemeal results and high administrative costs.46

If Canada continues to follow this piecemeal modelrather than a plan composed of fewer, more rigorousand innovative elements, it risks falling far behind inthe climate race; it will be a policy and technologytaker in the sustainable energy field, with attendantcompetitiveness concerns.

4.1.2 A Largely Voluntary EmphasisThe CCPC is heavily weighted to information, sua-sion and voluntary action approaches.47 The mainexception to Canada’s largely voluntary approach is the domestic emissions trading system being established for large final emitters (LFEs); there iswidespread confidence that real emission reductionswill be achieved under this program. There are also

some targeted subsidy programs, but other sources of emissions are still primarily addressed through voluntary means.

Evaluations of the environmental effectiveness of voluntary initiatives have been inconclusive.Surprisingly, the economic efficiency of such initia-tives has also been found to be generally low,48 due to administrative costs and to the high proportion ofactors who choose not to take action. Both of thesefactors can to some extent be addressed through rigorous criteria for use and robust design.49

Possible reasons for the ongoing reliance on voluntaryand suasive approaches are set out below:

• The knowledge and information infrastructure formanaging and monitoring economic instrumentsand other regulatory systems is large and complex,requiring a long lead time to design and establish it.

• The CCPC’s goal is “to reduce greenhouse gasemissions in the most cost-effective way possible.”This creates a preference for policy instrumentsthat place a priority on achieving low cost or leastcost at the firm level. Voluntary programs andexpenditure instruments do this best. The CCPC’sgoal reflects competitiveness priorities, which havedominated effectiveness considerations.

• The concern with competitiveness has also madepolicy-makers reluctant to use instruments thatput a price on emissions (whether through a tax or a tradable emissions permit system); there is afeeling that this would hurt the competitiveness ofCanadian industry, particularly in the absence ofany equivalent price signal in the U.S. market.The scale and extent of this effect, however, is not known.

• Another key factor in the design of policy instru-ments has been concern to manage federal–provincialrelations in an area of contested jurisdiction. Federalleadership on voluntary initiatives and federal will-ingness to subsidize expenditure instruments face less provincial resistance than regulatory measures(including various types of emission charges andmarket-based regulations).

This is not to say that there is no role for voluntaryinitiatives in managing an environmental issue. Butvoluntary initiatives are best undertaken at an early,learning stage in the management of the issue. Wehave moved beyond this stage in managing green-house gas emissions.

21Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

Page 36: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

4.1.3 Project GreenProject Green is a set of policies and programs from the federal government, aimed at supporting a sustainable environment and a more competitiveeconomy. Project Green’s groundwork was establishedby the October 2004 Speech from the Throne andBudget 2005. Launched on April 13, 2005, MovingForward on Climate Change: A Plan for Honouringour Kyoto Commitment, is Project Green’s first instalment.

4.2 MACROECONOMIC IMPACTS OF FISCALPOLICY TO PROMOTE LONG-TERM CARBON EMISSION REDUCTIONS

This following discussion presents a qualitative reviewof findings from other studies that have attempted to quantify the macroeconomic impacts of climatechange and energy policies, with an emphasis oninsights related to targeted policies. The review is lim-ited mostly to studies in developed countries and, inparticular, to studies related to the Canadian contextsuch as those conducted from 1998 to 2003 by theAnalysis and Modelling Group (AMG) of Canada’sNational Climate Change Process (NCCP).50

4.2.1 What Are Macroeconomic Impacts?Macroeconomic impacts are the economy-wide effectsof a policy (i.e., the direct and indirect changes inprices and output throughout the economy), created bythe backward and forward linkages among sectors andmarkets. Allowing for these dynamic and economy-wide effects can increase or decrease the overall costs(and benefits) of climate and energy policies.

One of the most comprehensive and common meas-ures of the macroeconomic impact of policy is thepercentage change in real gross domestic product(GDP) relative to a reference case or business-as-usual (BAU) case without the policy. However, GDPhas some disadvantages as an indicator of long-termeffects and overall societal well-being:

• the measure does not include changes in non-marketed goods and services such as the quality of goods, environmental amenities and leisure;

• changes in real GDP can also mask distributionaleffects (i.e., differences in the incidence of costsand benefits) among different sectors, regions,firms and individuals; and

• long-term impacts on GDP are difficult to predictand are sensitive to many different and controver-sial assumptions, such as the rate of technologicalchange with and without the policy.

For these reasons, many impact studies report effects onboth short- and long-term GDP growth, together withdistributional consequences and effects on specificdeterminants of long-term growth or structural change,such as the rate of technological change (innovation)and competitiveness. Some studies also consider othernon-market costs and benefits such as the effects ofenergy or carbon policies on local air quality.

4.2.2 Evaluating Macroeconomic Impacts: It’s Not So Simple

The macroeconomic impacts of energy and green-house gas policies are very uncertain. Impact studiesconducted after a policy has been implemented arecomplicated by the difficulty of unravelling theeffects of the specific policy from changes caused by a multitude of other factors that affect the overalleconomy. Estimating macroeconomic impact prior to the implementation of a policy requires complexmodels and numerous assumptions.

Numerous competing models exist for assessingmacroeconomic impact, and different models yielddifferent results depending upon model structure andinput assumptions. Even using the same model, themagnitude and duration of macroeconomic impactassociated with the same mix of policies can also varyacross economies and over time, due to differences in various factors that include initial resource endowments, economic structure, and labour and capital markets.

Regardless of the model or modelling approach, precise quantitative assessments of macroeconomicimpact are often resource- and time-intensive.Furthermore, many models of macroeconomicimpacts are too aggregated to capture the impact ofsmaller, more targeted policies (i.e., policy instru-ments directed at specific sectors and technologies),and they do not necessarily provide an adequate“story” of the macroeconomic impact or long-rundynamics for decision makers. In practice, the designand analysis of targeted policies can benefit from the use of more qualitative approaches such as simple screening techniques and rules of thumb for predicting possible macroeconomic impact.

22 National Round Table on the Environment and the Economy

Page 37: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

The recently released Project Greenprovides the following informationon the Large Final Emitters (LFE)system:The purpose of the LFE system is to secure emis-sion reductions from Canada’s largest emitters inthe mining and manufacturing, oil and gas, andthermal electricity sectors. These sectors are largecontributors to Canada’s GHG emissions — justunder 50 percent of the total. The LFE system willcover about 700 companies operating in Canada;80–90 of these companies account for approxi-mately 85 percent of the LFE GHG emissions.

The system that is being introduced respects all previous commitments that have been madeconcerning the LFE system, including that thecost of compliance to industry will not be morethan $15 per tonne of carbon dioxide equivalent.Appropriate mechanisms will be implemented toachieve that price cap commitment.

The overall target established for the LFEs is for 45 Mt of annual reduction during the2008–2012 Kyoto commitment period. The 45 Mt target is based on a BAU baseline towhich methodological improvements have beenmade to the electricity component.

LFE companies will have a number of options for compliance:

• Investment in in-house reductions. This is likely to be the first priority of LFE compa-nies, since it allows them to invest in theirown facilities and profit from increased pro-ductivity and reduced waste associated withsuch investments in emission reductions andmodernization.

• The purchase of emission reductions fromother LFE companies that have done betterthan their target.

• Investment in domestic offset credits (creditsattesting that a real emission reduction orcarbon sequestration has been generated out-side the LFE system — these credits may bepurchased by LFE companies and used forcompliance with their obligations).

• The purchase of international credits providedthat these represent verified emission reductions — i.e., only “green” internationalcredits will be recognized for Canadian compli-ance purposes. Investment in internationalcredits may be linked to sales of Canadiantechnology and provides LFEs with experiencein an international trading market that islikely to be of increased importance over time.

In addition to these options, LFEs would be ableto invest in technology developments and countthose investments for purposes of compliance.Legislation has been introduced in the House of Commons to establish a Greenhouse GasTechnology Investment Fund. The Fund wouldsupport the development and deployment ofinnovative domestic technologies that canreduce GHG emissions. For the most part, investments in the Fund would not generateemission reductions until after the Kyoto periodof 2008–2012. However, it is important to provide this additional compliance option to LFE companies so as to promote investment inCanadian technology and facilitate Canada’slong-term transformational change.

23Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

Page 38: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

24 National Round Table on the Environment and the Economy

4.2.3 What Do Recent Studies Suggest About the Macroeconomic Impacts of Carbon Fiscal Policies?

There are hundreds of estimates of the costs and benefits of environmental protection in the literature.In recent years, considerable analysis has beendirected toward the costs (and in some cases benefits)of meeting emission reduction targets under theKyoto Protocol. Many of these analyses considerprice or quantity instruments (i.e., taxes or tradablepermits) applied on an economy-wide basis toencourage the least-cost mix of investments that will achieve the desired target. A few examine moretargeted sector- or technology-specific instruments.In all cases, the macroeconomic impact of fiscalinstruments related to greenhouse gases and energy is still very uncertain and controversial.

In 2000, the NCCP’s Analysis and Modelling Groupconducted a macroeconomic analysis of the nationaland provincial effects of greenhouse gas reductionoptions. That analysis showed that, depending uponassumptions about microeconomic costs and interna-tional actions, meeting the Kyoto targets reduces real GDP by 0 to 3 percent by 2010 (equivalent to aone-year recession), if all necessary policies are imple-mented by 2000. Although there is a small increasein activity in the short term as a result of increasedcapital spending, GDP declines after a few years as aresult of the higher production costs, lower produc-tivity, trade effects and reduced disposable incomes.Provincial impacts are generally within 1.5 percent ofthe national average. However, the relative impactson each province vary depending on the reductionpath. If Canada acts alone, Saskatchewan andOntario are the most negatively affected. With international action, Alberta, Saskatchewan and New Brunswick are the most negatively affected.

The AMG’s analysis also showed that, if Canada acts alone, the marginal costs of all measures to meetthe Kyoto target range from $40 to $120/tonne in2010. If passed through to energy prices, these costsraise gasoline prices by 13 to 35 percent, natural gasprices (for residential use) by 30 to 75 percent andcoal prices by 300 to 800 percent. The impact onelectricity prices varies greatly across regions depend-ing on the dominant sources of supply and thepricing regime. Assuming average cost pricing, priceincreases vary from a low of 2 percent in Quebec toalmost 84 percent in Alberta.51

In general, the aggregate macroeconomic costs of thevarious instruments proposed in the NRTEE’s casestudies are likely much smaller than the estimates produced by the AMG. The reasons are threefold:

• For the most part, the marginal costs of emissionreductions in the case studies are lower than thoseassumed by the AMG to meet the Kyoto targets.

• Total emission reductions by 2010, even withoutadjusting for possible double-counting among thecase studies (e.g., both the renewables and energyefficiency case studies include reductions in theelectricity sector), are 3 to 10 times lower in the case studies than those assumed by the AMG.

• Even in the case of instruments such as emissionprices, the estimated impact on energy and otherproduct prices is smaller than that estimated by theAMG, suggesting more limited demand feedbacks.

The AMG analysis strongly supports the view thatcosts can be lowered by moving from sector-specifictargets to economy-wide targets. This effect allowsmarginal costs to converge across sectors. Sector-specific emission targets are also shown not to distribute the burden any more evenly across thecountry. As well, the analysis suggests that the designof instruments such as permit trading can greatlyaffect the distribution effects.

Studies in other countries have produced results withsimilar ranges of impact. However, there is no strictcorrelation between the carbon price necessary toreach a certain emission target and the GDP lossfaced by a country. For example, higher carbon taxesare required in Japan than in the United States, butGDP impact is lower in Japan than in the UnitedStates. This result is explained in part by pre-existingdifferences in energy supply, economic structure andthe tax system. For example, if a country relies moreon renewable energy and specializes in low-energy-intensive industry, a higher carbon price may berequired to achieve a given target but the aggregateimpact on output will be lower. However, in thesecases, the burden of emission reductions likely alsofalls only on a few sectors. The macroeconomicimpact can sometimes be positive for individualcountries in an international implementation frame-work. In addition, the impact is often non-linear;that is, the impact on GDP may increase more or less rapidly than the increase in carbon prices or permit values.

Page 39: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

4.3 GENERAL FINDINGS: USING ECONOMICINSTRUMENTS FOR LONG-TERM CARBON EMISSION REDUCTIONS AND TECHNOLOGY DEVELOPMENT

Economic instruments (including charges, tradablepermits, tax measures and government expenditure)are a favoured policy tool for driving emission reduc-tions because of the broad-based and diversifiednature of greenhouse gas emission sources.

There is also an important place for other tools, such as regulations, disclosure requirements and educational programs, but these were outside theboundaries of the EFR and Energy Program. Theefficiency and effectiveness of economic instrumentsshould always be tested against regulatory and strin-gent voluntary alternatives. Many experts believe thatregulatory approaches are more efficient and effectivefor low-intensity, “non-industrial” applications.Examples include building codes, appliance standardsand auto-efficiency standards. In addition, economicinstruments often need to be complemented by otherpolicy measures in order to be effective. For instance,access to transmission grids is essential for renewableenergy deployment.

4.3.1 Introduction to Economic InstrumentsEconomic instruments can be grouped into threebroad categories according to their effect on govern-ment finances:

1Revenue-raising instruments such as taxes and auc-tioned permits that increase the relative cost ofemission-intensive technologies and products.These instruments create a continuous incentivefor innovation to improve emission efficiency orto shift to lower-emission substitutes, as well asproviding revenues to the government.

2Budget-neutral instruments that increase the rela-tive cost of emission- and/or energy-intensivetechnologies and products but do not raise revenues for government. This category includes market-based regulation, which requires firms tomeet certain standards but allows them to trade with other parties in meeting this commitment.Budget-neutral instruments can focus on technol-ogy (e.g., a renewable portfolio standard orCalifornia’s Vehicle Emission Standard) or on performance (e.g., an LFE domestic emissionstrading program, discussed above).

3Expenditure instruments such as subsidies andother incentives that reduce the relative cost oftechnologies and products with lower emissionand/or energy intensity, making them more com-petitive with incumbent technologies. They maytarget current decisions (e.g., through accelerateddepreciation for tax purposes or mail-in rebateprograms) or long-term cost competitivenessthrough funding for research, development andcommercialization of new technologies. Financingthese subsidies requires governments to eitherincrease other taxes or reduce other expenditures.

Another perspective on economic instruments groupsthem according to the scope of application: are theybroad-based, sending signals across the economy and letting the market determine the nature of theresponse? Or are they targeted to a specific sector,technology or action? This perspective will be further discussed below.

Regardless of the economic instrument, a few generalprinciples apply to their design:

• The costs of fiscal policies are generally lower when they are expected, gradual, continuous andwell designed.

• All things being equal, broad instruments that provide more flexibility with respect to the formof response are generally less costly than more targeted or prescriptive instruments for achievingthe same reductions.

• Instruments that encourage firms and households to invest in more efficient equipment andprocesses (when they need to replace existingequipment or when they are considering newequipment purchases) are less costly than instruments that require them to accelerate capital replacement.

• Instruments that avoid transferring wealthbetween parties and/or regions are more likely to receive public support (e.g., in the absence oftargeted revenue recycling or transition measures,a carbon charge would transfer wealth from fossilfuel–intensive regions to those with hydroelectricresources).

The type and magnitude of the economic impact will vary across instruments even though the environ-mental outcome may be the same. As well, there

25Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

Page 40: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

26 National Round Table on the Environment and the Economy

are many opportunities to mitigate impacts and to improve effectiveness in the detailed design of specific instruments. Often there will be some trade-off between minimizing aggregate costs and otherobjectives such as minimizing distributional impact.

In developing packages of instruments, it is impor-tant to consider the interactions among policies andthe resulting impacts of these interactions on desired outcomes. Another key consideration in designing policy packages is staging—both to reduce costs byallowing adaptations to follow the natural rate ofturnover in long-lived capital stocks and to tailor the fiscal instrument to the development stage of the technology (see Section 5).

4.3.2 Application of Broad MeasuresAdvocacy for and against the use of broad-based pricesignals (emissions charges such as taxes and broad-based tradable permits) to achieve environmentalobjectives is an old (some would say tired) debate. In Canada, the debate is characterized by entrenchedpositions and little interest on the part of politicians.And yet experience from other jurisdictions offersmany examples of innovative ways to implement environmental charges—how to design these price signals to ensure effectiveness (the extent to whichthe measure will deliver its ecological objective),ensure efficiency (the extent to which the ecologicalobjective will be reached with the lowest marginaleconomic costs), and minimize concerns about competitiveness (at firm, industry and/or sector andnational levels) and distributional equity (the effectsof the measures across sectors, regions, individualsand generations).52

In assessing the effects of broad-based measures, it is essential to compare policy instruments that haveequivalent environmental outcomes. In this context,the key advantages of emissions charges emerge asgreater efficiency in the allocation of abatement costs and the creation of incentives for continuousimprovement. The primary appeal of broad-basedmeasures is that they are neutral to technologychoice, leaving the choice of response to the subjectparties. Because these instruments are performance-based, they avoid the risks associated with pickingwinners and, instead, enable winners to emergethrough continuous improvement and innovation.Improvement and innovation occur because it isalways in a party’s interest to lower its marginal costof abatement. However, the precise response to aprice signal cannot be predicted; hence, emissionscharges do not guarantee the achievement of a specific emission reduction target.

These instruments have the greatest impact on market prices. They can often affect energy-intensivesectors or regions more than others, and they tend tohave disproportionate effects on low-income house-holds. However, the cost and distributional impactcan be greatly reduced through revenue recyclingpolicies. For example, costs can be reduced by lower-ing or eliminating other taxes that dampen economicactivity. Alternatively, more focused revenue recyclingpolicies can be used to mitigate impact on specificincome groups, sectors or regions of the economy.Recycling mechanisms must be designed carefully to balance multiple objectives, such as protecting historical investments while providing incentives fornew investment and encouraging desirable long-termtechnological changes. Recycling mechanisms forindustry must also be designed carefully to minimizeany possible windfalls as a result of the policy.

The impact of these instruments on the competitive-ness of individual industries depends upon both their energy intensity and their trade intensity.Competitiveness is a complex concept that dependson numerous other interacting price and non-pricefactors such as overall tax rates, wages, productivitylevels, resource availability, proximity to markets,innovative activity and exchange rates. The incremen-tal effects of many existing energy and environmentalpolicies are small in comparison to other factors.However, greenhouse gas reduction policies couldhave a more significant impact if large and rapidreductions were required.

When considering the application of broad measures,it should be noted that large fluctuations in marketprices for energy, such those seen in recent years,would likely overwhelm most signals sent by policy.These fluctuations would be a stronger driver of thechoice of fuel and technologies. However, the fuelswitching that occurs might sometimes result in the use of more carbon-intensive fuels; thus such a market price signal should not be considered a substitute for policy action if our objective is a long-term reduction in carbon emissions.

In theory, broad-based price signals (emissionscharges such as taxes and tradable permits) supple-mented by targeted relief were widely acknowledgedby participants in the EFR and Energy Program tooffer the best combination of effectiveness and effi-ciency in stimulating long-term carbon emissionreductions. These instruments increase the relativecost of emission-intensive technologies and products,

Page 41: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

creating a continuous incentive for innovation toimprove emission efficiency or to shift to lower-emission substitutes. Broad-based measures will stimulate the most immediate response from maturetechnologies. However, when applied in a predictableand continuous fashion, they will also gradually stimulate the uptake of emerging technologies andinvestment in the development of new ones. Theywere considered to offer a better approach than thealternative array of complex and possibly arbitraryindividual regulations and standards.

In practice, however, broad-based price signals havereceived virtually no thoughtful discussion, let aloneapplication in Canada. The reasons are summarizedbelow:

• Broad-based price signals affect energy-intensivesectors or regions more than others and, depend-ing on their design, tend to have disproportionateeffects on low-income households. This makes them unpopular in the Canadian political context.However, international experience has tested manymethods to mitigate these distributional effects.

• International competitiveness concerns mitigateagainst the imposition of a price signal, particu-larly in commodity-based sectors where the marketprice is set internationally (such as oil) and whichare not able to pass on this cost. Although revenuerecycling can in theory address competitivenessimpacts, there is little practical experience withthis, except in the case of the U.K.’s ClimateChange Levy program. While competitiveness hasbeen a dominant concern shaping public policy inCanada, our case study on industrial energy effi-ciency suggests this concern may be overblown.The study looked at the effect of $30/tonne CO2eprice signals with no mitigation policies and foundthat only the industrial minerals and the iron andsteel sectors experienced changes in output priceshigh enough to reduce output.

• Revenue-generating price signals, such as taxes orauctioned permits, run counter to the prevailingpolitical movement to lower taxes. There is wide-spread public distrust regarding how governmentswill use new revenue and, in particular, whetherthey will fairly redistribute it. Tax shifting can beused to ensure that the net level of taxation remainsthe same, but there has been little discussion of thisapproach in Canadian climate change policy.

On the other hand, incentive instruments, such assubsidies, are also likely to face significant resistanceunless they have a funding base. Revenue-generatingprice signals can provide such a base. For this reason,a low energy or carbon charge, paired with incentiveprograms in a tax-shifting model, warrants seriousdiscussion and attention.

Given these dynamics, is there any room for the futureuse of broad-based measures in Canada? Participantsin the EFR and Energy Program did identify one possible application. The U.K. Climate Change Levy and companion Climate Change Agreements elicitedinterest due to their simplicity and targeted revenuerecycling. The Levy is a tax on the use of energy inindustry, commerce and the public sector. The revenueraised is recycled to business through three streams: (1) offsetting cuts of 0.3 percent in employers’National Insurance contributions; (2) additional support for energy efficiency (technical support plus a 100 percent first-year capital allowance for certainenergy-saving investments, which is expected to beworth up to £70 million a year); and (3) programs tostimulate the uptake of renewable sources of energy(£50 million a year). The objective has been no netgain for the public finances and no increase in the tax burden on industry as a whole (although it maynot be cost-neutral at the individual firm level). Under the companion Climate Change Agreements, energy-intensive industries receive a rebate of up to 80 percent of the Levy if they agree to a program ofenergy savings, negotiated sector by sector.53

4.4 APPLICATION OF TARGETED MEASURES

If broad-based measures cannot find political accept-ance, targeted measures will continue to be the maincategory of economic instrument available for drivinglong-term carbon emission reductions. The charge forpolicy-makers will be to find other ways to capturethe performance-based benefits of this approach.

Targeted economic measures focus on a technology,class of technologies or action. They do so in two ways:

• through subsidies, which reduce the relative cost of technologies and products with lower emissionintensities, making them as or more attractive than incumbent technologies; and

27Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

Page 42: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

28 National Round Table on the Environment and the Economy

• through so-called market-based regulation such asrenewable portfolio standards or the planned LFEdomestic emissions trading system, which requiresdesignated firms to meet certain targets but allowsthem to trade with other parties in meeting thiscommitment.

4.4.1 SubsidiesSubsidies form the backbone of the ecological fiscalmeasures that are currently in place in Canada.Subsidies may target current decisions by reducingupfront capital costs or target long-term cost competitiveness through funding for research, devel-opment and commercialization of new technologies.

The precise response to subsidies, like that to emis-sions charges, cannot be accurately predicted, andhence neither of these instruments is able to assure a specific emission reduction target.

The total cost of subsidies often exceeds the directcosts to government because governments must raisefunds through other taxes, which have dampeningeffects on economic activity. These effects may bepartly offset by raising government funds throughmore targeted approaches that correct for other distortions. For example, a subsidy for hydrogenvehicles may be funded through a levy on gasolinethat reflects its external costs.

Subsidies tend to require relatively large publicexpenditures per unit of effect, because of the presence of firms and individuals that would haveundertaken the desired change in the absence of thesubsidy. These costs can be large but are often under-estimated. Evaluations of energy efficiency incentiveprograms, for example, have found that 40 to 85 per-cent of program recipients would have acted in theabsence of the program.55 This rate can be reducedthrough more discriminating methods for distribut-ing subsidies. For example, grants can be tied tospecific performance criteria rather than general taxcredits for a class of technologies. The relatively highcost of subsidies per unit of reduction was observedin two of the EFR and Energy Program’s case studies:on industrial energy efficiency and, on emergingrenewable power technologies.

The cost of subsidies can be spread out over theentire economy, reducing, although not eliminating,negative distributional impacts. Moreover, the per-formance of subsidies can be improved throughbetter policy design. The benefits of various designoptions must also be weighed against other consider-ations such as higher administrative costs.

4.4.1.1 Current DecisionsSubsidies targeting current decisions (e.g., acceleratedcapital cost allowances or consumer rebates) usuallyaim to reduce the upfront capital costs of investmentsin specific technologies. However, the administrativeneed to designate specific, qualified technologiesdampens innovation, deters new market entrants and favours technology-specific responses rather than systems innovation and substitution.

Recommendation The option of a broad-based price signalshould be given serious consideration.The case study experience shows that thistype of instrument (such as a charge or apermit market) is the most effective indelivering on the policy objective to whichit is explicitly tied (in this case carbon emissions) and the most cost-efficient tosociety in that it allows for the greatestdegree of flexibility in societal response. A key feature of such instruments is thatthey are also effective in ensuring thatsome of the government’s other policyobjectives—notably in the area of innova-tion and technology development—arepromoted. At the same time, the consulta-tion conducted during the Program revealedserious concerns about the competitivenessimpacts of such a price signal. Another concern centred on the design and imple-mentation challenges posed by a broadinstrument of this sort and on the very highstandard for “getting it right.” Finally, therewas acknowledgement of the lukewarm polit-ical interest in such instruments. An existingmodel for Canadian policy-makers, if they are to consider a broad-based signal, is theU.K.’s Climate Change Levy and companionClimate Change Agreements.54

Page 43: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

Concerns about supporting higher-cost technologiesand being technology-prescriptive could be addressedby designing targeted measures that are performance-based. Under this approach, subsidies would bedirected more toward specific outcomes than towardspecific technologies. For example, a carbon trustcould be established to purchase reductions (throughcompetitive bidding) from a wide variety of sourcesregardless of the technology. Such a targeted measurewould share a key characteristic of broad-basedinstruments, notably their promotion of innovation.

This approach does raise some issues, however. In the area of emerging renewable power, for example, aperformance-based subsidy on its own would skewselection toward market-ready technologies to the detri-ment of pre-competitive ones. From the government’sperspective, verification issues are also more complex.

4.4.1.2 Long-term CompetitivenessSubsidies (e.g., grants and loans) for research anddevelopment, while a well-established category of expenditure instrument, are typically highly uncertain with regard to the scope of their impact on reductions and very long term in delivering their benefits.

4.4.2 Market-based RegulationMarket-based regulation avoids many of the weak-nesses of conventional subsidies. These instrumentsrequire firms to meet certain targets but allow themto trade with other parties in meeting this commit-ment. Overall costs are minimized through the use of trading. The target is specified by the regulation,and depending on the design, the regulation can beperformance-based and technology-neutral.

A portfolio standard is an example of a market-basedregulation with a technology focus. The policy objec-tive of a portfolio standard is rapid deployment of atechnology facing a price barrier in its early stage ofmarket entry. By design, it ensures a high penetrationrate for targeted technology and/or high participationrates. The design of this instrument, including thepoint of application, can greatly affect performance.

Different regional targets may be developed to reflectregional differences in supplies and costs or in green-house gas benefits. Costs could be further reducedthrough a national credit trading system. A phasedimplementation with clear targets and timelines mayalso offer more opportunity for technological changesthat lower the ultimate costs of the instrument.

Finally, the use of a system of penalties can provide a cap on the costs of the instrument, which areuncertain. Any revenues raised from penalties can be reinvested in the research and development of new technologies.

The planned LFE domestic emissions trading systemis an example of a market-based regulation with aperformance focus.

The application of market-based regulation inCanada faces a possible limitation: the need for themarket covered by the regulation to have adequatesupply and demand to ensure liquidity. This necessityrequires that the definition of “sector” or “technol-ogy” be kept broad, which may be difficult forcertain Canadian applications, particularly on theproduction side.

29Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

Unique RisksPromoting the development and adoption ofnew technologies may require greater incen-tives than suggested by economic models.There are many reasons: existing capital stockmay not be ready for replacement, capitalmarkets demand high premiums for takingrisks in early commercial applications, andnew technologies are not always perfect substitutes for the incumbent technology.

In very limited cases, there may be uniquerisks that merit an extra level of publicinvestment, because of the public good arising from successful adoption of a high-risk technology. One approach, adopted inother countries, is the use of loan guaran-tees. Other fiscal examples are targeted taxcredits, direct subsidies, repayable and con-tingently repayable contributions, and grantsto university technology incubation centres.

Page 44: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

30 National Round Table on the Environment and the Economy

Experience with LFE domestic emissions trading todate also demonstrates that these instruments, whichare based in regulation, require the same complexityof infrastructure (program design, reporting, moni-toring and enforcement) as any other regulation.

4.5 TRANSITION MEASURES

The EFR and Energy Program case studies did notexamine transition issues. However, EFR literaturehighlights transition measures as a key factor inachieving acceptance, particularly of new charges.Transition mechanisms include:

• Pilot projects: These help build awareness, understanding, experience and trust.

• Predictability and continuity: The details of an EFR measure should be provided to affected firms and households well in advance, and policycontinuity should be maintained over time so that businesses and households are confident inmaking the investments necessary to respond tothe price signals.

• Gradual implementation: The introduction of newtaxes or charges and the reduction or phase-out ofcurrent subsidies should proceed at a modest paceto give firms time to adjust to new costs.

• One-time assistance: One-time subsidies or creditscan be provided to support the transition costs ofimplementing new technologies.

Part 2 of the present report contains further discussionof economic instruments to support the development ofthe specific technologies examined in the case studies.

Recommendation As an alternative to broad-based price signals—and consistent with current policy approaches—economic instrumentstargeted to specific types of technologyshould be used, but they would need tobe broadened. They could also be designedto link directly to the policy objective beingpursued (in this case carbon emissionreductions). This linkage would allow the targeted measures to share the keycharacteristics of broad-based instruments,notably their promotion of innovation. Anexample of such an instrument is the U.K.’sEnhanced Capital Allowance for vehicleswith low carbon emissions.56

Page 45: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

5. A COORDINATED, LONG-TERM CARBON EMISSIONREDUCTIONS STRATEGY

Energy is a basic good in society, essential for thefunctioning of our modern civilization. People wantreliable, high-quality and affordable energy services.They care less about the source of such services, asdemonstrated by the sequential shifts to new fuelsover the course of history.

Energy is a dominant presence in Canadian society.We are large producers of, large consumers of andhighly dependent on energy, with our cold climateand far-flung geography. For these reasons, Canadaneeds to think now about how to navigate the foreseeable shifts in the energy economy, as new technologies are introduced, new ecological pressuresemerge and some incumbent sources ebb. The benefitof an explicit strategy will be an orderly transitionand greater certainty for all actors.

Sustained and sustainable efforts will be required to avert the more extreme scenarios of climatechange. Policy-makers will need to focus beyond the short-term horizon of the Kyoto Accord—and its comparatively timid first steps—and on the fundamental changes needed in the energy system to stabilize concentrations of greenhouse gases in the atmosphere at safe levels. The two levers mostamenable to public policy intervention are energyintensity (the amount of energy used to create a dollar of economic output) and the carbon intensityof the energy sector (see box).57 This will requirepath-breaking innovations such as those examined in this study: increasing the efficiency of energy use, removing obstacles to the wider use of existingcarbon-free energy technologies, and developing and deploying entirely new low-carbon technologies.These actions could produce long-term and enduringresults, positioning Canada as a winner in the shifttoward a less carbon-intensive global economy.

The 25-year time frame proposed by the EFR andEnergy Program would enable the exploration of acoordinated transition: phased deployment of provenmature technologies, complemented by the gradualadoption of emerging ones, and investment in theresearch, development, demonstration and commer-cialization of longer-term options.

The EFR and Energy Program used case studies toexamine the use of fiscal instruments in encouragingthe adoption of energy-based carbon mitigation technologies at three different stages:

1Mature technologies, at the market-ready or market-entry stage of development. Industrialenergy efficiency was the focus of investigationbecause apparently cost-effective energy efficiencyinvestments are routinely forgone, suggestingsome form of market barrier. Large hydro isanother example of a mature energy-based carbonmitigation technology.

2Emerging technologies, spanning the demonstrationto early market-entry stages. Emerging renewablepower technologies (based on the EcoLogo criteria) were examined; other examples in thiscategory are hybrid cars and thermal renewables,which were not covered.

31Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

…the key driver of historic and future carbonemissions…is a byproduct of four interrelatedfactors…

+ population growth rate+ per capita economic growth rate+ energy intensity growth rate + carbon intensity growth rate

Most scenarios for the future suggest that theexpected increases in population and eco-nomic growth will outweigh the continueddecreases in energy and carbon intensities….

—Battelle Memorial Institute, Global Energy Technology Strategy:

Addressing Climate Change.

Initial Findings from an InternationalPublic–Private Collaboration (Washington,

D.C.: Battelle, n.d.) pp. 14–15.

Page 46: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

32 National Round Table on the Environment and the Economy

3Longer-term new technologies, still in the fundamental research to demonstration stages.Hydrogen fuel technologies were the technologiesof interest in this study; other examples of longer-term new technologies are carbon capture and sequestration.

It should be noted that the choice of the specifictechnologies for our case studies does not imply primacy for any of these technologies: they areunderstood to fit within a broad mix of mitigationtechnologies, supply sources and demand sectors,now and in the future. This mix includes mitigationtechnologies such as carbon capture and sequestra-tion; other low-carbon energy sources (e.g., nuclear,large-scale hydro and thermal renewables) that,together with carbon fuels, will likely remain signifi-cant sources of primary energy in the future; andother demand sectors (e.g., residential, commercial and transportation) and technologies (e.g., hybrid andelectric vehicles). All need to be addressed as part of a balanced approach to long-term carbon emission reductions. It should also be noted that the specific recommendations related to these case studies do notconstitute a proposal for a comprehensive climatechange action plan or energy strategy for Canada; othertechnologies, initiatives and measures will be needed.These were simply outside the scope of this program.

In presenting the findings and recommendations ofthe EFR and Energy Program, we draw not only onthe specific analysis carried out in the case studies(and the general lessons they yield regarding the useof economic instruments), but also on the consulta-tion process conducted as part of the Program’s work.

5.1 STAGING AND CONSIDERATIONS FOR A COORDINATED TECHNOLOGY TRANSITION STRATEGY

A key consideration for policy-makers as they developa long-term, coordinated strategy for energy policywill be how to tailor policy measures to support thedifferent development stage of each technology.Particular consideration will need be given to creatingsynergies between current and future technologies, sothat these technologies can reinforce one anotherwhere possible.

• Mature technologies: Many carbon emission reduction options are currently available and cost-competitive: these should form the first and major focus of a coordinated technology transition strategy.

– The foremost emphasis should be on reducingdemand through carbon-efficient energy effi-ciency measures—the “low-hanging fruit” in emissions mitigation. This should be the priority before any investment in new supply.Mature and cost-effective options for significantefficiency improvements are available now in allsectors, and they are the focus of some of thefiscal measures proposed in this report. The bestopportunity for energy efficiency improvementscomes with the turnover of capital stock; eachone of these opportunities must be seized.Energy efficiency relieves the pressure to buildnew supply and has historically been less costlythan building new supply. It frees up resourcesand buys time to develop alternative energysources.

– The synergies between incumbent technologiesand future technologies identified for the strat-egy should be a factor in assessing incumbentsupply options. For example, large hydro complements many emerging renewable powersources by providing reservoirs that can offsettheir intermittent nature, while enhancing therenewable power component of the electricitygrid reduces the carbon intensity of electricityand is one strategy for carbon-efficient hydro-gen pathways.

– Economic instruments to support mature car-bon mitigation technologies should ideally bebroad-based to avoid picking winners. Theyshould focus on reinforcing the position ofthese technologies by increasing the relative cost of emission-intensive technologies andproducts, thereby creating a continuous incen-tive to shift to lower-emission substitutes or to innovate to improve emission efficiency.

• Emerging technologies: Some of these technologies(e.g., hybrid cars, wind and solar) are commer-cially viable or near-viable in certain applicationsand ready for immediate expanded use. Othertechnologies (e.g., wave power) require furtherdevelopment and would only be commerciallyviable in the mid- to long term.

– Instruments to support emerging technologiesshould focus on stimulating market adoption toencourage the learning by doing and economiesof scale needed to close the cost gap withincumbent technologies. Examples includeportfolio standards, guaranteed minimum feed-in tariffs and/or production subsidies.

Page 47: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

• Longer-term new technologies: By their nature, these still need to overcome technical challengesand large costs compared with incumbent technologies. Where these challenges are still sig-nificant, they are best addressed by research anddevelopment subsidies and incentives. Where thetechnology is more mature, demonstration andpre-commercialization assistance is important.

– Of the economic instrument options studied,public R&D investments are the most expensiveand uncertain in terms of assured carbon emis-sion reductions. For this reason, as well asbecause the demand for R&D funding can belimitless and because technology developmentoccurs within an international arena, theseinvestments should strategically target fields in which Canada has a competitive advantage.Consideration of Canadian capacity to respondto this assistance, particularly at the pre-commercialization stage, is also needed.

– Technology development is driven by privateinvestment as well as public investment. Thus fiscal mechanisms for mobilizing privateresearch and development investments mustalso be used. For fundamentally new tech-nologies that are highly research-intensive andhave long commercialization timelines, such ashydrogen fuel cells, new approaches to stimulat-ing R&D investments may also be needed.

It must be emphasized that technologies can spantwo or more stages of development. Take, forinstance, some of the technologies examined directlyor indirectly in the case studies: there are certainhydrogen technologies with competitive marketapplications today, although most are still in aresearch and development or early demonstrationstage. Adoption does not occur all at once; rather,technologies are gradually phased in as they become competitive, niche by niche. Similarly, even long-established, mature technologies can berevolutionized by radical new production processes,with potential breakthroughs in energy efficiency.

33Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

Instrument Choice andTechnology StageThe fiscal instrument should be tailored tothe development stage of the technology:

• Large cost differential between incumbentand new technology? Reduce differencethrough R&D subsidies.

• Cost differential reduced and performanceimproved? Focus on learning by doing andeconomies of scale; encourage marketadoption through portfolio standardsand/or subsidies.

• Cost difference eliminated? Reinforceposition of new technology throughbroad-based instruments (e.g., emissionspermits, taxes).

Emis

sion

s

2005 2030

Business-as-usual energy-based emissions Energy strategy scenario

Emissions reduction with enhanced use of mature carbon mitigation technologies (e.g., energy efficiency)

Emissions reduction from emerging carbonmitigation technologies

Emissions reduction from long-term carbonmitigation technologies

Emissions Impacts of Coordinated Energy StrategyOver Time (notional only; not to scale)

Page 48: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

34 National Round Table on the Environment and the Economy

Assessment of technologies for their potential toreduce carbon emissions should always be done onthe basis of life-cycle emissions (and life-cycle netbenefits, i.e., total benefits minus total costs), notjust at the final point of energy use. The significanceof life-cycle assessment was highlighted in the hydrogen case study, where the choice of hydrogenpathway affected life-cycle carbon emissions by asmuch as 175 percent. Other research shows that zero-emission vehicles, fuelled by hydrogen and electricity,

may have greater carbon emissions on a life-cyclebasis than best-in-class internal combustion vehicleson the road today, depending on the electricitysource and the method of producing hydrogen.Carbon capture and sequestration, another longer-term technology, may be able to moderate theseresults, but not without affecting the energy bal-ance—the amount of energy required across the lifecycle to produce a given unit of energy.

Page 49: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

6. LESSONS: THE EXPERIENCEWITH ASSESSING FISCALINSTRUMENTS

In its exploration of approaches, processes andmethodologies that link the issues of energy, climatechange, technology development and fiscal policy, the NRTEE has attempted to generate lessons thatcan inform policy development in the fiscal area.

The following discussion summarizes these general lessons.

6.1 DATA RELIABILITY AND COMPREHENSIVENESS

It goes without saying that the decision to apply fis-cal measures to increase the use of emerging energytechnologies should be based on information aboutthe anticipated effectiveness of such policies. Yet thecase studies showed that the ability to assess antici-pated effectiveness, and hence make sound policy, isseverely constrained by the absence of reliable, timelyand comprehensive data.

There were several dimensions to this constraint:

• Data on many aspects of alternative energyresources have not been collected in Canada. Forinstance, no comprehensive, high-resolution windresource atlas exists for Canada, presenting a con-siderable barrier to further development.58 As well,accurate and up-to-date information on the tech-nical and practical potential of many renewableenergy sources, including potential hydro sites (astaple of the Canadian energy picture), either doesnot exist or is far inferior to that for other OECDcountries. The information that is available pres-ents widely varying estimates, reflecting differentinterpretations of the concept of renewable energy.

• Alternative energy technology is being installed ata rate that exceeds current data collection; hencedata for the installed base of grid-connectedrenewable power in Canada can only be gatheredthrough extensive personal communications, notthrough formal statistical sources.

• Modelling results are highly dependent on data for which there is low confidence (e.g., the futureprice of natural gas).

Despite these constraints, the three case studies gathered considerable original data, representing a significant contribution of new data to the public domain.

6.2 SENSITIVITIES

The case studies proved highly sensitive to the priceof fossil fuels and, in particular, the price of naturalgas. This sensitivity was the single most importantfactor in the development of all three classes of tech-nologies examined. For example, in the hydrogencase study, the price of fossil fuels affects the finalprice, and hence the penetration, of hydrogen byaffecting the cost of input fuels and the price of competing commodities.

Yet to provide a common baseline for calibration—and to ensure the results would be comparable withother official Canadian modelling efforts in the fieldof greenhouse gas reduction measures—the hydrogencase study was forced to employ estimates of naturalgas pricing that are now outdated. However, therewas no other reference available. The pricing esti-mates used in the case study were developed in the late 1990s and reported in Canada’s EmissionsOutlook: An Update.59 Since then, the actual prices ofkey energy commodities have diverged significantlyfrom those portrayed in that study. For example, theprice of oil and the price of gas were, respectively,approximately 30 percent and 140 percent higher in2000 than forecast in the 1999 study. That study alsodid not include price impact data from Action Plan200060 and the 2002 Climate Change Plan forCanada, since these postdate the study.

There is inherent uncertainty in forecasting the priceof natural gas 30 years into the future. A significantfactor is expected to be the climate change policyitself, which by driving a shift to greater use of natural gas may create a significant supply gap in this commodity.

6.3 TECHNOLOGY PATHS

The path for long-term reductions in carbon emis-sions from energy use will involve both proven andstill-emerging technologies. Some of these technolo-gies could be adopted on a gradual and incrementalbasis. Other technology shifts may reflect a stepchange. Still other technologies are likely to be

35Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

Page 50: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

36 National Round Table on the Environment and the Economy

fundamentally disruptive, changing the pattern ofenergy use in unpredictable ways. Examples in thislatter category include stationary fuel cells.

The uptake of these different categories of technologyis likely to take place on different time scales: maturetechnologies on an immediate time scale (e.g., hydro,cogeneration and wind), emerging technologies on amedium time scale as they enter the market (e.g., cer-tain photovoltaic technologies) and longer-term newtechnologies on a longer time scale as they move outof the R&D phase and into commercialization (e.g.,hydrogen fuel cells). The question, from a policy perspective, is: should fiscal instruments be chosen to target potential breakthrough technologies? Thesepromise significant carbon emission reductions on amore speculative context. They may also support theenhanced uptake of proven technologies, ready fordeployment on a massive scale, and with a knownimpact on the output of clean or cleaner energy.

Companies are extra sensitive to the risk involved ininvesting in new, not commercially proven technolo-gies. Concerns include the possible effect on productquality, process reliability, maintenance needs andgeneral uncertainty about the performance of a newtechnology.61 New technologies carry a greater poten-tial for premature failure, and the presence of thisuncertainty can prove a significant barrier to invest-ment. Investors are tempted to postpone investmentand wait for additional information to inform theirdecision (“option value”).62 The effect grows whenenergy and technology price uncertainty increases,and technology costs are falling more quickly.63 Thisobservation might suggest that EFR measures shouldfocus on facilitating the market-entry phase of emerg-ing technologies, leaving the accelerated deploymentof proven technologies to existing market forces.

Another factor affecting the uptake of new tech-nologies is the presence of less competitive energymarkets. The introduction of disruptive technologies(e.g., hydrogen) is often controlled in such settings.

6.4 EXAMINING MID- TO LONG-TERMFUTURES: UNCERTAINTIES ANDUNKNOWNS

The long-term perspective adopted for the case stud-ies presents the unavoidable challenges of knowledgelimitations. There are inherent uncertainties in look-ing two to three decades into the future, particularlyin a field that will likely be characterized by unpre-dictable technological evolution and breakthroughs,potentially disruptive technologies and uncertainconventional energy stocks.

Many uncertainties were flagged by participants inthe EFR and Energy Program. Among these is thelikely impact of the anticipated depletion of non-renewable energy stocks. What will be the impact onfossil fuel pricing? What are the implications for thespeed of transition to alternatives? And how will thisaffect the urgency of government intervention tostimulate breakthroughs in energy efficiency and a more rapid transition to low-impact renewablepower sources?

Another category of uncertainties is the non-pricefactors that will also influence the rollout of newtechnologies and fuels. These include advantages ofquality, convenience and reliability of supply, whichmay be embodied in new energy sources and driveearly adoption; competition among firms to gainearly-adopter advantage in a new energy economy;and social pressures related to the external costs offossil fuel use in a world increasingly concernedabout climate change and urban air quality. Any ofthese could speed up the transition from incumbenttechnologies to lower-carbon energy sources.

6.5 MARKET SETTINGS

Sub-national factors as well as the international con-text will influence both the effectiveness and theunintended impact of national-level fiscal measuresto encourage lower-carbon energy futures.

Page 51: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

Profound shifts underway in some provincial energypolicies, including the deregulation of electrical utilities, consequent uncertainty and volatility inprices, and a new openness to independent powerproduction, will be major influences at the sub-national level. Some provinces are also considering or introducing their own measures to encouragegrowth in low-impact renewable power. The accelerated deployment of all of the low-carbon technologies examined will require coordinated andcollaborative arrangements between jurisdictions.Jurisdictional and governance challenges were identified in each of the case studies.

The international context also creates challenges forCanadian action. Some participants in the EFR andEnergy Program felt that the use of a price mecha-nism in the scenarios (e.g., the $30 shadow price for carbon in the energy efficiency case study) wasnot appropriate for Canada in the absence of policyaction by its major trading partner, because the onlyeffect would be to encourage mobile industries toleave the country. Increasing continental trade inelectricity could also influence the development ofrenewable supply in Canada or limit policy options.

6.6 OTHER ISSUES

As the three case studies proceeded, a number ofissues emerged relating to the potential relationshipsbetween initiatives in each of the technology areasexamined.

All three case studies revealed the need for technol-ogy development policies that specifically targetenergy and climate change considerations, while taking into account Canada’s comparative advantages.

In addition, the studies highlighted the variations in the cost-effectiveness of the carbon emission mitigation achieved by the different technologies,while also indicating that the options that are mostcost-effective in the short term are not necessarily theones that will yield the most significant long-termreductions.

37Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

Recommendation The federal government should put inplace a process to continuously evaluateand monitor progress in achieving thegoals and to suggest adaptation of meas-ures based on their effectiveness, aschanges occur or as new opportunitiesstart to develop.

To support a better ability to assess economic instruments for long-term carbon emissions reduction:

1The federal government should regularlyupdate its energy and emissions out-looks, incorporating new price forecastsand the effects of new climate change initiatives as these are adopted.

2Governments (federal and provincial)should support the development of reliable and comprehensive mapping ofthe technical and practical potential ofemerging renewable resources.

3Governments (federal and provincial)should support the gathering of timelydata on installed capacity and marketactivity with respect to emerging technologies.

4Governments (federal and provincial)should improve the data on the currentcapital stock in both energy supply anduse systems and on its performancecharacteristics.

Page 52: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions
Page 53: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

7. SUMMARY OF FINDINGS

39Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

Our analysis and consultation on the role of fiscal policy in promoting long-term carbon emission reductions yielded four main findings:

1Economic instruments can make a significant contribution to achievinglong-term reductions of energy-basedcarbon emissions. Their full potential will only be realized, however, if:• the government clearly restates its

sustained commitment to long-term carbon emission reductions;

• fiscal policy is developed in a coherentand consistent fashion to support this commitment to long-term carbonemission reductions.

• federal action is closely coordinatedwith provincial strategies targeting the same objectives;

• sufficient time, and a degree of predictability, is provided for in the introduction and application of eco-nomic instruments. This will allowefficient and effective long-term investment decisions to be made andimplemented; and

• all technologies being targeted with economic instruments are assessed for their life-cycle potential to reducecarbon emissions.

2There is no contradiction between promoting long-term carbon emissionreductions through EFR initiatives andpursuing Canada’s other key societalobjectives (such as energy security andeconomic development). Success, how-ever, requires a framework that clearlyidentifies the opportunities that exist for achieving these objectives and thenecessary actions for doing so.

3At the same time, promoting energy technology development through EFR initiatives does not necessarily equate to the long-term reduction of carbonemission. This finding points to the critical need to integrate carbon emissionobjectives with technology developmentpolicies.

4Economic instruments designed to promote these long-term carbon emis-sion reductions through technologyneed to reflect both the market and the technological maturity of the technology in question:• For mature carbon emission reduction

technologies (such as those represented in our case study on industrial energy efficiency), the focus should be ondemand–pull instruments that facilitateand promote the uptake of existing technologies, and on support for thedevelopment of new energy efficiencytechnologies, particularly those thatoffer radical energy efficiency benefits(e.g., through new productionprocesses).

• For emerging carbon-efficient energy technologies (such as those representedin our emerging renewables case study),the focus should be on instruments that help bridge the price gap betweenmature technologies and the emergingones. The operating assumption is thatthe price gap will close with increasing market penetration and progressivelyfavourable economies of scale.

cont’d on next page

Page 54: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

40 National Round Table on the Environment and the Economy

• For longer-term carbon emission reduction technologies(such as those represented in our hydrogen case study), the focus shouldbe on promoting research and develop-ment to address critical technical andeconomic barriers.

Page 55: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

PART 2: SPECIFIC FINDINGS

FROM THE CASE STUDIES

Page 56: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

42 National Round Table on the Environment and the Economy

The EFR and Energy Program carried out parallelcase studies of targeted fiscal instruments to promoteenergy-based carbon emission reduction technologiesat three stages of development:

• Mature technologies, represented by industrialenergy efficiency technologies in Canadian manufacturing and mining industries;

• Emerging technologies, represented by emergingrenewable power technologies (based on theEcoLogo criteria) for the integrated electricitygrid; and

• Longer-term new technologies, represented byhydrogen energy technologies, defined as anyenergy system where the primary fuel, at somepoint within the process, is hydrogen. The focuswas on transportation and stationary power production in residential and/or commercialbuildings.

Highlights of the findings and discussion of the policy implications of the three studies are presentedbelow; more extensive summaries of the findings canbe found in the appendices.

Page 57: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

8. CASE STUDY SCOPE,BOUNDARIES ANDMETHODOLOGIES

Several aspects of the scoping and boundary decisionsmade within the case studies were contentious:

• Members of the EFR and Energy Task Forceemphasized that the case studies are intended toportray an illustrative sequencing of technologies,not a comprehensive energy strategy. The tech-nologies are understood to be part of a broadermix of supply sources and demand sectors, nowand in the future. Other energy sources—nuclearenergy and large-scale hydroelectricity, in particu-lar—represent a substantial share of low-carbonenergy sources, and fossil fuels will likely remain asignificant source of primary energy into the fore-seeable future.

• Some participants were concerned that the use ofthe EcoLogo certification criteria in the emergingtechnologies case study would send the wrong sig-nal regarding the renewability of large-scale hydro:

The EcoLogo criteria focus on “low impact” renewable energy, excluding most large-scalehydroelectricity, although this is a renewableenergy source. “Low impact” hydro is defined by a number of criteria based on protection ofindigenous species and habitat, requirements forhead-pond water levels, water flows, water qualityand several other factors. Theoretically, an installa-tion of any size could meet this requirement,although the general threshold is approximately 10 to 20 MW. As well, the length of time thatwater is retained upstream from the installationshould generally be less than 48 hours. (Note: theEcoLogo criteria also screen out some biomassfacilities. For more detail, see Appendix B.)

Some hydroelectric utilities consider the EcoLogoexclusion of larger installations to be confusingand misleading. Moreover, it was pointed out thatthe federal government defines large-scale hydro asa renewable energy source.64 Fiscal instruments foremerging renewable power sources should there-fore be complemented by other measures designedto support renewable sources at more maturestages of development, most notably large-scalehydro. Failure to do so would eliminate 90 percentof the current renewable electricity supply inCanada, as well as risking less displacement of fossil-fuel generation.

A related concern was that the EcoLogo, a volun-tary ecolabelling program, is a marketing tool, nota regulatory standard; as such, it should not beused as the basis for fiscal instruments.

There was widespread agreement that large-scalehydro is complementary to many emerging renewableenergies. Apart from geothermal energy, theseresources are intermittent and require backup energyproduction capacity, such as that from hydroelectricreservoirs.

• The solar industry and Natural Resources Canadaoriginally wanted the emerging renewable electric-ity case study to include off-grid applications (e.g., ground-source heat pumps, solar hot waterheaters and passive solar), which hold considerablepromise in mitigating long-term carbon emissions.These technologies could not be addressed in thecomputer model that was used and, for that reasononly, were excluded. Although certain modellingprograms do exist for such technologies (i.e., theRenewable Energy Deployment Initiative, REDI),these technologies do not lend themselves to production-related fiscal measures. Off-grid tech-nologies can contribute more to the displacementof existing generation (in ways that are sometimesdifficult to measure) than to the actual generationof electricity.

• One participant questioned the exclusive focus onhydrogen as an emerging fuel source for trans-portation. This person would have liked to haveseen electric vehicles studied as well. The technol-ogy for electric vehicles was thought to be morecommercially advanced than that for hydrogenvehicles and, in some regions of the country, tohave a better energy balance.

8.1 OVERVIEW OF CASE STUDY METHODOLOGIES

The three case studies shared a similar analyticalframework:

• define a business-as-usual (BAU) evolution assuming no government intervention;

• identify elements that offer an opportunity to alter development either in time or intensity;

• identify barriers that prevent opportunities frombeing achieved;

• define instruments that could overcome the barriers;

43Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

Page 58: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

44 National Round Table on the Environment and the Economy

• assess the economic and environmental efficiencyand effectiveness of the potential instruments; and

• have policy and technical experts review thesemodelling results, as well as validate and shape recommendations for economic instruments specific to each technology.

The hydrogen and renewable energy case studiesmodel the period from 2010 to 2030. The energyefficiency case study models a slightly longer periodfrom 2005 to 2030. It must be emphasized that thistime horizon introduced sizable uncertainties into thetechnology development pathway and commodityprices, influencing the reliability of the results.

The work of the Analysis and Modelling Group ofCanada’s National Climate Change Process was usedas a common baseline for calibrating assumptions toensure consistency and comparability of results.65

The BAU scenarios used in these studies do notinclude any of the measures committed to underAction Plan 2000.

Each case study uses a different model to evaluate thepossible impact of fiscal instruments on greenhousegas emissions in the target sectors. The case studiesalso differ in terms of definitions of costs, levels ofregional and sectoral detail, and the scope of feed-back included in the analysis. For example, inevaluating the impact of different fiscal instruments,

Table 1: Case Study Assumptions and Results

Hydrogen energy

Fiscal instruments considered

Estimated emission impacts (excluding macroeconomic feedbacks)

Marginal cost of emission reductions in 2030

Total direct costs of instrument (excluding other feedbacks)

Only subsidies are considered. Two alternative fiscalpackages are examined with different levels of subsidyin each:• Producer tax credits or grants to lower the cost of

hydrogen production by 10% or 25%• Producer incentives as above together with consumer

incentives to reduce the price of hydrogen vehiclesand stationary fuel cells by 10% or 25%

From an increase of 0.3 to a decrease of 1.2 Mt/yearby 2030 (Note 1)

~$800 to >$2,000/tonne (depending upon sub-sector)

No estimate of total costs is provided but, assumingaverage reduction costs of $1,400/tonne, an estimated~$1.6 billion in government subsidies per year will berequired by 2030

Page 59: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

the energy efficiency case study considers non-pricefactors affecting the adoption of energy efficiencytechnologies. In contrast, the renewable energy casestudy assumes the penetration of renewable energy isrelated primarily to relative prices only (except in thecase of a renewable portfolio standard, or RPS, whichmandates a minimum level of production fromrenewables). Similarly, the energy efficiency casestudy includes limited assumptions about inducedtechnological change (primarily in the form of adecline in technology costs with increasing marketshare), whereas the renewable energy case studyincludes the effects of policies on R&D decisions,and the effects of both R&D investments and cumu-lative experience on future renewable energy costs.

For this reason, comparisons of per-tonne emissionreduction costs between one study and another arenot possible.

None of the case studies includes feedback fromchanges in aggregate demand, including trade impact,or structural changes in the national economy.

Table 1 provides a summary of key assumptions andoutputs for each case study. Direct comparison wasnot easy because each study team reported inputs andoutputs in very different ways (e.g., present values vs.annual averages; aggregate impacts vs. sectoral orregional impacts). This table represents a best interpretation of the results of each case study.

45Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

Renewable energy Energy efficiency

Five alternative packages to achieve a 12% reduction in emissions: • Renewable portfolio standard (24%)• Emission pricing ($10/tonne)• Renewable subsidy ($0.006/kWh) • R&D subsidy (61% of forecast base case R&D)• Combined renewables and R&D subsidies

Decrease of 9 to 24 Mt/year by 2030

~$10 to $40/tonne (Note 2)

Case study estimates net levelized welfare costs of $68to $270 million/year, calculated as changes in con-sumer costs + changes in producer profits + changesin net government revenues. In the case of emissionpricing, government revenues would equal ~$1 billionper year. In the case of subsidies, government expen-ditures would be $125 to $460 million/year.

Three alternative instruments with two levels of shadow cost ($15 and $30/tonne):• Greenhouse gas tax• Tradable permits (auctioned)• Subsidies (grants, loans and tax incentives)

Decrease of 46 to 58 Mt/year by 2030

~$15 to $30/tonne

In the case of emission taxes, government would raise$5 to $10 billion/year (after changes in greenhouseintensity). In the case of subsidies, government wouldspend $0.2 to $0.5 billion per year. This estimateassumes no free riders, which could increase costs asmuch as 85%. In both cases, these costs represent thecost of inducing changes in industry based on priceand non-price considerations. In terms of real financialcosts, industry will also save $1.9 to $2.7 billion peryear in energy costs (net of capital investment).

Table 1 continued on next page

Page 60: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

46 National Round Table on the Environment and the Economy

Table 1: Case Study Assumptions and Results (cont’d)

Hydrogen energy

Price impact of instruments

Consideration of non-price factors in the analysis

Effects included

Effects excluded

Sectors directly affected

Regional impact

Technology impact

Use of subsidies results in no price increases for non-participants (Note 3)

Modelling framework considers non-price factors inestimating impact of subsidies on producer and consumer decisions

Hydrogen production costsEquipment purchases by producers and consumersHydrogen demand

Incremental effects of policies on R&D activityEffect of incremental R&D and/or penetration on rate of technology changeIndirect costs of government funds for subsidiesPossible changes in prices of fossil fuel generation(through technological change and changes in fossilfuel prices)

Transportation, residential and commercial

Impacts modelled by regionUptake is largest in Alberta, Ontario, B.C. andSaskatchewan

50% increase in hydrogen demand for transportation(43 to 67% increase in hydrogen-related vehicles) by 2030 472% increase in hydrogen demand for stationary fuelcells (230% increase in number of installed fuel cells)

Page 61: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

47Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

Renewable energy Energy efficiency

No price increases with subsidies. Under emission pricing and RPS, national average elec-tricity prices (delivered) increase 4.0 to 5.4% in 2015.Impact of RPS declines to 1.0% beyond 2015 as aresult of R&D investments. (Note 4)

Modelling framework assumes all technologies/optionsare perfect substitutes with decisions based entirelyon relative prices

Uptake of renewablesIn the case of emission pricing, fuel switching (coal to natural gas) is includedDemand feedbacks based on electricity price increases(aggregate elasticities)R&D investment and subsequent reduction in technology costsReduction in technology costs associated withincreased experience

Electricity tradeDownstream impacts on output for individual sectorsAggregate demand feedbacksIndirect costs of government funds for subsidies andindirect benefits from revenue recycling of taxes

Electricity

Impacts modelled using aggregate national parameters

58 to 80% increase in renewable production$22 to $172 million increase in annual R&D spending13 to 26% reduction in renewable costs

In case of subsidies, combined effects of subsidies andenergy savings could actually lower prices in somesectors (by 0.1 to 9.0% depending upon the reductionscenario and sector). In the case of carbon taxes,prices could decline in some sectors (energy savingsexceed cost of compliance) and increase in other sectors. Largest price impact occurs in industrial minerals, where additional costs exceed 5% of totalvalue of output. The impact could be mitigated in part through revenue-recycling mechanisms.

Modelling framework considers non-price factors inestimating impact of instruments on producer decisions

Investments in energy efficiency equipment in targetsectors as well as reductions in upstream electricityemissions (through cogeneration)Some reduction in technology costs incorporated withincreased market shares

Effects of policies on R&D activity Effect of cumulative experience on technology costsSectoral demand feedbacksAggregate demand feedbacksIndirect costs of government funds for subsidies andindirect benefits from revenue recycling of taxes

Mining and manufacturing (indirect impacts on electricity sector through fuel substitution and cogeneration)

Impacts modelled by region but sub-regional impactsnot reported separately

Encompasses a wide variety of technologies andprocesses; impact is diffuse

Table 1 continued on next page

Page 62: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

48 National Round Table on the Environment and the Economy

Notes:1. Emissions may increase depending upon the source of hydrogen (e.g., SMR vs. electrolytic production).2. The price instrument has the lowest unit cost. The other instruments are more costly on a unit cost basis.

The higher value reflects the approximate cost of reductions under R&D subsidies. 3. For participants, the cost of hydrogen still exceeds the cost of gasoline and electricity. Uptake is driven by

non-financial considerations. In theory, reduced demand for conventional fuels from participants could lowerprices of conventional fuels for non-participants.

4. It is not entirely clear from the case study why the cost of electricity does not also decline under emissionpricing with increased R&D expenditure.

Source: Trent Berry, “Macroeconomic Impacts of Fiscal Policy Promoting Long-term Decarbonization in Canada,” Working paper preparedfor the National Round Table on the Environment and the Economy (Vancouver: Compass Resource Management Ltd., August 2004).

Page 63: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

9. SPECIFIC FINDINGS:INDUSTRIAL ENERGY EFFICIENCY

Energy efficiency refers to the relationship betweenthe output (service) of a device or system and theenergy put into it. This case study focused onCanadian manufacturing and mining industries,66

seeking energy efficiency opportunities in energy-using equipment, major industrial processes, supplytechnologies and delivery networks. Fuel switchingwas considered in conjunction with efficiencyoptions.

Economy-wide energy intensity (unit energy per unitGDP) is influenced by two factors: energy efficiencyitself and other factors such as structural shifts in the economy toward new industries or value-addedcommodities with different energy intensities of production and interaction effects. Past reductions inthe energy intensity of the economy can be attributedin part to shifts in the composition of the economy,such as the growth of the service sectors and the relo-cation of manufacturing facilities to other regions.The design of EFR measures may affect the structureof the economy by encouraging a move in produc-tion up the value-added chain, toward value-addedproducts that have greater price elasticity and hencethe ability to absorb new environmental costs.

From an analytical perspective, it is important tonote that the electricity sector was not included inthe study. The argument against including it was that most electricity in Canada is still produced bypublicly owned utilities, and these are not subject tothe same fiscal instruments as private corporations.Some participants thought the sector should beincluded, since it holds many opportunities forenergy efficiency improvements. They also pointedout that, in many Canadian jurisdictions,67 electricity(and, in particular, electricity at the margin) willincreasingly be generated by independent producers,and their choice of feedstock will have significantenvironmental consequences. Excluding electricitygeneration from the purview of the fiscal instrumentscould also create unintended perversities—for example, it could motivate industries to install high-efficiency boilers rather than cogeneration units, which would be better from a system-widegreenhouse gas reduction perspective.

This case study considered the role of energy effi-ciency in promoting decarbonization of the energysystem. At the same time, it acknowledged the multiple policy objectives served by energy efficiency.For example, a carbon reduction focus was thoughtto buttress steps to meet air quality standards and, as such, to be of interest to firms that would other-wise resist measures to improve energy efficiency.Furthermore, promoting energy efficiency would support other policy priorities, such as reducingenergy demand.

According to OECD research, innovative energy- andmaterial-efficient technologies have multi-functionalbenefits in addition to their GHG mitigation effects.Ancillary local air quality, macroeconomic and healtheffects are well understood. More neglected are otherancillary benefits:

• improved product quality, quality of life, capitaland labour productivity from energy- and material-efficient process substitution;

• dynamic effects of learning, economies of scaleand technological competition between the newand the traditional technology;

• net employment effects because of import substi-tution and first-mover effects; and

• regional redistribution of net employment fromthe more equitable distribution of jobs in aresource-efficient economy.

The benefits of these other aspects may in fact sur-mount the energy savings and mitigation benefits.68

9.1 STATUS OF INDUSTRIAL ENERGY EFFICIENCY

The industrial sector, which includes mining andmanufacturing activities, is a significant GHG-producing sector in Canada. The sector produced237 Mt CO2e of direct GHG emissions in 2000, themajority of which were energy-consumption based.69

Total energy consumed by industry in that same yearwas 3,187.2 petajoules (PJ).70

Energy intensity (based on GDP) in Canadian indus-try decreased by about 27 percent between 1990 and2002.71 Trends in carbon intensity are similar (asmeasured by GHG emissions per unit of GDP).During the same period, the carbon intensity (alsobased on GDP) of Canadian industry also declined,levelling off at approximately 34 percent below 1990levels in 2002.72 The decline in energy and carbon

49Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

Page 64: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

50 National Round Table on the Environment and the Economy

intensity is due to improved efficiency among energyusers and to structural changes in industry (a changein product or industry mix). It is also affected by factors associated with GDP monetary units, such ascosts of labour or selling price of the final product.Composite indicators computed for aggregate physi-cal energy intensity in Canadian industry between1990 and 1996 suggest a smaller decline in energyintensity relative to the measure based on GDP.73

The potential for energy efficiency improvements can still be significant, particularly for some industrysectors. For example, a 1996 study prepared forNatural Resources Canada found that the technicalpotential for energy conservation in six major energy-consuming industries ranged from 3 to 25 percent ofprojected energy consumption in 2010.74 However,three decades of research show that consumers andfirms forgo apparently cost-effective investments inenergy efficiency. One reason for this is that energyefficiency projects must compete for capital within afirm and may simply not meet internal required ratesof return. Another reason may be that firms hesitateto adopt new technologies, which carry a greaterpotential for failure. Since these investments are irreversible and can be delayed, this uncertainty cancreate a significant drag on investment. This so-calledenergy efficiency gap is a critical issue in evaluatingthe economic cost and potential of EFR to influencethe uptake of energy-efficient technologies.

9.2 STATUS OF INDUSTRIAL ENERGY EFFICIENCY TO 2030 ASSUMING BUSINESS AS USUAL

Overall, emissions in the industry sector (as definedin this case study) grow by 50 percent over the2000–2030 simulation period, with direct emissionsincreasing and indirect emissions decreasing.75 Totalemissions grow at an average annual rate of 1.53 per-cent, which is faster than the average annual rate of

growth in energy consumption of 1.48 percent (Table 2). This growth occurs because the productionin a number of carbon- and energy-intensive sub-sectors is expected to grow significantly. The share of electricity produced by cogeneration in the indus-trial sector increases over the simulation period,particularly in oil sands operations. The oil and gas sector generates the largest quantity of GHGemissions driven by strong growth in exports to the United States.

9.3 INDUSTRIAL ENERGY EFFICIENCY SCENARIOS TO 2030 WITH GOVERNMENTINTERVENTION

The CIMS model76 explores an achievable potential,rather than one that may be only technically feasible.Energy efficiency actions are adopted according to a technology competition that represents firm pur-chasing decisions based not only on minimization ofannualized life-cycle costs, but also on performancepreferences, cost heterogeneity, option value and failure risk.

Table 2: Baseline Forecast of GHG Emissions and Energy Consumption for Canada

2000 2010 2020 2030 Average Annual Growth

GHG emissions (Mt CO2e) 288 343 396 453 1.53%Direct 237 307 358 407 1.82%Indirect 50 36 38 46 -0.30%

Energy (PJ) 4,239 5,030 5,783 6,579 1.48%

Findings INDUSTRIAL ENERGY EFFICIENCY

• A $15/tonne CO2e shadow price wouldlead to a reduction of 46 Mt CO2e by2030, compared with the BAU scenario.

• A $30/tonne CO2e shadow price wouldlead to a reduction of 58 Mt CO2e by2030, compared with the BAU scenario.

Page 65: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

The case study used two alternative forecasts, LowCarbon I and Low Carbon II, which model a shadowprice for carbon of $15/tonne CO2e and $30/tonneCO2e respectively, to influence a shift in investmentpatterns over a 25-year period (2005–2030). Theprice was also applied to the electricity sector so thata carbon price can be reflected in the electricity priceseen by the industry sub-sectors.

Table 3 summarizes the results of the Low Carbon Iand Low Carbon II scenarios relative to the baselinebusiness-as-usual scenario in Table 2. In Low CarbonI, GHG emissions are reduced by 46 Mt CO2e; in Low Carbon II, GHG emissions are reduced by 58 Mt CO2e. Direct emissions make up most ofthese emission reductions, though the response ofindirect emissions to the imposition of a shadowprice is stronger than the response of direct emissions (indirect emissions decline by 53 to 62 percent in 2030, while direct emissions decline by only 5 to 7 percent). Actions behind this strong indirect response include the greater adoption of cogeneration systems and actions that improve the overall efficiency of auxiliary motor systems. The metal smelting and refining sector, petroleumrefining, and iron and steel sub-sectors contribute the most emission reductions because of improvedenergy efficiency.

Ex ante financial costs are –$17.64 billion for theLow Carbon I scenario and –$24.87 billion for theLow Carbon II scenario (2000 dollars). In otherwords, the value of energy savings (discounted to2004 at a rate of 20 percent) is greater than any asso-ciated increase in upfront capital costs for all industrysub-sectors; this is revealed as a negative cost.

These estimates do not account for risk, option value,market heterogeneity and perceived quantitative orqualitative advantage of product preferences; there-fore, they do not reflect the full compensationrequired for firms to make the technology switch(i.e., the energy efficiency gap). The total monetaryincentive needed to overcome baseline technologypreferences (e.g., through a subsidy) is $2.012 billionfor Low Carbon I and $4.885 billion for Low Carbon II(2000 dollars). Notably, this incentive is for a pro-gram perfectly designed to target cost-effectiveactions; it does not include expenditures required to subsidize firms that have already undertaken thetechnology switch in the baseline scenario, a groupthat can often be in the order of 40 to 85 percent ofprogram recipients in previous evaluations of energyefficiency programs.

Further detail on the case study findings is providedin Appendix A.

51Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

Table 3: GHG Emissions and Energy for Alternative Scenarios, Canada

2000 2010 2020 2030Total GHG emissions (Mt CO2e)

BAU 288 343 396 453Low Carbon I 288 322 365 407Low Carbon II 288 316 355 395

Direct GHG emissions (Mt CO2e)BAU 237 307 358 407Low Carbon I 237 292 339 386Low Carbon II 237 293 335 378

Indirect GHG emissions (Mt CO2e)BAU 50 36 38 46Low Carbon I 50 29 26 22Low Carbon II 50 23 20 17

Energy (PJ)BAU 4,239 5,030 5,783 6,579Low Carbon I 4,239 4,822 5,537 6,298Low Carbon II 4,239 4,818 5,497 6,232

BAU = business as usual

Page 66: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

52 National Round Table on the Environment and the Economy

9.4 MACROECONOMIC IMPACT: INDUSTRIALENERGY EFFICIENCY CASE STUDY

The macroeconomic impact of the proposed instru-ments in the industrial energy efficiency case studycan be summarized as follows:

• Aggregate macroeconomic impact: Insignificant froma national perspective.

• Distributional and competitiveness impact: Possibledistributional impact varies with the specific typeof instrument employed. Subsidies would produceno price increases and could even lower outputprices. Emissions pricing (through taxes or tradable permits) will increase costs for industry.However, these costs will in part be offset by savings from energy efficiency and fuel switching,including cogeneration. Many industries experi-ence cost increases of less than 1 percent of the value of output. Under a shadow price of$15/tonne, price impact varies from reductions of0.4 percent in the chemical products and pulp andpaper sectors to an increase of more than 5 per-cent in the industrial minerals sector. There arefewer cases of cost decreases at $30/tonne, andcosts (as a percentage of the value of output)increase more than 12 percent in the industrialminerals sector. When the price responsiveness ofdomestic and international markets is considered,only the industrial minerals and the iron and steelsectors experience changes in output prices highenough to reduce output.

These impacts assume no mitigation policies areimplemented.

• Effects on technological change: The impact onlong-term technological change is very uncertainand will depend in part upon the types of instru-ments employed and the detailed design of thoseinstruments. However, there is also empirical evidence that the energy price shocks of the 1970s clearly stimulated investment in R&D for more efficient equipment.

Further detail on the macroeconomic impact of theproposed instruments can be found in a backgroundpaper for the EFR and Energy Program.77

9.5 POLICY IMPLICATIONS: INDUSTRIALENERGY EFFICIENCY

The strategic significance of having carbon emissionreductions as a priority objective is well illustrated in

the energy efficiency case study, where three relatedpolicy objectives can each lead to very differentactions being taken:

• An emphasis on industrial energy efficiency alonecan, in some cases, result in increased carbonintensity. While improved energy efficiency inindustry is closely connected to fuel switching andother means of carbon emission reduction, thereare instances where increased energy efficiency can also increase carbon intensity. For instance, anefficient coal-fired boiler is more efficient than awood-fired or certain natural gas–fired boilers.This emphasis would support other energy policypriorities, such as the need to narrow forecast gapsbetween energy demand and supply.

• A dual emphasis on carbon efficiency and energyefficiency, as explored in the case study, wouldencourage only those energy efficiency actions thatalso provide carbon reduction dividends.

• An emphasis on greenhouse gas mitigation alonewould open the door to non-efficiency means toreduce emissions such as fuel switching, reducingfugitive emissions, reducing process emissions, andthe capture and storage of carbon dioxide. Theseemission reductions are sometimes more cost-effective than those occurring through energyefficiency.

These findings illustrate the importance of pursuing adual objective—an approach that will also support abroader set of public policy objectives, including narrowing the supply gap.

The underlying conclusion from the case study isthat the issue of energy efficiency in the industrialsector is essentially an issue of project finance.Industrial firms are assumed to be generally morelikely than households to have already pursued cost-effective options to reduce energy consumption.Nonetheless, research over the past 30 years has consistently shown that firms and consumers forgoapparently cost-effective investments in energy efficiency. The results of the energy efficiency casestudy’s economic analysis confirm this general knowl-edge, identifying energy savings78 greater than theassociated capital cost investments for all of theindustry sub-sectors analyzed. Why do firms notmake these investments? One reason is that energyefficiency projects must compete for capital within afirm and may simply not meet internal required ratesof return—or may not be as attractive as alternativeinvestments, such as investments in productivity

Page 67: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

improvement. These situations offer a sound businessopportunity for third-party engineering and/orfinance firms. Another reason may be that firms hesitate to adopt new technologies, which carry agreater potential for failure.

The market setting within which a firm operatesexerts a powerful influence on its energy efficiencyinvestment decisions. In markets with strong growthand competition, efficiency with respect to energyand other inputs is necessary to survive. In contrast,stagnating markets are poor theatres for innovationand investment, and instead rely on already depreci-ated equipment to maintain low production costs.79

Projects designed to promote energy efficiency com-pete against a variety of other projects for corporateinvestment. In highly energy-intensive industries,firms have a strong incentive to invest in moreenergy-efficient systems. In other sectors, however,the most promising investments may lie in the devel-opment of new products or in modernization andrestructuring projects that do not yield accompanyinggains in energy efficiency. For small and medium-sized enterprises (SMEs) with very limited investmentcapital, there are especially strong economic pressuresto avoid projects with the long paybacks that are typ-ical of energy-saving measures.80 Furthermore, SMEsoften do not have the internal expertise to identifyand follow up on energy efficiency opportunities.

These findings underscore the role that energy pricesand market forces play in stimulating energy effi-ciency actions, as well as the need for a price signalgiven that current prices appear too low to stimulatemajor efficiency improvements. The choice of appro-priate fiscal instrument is between targeted measuresthat relate to one set of technologies or one particularsector, or a broad fiscal instrument that does notassign technological or sectoral preference. In eitherscenario, the ultimate impact is largely a function ofthe level at which the instrument is set (in the casestudy itself, the “shadow carbon price”). This levelmust at the very least overcome the hurdle of theenergy efficiency gap.

The case study concludes that policy interventionwould be most appropriate at the two ends of theproduct pipeline: (1) the market uptake of existing(and eventually emerging) technologies and processesand (2) the research and development related to thedevelopment of new energy efficiency technologies,particularly those that offer significant energy efficiency benefits.

There is an obviously close relationship between thetwo stages, inasmuch as they involve a cycle of invest-ment, development and market uptake, which isdynamic and ongoing. In this scenario, promotingthe market uptake of “on the shelf ” technologiesleads to reinvestment into new generations of energyefficiency technologies, and so to a virtuous cycle of investment leading to R&D and continuousimprovement in energy efficiency performance.Improvements in energy efficiency performance follow an incrementally positive trend, as seen in the cumulative impact of the 1 percent per yearenergy efficiency improvements observed under theCanadian Industry Program for Energy Conservation.

For the mature industrial energy efficiency technolo-gies, policy intervention should encourage marketuptake of existing technologies and processes. Thechoice of EFR tools to do this will be influenced bythe nature of the industrial energy efficiency oppor-tunities. Energy use in industry can be categorizedinto generic or auxiliary services (steam generation,lighting, HVAC [heating, ventilation, air condition-ing], and electric motors) and processes unique toeach specific sector and even each facility. Within this latter category of use, the energy efficiencyopportunity is characterized by countless specific and differentiated technologies and processes, notonly among different sectors but also among theoperations within one sector.

Fiscal tools for industrial energy efficiency have beendominated by capital cost allowance tax measures, an approach that, for tax administration purposes, istechnology-prescriptive. It is therefore well suited forgeneric and auxiliary technologies with widespreadapplication. These tools are less suited to sector- and facility-specific processes, where the energy efficiency opportunity is characterized by countless,differentiated technologies and processes among dif-ferent sectors and among the operations within onesector. They are also less suited to the system-basedor sector- and/or process-specific technology oppor-tunities, which are radical in nature. An example isprocess substitution using membrane techniques orbiotechnology instead of thermal processes, orimprovements to the material efficiency of produc-tion. These categories of opportunity are bettersupported through broad-based fiscal measures that are performance-based (as opposed to tech-nology-prescriptive), such as an emissions tax ormarket-oriented regulation (tradable permits). Under this approach, government sets a target backed by regulation—which can be emissions-based

53Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

Page 68: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

54 National Round Table on the Environment and the Economy

(for certainty of environmental outcome) or technol-ogy-based (for certainty of market outcome)—andallocates tradable permits81 (by auction and/or bygratis) to all subject parties. This approach allowsindividual flexibility in achieving the compulsorylimit or requirement—the party can either meet thetarget or pay others to do so. In addition, experiencewith this approach indicates that it is more efficientthan subsidies in preventing rebound effects and in providing a long-term signal for technologicalinnovation.

Program participants felt that tax measures alone areunable to address the diversity of industrial energyefficiency technological opportunities or system-based improvements; in addition, there was concernabout the large public expenditure per unit of effecttypically experienced in subsidy programs, because ofthe presence of firms that would have undertaken thedesired change even in the absence of the subsidy.

At a theoretical level, participants favoured the emis-sions tax, and it has been shown in other research tobe economically attractive, particularly when compet-itiveness concerns are addressed through the creativerecycling of revenues, sectoral exemptions and bordertax adjustments.82 However, an emissions priceapplied to the industrial sector was considered bymost to be politically unviable despite its very limitedeffect on output: the macroeconomic assessment ofthe impact of the case study’s $30/tonne CO2e pricesignal (with no mitigation policies) concluded thatonly the industrial minerals and the iron and steelsectors would experience changes in output priceshigh enough to reduce output.

For these reasons, participants considered market-oriented regulation (similar to the LFE domesticemissions trading system) to be the most environ-mentally effective, economically efficient andpolitically acceptable means of encouraging marketuptake of energy-efficient technologies and processesin the manufacturing and mining industries.

Not all energy efficiency technologies are maturetechnologies. Others are at the demonstration stageor have been applied in a relatively narrow niche (e.g., direct reduction in iron and steel). Still othershave not been technically realized and are the subject of active research and development programs.Technological innovation may be incremental (smalland gradual innovation in existing technologies) orradical (the development and introduction into themarketplace of new technologies or processes thatdramatically improve energy efficiency performance).

It is not always possible to predict which type will bemore effective in reducing energy over longer periods.

Radical innovation is where the step changes inenergy efficiency are to be found. At the same time,much greater capital stock replacement is required for these radical, process-based innovations than forincremental innovations that may only involve sometechnological components. The need for greater capi-tal stock replacement presents an additional hurdle to the adoption of radically innovative technologies,since the energy efficiency marketplace, especially inthe industrial sector, is bound by the timetables ofcapital stock turnover. It is thus difficult to predicthow such innovation will contribute to decarbonizingthe energy system. The impact of not includingfuture radical innovation may make the analysis conservative.

Recommendation To support long-term carbon emissionreductions through the adoption ofindustrial energy efficiency, the federalgovernment should:

a) Integrate a carbon efficiency focus inactivities to promote energy efficiency,so that these activities do not per-versely increase carbon emissions.

b) Implement a broad-based price signalfor carbon emission reductions.

c) If (b) is not possible, augment targetedtax measures (best suited to generic and auxiliary technologies) with broader,market-oriented regulation (either emis-sions- or technology-based) to capturesystem-wide opportunities.

d) Provide R&D support for the developmentof new energy efficiency technologies,particularly those that offer radicalenergy efficiency benefits (e.g., throughnew production processes). Support, inthe form of targeted tax measures, shouldcontinue through to commercialization of the technology.

Page 69: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

10. SPECIFIC FINDINGS:EMERGING RENEWABLEPOWER TECHNOLOGIES

Emerging renewable power was delineated in thisstudy as EcoLogo-certifiable, electricity-generating,grid-connected technologies. The scope of technolo-gies covered includes wind turbines (onshore andoffshore), small hydro, grid-connected photovoltaics(PV), landfill gas (for electricity generation), biomass(for electricity generation), ocean energy (includingwave and tidal power conversion technologies) andgeothermal. Thermal technologies, such as ground-source heat pumps, solar hot water heaters andstand-alone systems, were excluded because of modelling constraints, and large hydroelectricity was not included because it was considered a mature technology. Participants highlighted theseexclusions, cautioning that these renewable sourcesare significant and also need to be considered whendesigning policy.

Emerging renewable power technologies face manybarriers to development: market acceptance anddemand, permitting and community acceptance,intermittency of the resource, proximity of resourcesto transmission grids, insufficient transmission capac-ity, dearth of resource mapping, lack of engineeringstandards and national technical rule making, short-ages in trained technical labour, and a wide variety ofpolicies and regulations that, inadvertently perhaps,give preference to other technologies.83

Added to this long list are economic barriers. Theseinclude generally higher prices than for conventionalelectricity sources, although steep cost reductionsfrom economies of scale and continued research anddevelopment are forecast. Renewable energy facilitiesare normally capital-intensive but have no ongoingfuel costs (with the exception of biomass); this makestheir economic viability sensitive to the cost of capi-tal and the ability to reduce capital costs. Generally,access into the market is favoured by retail competi-tion in deregulated electricity markets. Investors tendto see emerging renewable energy technologies ashigh risk, and immature public policy and changingfiscal incentives in the field contribute to a lack ofcertainty.84

These barriers combine to create a large gap betweenthe technical resource potential for emerging renew-able power and actual installed capacity. Technicalresource potential was estimated in the case study at68,500 to 336,600 MW capacity and 244,700 to1,210,400 GWh/yr supply, compared with an actualinstalled base today of only 2,300 MW capacity and12,100 GWh/yr supply.85

This case study, like the others, encountered challenges in data reliability. The study identifiedtechnical potential for emerging renewables (the long-term “upper limit” of installed capacity for agiven technology) and practical potential (a largelysubjective estimate of the generating capacity of agiven technology that could reasonably be installedwithin a given time period). The discussion of thedata revealed that different studies and individualsinterpret these potentials differently. For example, theassessment of practical potential relies on an appraisalof whether the resource is accessible and/or whetherit is possible to access with transmission upgrades.How should transmission constraints be assessed?What level of investment is needed to enhance transmission? Who should ultimately pay for these connections?

Some participants in the EFR and Energy Programfelt that current analysis may also overemphasize central power generation; this would diminish theimpact of the small-scale, distributed power genera-tion that is evolving in many jurisdictions. There wasalso discussion of whether there would eventuallyneed to be limits to renewable power generation to preserve grid stability. It was noted that somerenewables (e.g., wind and hydro) complement oneanother in such a way as to increase grid stability.

10.1 STATUS OF THE EMERGING RENEWABLEPOWER SECTOR

In 2003, the installed base of emerging renewablepower technologies (using the boundaries describedabove) in Canada was approximately 2,300 MW. Itgenerated an estimated 12,100 GWh of electricityand accounted for about 2 percent of Canada’sinstalled electricity generation capacity. Of this,hydro represents 1,800 MW and 9,460 GWh/yr; ifthe large hydro screened out by the EcoLogo criteriawere included, the total installed capacity for hydrowould be 68,100 MW, generating 346,000 GWh, or 59 percent of Canada’s total annual electricity generation of 589,500 GWh.

55Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

Page 70: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

56 National Round Table on the Environment and the Economy

Looking beyond Canada, in 2001 renewable energysources provided 5.7 percent of total primary energysupply for the OECD countries, of which 54 percentwas supplied by combustible renewables and waste,86

35 percent by hydro power and 12 percent by geo-thermal, solar, wind and tide energy. Worldwide,renewables represented 15 percent of electrical energyproduction worldwide, but only 2.1 percent if oneexcludes large hydro.

10.2 STATUS OF THE EMERGING RENEWABLEPOWER SECTOR TO 2030 ASSUMINGBUSINESS AS USUAL

The business-as-usual scenario for emerging renew-able power technologies in 2030 identified thetechnical potential and the practical resource poten-tial of each technology. The technical potential is thelong-term “upper limit” of installed capacity for agiven technology.87 The practical potential is a subsetof technical potential; it refers to the generatingcapacity of a given technology that could “practically”be installed within a specific time period.88

The research results unearthed a very wide range ofestimates, and therefore the data for both technicaland practical potential are estimates. For total (notadditional) technical resource potential, a low capacity of 68,550 MW and a high capacity of336,600 MW were estimated. These translated to a supply of 244,700 GWh/yr at the low end and1,210,400 GWh/yr at the high end. The estimatedpractical potential of emerging renewable power inCanada is identified in Table 4, using ranges toreflect the inherent uncertainty.89

For comparison, the United States aims to nearlydouble energy production from renewable sources(excluding hydro) between 2000 and 2025, while theEuropean Union has adopted a target for 2010 of22.1 percent of electricity from renewable energy and 12 percent of renewables in gross national energy consumption.

Table 4: Estimated Practical Resource Potential of Grid-Power Renewable Energy Technologies (RET) in Canada, 2010 and 2020

Grid-Power RET Capacity (MW) Supply (GWh/yr)(EcoLogo certifiable) 2010 2020 2010 2020

Low High Low High Low High Low HighTotal estimated practical resource potential 12,434 22,185+ 26,829+ 51,295+ 57,412 98,260+ 112,512+ 174,700+

“+” indicates that lack of data has led to an underestimation of practical resource potential. Full details on underlying data can be found in Appendix B.

Emerging Renewable PowerTo achieve a 12 percent reduction in emis-sions would require:

• an emissions price of $10/tonne CO2; or

• a 24 percent renewable portfolio standard; or

• a $0.006/kWh renewable generation subsidy; or

• a combination of a 24.21 percent renew-able portfolio standard plus a $0.002/kWhrenewable generation subsidy; or

• a 61 percent increase in renewable energy R&D.

Page 71: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

10.3 STATUS OF THE EMERGING RENEWABLEPOWER SECTOR TO 2030 WITH GOVERNMENT INTERVENTION

The model used for the emerging renewable powercase study sets one emission reduction target (in thiscase a 12 percent reduction in carbon emissions fromthe base case) and then assesses a variety of policyoptions for achieving this target. The model has twostages: 2010–2015 and 2015–2030; electricity gener-ation, consumption and emissions occur in both,while investment in knowledge takes place in the first stage, followed by technological change andinnovation that lowers the cost of renewable powergeneration in the second. Fossil fuel is assumed to be the marginal technology that would be displacedby renewable generation and that sets the overallmarket price.

The carbon intensity of the electricity market hingeson three drivers:

• Renewable power penetration: How much of totalCanadian electricity generation is supplied byrenewable power. This driver is affected by thecost of renewable compared with fossil fuel generation.

• Carbon intensity of fossil fuel generation: How muchcarbon a unit of electricity generated by fossil fuelscontains. This driver is affected by the cost of carbon emissions.

• Total electricity demand: Determined by consumerenergy efficiency and conservation. This driver isaffected by the price of electricity.

The economic efficiency and environmental effective-ness of these instruments is linked to their ability toinfluence the entire electricity market and the threedecarbonizing drivers in particular. As a general rule,the economic instrument will be more efficient andeffective if it signals to multiple agents in the electric-ity market that carbon is more expensive: fossilenergy producers will reduce their emission intensity;renewable energy producers will supply more outputwhen the price difference between renewable and fossil generation decreases; and consumers will takemeasures to conserve electricity, reduce demand and

displace fossil output. This finding holds up undermultiple input variable assumptions and explains whyan emissions price is preferable to a renewable portfo-lio standard or renewable generating subsidy. TheR&D instrument scenario offers a good example ofthe increased risk in using a single instrument: herethe emission reduction depends entirely on the abilityof R&D investments to reduce the costs of renew-ables through innovation. While cost reductions canbe expected to result from R&D spending, the scopeand scale of the cost reductions are questionable,increasing the overall uncertainty in the instrument.

The model used in the case study showed that thetarget of a 12 percent reduction in emissions (com-pared with the business-as-usual case) could beachieved through any of the following instruments:

• a carbon emissions permit price of $10/tonneCO2;

• a 24 percent renewable portfolio standard, whichrequires green certificates, or the equivalent, to bepurchased by utilities so that renewable generationincreases relative to fossil fuel generation;

• a $0.006/kWh renewable generation subsidy,modelled as a direct subsidy from government toemerging renewable power producers;

• a combination of a 24.21 percent renewable portfolio standard and $0.002 renewable genera-tion subsidy, modelled in tandem; and

• a 61 percent increase in renewable research subsidies to reduce the cost of future renewableenergy generation.

The modelling results for each of these instrumentsare listed in Table 5. A summary of the distributionalresults of the instruments is provided in Table 6.Further detail on the case study findings is providedin Appendix B.

57Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

Page 72: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

58 National Round Table on the Environment and the Economy

Table 5: Summary of Modelling Results for Fiscal Instruments (2000 $)

Base case Emissions Renewable Renewable Combination Renewable price portfolio generation RPS and research

standard subsidy RGS subsidy1. Policy level for 12%

emission reduction $10/t CO2 24% of $0.006 RPS=24.21% 61%generation RGS=$0.002in case*

2. Electricity price (in $/kWh)1st stage $0.092 $0.097 $0.095 $0.092 $0.095 $0.0922nd stage $0.092 $0.097 $0.093 $0.092 $0.092 $0.092

3. Carbon emissions (Mt)1st stage 106 98.10 91.00 98.97 91.08 104.002nd stage 101 84.40 91.90 83.50 91.95 77.40

4. Renewable output (MWh 10^11) 1st stage 0.29 0.40 0.54 0.42 0.55 0.312nd stage 0.38 0.66 0.55 0.72 0.55 0.83

5. Fossil output (MWh 10^11)1st stage 2.00 1.85 1.71 1.87 1.72 1.982nd stage 1.91 1.59 1.73 1.57 1.73 1.46

6. Total electricity output (MWh 10^11)1st stage 2.29 2.25 2.26 2.29 2.27 2.292nd stage 2.29 2.25 2.28 2.29 2.29 2.29

7. Renewable R&D ($M) $129 $450 $320 $533 $325 $1,5768. Additional renewable

cost reduction 0% 15% 13% 16% 13% 26%9. �Consumer surplus ($M) $0 ($11,690) ($4,521) $0 ($3,533) $010.�Producer surplus ($M) $0 $2, 215 $3,480 $2,846 $3,547 $1,59011.�Transfers ($M) $0 $8,896 $0 ($3,557) ($1,072) ($3,890)12.�Welfare—no benefits

measured ($M) (9+10+11=12) $0 ($579) ($1,041) ($711) ($1,058) ($2,300)

13.�Welfare relative to emissions price — 1.00 1.80 1.23 1.83 3.97

Figures may not sum due to rounding. * This is 9% of all annual Canadian generation.

Source: Marbek Resource Consultants and Resources for the Future.

Page 73: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

59Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

Table 6: Summary of Distributional Results

I. II. III. IV. V. VI. Base case Emissions Renewable Renewable Combination Renewable

price portfolio generation RPS and research standard subsidy RGS subsidy

To achieve a 12% carbon emission reduction target from 2010 to 2030, you would see…

Impacts on electricity generation

Impacts on consumers

Impacts on government

Impacts on the renewable sector

(No attemptto reach target)

Renewablesgain somemarketshare; carbon isreduced by5%

Status quo

Status quo

Status quo;some continuedpenetration

Emitters pay$10 for eachtonne of CO2

Renewablespenetrateslightly morequickly than inI; electricityproducers workhardest onreducing car-bon emissions

Electricityprices rise the most; conservationemphasized;negativeimpacts onsome sectors

Governmentrevenues raised(as governmentcollects onemissionsprice); redistribution toaffected sectorsis possible

Output up;productioncost down;some profit;R&D levelshigh

Renewableshave a 24%share of casestudy genera-tion—9% ofannual totalCanadiangeneration

A greaterpenetrationof renewablesthan in II;costly forelectricityproducers atfirst butcosts fallover time

Overall elec-tricity pricesare lowerthan in II,but rise andthen fall; con-servation notemphasized

No governmentrevenuesraised, lostor transferred

Output upmore than inII; slightlymore profitthan in II;but less R&Dis done

Governmentsubsidy of$0.006 foreach kWhgenerated byrenewables

A greaterpenetrationof renewablesthan in II;not a driverof loweremissionsintensity (= higherefficiency)

Electricityprices remainthe same;conservationnot empha-sized

Governmentmakes significantdisbursementsto fund thesubsidy

Greater profits asmore produc-tion lowerscosts; highinvestmentin R&D

An RPS at24.21% andan RGS at$0.002

Slightly morerenewablesin the mix;fossil fuel–generatedoutputremainsunchanged

Electricitypricesslightly lowerthan in IV;conservationnot empha-sized

Governmentmakes dis-bursements($1 billion)to fund thesubsidy

Outputslightlyhigher; R&Dalso higher

The publicand privatesectorsincreasetheir R&Dspending by61%

High pene-tration ofrenewablesnear end oftime frameonly

Electricityprices remainunchanged;conservationnot empha-sized

Governmentmakes significantdisbursementsto fund R&Din renewables

Highestpotentialpenetrationnear end oftime framewith highR&D

Table 6 continued on next page

Page 74: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

60 National Round Table on the Environment and the Economy

10.4 MACROECONOMIC IMPACT: EMERGINGRENEWABLES CASE STUDY

This case study considers a variety of potential instru-ments for meeting a predefined emission reductiontarget of 12 percent in the electricity sector. Theseinstruments differ in overall costs, distributionalimpacts, risks and effects on technological change.

The macroeconomic impacts of the instruments proposed in the renewables case study can be summarized as follows:

• Aggregate macroeconomic impact: Insignificant froma national perspective.

• Distributional and competitiveness impact: Variesgreatly depending upon the instrument employed.

In the case of subsidies, costs are borne by taxpayersand widely distributed throughout the economy.Consumers do not see any increases in electricityprices. In the case of emissions pricing and renewableportfolio standards, costs are borne primarily by consumers. Increases in electricity prices will disproportionately affect low-income households.

Emissions prices, renewable portfolio standards andrenewable energy subsidies can all lead to windfallprofits for some producers of emerging renewablesthat are already cost-competitive with conventionalfossil fuel plants.

The regional and sectoral impact is more difficult to estimate. The case study was conducted from anational perspective. At the national level, averageelectricity prices increase from zero under subsidies to 5 percent under emissions pricing. These increasesare relatively small from a national perspective, particularly in light of a 20-year phase-in and thepossibility of revenue recycling to offset price impact.However, the national averages could mask importantdifferences in price impact across regions and endusers. These differences, in turn, could affect somesectors more than others. The impact will alsodepend on the instrument used and its design.

In the case of emissions pricing, costs will be highestin jurisdictions with higher fossil fuel–based electric-ity generation (e.g., Alberta, Saskatchewan and NewBrunswick), with a higher percentage change forindustry and a lower percentage change for house

Table 6: Summary of Distributional Results (cont’d)

I. II. III. IV. V. VI. Base case Emissions Renewable Renewable Combination Renewable

price portfolio generation RPS and research standard subsidy RGS subsidy

Impacts on Canadian societal welfare*

Level of uncertainty in reaching target

* = adding together (1) costs to consumers and (2) losses/profits of electricity producers (both renewable and fossil fuel) and (3) net government revenues, but excluding environmental costs/benefits (e.g., the costs of adapting to climate change are notincluded here).

Status quo

Target is notachieved

Overall lowestwelfare costsof the fiveoptions

Low; all long-term carbonemissionreduction driv-ers are actedon to worktoward target

Greater wel-fare coststhan in IIand lowerthan in IV

Medium; onlytwo long-term carbonemissionreductiondriversaffected

Second highest welfare costs

Medium–high; onlyone long-term carbonemissionreductiondriveraffected

Welfare costsslightly lowerthan in IV

Medium; onlytwo long-term carbonemissionreductiondriversaffected

Highest welfare costs

High due toreliance onone long-term carbonemissionreductiondriver (pene-tration notassured)

Page 75: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

holds. In the case of an RPS, regional price impactwill depend on the existing percentage of renewablepower generation in each province and the costs of renewable energy supply. If credit trading is per-mitted among provinces, regional cost differencesmight be small under an RPS because provinces withhigher-cost supplies could access lower-cost sourcesin other provinces. Provinces with low-cost supplieswould in turn pay higher prices as a result of nationaltrading.90

Assuming minimum regional variation in priceincreases and using national average changes, sector-specific impact can be assessed using nationalelectricity intensities by sector. Costs for most sectorswould increase by no more than 0.1 percent. Costincreases are highest for metal mining and smelting(1.6 percent in 2010) and for pulp and paper (0.8 percent in 2010), both electricity-intensive sectors. Metal mining, and pulp and paper are alsohighly export-intensive sectors, raising concernsabout the broader impact on competitiveness andtrade.91 Even though larger, the relative change inprices is still small, and the impact on exports couldbe mitigated through policy design.

• Effects on technological change: This case studyincluded an explicit analysis of the effects ofinstruments on technological change. Dependingon the fiscal instrument, the case study estimates a 58 to 80 percent increase in production fromrenewables over the study period. Annual R&Dspending on renewables increases by $22 to $172 million compared with the base case.Increased R&D, together with increased penetra-tion of technologies, produces cost reductions of13 to 26 percent. These cost reductions, however,are uncertain and depend in part on the success ofR&D spending in earlier periods. The effects ontechnological change could vary greatly amonginstruments and could be enhanced through thedesign of individual instruments.

Further detail on the macroeconomic impacts of theproposed instruments can be found in a backgroundpaper prepared for the EFR and Energy Program.92

10.5 POLICY IMPLICATIONS: EMERGINGRENEWABLE POWER TECHNOLOGIES

Canada has similar or better renewable energyresources than the nations that are leaders in renewable energy supply. These resources includesubstantial wind potential and viable sites across the country, a rich solar resource (Toronto has moresunshine than Berlin, and Regina more than Tokyo),several thousand potential sites for small hydroelec-tric plants and unused biomass potential. The largeand expanding electricity market also offers attractiveopportunities for the deployment of grid-connectedrenewables.

The rapidly evolving energy policy landscape inCanada (described in more detail in Part 1, Section 3)provides an excellent opportunity and indeed an exi-gency for aggressive policy innovation on emergingrenewable power technologies. Such innovation couldhelp solve growing supply, security and environmen-tal challenges in the short, medium and long term.Aggressive action on renewables would also be a necessary (but not sufficient) component of a carbon-efficient hydrogen strategy, as discussed elsewhere in this report.

Emerging renewable power technologies face manybarriers to development, as described at the top ofthis section. These need to be overcome to enablemaximum uptake of economic instrument–drivenopportunities. Some emerging renewable power technologies are intermittent, and developing them will require complementary sources that cancompensate for this. Large-scale hydro does this well, as will hydrogen.

This case study did not cover non-grid-connectedemerging renewable power technologies, such as geothermal, passive solar and photovoltaics; however,these are considered to have strong potential anddeserve their own set of targeted measures.

61Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

Page 76: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

62 National Round Table on the Environment and the Economy

The study reveals a strong case for the effectivenessand efficiency of economic instruments.93 This conclusion appears to be linked to three factors:

1Market failures of two types work against emerging technologies. First, present fiscal andregulatory regimes have been tailored to supportthe needs of incumbent generation technologies, such as large-scale hydro, nuclear, coal and fossil fuel. Second, market prices do not fullyincorporate environmental externalities, so theenvironmental advantages of emerging renewablesare not recognized in their price.

2Certain classes of emerging renewable energytechnologies (most notably wind but also othersfor niche applications) are near-competitive withincumbent technologies. This puts them in an excellent position to respond to the additionalstimulus of fiscal instrument support.

3Most of these technologies are still produced inlow volumes; therefore, their production costs arecomparatively higher than those of incumbenttechnologies. Economic instruments are able tosupport the cost-reduction and upscaling stages of their evolution.94

Economic instruments that target the price gapbetween emerging renewable energy technologies and incumbent technologies can therefore promotemarket penetration. However, unlike fossil fuel gen-eration, emerging renewable power technologies arecharacterized by high capital costs but lower and lessvolatile operating costs; thus policy certainty anddurability over the long term are essential for investorconfidence. Non-fiscal policies are important ele-ments of this enabling context to remove some of the non-market barriers.

The three drivers determining the carbon intensity ofthe electricity market (renewable power penetration,carbon intensity of fossil fuel generation and totalelectricity demand) are each affected differently bythe different economic instruments. As in both othercase studies, the choice of preferred economic instru-ment will depend on the priority policy objective:

• If the exclusive priority is economically efficient,long-term carbon emission reductions, an emis-sions price is the preferred option.

• However, a scenario with multiple policy objec-tives is more likely. In this case a renewableportfolio standard or a renewable generation subsidy are the preferred options for maximizingrenewable output because they target production asopposed to consumption. Here, producer-targetedfiscal instruments such as accelerated capital costallowance or government procurement programscan help mitigate the large upfront capital costs ofa renewable power generating project. For con-sumers, the fact that the end product of renewablepower—electricity—is not segregated according toits source means that consumption incentives arerelatively “invisible” and therefore not as effective.Combining the RPS with an RGS alleviates someof the distributional consequences of an RPS onits own and also leads to the fastest penetration of emerging renewables.

• An emphasis on R&D investment, on its own,could lead to major increases in renewable outputbut only in the 2015–2030 period—and with significant government disbursement and veryhigh levels of uncertainty.

Participants in the EFR and Energy Program cau-tioned against economic instruments that exclusivelyencourage current least-cost choices. These will consistently select more mature technologies, reward-ing wind or biomass production, for example, andprecluding solar from benefiting from the learning by doing and economies of scale that will help makeit more competitive. Production incentives should be broadened to enable a wide choice of emergingtechnologies, with different levels of subsidy set foreach technology according to the cost difference thatmust be overcome. Policy-makers should be aware,however, that such targeting of less mature technolo-gies will be more costly and may not always lead toCanadian R&D benefits, because Canada importsmany renewable technologies.

Page 77: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

There is also concern that the existing renewable generation subsidy, the Wind Power ProductionIncentive (WPPI), favours centralized production.Renewable power has tremendous potential for dis-tributed production, which will increase the resilienceof the power system. Generation subsidies that aremore supportive of distributed generation should alsobe introduced—feed-in tariffs, which guarantee priceand grid access, have been successful in stimulatingdistributed generation in Denmark, France, Germanyand Spain. Adopting feed-in tariffs, however, wouldalso require supporting policies (net metering andregulations) and infrastructure (distributed powernetworks).

Discussion within the EFR and Energy Program alsoaddressed the impact of Canadian R&D investmentin emerging renewables. Total expenditure on R&Din renewables in Canada was $91 million in 2001and is forecast to increase to $129 million in 2010.Renewable Energy Working Group members agreedthat innovation in emerging renewable technologieswould primarily come from international sources and that Canada would stand to benefit. However,Canadian R&D alone will not be able to shift the supply curve and reduce costs. Moreover, anemphasis on Canadian R&D alone would meandoing without all the current opportunities for carbon reductions from market-ready renewable technologies.

63Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

Recommendation To support long-term carbon emissionreductions through the development ofemerging renewable power technologies, the federal government should ensure thatits policies are fully supportive of, and con-sistent with, provincial policies in this area.Specifically, the federal government should:

a) Implement a broad-based price signal forcarbon emission reductions. This is the onlytool of the ones considered in our studythat will also influence consumer demandand the carbon emission intensity of thefull power system. Or, alternatively:

b) Supplement provincial renewable portfoliostandards—which are being developedacross the country—with a national system for trading of renewable energy certificates (REC),95 and combine this with a federally funded renewable generation subsidy covering a range of emerging technologies. The development of a

national REC market and its relationshipwith a generation subsidy should be care-fully thought through and informed byexperience in other jurisdictions.

c) Facilitate the implementation of feed-intariffs—where a minimum price for electricity generated from emerging renewables is combined with clear gridaccess rules—by working with provinces todevelop clear standards for grid access andpower purchase agreements. Feed-in tariffsare more effective than other policy meas-ures in promoting distributed renewablegeneration, which provides benefits inenergy security and grid stability.

d) Develop targeted measures for non-grid-connected emerging renewables such asgeothermal and passive solar.

e) Expand its program to purchase electricitygenerated from emerging renewable powertechnologies.96

Page 78: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions
Page 79: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

11. SPECIFIC FINDINGS:HYDROGEN ENERGY

Hydrogen energy is defined in this study as anyenergy system where the primary fuel, at some point within the process, is hydrogen. Fuel cells,because they use hydrogen as their primary fuel, are a major component of this sector.97 This studyfocused exclusively on carbon dioxide equivalent98

reductions; however, another main benefit of hydro-gen is reduced urban air emissions and human health benefits.

Hydrogen technologies are generally still in the fun-damental research, prototype development or productdemonstration stages, although there are niche appli-cations in which they are near-competitive withincumbent technologies. Hydrogen technologies face technical, economic and infrastructure barriersto market penetration, as summarized in Table 7.

For further detail and explanation, see Appendix C.

The case study focused on three end uses and pathways:

1On-road transportation applications using hydrogen production from decentralized steammethane reformers (SMRs).

2On-road transportation applications using hydrogen production from decentralized electrolyzers.

3Fuel cells in the residential and commercial sectors, using natural gas from pipelines.

Hydrogen is an energy carrier, not an energy source.This means that the life-cycle environmental impactof hydrogen is closely related to the environmentalprofile of its feedstock or primary energy source. Forhydrogen conversion technologies that use electricityas a feedstock, the carbon intensity will depend onthe technology and fuel type of marginal electricitygeneration. This accounts for some counterintuitivefindings, showing that some hydrogen pathways havethe potential to lead to increases in carbon emissions.

The carbon intensity of hydrogen feedstocks couldpotentially be reduced through carbon capture andsequestration. This technique was not included in the assessments of greenhouse gas emission impact.However, it was noted that the inclusion of carbonsequestration in fossil fuel generation processes signif-icantly alters the energy balance of generation, asgenerated energy is directed away from consumersand into carbon dioxide capture. The cost of thesesystems would also be very different with carbon capture and sequestration.

11.1 STATUS OF THE HYDROGEN ENERGY SECTOR

Canada is a leader in hydrogen technology develop-ment, along with the United States, the UnitedKingdom, Japan and Germany. Hydrogen development spans from early research stages to pre-commercialization and commercialization.

65Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

Table 7: Barriers Limiting Hydrogen Development in Canada

SECTOR ECONOMIC TECHNICALHydrogen fuel infrastructure Cost of hydrogen production Storage, compressors and

Cost of hydrogen distribution distribution networkFuel reformers and processors

Fuel cell technologies Cost of materials and components Durability, perfecting manufacturing Cost of production processes and improving performance Current market design for electricity Maintenance support

Hydrogen fuel infrastructure Need for capital investment Need for codes and standardsand fuel cell technologies and financing integration with other systems

Limited scale of operation

Page 80: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

66 National Round Table on the Environment and the Economy

Developments in hydrogen energy technologies areprimarily focused on three end-use sectors: trans-portation, stationary electricity and heat generation(both for primary and backup power), and portablepower applications. New technologies and productsare being discovered, advanced and introduced to themarketplace every year. Only the most commerciallyadvanced of these technologies were considered,because the focus of this study is on the impact ofhydrogen technologies between now and 2030.

11.2 STATUS OF THE HYDROGEN ENERGYSECTOR TO 2030 ASSUMING BUSINESS AS USUAL

The hydrogen technologies considered in this analysisrealize relatively little market penetration in the business-as-usual (reference) cases. In both the steammethane reformer and the electrolyzer transportationreference cases:

• Energy demand from hydrogen internal combus-tion engine (ICE) light duty vehicles (LDV) andfuel cell LDVs almost triples between 2010 and2030. Demand associated with fuel cell busesremains fairly constant or slightly declines over thestudy period. This is because the price differencebetween diesel and hydrogen creates less incentivefor diesel vehicles to switch to hydrogen. In con-trast, energy demand from conventional LDVsand from conventional transit buses increases byabout 25 percent each over the same study period.

The growth in numbers of hydrogen vehicles andbuses, and in conventional vehicles/buses, followsroughly the same trends.

• The share of energy demand attributable to hydrogen vehicles increases from 1.31 percent oftransportation energy demand in Canada in 2010to 3.1 percent in 2030 in the SMR case, and from1.28 percent in 2010 to 2.8 per cent in 2030 in the electrolyzer case. The share of demand associated with fuel cell buses actually declines.

• There is a slight shift in demand from personallight duty vehicles to fuel cell vehicles and hydrogen ICE vehicles.

• Greenhouse gas emissions from the transportationsector increase from 202.42 Mt/yr in 2010 to266.41 Mt/yr in 2030 in the SMR reference case,and from 204.13 Mt/yr in 2010 to 269.11 Mt/yrin the electrolyzer reference case.

In the business-as-usual forecast for stationary fuelcells, there is also only a small degree of penetrationwithin the study period:

• Total energy consumption associated with thesetechnologies increased from 2.38 PJ in 2015 to 3.02 PJ in 2030. The share of total energydemand remains modest, growing from 0.07 percent in 2012 to 0.16 percent in 2030 of total residential demand, and 0.01 per cent in2012 to 0.03 percent in 2030 of total commercialsector demand.

• Ontario realizes the greatest penetration of station-ary fuel cells, because of relatively high regionalprices for electricity compared with natural gas.Penetration in eastern and northern regions is constrained by limited access to natural gas.

• Greenhouse gas emissions from the residential andcommercial sectors grow from 239.93 Mt/yr in2010 to 274.05 Mt/yr in 2030.

11.3 STATUS OF THE HYDROGEN ENERGYSECTOR TO 2030 ASSUMING GOVERNMENT INTERVENTION

The case study considers the impact of two categoriesof fiscal instruments: consumer incentives and pro-ducer incentives (primarily tax credits and grants).These were chosen for their ability to narrow theprice gap between hydrogen and competing tech-nologies and increase the competitiveness ofhydrogen: producer incentives reduce the cost ofhydrogen production, and consumer incentivesreduce the cost of end-use hydrogen technologies.Consumer and producer incentives from the following list were combined:

• investment tax credits;

• producer tax credits;

• accelerated capital cost allowances;

• research and development grants;

• consumer tax credits; and

• pilot projects.

Page 81: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

These instruments were set at levels to reduce thecosts of producing hydrogen and the upfront cost of end-use hydrogen technologies by between 10 percent (low case) and 25 percent (high case).99

The following analysis focuses on the combinedimpact of producer and consumer incentives underthe high-subsidy case (i.e., a 25 percent reduction incosts for each).

Life-cycle emissions associated with transportationwould decrease by 0.24 Mt/yr, or 0.465 percent withSMR technology, but increase by 0.23 Mt/yr, or0.085 percent, with hydrogen production using electrolysis. This increase is due to the fact that new electricity to power the electrolyzers is generallyassumed to be coming from combined-cycle naturalgas units in the Energy 2020 model.100 (This out-come will depend on the regional mix of electricitygeneration; nonetheless, the increase in emissions inthe case of hydrogen from electrolyzers is consistent with U.S. research.101)

These emission reductions are achieved at high costs:for Alberta in 2010, the cost would be $927/tonnefor reductions from fuel cell buses and $5,090/tonnefor fuel cell cars in the SMR case, and $1,033/tonnefor fuel cell buses in the electrolyzer case (all prices in2000 dollars). For Ontario in the same year, the costwould be lower: $774/tonne for reductions from fuelcell buses and $3,768/tonne for fuel cell cars in theSMR case, and $868/tonne for fuel cell buses in theelectrolyzer case. These costs increase by 2030. Thehigh costs are due to the combined impact of thehigh costs associated with producing hydrogen andpurchasing hydrogen technologies, and the limitedemission reductions achieved with limited penetra-tion of hydrogen technologies in absolute terms. No reductions were achieved from the hydrogeninternal combustion engine and the fuel cell car in the electrolyzer case (i.e., subsidies led to addi-tional emissions).

In the residential sectors, the increased penetration ofstationary fuel cells raises emissions by 0.19 percentby 2030 (57.42 Mt/yr to 57.54 Mt/yr), but this isoffset by reduced emissions in the electric utilitiessector, as fuel cells are used to generate power in housesand less energy is demanded from the electrical grid. A0.3 percent decrease in emissions from the commercialsector between 2010 and 2030 (64.24 Mt/yr to 64.22Mt/yr) arises from the movement away from oil andliquefied petroleum gas as the use of stationary fuelcells increases. Electric utility emissions drop in thesame time period by 0.53 percent (152.38 Mt/yr to

67Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

Hydrogen EnergyReducing the combined costs of producingand consuming hydrogen fuels and technolo-gies by 25 percent leads to an increase by2030 of:

• 47,312 fuel cell vehicles, 33,371 hydrogeninternal combustion engines and 218 fuelcell buses; and

• 15,770 stationary fuel cells in the residen-tial sector and 90 in the commercialsector.

It also reduces greenhouse gas emissions by:

• 1,240 kt from transportation applicationsusing SMR hydrogen production, or 2,650 kt if the hydrogen source is zero-emission; and

• 710 kt from stationary fuel cells in theresidential and commercial sectors.

However,

• greenhouse gas emissions increase fromelectrolyzer transportation applications, if the marginal electricity source is combined-cycle natural gas.

The transportation emission reductions are achieved at high costs (all prices in 2000 dollars):

• For Alberta in 2010, $927/tonne forreductions from fuel cell buses and$5,090/tonne for fuel cell cars in the SMR case, and $1,033/ tonne for fuel cell buses in the electrolyzer case.

• For Ontario in 2010, $774/tonne forreductions from fuel cell buses and$3,768/tonne for fuel cell cars in the SMR case, and $868/tonne for fuel cellbuses in the electrolyzer case.

Page 82: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

68 National Round Table on the Environment and the Economy

151.58 Mt/yr). The total emission reduction between2010 and 2030 from the fiscal measures to promotestationary fuel cells is 0.71 Mt/yr, or 0.26 percent.These reductions come at a lower cost than thosefrom transportation but nonetheless remain verypricey compared with other mitigation options: theCanadian average is $293/tonne in 2010, escalatingto $944/tonne in 2030. There were wide regionaland temporal variations in costs (from $12.50/tonnein British Columbia in 2010 to $1,670/tonne inSaskatchewan in 2030). (All prices are in 2000 dollars.)

These findings are conservative because of theassumptions made for technology development,which were based on current knowledge and projected performance. While it is prudent and necessary, from a public policy point of view, to rely on these conservative assumptions, they are probably not reflective of the real pace of technologydevelopment in the sector. This observation points to a central constraint on public policy in this area,which is particularly acute in the case of hydrogen(but also relevant in the other two cases) because ofthe still-speculative nature of the technology.

Further detail and discussion of the case study findings is provided in Appendix C.

11.4 MACROECONOMIC IMPACT: HYDROGEN CASE STUDY

The case study does not account for any other signif-icant government policies associated with greenhousegas reduction targets, other than those in place whenCanada’s Emission Outlook: An Update was developedfor the National Climate Change Process. Othergreenhouse gas policies could affect the relative price of different fuels and, in turn, the uptake ofhydrogen with or without subsidies. In addition, theanalysis does not account for general breakthroughsor possible developments in hydrogen technologies asa result of policies in other countries.

The macroeconomic impacts of the proposed instru-ments in the hydrogen case study can be summarizedas follows:

• Aggregate macroeconomic impact: Insignificant froma national perspective.

• Distributional and competitiveness impacts: Thecosts of the fiscal instrument vary widely acrossend use, pathway and region. However, since

reductions are achieved entirely through subsidies,these costs are spread out over the entire economy.Uptake will be by actors willing to pay a premiumfor non-financial reasons and, therefore, will likelybe limited to consumers with higher incomes. Thegreatest penetration of stationary fuel cell tech-nologies occurs in Alberta and Ontario based onrelative energy prices, and these jurisdictionswould see the largest share of any co-benefits aris-ing from policy (e.g., reductions in local emissionsof air pollutants). Penetration in the transporta-tion sector is much more evenly distributed acrossthe country. The subsidies could benefit develop-ers of hydrogen technologies, which tend to beclustered in British Columbia and Ontario.However, the magnitude of additional demand is unlikely to be sufficient to stimulate domesticproduction of these technologies.

• Effects on technological change: With the proposedfiscal instruments (higher level of subsidy), there is a 50 percent increase in hydrogen demand fortransportation and a 43 to 67 percent increase inhydrogen-related vehicles by 2030. There is a 472 percent increase in hydrogen demand for stationary fuel cells, with a 230 percent increase in number of installed fuel cells. Although signifi-cant in relative terms, the increases in hydrogenproduction and penetration of hydrogen end-use technologies are small in absolute terms.Moreover, it is unlikely the policy will have significant effects on technological evolution.Advances in the technology are more likely tocome from changes in global demand and policiesin much larger countries.

Further detail on the macroeconomic impacts of theproposed instruments can be found in a backgroundpaper prepared for the EFR and Energy Program.102

11.5 POLICY IMPLICATIONS: HYDROGEN ENERGY

The hydrogen economy holds considerable economicpromise for Canada, although large-scale penetrationof hydrogen technologies (e.g., fuel cell vehicles) isdecades away. Canada is a global leader in the devel-opment of hydrogen technologies and applications,and support from the federal government has beenimportant—in August 2003 alone, the sector received$130 million in additional federal support.

Page 83: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

Continued success, however, will depend on properlypositioning Canadian efforts, particularly withrespect to the development of a North Americanhydrogen transportation industry. Our current leadership position is threatened by rapid progress in the United States and European Union, whichhave multibillion-dollar investment strategies, andinherent weaknesses in Canada’s ability to deliver new technologies at the commercial stage.

Canada’s investments in maintaining capacity andstimulating innovation in this field reflect our ambition to be a player in the emerging hydrogeneconomy. The level of investment is driven primarilyby industrial objectives. A long-term carbon emissionreduction objective alone, or even a broader environ-mental objective, would be unlikely to secure thislevel of investment, although reductions in trans-portation tail-pipe air pollutants are a significantco-benefit of hydrogen technologies.

Whether the production of hydrogen yields environ-mental benefits will depend on its pathways—thechoices of primary energy, intermediate energy carriers, distribution systems and final use. To be carbon-effective, a hydrogen system must contribute,on a life-cycle basis, relatively lower levels of carbonemissions than the incumbent technology. This casestudy confirmed that the choice of primary fuelsource and hydrogen production technology hasmajor implications for carbon emissions and, there-fore, on the cost per tonne of carbon reduction:

• The choice of primary energy source (whether fossil fuel–based or a source such as wind, nuclearor hydro that produces almost no greenhouse gasemissions) can affect greenhouse gas emissionreductions by as much as 175 percent (1,940 ktvs. 3,360 kt for hydrogen produced by SMR).

• On a life-cycle basis, the choice of hydrogen pro-duction technologies can reduce greenhouse gasemissions (in the case of SMR) or increase them(in the case of hydrogen production using electrol-ysis, where combined-cycle natural gas is themarginal energy source). This is because the newelectricity to power the electrolyzers is assumed tobe coming from combined-cycle natural gas units,the dominant technology for generation at themargin. However, this assumption does not holdtrue in every region of the country nor for everyhydrogen pathway.

These findings echo the results from other studies of the greenhouse gas profiles of various hydrogenpathways. For example, a study of several dozentransportation hydrogen pathways conducted for Fuel Cells Canada in 2003 concluded that:

GHG emissions for the hydrogen pathways rangefrom 1.3% to 395% of the gasoline baseline vehicle. With such a wide range in the GHGemission and energy use results it is clear that an unmanaged “Hydrogen Economy” is not apanacea for solving the GHG emissions problemor for resolving the energy security issues for energyimporting nations. There are hydrogen pathwaysthat can produce very significant GHG emissionreductions and energy savings but there are alsopathways that would result in increased GHGemissions and increased energy use. One of thechallenges of managing a transition to a hydrogeneconomy will therefore be ensuring that societyreceive the maximum possible benefits.103

Public investment in hydrogen technologies shouldtherefore focus on lower-carbon (on a life-cycle basis)hydrogen pathways, particularly those from zero-emission primary energy sources.

Adding further complexity to decisions on policy priorities, the same study concluded that the mostcarbon-efficient pathways do not align with the mostenergy-efficient pathways: “the coal to hydrogenpathways have some of the best energy efficiencyresults but the highest GHG results.”104

While Canada has clearly decided to compete in thehydrogen economy, we have not, to date, made anydecisions about the carbon intensity of the hydrogenpath we want to pursue. The government’s presentapproach (i.e., pursuit of a wide diversity of hydrogensources) risks maintaining the momentum towardcarbon-intensive source options. Given the fiscal constraints and the onset of an increasingly carbon-constrained economy—and assuming limited publicfunds to invest in hydrogen, climate change mitiga-tion and other air quality improvements—the timemay be right for a second Canadian public policydecision. Should Canada’s hydrogen strategy beexclusively technology-driven or also consider long-term carbon emission reductions?

69Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

Page 84: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

70 National Round Table on the Environment and the Economy

There could be three different, but compatible,Canadian policy objectives for hydrogen:

1Maintain our flexibility and ability to engage in thehydrogen economy: Canadian capacity and poten-tial in this field is sharply different from that inthe other two case studies—we are already a lead-ing innovator, not merely a technology taker.There are strong industrial strategy reasons for adopting this objective at a minimum. The long-term future of two vital sectors of the Canadianeconomy, the energy and automobile sectors, will be shaped by developments in the hydrogeneconomy.

2Make the transition to the hydrogen economy: Thereare many additional reasons to want Canada to be an early adopter of hydrogen technologies.These include environmental benefits (potentialgreenhouse gas and urban smog reductions),employment benefits particularly in remote com-munities, and increased energy security fromdiversification of primary energy sources andincreased distribution of energy systems.

2 If making the transition to the hydrogen econ-omy is the chosen objective, then policy-makersneed to consider how policies in other energy sec-tors will influence the viability of this transition.A key insight from our modelling work is that theuptake of hydrogen technologies is very sensitiveto the prices of other energy sources (both primary fuels for hydrogen production and competitor fuels). Therefore, the transition to ahydrogen economy will be affected by policies in other energy sectors, such as electricity andnatural gas. These include greenhouse gas policiesthat would affect the relative price of different fuelsand in turn the uptake of hydrogen.

3Use hydrogen as the backbone for a long-term carbon emission reduction strategy: In this case,there would need to be a deliberate focus on car-bon-efficient hydrogen supply options. Ecologicalfiscal reforms implemented in support of this latter objective would not be carbon-neutral butwould differentiate on the basis of the life-cyclecarbon content of hydrogen.

Pursuit of this objective would require action ontwo fronts: enhancing low-carbon105 primaryenergy supplies in the country, and developingcarbon capture and sequestration technologies tomitigate emissions from fossil fuel combustion.

Even under aggressive scenarios for developingemerging renewable technologies, these sourceswill not be sufficient to support the full potentialdemand for hydrogen energy. The most aggressivetargets that have been proposed for emergingrenewables remain in the range of 15 to 16 per-cent of Canadian electricity supply in 2020.106

From a carbon-efficiency perspective, it would bebetter to use energy from renewables to displacecoal generation than to power hydrogen conver-sion. This conclusion further suggests that otherforms of low-carbon electricity, such as large-scale hydro or nuclear, would need to be tappedand even expanded to support a low-carbonhydrogen strategy.

The forecast shortfall in the supply of natural gas is another reason for emphasizing renewables as a primary source for hydrogen energy. For example,an October 2003 report by the U.S. NationalPetroleum Council indicates that conventional gassources will satisfy only 75 percent of continentaldemand over the next 15 years.107 Oil sands production is one significant new source of thisdemand. The Canadian Energy Research Instituteforecasts that “even with … expected additionalsources, gas supply in Canada is expected to flat-ten by 2009 and begin declining by 2016.”108

As demand pressure generates higher natural gasprices, this will also benefit the price competitive-ness of hydrogen energy from renewable sources.

Carbon capture and sequestration (another long-term energy-based carbon emission reductiontechnology) may offer a companion technology forreducing the carbon intensity of other hydrogenpathways. However, the introduction of this miti-gation technology would come at a significant costto the energy balance of hydrogen fuels, makinghydrogen systems more expensive.

The marginal costs of the emission reductions identi-fied in the hydrogen case study greatly exceed thoseidentified under the National Climate ChangeProcess, ranging from $300 (stationary fuel cells) to$2,000/tonne depending on end use and hydrogenpathway. These costs reflect only the cost of govern-ment subsidies and exclude any costs borne byprogram participants, which although voluntarycould still be substantial. In comparison, the NCCPestimated marginal costs of $0 to $10/tonne for theresidential and commercial sectors, $50/tonne for the

Page 85: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

transportation sector under a sector-specific approachand as high as $120/tonne for both sectors under anational target. Despite these high unit costs, totalemission reductions are very small: less than 1 Mt.These small gains would require a subsidy of about$1 billion in 2015, rising to about $1.6 billion peryear by 2030.109 Assuming government expendituresgrow at roughly the same rate as GDP, this subsidywould increase government expenditures by about0.4 percent in 2030.110

These results led to significant debate regardinghydrogen’s potential to contribute to emission reductions, as well as substantial additional inputfrom the hydrogen industry. This process led to twoconclusions:

1The policy instrument modelled (producer andconsumer incentives to cut costs by 10 to 25 per-cent) will not increase the market penetration ofhydrogen technologies, which are still largely inthe research, development and demonstrationstages. This conclusion is based on the prohibitivecost per tonne emission reduction.

2Greater technology uptake might have beenachieved if the case study had been based, not onon-road hydrogen fuel cell vehicles, but on othernear-commercial transportation applications withfewer infrastructure challenges. Many of thesetechnologies are competitive in niche applicationssuch as off-road utility vehicles (e.g., forklifts).These applications are particularly well suited tosettings where diesel is now used but zero emis-sions are desired. The on-road vehicles modelledare particularly challenging since they requirereplacing an entire energy infrastructure—to produce, transport, store and convert the fuel to useful forms and distribute it to end users—as well as changes in the end-use technology.However, these niche applications would notresult in very large emission reductions at thenational scale.

These conclusions point to the need for an integratedhydrogen strategy that considers the best sequence offiscal tools in relation to the development cycles ofhydrogen technologies and business models. An integrated strategy would also need to address informational and regulatory policies that wouldcomplement the fiscal tools.

71Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

Recommendation To support long-term carbon emissionreductions through the use of hydrogenfuel, the federal government should:

a) Drive public investments toward lowercarbon pathways, including carbon-freehydrogen production and elimination of carbon at its source through sequestration.

b) Fund and stimulate increased researchand development to reduce the capitalcosts of fuel cell technologies and toimprove the energy balance and costs of hydrogen production.

c) Continue to focus on transportationapplications with long-term carbonemission reduction potential, in recogni-tion of Canada’s industrial interests inthe fuel cell, hydrogen and auto sectors.

Page 86: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions
Page 87: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

12. MACROECONOMICIMPACTS OF THE PROPOSED MEASURES

As stated earlier, the NRTEE commissioned a quali-tative assessment of the likely macroeconomic costsof the various instruments proposed in the case stud-ies. It then compared these estimates with similarestimates produced in 2000 for the National ClimateChange Process. The NRTEE found that, in general,the aggregate macroeconomic costs of the variousinstruments proposed in the NRTEE case studies are likely much smaller than those proposed for theNCCP. There are several reasons:

• For the most part, the marginal costs of emissionreductions in the case studies are lower than those assumed under the NCCP to meet theKyoto targets.

• The total emission reductions by 2010, even with-out adjusting for possible double-counting amongthe case studies (e.g., both the renewables andenergy efficiency case studies include reductions in the electricity sector), are 3 to 10 times lower in the case studies than those assumed in theNCCP study.

• Some proposed instruments such as subsidies haveno direct impact on prices. Even for instrumentssuch as emission prices, the estimated impacts onenergy and other product prices are smaller thanthose estimated for the NCCP, suggesting morelimited demand feedbacks.

It must be stressed, however, that in all cases themacroeconomic impacts of economic instrumentsrelated to greenhouse gases and energy are still veryuncertain and controversial.

73Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

Page 88: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions
Page 89: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

13. A SUPPORTING SUITE OFCOORDINATED ECONOMICINSTRUMENTS

The coordinated transition strategy described abovedemands a coordinated and synergistic set of sup-porting economic instruments. Adopted as a suite,these would support each technology through itspresent stage of development and prepare the subse-quent additional technology for commercializationand uptake.

75Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

A Coordinated Suite of Economic Instruments

TECHNOLOGY RECOMMENDED INSTRUMENTSBroad-based Targeted Long-term support

Mature: 1. Emissions charge 1. Performance-based R&D subsidies and Already in market at or tradable permit instruments investment incentivescompetitive price (supported by 2. Technology-based

targeted relief) instruments (e.g., CCA)Emerging: 1. Market-based regulationsIn the product (e.g., portfolio standards) commercialization/market and/ordevelopment or market- 2. Subsidies (e.g., ready stages, but face cost production incentives)differential with incumbent technologies and need for learning by doingLonger-term new: R&D subsidies and investment incentivesIn the fundamental research/prototype stage; large technical challenges remain and there is a large cost differential with incumbents

Recommendation The recommendations made above in relation to the three case studies should be adoptedas a coordinated suite, from the short term to the long term, to enable the maximum benefit to be derived from the technologies at the most appropriate point in their projected development, and to mitigate any discontinuity in the implementation of the economic instruments.

Page 90: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

INDUSTRIAL ENERGY EFFICIENCY

• To support long-term carbon emission reduc-tions through the adoption of industrial energyefficiency, the federal government should:

a) Integrate a carbon-efficiency focus in activitiesto promote energy efficiency, so that these activities to promote energy efficiency do not perversely increase carbon emissions.

b) Implement a broad-based price signal for carbon emission reductions.

c) If (b) is not possible, augment targeted taxmeasures (best suited to generic and auxiliarytechnologies) with broader, market-orientedregulation (either emissions- or technology-based) to capture system-wide opportunities.

d) Provide R&D support for the development ofnew energy efficiency technologies, particularlythose that offer radical energy efficiency bene-fits (e.g., through new production processes).Support, in the form of targeted tax measures,should continue through to commercializationof the technology.

EMERGING RENEWABLE POWER TECHNOLOGIES

• To support long-term carbon emission reduc-tions through the development of emergingrenewable power technologies, the federal government should ensure that its policies are fully supportive of, and consistent with,provincial policies in this area. Specifically, the federal government should:

Page 91: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

a) Implement a broad-based price signal for carbon emission reductions. This is the onlytool of the ones considered in our study thatwill also influence consumer demand and thecarbon emission intensity of the full power system. Or, alternatively:

b) Supplement provincial renewable portfolio standards—which are being developed acrossthe country—with a national system for tradingof renewable energy certificates (REC), andcombine this with a federally funded renewablegeneration subsidy covering a range of emergingtechnologies. The development of a nationalREC market and its relationship with a genera-tion subsidy should be carefully thoughtthrough and informed by experience in other jurisdictions.

c) Facilitate the implementation of feed-in tar-iffs—where a minimum price for electricitygenerated from emerging renewables is com-bined with clear grid access rules—by workingwith provinces to develop clear standards forgrid access and power purchase agreements.Feed-in tariffs are more effective than other policy measures in promoting distributedrenewable generation, which provides benefitsin energy security and grid stability.

d) Develop targeted measures for non-grid-connectedemerging renewables such as geothermal and passive solar.

e) Expand its program to purchase electricity generated from emerging renewable power technologies.

cont’d on next page

HYDROGEN CASE STUDY

• To support long-term carbon emission reduc-tions through the use of hydrogen fuel, the

federal government should:

a) Drive public investments toward lower-carbonpathways, including carbon-free hydrogen pro-duction and elimination of carbon at its sourcethrough sequestration.

b) Fund and stimulate increased research anddevelopment to reduce the capital costs of fuelcell technologies and to improve the energy balance and costs of hydrogen production.

c) Continue to focus on transportation applica-tions with long-term carbon emission reductionpotential, in recognition of Canada’s industrialinterests in the fuel cell, hydrogen and auto sectors.

77Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

14. SUMMARY OF RECOMMENDATIONS,PART II

Page 92: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

78 National Round Table on the Environment and the Economy

A SUPPORTING SUITE OF COORDINATED ECONOMIC INSTRUMENTS

• The recommendations made above in relation to the three case studies should be adopted as acoordinated suite, from the short term to thelong term, to enable the maximum benefit tobe derived from the technologies at the mostappropriate point in their projected develop-ment, and to mitigate any discontinuity in theimplementation of the economic instruments.

Page 93: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

Appendices

Page 94: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions
Page 95: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

A. EXECUTIVE SUMMARY:CASE STUDY ON ENERGYEFFICIENCY

By M.K. Jaccard & Associates

1 INTRODUCTION

Ecological fiscal reform (EFR) is the systematic align-ment of fiscal policy with other policy tools for theachievement of simultaneous economic and environ-mental objectives. This case study explores how fiscalpolicy can promote the energy efficiency of Canada’sindustrial sector in a way that leads to long-termreductions in energy-based carbon emissions.

For the purposes of this case study, industry is definedas establishments engaged in manufacturing and mining activities. It does not include establishmentsinvolved in electrical generation, agriculture or providing services.

Energy efficiency refers to the relationship between the output (service) of a device or a system and theenergy put into it. Improved energy efficiency isdoing more with equal or less energy input. Energyefficiency analysis can be applied to different aspectsof the energy system, including energy-using equip-ment, major industrial processes, supply technologies,delivery networks, and even urban form and infra-structure. Energy intensity is a common indicator inenergy analysis, given that energy efficiency cannot bemeasured directly at an aggregate level. Energy inten-sity is defined as unit energy per unit output, whereoutput is measured in physical units (gross output) ormonetary units (gross domestic product or GDP).

There are various ways of reducing the carbon inten-sity of energy. Improving energy efficiency will resultin lower carbon emissions if, as is often the case, the carbon intensity of energy (tonnes of carbon pergigajoule energy) does not increase significantly.

In designing policies and assessing their impact and costs, it is useful to clearly distinguish betweenaction and policy. An action is a change in equipmentacquisition, equipment use rate, lifestyle or resourcemanagement practice that changes net greenhouse gas(GHG) emissions from what they otherwise wouldbe. This study focuses on energy efficiency actionsbased on changes in technology acquisition, but italso considers these actions in relation to otheractions to decarbonate.

In describing carbon-based emissions for the industrysector, it is useful to use the concepts of direct andindirect emissions. Direct emissions are emissions thatare produced by a source controlled by the sector,while indirect emissions are those resulting from thatsector’s activity but are produced by an externalsource. When considering the impact of actions, weconsider the combined impact on both indirect anddirect emissions, since considering only direct emis-sions would actually show an increase in emissionsfor an action such as cogeneration.

2 INDUSTRY SECTOR CHARACTERISTICS

The industrial sector, which includes all mining and manufacturing activities, is the largest GHG-producing sector in Canada. In 2000, it produceddirect GHG emissions of 237 Mt carbon dioxideequivalent (CO2e), the majority of which were energy consumption–based. Energy consumptionreflects activity levels, industry structure and theenergy efficiency of energy use, while GHG emis-sions also reflect the GHG intensity of energy useand process-related emissions.

Energy is particularly critical in the production ofbasic industrial products, which are used to producegoods for final consumption, either within or outsideCanada. These primary product industries accountfor more than 80% of total industrial energy con-sumption. They include industries such as iron andsteel, pulp and paper, metal smelting, petroleumrefining, chemical manufacturing and industrial min-erals. The remaining industries, which are many anddiverse (food processing, transportation equipmentmanufacturing, etc.), account for only 15% of indus-trial energy consumption but are responsible for 60%of industrial economic output.

Energy intensity (based on GDP) in Canadian industry generally decreased after 1990 to a level27% below 1990 levels in 2002. The decline inenergy intensity is due both to improved efficiencyamong energy users as well as to structural change inindustry. The term structural change in this contextrefers to a change in product or industry mix thatdetermines total industrial production volume.Between 1995 and 2001, the activity share of lessenergy-intensive industries has increased while theshare represented by more energy-intensive industrieshas decreased, leading to a decline in total energy useof 11.5% relative to 1995.

81Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

Page 96: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

82 National Round Table on the Environment and the Economy

Trends based on economic output cannot provide anaccurate picture of energy intensity because monetaryunits are affected by many factors not associated withenergy, such as costs of labour or selling price of thefinal product. Indicators computed for aggregatephysical energy intensity suggest a smaller decline in energy intensity relative to the measure based on GDP.

Managers in industry are considered more directlymotivated to minimize costs than are residential andcommercial consumers. Thus firms may have alreadypursued many cost-effective options to reduce energyconsumption, particularly when energy costs makeup a high percentage of total production costs. Somesectors are more physically limited in their ability to reduce energy use, particularly fossil fuel use.Nevertheless, the potential for energy efficiencyimprovements can still be significant, depending on the industry sector.

3 CURRENT POLICY

Current policies relating to industrial energy effi-ciency have their roots in the 1970s. The oil priceshock of 1973 made energy security a high-priorityconcern and led to, among other responses, thedevelopment of numerous energy efficiency programs internationally and within Canada (e.g., the Canadian Industry Program for EnergyConservation, or CIPEC, and the Industrial EnergyInnovators Initiative). Since then, industrial energyefficiency has become closely associated with climatechange policy initiatives. It has figured strongly involuntary efforts by industry to curtail its GHGemissions as part of the Voluntary Challenge andRegistry, which was initially launched by governmentto encourage private and public sector organizationsto voluntarily limit their net GHG emissions. Justprior to ratifying the Kyoto Protocol in December2002, the Government of Canada released theClimate Change Plan for Canada, which establishedan approach for addressing emissions from largeindustrial emitters.

The federal budget of 2003 followed up on theClimate Change Plan with allocations to providelong-term support for research and development inemerging energy-efficient technologies ($250 million)and to subsidize industrial energy efficiency actionsand carbon offsets ($303 million). Research and

development in advanced end-use efficiency tech-nologies is one of the five federal priority areas inscience and technology. Outside federal policy andinitiatives, provincial governments and Crown utilitycorporations have also been active in promotingenergy efficiency in industry and in climate changepolicy in general.

The fiscal system may provide a non-level playingfield for competing energy investments due to differ-ent tax treatments of investments. A special capitalcost allowance (CCA) class for “Energy Conservationand Renewable Energy” equipment (Class 43.1) qualifies certain investments for an annual 30%depreciation rate. This class specifically targets combined heat and power systems, high-efficiencygas generation and heat recovery equipment as energy efficiency investments relevant to the indus-trial sector. Canada does not employ any other tax incentives as part of the personal or corporateincome tax system.

Outside the tax system, a few programs operated bygovernment and utilities provide incentives to pro-mote energy efficiency by industry. Most programsare part of broader policies that include informationprovision. The Climate Change Plan for Canadaseeks to develop a tradable permit system that willprovide an incentive for decarbonization by largeindustrial emitters. The government is currently considering how its permit system could be designedto best develop this market. However, it is alreadyoperating a pilot “voluntary” emissions trading sys-tem, the Pilot Emission Removals, Reductions andLearnings Initiative.

As noted above, the Climate Change Plan provides for direct funding for R&D in energy efficiency technologies. The Office of Energy Research andDevelopment coordinates federal energy research and development activities and directs the Program of Energy Research and Development (which includes a strategy for energy efficiency in industry).The Canmet Energy Technology Centre and theInnovative Research Initiative for Greenhouse GasMitigation also fund research programs that includeenergy efficiency projects. Overall, Canada hasfavoured fiscal incentives over direct funding to sup-port research and development, and it provides one ofthe most generous systems among all Organisation forEconomic Co-operation and Development countries.

Page 97: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

4 ENERGY EFFICIENCY OPPORTUNITIES

Energy use in industry can be understood in terms of generic or auxiliary services and unique processes.Generic or auxiliary energy services are those that arenot specific to a particular industry. They fall intofour general categories: steam generation systems(boilers and cogenerators), lighting, HVAC (heating,ventilation and air conditioning) systems, and electricmotor systems (pumps, fans, compressors or convey-ors). Significant reductions can occur through energyefficiency improvements to steam generation systemsand to electric motors and their attached auxiliarydevices. The efficiency of steam generation variesgreatly depending on boiler design, age and fuel used. Substantial energy efficiency improvements canalso be achieved by using cogenerators rather thansimple steam boilers. Although some potential existsto improve the efficiency of electric motors, there is greater potential to improve the efficiencies ofequipment driven by them (pumping, air displace-ment, compression, conveyance and other types ofmachine drive).

The remaining energy efficiency opportunities are quite specific to the unique processes of each par-ticular industry. Some industries use large amounts ofheat to accomplish their activities. For instance,materials production industries (such as iron, steel,other primary metals and building materials) arecharacterized by heavy use of direct process heat.Other industries are very dependent on electricity todrive large motors or to generate or purify chemicalsor metals in electrolytic cells. Such energy-intensiveindustries typically have fewer options for energy (orCO2) reduction than industries that make use ofmany tens or hundreds of processes, each requiringonly a small amount of energy, to transform semi-finished products into their final form.

Many energy-efficient technologies are on the markettoday. Some have been available for some time butcould still see greater uptake. Others are poised toemerge and are currently at demonstration stages orhave been applied in a relatively narrow niche (e.g.,direct reduction in iron and steel). Still others havenot been technically realized and are the subject ofactive R&D programs (e.g., inert anodes/wetted cathodes in aluminum electrolysis). Technologicalinnovation may be either radical (disruptive) orincremental. Radical technological innovation repre-sents a transition to a new technology or a new

paradigm, which often changes the way people thinkabout the product or process. Incremental innovationoccurs as small and gradual innovation in existingtechnologies.

5 CHALLENGES TO ADOPTION

Research during the past 30 years has shown thatconsumers and firms forgo apparently cost-effectiveinvestments in energy efficiency. They appear to dis-count future savings of energy efficiency investmentsat rates well in excess of market rates for borrowingor saving. This phenomenon has often been referredto as the energy efficiency “gap” and is a critical issuefor this case study in evaluating the economic costand potential for fiscal policy to influence the uptakeof energy-efficient technologies.

While there is clearly potential for firms to makeenergy efficiency improvements, determining theextent of that potential is not easy. New technologiescarry a greater potential for failure, and this uncer-tainty can create a significant investment hurdle forfirms considering irreversible investments that can bedelayed. Also, different consumers in different loca-tions will face varying acquisition, installation andoperating costs, and energy efficiency equipment willbe more appropriate in some situations than others.

Understanding the impact of energy efficiencyimprovements on aggregate energy consumption andon decarbonization is complicated by several factors.First, pursuing energy efficiency can result in decar-bonization, but one must keep in mind that primaryfuels differ substantially in their carbon emissions.There are also significant “second order” feedbacksthat occur between the energy demand and supplysectors in the economy. For instance, the widespreadadoption of high-efficiency electric motor and auxiliary systems would affect the demand for electricity, with potential price impacts that wouldaffect energy-related decisions throughout the econ-omy. In cases where energy-efficient technologiesachieve substantial market penetration, the resultinglower cost of energy services elicits a rebound effectof increased energy service demand and thus greaterenergy consumption.

83Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

Page 98: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

84 National Round Table on the Environment and the Economy

6 MODELLING METHODOLOGY

A variety of energy economy models can be used todevelop a baseline of GHG emissions in the industrysector and to estimate how changes in the energy effi-ciency, fuel type or emission controls of technologieswould lead to different levels of GHG emissions. TheCIMS model, developed by the Energy and MaterialsResearch Group at Simon Fraser University, is usedin this analysis. Unique technologies, processes andtechnological interactions in the Canadian industrysector are represented in detail. It is therefore possibleto explicitly explore the relationship between theunderlying process and technology structure of thesector and its aggregate energy use and GHG emis-sions. CIMS also portrays technology acquisitiondecisions based on financial cost and behaviouralparameters estimated from empirical studies of con-sumer and business decision making. The model thusdiffers from those that use a single, ex ante (expected)estimate of financial cost as the basis for technologyselection and thus do not address the complexities ofdecision making evidenced by the energy efficiency gap.The CIMS model is also able to incorporate energyprice feedbacks between energy demand and supply sectors, as well as energy service demand feedbacks.

6.1 Model OverviewA CIMS simulation involves six basic steps.

1Assessment of demand: Technologies are repre-sented in the model in terms of the quantity of service and/or product they provide (e.g.,tonnes of paper produced). A forecast of servicegrowth drives the model simulation in five-yearincrements.

2Retirement: In each future period, a portion of the initial year’s technology stock is retired basedon age. The residual technology stocks in eachperiod are subtracted from the forecast energyservice demand.

3New technology competition/retrofit competition:Prospective technologies compete for the newinvestment required to meet service demandbased on the minimization of annualized life-cycle costs, which include identified differences innon-financial technology preferences and failurerisks. The model allocates market shares amongtechnologies probabilistically to reflect varying

acquisition, installation and operating costs andequipment. In each time period, a similar compe-tition occurs prior to new stock purchases tosimulate retrofitting of residual stock.

4Equilibrium of energy supply and demand: In eachfuture time period, a cycle occurs between tech-nology choice in the energy demand models andtechnology choice and energy prices in the supplymodels, until prices and demand have stabilizedat an equilibrium.

5Equilibrium of energy service demand: Once theenergy supply and demand cycle has stablized,this step adjusts demand for energy services basedon price elasticities. If this adjustment is signifi-cant, the whole system is rerun from step 1 withthe new demands.

6Output: Total energy, emission and cost informa-tion can be derived from the final model resultssince each technology has net energy use, netenergy emissions and costs associated with it.

The CIMS model is used to construct the baselinescenario and to develop two alternative scenarios thatestimate how changes in the energy efficiency, fueltype or emission controls of technologies can lead to different levels of GHG emissions in the industry sector.

7 BASELINE SCENARIO

The baseline scenario is developed using the CIMSmodel according to simulation steps 1, 2, 3 and 6described in the preceding section (steps 4 and 5 arenot used in the case study). The baseline forecastperiod runs from 2000 (CIMS base year) to 2030.For this study, assumptions regarding economicgrowth (more specifically, region-specific growth ratesfor GDP for 2000 to 2020) and future energy pricesare adopted from Canada’s Emissions Outlook: AnUpdate (CEOU).1 For the simulation past 2020,annual price and growth trends of the 2015–2020period are assumed to continue to 2030. The emis-sion forecast generated by CIMS is calibrated to theofficial GHG forecast (as of December 2003), whichwas formulated since the release of the CEOU.

1 Available on-line at: www.nrcan.gc.ca/es/ceo/update.htm

Page 99: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

A summary of the baseline scenario for the industry sec-tor in Canada is presented in Table 1. Overall, emissionsin the industry sector (as defined for this case study)grow by 50% over the 30-year simulation period, with direct emissions increasing and indirect emissionsdecreasing. The share of electricity produced by cogeneration in the sector increases over the simulationperiod, particularly in oil sands operations. The oil andgas sector generates the largest increase in GHG emis-sions, which is driven by a strong growth in oil and gas exports to the United States.

8 ALTERNATIVE SCENARIOS

Two alternative forecasts are produced by simulatingtwo different shadow prices over a 25-year simulationperiod (2005–2030). We model one price of$15/tonne CO2e and one of $30/tonne CO2e toinfluence a shift in investment patterns. In additionto applying this shadow price to the industry sectorsub-models, we also apply the price to the electricitysector so that a carbon price can be reflected in theelectricity price seen by the industry subsectors.

Emerging technologies have a greater ability to gain market acceptance in a 25-year time frame. Inorder to capture the long-term promotion of thesetechnologies through R&D and commercializationsupport, we adjust the “intangible costs” of a selec-tion of emerging technologies in the model to reflecta more targeted R&D and commercialization effort.

Simulating a carbon emission shadow price in theindustrial sector sub-models indicates the emissionreduction potential from energy efficiency actions.This type of simulation reveals the potential for emission reductions that could occur from energy

efficiency actions up to a specified marginal abate-ment cost for carbon. This methodology is built onthe principle that the goal (decarbonization) woulddrive the formulation of an alternative GHG scenario(as simulated by a shadow price for GHG), whichwould indicate what role energy efficiency invest-ments could play in decarbonization compared withother options. The choice of carbon prices reflects arelatively modest “achievable potential” that could beinfluenced by fiscal policy.

The Low Carbon I and II scenarios result in GHGreductions of 46 Mt CO2e and 58 Mt CO2e by 2030(see Table 2). Direct emissions make up most of theseemission reductions, though the response of indirectemissions to the imposition of a shadow price isstronger than the response of direct emissions (indirect emissions decline by 53% to 62% in 2030, while direct emissions decline by 5% to 7%).Actions behind this strong indirect response includethe greater adoption of cogeneration systems andimprovements to the overall efficiency of auxiliarymotor systems. The metal smelting and refining sector and the petroleum refining and iron and steel subsectors realize the most emission reductionsfrom improved energy efficiency.

Where energy-efficient technologies achieve substan-tial market penetration, the resulting lower cost ofenergy services produces a rebound effect, driving up energy service demand and increasing energy consumption. The alternative scenarios do not incorporate this effect.

85Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

Table 1: Baseline Forecast of GHG Emissions and Energy Consumption, Canada

2000 2010 2020 2030 Average Annual Growth

GHG emissions (Mt CO2e) 288 343 396 453 1.53%Direct 237 307 358 407 1.82%Indirect 50 36 38 46 -0.30%

Energy (PJ) 4,239 5,030 5,783 6,579 1.48%

Page 100: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

86 National Round Table on the Environment and the Economy

9 ECONOMIC AND POLICY ANALYSIS

The alternative scenario simulations reveal thatreductions of up to 58 Mt CO2e could be achievedby 2030 in part by actions leading to greater energyefficiency by industry. We calculate ex ante (expected)financial costs of the scenarios (shown in Table 3),which represent the difference in the net presentvalue of capital, energy and operating and mainte-nance costs in 2004 (2000 $), discounted at a socialdiscount rate for the period 2005–2030, between thebaseline and each alternative scenario. All subsectorsshow negative costs because the value of energy sav-ings is greater than any increase in upfront capitalcosts from adopting these measures. Welfare costsmay be, and usually are, much higher and areembodied in the technology choices of firms and households.

Because the CIMS simulation did not incorporatefinal demand feedbacks (step 5 of the CIMS simula-tion), the results provide only a partial equilibriumportrayal of the response to the shadow price ofCO2e.

Table 2: GHG Emissions and Energy for Alternative Scenarios, Canada

2000 2010 2020 2030Total GHG emissions (Mt CO2e)

BAU 288 343 396 453Low Carbon I 288 322 365 407Low Carbon II 288 316 355 395

Direct GHG emissions (Mt CO2e)BAU 237 307 358 407Low Carbon I 237 292 339 386Low Carbon II 237 293 335 378

Indirect GHG emissions (Mt CO2e)BAU 50 36 38 46Low Carbon I 50 29 26 22Low Carbon II 50 23 20 17

Energy (PJ)BAU 4,239 5,030 5,783 6,579Low Carbon I 4,239 4,822 5,537 6,298Low Carbon II 4,239 4,818 5,497 6,232

BAU = business as usual

Table 3: Ex Ante Financial Costs for 2005–2030 ($ billion)

Low LowCarbon I Carbon II

Chemical products -4.98 -4.04Coal mining -0.99 -2.19Industrial minerals -1.16 -2.08Iron and steel -1.84 -1.93Metal smelting and refining -1.42 -1.76Mining -0.26 -0.59Other manufacturing -1.92 -2.75Petroleum crude extraction -0.04 -0.03Petroleum refining -0.19 -0.38Pulp and paper -3.39 -4.80Natural gas industry -1.45 -4.32Total -17.64 -24.87

Note: Figures are reported in 2000 $.

Page 101: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

Pursuing long-term carbon emission reductions bytargeting industrial energy efficiency may be accom-panied by benefits that go beyond reducing GHGemissions and the ecological harm associated withglobal warming. First, declining energy intensity willreduce the energy costs per unit of service output,and economic growth will be less constrained byfuture energy costs. Second, the innovation of moreefficient technologies will be encouraged, which mayserve as an opportunity to increase exports. Third,negative health effects associated with poor air qualitymay be reduced.

Ecological fiscal reform as defined in this study (seeIntroduction) is a broad approach, which can employsuites of instruments in a reinforcing package to support the shift to sustainable development. Asdescribed in the NRTEE’s report Toward a CanadianAgenda for Ecological Fiscal Reform: First Steps, thecommon purpose of these instruments is to provideincentives for producers and consumers to alter theirdecisions and behaviour. These instruments eitherinternalize environmental costs or reward more sustainable practices. We relate three key policy tools to the modelling analysis: the application ofenvironmental taxes, tradable permits (as part of market-oriented regulation) and subsidies.

9.1 Environmental Taxes and Tax ShiftingThe modelling results directly suggest the applicationof a GHG tax—a charge paid on each fossil fuel,proportional to the quantity of GHG emissions emit-ted when it is burned.2 However, because the carbonprice was applied to all GHG emissions representedin the industry subsectors (including process andfugitive emissions), non-fuel combustion emissionswere also subjected to the carbon price. The LowCarbon I scenario describes a tax of $15/tonne CO2e,and the Low Carbon II scenario represents a tax of$30/tonne CO2e. A GHG tax applied across theindustry sector causes each subsector to increase ordecrease its emission reduction efforts until each isfacing the identical incremental cost for the next unitof reduction.

Revenues from environmental taxes can be used fordifferent purposes: they may be part of general rev-enues, earmarked for specific environmental projects,redistributed as rebates or used to reduce other taxes.Each option has different costs for different members

and sectors of the economy. In practice, environmen-tal tax designs have used varying degrees of refunds,differentials in the tax rates applied to industry andhouseholds, and exemptions to address equity andcompetitiveness concerns.

9.2 Tradable Permits (Market-oriented Regulation)

An important area of policy innovation has been the development of market-oriented regulation,which like a GHG tax allows individual flexibility in achieving a compulsory limit or requirement.Unlike traditional command-and-control regulation,the manner of participation is at the discretion of thefirm or household (whether to reduce emissions oracquire the designated technology, or pay others to do so).

The modelling results suggest an emissions cap andtradable permit system applied to all industry sectorsthrough auctioned permits, with a cap equivalent to the emission levels reported in the alternative sce-narios: 407 Mt CO2e in 2030 in Low Carbon I, and 395 Mt CO2e in Low Carbon II (Table 2). Thetradable permit prices correspond with the shadowprices applied in those simulations ($15/tonne CO2e and $30/tonne CO2e respectively).

Market-oriented regulation can also be applied in different contexts by, for instance, specifying thedesirable market outcome rather than the environ-mental outcome. Considerable design options alsoexist with emissions cap and tradable permit systems.

9.3 SubsidiesEFR can support decarbonization through theremoval or redirection of existing subsidies andthrough the provision of new subsidies. Financialsupport in the form of direct grants, guaranteed orlow-interest rate loans, and tax incentives can be usedto directly support the greater adoption of energy-efficient technologies and long-term research anddevelopment in new energy-efficient technologies.

The alternative scenarios suggest the impact of a subsidy program that is perfectly designed to targetcost-effective actions. The size of the incentiverequired to target the actions inherent in the modelsimulation is estimated by calculating the perceivedprivate costs of the alternative scenarios (shown inTable 4). The estimates are made by calculating the

87Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

2 A CO2 tax is specified per tonne of CO2 emitted, not carbon. It can be easily translated into a carbon tax: 1 tonne of carbon corresponds to 3.67 tonnes of CO2. A GHG tax covers other GHGs and is measured in tonnes of CO2e.

Page 102: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

88 National Round Table on the Environment and the Economy

area under a curve that plots cumulative emissionreductions against rising CO2e shadow prices. Thearea under the resulting marginal cost curve, up to the shadow price of the alternative scenario, represents the compensation required to have firmsundertake actions that they would not have under-taken otherwise (their perceived private cost).

These estimates do not include expenditures requiredto subsidize firms that would have purchased energy-efficient technologies in the baseline scenario (“freeriders”). If this effect is incorporated, the subsidy cost of the program is greater. Evaluations of energy efficiency incentive programs suggest that the proportion of free riders can be significant, oftenin the order of 85% of program recipients. Subsidyprograms can therefore require relatively large publicexpenditures per unit of effect. The administrativecosts of program delivery and the transaction costs of firm participation, which depend significantly on the design of the specific measure, have not been considered.

Potential avenues for new subsidies include directfinancial transfers (as grants or preferential- or low-interest loans) and tax incentives (e.g., the expansionof CCA 43.1 to include more energy efficiency technologies). The use of revolving loan programs has gained popularity in the commercial and institu-tional sector in Canada and could be applied in anindustry context.

The amount spent on a subsidy will have differenteffects depending on program design. Financialincentives can be directed to reduce the upfront orthe operating costs of energy-efficient investments,and they can be based on prescriptive or custom (performance-based) criteria. Subsidies directed at upfront capital costs recognize that the higher capital cost of energy-efficient technologies can deterinvestment. Measures that target upfront costs arenot based on the actual performance of the invest-ment in meeting the desired policy objective.Performance-based subsidies can be more flexible inallowing firms to meet “demonstrated” improvementsin energy efficiency or carbon emission reduction.

Another factor to consider in designing subsidies isdifferences in how firms respond to incentive tools.Small and medium-sized enterprises, which may not have the capital required to make use of taxincentives, may find more value in loans, loan guarantees and interest rate subsidies, as well as thesupport provided by private sector incentive mecha-nisms such as energy performance contracts, leasesand venture capital.

10 POLICY DESIGN CONSIDERATIONS

The choice of fiscal policy tools and the ultimatedesign of a policy package involve many considera-tions. For instance, the policy package that realizesenvironmental benefits in the most cost-effective way may be difficult to administer or politicallyunfeasible. We offer a general assessment of how the fiscal policy tools discussed above stack up against common policy design criteria.

10.1 Effectiveness in Reaching Environmental Targets

An emissions cap and tradable permit is the mosteffective policy tool for realizing the environmentalobjective, because it specifies the emission reduction.A subsidy, on the other hand, may fail to achieve sufficient reductions if it is too low or not directedproperly. In both cases, poor design can weaken the intended policy impacts. Broad-based economicinstruments (taxes and permit systems) are more effi-cient than subsidies in preventing the rebound effect,encouraging a long-term carbon emission reductionin the energy system.

Table 4: Costs of Incentive (Perceived PrivateCost) for 2005–2030 ($ billions)

Low LowCarbon I Carbon II

Chemical products 0.528 1.284Coal mining 0.026 0.104Industrial minerals 0.047 0.194Iron and steel 0.070 0.158Metal smelting and refining 0.124 0.309Mining 0.015 0.036Other manufacturing 0.189 0.436Petroleum crude extraction 0.101 0.093Petroleum refining 0.003 0.026Pulp and paper 0.203 0.608Natural gas extraction 0.707 1.636Total 2.012 4.885

Note: Figures are reported in 2000 $.

Page 103: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

10.2 Economic EffectivenessA uniform carbon tax or an emissions cap and trad-able permit system is theoretically the most efficientway to achieve a decarbonization objective, becausethe least expensive reductions throughout the econ-omy are undertaken first. A subsidy may go to firmswith higher reduction costs (unless it is allocated viaa bidding process), and it can require large publicexpenditures per unit of effect due to free riders.Also, a subsidy requires that revenue be raised some-where else in the economy, which can also produce“dead weight” losses.

10.3 Administrative FeasibilityFiscal policy design should consider the burden on firms in either complying with a tax or market-oriented regulation, or in applying for grants andsubmitting tax credit claims. This burden may beparticularly onerous for smaller firms. Data must beavailable to ensure proper program monitoring andevaluation, which should focus on impacts (i.e., carbon emission reductions) rather than processesand outputs (e.g., number of applications, programrecipients).

10.4 Political AcceptabilityConcern about political acceptability has limited the use of policy tools such as GHG taxes to achievedecarbonization, even in countries where they arecurrently applied. The use of subsidies avoids impos-ing costs on firms by instead enhancing the ability ofenergy-efficient technologies to compete. However,the government must acquire the funds from some-where else in the economy, which has led tocriticism. Tax incentives are a less visible form ofpublic subsidy.

Industry groups have generally lobbied for voluntaryand tax incentive approaches in climate change policy, arguing that new measures must be situatedwithin an overall framework that is consistent with the broad fiscal and economic direction of the country.

10.5 Distributional and Competitiveness ImpactsWith a GHG tax or emissions cap and tradable per-mit, the manner of participation is at the discretionof the firm. Competitiveness impacts will arise if thepolicy imposes different levels of costs on competingfirms; this may occur if policies and regulations differat the country or sub-national levels or if firms havedifferent specific carbon intensities, substitution possibilities and trade levels.

Policy design is critical in minimizing distributionaland competitiveness impacts. For instance, sector-specific market-oriented regulation can minimizeaverage price increases, because only a small percent-age of the market is devoted to the newer, higher-costtechnologies and manufacturers will average thesecosts with their lower-cost, conventional technologiesin determining prices.

10.6 Technological InnovationThe level of technological innovation of environmen-tally related technologies will be below the theoreticalsocially optimal level in the presence of externalitiessuch as environmental damage. This reality providesan argument for the use of environmental taxes andmarket-based instruments that internalize this externality and provide a “pull” to innovation anddeployment. Other policies that support innovationdirectly by lowering the costs of R&D (e.g., by subsidizing R&D expenditures or encouraging jointventures) may be most valuable at the earliest stage ofdeployment. However, subsidies run the risk of sup-porting private R&D that would have taken placeanyway and supporting inappropriate technologies.

11 CONCLUSIONS

The potential for industrial energy efficiency actionsto contribute to the decarbonization of the energysystem is complex: it depends on the degree to whichtechnical potential can be further developed throughinnovation; the degree to which energy efficiencytechnology and habits can be adopted; the degree towhich this adoption translates into reduced aggregateenergy use; and the carbon intensity of conservedenergy. The adoption of energy efficiency as a way tolower energy-based carbon emissions in industry isfurther complicated by the fact that energy efficiencyis only one among a number of options that industrycan use to reduce carbon-based emissions.

In developing policy recommendations in this case study, it was important to evaluate the specificfocus on promoting industrial energy efficiency inthe context of a broader focus on the objective ofdecarbonization. The alternative scenario simulationsdemonstrate that improved energy efficiency inindustry is closely interrelated with fuel switchingand other means of reducing carbon emissions, suggesting that energy efficiency should be con-sidered among other actions in moving toward a

89Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

Page 104: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

90 National Round Table on the Environment and the Economy

decarbonized energy system. However, focusing onenergy efficiency alone as the means of achievingdecarbonization in industry may run the risk of orienting incentives and efforts in a direction that is not cost-effective.

Our evaluation of specific policy tools indicates that no one policy tool is optimal in its performanceagainst the criteria of environmental effectiveness,economic efficiency, administrative feasibility andpolitical acceptability. Rather, it suggests that a port-folio of policy instruments can enable a governmentto combine the strengths, while compensating for theweaknesses, of individual policy instruments. Such apolicy package should focus on measures that wouldbe politically acceptable today while nonethelessinfluencing technological innovation. Considerablepotential exists to use ecological fiscal reform to create conditions under which “winners” can emergeand attract sufficient investment in order to developand be widely adopted.

With this in mind, we recommend an emphasis on tradable permits (as part of market-oriented regulation) to drive fundamental change, with a complementary role for subsidies in supportingenergy-efficient technologies. Subsidies, and taxincentives in particular, score well on public accept-ability and may be effective if designed carefully andwith an understanding of relative costs in differentsectors and activities in the economy. Nevertheless,the impact and cost (including free-rider costs)should be realistically assessed in the design of any program. Tax incentives and direct grants shouldalso be designed to minimize government’s role inpicking technologies (by being more performance-based) and to minimize the transaction costs ofprogram participation.

There is a history of policy support for promotingenergy efficiency through information and awarenessprograms and through subsidies for research anddevelopment. Voluntary programs have laid thegroundwork for EFR policies in stimulating aware-ness of decarbonization opportunities; they will also provide needed complements to any new fiscalpolicy initiatives that are developed. There may be arole, too, for EFR to connect with traditional com-mand-and-control policy. While fiscal policy candrive technological gains, standards that phase out the sale of inefficient equipment can serve toconsolidate change.

12 LESSONS LEARNED

• While energy efficiency can be considered a pathtoward long-term carbon emission reductions ofthe energy system that can be targeted immedi-ately through the greater diffusion of technologiesalready in the market, it is also important to consider how energy-efficient technologies can fit into the long-term picture through continuedinnovation and commercialization.

• Energy efficiency is not necessarily the most cost-effective option available for reducing carbonemissions in the industry sector. Other meansinclude fuel switching, reducing fugitive emis-sions, reducing process emissions, and the captureand storage of CO2. While a significant share ofthe emission reductions occurs through increasedenergy efficiency in the modelling results, consid-erable reductions also occur through other means.Focusing on energy efficiency alone as the meansof achieving decarbonization in industry may runthe risk of orienting incentives and efforts in adirection that is not cost-effective.

• Promoting greater energy efficiency is not a new policy objective, but it has been actively pursued in many countries over the past 30 years.Considerable experience can be gained fromunderstanding the successes and failures of theseefforts. For example, research shows a gap betweenthe level of investment in energy efficiency thatappears cost-effective and the lower level of invest-ment that is actually occurring. This “efficiencygap” is a critical issue for this case study, particu-larly in estimating an alternative carbon emissionscenario, as well as evaluating the economic costand potential of fiscal policy to influence theuptake of energy-efficient technologies. This is an emerging analytical area that has only recentlybeen incorporated into technology simulationmodelling.

• Technical energy efficiency gains do not translatedirectly into reduced carbon emissions. The potential for industrial energy efficiency actions to contribute to long-term carbon emission reduc-tions in the energy system is complex and is basedon the following four factors.

Page 105: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

1The degree to which technical potential can be further developed: Our energy system is far from its maximum technical potential forsecond law efficiency, but how and when willtechnologies and systems be developed?

2The degree to which this potential can beadopted: Mature energy-efficient technologiesthat appear cost-effective are available but havenot transformed the market. To what degreewill energy-efficient technologies, systems andpractices be adopted?

3The degree to which this adoption translates intoreduced aggregate energy use: Lower-cost energyservices from energy efficiency investmentselicit a rebound effect of increased energy service demand and thus greater energy consumption.

4The carbon intensity of conserved energy:Reductions in carbon emissions will depend on the carbon intensity of energy. For instance,the impact of improved electrical end-use effi-ciency will be considerably different dependingon whether that electricity was generated byhydropower or thermal generation.

• The modelling work in the case study sought toanalyze the complex relationships noted in thepreceding point. Models are inevitably wrong in that they cannot possibly incorporate all infor-mation and relationships of potential importance,nor accurately depict all uncertainties.3 Still, onecan look to the modelling results to suggest theability to harness the energy efficiency potential of current and emerging technologies, the roleenergy efficiency can play among other options todecarbonize industry, and the relative long-termcarbon emission reduction potentials of varioussubsectors.

• Modelling the long-term potential for policy toincrease energy efficiency adoption suggests adynamic analysis that could consider how techno-logical innovation and perhaps even consumer and firm preferences may be influenced by policy.This analysis was beyond the capability of the casestudy, but it is an emerging research direction thatshould be noted.

• The results of the alternative scenarios reflect themagnitude of the carbon price that was modelled;that is, a $250 price for carbon would haverevealed a different reduction potential. Whilehigher carbon prices have greater long-term car-bon emission reduction potential, they tend toshow diminishing returns (less additional emissionreduction for each additional dollar per tonne of carbon).

• The long-run potential for energy efficiency tocontribute to a decarbonized energy system will be constrained by what it will cost to produce aclean energy supply. Energy price represents anupper-bound constraint on the contribution ofenergy efficiency.

91Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

3 Energy use in the industry sector is particularly complex given the large number of end uses and interactions between energy-using and -producing processes.

Page 106: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions
Page 107: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

B. EXECUTIVE SUMMARY:CASE STUDY ON RENEWABLE GRID–POWER ELECTRICITY

By Marbek Resource Consultants in association withResources for the Future

1 INTRODUCTION

This case study analyzes the role that fiscal policy canplay in promoting the long-term development ofCanada’s renewable energy sector. Ecological fiscalreform (EFR) is recognized as a lever for promotingand, where appropriate, accelerating the use ofrenewable energy technologies in order to make long-term reductions in energy-based carbon emis-sions. This case study addresses the renewable energysector and explores the ability or “traction” of five fis-cal instruments to improve the uptake or deploymentof grid-power renewable energy technologies (RETs)in Canada.

2 THE RENEWABLE ENERGY CONTEXT

The focus of the current study is on renewable energytechnologies. However, the term renewable energytechnologies is commonly used interchangeablythroughout the literature with terms such as cleanenergy, green power, alternative energy and low-impacttechnologies. While there is considerable overlap in thetechnologies included within each group, they are notidentical. In practice, these definitional differencescan become quite important when dealing with theRET policy and technology eligibility issues.

After some discussion of the scope of RETs to beused in this case study, it was concluded that theEnvironmental Choice Program (ECP)’s EcoLogodefinition provided the best available match with theoverall goals of this study. This conclusion was basedon consideration of two factors:

• the goal of the NRTEE’s EFR initiative clearlystates that “long-term carbon emissions reduction”should not result in increased loading of other pollutants; and

• an implied goal of this initiative is the promotionof innovation.

In addition, to provide a focused output, the NRTEEdirected the study team to examine only those RETsthat generate electrical power (as opposed to thermaltechnologies such as solar hot water heaters). In asimilar vein, the NRTEE directed the study team to look only at those RETs that are, or will be, tiedinto the national electricity grid (as opposed to stand-alone systems).

Consequently, the following technologies are considered in this case study:

• wind turbines (onshore and offshore);

• low-impact hydro;

• grid-connected photovoltaics (PV);

• landfill gas (for electricity generation);

• biomass (for electricity generation);

• ocean energy, including wave and tidal power conversion technologies; and

• geothermal.

For this case study, the term RET refers to renewablegrid-power technologies or grid-power RETs.

3 RENEWABLE GRID POWER IN CANADA

The study addresses three key areas with respect togrid-power RETs:

• Current status: What is the current status of eachtechnology in terms of installed Canadian gridelectricity generating capacity, technical maturityand costs?

• Future potential in Canada: What is considered the long-term upper-limit capacity for each technology and how much of this upper limit is practically achievable by 2010 and 2020?

• Renewable power technology costs and learningtrends: What are the current and projected futurecosts for the targeted technologies and what arethe learning trends that impact these costs?

3.1 Current StatusTable 1 shows the current total installed electricitygeneration capacity in Canada as well as the totalshare of electricity generated by each source in 2003.As illustrated, if the estimate includes large hydro andall biomass installations, then Canada’s total installedbase of renewable electricity generation capacity isover 70,000 MW, or about 60% of the total; virtuallyall of this capacity is large hydro.

93Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

Page 108: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

94 National Round Table on the Environment and the Economy

If the more stringent low-impact environmental crite-ria defined by the Environmental Choice Program(ECP) are used, then large hydro and some of the bio-mass facilities are excluded. (A summary of the ECPcriteria is presented at the end of this appendix.) Abreakdown of the estimated current (2003) installedbase of EcoLogo-certifiable grid-power RETs is shownin Table 2. In 2003, these renewable energy technolo-gies generated an estimated 12,100 GWh of electricityor about 2% of Canada’s total electricity generation.

3.2 Future Potential in Canada Technical potential refers to the long-term upperlimit of total installed capacity for a given technol-ogy. For example, if wind power has a technicalpotential of 100,000 MW, it means that this is themaximum total generating capacity that wind tur-bines could supply if they were installed in everytechnically feasible location across the country.

Table 1: Installed Electricity Capacity and Annual Electricity Generation in Canada in 2003

Source Installed capacity GenerationMW Share GWh Share

Hydro 68,100 58% 346,000 59%Nuclear 12,600 11% 81,700 14%Coal 16,600 14% 109,400 19%Oil 7,500 6% 14,200 2%Natural gas 11,000 9% 29,100 5%Wind and biomass 2,200 2% 9,100 2%Total 118,000 100% 589,500 100%

Note: Figures may not sum due to rounding.Source: National Energy Board <www.neb.gc.ca/energy/SupplyDemand/2003/index_e.htm>.

Table 2: Current Installed Base of ECP Grid-Power RETs in Canada in 2003

Grid-power RET Current installed base(EcoLogo-certifiable) Cap factor Capacity (MW) Supply (GWh/yr) Share of total grid-power

RET supplyWind (onshore) 35% 316 970 8%Hydro* 60% 1,800 9,460 78%Solar PV 14% 0.092 0.1 0%Landfill gas (LFG) 90% 85 670 6%Biomass 80% 128 900 7%Wave 35% 0 0 0%Tidal 35% 0 0 0%Geothermal (large) 95% 0 0 0%Total 2,300 12,100 100%

Notes: 1. Installed capacities are for grid-power electricity and potentially could be EcoLogo-certifiable.2. Figures may not sum due to rounding.

*Includes many existing small hydro sites that may not be EcoLogo-certifiable.

Page 109: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

95Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

Table 3: Technical Resource Potential of Grid-Power RETs in Canada

Grid-power RET Cap Technical resource potential (total, not additional)(EcoLogo-certifiable) factor

Capacity (MW) Supply (GWh/yr)Low High Low High

Wind (onshore)* 35% 28,000 100,000 85,800 306,600Low-impact hydro 60% 11,000 14,000 57,800 73,600Solar PV 14% 9,800 100,000 12,000 122,600Landfill gas (LFG) 90% 350 700 2,700 5,500Biomass 80% 6,800 79,300 47,700 555,600Wave 35% 10,100 16,100 31,000 49,400Tidal 35% 2,500 23,500 7,700 72,100Geothermal (large) 95% No data 3,000 No data 25,000

*Offshore not included due to lack of independent estimates.

Table 4: Estimated Practical Resource Potential of Grid-Power RETs in Canada

Grid-power RET Cap Practical resource potential (total, not additional)(EcoLogo- factor Annual growth in Capacity (MW) Supply (GWh/yr)certifiable) deployment to fill

practical potential* 2010 2020 2010 2020Min. Max. Low High Low High Low High Low High

Wind (onshore) 35% 25% 64% 5,000 10,000 15,000 40,000 15,300 30,700 46,000 122,600Low-impact hydro 60% 18% 27% 5,600 9,000 9,800 no data 29,400 47,300 51,500 no dataSolar PV 14% 152% 347% 60 265 225 3,295 100 300 300 4,000Landfill gas (LFG) 90% 10% 17% 170 no data 250 no data 1,300 no data 2,000 no dataBiomass 80% 42% 73% 1,500 2,000 no data 6,000 10,500 14,000 no data 42,000Wave 35% 0% infinite 0 20 4 no data 0 60 12 no dataTidal 35% infinite infinite 4 300 50 2,000 12 900 200 6,100Geothermal (large) 95% infinite infinite 100 600 1,500 no data 800 5,000 12,500 no data

* Assuming logarithmic growth and based on practical resource potential numbers in 2010 and 2020. The growth rates are not forecasts of abase case of renewable supply, but rather the growth required on an annual basis to satisfy the practical potential. Refer to the full casestudy for details on the data presented (available at <www.nrtee-trnee.ca>).

Page 110: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

96 National Round Table on the Environment and the Economy

Table 3 provides an indication of the estimated tech-nical potential for each technology. In each case, arange is provided, which reflects the relatively highlevel of uncertainty that exists.

Practical potential is necessarily a subset of technicalpotential. It recognizes that the ability to capture thetechnical potential within any given period will beaffected by factors such as grid access and capacity;zoning and permitting; technological advances;financing; market demand and acceptance; anddesign, manufacturing and installation capacity.1

Table 4 provides the estimated practical potential.The estimates were developed based on broad consid-eration of a number of factors, complemented byconsultations with industry and government person-nel. As with all figures, the estimates are given inranges to reflect the high level of uncertainty.

3.3 Renewable Energy Technology Costs andLearning Trends

A summary of the expected levelized costs for each ofthe targeted grid-power RETs is presented in Table 5.To ensure consistency among the technologies, allcost data are derived from recent estimates providedby the International Energy Agency (IEA). And, toreflect the cost uncertainties involved, the data areexpressed as a range. Table 5 also provides a summaryof IEA estimates of forecast cost reductions for eachtechnology over the study period. The forecast costreductions are based on learning theory. This theory,which is well supported by empirical data, defines thelink between the increase in installed capacity andthe rate of cost decrease.

The practical potential and levelized costs are used inmodelling the fiscal instruments. The results of themodelling are discussed below in Section 4.

Table 5: IEA Cost Reduction and Estimates for Targeted Grid-Power RETs

Grid-power Cap Cost reduction Cost estimatesRET (EcoLogo- factor Cost reduction Annual cost Levelized cost estimates (2000 cents/kWh)certifiable) every 10 yrs* reduction* 2003 2010 2020

Min. Max. Min. Max. Low High Low High Low HighWind (onshore) 35% 25% 25% 3% 3% 3.8 15.1 3.0 11.3 1.9 8.5Low-impact hydro 60% 0% 13% 0% 1% 2.5 18.8 2.5 16.3 2.3 15.2Solar PV 14% 30% 50% 4% 7% 22.6 100.3 12.5 50.2 7.5 30.1Landfill gas (LFG) 90% 0% 20% 0% 2% 2.5 18.8 2.5 15.1 2.3 13.5Biomass 80% 0% 20% 0% 2% 2.5 18.8 2.5 15.1 2.3 13.5Wave 35% no data no data no data no data 4.4 7.6 no data no data no data no dataTidal 35% no data no data no data no data 4.7 9.6 no data no data no data no dataGeothermal (large) 95% 10% 25% 1% 3% 2.5 15.1 2.5 12.5 2.1 10.3

Note: Cost estimates are for all OECD countries; the wide range of values reflects both the diversity of conditions experienced and the high levels of uncertainty.

* Assuming logarithmic cost reductions

Source: IEA figures cited by Martin Tampier in “Background Document for the Green Power Workshop Series, Workshop 4,” Prepared for Pollution Probe and the Summerhill Group, February 2004, pp. 30–32.

1 It is widely recognized that issues related to grid access, grid capacity and the costs of grid extension will be particularly influen-tial in determining the amount of grid-power RETs that can be practically developed. While these issues are beginning to beaddressed in some regions, they are far from being resolved at this time. Further consideration of these issues is well beyond the scope of this case study.

Page 111: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

Finally, the share of total electricity generation inCanada in 2010 covered under this case study is presented in Table 6. As can be seen, the case study is concerned only with 37% of electrical generationin Canada in 2010.

4 ECONOMIC AND POLICY ANALYSIS—APPLICATION TO CANADA

This section presents the modelling results for eachof the fiscal instruments. The discussion is organizedand presented as follows:

• Overview of the fiscal instruments that are assessed;

• Overview of the Resources for the Future (RFF)model used to assess the instruments;

• Summary of results (including a road map for understanding the results);

• Detailed discussion of the base case and each fiscal instrument; and

• Sensitivity analysis results.

4.1 Fiscal Instruments Assessed In collaboration with the NRTEE, a base case andfive fiscal instruments were selected and modelled.The five instruments are:

1An emissions price, which is analogous to an emissions trading permit system or a carbon tax.Under this scenario, a shadow price is placed on carbon equivalent to $10/tonne CO2. Thisshadow price is equivalent to the cost of an emis-sions trading permit or the tax rate on carbon.The emissions price is applied uniformly across all fossil fuel generation in Canada in 2010.

2A renewable portfolio standard (RPS), whichrequires utilities to buy green certificates, or theequivalent, so that renewable generation increasesrelative to fossil fuel generation. The model com-pares renewable generation attributable to an RPSwith generation from fossil fuels (i.e., not all elec-trical generation). Constraints are not placed ontechnologies or regional shares of the total RPS.Instead, the prevailing electricity price determinesthe type of technology used to generate electricity.

3A renewable generation subsidy (RGS), which ismodelled as a direct subsidy from government togrid-power RET producers on a per-kWh basis.In practice, a subsidy could include any fiscalinstrument that lowers the cost of production forproducers, such as a direct production subsidy ora capital cost allowance.

4A combination of RPS and generation subsidy,modelled in tandem. We let the RPS be the dominant policy, since the standard is meaning-less if the subsidy encourages more renewablegeneration than required. A notable feature ofthis combination is that the price of the green certificates is offset in part by the subsidy, in contrast to the situation where the instrumentsare implemented in isolation. This outcome willtherefore trigger some redistribution of costs.

5An R&D subsidy, which is a program to reducethe future cost of renewable generation. As such, the instrument can be anticipated to have a greater impact in future periods. The modelidentifies the annual increase in renewable energy R&D required to achieve the emissionreduction target.

97Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

Table 6: Projected Share of Grid-Power RETs and Fossil Fuel Generation in 2010

Electricity-generating Projected Share of technology electricity total

generation generationin 2010 (GWh)

Grid-power RETs(as included in this study) 31,000* 5%Fossil fuels (coal, gas, oil as included in this study) 198,000** 32%Other (nuclear and renewables excludedfrom this study) 394,000 63%Total 623,000** 100%

*2003. National Energy Board, Canada’s Energy Future:Scenarios for Supply and Demand to 2025 (Techno-VertScenario) <www.neb-one.gc.ca/energy/SupplyDemand/2003/index_e.htm>.

**1999. Natural Resources Canada, Canada’s Emissions Outlook:An Update <www.nrcan.gc.ca/es/ceo/update.htm>.

Page 112: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

98 National Round Table on the Environment and the Economy

In the model, the levels of the instruments, such asan RPS target (i.e., 10% of generation from renew-ables) or a subsidy level (i.e., $0.01 per kWh), aresolved endogenously. Each instrument is required to achieve a common emission reduction (or policytarget), and then the model indicates the policy level that would achieve the carbon target.

4.2 Overview of RFF Renewable Energy Uptake Model

The RFF unified analytical model was employed to assess the impacts of the fiscal instruments onreducing greenhouse gas emissions, as well as thedevelopment and diffusion of renewable energy. This model was developed and tested for the U.S.Environmental Protection Agency to assess the pre-ferred fiscal instruments for promoting renewableenergy technologies. The analytical model includestwo sectors, one emitting and one non-emitting, andboth are assumed to be perfectly competitive andsupplying an identical product, electricity. Fossil fuel production is the marginal technology, settingthe overall market price; thus, to the extent thatrenewable energy is competitive, it displaces fossilfuel generation in future policy periods.

The model has two stages: a short-term stage cover-ing 2010 to 2015, and a longer-term stage covering2015 to 2030. Electricity generation, consumptionand emissions occur in both, while investment inknowledge takes place in the first stage, followed bytechnological change and innovation that lowers thecost of renewable generation in the second.

The carbon-emitting sector of the electrical genera-tion industry relies on fossil fuels. These are a maturetechnology, and the productivity improvements available through new R&D are assumed to be negli-gible.2 The marginal production costs of the sectorare assumed to be constant with respect to output,increasing with reductions in emission intensity. Therepresentative firm chooses an emission intensity toequate the additional costs of abatement to the priceof emissions. The full marginal costs of generationthen include both the marginal production costs,given the emission intensity choice, and any effectivetax, such as the price of the emissions or carbonembodied in an extra unit of output, or the cost ofgreen certificates under an RPS. As long as fossil fuelgeneration occurs, the competitive market price mustequal the sum of these marginal costs.

Another sector of the industry generates withoutemissions by using renewable resources. Unlike the fossil supply curve, which is flat and set at thelong-term marginal cost of electricity, the renewablesupply curve slopes upward, reflecting marginal production costs that increase with output. Becauserenewables are a young technology, the costs ofrenewable power shift down over time as the knowl-edge stock increases. There are two ways to increasethe knowledge stock: through investments in R&Dand “learning by doing,” which is a function of totaloutput during the first stage in the model. The repre-sentative renewable energy firm chooses output ineach stage as well as R&D investment to maximizeprofits. In the first stage, it produces until the mar-ginal cost of production equals the value it receivesfrom additional output, including the competitivemarket price, any production subsidy, and the contribution of such output to future cost reductionthrough learning by doing. The firm also invests inresearch until the discounted returns from R&Dequal investment costs on the margin.

Since we target equivalent emission reductions foreach of the fiscal instruments, we hold the environ-mental effects constant across the policy scenarios.While we calculate the costs of achieving emissiontargets in this case study, the benefits of the fiscalinstruments are not estimated. The fiscal instrumentsthrough their displacement of fossil fuel can beexpected to trigger a number of environmental andeconomic benefits, including:

• improved ambient air quality and reduced carbonin the atmosphere;

• avoided ambient air quality impacts on sensitiveecosystem and health receptors and the associatedeconomic value of the avoided damages; and

• climate change mitigation benefits such as avoidedecosystem, health and economic damages stem-ming from extreme weather events, temperaturechanges and sea-level rise and the associated economic value of the avoided damages.

While they are important in assessing the desirabilityof the fiscal instruments from a social perspective, thebenefits are in a sense fixed in the case study becauseof the stipulation of a common emission target thatall instruments achieve.

2 While it is not strictly true that fossil fuel technologies will experience no further technological advance, incorporation of a positivebut slower relative rate of advance in fossil fuels would complicate the analysis without adding substantial additional insights.

Page 113: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

4.3 Summary Results When reviewing the summary results, it is useful tounderstand that the outcomes are a function of howeach instrument influences the energy market. In the model, outcomes differ due to changes in threedecarbonization drivers: renewable power penetra-tion, the carbon intensity of fossil fuel generation and total electricity demand.

The outcomes listed in Table 7 can be traced back to an instrument’s ability to affect one or all of thethree decarbonization drivers in the electricity mar-ket. Generally speaking, an instrument will be moreeconomically efficient if it targets all of these threedrivers. For purposes of comparison, the base caseindicators are provided to allow for comparison withthe policy scenarios. In the no-policy base case, ourmodel predicts that renewable energy generation willincrease from 13% to 17% of included generation inthe second stage, which corresponds to a 5% emis-sion reduction. Subsequent policy scenarios willtarget a 12% reduction overall from the combinedemissions in the two stages of the no-policy case.

The numbered items in the first column of Table 7are defined as follows:

1Policy level for 12% emission reduction: This rowprovides an estimate of the size of the fiscalinstrument required to achieve the carbon reduction target:

• For the emissions price, a tax of $10/tonne CO2 would achieve the 12% reduction in totalcarbon emissions from the base case.

• For the RPS, a portfolio standard of 24% wouldachieve the 12% carbon reduction. This 24% isthe final share of renewable power generation in the generation covered by this case study—which consists of both renewable and fossil fuel generation but excludes major hydro and nuclear.

• For the RGS, a value of about $0.006/kWhachieves the policy objective of a 12% carbonreduction.

• When combined with a subsidy of $0.002, theRPS needs to be set at a slightly higher target of 24.2%.

• For the R&D subsidy, a program that increasesR&D spending by 61% annually above thebase-case R&D levels would achieve the target.

2Electricity price ($/kWh): This row indicates theimpact of the fiscal measure on the annual priceof electricity in the first and second stages (2015and 2030, respectively).

3Carbon emissions (Mt): Carbon emissions are pre-sented as annual estimates in megatonnes of CO2for the last years in the first and second stages.Carbon reductions are influenced by the threedrivers in the following ways:

• Renewable power penetration displaces fossil generation when an instrument reduces renewable production costs relative to fossil generation costs.

• The carbon intensity of fossil fuel generation isreduced when carbon is priced in the fossil sec-tor (i.e., abatement from natural gas generationthat displaces coal).

• An increase in the electricity price reduces totalelectricity demand, which displaces output fromfossil fuels.

For each scenario, carbon emissions are estimated bymultiplying the “on margin” emission intensity offossil fuel by the quantity of fossil fuel supplied.

4Renewable output (MWh 10^11): This row indi-cates the output of renewable generation in thetwo stages. Renewable output is a function of production cost differentials between renewablesand fossil fuels. Instruments affect the cost differ-ential through subsidizing renewable generation,inducing renewable production cost decreasesthrough innovation, and/or taxing fossil fuel production. Instruments that promote innovationreduce renewable costs and carbon emissions inthe second stage.

5Fossil output (MWh 10^11): As with renewableoutput, fossil fuel output is altered by the instru-ments through price changes in production costs.Fossil output is also altered by total demandreductions, which occur when an instrumentincreases the price of electricity.

6Total electricity output (MWh 10^11): Total generation includes fossil and renewable output;changes indicate that the instrument influencesfinal demand through electricity price increases.

7Renewable R&D ($M): Expenditures are expressedin millions of dollars annually in total R&Dspending by the public and private sectors.

99Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

Page 114: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

100 National Round Table on the Environment and the Economy

8Additional renewable cost reduction: This row indi-cates the percent reduction in the cost of therenewable supply below the base case.

9�Consumer surplus ($M): This is the net con-sumer cost of the instrument measured as thechange in the present value of the total cost toconsumers for both stages. The consumer surplus

is negative and is present when the instrumentincreases the price of electricity.

10� Producer surplus ($M): This is the change inthe measure of total profit in the renewablesector for both stages. Renewable sector profitsincrease when the instrument raises the pricereceived by renewable generation, either by a

Table 7: Summary of Modelling Results for Fiscal Instruments (2000 $)

Base case Emissions Renewable Renewable Combination Renewable price portfolio generation RPS and research

standard subsidy RGS subsidy1. Policy level for 12%

emission reduction $10/t CO2 24% of $0.006 RPS=24.21% 61%generation RGS=$0.002in case*

2. Electricity price (in $/kWh)1st stage $0.092 $0.097 $0.095 $0.092 $0.095 $0.0922nd stage $0.092 $0.097 $0.093 $0.092 $0.092 $0.092

3. Carbon emissions (Mt)1st stage 106 98.10 91.00 98.97 91.08 104.002nd stage 101 84.40 91.90 83.50 91.95 77.40

4. Renewable output (MWh 10^11) 1st stage 0.29 0.40 0.54 0.42 0.55 0.312nd stage 0.38 0.66 0.55 0.72 0.55 0.83

5. Fossil output (MWh 10^11)1st stage 2.00 1.85 1.71 1.87 1.72 1.982nd stage 1.91 1.59 1.73 1.57 1.73 1.46

6. Total electricity output (MWh 10^11)1st stage 2.29 2.25 2.26 2.29 2.27 2.292nd stage 2.29 2.25 2.28 2.29 2.29 2.29

7. Renewable R&D ($M) $129 $450 $320 $533 $325 $1,5768. Additional renewable

cost reduction 0% 15% 13% 16% 13% 26%9. �Consumer surplus ($M) $0 ($11,690) ($4,521) $0 ($3,533) $010.�Producer surplus ($M) $0 $2, 215 $3,480 $2,846 $3,547 $1,59011.�Transfers ($M) $0 $8,896 $0 ($3,557) ($1,072) ($3,890)12.�Welfare—no benefits

measured ($M) (9+10+11=12) $0 ($579) ($1,041) ($711) ($1,058) ($2,300)

13.�Welfare relative to emissions price — 1.00 1.80 1.23 1.83 3.97

Figures may not sum due to rounding.

* This is 9% of all annual Canadian generation.

Source: Marbek Resource Consultants and Resources for the Future.

Page 115: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

subsidy or a tax on fossil generation. Whenthis occurs, profits can be made if somerenewable production costs are below theinstrument electricity price in the scenario.

11� Transfers ($M): This is the change in govern-ment revenues, where a positive number isrevenue and a negative one is a disbursement.Again, the estimate is a total cost for both stages.

12� Welfare (excluding environmental benefits)($M): This is the change in social welfare andis a proxy for the societal cost of the instru-ment. It is the sum of consumer and producersurpluses and transfers. It is an important met-ric, since all scenarios achieve the same carbonreduction target, yet have differing social costs.

13� Welfare relative to emissions price: This is simply a ratio that indicates the welfare costsof each scenario compared with the emissionsprice scenario. The emissions price is selectedas the basis for comparison since it has thelowest welfare cost.

4.4 Detailed Results by Instrument

4.4.1 Base CaseThe base case provides the reference from which the percentage changes are estimated in Table 7.Renewable power penetration is forecast based on therelative costs of fossil fuel and renewable production.The baseline penetration of renewables increases overtime, reflecting decreasing renewable power produc-tion costs due to innovation.

Total electricity output remains fixed in both periodsin the base case3, and thus increased penetration ofrenewables decreases the carbon intensity of overallgeneration. This reduction is captured as a decreasein carbon emissions over time, from an annual level of 106 Mt in the first stage to 101 Mt in thesecond stage.

4.4.2 Emissions PriceAn emissions price works to reduce emissions byreflecting their cost, either in environmental damage(as with an environmental levy) or opportunity costelsewhere in the economy (as with an emissions cap-and-trade system). This price sends a signal toeveryone in the energy market to conserve carbon.

Fossil energy producers can reduce costs by boostingefficiency or switching to lower-carbon fuels andprocesses. Since the price of fossil energy will thenincorporate the cost of the carbon associated withthat form of generation, the price of electricity will also rise, creating two effects. First, it signals consumers to conserve and take advantage of oppor-tunities to reduce their demand by, for example,adopting more energy-efficient appliances. Second, it increases the price received by renewable energy producers, encouraging production and investment in non-emitting generation technologies. From a distributional perspective:

1Consumers incur the highest electricity priceincrease and consumer surplus loss under theemissions price. Since consumers are also taxpayers, the use of the revenues (i.e., transfers) is important in assessing the net effect on households.

2For renewable energy producers, the emissionsprice has a modest but significant impact onrenewable output, production cost decreases andproducer surplus. The impact is also relativelyconsistent across stages.

3For fossil fuel electricity generators, the emissionsprice is the only policy with an incentive toreduce emission intensity. Although profits for the fossil sector are not modelled—rather, theyare assumed to be driven to zero in the long runby the market—the potential costs to the fossilsector under an emissions price would depend on its ability to pass along the production costincreases due to carbon abatement (i.e., coal togas) to consumers, as well as any windfall gainsfrom permit allocation.

4For government, significant transfers or revenuecould be raised under the emissions price, eitherthrough a tax-based system that collects revenueor through the allocation or auctioning of carbonpermits under an emissions trading system. Thisis the only modelled scenario where significantgovernment revenue potential exists. It also repre-sents the value of the emissions rents, which areavailable to be allocated to consumers, generatorsand their shareholders, funds for transition assis-tance, or taxpayers more generally.

101Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

3 It is recognized that electrical production is increasing over time, but total electricity output in the model is fixed in both stagesso that the demand and supply responses of the policies can be better understood.

Page 116: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

102 National Round Table on the Environment and the Economy

5For society as a whole, welfare costs are lowestwith the emissions price, making it the preferredoption. One negative consequence of this sce-nario, not incorporated into this single-sectoranalysis, is that the increase in electricity pricescould lead to economy-wide competitiveness.Reserving some permits for allocation to trade-exposed sectors that are electricity-intensive couldmitigate these impacts.

6An advantage of a cap-and-trade system is cer-tainty in reaching the carbon target; however,uncertainty will then manifest itself in the price.All the other policies face challenges in setting a policy level that would achieve the emissionstarget with certainty.

4.4.3 Renewable Portfolio StandardThe renewable portfolio standard requires total elec-tricity generation to be based on a minimum share ofrenewable sources. Although such a market sharerequirement can be implemented in several ways—quota obligations for retailers, green certificates forfossil generators—the general effect is the same. Aslong as the market would not meet the requirementon its own, renewable energy producers receive aprice premium (the value of the green certificatesthey generate), while fossil energy producers receive a negative one (the cost of the green certificates they must buy in proportion to their generation).Moreover, the total subsidy to renewable energy producers is equal to the total effective tax paid byfossil energy generators, so no net revenues are raisedor lost by the government.

Since the RPS does not distinguish among fossil gen-eration technologies, there is no incentive to reduceemission intensity in that sector. Consumer pricesrise due to the effective tax on fossil energy to fundthe renewable subsidy (i.e., buy green certificates),but not as much as with the emissions price instru-ment. Although under the RPS more renewableenergy is generated than under the emissions price,the timing of that generation is changed. Normally,when prices are fixed, as costs fall over time renew-able generation expands. However, the RPS fixes theshare of renewables in both periods, and over timethis becomes easier to meet; hence, the effective taxand subsidy fall (i.e., the price of green certificatesfalls), while total electricity generation increases withthe reduced price (the market price is equal to theprice of electricity plus the price of green certificates,which fall due to innovation over time; therefore,electricity prices fall and final demand increases).

Renewables then get a bigger boost in the first periodand less in the second. The larger current subsidymay enable more learning by doing; however, recognizing that the support will fall in the future,investment in cost-reducing R&D may be smaller(this result is borne out in our scenarios). From a distributional perspective:

1Consumers experience some electricity priceincrease and consumer surplus loss under theRPS. This effect is about 80% as large as with theemissions price in the first stage, and nearly negli-gible in the second. The electricity price rise isdue to the purchase of renewable power in theform of green certificates (or the equivalent) bythe fossil sector. Since renewables become cheaperwith technical innovation, the cost of green cer-tificates (and thereby consumer prices) is higherin the first stage but lower in the second as thecost of renewable supply decreases.

2For renewable energy producers, the RPS inducesa high uniform penetration through both periods,which is not surprising since the RPS fixes theshare of renewables in both periods. Producerprofits are also high, indicating the potential forthe sector to benefit under an RPS. While there iscertainty in terms of market share for the renew-able sector, there is less stability in prices and lessflexibility in the timing of renewable energy gen-eration. Furthermore, the fact that the implicitsubsidy falls over time with cost decreases meansthat incentives for innovation may be muted—indeed, our model predicts less R&D spendingthan under the emissions price. Although morerenewable generation is needed overall, so muchis done in the first stage that the return on lower-ing costs in the second stage is reduced, bothbecause of the lower second-stage output (relativeto the other policy scenarios) and also possiblybecause of greater learning by doing in the firststage, which can substitute for R&D.

3For fossil fuel generators, output shares remainsteady in the two periods, with lower output inthe first stage and higher output in the secondcompared with other scenarios. In other words,cost reductions in renewables allow for fossil sec-tor expansion. Still, short-term transitional costscould be expected to be greater under the RPSthan in other scenarios. Actual potential costs tothe fossil sector under an RPS will be higher if itis not fully able to pass along the costs of greencertificates to consumers.

Page 117: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

4For government, the RPS has a neutral impact,with no revenue and no program disbursements.

5For society as a whole, the welfare costs aregreater than with the emissions price and generation subsidy, but lower than with the combination and R&D subsidy. This rankingdoes not necessarily hold in all circumstances but rather depends on the particular trade-offbetween the extra costs of encouraging moreeffort upfront and the inefficiencies of not givingconsumers incentives to conserve. Indeed, if onecoped with the former problem by optimallydesigning the RPS requirement to increase overtime, the RPS could be made to dominate thesubsidy always, due to the presence of the modestconservation incentive.

6Looking beyond the electricity sector, the increasein electricity prices risks causing some economy-wide competitiveness impacts such as decreasedproductivity or reduced exports, but these effectswill be less severe than with the emissions price,particularly in the second stage.

4.4.4 Renewable Generation SubsidyThis fiscal instrument includes a range of possiblepolicies that subsidize renewable energy generation(e.g., tax credits or direct subsidies) to encourage theexpansion of carbon-free generation; however, theydo nothing to encourage conservation or reduce theemission intensity of fossil generators. As well, thereis no impact on the price of electricity, and thus con-sumers are not encouraged to reduce demand andtherefore carbon emissions. Hence, much more effortmust be expended on higher-priced renewables todisplace fossil generation and meet the carbon reduc-tion target. From a distributional perspective:

1Consumer prices are not affected in the subsidyscenario, since all of the reductions are suppliedthrough lower renewable energy costs, which do not affect the fossil fuel sector directly.Consumers would be indirectly affected since it istheir tax revenue that funds some portion of thesubsidy transferred to the renewable sector.

2For renewable energy producers, the generationsubsidy has the largest impact on profits, sincethey must be encouraged to displace more fossiloutput than in the preceding scenarios. Ongoinginnovation is stimulated by the greater scope forreducing production costs at the higher outputlevels induced by the price premium.

3For fossil fuel generators, the impact of the gener-ation subsidy on fossil output is similar to that of the emissions price, since the additional renewable energy generation is partly offset byadditional demand. The decline in output isslightly larger in the second stage, due to themore dramatic increase in the competitiveness ofrenewables from innovation. It might seem sur-prising that fossil output may be lower with thesubsidy than with the emissions price, since theelectricity price increase is absent. However, sincethe fossil sector lacks an opportunity to adjust itsown emissions, the full burden of reductions fallson renewables to displace fossil output.

4For government, the subsidy required to achievethe emission reduction target is a significant disbursement.

5For society as a whole, welfare costs are greaterthan with the emissions price. With respect toreaching the emissions target, the renewable subsidy is likely to suffer from greater uncertaintythan the preceding policies. Although not mod-elled, the reasoning is twofold:

• First, the uncertainty over the scope and speed of cost reductions in renewables is likely to begreater than uncertainty surrounding the costs of abatement in the fossil sector or the extent ofconservation by consumers.

• Second, even if all cost uncertainties were similar, the reliance on only one method ofemission reductions raises overall uncertainty. Ina broader scenario, if innovation does not lowerrenewable energy production costs significantly,one could engage in relatively more emissionabatement or conservation, whichever turns outto have the lower costs.

The renewable subsidy alone has more uncertaintyregarding how much emissions will be reduced. Italso has more uncertainty regarding the revenuerequirement. If costs fall more than expected, a highsubsidy would induce an oversupply relative to thecarbon target, reflecting additional efficiency loss, as well as lost public funds. If costs do not fall asexpected, either the emissions targets will not be met(and some public funds will be saved) or the subsidymust be increased even more to meet them, requiringgreater-than-expected outlays.

103Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

Page 118: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

104 National Round Table on the Environment and the Economy

4.4.5 A Combination of RPS and RGSRenewable energy is often addressed by a combina-tion of policies. Reasons include the overlappingjurisdictions of the federal, provincial and local governments and, perhaps, a desire for diversifica-tion. We have estimated the effects of placing aportfolio standard and a renewable production subsidy in place simultaneously. The key result is that the subsidy weakens the effect of the portfoliostandard and raises costs slightly.

With both policies, the fossil fuel producer must stillpurchase green certificates for every unit of electricitygenerated. For the renewable energy producer, thereare now two subsidies—the value of a green certifi-cate and the direct subsidy. Since the direct subsidyboosts renewable supply, the equilibrium price of a green certificate does not need to be as high toreach the portfolio standard (compared with the RPSimplemented in isolation). Consequently, when the policy target is a portfolio share, a direct subsidyto renewables primarily offsets the burden to fossilproducers and consumers instead.

Since we assume the RPS is the driving policy instru-ment in our combination scenario, the distributionaleffects are quite similar to those of the RPS alone.The slight differences are as follows:

1Consumer prices are slightly lower. Despite theadditional electricity demand, emissions are also lower in the first stage—this is because thestandard must be raised to offset the loss of conservation incentive, leading to even morereduction in the first stage and less in the second.

2Renewable energy production is 0.5% higher andR&D spending is 1.5% higher.

3For fossil fuel generators, output is nearlyunchanged relative to the portfolio standardalone. This is because, even though the fossil fuelproducer has to buy more certificates, the cost ofthese certificates is lower because the subsidy hasgenerated a greater supply of them.

4Perhaps the most telling effect is that the govern-ment in this combination scenario spends justover $1 billion on a subsidy that has little or no effect on behaviour, given the presence of the RPS.

5From society’s perspective, to the extent the sub-sidy does affect behaviour, it tends to lower pricesand raise overall welfare costs. The weaker conser-vation incentive and the additional frontloadingof emission reduction efforts (through increases inthe RPS) lead to an increase in welfare costs, from1.80 to 1.83 times that of the emissions price.

4.4.6 Renewable Research SubsidyThe renewable research subsidy uses current invest-ments in reducing costs to increase future renewableenergy production. Since it does not change any price incentives for demand or production, or changecurrent costs, all the burden of emission reductions isplaced on future displacement of fossil by renewableenergy generation. Furthermore, given the lack offuture production incentives, the required cost reduc-tions are large and the required investments evenlarger. The ability of an R&D subsidy alone todeliver all of this is clearly an area of uncertainty.From a distributional perspective:

1Consumers do not experience electricity priceincreases and consumer surplus losses under theR&D subsidy. As with the generation subsidy,they indirectly contribute to the renewable sector through tax contributions to fund theR&D subsidy.

2For renewable energy producers, the R&D sub-sidy induces the highest penetration in the secondstage. This penetration is driven exclusively byinnovation and cost decreases from renewableproduction. An important caveat is the degree to which Canadian learning by doing and R&Dcan drive cost decreases in renewables. While such production cost decreases are observed inCanada and internationally, it is not certain thatCanadian R&D alone can reduce costs suffi-ciently to achieve the high levels of renewablepower penetration predicted in this scenario. As a general observation, innovation in renewableproduction occurs internationally and is importedinto Canada. This uncertainty regarding the ability of domestic R&D subsidies to achieve the penetration predicted in the model only reinforces the conclusion that this policy is a much more costly method for achieving emission reductions.

Page 119: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

3For fossil fuel generators, the R&D subsidy doesnot affect electricity price, but it does signifi-cantly reduce fossil output in the second stage.Although not modelled, costs associated withstranded assets or variable costs due to lowercapacity utilization could arise. But transactioncosts associated with decreased fossil demand arelikely lower in this scenario, since a majority ofreductions occur in the second stage. Thus, thetransition period for the fossil sector to adjust todecreased demand is long and there is potentialfor costs to be minimized.

4For government, the R&D subsidy requires thelargest disbursement of the instruments. Thatsaid, promoting innovation is a government pol-icy, and therefore R&D programs are generallypart of a desirable policy approach to long-termcarbon emission reductions. However, given thelonger-term nature of the reductions associatedwith R&D, a government faced with a carbonreduction target would likely not achieve signifi-cant reductions in the short term under an R&D program.

5From society’s perspective, welfare costs are great-est under the R&D subsidy. Another negativeconsequence of this scenario is uncertainty. As with the renewable generation subsidy, theuncertainty of renewable cost reductions makesthis a relatively risky policy for promoting carbonreductions—all the more so, since in the absenceof cost reductions, there is no incentive for addi-tional uptake of renewables in either stage. Giventhe uncertainty over innovation success in generaland the impact of domestic efforts in particular, itis highly uncertain that a domestic R&D programalone could achieve a significant carbon reductiontarget through renewable generation. Instead, anR&D subsidy can be seen as a complementaryinstrument that could be used to achieve longer-term societal goals such as promoting innovation.

4.5 Sensitivity AnalysisTo further test the robustness of the results presentedin the preceding discussion, a sensitivity analysis wasconducted for the following factors:

1An increase in the baseline price of electricity: The sensitivity analysis shows that the differentialbetween the renewables price and the electricityprice is an important determinant of the size ofthe welfare cost. As well, this differential affectsthe desirability of an RPS compared with a renew-able generation subsidy. These results can also beexpected when the price of renewables changes;that is, a decrease in the price of renewableswould produce results that are directionally similar to an increase in the electricity price.

2An increase in the baseline price of natural gas:The sensitivity results indicate that increasing natural gas prices have a minimal impact on theoutcomes with respect to the reference case. Asdiscussed in the previous scenario, however,increasing gas prices could increase the price ofelectricity, and the response would be similar toan electricity price increase.

The sensitivity testing concludes that the results arerobust to changing key variable assumptions. Indeed,our core observation holds: the economic efficiencyand environmental effectiveness of the EFR instru-ments are linked to their ability to influence theentire electricity market and the three decarbonizingdrivers in particular. As a general rule, an EFR instrument will be more efficient and effective if itsignals to multiple agents in the electricity marketthat carbon is more expensive: fossil producers willreduce their emission intensity; renewable power producers will supply more output when the pricedifferential between renewable and fossil generationdecreases; and consumers will take measures to con-serve electricity, reduce demand and displace fossiloutput. This finding holds under multiple inputassumptions and explains why an emissions price ispreferable to either an RPS or RGS. A good exampleof the increased risk in using a single instrument ishighlighted by the R&D instrument scenario, wherethe emission reduction is entirely dependent on theability of R&D investments to reduce renewableenergy costs through innovation. While cost reduc-tions can be expected from R&D spending, the scopeand scale of the cost reductions are questionable, thusincreasing the overall uncertainty in the instrument.

105Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

Page 120: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

106 National Round Table on the Environment and the Economy

5 LESSONS LEARNED

Unquestionably, EFR instruments have traction withrespect to decarbonizing electricity and increasing theuptake of renewables. Our results indicate that a widerange of EFR instruments can be used to decarbonizethe economy and increase the installed capacity ofrenewable technologies. Important lessons learnedinclude the following:

1 Instruments are most economically efficient andenvironmentally effective if they are comprehensivelyapplied and target all actors in a market: Each EFR instrument outlined in the case study hasdifferent impacts on the three principal elementsof an electricity market:

• renewable power penetration, which is howmuch of total Canadian electricity generation is supplied by renewable power;

• the carbon intensity of fossil fuel generation,which is how much carbon a unit of electricitygenerated by fossil fuels contains. Carbon inten-sity can be reduced by using natural gas insteadof coal, for example; and

• total electricity demand, where consumers canreduce their electricity demand by practisingenergy conservation.

The success of one or more EFR instruments willrest on their ability to continue to influence theentire electricity market and these three decar-bonization drivers in particular. Of the EFRoptions presented:

• the emissions price is the most effective at influ-encing the market and its drivers. It provides themeans for attenuating negative effects;

• the renewable portfolio standard ensures a highpenetration rate for renewables in the short andlonger terms but only marginally influences con-sumer behaviour;

• the renewable generation subsidy ensures aneven higher penetration rate for renewables, butit does not influence consumer behaviour orencourage electricity producers to work towardlower, permanent carbon emission intensities;

• a mix of RPS and RGS produces a slightly betterresult than the RPS or the RGS alone—however,the welfare cost is very high due to significantgovernment disbursements to achieve the result; and

• the renewable research subsidy has considerablepositive impact on the renewable sector, but itdoes nothing to influence the other drivers orassure market penetration in the long run.

2A small portion of renewable energy technologies arecompetitive with fossil fuel generation now: Giventhat some renewables are competitive now, EFRinstruments can be expected to increase theinstalled capacity of renewables in Canada tosome degree. However, ambitious carbon reduc-tions will require binding EFR instruments thatclose the price gap between fossil generation andrenewable technologies.

3 Innovation reduces renewable energy costs:Innovation in renewable technologies will primarily come from international sources andultimately reduce renewable supply costs inCanada. Thus the installed capacity of renewablesin Canada can be expected to grow over time inthe absence of EFR polices.

4Renewables are an immature technology with uncer-tain costs and practical potential: Any modellingeffort that targets renewables is faced with signifi-cant uncertainty in forecasting price and practicalpotential. This uncertainty is unavoidable, andthe modelling should address uncertainty.

5Renewables are at different stages of technologicaldevelopment: This implies that some instruments,such as an RPS, can be effective in deployingrenewable technologies that are commerciallyviable in the short term, whereas R&D subsidiesare better suited to targeting technologies still inthe developmental stage.

6The temporal impacts of the EFR instruments differ:The path of emission reductions and renewablepower penetration can vary significantly betweeninstruments. Instruments that require reductionsfrom renewables in the short term will necessarilybe more costly than instruments that targetlonger-term reductions. This effect occurs whenthe price of renewable supply drops over time.

7The distributional consequences of the EFR instru-ments differ significantly: Comparing overallinstrument costs can mask the distributional consequences of an EFR instrument. Table 8 provides an overview of the distributional conse-quences of the instruments included in this case study.

Page 121: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

107Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

Table 8: Summary of Distributional Results

I. II. III. IV. V. VI. Base case Emissions Renewable Renewable Combination Renewable

price portfolio generation RPS and research standard subsidy RGS subsidy

To achieve a 12% carbon emission reduction target from 2010 to 2030, you would see…

Impacts on electricity generation

Impacts on consumers

Impacts on government

Impacts on the renewable sector

(No attemptto reach target)

Renewablesgain somemarketshare; carbon isreduced by5%

Status quo

Status quo

Status quo;some continuedpenetration

Emitters pay$10 for eachtonne of CO2

Renewablespenetrateslightly morequickly than inI; electricityproducers workhardest onreducing car-bon emissions

Electricityprices rise the most; conservationemphasized;negativeimpacts onsome sectors

Governmentrevenues raised(as governmentcollects onemissionsprice); redistribution toaffected sectorsis possible

Output up;productioncost down;some profit;R&D levelshigh

Renewableshave a 24%share of casestudy genera-tion—9% ofannual totalCanadiangeneration

A greaterpenetrationof renewablesthan in II;costly forelectricityproducers atfirst butcosts fallover time

Overall elec-tricity pricesare lowerthan in II,but rise andthen fall; con-servation notemphasized

No governmentrevenuesraised, lostor transferred

Output upmore than inII; slightlymore profitthan in II;but less R&Dis done

Governmentsubsidy of$0.006 foreach kWhgenerated byrenewables

A greaterpenetrationof renewablesthan in II;not a driverof loweremissionsintensity (= higherefficiency)

Electricityprices remainthe same;conservationnot empha-sized

Governmentmakes significantdisbursementsto fund thesubsidy

Greater profits asmore produc-tion lowerscosts; highinvestmentin R&D

An RPS at24.21% andan RGS at$0.002

Slightly morerenewablesin the mix;fossil fuel–generatedoutputremainsunchanged

Electricitypricesslightly lowerthan in IV;conservationnot empha-sized

Governmentmakes dis-bursements($1 billion)to fund thesubsidy

Outputslightlyhigher; R&Dalso higher

The publicand privatesectorsincreasetheir R&Dspending by61%

High pene-tration ofrenewablesnear end oftime frameonly

Electricityprices remainunchanged;conservationnot empha-sized

Governmentmakes significantdisbursementsto fund R&Din renewables

Highestpotentialpenetrationnear end oftime framewith highR&D

Table 8 continued on next page

Page 122: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

108 National Round Table on the Environment and the Economy

8Program design and detail matter, but they are notcaptured in the analysis: We assessed the EFRinstruments at a high level but observe thatenabling conditions significantly affect outcomes.Enabling conditions such as local permitting, reg-ulations, transmission distance and access to thegrid all affect the technical and economic feasibil-ity of the renewable supply and ultimately thepredicted results of the EFR instruments. Simplyassuming that the EFR instruments will achievecost-effective carbon reductions without a clearunderstanding of the enabling conditions for and barriers to the uptake of renewables is highlyrisky policy.

9Policy certainty and durability over the longer termare important: Policy certainty or the durability ofthe EFR instrument over the longer term is animportant driver of renewable uptake. This is par-ticularly the case for renewables where startupcapital costs are high and investment returns mustbe established prior to project implementation.

Table 8: Summary of Distributional Results (cont’d)

I. II. III. IV. V. VI. Base case Emissions Renewable Renewable Combination Renewable

price portfolio generation RPS and research standard subsidy RGS subsidy

Impacts on Canadian societal welfare*

Level of uncertainty in reaching target

* = adding together (1) costs to consumers and (2) losses/profits of electricity producers (both renewable and fossil fuel) and (3) net government revenues, but excluding environmental costs/benefits (e.g., the costs of adapting to climate change are notincluded here).

Status quo

Target is notachieved

Overall lowestwelfare costsof the fiveoptions

Low; all long-term carbonemissionreduction driv-ers are actedon to worktoward target

Greater wel-fare coststhan in IIand lowerthan in IV

Medium; onlytwo long-term carbonemissionreductiondriversaffected

Second highest welfare costs

Medium–high; onlyone long-term carbonemissionreductiondriveraffected

Welfare costsslightly lowerthan in IV

Medium; onlytwo long-term carbonemissionreductiondriversaffected

Highest welfare costs

High due toreliance onone long-term carbonemissionreductiondriver (pene-tration notassured)

Page 123: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

ENVIRONMENTAL CHOICECRITERIA FOR RENEWABLELOW-IMPACT ELECTRICITYSummary only; for full technical criteria, see “Electricity Generation” at <www.environmentalchoice.com>.

Renewable Low-Impact Electricity

From a consumer perspective, electricity is clean,cheap and has no visible environmental conse-quences. If we look beyond the outlets in our walls,however, environmental costs become apparent. InCanada, the major methods of generating electricityinclude burning fossil fuels, harnessing the power ofwater and using nuclear power. Each power sourcehas consequences for the environment, from creatingacid rain to flooding lands to disposing of radioactivewaste. The Environmental Choice Program has madea commitment to promoting electrical energy sourcesthat have greatly reduced environmental impacts. TheECP recognizes electricity that has been generatedfrom naturally occurring energy sources (such as thewind and the sun) and from power sources that, withthe proper controls, add little in the way of environ-mental burdens (such as less intrusive hydro andcertain biomass combustion).

Certification Criteria

All Sources

• The facility must be operating, reliable, non-temporary and practical.

• During project planning and development, appropriate consultation with communities andstakeholders must have occurred, and prior orconflicting land use, biodiversity losses and scenic, recreational and cultural values must have been addressed.

• No adverse impacts can be created for any speciesrecognized as endangered or threatened.

• Supplementary non-renewable fuels must not beused in more than 2% of the fuel heat inputrequired for generation.

• Sales levels of ECP-certified electricity must notexceed production/supply levels.

Specific Sources (additional criteria to those listed above)

• Solar (cadmium-containing wastes must be properly disposed of or recycled)

• Wind (protection of concentrations of birdsincluding endangered bird species)

• Water (compliance with regulatory licences; protection of indigenous species and habitat;requirements for head pond water levels, waterflows, water quality and water temperature; measures to minimize fish mortality and to ensure fish migration patterns)

• Biomass (use only wood wastes, agricultural wastesand/or dedicated energy crops; requirements forrates of harvest and environmental managementsystems/practices; maximum levels for emissions of air pollutants)

• Biogas (maximum levels for emissions of air pollutants; leachate management)

• Other technologies that use media such as hydrogen or compressed air to control, storeand/or convert renewable energy

• Geothermal technologies

109Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

Page 124: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions
Page 125: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

C. EXECUTIVE SUMMARY:CASE STUDY ON HYDROGENTECHNOLOGIES

By the Pembina Institute and the Canadian EnergyResearch Institute

1 OVERVIEW

The Pembina Institute and the Canadian EnergyResearch Institute (CERI) were commissioned tocomplete a study on the role of fiscal policy in pro-moting development of hydrogen technologies andreducing greenhouse gas emissions in Canada. Thisexercise produced two studies, a baseline report andan economic analysis report.

The baseline report describes the state of developmentof hydrogen technologies in Canada and the existingpolicy framework, and it provides an initial evalua-tion of a range of fiscal policy options for promotingthe development of hydrogen technologies. Thereport identifies six fiscal policies capable of provid-ing direct incentives for the development of hydrogentechnologies while explicitly addressing a major barrier limiting the technology’s market penetration. The six fiscal policies are investment tax credits, producer tax credits, accelerated capital costallowances, research and development grants, consumer tax credits and pilot projects. The initialevaluation focuses on producer incentives, designedto reduce the production cost of hydrogen technolo-gies, and consumer incentives, designed to reduce theend-use cost of hydrogen technologies. More specifi-cally, the fiscal policies considered in this analysisreduced the cost of hydrogen production, stationaryfuel cells, fuel-cell vehicles and buses, and hydrogeninternal combustion engine (ICE) vehicles.

The economic analysis report presents the results of the modelling exercise undertaken to test theimpact of these fiscal policies on particular hydrogentechnologies.

A national macroeconomic model—CERI’s Energy2020 model—was used to test the effect of the producer and consumer incentives on the marketpenetration of hydrogen technologies and associatedGHG emissions. The model simulated two methodsof hydrogen production: steam methane reformers(SMRs) and electrolysis. The modelling began with

a reference case (or business-as-usual model), towhich producer and consumer incentives were added(the fiscal scenario model). The results presentedbelow and in the economic analysis report reflect theimpact of a combination of producer and consumerincentives equivalent to a 25% decrease in produc-tion costs. For the transportation sector, the twodifferent methods of hydrogen production were simulated and the fiscal results presented for both.

In all relevant sectors, the fiscal policies increase the demand for energy associated with hydrogentechnologies. In the transportation sector, while theabsolute energy demand associated with hydrogentechnologies is not significant—constituting between0.03 and 34.87 petajoules (PJ) of demand in 2030,depending on the particular region—the increase in hydrogen-related energy demand is significant.Nationally, energy demand associated with hydrogen-related vehicles increases from 64.36 PJ in 2030 inthe SMR reference case and 62.24 PJ in 2030 in theelectrolysis reference case, to 96.26 PJ in 2030 in theSMR fiscal scenario model and 93.25 PJ in 2030 in the electrolysis fiscal scenario model. This is anincrease of almost 50%. In terms of the number of vehicles, the SMR fiscal scenario model leads to an increase of 47,312 fuel-cell vehicles, 33,371hydrogen ICE vehicles and 218 fuel-cell buses.Similar results are realized for hydrogen productionusing electrolysis. On a regional basis, the fiscal scenario model results in an increase of over 45% in hydrogen-related energy demand for mostprovinces and territories.

Like the transportation sector, the residential build-ing sector and the commercial sector realize anincrease in energy demand associated with stationaryfuel cells following the application of fiscal policies.In the residential building sector, energy demandfrom stationary fuel cells increases from 2.61 PJ in2030 in the reference case to 14.45 PJ in 2030 in the fiscal scenario model, for an increase of 454%.Similarly, in the commercial sector, energy demandfrom stationary fuel cells increases from 0.41 PJ in2030 in the reference case to 2.81 PJ in 2030 in thefiscal scenario model, for an increase of 592%. Interms of numbers of stationary fuel cells, the fiscalscenario model leads to an increase of 15,770 stationary fuel cells in the residential sector by 2030,with an increase of 90 in the commercial sector.

111Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

Page 126: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

112 National Round Table on the Environment and the Economy

In the fiscal scenario model, GHG emissions associated with the transportation, residential andcommercial sectors decline as the market penetrationof hydrogen technologies increases. In the transporta-tion sector, reductions in emissions equal 1,240 kt in 2030 for hydrogen produced from SMRs. If thehydrogen is produced from a source with almost noGHG emissions (i.e., wind or nuclear power), thereductions in emissions increase to 2,650 kt in 2030.The penetration of stationary fuel cells into the resi-dential and commercial sectors leads to a decline inGHG emissions of 710 kt from these sectors in2030. Taking into account the impact of mobile andstationary fuel cells, total GHG emissions in Canadadecline by 1,940 kt for hydrogen produced fromSMRs. These figures include GHG emissions associ-ated with hydrogen production. Taking into accountonly those emissions associated with hydrogen consumption (i.e., assuming that the hydrogen isproduced from zero-GHG emission sources, or thatany GHG emissions are captured), emissions declineby 3,360 kt for hydrogen produced by SMRs and3,370 kt for hydrogen produced by electrolysis.

The modelling analysis reveals that the reduction inGHG emissions as a result of the market penetrationof hydrogen technologies comes at a fairly high costper tonne. This high cost is due to the combinedeffect of the limited reductions in GHG emissionsthat are actually realized and the existing cost barriersassociated with the development of hydrogen tech-nologies. The producer and consumer incentivesreduce capital and operating costs by 25% each; how-ever, given the high costs associated with hydrogentechnologies (initially 50% more than the capitalcosts associated with conventional technologies in thetransportation sector), the investment required toachieve these reduced costs is significant.

This analysis reveals that fiscal policy could facilitatean increase in the market penetration of hydrogentechnologies in the transportation, residential andcommercial sectors. For all sectors, and in all regionsin Canada, the introduction of fiscal policies leads to increased demand for energy associated withhydrogen technologies. This result holds true on anabsolute basis and also as a percentage of total energy,with hydrogen technologies capturing a greater shareof total energy when fiscal policies are in place.

Despite these results, the market penetration ofhydrogen technologies is still relatively minor and thereduction in GHG emissions that is achieved is alsorelatively small, even with the fiscal policies.

2 LESSONS LEARNED

The time horizon for the hydrogen technologiesincluded in this modelling exercise is longer than that for the technologies considered in the two otherEFR case studies (i.e., energy-efficient and renewableenergy technologies). Even over a 30-year period, relatively little market penetration of hydrogen tech-nologies occurs. Reduced costs and technologicalimprovements would increase the competitiveness of hydrogen technologies.

1Given the long time frame associated with hydrogen technologies, any reductions in GHGemissions that result will also take place over along time period.

2The successful market penetration of hydrogentechnologies does not guarantee significant reduc-tions in GHG emissions. Consideration of sourcefuel and energy pathway is key if hydrogen is tobe part of a plan to reduce GHG emissions. If theintention is to increase penetration of hydrogentechnologies and reduce GHG emissions at thesame time, then a focus on low-emission hydro-gen sources is necessary (e.g., renewable energy,natural gas reformers and systems that capturecarbon emissions).

3Cost and technology barriers are still significantfor some technologies and are expected to remainso for the next 10 to 20 years.1

4Given the current cost barriers associated withhydrogen technologies, any reductions in GHGemissions that are achieved come at a very highcost. If the main objective of fiscal policy is toreduce GHG emissions in the near future, focusing on other methods to reduce GHG emissions is likely more cost-effective than focusing on hydrogen technologies.

1 According to the U.S. Department of Energy’s Hydrogen Posture Plan (2004), the introduction into the transportation market ofpersonal vehicles that use hydrogen is not expected to occur until after 2020. Hydrogen use in commercial fleets and distributedcombined heat and power (CHP) are on the same timeline.

Page 127: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

5 It may be most effective to focus fiscal policiesaimed at increasing the market penetration ofhydrogen technologies on technological improve-ments (research and development, demonstrationprojects) and cost reductions. As indicated initem 2 above, the application of fiscal policies tohydrogen technologies will not necessarily ensurereductions in GHG emissions unless the sourcefuel and energy pathway is taken into account inpolicy design.

6 In the transportation sector, increasing the marketpenetration of hydrogen technologies will requirea focus not only on cost reductions and improve-ments in efficiency but also on the supply andavailability of hydrogen fuel and hydrogen-relatedvehicles. There may be a role for fiscal policiestargeted at manufacturers and retailers in thisregard, although that is outside the scope of this analysis.

7The development of hydrogen technologies inCanada is and will be largely influenced by trendsin other countries, such as the United States,Japan and Germany. While such trends were not taken into account in this analysis, it is useful to keep this factor in mind in interpretingthe results.

8From a methodological point of view, the calibra-tion of the Energy 2020 model to Canada’sEmissions Outlook: An Update (CEOU)2 introducesan inherent level of uncertainty into the modellingresults. We already know that the fuel prices con-tained in the CEOU are incorrect. The effect ofthis error on the model results is uncertain.

9There are gaps in data when it comes to the technology parameters and predictions of marketavailability for hydrogen technologies. For anytechnologies that are not yet commercially avail-able or even in real-world operation, assumptionsmade regarding both costs and performance areoften based on best predictions by technologyresearchers and developers. Thus there is highuncertainty with these parameters. The modellingresults are also highly dependent on assumptionsabout when particular technologies will be avail-able in the marketplace and access to supportingservices such as refuelling infrastructure. There is a wide range of predictions and speculation on when these new technologies will becomeavailable.

113Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

2 Analysis and Modelling Group, Canada’s Emissions Outlook: An Update (Ottawa: National Climate Change Process, December 1999).

Page 128: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions
Page 129: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

D. SELECTED READINGBattelle Memorial Institute, Global Energy Technology

Strategy: Addressing Climate Change. InitialFindings from an International Public–PrivateCollaboration. (Washington, D.C.: Battelle,n.d.).

Berry, Trent, “Macroeconomic Impacts of FiscalPolicy Promoting Long-term Decarbonization in Canada,” Working paper prepared for theNational Round Table on the Environment andthe Economy, August 2004.

Canadian Energy Research Institute, “ContinentalEnergy Sector Issues,” Working paper preparedfor the National Round Table on theEnvironment and the Economy, March 2004.

Distributed Generation Industry Task Force SteeringCommittee, Decentralizing Energy Security inOntario: Task Force Report on DistributedGeneration (August 26, 2003).

Energy Information Administration, U.S.Department of Energy, International EnergyOutlook 2003 (Washington, D.C.: DOE, 2003).

Environment Industry Innovation Committee, TheEnvironment Industry and Innovation: A Responseto Canada’s Innovation Strategy (July 2002).

Estill, Glen, and Doug Duimering, ManufacturingCommercial Scale Wind Turbines in Canada(Ottawa: Canadian Wind Energy Association,April 2003).

Fuel Cells Canada, The Canadian Fuel Cell Industry;World Leading Innovation Today and Tomorrow,Submission to Canada’s Innovation Strategy(2003) [on-line]. Available at: <www.innovation.gc.ca/gol/innovation/site.nsf/en/in02319.html>.

Global Change Strategies International, “Energy andClimate Change—Review and Assessment ofNational Plan,” Working paper prepared for the National Round Table on the Environmentand the Economy, March 31, 2004.

Government of Canada, Address by the PrimeMinister in Response to the Speech from the Throne, February 3, 2004.

———, Speech from the Throne 2004, February 2, 2004.

Harrington, Winston, and Richard D. Morgenstern,“Economic Incentives versus Command andControl: What’s the Best Approach for SolvingEnvironmental Problems?” Resources for theFuture (Fall/Winter 2004).

Her Majesty’s Customs and Excise (U.K.), A generalguide to climate change levy (March 2002) [on-line]. Available at: <www.hmce.gov.uk>; and Climate Change Agreements [on-line].Available at: <www.defra.gov.uk/environment/ccl/intro.htm>. Both accessed October 30, 2004.

Horne, Matt, “Canadian Renewable ElectricityDevelopment: Employment Impacts,” Preparedfor the Pembina Institute for AppropriateDevelopment, 2004.

Industry Canada, Environmental Affairs Branch,Sustainable Development Strategy 2003–2006(Ottawa: Industry Canada, 2003).

———, The Kyoto Protocol and Industry GrowthOpportunities: Input to the AMG Working Group(Ottawa: Industry Canada, April 25, 2002).

———, Canada’s Environment Industry: An Overview(Ottawa: Industry Canada, January 2002).

International Energy Agency, World EnergyInvestment Outlook 2003 (Paris: IEA, 2003).

———, World Energy Outlook 2002 (Paris: IEA, 2002).

Jaccard, Mark, Nik Rivers and Matt Horne, TheMorning After: Optimal Greenhouse Gas Policiesfor Canada’s Kyoto Obligations and Beyond, C.D. Howe Institute Commentary, No. 197(March 2004).

Jochem, E., and R. Madlener, The Forgotten Benefitsof Climate Change Mitigation: Innovation,Technological Leapfrogging, Employment, andSustainable Development (Paris: OECD, 2003).

Marbek Resource Consultants and Resources for theFuture, Case Study on Renewable Grid-PowerElectricity (Ottawa: NRTEE, 2004).

M.K. Jaccard & Associates, Case Study on Energy Efficiency (Ottawa: NRTEE, 2004).

National Energy Board, Canada’s Energy Future:Scenarios for Supply and Demand to 2025(Ottawa: National Energy Board, 2003).

115Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

Page 130: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

116 National Round Table on the Environment and the Economy

National Round Table on the Environment and theEconomy, Reducing Sulphur Emissions from HeavyFuel Oil Use—A Quantitative Assessment ofEconomic Instruments, Working paper (Ottawa:NRTEE, 2003).

———, Toward a Canadian Agenda for EcologicalFiscal Reform: First Steps (Ottawa: NRTEE,2002).

New Directions Group, Criteria and Principles for theUse of Voluntary or Non-regulatory Initiatives toAchieve Environmental Policy Objectives(November 4, 1997).

NRCan Advisory Board on Energy Science andTechnology, Innovation in Canada: Submission[on-line]. Accessed March 16, 2005, at:<http://innovation.gc.ca/>.

Organisation for Economic Co-operation andDevelopment, Environmental Performance Reviewof Canada, 2004 (Paris: OECD, 2004).

———, Environmental Taxes and Competitiveness: AnOverview of Issues, Policy Options, and ResearchNeeds (Paris: OECD, 2003).

———, Voluntary Approaches for EnvironmentalPolicy: Effectiveness, Efficiency, and Usage in thePolicy Mixes (Paris: OECD, 2003).

———, Environmentally Related Taxes: Issues andStrategies (Paris: OECD, 2001).

Ontario Medical Association, The Illness Costs of AirPollution in Ontario: A Summary of Findings(June 2000) [on-line]. Accessed October 27,2004 at: <www.oma.org/phealth/icap.htm>.

Pembina Institute for Appropriate Development andthe Canadian Energy Research Institute, CaseStudy on the Role of Ecological Fiscal Reform inHydrogen Development (Ottawa: NRTEE, 2004).

(S&T)2 Consultants Inc., “Hydrogen Pathways,Greenhouse Gas Emissions and Energy Use,”Prepared for Fuel Cells Canada, December 2003.

Smith, Stephen, Environmental Taxes andCompetitiveness: An Overview of Issues, PolicyOptions, and Research Needs (Paris: OECD, 2003).

Tampier, Martin, “Background Document for theGreen Power Workshop Series, Workshop 5,”Prepared for Pollution Probe and the SummerhillGroup, April 2004.

———, “Background Document for the GreenPower Workshop Series, Workshop 4,” Preparedfor Pollution Probe and the Summerhill Group,February 2004, p. 15.

Page 131: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

E. PROGRAM PARTICIPANTSNote: This program was carried out over a number ofyears, and some participants’ titles/organizations mayhave changed during that time.

Hydrogen Scoping Group Meetings – May 28, 2003, January 13, 2004, April 7, 2004

Bélanger, Jean(NRTEE Member) Chair, EFR & Energy ProgramNRTEEOttawa, ON

Belletrutti, JackVice-PresidentCanadian Petroleum Products InstituteOttawa, ON

Bhargava, AhbaSenior Director, Energy-Environment ModellingCanadian Energy Research InstituteCalgary, AB

Bose, Tapan K.PresidentCanadian Hydrogen AssociationToronto, ON

Bowie, BruceDirector General, Energy & Marine BranchIndustry CanadaOttawa, ON

Cairns, StephanieConsultant/WriterWrangellia ConsultingVictoria, BC

Campbell, LizaSustainable Management ConsultantOttawa, ON

Curran, KimMarket Manager, Chemicals & Refining – Process IndustriesAir Liquide Canada Inc.Ottawa, ON

Desgagné, AnnieSenior Commerce Officer, Energy DirectorateIndustry CanadaOttawa, ON

Fairlie, Matthew J.PrincipalFairfield Group – Fairfield FarmShelburne, ON

Kauling, DickEngineering Group Manager, Alternative Fuels IntegrationGeneral Motors of Canada Ltd.Oshawa, ON

Kosteltz, AnthonyHead, Climate Change Initiatives, Technology & Industry, ETAEnvironment CanadaOttawa, ON

Long, AlexResearch Associate, EFR & Energy ProgramNRTEEOttawa, ON

MacDonell, GlennDirector, Energy, Energy DirectorateIndustry CanadaOttawa, ON

McGuinty, David J.President and CEONRTEEOttawa, ON

McMillan, Roderick S.Principal Research Officer Electrochemical TechnologyInstitute for Chemical Process and Environmental TechnologyNational Research Council Ottawa, ON

Minns, David E.Special Advisor, Sustainable Development TechnologyNational Research CouncilOttawa, ON

Nyberg, EugeneCorporate Secretary and Director of OperationsNRTEEOttawa, ON

117Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

Page 132: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

118 National Round Table on the Environment and the Economy

Patenaude, LynneSenior Program Engineer, Oil, Gas and EnergyEnvironment CanadaOttawa, ON

Robles, LindsayEconomist, Resources, Energy and Environment –Economic Development and Corporate FinanceFinance CanadaOttawa, ON

Row, JesseEco-efficiency Technology Analyst, Corporate Eco-Solutions ServicePembina Institute for Appropriate DevelopmentCalgary, AB

Samak, Qussai(NRTEE Member) Conseiller syndicalConfédération des syndicats nationauxMontréal, QC

Scepanovic, VesnaA/Program Manager – Fuel Cells and HydrogenCANMET Energy Technology Centre – OttawaNatural Resources CanadaOttawa, ON

Schingh, MarieA/Manager, Environmental Measures, Oil, Gas and EnergyEnvironment CanadaOttawa, ON

Taylor, AmyDirector, Ecological Fiscal ReformPembina Institute for Appropriate DevelopmentCanmore, AB

Watters, David B.ConsultantGlobal Advantage ConsultingOttawa, ON

Wood, AlexanderPolicy Advisor, EFR & Energy ProgramNRTEEOttawa, ON

Renewable Power Scoping Group Meetings –June 3, 2003, January 14, 2004, April 6, 2004

Andres, Philipp Senior Vice-President & General ManagerVestas Canadian Wind Technology Inc.Kincardine, ON

Bailey, MargaretSenior Advisor, Renewables & Sustainable DevelopmentIndustry CanadaOttawa, ON

Bélanger, Jean(NRTEE Member) Chair, EFR & Energy ProgramNRTEEOttawa, ON

Cairns, StephanieConsultant/WriterWrangellia ConsultingVictoria, BC

Campbell, LizaSustainable Management ConsultantOttawa, ON

DiQuinzio, DanielTax ExpertHydro-QuébecQuébec, QC

Eggertson, BillExecutive DirectorEarth Energy Society of CanadaOttawa, ON

Favreau, GillesChargé d’équipe enjeux réglementaireHydro-QuébecQuébec, QC

Gagné, ÉricFA Support Officer – Sustainable DevelopmentEnergy and Marine BranchIndustry CanadaOttawa, ON

Page 133: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

Goldberger, Dan J.PresidentNew Paradigm Capital Corp.Toronto, ON

Goodlet, WarrenEconomist, Resources, Energy & EnvironmentFinance CanadaOttawa, ON

Hetherington, DeirdreAnalyst, Renewable Energy Policy, Renewable andElectrical Energy DivisionNatural Resources CanadaOttawa, ON

Hornung, RobertExecutive DirectorCanadian Wind Energy AssociationOttawa, ON

Long, AlexResearch Associate, EFR & Energy ProgramNRTEEOttawa, ON

Lagos, JulioAdvisor, Environmental IssuesCanadian Electrical AssociationToronto, ON

McCauley, SteveDirector, Oil, Gas and Energy BranchEnvironment CanadaOttawa, ON

McGarrigle, PaulaManager, RenewablesShell Canada LimitedCalgary, AB

McMonagle, RobExecutive DirectorCanadian Solar Industries AssociationOttawa, ON

Ogilvie, Kenneth B.(NRTEE Member) Executive DirectorPollution ProbeToronto, ON

Olewiler, NancyProfessor, Department of Economics – Public Policy ProgramSimon Fraser UniversityBurnaby, BC

Painchaud, GuyPrésident sortant et directeurAssociation canadienne d’énergie éolienne (ACEE)Québec, QC

Patenaude, LynneSenior Program Engineer, Oil, Gas and EnergyEnvironment CanadaOttawa, ON

Paterson, MurrayManager, Business Development, Evergreen EnergyOntario Power GenerationToronto, ON

Robillard, PaulPrincipalMarbek Resource ConsultantsOttawa, ON

Samak, Qussai(NRTEE Member) Conseiller syndicalConfédération des syndicats nationauxMontréal, QC

Sawyer, DavidConsulting EconomistMarbek Resource ConsultantsOttawa, ON

Watters, David B.ConsultantGlobal Advantage ConsultingOttawa, ON

Whittaker, SeanConsultantMarbek Resource ConsultantsOttawa, ON

Wood, AlexanderPolicy Advisor, EFR & Energy ProgramNRTEEOttawa, ON

119Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

Page 134: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

120 National Round Table on the Environment and the Economy

Energy Efficiency Scoping Group Meetings –June 18, 2003, January 15, 2004, April 5, 2004

Bélanger, Jean(NRTEE Member) Chair, EFR & Energy ProgramNRTEEOttawa, ON

Cairns, StephanieConsultant/WriterWrangellia ConsultingVictoria, BC

Campbell, LizaSustainable Management ConsultantOttawa, ON

Chantraine, PeterManager, Power, Energy Conservation, Recycling & Environment AffairsDuPont Canada Inc.Kingston, ON

Dunsky, Philippe U.Executive Director and Senior ResearcherHelios CentreMontréal, QC

Goodlet, WarrenEconomist, Resources, Energy & EnvironmentFinance CanadaOttawa, ON

Hornung, RobertExecutive DirectorCanadian Wind Energy AssociationOttawa, ON

Hughes, Stephen M.Energy ConservationDuPont Canada Inc.Mississauga, ON

Jago, Philip B.Senior Chief, Industrial Energy Efficiency ProgramOffice of Energy EfficiencyNatural Resources CanadaOttawa, ON

Lansbergen, PaulDirector, Taxation and Business IssuesForest Products Association of CanadaOttawa, ON

Lemay, AndyEnergy AnalystInco Ltd.Copper Cliff, ON

Long, AlexResearch Associate, EFR & Energy ProgramNRTEEOttawa, ON

Macaluso, NickSenior Policy Advisor, Climate Change Economics BranchEnvironment CanadaOttawa, ON

Martel, DenisAnalyst, Economic & Regional Development PolicyPrivy Council OfficeOttawa, ON

Norris, TimDirector, Industrial Program DivisionNatural Resources CanadaOttawa, ON

Nyboer, JohnResearch AssociateM.K. Jaccard and AssociatesNew Westminster, BC

Oliver, FionaProgram ManagerCanadian Energy Efficiency AllianceToronto, ON

Podruzny, Dave F.Senior Manager, Business and EconomicsCanadian Chemical Producers AssociationOttawa, ON

Rahbar, ShahrzadVice President, Strategy and OperationsCanadian Gas AssociationOttawa, ON

Raphals, PhilDirectorHelios CentreMontréal, QC

Page 135: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

Rouse, ScottManaging PartnerEnergy @ WorkToronto, ON

Sadownik, BrynResearch AssociateM.K. Jaccard and AssociatesNew Westminster, BC

Samak, Qussai(NRTEE Member) Conseiller syndicalConfédération des syndicats nationauxMontréal, QC

Versfeld, KeesEnergy Management LeaderSyncrude Canada Ltd.Fort McMurray, AB

Watters, David B.ConsultantGlobal Advantage ConsultingOttawa, ON

Wood, AlexanderPolicy Advisor, EFR & Energy ProgramNRTEEOttawa, ON

Meeting on Research and Methodology – January 14, 2004

Bélanger, Jean(NRTEE Member) Chair, EFR & Energy ProgramNRTEEOttawa, ON

Bhargava, AhbaSenior Director, Energy-Environment ModellingCanadian Energy Research InstituteCalgary, AB

Cairns, StephanieConsultant/WriterWrangellia ConsultingVictoria, BC

Campbell, LizaSustainable Management ConsultantOttawa, ON

Hayhow, IanChief, Supply Analysis and Modelling TeamAnalysis and Modelling DivisionNatural Resources CanadaOttawa, ON

Long, AlexResearch Associate, EFR & Energy ProgramNRTEEOttawa, ON

Macaluso, NickSenior Policy Advisor, Climate Change Economics BranchEnvironment CanadaOttawa, ON

Olewiler, NancyProfessor of Economics, Public Policy ProgramSimon Fraser UniversityBurnaby, BC

Robillard, PaulPrincipalMarbek Resource ConsultantsOttawa, ON

Row, JesseEco-efficiency Technology Analyst, Corporate Eco-Solutions ServicePembina Institute for Appropriate DevelopmentCalgary, AB

Sadownik, BrynResearch AssociateM.K. Jaccard and AssociatesNew Westminster, BC

Samak, Qussai(NRTEE Member) Conseiller syndicalConfédération des syndicats nationauxMontréal, QC

Sawyer, DavidConsulting EconomistMarbek Resource ConsultantsOttawa, ON

Taylor, AmyDirector, Ecological Fiscal ReformPembina Institute for Appropriate DevelopmentCanmore, AB

Watters, David B.ConsultantGlobal Advantage ConsultingOttawa, ON

121Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

Page 136: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

122 National Round Table on the Environment and the Economy

Wood, AlexanderPolicy Advisor, EFR & Energy ProgramNRTEEOttawa, ON

Workshop Participants – October 12–13, 2004

Bailey, MargaretSenior Advisor, Renewables & Sustainable DevelopmentIndustry CanadaOttawa, ON

Bélanger, Jean(NRTEE Member) Chair, EFR & Energy ProgramNRTEEOttawa, ON

Belletrutti, JackVice-PresidentCanadian Petroleum Products InstituteOttawa, ON

Bennett, DavidNational DirectorHealth, Safety & EnvironmentCanadian Labour CongressOttawa, ON

Bennett, JohnSenior Policy Advisor, Energy & Atmosphere CampaignSierra Club of CanadaOttawa, ON

Boston, AlexSenior Climate Change SpecialistDavid Suzuki FoundationVancouver, BC

Brown, James D.Senior Advisor, Climate ChangeShell Canada LimitedCalgary, AB

Bruchet, DouglasSenior Vice PresidentEnvironment–Energy ResearchCanadian Energy Research InstituteCalgary, AB

Cairns, StephanieConsultant/WriterWrangellia ConsultingVictoria, BC

Carpentier, Chantal LineHead, Environment, Economy and TradeCommission for Environmental CooperationMontréal, QC

Cloghesy, MichaelPresidentCentre patronal de l’environnement du QuébecMontréal, QC

Comeau, LouisePresident and CEOFuels Cells CanadaOttawa, ON

Crandlemire, AllanManager, Energy Transportation & UtilizationNova Scotia Department of EnergyHalifax, NS

Dixon, RichardSenior Advisor, Strategic IntelligenceAlberta Department of EnvironmentEdmonton, AB

Down, ErinConsultantStratos Inc.Ottawa, ON

Fink, SylvestrePolicy Analyst, EnvironmentFederation of Canadian MunicipalitiesOttawa, ON

Gagnon, LucSenior Advisor, Climate ChangeHydro-QuébecQuébec, QC

Goodlet, WarrenEconomist, Resources, Energy & EnvironmentFinance CanadaOttawa, ON

Green, ChristopherProfessor of EconomicsMcGill UniversityMontréal, QC

Greene, GeorgePresidentStratos Inc.Ottawa, ON

Page 137: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

Guimond, Pierre A.DirectorFederal Government LiaisonOntario Power Generation Inc.Ottawa, ON

Higgins, StevePolicy AdvisorCanadian Solar Industries AssociationOttawa, ON

Hnatyshyn, John G.Deputy DirectorFramework Policies TeamIndustry CanadaOttawa, ON

Hornung, RobertExecutive DirectorCanadian Wind Energy AssociationOttawa, ON

Hyndman, RickSenior Policy Advisor, Climate ChangeCanadian Association of Petroleum ProductsCalgary, AB

Isaacs, EddyManaging DirectorAlberta Energy Research InstituteEdmonton, AB

Lemay, AndyEnergy AnalystInco Ltd.Copper Cliff, ON

Lewkowitz, Michael A.B.Venture PartnerQuantum Leap Company LimitedToronto, ON

Long, AlexResearch Associate, EFR & Energy ProgramNRTEEOttawa, ON

MacDonald, DanielTax Policy Officer, Tax Policy BranchFinance CanadaOttawa, ON

Martin, AliceSocio-economic Director – APCAAthabasca Tribal CouncilFort McMurray, AB

McCuaig-Johnston, MargaretAssistant Deputy MinisterEnergy Technology & Program SectorNatural Resources CanadaOttawa, ON

McKeever, GarryCoordinator, Energy EconomicsOntario Ministry of EnergyToronto, ON

Mead, Harvey L.(NRTEE Member) Chair, NRTEEQuébec, QC

Meadowcroft, JamesProfessor, Public Policy & AdministrationCarleton UniversityOttawa, ON

Minns, David E.Special Advisor, Sustainable Development TechnologyNational Research CouncilOttawa, ON

Murphy, MichaelSenior Vice-President – PolicyCanadian Chamber of CommerceOttawa, ON

Nantais, Mark A.PresidentCanadian Vehicle Manufacturers’ AssociationToronto, ON

Napier, LorneProgram Coordinator, Lands and EnvironmentDenedeh National OfficeYellowknife, NWT

Nyberg, EugeneA/Executive Director and CEONRTEEOttawa, ON

123Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

Page 138: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

124 National Round Table on the Environment and the Economy

Padfield, ChristopherAnalyst, Economic & Regional Development PolicyPrivy Council OfficeOttawa, ON

Podruzny, Dave F.Senior Manager, Business and EconomicsCanadian Chemical Producers AssociationOttawa, ON

Pollock, DavidExecutive DirectorBIOCAP Canada FoundationKingston, ON

Porteous, HughDirector, Research & Corporate RelationsAlcan Inc.Ottawa, ON

Potter, MarkSenior Chief, Economic Development PolicyFinance CanadaOttawa, ON

Rahbar, ShahrzadVice-President, Strategy and OperationsCanadian Gas AssociationOttawa, ON

Raphals, PhilDirectorHelios CentreMontréal, QC

Rivers, NicResearch Associate, Energy & Materials Research GroupSimon Fraser UniversityBurnaby, BC

Runnalls, DavidPresident and CEOInternational Institute for Sustainable DevelopmentWinnipeg, MB

Russell, DouglasManaging DirectorGlobal Change Strategies International Inc.Ottawa, ON

Sadik, PierreManagerGreen Budget CoalitionOttawa, ON

Sawyer, DavidConsulting EconomistMarbek Resource ConsultantsOttawa, ON

Schwartz, SandraPolicy Advisor, Office of the MinisterEnvironment CanadaOttawa, ON

Scott, AllisonDeputy MinisterNova Scotia Department of EnergyHalifax, NS

Sharpe, Victoria J.President and CEOSustainable Development Technology CanadaOttawa, ON

Taylor, AmyDirector, Ecological Fiscal ReformPembina Institute for Appropriate DevelopmentCanmore, AB

Toner, GlenProfessor, Public AdministrationCarleton UniversityOttawa, ON

Torrie, RalphPrincipalTorrie Smith Associates Inc.Ottawa, ON

Watters, David B.ConsultantGlobal Advantage ConsultingOttawa, ON

Wood, AlexanderPolicy Advisor, EFR & Energy ProgramNRTEEOttawa, ON

Page 139: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

F. ENDNOTES1 This deficiency has been noted most recently in the OECD’s

Environmental Performance Review of Canada, 2004(Paris: OECD, 2004).

2 Battelle Memorial Institute, Global Energy TechnologyStrategy: Addressing Climate Change. Initial Findings froman International Public–Private Collaboration(Washington, D.C.: Battelle, n.d.), p. 27.

3 A. Jaffe, R. Newell and R. Stavins, “Environmental policy and technological change,” Environmental and ResourceEconomics 22 (1-2) (2002), pp. 41–69.

4 NRCan Advisory Board on Energy Science and Technology,Innovation in Canada: Submission [on-line]. Accessed March 16, 2005, at: <http://innovation.gc.ca/>.

5 The National Energy Board’s “Techno-Vert” environmentand technology innovation scenario predicts the supplyshare of primary fuels in 2025 as follows: fossil fuels 69%(natural gas 31%, oil 27%, coal 8%, liquefied petroleumgas 2%, ethane 1%) nuclear 11%, hydro 10%, hog fueland pulping liquor 6%, wood 1%, other 1%. NationalEnergy Board, Canada’s Energy Future: Scenarios for Supply and Demand to 2025 (Ottawa: National EnergyBoard, 2003), p. 18.

6 The “gap” is the difference between what Canada has committed to under Kyoto and what it is producing now.

7 National Round Table on the Environment and theEconomy, Toward a Canadian Agenda for Ecological Fiscal Reform: First Steps (Ottawa: NRTEE, 2002).

8 These case studies were on cleaner transportation, agricultural landscapes and heavy fuel oil.

9 A listing of some EFR measures currently in place inCanada can be found at: <www.fiscallygreen.ca/experience.html>.

10 Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development,Environmentally Related Taxes: Issues and Strategies(Paris: OECD, 2001).

11 Government of Canada, Climate Change Plan for Canada(November 21, 2002) [on-line]. Available at: <www.climatechange.gc.ca/english/canada/goc_historical.asp>.

12 Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development,Environmental Performance Review of Canada, 2004(Paris: OECD, 2004).

13 Department of Finance, The Budget Plan 2005 (Ottawa:Department of Finance, 2005) [on-line]. Available at:<www.fin.gc.ca>, p. 184.

14 W. Harrington and R.D. Morgenstern, “Economic Incentivesversus Command and Control: What’s the Best Approach forSolving Environmental Problems?” Resources for the Future(Fall/Winter 2004).

15 Martin Tampier, “Background Document for the GreenPower Workshop Series, Workshop 4,” Prepared forPollution Probe and the Summerhill Group, February 2004,p. 15.

16 For a description of sources and assumptions behind these figures, consult Marbek Resource Consultants and Resourcesfor the Future, Case Study on Renewable Grid-PowerElectricity (Ottawa: NRTEE, 2004).

17 International Energy Agency, World Energy Outlook 2002(Paris: IEA, 2002), p. 25.

18 International Energy Agency, World Energy InvestmentOutlook 2003 (Paris: IEA, 2003), Chapter 2.

19 International Energy Agency, World Energy Outlook 2002(Paris: IEA, 2002), p. 28.

20 International Energy Agency, Renewables Information(Paris: IEA, 2003).

21 U.S. Department of Energy, Protecting National, Energy,and Economic Security with Advanced Science andTechnology and Ensuring Environmental Cleanup,Department of Energy Strategic Plan (Washington, D.C.: DOE, August 6, 2003).

22 International Energy Agency, World Energy InvestmentOutlook 2003 (Paris: IEA, 2003), p. 406.

23 Ibid., p. 435.

24 Ibid., p. 428.

25 PricewaterhouseCoopers, Fuel Cells: The Opportunity for Canada (June 2002) [on-line]. Available at:<www.pwc.com/extweb/ncsurvres.nsf/DocID/F7279B67D838C55685256BD1004B652B>.

26 Quoted in Battelle Memorial Institute, Global EnergyTechnology Strategy: Addressing Climate Change. Initial Findings from an International Public–PrivateCollaboration (Washington, D.C.: Battelle, n.d.). p. 30.

27 Global Change Strategies International, “Energy andClimate Change—Review and Assessment of NationalPlan,” Prepared for the National Round Table on theEnvironment and the Economy, March 31, 2004, p. 24.

28 Electricity Conservation and Supply Task Force, ToughChoices: Addressing Ontario’s Power Needs, Final Report(Toronto: Ontario Ministry of Energy, January 2004).

29 Manitoba Energy, Science and Technology, “EnergyDevelopment Initiative” [on-line]. Accessed May 26, 2004,at: <www.gov.mb.ca/est/energy/index.html>.

125Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

Page 140: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

126 National Round Table on the Environment and the Economy

30 New Brunswick Department of Energy, New BrunswickEnergy Policy, 2001, White Paper; Remarks for MinisterBruce Fitch at the Green Power in Canada Workshop Series, October 1, 2003; Communications New Brunswick,“Nuclear Expert Will Examine Lepreau,” Press release,January 30, 2004.

31 Martin Tampier, “Background Document for the GreenPower Workshop Series, Workshop 5,” Prepared forPollution Probe and the Summerhill Group, April 2004.

32 Martin Tampier, “Background Document for the GreenPower Workshop Series, Workshop 4,” Prepared forPollution Probe and the Summerhill Group, February 2004,p. 27.

33 Canadian Energy Research Institute, “Continental EnergySector Issues,” Prepared for the National Round Table on the Environment and the Economy, March 2004, p. 10.

34 Ontario Medical Association, The Illness Costs of Air Pollution in Ontario: A Summary of Findings (June 2000)[on-line]. Accessed October 27, 2004, at:<www.oma.org/phealth/icap.htm>.

35 Industry Canada, Environmental Affairs Branch, The Kyoto Protocol and Industry Growth Opportunities: Input to the AMG Working Group (Ottawa: IndustryCanada, April 25, 2002).

36 Ibid. Note that this study used a marginal cost for carbondioxide emissions of $56 to $120/tonne, whereas therange used in the eventual 2002 Climate Change Plan for Canada was $10 to $50/tonne. Using the $56 to$120/tonne range, the Industry Canada study found thattotal investment to meet the Kyoto targets would likely bein the $100 to $400 billion range. The impact of a mar-ginal cost of $25/tonne of carbon dioxide on investmentand energy production was also analyzed; this led to a 40 percent drop in the value of the opportunities, with significant reductions in the amount of energy productionfrom renewable energy sources. It is assumed, however,that this would not affect the key finding that Canadawould have to import much of the machinery and equip-ment required to satisfy potentially tougher post-Kyotocommitments.

37 G. Estill and D. Duimering, Manufacturing CommercialScale Wind Turbines in Canada (Ottawa: Canadian WindEnergy Association, April 2003).

38 International Energy Agency, World Energy InvestmentOutlook 2003 (Paris: IEA, 2003), p. 47.

39 Government of Canada, Speech from the Throne, February 2004.

40 Richard Adamson, Senior Vice-President, Mariah EnergyCorporation, Victoria Sharpe, President and CEO,Sustainable Development Technology Canada, and audiencecomments at the Breakout Session on Environment andClean Energy, National Summit on Innovation andLearning, Toronto, November 18 and 19, 2002.

41 Martin Tampier, “Background Document for the GreenPower Workshop Series, Workshop 4,” Prepared forPollution Probe and the Summerhill Group, February 2004,p. 24.

42 Matt Horne, “Canadian Renewable Electricity Development:Employment Impacts,” Prepared for the Pembina Institutefor Appropriate Development, 2004.

43 Ibid.

44 E. Jochem and R. Madlener, The Forgotten Benefits ofClimate Change Mitigation: Innovation, TechnologicalLeapfrogging, Employment, and Sustainable Development(Paris: OECD, 2003), p. 19.

45 Comments at the Breakout Session on Environment andClean Energy, National Summit on Innovation andLearning, Toronto, November 18 and 19, 2002.

46 Global Change Strategies International, “Energy andClimate Change—Review and Assessment of NationalPlan,” Prepared for the National Round Table on theEnvironment and the Economy, March 2004, p. 27.

47 For a fuller analysis of this, see ibid.

48 Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development,Voluntary Approaches for Environmental Policy:Effectiveness, Efficiency, and Usage in the Policy Mixes (Paris: OECD, 2003), p. 14.

49 For example, those laid out by the New Directions Group in “Criteria and Principles for the Use of Voluntary or Non-regulatory Initiatives to Achieve Environmental Policy Objectives” (November 4, 1997).

50 For further discussion, see Trent Berry, “MacroeconomicImpacts of Fiscal Policy Promoting Long-term CarbonEmissions Reduction in Canada,” Working paper preparedfor the National Round Table on the Environment and theEconomy, August 2004.

51 Information from the NCCP website at:<www.nccp.ca/NCCP/index_e.html>.

52 Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development,Environmentally Related Taxes: Issues and Strategies(Paris: OECD, 2001).

53 Her Majesty’s Customs and Excise (U.K.), A general guide to climate change levy (March 2002) [on-line].Available at: <www.hmce.gov.uk>; and Climate Change Agreements [on-line]. Available at:<www.defra.gov.uk/environment/ccl/intro.htm>. Both accessed October 30, 2004.

54 Ibid.

Page 141: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

55 J. Farla and K. Blok, “Energy Conservation Investments ofFirms,” Industrial Energy Efficiency Policies: UnderstandingSuccess and Failure, Proceedings of a workshop organizedby the International Network for Energy Demand Analysisin the Industrial Sector, Utrecht University, Netherlands,November 1998. The energy bonus evaluated was a large-scale tax credit subsidy scheme in the Netherlands thatexisted between 1980 and 1988 to stimulate energy effi-ciency improvement and renewable energy. See also D.Loughran and J. Kulich, “Demand-side Management andEnergy Efficiency in the United States,” The Energy Journal25, 1 (2004), pp. 19–40. This DSM study examined datafrom 324 utilities spanning 11 years; it found that DSMexpenditures do poorly at targeting consumers on the mar-gin of making energy efficiency investments, and for thisreason most utilities overstated the effectiveness andunderstated the costs of these programs. See also M.K.Jaccard & Associates Inc, Comparison of How Absolute vs.Intensity-based GHG Emissions Reductions StrategiesMight Affect Energy Efficiency Actions and Programs,Prepared for Natural Resources Canada, 2004. This studyexamined the free-rider share in subsidy programs forindustrial auxiliary technologies, residential equipmentsuch as refrigerators and clothes washers, and commercialsector equipment such as lighting and cooling technolo-gies; the study found that the free-rider share ranged from40 to 82 percent of subsidy recipients and depended onthe end use and the magnitude of the subsidy—the proportion of free riders declined at higher subsidies.

56 Inland Revenue (U.K.), 100 Per Cent First-Year Allowancesfor Cars with Low Carbon Dioxide Emissions and NaturalGas and Hydrogen Refuelling Equipment [on-line].Available at: <www.inlandrevenue.gov.uk/capital_allowances/cars.htm>.

57 This latter factor would in turn be affected by emergingnon-energy technologies such as carbon sequestration.

58 This contrasts with efforts in the United States to compilea highly detailed wind atlas to assist in siting wind farms.See: <http://rredc.nrel.gov/wind/pubs/atlas>.

59 Analysis and Modelling Group, Canada’s Emissions Outlook:An Update (Ottawa: National Climate Change Process,December 1999).

60 Government of Canada, Government of Canada Action Plan2000 on Climate Change (October 6, 2000) [on-line].Available at: <www.climatechange.gc.ca/english/canada/goc_historical.asp>.

61 Office of Technology Assessment, U.S. Congress, IndustrialEnergy Efficiency (Washington, D.C.: U.S. GovernmentPrinting Office, 1993).

62 R. Pindyck, “Irreversibility, Uncertainty and Investment,”Journal of Economic Literature 29, 3 (1991), pp. 1110–1152.

63 A. Jaffe and R. Stavins, “The Energy-Efficiency Gap: What Does It Mean?” Energy Policy 22, 10 (1994), pp. 804–810.

64 Natural Resources Canada, About Hydroelectric Energy[on-line]. Available at: <www.canren.gc.ca/tech_appl/index.asp?CaID=4&PgID=26>.

65 There have been some important updates to these assump-tions since 2000. Prices for most energy commodities havebeen higher than assumed in Canada’s Emissions Outlook,An Update, produced for the National Climate ChangeProcess. In addition, estimates of BAU emissions in 2010have increased from 770 Mt to 809 Mt due to higher eco-nomic growth from 1997 to 2000 than originally projected,substantially more oil sands development, higher naturalgas production, and changes in the electricity generationmix. In addition, the price of natural gas used in the 2000study is now outdated. Modelling results from the casestudies are very sensitive to the price of natural gas.

66 Chemical products, coal mining, industrial minerals, ironand steel, mining, natural gas extraction, other manufac-turing, petroleum crude extraction, petroleum refining,pulp and paper, smelting and refining.

67 Alberta, British Columbia, Nova Scotia, Ontario and Quebec.

68 E. Jochem and R. Madlener, The Forgotten Benefits ofClimate Change Mitigation: Innovation, TechnologicalLeapfrogging, Employment, and Sustainable Development(Paris: OECD, 2003).

69 Summarized from Table S-1 in: Environment Canada,Canada’s Greenhouse Gas Inventory: 1990–2000 (Ottawa:Environment Canada, 2002). Includes combustion, fugitiveand process emissions in the following categories: fossilfuel industries, mining, manufacturing, fugitive total andindustrial processes total.

70 Natural Resources Canada, End-Use Energy Data Handbook1990 to 2001 (Ottawa: NRCan, 2003), p. 12.

71 Ibid., p. 11.

72 Canadian Industrial Energy End-Use Data and AnalysisCentre, Development of Greenhouse Gas IntensityIndicators for Canadian Industry 1990 to 2002(Burnaby, B.C.: CIEEDAC, 2004).

73 M. Nanduri, J. Nyboer and M. Jaccard, “AggregatingPhysical Intensity Indicators: Results of Applying theComposite Indicator Approach to the Canadian IndustrialSector,” Energy Policy 30 (2002), pp. 151–137.

74 The conservation potential estimates are for phase II com-pared with the “natural run.” The technical potentials foreach sector were as follows: pulp and paper, 25%; petro-leum refining, 7%; mining, 3%; iron and steel, 14%;chemicals, 8%; industrial minerals, 11%. M.K. Jaccard andAssociates, and Willis Energy Services Ltd., “IndustrialEnergy End-Use Analysis and Conservation Potential in Six Major Industries in Canada,” Prepared for NaturalResources Canada, 1996.

127Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

Page 142: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

128 National Round Table on the Environment and the Economy

75 Direct emissions refer to emissions from sources owned orcontrolled by the company; indirect emissions are thoseassociated with the generation of imported and/or pur-chased electricity, heat or steam.

76 Developed by the Energy and Materials Research Group atSimon Fraser University.

77 Trent Berry, “Macroeconomic Impacts of Fiscal PolicyPromoting Long-term Decarbonization in Canada,” Working paper prepared for the National Round Table on the Environment and the Economy, August 2004.

78 Discounted to 2004 dollars at a 10 percent social discount rate.

79 Interlaboratory Working Group, Scenarios for a CleanEnergy Future (Oak Ridge, Tenn.: Oak Ridge NationalLaboratory, and Berkeley, Calif.: Lawrence BerkeleyNational Laboratory, 2000), Section 5.21.

80 Industry Table, Industrial Table Overview Report(Ottawa: National Climate Change Process, 2000), p. 20.

81 Depending on the design of the fiscal instrument, energyefficiency gains may not be the mitigation option chosento respond to the policy.

82 Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development,Environmental Taxes and Competitiveness: An Overview of Issues, Policy Options, and Research Needs (Paris: OECD, 2003).

83 Martin Tampier, “Background Document for the GreenPower Workshop Series, Workshop 5,” Prepared forPollution Probe and the Summerhill Group, April 2004,Chapter 4.

84 Ibid.

85 For a description of sources and assumptions behind these figures, see Appendix B or consult Marbek ResourceConsultants and Resources for the Future, Ecological FiscalReform and Energy Case Study on Renewable Grid-PowerElectricity (Ottawa: NRTEE, 2004).

86 Including biomass but excluding trash and non-renewablewaste.

87 For example, if wind power has a “technical” potential of 100,000 MW, it means that this is the maximum totalgenerating capacity that wind turbines could supply if theywere installed in every technically feasible location acrossthe country.

88 “Practical” potential integrates considerations such as gridaccess and capacity; technological advances; financing;market demand and acceptance; and design, manufactur-ing and installation capacity. This case study also includedtechnology, site and industry supply criteria.

89 The technologies included for both technical and practicalpotentials were wind (onshore), low-impact hydro, solarphotovoltaic, landfill gas, biomass, wave, tidal and large geothermal.

90 Under a renewable credit trading system, investment willlikely be allocated to jurisdictions with a higher share of low-cost non-hydro renewable resources such as British Columbia.

91 Armington elasticities produced by Bataille are -1.3 to -1.5for mining and pulp and paper production, respectively,indicating a high responsiveness of domestic and exportdemand to price changes. However, metal smelting is muchless sensitive (-0.59). C. Bataille, “Design and applicationof a technologically explicit hybrid energy–economy modelwith macroeconomic feedbacks,” Draft doctoral disserta-tion, School of Resource and Environmental Management,Simon Fraser University, Burnaby, B.C.

92 Trent Berry, “Macroeconomic Impacts of Fiscal PolicyPromoting Long-term Decarbonization in Canada,” Workingpaper prepared for the National Round Table on theEnvironment and the Economy, August 2004.

93 Although it should be noted that the modelling metho-dology used for the renewable power case study may have been biased toward a more favourable result. Thatmethodology starts with the policy objective and thenmeasures the effectiveness of a given instrument in achieving the objective; the other two methodologies start with the instruments themselves and then evaluatewhat contribution they can make to a set of more looselydefined policy objectives.

94 For example, the cost of wind turbines is forecast to dropby 15 percent every time cumulative installed capacitydoubles, or every three years. See G. Estill and D.Duimering, Manufacturing Commercial Scale Wind Turbinesin Canada (Ottawa: Canadian Wind Energy Association,April 2003).

95 Renewable energy certificates (or “green tags”) are trad-able commodities awarded to renewable power producers, consumers or financial backers. Demand for the certifi-cates—which are meant to act as a proxy for theenvironmental attributes of the renewable power—typicallycomes from power producers, which are bound by regula-tion to deliver a certain percentage of renewable power butwhich do not have sufficient generating assets to do so.

96 The 2002 Climate Change Plan for Canada currently com-mits the government to “green power purchases for 20percent of the Government of Canada’s electricity needs.”

97 This definition purposely excludes hydrogen used in an oilrefinery to produce gasoline and other fuel products, andhydrogen used for medical or manufacturing purposes.

Page 143: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

98 Carbon dioxide equivalent (CO2e) is the universal unit ofmeasurement used to indicate the global warming poten-tial (GWP) of each of the seven greenhouse gases. It isused to evaluate the impacts of releasing (or avoiding the release of) different greenhouse gases.

99 Two levels of incentives are considered. For the remainderof this discussion, we assume the higher level of incen-tives, which reduce the costs of production and the costsof end-use technologies by 25 percent.

100 Used by the Canadian Energy Research Institute.

101 See, for example, Matthew Wald, “Questions about aHydrogen Economy,” Scientific American (May 2004).

102 Trent Berry, “Macroeconomic Impacts of Fiscal PolicyPromoting Long-term Decarbonization in Canada,” Workingpaper prepared for the National Round Table on theEnvironment and the Economy, August 2004.

103 (S&T)2 Consultants Inc., Hydrogen Pathways, GreenhouseGas Emissions and Energy Use, Prepared for Fuel CellsCanada, December 2003, p. ii.

104 Ibid., p. iv.

105 To be consistent, these would all need to be assessed on a life-cycle basis.

106 See Martin Tampier, “Background Document for the Green Power Workshop Series, Workshop 5,” Prepared forPollution Probe and the Summerhill Group, April 2004, p. 24.

107 National Petroleum Council, Balancing Natural Gas Policy: Fueling the Demands of a Growing Economy(Washington, D.C.: NPC, October 2003).

108 Canadian Energy Research Institute, “Continental EnergySector Issues,” Prepared for the National Round Table onthe Environment and the Economy, March 2004, p. 18.

109 This estimate is based on an average cost of emissionreductions of $1,400/tonne. The case study does not pro-vide an estimate of aggregate costs. Rather, it provides anestimate of “representative” costs by end use and path-way. The average cost of $1,400 is based on a qualitativereview of the range of costs presented in the analysis; butit would be much higher for certain applications ($4,450for SMR fuel cell vehicles in 2030 in Ontario) and muchlower for others ($856 for SMR buses in 2030 also inOntario).

110 The estimate of subsidies does not include administrativecosts.

129Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

Page 144: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

130 National Round Table on the Environment and the Economy

Notes:

Page 145: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

131Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

Notes:

Page 146: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

132 National Round Table on the Environment and the Economy

Notes:

Page 147: Economic Instruments for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Emissions

Canada Building,

344 Slater Street, Suite 200

Ottawa Ontario Canada

K1R 7Y3

Tel.: (613) 992-7189

Fax: (613) 992-7385

E-mail: [email protected]

Web: www.nrtee-trnee.ca

Economic Instrum

ents for Long-term Reductions in Energy-based Carbon Em

issions

Printed in Canada onrecycled paper