economic analysis of proposed forest service timber sales

95
University of Montana University of Montana ScholarWorks at University of Montana ScholarWorks at University of Montana Graduate Student Theses, Dissertations, & Professional Papers Graduate School 1983 Economic analysis of proposed Forest Service timber sales| A Economic analysis of proposed Forest Service timber sales| A case study of the Ketchikan salvage sale, Flathead National case study of the Ketchikan salvage sale, Flathead National Forest Forest Terry L. Egenhoff The University of Montana Follow this and additional works at: https://scholarworks.umt.edu/etd Let us know how access to this document benefits you. Recommended Citation Recommended Citation Egenhoff, Terry L., "Economic analysis of proposed Forest Service timber sales| A case study of the Ketchikan salvage sale, Flathead National Forest" (1983). Graduate Student Theses, Dissertations, & Professional Papers. 2134. https://scholarworks.umt.edu/etd/2134 This Professional Paper is brought to you for free and open access by the Graduate School at ScholarWorks at University of Montana. It has been accepted for inclusion in Graduate Student Theses, Dissertations, & Professional Papers by an authorized administrator of ScholarWorks at University of Montana. For more information, please contact [email protected].

Upload: others

Post on 11-Dec-2021

4 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Economic analysis of proposed Forest Service timber sales

University of Montana University of Montana

ScholarWorks at University of Montana ScholarWorks at University of Montana

Graduate Student Theses, Dissertations, & Professional Papers Graduate School

1983

Economic analysis of proposed Forest Service timber sales| A Economic analysis of proposed Forest Service timber sales| A

case study of the Ketchikan salvage sale, Flathead National case study of the Ketchikan salvage sale, Flathead National

Forest Forest

Terry L. Egenhoff The University of Montana

Follow this and additional works at: https://scholarworks.umt.edu/etd

Let us know how access to this document benefits you.

Recommended Citation Recommended Citation Egenhoff, Terry L., "Economic analysis of proposed Forest Service timber sales| A case study of the Ketchikan salvage sale, Flathead National Forest" (1983). Graduate Student Theses, Dissertations, & Professional Papers. 2134. https://scholarworks.umt.edu/etd/2134

This Professional Paper is brought to you for free and open access by the Graduate School at ScholarWorks at University of Montana. It has been accepted for inclusion in Graduate Student Theses, Dissertations, & Professional Papers by an authorized administrator of ScholarWorks at University of Montana. For more information, please contact [email protected].

Page 2: Economic analysis of proposed Forest Service timber sales

COPYRIGHT ACT OF 1976

THIS IS AN UNPUBLISHED MANUSCRIPT IN WHICH COPYRIGHT SUB­SISTS. ANY FURTHER REPRINTING OF ITS CONTENTS MUST BE APPROVED BY THE AUTHOR.

MANSFIELD LIBRARY UNIVERSITY OF MONTANA DATE : I 19 8 3

Page 3: Economic analysis of proposed Forest Service timber sales
Page 4: Economic analysis of proposed Forest Service timber sales

ECONOMIC ANALYSIS

OF PROPOSED FOREST SERVICE TIMBER SALES

A CASE STUDY OF THE KETCHIKAN SALVAGE SALE,

FLATHEAD NATIONAL FOREST

By

Terry L. Egenhoff

B.A., Eastern Oregon State College, 1978

Presented in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of

Master of Science

UNIVERSITY OF MONTANA

1983

Approved by;

Chairman, Board of Examiners

Graduate Saffob.

.5-- 3̂ Date

Page 5: Economic analysis of proposed Forest Service timber sales

UMI Number: EP34477

All rights reserved

INFORMATION TO ALL USERS The quality of this reproduction is dependent upon the quality of the copy submitted.

In the unlikely event that the author did not send a complete manuscript and there are missing pages, these will be noted. Also, if material had to be removed,

a note will indicate the deletion.

UMT Oknwtitton RMMiing

UMI EP34477

Published by ProQuest LLC (2012). Copyright in the Dissertation held by the Author.

Microform Edition © ProQuest LLC. All rights reserved. This work is protected against

unauthorized copying under Title 17, United States Code

ProQuest LLC. 789 East Eisenhower Parkway

P.O. Box 1346 Ann Arbor, Ml 48106-1346

Page 6: Economic analysis of proposed Forest Service timber sales

ii

TABLE OF CONTENTS

LIST OF TABLES iv

INTRODUCTION 1

NORTH END SALVAGE SALES AND APPEALS 6

CRITICAL HABIT AND CUMMULATIVE IMPACTS 9

MOUNTAIN PINE BEETLE AND LODGEPOLE PINE; ECOLOGY AND ECONOMICS 13

Mountain Pine Beetle Control History 13

Lodgepole Pine/Mountain Pine Beetle Ecology 14

Forest Pest Economics 18

ECONOMIC ANALYSIS 21

EAR Analysis 21

New Approach 24

Methods and Assumptions 26

Results 30

Discussion 32

CONCLUSIONS 37

APPENDIX A: STUMPAGE VALUE ESTIMATES 43

Initial Entry Stumpage Value 43

Re-entry Stumpage Values ..... 47

APPENDIX B: ROAD COST ESTIMATES 60

Initial Road construction 61

Future Road Reconstruction 65

APPENDIX C: SALE PREPARATION AND ADMINISTRATION COST ESTIMATES 68

APPENDIX D: SITE PREPARATION AND FUEL TREATMENT COST ESTIMATES 72

APPENDIX E: PLANTING, STOCKING SURVEY AND PRECOMMERCIAL THINNING COST ESTIMATES 77

Page 7: Economic analysis of proposed Forest Service timber sales

lii

APPENDIX F: PRESENT VALUE 80

REFERENCES 84

MAP pocket

Page 8: Economic analysis of proposed Forest Service timber sales

iv

LIST OF TABLES

A-1. Initial Entry Benefits 47

A-2. Scheduled Harvest Activity 50

A-3. Projected Volume Species Composition and d.b.h. for Future Harvests, by Unit 53

A-4. Future Harvest Volume by Species 55

A-5. Weighted Lumber Prices for Future Harvests 56

A-6. Derivation of Current Stumpage Value for Future Harvest 57

A-7. Projected Future Stumpage Values 59

A-8. Re-entry Benefits 59

B-1 . Initial Entry Road Costs 64

B-2. Re-entry Road Costs 66

B-3. Total Road Costs 67

C-1. Sale Preparation and Administration Cost Classes 69

C-2. Sale Preparation Costs . 70

C-3. Sale Administration Costs 71

D-1. Site Preparation and Fuel Treatment Cost Classes 74

D-2. Site Preparation and Fuel Treatment Costs 76

E-1 . Planting Costs 78

E-2. Stocking Survey Costs 79

E-3. Precommercial Thinning Costs 79

F-1 . Total Expected Costs 81

F-2. Discounted Total Costs 82

F-3. Discounted Total Benefits 83

Page 9: Economic analysis of proposed Forest Service timber sales

1

INTRODUCTION

Timber management on U.S. Forest Service land often conflicts,

to some degree, with nontimber resources and/or the desires of certain

interest groups. The use of economic analysis as a decision criterion

for proposed Forest Service timber sales is not yet a well defined

process. This paper presents one method of economic analysis for the

evaluation of proposed Forest Service timber sales, and discusses the

integration of quantifiable timber management economics with other

resource impacts which may be difficult to quantify economically.

While this study was prepared for the special case of the Ketchikan

Salvage Sale proposed in northwestern Montana, the methods developed

here are fairly easy to employ — only basic algebra and a hand-held

calculator were used — and should be applicable to other proposed

Forest Service timber sales.

The Ketchikan Sale was designed to salvage roadless timber

stands recently involved in a bark beetle outbreak, and has generated

considerable controversy. Due to the unique condition and location of

the sale area, different public constituencies have very divergent

views as to how the Forest Service should react to the beetle in­

festation. The area is critical habitat for grizzly bear and gray

wolf, which are officially threatened and endangered species. Wild­

life biologists and conservationists argue that various development

activities in the vicinity increase the need for the Forest Service to

Page 10: Economic analysis of proposed Forest Service timber sales

2

maintain its remaining roadless areas in a wild condition. The

Forest Service and those oriented toward timber production hold

that the area should be roaded and logged in order to utilize dead

trees before they lose their timber value, to limit the bark beetle

epidemic, and to reduce the fire hazard resulting from the dead trees.

This may appear to be a fairly typical conflict faced by the

Forest Service in attempting to manage public lands for "multiple

use" where timber production and other resources tend to be mutually

exclusive. However, the economics of this particular sale further

complicate the issue. The Forest Service prepared an economic analysis

of the proposed sale which concluded that the sale would have a nega­

tive net present value. Opponents of the sale were perplexed as to

why the Forest Service should damage critical wildlife habitat while

losing money managing the timber resource. The Forest Service dis­

missed its own analysis, claiming that the logging industry would

"bid up" the sale to a point which would make it a positive economic

investment.

That assuption, based on recent bidding activity for local

Forest Service timber sales, was the source of much confusion re­

garding the economics of the Ketchikan Sale. Forest Service timber is

sold at auction to the highest bidder, subject to a minimum bid. The

minimum bid is derived through a detailed appraisal and residual

pricing system which attemptps to determine the selling value of the

lumber that could be obtained from the sale, less all costs (including

profit) necessary to convert the sale stumpage to finished lumber (see

page 23). The problem here is that actual bids for Forest Service

timber in recent years have often been several times higher than the

Page 11: Economic analysis of proposed Forest Service timber sales

3

bids predicted by the Forest Service appraisal. Even though many

sales on the Flathead National Forest had recently been appraised

at low or even negative values, several had sold for relatively high

bids. Regardless of the reasons for this "bidding up" (which may in­

clude such things as inaccurate estimates of milling costs, scaling

measurements which underestimate milling efficiency, or bidder specu­

lations that lumber values would significantly appreciate over the

contract period), the fact that the Forest Service could not accurately

predict the selling value of the sale naturally would lead to dif­

ficulties in the economic analysis prepared by the Forest Service for

the sale.

The analysis presented here will attempt to reduce the confusion

surrounding.the economics of the Ketchikan Sale. Two fundemental

flaws in the Forest Service analysis will be dealt with: inability

to predict accurately the selling value of stumpage, and failure to

include certain timber management costs resulting from the sale.

Benefits and costs of timber management will be considered over one

full rotation (100 years), rather than the 20 year period used by

the Forest Service. The results of this analysis show that the

Ketchikan Sale would be an investment with very negative returns in

terms of timber management economics.

The Ketchikan Sale may be unique in many respects, but similar

conflicts involving deficit salvage sales and noncommodity resources

on Forest Service land may occur in the future. A recent study, using

very conservative assumptions, concluded that a great deal of Forest

Service timber is already being sold at a loss (Barlow, et al, 1980).

Section 6k of the 1976 National Forest Management Act (NFMA) is inter­

Page 12: Economic analysis of proposed Forest Service timber sales

4

preted by some authorities as mandating economic efficiency — benefits

equal or exceed costs — in Forest Service timber management (Stoel,

1978; Krutilla and Haigh, 1978), but the implementing regulations only

call for cost efficiency — least cost — in meeting assigned pro­

duction goals [36 CFR 219.12 (b) (3) (iii)]. The Forest Service

Northern Region Draft Plan states that nationally assigned timber

production goals cannot be met unless salvage sales are more aggres­

sively pursued and existing roadless areas are accessed with capital

funds (not timber receipts) at a greatly accelerated rate (USDA 1981c).

This means that capital funds must be used to subsidize timber sales

where road costs exceed the value of harvestable timber; an econo­

mically inefficient practice. Salvage sales are excepted from im­

portant restrictions placed on timber management activity by the NFMA

regarding size of opening, prohibition of timber harvest on "marginal

lands," prohibition of timber harvest before culmination of mean

annual increment, and prohibition of timber harvest above the sus­

tained yield-allowable cut level. Thus, salvage sales could be used

to circumvent NFMA constraints which were designed to insure economic

efficiency of, and to protect nontimber resources impacted by, Forest

Service timber harvesting.

Such items suggesting future policy debates over Forest Service

deficit salvage sales will be discussed after examining the economic

analysis of the Ketchikan Sale. However, the geopgraphic, historic,

and ecological contexts within which the area must be managed will

be discussed before presenting the economic analysis. The wildlife

habitat issue and the cummulative developmental pressures in the

vicinity are largely beyond the scope of any economic analysis of a

Page 13: Economic analysis of proposed Forest Service timber sales

5

timber sale and must be considered as seperate factors in making

a land management decision on the salvage sale proposal. While the

salvage sale proposal implies that insect damage can be controlled

and economic loss can be reduced, the ecology of the particular

insect and forest ecosystem must be understood before such claims

can be made or evaluated.

Page 14: Economic analysis of proposed Forest Service timber sales

6

NORTH END SALVAGE SALES AND APPEALS

In the spring of 1980, the Flathead National Forest released

a controversial Environmental Assessment Report (EAR) for four pro­

posed timber sales on the Glacier View Ranger District. The four

sales were collectively titled the North End Salvage Sales and in­

cluded: Frozen Lake, 350 acres; Ketchikan, 5,800 acres; Thoma, 180

acres; and Trail, 390 acres (USDA, 1980a). The sale areas are located

within the Mt. Hefty, Tuchuck, and Thompson-Seaton roadless areas,

all of which were recommended for nonwilderness allocation by the RARE

II process. The North End Salvage areas are on or very near the

Canadian border and mostly within the Trail Creek Drainage, which is

a tributary of the North Fork of the Flathead River, a national Wild

and Scenic River. The areas are at the very northern end of the

Flathead National Forest. The Kootanai National Forest lies to the

west, the North Fork of the Flathead River flows south on the east

side of the areas, and private land lies along the North Fork and

Trail Creek, to the east and southeast. The North Fork of the Flathead

River also forms the western boundary of Glacier National Park (see

map).

The EAR considered several alternatives designed to salvage dead

and "high risk" lodge pole pine (Pinus contorta Douglas var. latifolia

Englemann) in response to a recent mountain pine beetle Dendroctonus

pondersae Hopkins) outbreak. A controversy arose in reaction to plans

Page 15: Economic analysis of proposed Forest Service timber sales

7

which called for building more than 20 miles of road and cutting timber

in some 6,720 acres or roadless areas considered by many wildlife

biologists to be critical habitat for the officially threatened

grizzly bear (Ursus arctos horribilus) and endangered gray wolf

(Canus lupus). One sale alone, the Ketchikan Sale, was to cover

5,800 acres of roadless area and included 16.1 miles of road. The

controversy was exacerbated by the economic analysis completed by the

Flathead National Forest, which indicated that the Ketchikan Sale

alone would amount to a net present worth loss of $880,000 (USDA,

1980a).

On August 6, 1980, the Flathead National Forest released a

Supplement to the EAR which announced Forest Service plans to go

ahead with one of the proposed alternatives. To reduce impacts on

grizzly habitat, the chosen alternative was substantially altered

fron the alternatives analyzed in the EAR (e.g. the Ketchikan Sale

was reduced to 2,300 acres with 11.3 miles of new road), but no

analysis was made of the economic consequences of these modifications.

The Supplement also concluded that an Environmental Impact Statement

(EIS) was not necessary for the proposal. The conclusion was based

on a U.S. Fish and Wildlife Service (FWS) determination that the

proposed sales (with an extensive list of mitigation requirements)

were "not likely to jeopardize the continued existence of the grizzly

bear, gray wolf, and bald eagle" (USDA 1980b).

The Defenders of Wildlife and the Flathead chapter of the

Montana Wilderness Association appealed the timber sales, largely

on the grounds that the decision to forgo an EIS was wrong. The

appellants argued in part that the grizzly bear and gray wolf habitat

Page 16: Economic analysis of proposed Forest Service timber sales

8

issue had not been properly addressed, especially in terms of cum-

mulative development activities occurring in the vicinity of the

proposed sales. They also questioned the need for the proposed sales

at a time when the national lumber economy is depressed, the local

annual timber cut appears to exceed the local mill capacity (USDA,

1980a), and the Forest Services's own economic analysis concluded

that the proposals would lose well over $880,000.

After denial of the appeal at the Flathead Supervisor's Office

and the Northern Regional Office, the appellants were jained by the

Sierra Club Legal Defense Fund and the appeal was taken to the Chief

of the Forest Service in the Washington D.C. Office. The Chief denied

the appeal in the fall of 1981 and all four sales were immdiately

offered at auction. The three small sales sold, but the Ketchikan

Sale failed to receive any bids. The Flathead National Forest tem­

porarily withdrew the sale, planning to reoffer it in the spring of

1982. The appellants sought to have the sale withdrawn until the

issue could be considered in the upcoming Integrated Forest Plan

(the draft is due to be published in February, 1983). They also

kept open the option of taking the appeal to court if the sale were

reoffered and sold.

Over the winter, the Flathead National Forest made changes in

the sale package, hoping to make the sale more attractive to bidders.

The appellants maintained efforts to block the sale and a summary

of this study was made available to the staff of Senator Max Baucus

for use in discussion of the sale with the Forest Supervisor. On

April 6, 1982, the Supervisor announced that the sale proposal would

be dropped until the forest plan could be completed.

Page 17: Economic analysis of proposed Forest Service timber sales

9

CRITICAL HABITAT AND CUMMULATIVE IMPACTS

In letters printed in the EAR and Supplement, Dr. Charles

Jonkel, Director of the University of Montana Border Grizzly project,

Dr. Robert Ream, Director of the University of Montana Wolf Ecology

Project, and Thomas Hay, Regional Supervisor of the Montana State

Department of Fish and Game, all stated that the Ketchikan area is

very important wildlife habitat, especially for grizzly bear, gray

wolf and Dolly Varden trout. Jonkel and Ream were particularly con­

cerned about cummulative developmental impacts in the vicinity, and

the lack of Forest Service attention to those cummiulative impacts.

These letters indicate that the Ketchikan Sale is a major portion of

one of the last undeveloped areas in the vicinity which is suitable

for grizzly bear and wolf habitat. The Missoulian reported the follow­

ing reactions to the FWS decision that the North End Salvage sales

would not jeopardize the grizzly bear or gray wolf:

Jonkel, one of the leading bear experts in the world today, said he was amazed by the federal agency's decision that the Ketchikan salvage logging will not jeopardize the grizzly bear.-

"I don't know how in God's name they could have come to the conclusion they did," he said, adding that the Ketchikan area is "extremely good grizzly habitat — some of the best habitat west of the Continental Divide."

Ream voiced a similar reaction to the agency's decision. "I was really surprised when they came out with it," he said.

The logging plans might have been acceptable had not surrounding areas already faced such extensive development, (Jonkel) said. But now, Ketchikan "for some of the bears might be the last option." (Schwennesen, 1980a).

Page 18: Economic analysis of proposed Forest Service timber sales

10

The cumraulative impacts which worry Jonkel, Ream and others,

include extensive logging in Canada, the Kootanai National Forest,

and adjacent private and Flathead National Forest lands, coal mining

in Canada, oil and gas drilling Canada, seismic exploration all around

and possibly within the area, potential electricity transmission

corridors, pipelines, increased housing development in the North Fork

valley, road construction and improvement to support the above and

other developments, and increasing hunting, trapping, and recreation

pressures. Logging in the vicinity is especially extensive, due to

the mountain pine beetle outbreak. Just over the Canadian border,

approximately $1 billion worth of coal lies near the surface, seismic

exploration has been extensive, and two oil and gas wells are being

drilled (Jonkel, 1979). Seismic exploration is proposed for much of

the North Fork drainage; Amoco has filed a prospecting plan for a

seismic line (a 30 pound explosive charge detonated every 220 feet for

20 miles) that runs right through the Ketchikan area (Schwennesen,

1981c). A BPA transmission corridor and pipelines from Canada are

possible in the vicinity (Schwennesen, 1980b). Increased recreation,

hunting, and trapping use and a new policy in Glacier National Park

requiring the destruction of bears involved in two encounters with

humans, put additional pressures on grizzly bears in the vicinity.

The Ketchikan Sale is not the only proposed development in the

North Fork Valley which is being actively opposed by conservationists.

A Canandian firm is seeking permits for two open pit coal mines —

each one mile wide and 1,000 feet deep — Just five miles north of the

sale area. The proposed Cabin Creek mines spurred the creation of

the. Flathead River Basin Environmental Impact Study, which is nearing

Page 19: Economic analysis of proposed Forest Service timber sales

11

completion of several year long investigation designed to provide

comprehensive baseline environmental data for the Flathead Basin.

The Cabin Creek mines have also united many Canadian and U.S. citizen

groups concerned about threats to wildlife and the pristine qualities

of the North Fork Valley {Lakes, 1982).

For similar reasons, a Federal Highway Administration proposal

to pave a ten mile stretch of the North Fork road at the south end

of the valley is drawing considerable public opposition. Even the

FWS has ruled that this project (as originally proposed) would

jeopardize the continued existence of the grizzly bear and gray wolf.

The U.S. Park Service and the Montana Department of Fish and Game also

oppose the paving project, while the U.S. Forest Service and the

Montana Department of State Lands support it (USDOT, 1982).

Meanwhile, north of the border, the British Columbia Forest

Service has undertaken a very extensive response to the pine beetle

outbreak. With 7,000 acres already "salvaged" and 47,000 acreas left

dead, BCFS plans to spend $4.5 million over the next 4-5 years to

simply flatten 23,000 acres of non-commercial timber stands. The

BCFS recently announced plans to cut an additional 1 ,235 acres of

beetle infested lodgepole just over one mile from Glacier National

Park (Schwennsen, 1981a; 1981b; 1981d).

Taken together, these developmental pressures pose serious

threats to the remaining wildlife and wildness in the North Fork

Valley. The Forest Service is required by law to manage National

Forest lands for multiple-use resources, and to maintain and enhance

habitat for threatened and endangered wildlife. Placed in this con­

text, a decision on the Ketchikan Sale should carefully weigh the

Page 20: Economic analysis of proposed Forest Service timber sales

12

damage done to wildlife habitat against the need for, and benefit

of, intensive timber management on this particular tract.

The Forest Service offered three basic reasons for supporting

the Ketchikan Sale (to combat the pine beetle epidemic, reduce fire

hazards, and utilize timber that would otherwise go to waste), while

implying that impacts on wildlife would be negligible. For example:

Dick Call, ranger of the Glacier View District which oversees the sale, says leaving all that dead timber could trigger a large forest fire. And that would be bad for both bear and man.

"I do not feel too well about allowing 19 million board feet of timber go to waste," he says.

• • •

"We've been logging for 40 years (in the North Fork)," he says. "My personal observation is that the bears are increasing." (O'Harra, 1982a).

As discussed above, wildlife experts are quite concerned by

the potential impacts which this sale would have on wildlife. A

permanent road system and increased human activity in the Ketchikan

area are seen as greater threats to the grizzly bear than is the risk

of fire (Jonkel, 1979). The following sections will demonstrate that

there is-no foundation for assumptions that the Ketchikan Sale would

combat the mountain pine beetle epidemic or that it would reduce the

"waste" of timber resources.

Page 21: Economic analysis of proposed Forest Service timber sales

13

MOUNTAIN PINE BEETLE AND LODGEPOLE PINE; ECOLOGY AND ECONOMICS

The prospectus for the Ketchikan Sale states: "This sale is

being sold to reduce the spread of the mountain pine beetle," (USDA

1981d). This statement flies in the face of studies published by

Forest Service entomologists and other experts on the mountain pine

beetle. In order to evaluate possible land management decisions made

in reaction to a mountain pine beetle epidemic, it is necessary to

review the history of control attempts, the ecological role of the

beetle, and the literature concerning the economics of insect control.

Mountain Pine Beetle Control History

Although the first recorded outbreak of mountain pine beetle

(Dendroctonus Ponderosas Hopkins) in Rocky Mountain lodgepole Pinus

contorta Douglas var. latifolia Engleman) forests occurred in Flathead

County in 1909 (USDA, 1979; Klein, 1978), it is believed that the

mountain pine beetle has coexisted and probably coevolved with lodge-

pole pine from the beginning of the tree's existence (Cole and Amman,

1980; Peterman 1978). Forest Service attempts to control the mountain

pine beetle in lodgepole forests of the Rocky Mountains were initiated

in 1912 in the Flathead and Beaverhead National Forests. Extensive

and largely unsuccessful control attempts have been made throughout

the western U.S. from that time to the present, and actual control

of an epidemic is now generally considered not to be economically

Page 22: Economic analysis of proposed Forest Service timber sales

u

efficent (Furniss and Carolin, 1980; Klein, 1978). Control techniques

have included underburning, felling and peeling, felling and burning

(in one case over 1,800 acres of lodgepole were cleared, wind-rowed

and burned), burning individual trees with flame throwers, spraying

with various chemicals, and even wrapping individual trees with

explosive cord and detonating (Klein,.1978). Currently, management

techniques can protect individual trees (at high cost) and can some­

times delay the spread of an outbreak, but the consensus of Forest

Service experts seems to be that management of the mountain pine

beetle should be limited to; individual tree or stand protection

where economically justified, prevention of future outbreaks through

manipulation of tree age and species diversity where justified by

timber values, or simply allowing nature to run its course in many

cases (Cole and Amman, 1980; Klein, 1978; Cole, 1978; Amman et at,

1977). This history of extensive and unsuccessful control attempts

is blamed on an inadequate understanding of mountain pine beetle

ecology (Klein, 1978; Peterman, 1978).

Lodgepole Pine/Mountain Pine Beetle Ecology

Lodgepole pine is often a dominant species in forest eco­

systems where wildfire and bark beetles play important roies. The

following synopsis of lodgepole/beetle ecology is taken largely from

Peterman (1978) and two Forest Service publications on the mountain

pine beetle in lodgepole pine (Cole and Amman, 1980; Amman et al,

1977).

Lodgepole pine occurs in western North America from Alaska

south to Baja California and east to Wyoming and Colorado, ranging

Page 23: Economic analysis of proposed Forest Service timber sales

from sea level to 11,500 feet in Colorado. Lodgepole is considered

a serai, shade intolerant, prolific seed producing tree, which means

that it is quick to colonize distrurbed forest sites, but may be

subject to replacement by species which are more shade tolerant.

However, lodgepole often persists as the dominant species on forest

sites where other trees are considered the climax species. This

persistence can be attributed to several aspects of lodgepole ecology,

including fire and bark beetles (Brown, 1975; Pfister and Daubenmire,

1975).

Lodgepole pine can begin producing cones at 5 to 10 years of

age (Latham, 1965; Crossley, 1956) with each cone containing 25 to

40 seeds (Armit, 1966; Bates, 1930; Clements, 1910). These cones

are often serotinous, meaning they will not open to release seeds

unless subjected to high temperatures (such as in fires), and seeds

may remain viable for 75 years (Mason, 1915). An old lodgepole

stand can have in storage hundreds of thousands of seeds per acre,

ready to be released by an event such as fire (Lotan, 1975). This

reproductive system often leads to development of dense, stagnated

stands which are susceptible to mountain pine beetle attack and high

fuel build-up, setting the stage for an intense fire followed by

establishment of a new lodgepole pine stand. Repetition of this

cycle can be seen as a mechanism which allows the serai lodgepole

pine to persist as a dominant species while at the same time pro­

viding habitat for the mountain pine beetle. What on the face may

appear to be a parasitic attack on one species by another, may actually

be a classic case of coevolutionary mutualism.

Further evidence of this mutualism can be found in the life

Page 24: Economic analysis of proposed Forest Service timber sales

16

cycle and habits of the mountain pine beetle in lodgepole pine.

Usually in late summer, new adult beetles emerge and attack living

trees, where they construct galleries and lay eggs in the inner bark.

Larvae move horizontally while feeding on the inner bark and kill the

trees by effectively girdling them, cutting off the trees' nutrient

transport system (the phloem). Several species of blue-stain fungi

(e.g., Ceratocytis montia Rumb., and Europhium clavigerum Robinson

and Davidson), which are carried from tree to tree by the adult

beetles, seem to regulate moisture conditions within affected trees

in a manner which is beneficial to the developing larvae. Thus,

additional species may be involved in the coevolutionary, mutualistic

cycle. In fact, some authorities state that it is the blue-stain

fungi, not the beetle, which kills the trees by invading and des­

troying living tissues.^ It appears that the beetle/fungi association

behaves as a mutualistic system where the beetle transports the

fungi from host to host and the fungi weakens and conditions the host

to the benefit of the beetle (Safranyik et al, 1975).

Beetle population aynamics are affected by several factors

(including tree diameter, phloem thickness, tree age, stand density,

and climate) such that epidemics are most common in lodgepole stands

over 8U years of age and rarely occur in stands under 60 years of

age, nor at high elevation. This gives the stand plenty of time to

accumulate a considerable seed reservoir and fuel loading, thus en-

1 It may occur to some that control strategies aimed at the beetle may be misplaced if the fungi is the killing agent. I have not seen a discussion of this in the literature.

Page 25: Economic analysis of proposed Forest Service timber sales

17

hancing the probability of fire and subsequent reseeding of lodgepole

pine following any beetle outbreak.

Breaking this cycle by preventing large wildfires (which were

a periodic part of lodgepole ecosystems until recent human suppression

practices) can be expected to allow forest succession to proceed to

climax (replacement of lodgepole by other species) where lodgepole

is serai. Fire suppression and prevention may be increasing the total

habitat suitable for (and size of) bark beetle outbreaks by allowing

more lodgepole stands to escape burning and live past age 60-80. If

a beetle epidemic kills a dominant lodgepole stand, and fire does

not occur to give lodgepole its reproductive advantage after a fire

(and if a seed source for more shade tolerant species is available),

the stand would eventually convert to a climax species such as fir

or spruce. This type of conversion would create species and age

mosaics which would significantly reduce the effects of future bark

beetle epidemics, given the beetle's habits which limit outbreaks to

lodgepole pine at least 60 years of age. Thus, while there may be

large short-term losses of lodgepole pine volume during an outbreak,

leaving the stand alone after an outbreak could lead to a situation

where long-range timber productivity would not be seriously impaired

(Wellner, 1978).

Understanding the ecology of lodgepole pine and mountain pine

beetle evokes a comparison between beetle management and fire manage­

ment. In the late 1960's, the Forest Service began to realize that

its inflexible policy of aggressively suppressing all fires was often

counterproductive. Fire is now being seen as a mangement tool and

is often either allowed to burn naturally or even set deliberately

Page 26: Economic analysis of proposed Forest Service timber sales

18

1 to attain management goals. Similarly, it has been suggested that

some mountain pine beetle outbreaks be allowed to run their course

2 naturally, as a management tool. Under certain conditions, the

mountain pine beetle is expected to convert current stagnant stands

to more economically desirable future stands (Peterman, 1978). For

resources other than timber, a beetle outbreak generally has negli­

gible to positive impacts (Wellner, 1978). A recent Forest Service

publication on the mountain pine beetle (Cole and Amman, 1980) concurs

with other authorities that: 1) salvage or sanitation cuttings

cannot prevent or deter beetle outbreaks; 2) salvage operations

should be justified either directly by timber economics or indirectly

by impacts on other resources which warrant subsidization; and 3) a

"do-nothing" policy is often preferred (Cole, 1978; Peterman, 1978;

Wellner, 1978; Amman et al, 1977).

Forest Pest Economics

There is a surprising lack of literature on the subject of

Forest pest economics. As one authority puts it,

It is striking that so little good economic analysis has been done on forest pest management, considering the controversies over spray projects, the sizable annual outlays, and the dramatic impact of pests on forest growth. Recent compendia on forest economics and policy, e.g. Clawson, Research in Forest Economics and Policy, have almost nothing

Vor instance, see Troy Fire Management Plan, 1979. Kootanai National Forest, USDA Forest Service, Troy, Montana.

2 The Forest Service has engaged in extensive, expensive and controversial attempts to control another forest insect, the Douglas fir tussock moth. Recent studies suggest that the moth may actually be beneficial to forest productivity while control and salvage opera­tions may cause more damage to the timber resource than the insect (Corkran, 1980; USDA, 1978).

Page 27: Economic analysis of proposed Forest Service timber sales

19

to say on the economics of forest protection (Irland, 1980).

General pest management systems theory has faired somewhat

better. A 1976 review of that subject has 159 citations (Ruesink,

1976). In this general field, the economic optimization of pest

control activities has received considerable study. The concept of

economic threshold has been discussed since at least 1959 (Stern,

et al) and is now defined as;

That population where the marginal benefit from damage prevented by the control program is equal to the marginal cost of realizing that population through a control pro­gram (Hall and Norgaard, 1973).

If a pest control program is to be economically efficient, the

economic threshold (as defined above) for the particular control

program should be identified accurately, and pest damages below that

threshold should be tolerated (Norgaard, 1976; Stern, 1973). Despite

frequent calls for economic efficiency, forest pest control practice

has not kept up with theory:

economic thresholds, where they are set at all, are set arbitrarily and are dictated largely by emotional responses . . . fear of what might occur rather than any Justified economic base. The many absurd "control projects" committed in the name of protection are possible only through govern­ment subsidy (Stark, 1971).

That economic efficiency rather than vague notions of "good

forestry" should be the major decision criterion in forest management

investment is not a new position to be taken by professional foresters

(Newport, 1962; Stoltenberg, 1959). Arguments that economic efficiency

should be applied to forest insect control are not new either (Marty and

Allison, I960; Johnson, 1963). And yet, very expensive forest insect

control projects are pursued to this day and are often arbitrarily

justified by "good forestry," or emotional reactions to "waste" or

Page 28: Economic analysis of proposed Forest Service timber sales

20

potential fire hazard. Where a benefit/cost analysis is employed,

it is often very poorly designed (Irland, 1977). For example, a

General Accounting Office investigation of a proposal to salvage

lodgepole pine involved in a mountain pine beetle outbreak in eastern

Oregon concluded that the Forest Service analysis of the project was

flawed to the point of uselessness because it omitted or understated

costs, used improper procedures, used unreliable or outdated data,

and failed to develop and analyze alternatives properly (U.S. Comp­

troller General, 1976).

The following analysis will identify and attempt to correct

similar problems in the economic analysis prepared by the Flathead

National Forest for the proposed Ketchikan Sale.

Page 29: Economic analysis of proposed Forest Service timber sales

21

ECONOMIC ANALYSIS

EAR Analysis

The economic analysis of the Ketchikan Sale which was prepared

by the Flathead National Forest for use in the North End Salvage EAR

was flawed in many ways with repect to the sale proposal which was

actually offered for bid. For instance, the original proposal

evaluated in the EAR involved much more timber volume and road con­

struction than the sale ultimately offered, but no revision was ever

made in the economic analysis to examine these changes. The EAR

analysis failed to include many timber management costs (i.e. sale

preparation, sale administration, site preparation, fuel treatment,

planting or thinning) that would result from the sale. While pur­

porting to be simply a salvage operation, the proposal called for

a permanent road system and the economic analysis claimed as a benefit

the harvest of a very large volume of larch twenty years after the

initial entry. All other benefits and costs of future timber manage­

ment in the area were ignored. The analysis also used an extremely

low estimate of the proportion of dead volume in the sale.

Perhaps the biggest problem with the Flathead National Forest's

economic analysis lies in its timber resource valuation methodology.

The value of the timber was set by averaging the sum of.estimated

logging costs, the estimated road costs and statistical high

Page 30: Economic analysis of proposed Forest Service timber sales

bid^ received for twelve timber sales on the Glacier View Ranger

District from August, 1977 to October, 1978. The average value was

found to be $207.32/m.b.f. This figure was calculated using an

average of $21.81/m.b.f. for road costs, but an examination of the

timber sale reports for the twelve sales indicates that the estimated

road cost averaged only $5.96/m.b.f. The actual sum of logging costs,

road costs and statistical high bid for these sales ranged from

$120.14/m.b.f. to $309.05/m.b.f. Any value based on such a wide

range of data would be statistically quite weak.

Although site-specific logging and road cost estimates were

subtracted from this average resource value to calculate the benefits

of the initial entry, the value of the larch harvest planned for

twenty years later was calculated using a Forest-wide (not District-

wide) average statistical high bid for larch with no attempt to ad­

just for any site-specific costs other than road construction.

These methods for valuing the two harvests are quite inconsistent.

The results of the Forest's economic analysis indicated that

the Ketchikan Sale would have a benefit/cost ratio of 0.76 and would

be a net present loss of $882,992. However, the Flathead decided to

offer the sale anyway, believing that the sale would be "bid up" by

competing buyers to a level well above the value at which it was ap­

praised. Some timber sales on the Flathead National Forest had been

"bid up" by as much as six times the appraised value during the period

1 Statistical high bid is the winning bid (high bid) less pur­

chaser credit. Purchaser credit is the value of timber that the purchaser is allowed to remove without payment, as compensation for road construction expenses. Thus, statistical high bid represents actual financial payment received by the Forest Service.

Page 31: Economic analysis of proposed Forest Service timber sales

immediately preceeding the offering of the Ketchikan Sale (Armstrong,

1981). This "bidding up" indicates that the pricing method employed

by the Forest Service is no longer functional as a means of predicting

stumpage prices.

The Forest Service uses a residual pricing system to determine

the stumpage value at which to sell its timber. In this system, the

selling value for finished lumber is determined and all manufacturing,

transportation, and logging costs, along with an allowance for profit,

are subtracted from the lumber selling value. The resulting residual

price is considered the fair market stumpage value at which bidding

"I may begin (Davis, 1966). If, as in the Ketchikan case, this process

results in a negative indicated stumpage value (a deficit sale), then

the advertised rate is set at a minimum base rate. This residual

pricing system allows for timber to be sold at stumpage rates well

below what would be required to recover all timber management costs

associated with producing that timber (Barlow et al, 1980).

The Flathead's inability to estimate the selling value of its

timber accurately placed it in the contradictory position of demon­

strating that the sale has a negative economic value while at the same

time preparing and offering the sale. Conservationists opposing the

sale were perplexed as to why the Forest did not seize the opportunity

to forgo a negative timber management investment while at the same

time protecting wildlife habitat and other multiple-use resources.

Coupled with the denial of its own analysis, the Flathead's omission

1 An excellent paper explaining the Forest Service's residual

pricing method is available from John A. Combes, Timber Management, Northern Region Office, USDA Forest Service, Missoula, Montana.

Page 32: Economic analysis of proposed Forest Service timber sales

24

of timber management costs, its inconsistent methodology for valuing

benefits, and its inability to predict an accurate selling value

created very fertile ground for misunderstanding and misinterpretation

of the sale's economics by those on both sides of the controversy.

New Approach

This paper was initiated in an attempt to rectify these problems

and clarify the economics of the Ketchikan Sale. The economic analysis

given here is not presented as a hind-sight correction of the Flat­

head's analysis. In fairness to the Forest, much of the methodology

and data used here were developed after the Flathead's analysis was

undertaken. This analysis is offered as a new approach, using the

most recent and site-specific methodology and data available. For

instance, a new transaction evidence model for stumpage valuation

on the Flathead was used to overcome the inability to predict the

selling value of the sale's timber accurately. Except for the pre­

diction of road costs, all methodology and values used here are the

same as those employed in the preparation of the Flathead forest plan.

It is hoped that this study will help clarify the economics

of the Ketchikan sale for both sides in the debate. If this raethc-

dology and data had been available at the outset of preparation of

the Ketchikan Sale, and if the Flathead had used it to predict the

timber selling value and management costs associated with the sale,

a good deal of time and money might have been saved, and much mis­

understanding avoided by both sides in the controversy.

1 The Draft Flathead National Forest Plan is due to be published

February, 1983.

Page 33: Economic analysis of proposed Forest Service timber sales

25

For instance, use of the stunipage valuation equation (explained

below) would have predicted that the original sale would not receive

any bids. Some Forest Service officials still maintain that the

Ketchikan Sale was the victim of a lumber market which dropped during

the lengthy appeals process. Although real lumber price, lumber

1 tally for lodgepole pine has continued to drop since it peaked in

1 mid 1978, the current real lumber price, log scale for lodgepole pine

is actually slightly above the average for large timber sales sold on

the Flathead during 1978 (calculated from Flathead Large Sale Data

computer printout dated 11/5/81, USDA, 1981e). This surprising

situation can be attributed to an increase in the real value of by­

products (chips) and to improved milling efficiency. These factors

have offset reductions in lumber price, lumber tally, so that even

though the lumber market price has declined, the vlaue of a thousand

board feet of logs has remained fairly constant.

The Flathead stumpage valuation model predicts that the ori­

ginally offered sale would not have sold even under the peak con­

ditions of 1978. However, the model predicts that the modifications

made in the sale contract over the winter were sufficient to have

allowed the revised sale to sell, provided that there are buyers in

the vicinity willing to contract to cut timber at the present

1 Lumber price, lumber tally is the price of a unit of milled

lumber. Lumber price, log scale is the price of wood products which can be milled from a unit of raw logs. Lumber price, log scale is derived by adding the value of by-products such as chips obtained in the milling of a unit of logs to the lumber price, lumber tally and then multiplying the sum by an overrun factor. The overrun (or recovery) factor is a measure of milling efficiency. Current log scaling methods seriously underestimate the volume of lumber that today's sawmills can produce from a unit of logs.

Page 34: Economic analysis of proposed Forest Service timber sales

26

1 time. But as shown below, even if the sale had sold for the pre­

dicted bid, it would not have covered the timber management costs

associated with it.

Methods and Assumptions

The approach used here is very similar to a bare land or site

expectation analysis based on the Faustmann formula (also known as

soil expectation, land rent or land expectation vlaue. See Davis,

1966). The essential difference between this analysis and the Faust­

mann formula is that here costs and benefits of harvesting the exist­

ing stand are added to the costs and benefits of managing timber over

2 only the next rotation. The Faustmann formula would ignore the

existing stand and would consider an infinite series of rotations

beginning with stand establishment. This analysis was limited to

one rotation because all calculations were done manually, and any

costs or benefits accruing after the first rotation would have minimal

present values (for instance, a $5 million harvest 200 years from now

would have a gross present value of $1,960 using a 4% discount rate,

and only a $5 present value using 7 1/8%).

The inclusion of existing stand values allows a marginal economic

analysis of the sale as a timber management investment. By including

future benefits and costs, the high initial road costs (which would

1 The model is based on local transaction evidence from the

period July, 1974 - January, 1980, and thus may overvalue stumpage during periods fo extreme lumber industry stagnation and low timber demand.

2 A rotation is the period between timber harvest on a particular site.

Page 35: Economic analysis of proposed Forest Service timber sales

27

not be covered by the net timber value of the initial sale) can be

more equitably attributed to future as well as initial uses J Fixed

annual benefits and costs (e.g. grazing receipts or general adminis­

tration costs) are not included here. Such annual receipts or expenses

at the district or forest level should not be significantly affected

by a decision to proceed with or forgo the Ketchikan Sale.

The planning horizon for the analysis was increased from the

20 years used in the EAR to 100 years (one full rotation), and the

net present value through the first rotation was calculated based on

current stand conditions, scheduled management activity, and pro­

jected yield estimated in detailed working papers prepared for each

cutting unit by the district silviculturalist (Wilson, 1981). This

entailed quantifying all management costs (i.e. road construction

and reconstruction, road engineering and administration, sale pre­

paration and administration, site preparation and fuel treatment,

planting, stocking surveys, and thinning) and expected benefits

2 (stumpage values for all commercial harvests) in constant dollars

discounted to the present. (While 100 years may stretch the limits

of prognostication at this point is time, using the silviculturalist's

detailed projections of yield and management activity through one

1 This approach (mixing benefits and costs of initial harvests with those of future harvests) can become problematic where an old growth stand may have high value on a site with a negative bare land value. It would be possible in such a case to have a positive net present value (in terms of timber management economics) even though management costs would exceed benefits for all future harvests. This situation is not encountered here.

2 All values are adjusted for inflation using the quarterly GNP Implicit Price Deflator Indices reported in the Survey of Current Business (USDOC, 1979-82).

Page 36: Economic analysis of proposed Forest Service timber sales

rotation allows a virtual state of the art estimate of timber manage­

ment costs and benefits without resorting to a computer. Since vir­

tually all of the models and value data used here are taken from the

Flathead FORPLAN computer model, it should be relatively easy for the

Forest Service to use its computers to apply this approach to an in­

finite series of rotations when preparing future economic analyses

of timber sales).

Three discount rates were applied; 4%, 7 1/8%, and 10%.

The debate over the proper discount rate for public forestry has

not yet been settled, but these three rates seem to cover the range

of common argument (O'Toole, 1981; Mikesell, 1977; Samuelson, 1976).

The 4% rate was recently proposed by the Forest Service as the rate

it will use in its planning process, along with a 7 1/8% rate as a

sensitivity test (USDA, 1981b). Use of the lower discount rate for

public forestry is often supported by foresters and conservationists

because higher rates reduce the age at which timber matures finan­

cially. Foresters also worry that a higher discount rate would pre­

clude investment in timber management on much slow-growing public

timberland currently committed to timber production. Economists

supporting the lower rate often argue that since public entities

incur lower risk than private enterprise, the public rate of discount

should be similar to the marginal real interest rate born by low risk

financial instruments (i.e. AAA rated bonds). Other economists argue

that the public discount rate should approximate the marginal rate

for private industry engaged in similar activity. A recent canvass

of timber companies in the Pacific Northwest concluded that the

marginal rate for the industry was approximately 7% - 8% (O'Toole,

Page 37: Economic analysis of proposed Forest Service timber sales

29

1981). This is very close to the 7 3/8% rate recommended by the

Water Resources Board for public works. On the upper end, the Office

of Management and Budget has insisted for several years that 10% is

the proper social rate of discount.

Benefits were estimated through the use of a stumpage valuation

model developed for the Flathead in the spring of 1981 for use in

the forest plan (USDA, 1981a). The model is a multiple regression

equation based- oh 39 large timber sales sold on the Flathead National

Forest during the period July, 1974 through January, 1980. The equa­

tion is adjusted for inflation and uses sale-specific factors and

market variables to predict the selling value of timber on the Flat­

head. Predicted real increases in lumber price, production costs

and overrun factor for the Flathead were included in the estimation

of timber selling value for future harvests (see Appendix A). (Ap­

plication of this equation to the Ketchikan Sale is unique in that

the data base for the Flathead stumpage valuation model included no

sales with such a large proportion of dead timber. The fact that

this sale contains 73% dead timber, much of it dead since 1979, may

create a situation in which the equation would tend to overvalue

the sale stumpage).

Another recently developed model was used to predict initial

entry road construction costs and reconstruction costs for future

management entries. Jackson and Loveless (1981) have generated a

multiple regression equation based on 52 road construction and re­

construction contracts let by the Forest Service Northern Region

during fiscal years 1979 and 1980. This equation is adjusted for

inflation and is as accurate as .an Engineer's Cost Estimate while

Page 38: Economic analysis of proposed Forest Service timber sales

30

being relatively simple to apply. The construction costs predicted

by this equation were adjusted downward to allow for Bacon-Davis

wage rates and a recent trend indicating reduced road construction

bids in the Northern Region (See Appendix B).

Other costs were taken from documentation of the FORPLAN analysis

prepared for the Flathead Forest Plan (USDA, 1981a). These costs are

based on 1980 experienced costs and are adjusted for inflation. These

costs have also been presented in a manner which allows adjustment

for many site-specific factors such as unit size, percent slope,

habitat type, harvest and yarding methods, etc. (see Appendices C - E).

Two other assumptions made here are that the road system pro­

posed for the Ketchikan Sale will not be extended to access additional

stands and that timber mangement will be limited to the units included

in the current proposal. These limits were imposed as wildlife

habitat mitigation, and it is assumed that this mitigation will con­

tinue through the planning period. Detailed documentation of assump­

tions, methods and mathematical operations appear in the appendices.

Results

The above methods and assumptions were applied to two potential

outcomes of the Ketchikan Sale; Case 1 and Case 2. These examples

were employed in order to reflect the predictive nature of the cost

and benefit valuation methodology used. An examination of the ap­

pendices shows that great effort was made to make the valuation metho­

dology as detailed and specific as possible with respect to the con­

ditions which would be experienced for the Ketchikan Sale area.

These values are based on actually experienced values for recent

Page 39: Economic analysis of proposed Forest Service timber sales

31

sales in the same vicinity. However, at some point such valuation

must be based on some sort of average. For instance, the regression

equation used to predict stumpage value (Appendix A) is much more

responsive to sale-specific factors (i.e. current lumber price,

contract length, logging method, haul distance, volume per acre, and

tree diameter) than is the method used in the Flathead National

Forest's EAR (an average of predicted logging and road costs plus

statistical high bid for several timber sales on the same ranger

district, less predicted logging and road costs for the Ketchikan

Sale). While no statistical analysis is available for the reliability

of the latter method, the regression equation has an of .806 and

confidence intervals of approximately ± 30% at the 95% confidence

level.^

Case 1 assumes that the sale will sell for the advertised rates

and that the roads will be constructed using the contributed funds and

purchaser credit offered in the current sale package. This represents

the minimum bid for which the sale could be sold, and avoids reliance

on estimates derived from the regression equations for initial sale

1 Although this 30% confidence interval is rather wide, the

equation is superior to the residual price appraisal method. The regression equation is more responsive to sale-specific conditions; has the ability to incorporate expected changes in lumoer milling efficiency, logging costs, and lumber values; and is easier to apply to future sales. In addition, the equation would appear to be much more accurate than a method which has been underestimating bids on the Flathead National Forest by six to eight times. This study used mean values — not statistical ranges — for the various value data because mean values represent the best available estimates, avoid excess calculations and confusion, and because statistical analyses are not available for most of the data.

Page 40: Economic analysis of proposed Forest Service timber sales

stumpage value and road costs. Case 2 assumes that the sale will

sell for the bid predicted by the transaction evidence models for

stumpage value and road costs. This assumption predicts the selling

bid under conditions experienced on the Flathead during the period

1974 to 1980 and may tend to overestimate the selling bid for the

Ketchikan Sale, given the unusually large proportion of deal volume

in the sale and the currently stagnated timber market. Thus, these

two cases present a range into which the actual bid could have fallen

(probably nearer to Case 2).

Both cases are based on the most recent modifications pro­

posed for the sale (Armstrong, 1982b). The computation of discounted

present values is shown in Appendix F. The results given below are

in fourth quarter 1981 dollars.

Case 1

4%

Discounted Total Benefits

Discounted Total Costs

Present Net Value

Benefit/Cost Ratio

490,868

1 ,075,388

-584,520

0.4565

7 1 /8%

181,384

885,288

-703,905

0.2049

10%

115,252

808,100

-692,848

0.1426

Case 2

4%

Discounted Total Benefits

Discounted Total Costs

Present Net Value

Benefit/Cost Ratio

1 , 122 ,218

1,279,006

-154,074

0.8774

7 1 /8%

773,438

1,085,476

-312,038

0.7125

10%

637,832

1,005,300

-330,822

0.6709

Discussion

This study indicates that timber management economics cannot

Page 41: Economic analysis of proposed Forest Service timber sales

33

be used to justified the Ketchikan Sale. Except for road construction

costs, all costs and benefits were estimated using the same methods

and values that the Flathead National Forest is using in the develop­

ment of its forest plan. These cost and benefit values were applied

to all timber management activities and harvest yields projected by

the district silviculturalist for the next 100 years. The results

show that the Ketchikan Sale would have a net present value of

"$154,000 to "$704,000, and a benefit/cost ratio ranging from 0.88 to

0.14. In terms of timber management economics, the proposed Ketchikan

Salvage Sale would be a greater loss than would a no-harvest policy

allowing the timber to de'cay and regenerate naturally.

Since the road system is to be closed except during timber

management activity, the only other benefits which could possible

be claimed for the Ketchikan Sale proposal are insect and fire damage

reduction. Both are primarily associated with the timber resource.

As shown earlier, the Forest Service's own experts agree that mountain

pine beetle control or salvage should be justified by timber management

economics.

While fire mangement costs were included here (they are direct

costs of timber management on Forest Service land), fire hazard re­

duction benefits were omitted due to time and data constraints.

However, the methodology is available to estimate the benefits and

costs associated with events, such as fire, which involve uncertainty

and risk (Halvorsen and Ruby, 1981; Hirshleifer- and Riley, 1 9 7 9 ) .

The Forest Service Rocky Mountain Region has developed a methodology

specifically for evaluating benefits and costs associated with mountain

pine beetle control, including fire' management (Averill et at., 1 9 7 7 ) .

Page 42: Economic analysis of proposed Forest Service timber sales

An analysis of fire management benefits attributable to the

Ketchikan Sale proposal would entail determining the value and

probability of suppression costs and resource losses, both with and

without the sale. This would include modeling of fuel types, rates

of spread, size at control, suppression costs and resource damage

under both the with and without assumptions. Probability of fire,

derived from local fire statistics, could then be used to estimate

monetary values under each condition, and risk analysis could be

applied to evaluate the either/or decision in terms of fire manage­

ment.^ If fire management is to be claimed as a benefit for a timber

sale, such an analysis should be made.

While the omitted benefits, if any,-are related to fire manage­

ment, the costs of the Ketchikan Sale proposal which have been omitted

here include wildlife habitat destruction (especially critical threat­

ened and endangered species habitat), watershed and fisheries damage,

and aesthetic disruption near a national park and a national wild and

scenic river. A rational decision based on economics for the Ketchikan

Sale would weigh the timber management present net loss of $154,000 to

$704,000 plus unquantified wildlife habitat, watershed and aesthetic

damage against unquantified fire suppression benefits.

If economic efficiency were required in Forest Service timber

1 A computer model which may be capable of this sort of analysis

is being developed by the U.S. Forest Service's Pacific Southwest Station. Called the "Fire Economics Evaluation System," a prototype is planned to be tested in the Rocky Mountain-Intermountain Climate Zone by 1985. See Marcia Wood, "Is your fire management program 'economically efficient'?" Forestry Research West. Sept., 1982, pp. 5-9. USDA Forest Service, Ft. Collins, Colorado.

Page 43: Economic analysis of proposed Forest Service timber sales

management, the minimum acceptable (or marginal) bid for the Ketchikan

Sale would be that which would give the sale a net present value of

zero. For example, to offset the net present loss shown above for

Case 2, the present value of the predicted bid for the initial sale

would have to increase by $312,038 (under the 7 1/8% discount rate).

This would require a stumpage price of $91.69 per m.b.f., which is

$29.72 (48%) more than the bid predicted by the Flathead stumpage

1 valuation model and $90.04 more than the advertised rate. In other

words, had the Ketchikan Sale been reoffered, the Forest Service would

have accepted a bid as low as $1.65 per m.b.f., even though timber

management costs would not be covered unless the bid was at least

$91.69 per m.b.f.

Even using the upper confidence interval at the 95% confidence

level for the stumpage valuation equation, the predicted bid would be

$61.08 per m.b.f., still $30.61 short of covering timber management

costs. Only under the 4% discount rate could the 30% confidence

interval for the equation possibly give the timber management economics

of the Ketchikan Sale a positive present net value. Correctly stated,

at the 95% confidence level, assuming a 4% discount rate, the expected

net present value for Case 2 would range from +$80,171 to -$388,319,

with an expected mean of "$154,074. The associated benefit/cost ratio

would range from 1.06 to 0.69, with a mean of 0.88. For reasons

discussed above, the slightly positive outcome at the upper limit of

Vrom Appendix A, the predicted bid was $45.66 (first quarter 1978) which converts to $61.97 fourth quarter 1981 using the factor 199.58 T 147.05.

Page 44: Economic analysis of proposed Forest Service timber sales

this confidence interval is considered improbable.

Page 45: Economic analysis of proposed Forest Service timber sales

37

CONCLUSIONS

Economic analysis cannot and should not be the sole criterion

in Forest Service land management decisions, but the use of economics

in decision-making can and should be improved. In the Ketchikan

case, a proper application of economic analysis to timber management

clearly shows that timber management economics do not support the sale.

Other criteria which must be considered include damage to critical

wildlife habitat, watershed, fisheries and aesthetic resources in a

relatively pristine area of national significance which is facing

intense developmental pressures on many fronts.

These negative impacts must be weighed against the unevaluated

fire management situation. If fire hazard is a problem which must

be addressed, a fire management economic analysis should be made,

not only of the proposed timber sale, but also of alternatives which

deal directly with the fire hazard problem, including a no-action

alternative. In cases such as the Ketchikan Sale where the main re­

source threatened by fire (timber) has a negative present value, a

no-action policy for fire hazard reduction may be justified. An

analysis of risk and uncertainty should be conducted, especially in

a case such as this, where a proposed action would have certain

negative impacts on many resources while the action would only pos­

sibly reduce impacts from uncertain future events.

Page 46: Economic analysis of proposed Forest Service timber sales

38

At least on the Flathead National Forest, the forest planning

process has developed methodology and values which can be used for

vastly improved timber management benefit/cost analyses. Timber

management costs have been identified and sale specific stumpage

values can now be predicted. This information should be applied to

the economic analyses of future timber sales. The current residual

pricing method employed by the Forest Service should be replaced by

more appropriate methods. For instance, the long term timber manage­

ment costs for the sale area could be estimated to set a marginal

price. The stumpage valuation model could then be used to predict

the price that the timber industry would be willing to pay. Proposed

sales with a predicted selling value falling below the marginal price

could be eleminated from further consideration (thereby preventing

the waste of time and money for both the Forest Service and groups

opposing controversial sales). Proposed sales with predicted selling

values exceeding the marginal price could then be examined to compare

timber management benefits with unquantifiable costs to other re­

sources.

Timber management on national forest lands is primarily a

commodity production activity. Although the Forest Service is con­

strained by multiple-use resource considerations where a private

timberland owner would be more or less free to manage soley for

maximum timber production profits, there is no reason why Forest

Service timber management should not be economically efficient.

This is not to say that all Forest Service management ac­

tivities should be rigidly constrained by quantified economic analy­

ses. Many national forest resources are non-commodity in nature

Page 47: Economic analysis of proposed Forest Service timber sales

39

(e.g., wildlife, watershed) and are difficult, it not impossible,

to quantify. Where commodity production such as timber management

has quantifiable value and conflicts with noncommodity resources

such as endangered species habitat, subjective decisions must be made,

because such things as wildlife habitat and extinction cannot be

objectively quantified in economic terms. Commodity production can be

rendered to objective economic analysis, and when such an analysis

indicates that the commodity has a negative value, a rational decision

would forgo commodity production.

There may be cases where timber cutting could support noncom­

modity resource, multiple-use goals (e.g. production of brush for big

game browse might be increased by cutting some trees to open up a

dense forest canopy, allowing more light to reach the forest floor).

Unfortunately, multiple-use rhetoric is often used after controversy

arises to justify timber sales originally planned to meet timber pro­

duction goals. An example is the proposed Canyon Creek Sale on the

Bitterroot National Forest. Part of that sale calls for clearcuts

which are objected to by many area citizens. After the Forest's own

economist had determined that if the clearcuts were removed, the

sale would have positive, rather than the current negative timber

management economics, the Forest Supervisor and Regional Forester

both argued that the clearcuts were necessary to enhance nontimber

resources.

Although public pressure and the current economic situa:tion

finally convinced the Supervisor of the Flathead National Forest

to withdraw the Ketchikan Sale, had a willing buyer appeared last

fall,..the Forest Service would have let the sale at a significant

Page 48: Economic analysis of proposed Forest Service timber sales

40

economic loss.

Sales such as Ketchikan and Canyon Creek are not isolated events.

A study released by the Natural Resources Defense Council in 1980

(Barlow et al) shows that even under conservative assumptions, a great

deal of Forest Service timber is managed at a loss and that a signifi­

cant number of national forests operate their timber management func­

tion at a net loss. Part of the problem is the result of the residual

pricing method currently used to set Forest Service stumpage prices.

Instead of setting the price at a level which would return timber

management costs, the residual pricing method attempts to determine

what a purchaser would be able to pay, net of all estimated production

costs. This method is clearly inaccurate and incapable of insuring

economic efficiency in timber management. In addition to economic

inefficiency, Barlow, et al., argue that this residual pricing method

leads to reduced timber production on the nation's most productive

lands — the small, privately owned timberlands. Since the Forest

Service is the largest single producer of timber in the U.S., the

Forest Service practice of selling timber below production costs

maintains an artificially low market price for stumpage and creates

disincentives for private production.

Beyond the pricing problem there appears to be great potential

for future conflicts between noncommodity resources and economic

efficiency in timber management on one side, and deficit salvage

sales such as Ketchikan on the other. Great pressure is being put

on Forest Service line officers to meet timber production quotas.

These quotas are set by largely political decisions made at the

Washington D.C. level and are passed down the line.

Page 49: Economic analysis of proposed Forest Service timber sales

41

Although the National Forest Management Act limits timber pro­

duction on national forests to land which is biologically, physically,

technologically and economically capable of producing timber, the

definitions of these limits are the subjects of debate and manipula­

tion. For instance, the regulations implementing the NFMA define the

economic limit as cost effectiveness in meeting assigned goals, while

some authorities argue that the NFMA calls for economic efficiency

In timber management (Krutilla and Haigh, 1978; Stoel, 1978). Re­

gional Plans are maintaining the antiquated definition of commercial

forest land as any site capable of producing 20 cubic feet/acre/year,

even though many respondents to the plans argue that the appropriate

definition is closer to 50 or even 100 cubic feet/acre/year.

The Northern Region Plan states flatly that the region will

be unable to meet its assigned timber production goals unless capital

funds are used to access roadless areas at a greatly accelerated

pace — meaning that timber must be cut in areas where road costs

exceed timber values — and salvage sales are offered in larger

numbers (USDA 1981c, pp. 44-22 & 44-23). Salvage sales are excepted

from important restrictions placed on timber management activity by

the NFMA regarding size of opening, prohibition of timber harvest

on "marginal lands," prohibition of timber harvest before culmination

of mean annual increment, and prohibition of timber harvest above the

sustained yield-allowable cut level. These restrictions were created

to regulate timber cutting on national forest land, largely for the

protection of nontimber resources which are adversely impacted by

extensive cutting and elimination of old growth stands. Thus, use

of the salvage loophole in NFMA may lead to many future conflicts

Page 50: Economic analysis of proposed Forest Service timber sales

42

between timber management and other forest resources.

Those concerned with these potential future conflicts should

identify and deal with the political and policy decisions which force

the issue. Salvage sales should be justified either by positive

timber management economics in excess of negative impacts to other

resources, or by compelling management needs of other resources, not

by emotional appeals to prevention of waste or "good forestry" which

cannot be supported by rational analysis.

Page 51: Economic analysis of proposed Forest Service timber sales

43

Appendix A

STUMPAGE VALUE ESTIMATES

Stumpage. value is estimated here using methods developed by

Jackson and McQuillan (1979) and Merzenich (1979). In the spring

of 1981, Merzenich derived a multiple regression equation based on

data from 39 large timber sales sold on the Flathead National Forest

during the period July 1974 through January 1980. The equation uses

market variables and sale-specific site factors to estimate what the

logging industry would be willing to pay for the stumpage in a par­

ticular sale, assuming that environmental protection, road maintenance

and temporary development costs are zero. The equation gives this

stumpage value in first quarter 1980 dollars, has an adjusted of

.806, and has a standard error of $19.90 (15% of the mean predicted

high bid). Thus, at the 95% confidence level, the confidence interval

is ± $39.80 (30%). Merzenich's equation is being used in the economic

portion of FORPLAN by the Flathead National Forest in the development

of its Integrated Forest Plan (USDA, 1981a).

Initial Entry Stumpage Value

By substituting the mean value for the independent variable

dealing with ineffective purchaser credit (which is unknown for the

Ketchikan Sale), the Flathead equation can be simplified to the

Page 52: Economic analysis of proposed Forest Service timber sales

k k

form:

Y - "283.28 + 0.3814x^ + 0.563X2 - O.AgS^x^ - 0.660x^

+ 101.36x^ - 35.57Xg + 0.6037Xg - 0.4369Xg

where:

Y = high bid value/ra.b.f. (first quarter 1980 dollars)

x. = weighted average lumber price, log scale (first quarter 1980 dollars/m.b.f.

x^ = contract length in months

x^ = percent of sale volume jammer logged

x^ = percent of sale skyline logged

Xp = natural log of the weighted median d.b.h. t) Xg = a dummy variable for SBA sales

Xg = volume/acre harvested (m.b.f.)

Xg = total haul distance in miles

The stumpage value for the Ketchikan Sale is estimated using

the above equation and the following independent variable values.

Data sources, assumptions used, and derivation of each value are

also given below:

x^ = 247.82 The derivation of this value is shown below. The

species and percent net volumes are taken from the Sale

Prospectus. The lumber price, log scale, is taken from the

"West Side Zone Index Operation #6" in the most recent

update of lumber prices for Forest Service Region One 1

(Combes, 1982), except dead lodgepole and dead white pine.

The first lumber price, log scale, shown is in fourth

quarter 1981 dollars and is deflated to first quarter

1980 dollars using the GNP Implicit Price Deflator Indeces:

171.23 7 199.58 = .8580.

1 These prices for dead species are extrapolated from the live

prices using the lumber tally price and overrun factor for dead lodge-pole found at FSM SUPP. R-1 281 11 /81 2422.34—3 and using the 15% reduction in lumber tally price and 9.8% reduction in overrun for dead white pine found in the Appraisal Summary for the Ketchikan Sale.

Page 53: Economic analysis of proposed Forest Service timber sales

45

Species % net VolJ x L.P.L.S. x Deflation = Weighted L.P.L.S. (1981 $) Factor dst Qtr. 1980 $)

L-DF 1 ,100/12,200 350.86 .8580 27.14 S-0 590/12,200 343.09 .8580 14.24 SAF 240/12,000 261.65 .8580 4.42 LPL 1 ,340/12,200 317.22 .8580 29.89 LPD 8,900/12,000 273.40 .8580 171 .12 WPL 10/12,200 500.18 .8580 0.35 WPD 20/12,200 400.89 .8580 0.56

247.72

^2 = 26.5 (from the Sale Prospectus) The unusual operating

season limits prescribed by the contract could add risks

(costs) not measured by this' equation.

x^ = 3.1 (from the Contract Volume Summary, 361,308711,665,804)

x^ = 0 (from the Contract Volume Summary)

x_ = 2.485 Average d.b.h. by species from the sawlog Appraisal 5

Table (Sale Cruise Computer printout dated 4/30/81 with

correction of dead lodgepole volume dated 7/10/81) was

converted to median d.b.h. by adding the difference between

average d.b.h. and median d.b.h. for each species computed

for sales over 1 m.m.b.f. on the Flathead from 7/74 to

5/81 (printout dated 11/5/81 on file in the Regional

Office). The resulting median d.b.h. was weighted by

% net volume of the total sale by species as corrected

in the Sawlog Appraisal Table. This weighted median d.b.h.

was found to be 12, the natural log of which is 2.485.

x, = 0 The sale was not offered as a Small Business Set-Aside. o Xq = 13 (from the Sale Prospectus) o x = 56 (from the Appraisal Summary)

Substituting these values for the independent variables in the

above equation gives the following estimated bid:

1 This does not include 160 m.b.f. of unsound sapwood which has

no listed lumber price. Inclusion of the unsound sapwood would tend to reduce the weighted average lumber price for this sale.

Page 54: Economic analysis of proposed Forest Service timber sales

46

Y = -283.28 + 0.3814(24.72) + 0.563(26.5) - 0.4954(3.1) - 0.660(0) + 101.36(2.485) - 35.57(0) + 0.6037(13) - 0.4369(56) = 59.84

This is the predicted high bid value (first quarter 1980 dollars)

for the Ketchikan Sale assuming that environmental protection, road

maintenance and temporary development costs are zero. The current

Appraisal Summary estimates these costs to be $6.37, $4.07 and $1.20

1 per m.b.f. respectively. Subtracting these costs (deflated to first

quarter 1980 dollars), the predicted high bid becomes;

59.84 - (6.37 + 4.07 + 1.20)(.8580) = 49.85

In order to estimate the dollar benefits to accrue to the

Ketchikan Sale, the above stumpage value must be added to the slash

disposal deposits required in the sale contract. These deposits are

included as benefits because they will be used in part to defray the

2 site preparation and fuel treatment costs considered later. The

current sale package requires slash disposal deposits of $4.04 per

m.b.f. for live timber and $3.80 per m.b.f. for dead lodgepole and

dead white pine (second quarter 1981 dollars). Weighting these values

for the sale volume and deflating to first quarter 1980 dollars gives

the following deposit value;

4.04(3280 f 12,200) + 3.80(8920 T 12,200)(.8580) = 3.32

Adding this deposit value to the above bid value gives a total benefit

for the Ketchikan Sale of; 49.85 + 3.32 = 53.17 first quarter 1980

dollars per m.b.f. This value deflates to 45.66 first quarter 1978

^These cost values include required slash disposal and road maintenance deposits^

2 It is assumed here that road maintenance deposits will cover

road maintenance costs and, thus, cancel each other out.

Page 55: Economic analysis of proposed Forest Service timber sales

47

dollars [53.17(147.05 7 171.23)].

Table A-1 shows total benefits, by year, expected for the

Ketchikan Sale. An assumption that 20% of the sale volume will be

harvested in the first year and 40% in each of the two following

years was made in the economic analysis prepared by the Forest Service

for the sale EAR. The same assumption is made here. Benefits are

attributed to the end of the fiscal year in which they accrue and thus

the dates listed below are one year later than actual harvest.

TABLE A-1

INITIAL ENTRY BENEFITS

(1st quarter 1978 dollars)

Volume Stumpage Value Total Benefit Year (m.b.f.) x ($/m.b.f.) = [$_)

1983 2,440 45.66 111,410 1984 4,880 45.66 222,821 1985 4,880 45.66 222,821

Re-entry Stumpage Values

Stumpage values for future harvests will be predicted following

the method used by Merzenich (1979). In order to allow for real in-

1 creases in lumber price, overrun factor and production costs, and to

maintain the inherent relationships of the stumpage valuation equation,

future harvest stumpage value must first be calculated using current

lumber prices, and then adjusted for projected increases in lumber

price and production cost. Once the current stumpage value is known,

current production costs can be derived using the formula:

PC = LP - SV; or SV - (LP - PC)

1 Overrun, or recoyery factor, is a measure of milling efficiency.

Page 56: Economic analysis of proposed Forest Service timber sales

48

where:

PC = production cost/m.b.f., log scale

LP = lumber price/m.b.f., log scale

SV = stumpage value/m.b.f., log scale

This formula can also be used to convert current stumpage

value (SVQ) to projected future stumpage value for year n. If pro­

jected multiplicative increases for lumber price and production

costs are known for the period 0-n, then projected future stumpage

value can be claculated using the following relationships;

PC^ = PCQ X b^ ̂ (b = production cost multiplicative factor)

LP^ = LPQ X a^ ̂ (a = lumber price multiplicative factor)

Such multiplicative factors, based on projected increases in

overrun, lumber price and production costs have been developed for the

Flathead FORPLAN analysis, using a study by Adams and Haynes (1979).

The projections model increases in all three factors from 1980 to

2040, in ten year increments. The Adams and Haynes study indicates

that each factor will reach its potential limit for increase by 2043.

The appropriate projection is used below in calculation of future

stumpage values.

The same equation used above to predict initial entry stumpage

value will be used to estimate current stumoage values for future

entries; however, the equation must be further simplified. Since

the contract length and SBA variable for future sales are unknown,

the forest mean for the Flathead equation is used for independent

variables x^ and x^. It is assumed that there will be no skyline

logging in future sales, so independent variable x^ drops out. It

is also assumed that the haul distance will remain 56 miles, so this

value is used for variable Xg, which becomes part of the constant.

Page 57: Economic analysis of proposed Forest Service timber sales

^9

The simplified equation thus becomes:

Y = -288.60 + 0.38UX, - 0.'4954x_ + 101 .36x^ + 0.6037x„ 13 5 8

Therefore, the unknowns which remain to be found for each future

harvest re-entry are; current lumber price, percent volume jammer

logged, median d.b.h., and volume per acre. To determine the

appropriate lumber price, each harvest volume must be weighted by

percent of each species having a different lumber price. First, the

future harvest schedule must be determined.

Table A-2 shows the acreage and harvest activity by year for

each unit in the Ketchikan Sale area, as projected by the Silvicul-

turalist's Diagnonsis and Prescription (Wilson, 1981). The units

are grouped according to the road segment by which they are accessed.

Units to be jammer logged are denoted by the letter (J).

Page 58: Economic analysis of proposed Forest Service timber sales

TABLE A-2 Scheduled Harvest Activity

50

Rd #1046-1 Unit

1

2 3 4 5 6 7 8

20 21

Acres 3 6

1 1

5 22

2 26 11 25 48

2002 CC CC CC

OR OR OR OR

OR

2012 2042

CT CT CT CT CT CT CT

2052 2062 CT CT CT CT CT CT CT CT CT CT

2082

ST ST ST ST ST ST ST

Rd #1046-2 11 (J) 12 12* 13 14 15 16 17(J) 18{J) 19 22 23 24(J)

12 17 13 15 12 47

116 6

10 93 37 13 7

CC CC OR

CC

CT CT

CT CT

CT

CT

CT CT

CT CT

CT CT

CT CT CT CT

CT CT

CC CC CC CT CT ST CC CC CC CC CT CC CT

9 10

68 77

OR Pd #1047

CT CT

CT CT

ST CC

34(J) 35 36 37 38

1

5 26 40 43

SW OR

OR

Rd #1048-1 "Tm

CT

CT CT

CT

CT CT

CT CT

CT ST CC ST CC

30 21 31 14 32(J) 5 33 18

Total Acres

SW SW SW 391

Rd #1048-2

OR OR OR 38 657

CT

96

CT CT CT 779

CC CT CT CT

855

CT NOTE; CC = clear cut; OR = overstory removal; SW = shelterwood; commercial thin; ST = seed tree.

*Unit 12 is divided into two seperate portions receiving different management regimens by the Silviculturalist's Diagnosis and Prescription.

Page 59: Economic analysis of proposed Forest Service timber sales

51

Projected volume, species composition, and d.b.h. for each unit

are given by year in Table A-3. Each factor in Table A-3 was derived

using the following assumptions:

Volume; The Silviculturalit's Prescription gives an expected

yield per acre for each unit, except units 1-3, 13, 14, 22,

31-34. The volume values in Table A-3 are the product of the

yield per acre and unit acreage for units projected in the Sil-

viculturalist's Prescription. Volumes for the remaining units

were calculated with the most appropriate yield tables prepared

for the Flathead's FORPLAN analysis (USDA, 1981a).^

Species Composition; The Silviculturalist's prescription calls

for planting of larch and Douglas fir and expects natural lodge-

pole regeneration. The silviculturalist expects to attain a

1:1;1 ratio of these species, and emphasis on removal of the

lodgepole on the final commercial thin (Wilson, 1982). It is

assumed here that units receiving one commercial thin will have

at harvest a species composition of 50% lodgepole for the com­

mercial thin and 25% lodgepole for the regeneration harvest,

while units receiving two commercial thins will have compositions

of 50% lodgepole for the first thinning, 75% lodgepole on the

second thinning, and 100% larch-Douglas fir on the regeneration

harvest. For units receiving their first regeneration harvest

1 The first regeneration harvest used Existing Yield Table 56 for

units 1-3 and Existing Yield Table 35 for units 13,14 and 22. Sub­sequent thinning and regeneration harvests used Regenerated Yield Table 5 for units 1-3 and Regenerated Yield Table 7 for units 13, 14, 22, 31-34. The yields in these tables are in cubic feet and were converted to board feet using conversion factors in the Flathead FORPLAN data base.

Page 60: Economic analysis of proposed Forest Service timber sales

during the second (rather than initial) entry, the species

composition is projected from the stand composition and removal

pattern outlined in the Silviculturalist's Diagnosis and Pre­

scription. Harvest volumes for years 2002, 2012 and 2082 are

100% larch-Douglas fir, years 2042 and 2052 are 59% lodgepole,

and year 2062 is 75% lodgepole, except as footnoted.^

d.b.h.; Expected d.b.h. for each unit was projected using the

yield tables in the Flathead FORPLAN Economics Coefficient

Documentation (USDA 1981a). The appropriate yield table was

selected on the basis of productivity (by Habitat Type Group)

and management intensity shown for each unit in the Silvicul­

turalist's Diagnosis and Prescription.

1 EYT 35 was used for all first regeneration cuts and overstory

removals except units 1-3, which used EYT 56. RYT 7 was used for the remaining harvests, except; units 12 (second part), 17, 23 and 36-RYT 4; units 18, 24 and 30-RYT 5; unit 38-RYT 8.

Page 61: Economic analysis of proposed Forest Service timber sales

uni

1

2 3 A 5 6 7 8 9

10 1 1 12 12 13 U 15 16 17 1 8

19 20 21 22 23

TABLE A-3

Projected Volume, Species Composition and d.b.h. for Future Harvests, by Unit

2002 (100% L-DF) rabf

2012 (100% L-DF)

20A2 (50% LP)

2052 •(50% LP)

2062 (75% LP)

2082 (100% L-DF)

dbh mbf dbh mbf dbh mbf dbh mbf dbh mbf dbh

11 .1 8.06^ 9.5 11 .1 - - - — - 16.12 9.5 - -

11 .1 - - - - - 29.55^ 9.5 - -

- - 22.43 10.7 - - 23.06 13.3 110.92 15.6 12.2 - 98.67 10.7 - - 101.44 13.3 488.05 15.6 12.2 - 8.97 10.7 - - 9.22 13.3 44.37 15.6 12.2 - 116.61 10.7 - - 119.89 13.3 567.78 15.6 12.2 - 49.34 10.7 - - 50.72 13.3 244.02 15.6 12.2 - 304.98 10.7 - - 313.55 13.3 1 ,508.51 15.6 - - 345.35 10.7 - - 355.05 13.3 1 ,708.17 15.6 - - 53.82 10.7 - - 55.33 13.3 266.21 15.6 - - 76.25 10.7 - - 78.39 13.3 377.13 15.6 - - - - - 65.03 12.0 - - 312.94 15.6

12.2 - - - - - 55.49^ 10.7 76.42® 13.3 12.2 - - - - - 44.39 10.7 61 .13 13.3 12.2 - 210.80 10.7 - - 216.72 13.3 1 ,042.65 15.6 - - 520.26 10.7 - - 534.88 13.3 2 ,573.34 15.6 — — — — — 30.01

50.02 12.0 10.6

— — 144.43" 240.72

15.6 13.8

- - 417.11 10.7 - - 428.82 13.3 2 ,063.11 15.6 - - 112.12 10.7 - - 115.23 13.3 554.60 15.6

12.2 - 215.28 10.7 - - 221.33 13.3 1 ,064.83 15.6 12.2 - - - - - 136.88 10.7 188.49^ 13.3 - - - - 65.03 10.6 - - 312.94 15.6

21 .99 43.35 61 .04

118.80 9.20

119.89 59.40 312.80

151 .67: 119.50 216.20

259.20 280.59

U)

Page 62: Economic analysis of proposed Forest Service timber sales

TABLE A-3 Continued

2002 2012 2042 2052 2062 2082

(100% L-DF) (100% L-DF) (50% LP) (50% LP) (75% LP) (100% L--DF)

unit mbf dbh mbf dbh mbf dbh mbf dbh mbf dbh mbf dbh

2k 35.01 10.6 _ 168.50^ 13.8

30 _ — — - - 105.04 10.6 p - 505.51g 13.8

31 96.60 15.7 100.80 16.0 - - - - 51.79^ 10.7 71.32 13.3

32 42.00 15.7 21 .00 16.0 - - - - 18.50^ 10.7 25.47g 13.3

33 124.20 15.7 129.60 16.0 - - - - 66.59^ 10.7 91.70^ 13.3

34 12.20 15.7 5.30 16.0 - - - - 3.70 10.7 5.09 13.3

35 27.00 15.T - - 22.43 10.7 - - 23.06 13.3 110.92 , 15.6

36 _ — — - - 130.05 12.0 - - 625.87 15.6

37 224.00 15.7 — — 179.40 10.7 - - 184.44 13.3 887.36 15.6

38 - — - - 192.86 9.5 - - 198.27 11.8 953.91 13.8

NOTE: L-DF = larch & Douglas fir, LP = lodgepole pine

50% spruce/other

*^35% spruce/other

So% LP

^25% LP

®75% LP

Unit 12 is divided into two seperate portions receiving different management regimens by the Sil-

vlculturallst's Diagnosis and Prescription.

Page 63: Economic analysis of proposed Forest Service timber sales

55

Table A-4 uses data from Table A-3 to show total volume by

species for each future harvest. The volumes are rounded to the

nearest ten thousand board feet.

TABLE A-4

Future Harvest Volume by Species (m.b.f.)

Species 2002 2012 2042 2052 2062 2082

L-DF 2,170 260 1 ,470 245 930 16,060 LP 0 0 1 ,470 245 2,540 1 ,340 S-0 120 0 0 0 0 0

Total 2,290 260 2,940 490 3,470 17,400

Now that future harvest volumes by species are known, current

weighted lumber prices may be calculated for each harvest. This is

shown in Table A-5 using species and volume data from Table A-4, and

lumber prices from the 1/29/82 letter to FSM 2420 {Combes, 1982).

The values for lumber price, log scale, appearing in the last two

columns of Table A-5 have been deflated to first quarter 1980 dollars

using the GNP Implicit Price indices 171.23 4- 199.58, and to first

quarter 1978 dollars with the indices 147.05 t 199.58. Lumber price,

log scale, must be in 1980 dollars for use in the stumpage valuation

equation, while the present discounted value analysis in Appendix F

uses 1978 dollars.

Page 64: Economic analysis of proposed Forest Service timber sales

56

TABLE A-5

Weighted Lumber Prices for Future Harvests

Species % Volume

2002

LP, l.s. 1981$

LP, l.s. 1980$

LP, l.s. 1978$

L-DF S-0

95 5

Total Weighted Value/m.b.f.

301 .1 4 294.47

245.45 12.63

258.08 221.64

L-DF 100

2012

301 .14 258.36 221.88

L-DF LP

50 50

Total Weighted Value/m.b.f.

2042

301 .14 272.27

129.18 116.80

245.98 211 .24

L-DF LP

50 50

Total Weighted Value/m.b.f.

2052

301 .14 272.27

129.18 116.80

245.98 211.24

L-DF LP

27 73

Total Weighted Value/m.b.f.

2062

301 .14 272.27

69.76 170.52

240.28 206.35

L-DF LP

92 8

2082

301 .14 272.27

237.69 18.69

Total Weighted Value/m.b.f. 256.38 220.18

At last, all the necessary information is available to allow

computation of current stumpage values for future harvests. Table A-6

shows variable values and results of this computation, using the

simplified valuation equation derived earlier:

Y = -288.60 + 0.3814X, - 0.4954x^ + 101.36x^ + 0.6037x„ 1 J D O

Page 65: Economic analysis of proposed Forest Service timber sales

57

The values for the independent variables shown inTable A-6 are taken

from the following sources:

= weighted lumber price, log scale (first quarter 1980

dollars) from Table A-5

x^ = % volume jammer logged from Table A-2 (units jammer logged),

Table A-3 (volume for each jammer unit) divided by total

harvested volume (Table A-4)

x^ = natural log of weighted d.b.h. from data in Table A-3 D

x_ = volume per acre harvested (m.b.f.) from Table A-A (total o

volume) divided by total acres harvested in Table A-2

Y (first quarter 1980 dollars) is converted in the final column to

stumpage value in first quarter 19T8 dollars with the GNP Implicit

Price indices; 147.05 t 171.23.

TABLE A-6

Derivation of Current Stumpage Value for Future Harvests

Y SV (1st qtr (1st qtr

Year x^ x^ x^ x^ 1980$) 1978$)

2002 258.08 2.2 2.565 5.9 72.29 62.08 2012 258.36 11 .5 2.773 6.8 89.42 76.79 2042 245.98 1 .7 2.398 4.5 52.24 45.12 2052 245.98 24.5 2.398 5.1 39.22 33.68 2062 240.28 2.3 2.565 4.5 64.61 55.49 2082 256.38 4.9 2.708 20.4 93.55 80.34

The current stumpage values derived for each harvest in Table

A-6 can now be converted to future stumpage values incorporating the

projected increases in lumber price, production costs and overrun.

This is done below for each future harvest using the relationships

mentioned earlier:

Page 66: Economic analysis of proposed Forest Service timber sales

58

^ ̂ 0-n LP = LP- X b„ n 0 0-n

SV = LP - PC n n n

Combining these equations gives the equation used in Table A-7:

SV = (LP^ X a) - [(LP_ - SV^) X b ] n o 0 0

Current weighted lumber price (LP^) is taken from Table A-5. Current

sturapage value (SV^) is found in Table A-6. Lumber price and pro­

duction cost multiplicative factors for each harvest are taken from

1 the Flathead FORPLAN Adams and Haynes projections.

Finally, the projected dollar benefits for each future harvest

can be calculated for each year by simply multiplying the future

stumpage values in Table A-7 by the total volumes in Table A-4.. The

results appear in Table A-8. Benefits are attributed to the end of

the fiscal year in which they accrue and thus the dates listed below

are one year later than the actual harvest.

1 Year 2002 uses projections for the period 1980-2010 (median

year 2005); year 2012 uses projections for the period 1980-2020 (median year 2015); the remaining harvests use projections for the period 1980-2040 and beyond (median year 2035) because this is the last projection period in the Flathead data and the Adams and Haynes projections predict no increases after 2043 (Merzenich, 1979).

Page 67: Economic analysis of proposed Forest Service timber sales

59

TABLE A-7

Projected Future Sturapage Values (1st quarter 1978 dollars)

Current Lum. Price Current Stump. Val. Harv. Lum. Price Mult. Fact. Stump. Val. Mult . Fact. Date (LPo) (a) (SVq) (b)

2002 221.64 1 .653 62.08 1 .509 2012 221.88 1.863 76.79 1 .547 2042 211.24 2.188 45.12 1 .595 2052 211.24 2.188 33.68 1 .595 2062 206.35 2.188 55.49 1 .595 2082 220.18 2.188 80.34 1 .595

Future Stump. Val.

(SB )

125.99 188.91 197.23 178.98 210.87 258.71

TABLE A-8

Re-entry Benefits (1st quarter 1978 dollars)

Volume Stumpage Value Total Benefit Year (m.b.f.) x ($/m.b.f.) = ($)

2003 2,290 125.99 288,517 2013 260 188.91 49,117 2043 2,940 197.23 579,856 2053 490 178.98 87,700 2063 3,470 210.87 731,719 2083 17,400 258.71 4,507,554

Page 68: Economic analysis of proposed Forest Service timber sales

60

Appendix B

ROAD COST ESTIMATES

Road costs will be incurred both during the initial road con­

struction for the Ketchikan Sale and during reconstruction for each

subsequent management entry. Since the roads in the sale area will

be closed during periods of inactivity ranging from 10 to 40 years,

road reconstruction costs will be significant. Road maintenance

costs during management activities are assumed to be covered by pur­

chaser deposits.

In addition to construction or reconstruction costs incurred

by contractors, road costs must also include those costs incurred by

the Forest Service for survey, design, layout and administration.

Road costs estimates for each road segment are developed in Tables

B-1 and B-2 with assumptions and data sources explained below.

Table B-3 displays total expected road costs by year (in first quarter

1978 dollars adjusted from Tables B-1 and B-2 with the GNP Implicit

Price Deflator Indices: (147.05 7 171.23) for the initial entry,

and for each re-entry scheduled by the silviculturalist's prescrip­

tions (Wilson, 1981), as shown in Table A-1 (Appendix A).

It will be assumed here that the road system planned for the

Ketchikan Sale will not be extended in the future to access additional

Page 69: Economic analysis of proposed Forest Service timber sales

61

timber stands. The original proposal presented in the EAR called

1 for 4.82 miles of additional road segments (Schluessler, 1981),

which were deleted in the EAR Supplement as mitigation for wildlife

habitat.

Discussions with the Forest highway engineer and District

timber staff officer involved in planning the Ketchikan Sale indicated

that, due to terrain and quality of timber stands, extensions of the

road system beyond what was originally planned in the EAR would

probably not be feasible (Schluessler, 1982a and Armstrong, 19821).

Since the potential extensions were deleted as wildlife habitat miti­

gation, it is assumed that this habitat will remain unroaded for the

duration of the planning horizon in this analysis.

Initial Road Construction

Road constuction costs for the Ketchikan Sale are predicted

here through the use of a recently developed multiple regression

equation (Jackson and Loveless, 1981). This equation was chosen over

the Engineer's Cost Estimate in the Sale Prospectus for several rea­

sons: 1 ) The equation is based on 52 road construction and recon­

struction contracts let by the Forest Service Region One during fiscal

years 1979 and 1980 (adjusted for inflation), and predicts the winning

bid in first quarter 1980 dollars, while the Engineer's Cost Estimate

is based on various component cost revisions ranging from December

1979 to July 1981, with no adjustment for inflation. The equation

''TWO roads extending north along the west side of Ketchikan Creek from road 10428, three roads extending north into the Colts Creek drainage from road 10426 and an extension of road 10426 to the southern end of Ketchikan Ridge. See map.

Page 70: Economic analysis of proposed Forest Service timber sales

62 is derived from actual transaction evidence rather than component

cost estimates and is as accurate as the Engineer's Cost Estimate

(Jackson, 1982). The equation has an adjusted of .8553 and a

standard deviation of 25.19% of theraean predicted bid, or a confidence

interval of ±50.38% at the 95% confidence level. There is no analysis

of the statistical reliability of the Engineer's Cost Estimate. (The

Engineer's Cost Estimate for the original Ketchikan sale was $569,912

and the comparable bid predicted by the regression equation [total Y

from Table B-1 ] is $591 ,329, a 3.7% difference). 2) The equation

predicts initial road construction costs using a relatively limited

set of standardized inputs, which for this analysis were taken from

the Schedule of Items in the Ketchikan Sale contract. 3) The equation

can be used to predict future reconstruction costs for each re-entry

from existing data, without resorting to the complex recalculations

which would by necessary if an Engineer's Cost Estimate were used.

The Jackson and Loveless equation can be expressed as:

Y = 1975.26(d) + 2534.76x, + 1.26x„ + .37x_ + 7.1Ax, + .12x^ 1 2 3 4 5

where ;•

Y = Total road construction cost in 1st quarter 1980 dollars (predicted winning bid)

d = Total length of road in miles

x^ = Total acres clearing and grubbing

x^ = Total cubic yards excavation

x^ = Total station yards haul

x^ = Total tons gravel

X = Sura of the products of squared diameter and length for each size class of culvert (B D^xL)

Page 71: Economic analysis of proposed Forest Service timber sales

63

Table B-1 shows the computation of total road cost for the Ket­

chikan Sale. Values for each variable in the above equation, taken

from the sale contract, are listed first. Given next are the products

of the variable values and the corresponding coefficient in the above

equation. Haul and gravel values are not shown because none were given

in the schedule of items. The predicted bid is then adjusted downward

to allow for Bacon-Davis wage rates^ and recent trends in. road con-

2 struction bidding (Adj. Y). Total road costs by road segment are de­

rived by adding these construction costs to Forest Service engineering

and administration costs, which were estimated in the development of

FORPLAN to be $6200 per mile (first quarter 1978 dollars) on the Flat­

head National Forest (USDA 1981a, p. E-5 9 of 11). This converts to

7220 first quarter 1980 dollars using the GNP Implicit Price Deflator

Indicies: 171.23 t 147.05. Completion dates come from the Prospectus.

1 Construction contracts let by the federal government must comply

with wage rates set by the Bacon-Davis Act, while purchasers building roads may use lower rates prevailing in the area. This is why the En­gineer's Cost Estimate (based on Bacon-Davis rates) is higher than the Purchaser Credit Limit (the estimated cost to a purchaser). The orig­inal Engineer's Cost Estimate $569,912 while the Purchaser Credit Limit was $555,833; 97.53% of the Engineer's Estimate. Since the Jackson and Loveless equation is based on contracts using Bacon-Davis rates, the predicted bid (Y) is reduced by the factor .9753.

2 Based on this trend in road construction bidding (analyzed by the Northern Region Office) the Purchaser Credit Limit for the Ketchi­kan Sale was reduced from the original $555,833 to $463,897; 83.46% of the original estimate (Armstrong, 1982b). Thus, the predicted bid (Y) is further reduced by the factor .8346 (giving a total reduction factor of .9753 X .8346 = .8140). One possible explanation for this downward trend is that the recessionary economy has created a shortage of con­struction projects, and thus a surplus of construction equipment. Faced with fixed capital costs, contractors may be lowering their bids below normal in an attempt to keep their equipment working, generating cash flows to service debts.

Page 72: Economic analysis of proposed Forest Service timber sales

TABLE B-1

Initial Entry Road Costs :ist quarter 1980 dollars)

Coefficient Rd #1046-1

value $ Rd #1046-2

value $ Rd #1047

value $

d (total miles) (acres clear and grub)

X (yards^ excavation) X (X[D^ X L] culverts) Y (Predicted Bid) Adj. Y (tot. const, cost [Y x .814] F.S. eng. & admin. ($7220/mi.)

TOTAL ROAD COST

.98 4.70 4706 24,960

.98

1,935.75 5.30 10,468.88 11,913.37 24.20 61,341.19 5,929.56 22,246 28,029-96 29,635.20 699,048 83,885.76 49,413.88 183,725.79 40,222.18 149,603.86 7,075.62 5.30 38,266.00 47,298 . 187,870

1.76 3,476.46 9.01 22,838,19 13,539 17,059.14 392,112 47,053.44

90,427.22 73,632.89

1 .76 12,707.20 86,340

Completion Date 1982 1983 1983

Rd #114 Rd #1048-1 Rd #1048-2 Coefficient value $ value $ value $

d (total miles) 3.51 6,933.16 1.88 3,713.49 1.36 2,686.35 x^ (acres clear and grub) 19.39 49,149.00 9.84 24,942.04 7.40 18,757.22 X2 (yards' excavation) 16,795 21,161.70 16,935 21,338.10 15,549 19,591.74 X5 (S[D' X L] culverts) 193,104 23,172.48 389,952 46,794.24 246,024 29,522.88 Y (Predicted Bid) 100,416.34 96,787.82 70,558.19 Adj. Y (tot. const, cost [Y x .814]) 81,766.81 78,812.19 57,453.98 F.S. eng. & admin. ($7220/mi.) 3.51 25,342.80 1.88 13,573.60 1.36 9,819.20

TOTAL ROAD COST 107,110 92,386 67,273

Completion Date 1982 1982 1983

Page 73: Economic analysis of proposed Forest Service timber sales

65

Future Road Reconstruction

After the initial entry, current plans are to close all area

roads for a 20 year period, followed by a re-entry for timber harvest

and management activities. Similar re-entries could occur thereafter

in periods ranging from 10 to 40 years (Wilson, 1981). The project

engineer expects reconstruction costs after 20 years of closure to be

essentially limited to clearing the road bed of vegetation and repair­

ing any damage to drainage structures. After a 40 year closure, it was

considered uncertain whether or not culverts would have to be replaced

(Turner, 1982). In order to use the Jackson and Loveless equation to

predict future reconstruction costs, it is assumed here that recon­

struction activity will be limited to clearing and grubbing an average

14 foot wide roadway during each entry, with replacement of all cul­

verts during the first entry made more than 60 years after the initial

entry. Forest Service engineering and administration costs for recon­

struction were estimated to be approximately half of the value used for

new roads in FORPLAN (Schluessler, 1982b).

Table B-2 shows expected road costs associated with future re­

entries, by road segment (both with and without culvert replacement).

Variable values (except x-| ) are taken form Table B-1 . Costs associated

with Road #114 are not shown in Table B-2 because it is a system road

which should receive normal maintenance, and therefore may not require

reconstruction attributable solely to timber management in the Ketchi­

kan area. Acreage cleared and grubbed is calculated by multiplying

average road width (14 feet) by road length in feet and dividing by

square feet per acre (43,560).

Page 74: Economic analysis of proposed Forest Service timber sales

TABLE B-2

Re-entry Road Costs (1st quarter 1980 dollars)

Rd #10A6-1 Rd #1046-2 Rd #1047 Coefficient value | value $ value $

d (total miles) .98 1,935.75 5.30 10,A68.88 1.76 3,713.49 (acres clear and grub) 1.66 4,207.70 8.99 22,787.49 2.99 7,578.49

F.S. eng. & adm. ($36l0/rai.) .98 3,537.80 5.30 19,133.00 1.76 6,353.60 RECONSTRUCTION WITHOUT CULVERTS 9,681.25 52,389.37 17,408.99

xc; (£[D' X L] culverts) 246,960 29,635.20 699,048 83,885.76 392,112 47,053.44 RECONSTRUCTION WITH CULVERTS 39,316.45 136,275.13 64,462.43

Coefficient Rd #1048-1

value $ Rd #1048-2

value $

d (total miles) x-| (acres clear and grub) F.S. eng. & adm. ($36l0/mi.)

RECONSTRUCTION WITHOUT CULVERTS

X5 ("[D^ X L] culverts) RECONSTRUCTION WITH CULVERTS

1 .88 3.19 1 .88

389,952

3,713.49 8,085.88 6,786.80 18,586.17

46,794.24 65,380.41

1 .36 2.31 1 .36

246,024

2,686.35 5,855.30 4,909.60 13,451.25

29,522.88 42,974.13

cr-o

Page 75: Economic analysis of proposed Forest Service timber sales

67

TABLE B-3

Total Road Costs (1st quarter 1978 dollars)

Rd. Rd. Rd. Rd. Rd. Rd. Total Year #1046-1 #1046-2 #1047 #114 #1048-1 #1048-2 Cost

1982 40,619 91,985 79,340 211,944 1983 — 161,340 74,148 — — 57,773 293,261 2002 8,314 44,991 14,951 — 15,962 11,552 95,770 2012 — — — — 15,962 11,552 27,514 2042 33,764 117,031 55,359 — 56,148 — 262,302 2052 — 44,991 — — 15,962 36,906 97,859 2062 8,314 44,991 14,951 — 15,962 11,552 95,770 2082 8,314 44,991 14,951 — 15,962 11,552 95,770

Page 76: Economic analysis of proposed Forest Service timber sales

68

Appendix C

SALE PREPARATION AND ADMINISTRATION

COST ESTIMATES

The Flathead FORPLAN Economic Coefficient Documentation (USDA,

1981a) is the source for sale preparation (p. E-1E 13) and adminis­

tration (p. E-1e 16) costs used here. The documentation arrays

estimated costs for these activities, on a per acre bases, according

to harvest method, unit size and yarding method projected for the

Ketchikan Sale area over the next 100 years. Table C-1 was constructed

using data from Table A-1, and appropriate costs from Appendix E in

the Flathead coefficient documentation.

Table C-2 estimates sale preparation costs for each harvest

and Table C-3 estimates sale administration costs for each harvest.

Both tables use the cost classes from Table C-1 and acreages from

Table A-1. (It should be noted that these costs are based on Forest-

wide averages applied to site-specific factors. Actual preparation

costs for the Ketchikan Sale may be much higher than average due to

the sale's highly controversial nature and extended appeals process,

which have not be representative of Forest-wide average timber sales.

The Forest Service could not give an estimate for the appeals costs

attributable to the Ketchikan Sale, but off-the-cuff estimates of

Region-wide average timber sale appeals costs ranged from $2,000 -

$5,000. It was generally agreed that the appeals costs for the Ket-

Page 77: Economic analysis of proposed Forest Service timber sales

chikan Sale were probably higher than average.)

69

TABLE C-1

Sale Preparation and Administration Cost Classes

(1st quarter 1978 dollars)

Cost Site Factors Cost($) Class Harv. Methodl Unit Size (acres) Yard. Method Prep. Admin

AIT CC-ST 0-2 Tractor 152 45 A2T CC-ST 3-10 Tractor 115 37 A2J CC-ST 3-10 Jammer 136 53 A3T CC-ST 11-20 Tractor 92 30 A3J CC-ST 11-20 Jammer 97 45 AAT CC-ST >20 Tractor 84 23 BIT SW-CT 0-2 Tractor 234 53 B1J SW-CT 0-2 Jammer 273 68 B2T SW-CT 3-10 Tractor 140 45 B2J SW-CT 3-10 Jammer 157 60 B3T SW-CT 11-20 Tractor 102 37 B3J SW-CT 11-20 Jammer 109 53 B4T SW-CT >20 Tractor 86 23 C1T OR 0-2 Tractor 152 53 C1J OR 0-2 Jammer 172 68 C2T OR 3-10 Tractor 115 45 C2J OR 3-10 Jammer 125 60 C3T OR 11-20 Tractor 95 37 C4T OR >20 Tractor 91 23

^CC.= clear cut; ST = seed tree; SW = cial thin; OR - overstory removal.

shelterwood; CT = commer-

Page 78: Economic analysis of proposed Forest Service timber sales

TABLE C-2

Sale Preparation Costs {1st quarter 1978 dollars)

1981 2001 2011 2041 2051 2061 2081

Cost $ $ Class $/acre ac $ ac $ ac $ ac $ ac $ ac $ ac $

AIT 152 2 304

A2T 115 5 575 9 1 ,035 — 10 1 ,150

A2J 136 21 2,856 — — — — — — — — — — 21 2,856

A3T 92 43 3,956 38 3,496 — 54 4,968 A3J 97 12 1 ,164 — — — — — — — — — — 12 1 ,164 AAT BA 401 33,684 22 1 ,848 — 652 54,768

BIT 234 2 468 2 468 — — 2 468 — —

B1J 273 1 273 1 273 — — — — — — 1 273 1 273 B2T 140 14 1 ,848 — — — — 10 1,400 — — 19 2,660 — —

B2J 157 5 785 5 785 — — — — 21 3,297 5 785 5 785 B3T 102 81 8,262 32 3,264 — — 28 2,856 26 2,652 98 9,996 59 6,081 B3J 109 12 1,308 — — 12 1 ,308 — —

B4T 86 288 24,768 505 43,430 47 4,042 542 46,612 37 3,182

C1T 152 — — 2 304 — — — — — — — — — —

C1J 172 1 172 C2T 115 — — 5 575 —

C2J 125 — 5 625 C3T 95 — — 11 1 ,045 32 3,040 C4T 91 — — 262 23,742

Total Cost 78,751 36,467 3,837 49,462 9,991 62,102 72,531

Page 79: Economic analysis of proposed Forest Service timber sales

TABLE C-3

Sale Administration Costs (1st quarter 1978 dollars)

1983* 2002 2012 2042 2052 2062 2082 Cost Class $/acre ac $ ac $ ac "$ ac $ a^ $ ac $ ac $

AIT 42 2 90 A2T 37 5 185 • 9 333 10 370 A2J 53 21 1,113 21 1,113 A3T 30 43 1 ,290 38 1 ,140 54 1 ,620 A3J 45 12 540 12 540 A4T 23 401 9,223 22 506 652 14,996 BIT 53 2 106 — — — — 2 106 — — 2 106 — —

B1J 68 1 68 1 68 — — — — — 1 68 1 68 B2T 45 14 630 — — — — 10 450 — — 19 855 — —

B2J 60 5 300 5 300 — — — — 21 1 ,260 5 300 5 300 B3T 37 81 2,997 32 1 ,184 — — 28 1,036 26 962 98 3,626 59 2,183 B3J 53 — — — — — — 12 636 — — 12 636 — —

B4T 23 288 6,624 505 11,615 47 1 ,081 542 12,466 37 851 C1T 53 — — 2 106 — — — — — — — — —

CU 68 1 68 C2T 45 — — 5 225 C2J 60 5 300 C3T 37 — — 11 407 32 1 ,184 C4T 23 — — 262 6 ,026 — — — — — — — — — —

TOTAL COST: 23,076 10 ,295 1 ,552 13,843 3 ,303 18,057 22,131

* 20% in 1982, 40% in 1983 and 40% in 1984.

Page 80: Economic analysis of proposed Forest Service timber sales

72

Appendix D

•SITE PREPARATION AND FUEL TREATMENT

COST ESTIMATES

Economic analyses of timber management often attempt to seperate

site preparation costs (those associated with regeneration) from fuel

treatment or slash disposal costs (those associated with fire hazard

reduction). The seperation can be difficult and subjective because

single activities often accomplish both objectives (e.g. broadcast

burning both prepares a site for planting and reduces the fuel load)

and funds collected or appropriated for one objective are often used

to accomplish the other (Merzenich, 1979). It is often argued that

such a seperation must be made, however, so that only regeneration

costs will be charged to timber management while slash disposal costs

are charged to fire management.

No such seperation is made in this analysis. Both fuel treat­

ment and site preparation costs are included here for the following

reasons. Both regeneration costs and slash disposal costs are

quantifiable and will be incurred as a direct result of timber manage­

ment activities. None of the costs used here would be incurred in

the absence of timber harvesting. While the benefits associated with

fuel treatment are not accounted here, in so far as they are quan­

tifiable they are predominately attributable to the timber resource.

It must be remembered that many costs associated with the Ketchikan

Sale have not been quantified and accounted for here. Furthermore,

Page 81: Economic analysis of proposed Forest Service timber sales

wildfire can also have minimal or even beneficial impacts on non-

commodity resource values such as wildlife habitat.

Site preparation and fuel treatment costs are taken from the

Flathead FORPLAN Economic Coefficient Documentation (USDA, 1981a).

These costs vary according to site factors such as unit size, harvest

method and percent slope. Table D-1 shows cost classes for projected

activities and site factors (as shown in Table A-2) in the Ketchikan

Sale area for the next 100 years. Percent slope is assumed to be

less than 40% for all units except those which are jammer logged.

It is assumed that all shelterwood or seedtree units will be dozer

piled (D4 tractor), except cost class 7, following the instructions

in the Silviculturalist's Diagnosis and Prescription (Wilson, 1981).

Zero costs are assumed for precommercial and commercial thins.

Expected total costs for site preparation and fuel treatment

are shown by year in Table D-2. Cost values are taken from Table D-1

while acres treated are derived from Table A-1, the Silviculturalist'

Diagnosis and Prescription (Wilson, 1981), and the current sale

package (Armstrong, 1982b).

Page 82: Economic analysis of proposed Forest Service timber sales

74

TABLE D-1

Site Preparation and Fuel Treatment Cost Classes (1st quarter 1978 dollars)

Cost Class Unit Size (ac) Harvest Method % Slope Cost/Acre 1 >19 CC <40 254 2 5-19 CC <40 267 3 5-19 CC >40 1,000 4 >19 SW-ST <40 141 5 5-19 SW-ST <40 148 6 0-.4 SW-ST <40 199 7 <<<<<<<<<<<(Shelterwood Underburn)>>»>>>>>» 1,000 8 «<«« (O^erstory Removal-Pile Burning)»»» 10

NOTE: CC = clear cut; SW = shelterwood; ST = seedtree.

TABLE D-2

Site Preparation and Fuel Treatment Costs (1st quarter 1978 dollars)

Cost 1984* 2003 2013 2083 Class $/acre ac $ ac $ ac $ ac $

1 254 31 7,874 37 9,398 — 31 7,874 2 267 37 7,879 29 7,209 — — 37 1 ,879 3 1 ,000 10 1 ,000 10 1 ,000 4 141 276 38,916 276 38,916 5 148 21 3,108 54 7,992 — — 21 3,108 6 199 2 398 4 796 — — 2 398 7 1 ,000 — — — — 38 38,000 — —

8 10 — — 299 2,990 Total Cost 51,296 28,385 38,000 51 ,296

*20% in 1983, 40% in 1984 and 40% in 1985.

Page 83: Economic analysis of proposed Forest Service timber sales

75

Appendix E

PLANTING, STOCKING SURVEY AND PRECOMMERCIAL

THINNING COST ESTIMATES

Cost values for planting, stocking surveys and precommercial

thinning are taken from the Flathead FORPLAN Economic Coefficient

Documentation (USDA, 1981a). Total planting costs (first quarter

1978 dollars) on the Flathead National Forest average $158 per acre

for a full 10' X 10' planting and $118 per acre for a planting of

200 trees per acre (this is slightly less than 20' x 20' planting

which would require 218 trees per acre). The Silviculturalist's

Prescription makes regeneration recommendations including 9' x 9',

10' X 10', 12' X 12', 14' X 14' plantings and natural regeneration

(Wilson, 1981). Although these alternatives do not correspond

exactly to the cost classes used in the Flathead FORPLAN, costs for

9' x 9' and 12' x 12' plantings are assumed to be equivalent to

10' X 10' planting, and 14' x 14' planting is assumed to be equiva­

lent to 200 trees per acre.

Actual costs would probably be slightly higher. Planting costs

may also be underestimated here because planting is assumed to be

accomplished the second year after a regeneration harvest with 100%

success, and no allowance is made here for the above average hand-

scalping which will probably be required. (In order to reduce slash

disposal costs, the sale package was revised over the winter to

require tree length yarding on most clearcut units. This would

Page 84: Economic analysis of proposed Forest Service timber sales

eliminate the need for most of the expensive broadcast burning

originally scheduled for those units, but would increase the need

for handscalping during planting).

Stocking surveys and certifications occur over a four to five

year period after planting. Costs (first quarter 1978 dollars) are

approximately $5 per acre for natural regeneration, $6 per acre for

overstory removals, and $7 per acre for plantings (USDA, 1981a,

E-1E3, E-5). For dating purposes, stocking survey costs are assumed

to be centered on the second year after planting.

Total precommercial thinning costs average $178 per acre on

the Flathead (USDA, 1981a, E-1E 7). Where scheduled, precommercial

thinning is assumed to occur 22 years after the regeneration harvest.

Tables E-1 , E-2 and E-3 give total expected planting, stocking

survey and precommercial thinning costs as scheduled by the Silvi-

culturalist's Prescription.

TABLE E-1

Planting Costs (1st quarter 1978 dollars)

1985 a

2004

$/acre acres $/acre $ acres $

TOTAL COST:

137 434

118 16,166 158 71,732

87,898^

38 84

118 158

4,484 13,272

17,756

3, Following the staggered initial harvest, assume 20% 1984,

40% 1985, 40% 1986.

Page 85: Economic analysis of proposed Forest Service timber sales

77

TABLE E-2

Stocking Survey Costs (1st quarter 1978 dollars)

1987*^ 2006 2016 acres $/acre $ acres $/acre $ acres $/acre

162 5 810 37 5 185 5 — 6 — 273 6 1 ,644 38 6

591 7 4,137 85 7 595 — 7

TOTAL COST 4,947^^ 2,424 288

^Following the staggered initial harvest, assume 20% 1986, 40% 1987, 40% 1988.

TABLE E-3

Precomraercial Thinning Costs (1st quarter 1978 dollars)

acres $/acre $ acres $/acre $

753 178 134,034 122 178 21,716

Page 86: Economic analysis of proposed Forest Service timber sales

78

Appendix F

PRESENT VALUE

The present net value and benefit/cost ratio for the Ketchikan

Sale can now be calculated using the data generated in the preceeding

appendices. Table F-1 lists total expected costs by year for: sale

preparation (Table C-2), sale administration (Table C-3), road costs

(Table B-3), site preparation and fuel treatment (Table D-2), planting

(Table E-1), stocking survey (Table E-2) and precoramercial thinning

(Table E-3). These costs are discounted to the present for discount

rates 4%, 7 1/8% and 10% in Table F-2 using the formula;

VQ = Ml . i)"

where:

VQ = discounted present value

= total value at year n

n = year of accrual

i = discount rate

The same formula was used in Table F-3 to discount the expected

benefits (from Tables A-1 and A-8). The present net values and benefit/

cost ratios for the Ketchikan Sale (Case 1 and Case 2, p. 32) were

derived from Tables F-2 and F-3. First quarter 1978 dollars were con­

verted to fourth quarter 1981 dollars with the GNP Implicit Price

Deflator Indices: 199.58 t 147.05.

Page 87: Economic analysis of proposed Forest Service timber sales

Year

1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 2001 2002 2003 2004 2006 2011 2012 2013 2016 2022 2041 2042 2051 2052 2061 2062 2081 2082 2083

79

TABLE F-1

Total Expected Costs (1st quarter 1978 dollars)

Sale Sale Road Site Stck Total Prep Admin Costs Prep Planting Surv Thinning Cost

78,751 — — 78,751 — 4,615 211,944 — — — 216,559 — 9,231 293,267 10,260 — — — 303,521 — 9,230 — 20,518 17,580 — — 47,328 — — — 20,519 35,159 — — 55,615 — — — — 35,159 990 — 36,149 — — — — — 1 ,979 — 1 ,979 — — — — — 1 ,978 — 1 ,978

36,467 — — — — — — 36,467 — 10,295 95,770 — — — 134,034 240,099 — — — 28,385 — — — 28,385 — — — — 17,756 — — 17,756 — — — — — 2,424 — 2,424

3,837 — — — — — — 3,837 — 1 ,552 27,514 — — — — 29,066 — — — 38,000 — — — 38,000 — — — — — 228 — 228 — — — — — — 21 ,716 21,716

49,462 — — — — — — 49,462 - - 13,843 262,302 — — — — 276,145

9,991 — — — — — — 9,991 — 3,303 97,859 — — — — 101 ,162

62,102 — — — — — — 62,102 — 18,057 95,770 — — — — 113,827

75,531 — — — — — — 75,531 — 22,131 95,770 — — — — 117,901 — — — 51,296 — — — 51,296

Page 88: Economic analysis of proposed Forest Service timber sales

80

TABLE F-2

Discounted Total Costs (1st quarter 1978 dollars)

Total Discount Factor Discounted Cost

Year Cost 4% 7 1 /8% 10% 4% 7 1/8% 10%

1981 78,751 1 .040 1 .071 1 .100 81,901 84,342 86,626 1982 216,559 1 .000 1 .000 1 .000 216,559 216,559 216,559 1983 305,512 .9615 .9335 .9091 291,827 283,328 275,923 1984 47,328 .9246 .8714 .8264 43,759 41,242 39,112 1985 55,615 .8890 .8134 .7513 49,442 45,237 41 ,778 1986 36,149 .8548 .7593 .6830 30,900 27,448 24,690 1987 1 ,979 .8219 .7088 .6209 1 ,627 1 ,403 1 ,229 1088 1 ,978 .7903 .6617 .5645 1 ,563 1 ,309 1 ,117 2001 36,467 .4746 .2704 .1635 17,312 9,863 5,964 2002 240,099 .4564 .2525 .1486 109,581 60,625 35,679 2003 28,385 .4388 .2357 .1351 12,455 6,690 3,835 2004 17,756 .4220 .2200 .1228 7,493 3,906 2,180 2006 2,424 .3901 .1917 .1015 946 465 246 2011 3,837 .3207 .1359 .0630 1 ,231 533 242 2012 29,066 .3083 .1268 .0573 8,961 3,686 1 ,665 2013 38,000 .2965 .1184 .0521 11,267 4,499 1 ,980 2016 228 .2636 .0963 .0391 60 23 9 2022 21 ,716 .2083 .0637 .0221 4,523 1 ,383 480 2041 49,462 .0989 .0172 .0036 4,892 851 178 2042 276,145 .0951 .0161 .0033 26,261 4,446 911 2051 9,991 .0668 .0087 .0014 667 87 14 2052 101 ,162 .0642 .0081 .0013 6,495 819 132 2061 62,102 .0451 .0044 .0005 2,801 273 31 2062 113,827 .0434 .0041 .0005 4,940 467 57 2081 75,531 .0206 .0011 .0001 1 ,556 83 8 2082 117,901 .0198 .0010 .0010 2,334 118 12 2083 51,296 .0190 .0010 -.0001 3,975 51 5

DISCOUNTED TOTAL COST 942,368 799,776 740,702

Page 89: Economic analysis of proposed Forest Service timber sales

81

TABLE F-3

Discounted Total Benefits (1st quarter 1978 dollars)

Discount Factor Discounted Benefit

Year Benefit 4% 7 1/8% 10% 4% 7 1/8% 10%

1983 111 ,410 .9615 .9335 .9091 107,121 104,002 101,283 1984 222.821 .9246 .8714 .8264 206,021 194,166 184,139 1985 222,821 .8890 .8134 .7513 198,088 181,242 167,405 2003 288,517 .4388 .2357 .1351 126,601 68,003 38,979 2013 49,117 .2965 .1184 .0521 14,565 5,815 2,559 2043 579,856 .0914 .0150 .0030 52,999 8,698 1 ,740 2053 87,700 .0617 .0075 .0012 5,411 658 105 2063 731,719 .0417 .0038 .0004 30,513 2,781 293 2083 731,719 .0190 .0010 .0001 85,530 4,502 450

DISCOUNTED TOTAL BENEFIT 826,847 569,867 496,953

Page 90: Economic analysis of proposed Forest Service timber sales

82

REFERENCES

Adams, D.M., and Haynes, R.W. 1979. The 1980 softwood timber assessment market model: structure projections and policy simulations. Unpublished report on file at the USFS Pacific Northwest Forest and Range Exp. Sta., Portland, Ore. (Cited in Merzenich, 1979).

The projections for the Flathead N.F. are on file in the Flathead N.F. Supervisor's Office, Kalispell, Mont.

Amman, G.D., McGregor M.D., Cahill, D.B., and. Klein, W.H. 1977. Guidelines for reducing losses of lodgepole pine to the moun­tain pine beetle in unmanaged stands in the Rocky Mountains. Gen. Tech. Rpt. INT-36, Intermountain Forest and Range Exp. Sta., USDA Forest Service, Ogden, Utah.

Armit, D. 1966. Silvics and silviculture of lodgepole pine in the north central interior of British Columbia; a problem analysis. Brit. Columbia Forest Serv. Res. Note N. 40. Victoria. {Cited in Peterman, 1978).

Armstrong, Bonner, 1981, Timber Staff, Glacier View Ranger Dist. Flathead N.F., Columbia Falls, Mont. Tel. Con., 4/27/81.

. 1982a Per. Com. 1/4/82.

. 1982b Per. Com. 4/1/82.

Averill, R.D., Bunter, J.E., Lister, O.K., and Sonnen, D.H. 1977. Guidelines for estimating the benefits of mountain pine beetle control projects. Tech. Rpt. R2-11, Rocky Mountain Region, USDA Forest Service, Lakewood, Colo.

Barlow, T.J., Helfand," G.E., Orr, T.W., and Stoel, T.B. Jr. 1980. Giving away the national forests: an analysis of U.S. Forest Service timber sales below cost. Natural Resources Defense Council, Washington, D.C.

Brown, J.K. 1975. Fire cycles and community dynamics in lodgepole pine forests. In Baumgartner, D.M., ed. Management of lodge­pole pine ecosystems, Symp. Proc., pp. 429-456. Coop. Ext. Serv., Washington, St. Univ., Pullman, Wash. (Cited in Amman, et al, 1980).

Clements, F.E. 1910. The life history of lodgepole burn forests. USDA Forest Serv. Bull. No 79. U.S. Govt. Print. Off.,

Page 91: Economic analysis of proposed Forest Service timber sales

Washington D.C. (Cited in Peterman, 1978).

Cole, D.M. 1978. Feasibility of silvicultural practices for reducing losses to the mountain pine beetle in lodgepole pine forests. In Klbbee, D.L., et al, eds. Theory and Practice of mountain pine beetle management in lodgepole pine forests, Symp. Proc., pp. 140-147. Forest, Wildlife and Range Exp. Sta., Univ. of Id., Moscow, Id.

Cole, W.E., and Amman, G.D. 1980. Mountain pine beetle dynamics in lodgepole pine forests, part 1: course of an infestation. Gen. Tech. Rpt. INT-89, Intermountain Forest and Range Exp. Sta., USDA Forest Service, Ogden, Utah,

Combes, J.A. 1982. Letter to FSM 2420 Timber Appraisal dated Jan. 29, 1982. On file in Timber Managment, Northern Region Office, USDA Forest Service, Missoula, Mont.

Corkran, C. 1980. A new look at the Douglas fir tussock moth. Forest Planning Nov., pp. 12-13+.

Crossley, D.I. 1956. Fruiting habits of lodgepole pine. Forest Res. Div. Tech. Note No. 34. Canada Dept. Northern Affairs and Natural Resources. (Cited in Peterman, 1978).

Davis, K.P. 1966. Forest Management; regulation and valuation. New York; McGraw-Hill.

Furniss, R.L. and Carolin, V.M. 1980. Western forest insects. Misc. Pub No., 1339, USDA Forest Service, U.S. Govt. Print. Off., Washington D.C.

Hall, D. and Norgaard, R. 1973. On the timing and application of pesticides. Amer. J. Agr. Econ. 55;198-201. (Cited in Irland, 1977).

Halvorsen, R. and Ruby, M.G. 1981. Evaluation of uncertain benefits and costs. Chapter 5 in Benefit-cost analysis of air pollution control, pp. 63-75. Lexington, Mass.: Lexington Books.

Hirshleifer, J.and Riley, J.G. 1979. The analytics of uncertainty and information — an expository survey, J. Econ. Lit. 17(4); 1375-1421 .

Hodgeboom, Fred. 1982. Timber Planner, Flathead N.F. Supervisor's Office, Kalispell, Mont. Per. Com., 2/4/82.

Irland, L.C. 1977. Notes on the economics of spruce budworm control. Tech. Note No. 67, School of Forest Resources, Univ. of Maine, Orono, Maine.

. 1980. Notes on the economics of forest pest managment. Forest Planning. Nov. pp. 8-11.

Page 92: Economic analysis of proposed Forest Service timber sales

84

Jackson, D.H. 1982. Associate Professor, School of Forestry, University of Montana, Missoula, Mont. Per. Com., 4/30/82.

Jackson, D.H. and Loveless, R. 1981. Predicting forest road and bridge construction costs. Manuscript draft dated July 27, 1981. (School of Forestry, Univ. of Mont., Missoula, Mont.)

Johnson, N.E. 1963. Some economic considerations in planning control of insects affecting young forest trees. J. For. 61:426-429.

Jonkel, C.J. 1979. Ketchikan Creek: to cut or not. Border Grizzly Project Special Rpt. No. 33. School of Forestry, Univ. of Mont., Missoula, Mont.

Klein, W.H. 1978. Strategies and tactics for reducing losses in lodgepole pine to the mountain pine beetle by chemical and mechanical means. In Kibbee, K.L., et al, eds.. Theory and practice of mountian pine beetle management in lodgepole pine forests, Symp. Proc., pp. 148-158. Forest, Wildlife and Range Exp. Sta., Univ. of Id., Moscow, Id.

Krutilla, J.V. and Haigh, J.A. 1978. Integrated approach. En­vironmental Law, 8:385-395.

Lakes, G. 1982. Canadian coal mine opposition organizing. Mis-soulian (Mont.) 3/28/82, p. 15.

Latham, J.A. 1965. The effects of spacing on development of lodgepole pine in the Manning Park area of British Columbia, Vancouver. (Cited in Peterman, 1978).

Lotan, J.E. 1975. The role of cone serotiny in lodgepole pine forests. In Baumgartner, D.M., ed. Management of lodgepole pine ecosystems, Symp. Proc. pp. 471-495. Coop. Ext. Serv., Washington St. Univ., Pullman, Wash. (Cited in Peterman, 1978).

Marty, R.J. and Allison, G.R. 1950. Appraising white-pine weevil control opportunities. J. For. 58:203-206.

Mason, D.T. 1915. The management of lodgepole pine. For. Quart. 13:171-182. (Cited in Peterman, 1978).

Merzenich, J.P. 1979. Classifying forest land based upon its timber management potential: a case study of the Lolo National Forest. Master's thesis. School of Forestry, Univ. of Mont., Missoula, Mont.

Mikesell, R.F. 1977. The rate of discount for evaluating public projects. American Enterprise Institute for Public Policy Research, Washington, D.C.

Page 93: Economic analysis of proposed Forest Service timber sales

85

Newport, C.A. 1962. Economics of forest pest control. J. For. 60; 306-308.

Norgaard, R. 1976. The economics of improving pesticide use. Ann. Rev. Ent. 21!45-60.

O'Harra, D. 1982a. Room to roam. Missoulian (Mont.), 3/28/82, p. A-1.

. 1982b. The grizzly, people dilemma. Missoulian (Mont.), 3/28/82, p. A-1.

0'Toole, R. 1981. The 4% discount rate is too low — the Forest Service should learn from industry. Forest Planning. 2(3): 9-16.

Peterman, R.M. 1978. The ecological role of mountain pine beetle in lodgepole pine forests. In Kibbe, D.L., et al, eds.. Theory and practice of mountain pine beetle management in lodgepole pine forests, Symp. Proc., pp. 16-26. Forest, Wildlife and Range Exp. Sta., Univ. of Id., Moscow, Id.

Pfister, R.D. and Daubenmire, R. 1975. Ecology of lodgepole pine (Pinus contorta Dougl.). In Baumgartner, D.M., ed.. Manage­ment of lodgepole pine ecosystems, Symp. Proc. pp. 27-46. Coop. Est. Serv., Washington St. Univ., Pullman, Wash. (Cited in Amman, et al, 1980).

Ruesink, W.G. 1976. Status of the systems approach to pest manage­ment. Ann. Rev. Ent. 21:27-44.

Safranyk, L., Shrimpton, D.M. and Whitney, H.S. 1975. An interpretation of the interaction between lodgepole pine, the mountain pine beetle and its associated blue stain fungi in western Canada. In Baumgartner, D.M., ed. Manage­ment of lodgepole pine ecosystems, Symp. Proc., pp. 406-428. Doop. Ext. Serv., Washington St. Univ., Pullman, Wash.

Samuelson, P.A. 1976. Economics of forestry in an evolving society. Econ. Inquiry. 14(4):466-492.

Schleussler, N. 1981. Transportation system economic analysis, Ketchikan Sale alternative #3B. On file in Flathead N.F. Supervisor's Office, USDA Forest Service, Kalispell, Mont.

. 1982a. Highway Engineer. Flathead N.F. Supervisor's Office. USDA Forest Service, Kalispell, Mont. Per. Com., 2/4/82.

. 1982b. Tel. Con., 2/16/82.

Schwennesen, D. 1980a. Agency rapped for OKing salvage sale. Missoulian (Mont.), 6/25/80. p. 29.

Page 94: Economic analysis of proposed Forest Service timber sales

86

. 1980b. Environmental groups give F.S. notice of appeal. Missoulian (Mont.), 9/5/80.

. 1981a. Logging operation north of Glacier to expand. Missoulian (Mont.), 2/13/81. p. 17.

. 1981b. In the wake of the DEADLY pine beetle. Missoulian (Mont.), 2/15/82. pp. A-1 , A-3.

. 1981c. Forest's plan for leases questioned. Missoulian (Mont.), ̂ /12/81 .

. 1981d. Canadians plan more logging. Missoulian (Mont.), 5/14/81.

Stark, R.W. 1971. Integrated control, pest management, or population management? In Proc. Third Annual Northeastern Forest Insect Conference, p. 117. USDA Forest Service, Res. Paper NE-194, Northeastern Forest Exp. Sta.

Stern V.M. 1973. Economic thresholds. Ann. Rev. Ent. 18:259-280.

, Smith, R.F., van den Bosh, R. and Hagen, K.S. 1959. The Integrated control concept. Hllgardla. 29(2):81-101. (Cited in Norgaard, 1976).

Stoel, T. 1978. The National Forest Management Act. Environmental Law. 8:563-565.

Stoltenberg, C.H. 1959. An investment-opportunity approach to foresty programming. J. For. 57:547-550.

Turner, Jerry: 1982. Highway Engineer, Glacier View Ranger Dist., USDA Forest Service, Columbia Falls, Mont. Tel. Con. 2/16/82.

U.S. Comptroller General. 1976. Evaluation of a proposal to harvest and rehabilitate beetle-infested areas in three Oregon national forests. Gen. Accounting Off., CED-77-15, Washington, D.C.

USDA Forest Service. 1978. The Douglas-fir tussock moth; a synthesis. Tech. Bull. No. 1585. Washington, D.C.

. 1979. Programatic report for the treatment of the mountain pine beetle epidemic, Flathead National Forest. Environmental assessment report on file in the Flathead N.F. Supervisor's Office, Kalispell, Mont.

. 1980. North end salvage, Glacier View Ranger District. Environmental assessment report on file in the Flathead N.F. Supervisor's Office, Kalispell, Mont.

. 1980b North end salvage, Glacier View Ranger District. Supplement to environmental assessment report, 8/6/80. On file

Page 95: Economic analysis of proposed Forest Service timber sales

87

in the Flathead N.F. Supervisor's Offcie, Kalispell, Mont.

. 1981a. FORPLAN coefficient documentation. On File in the Flathead N.F. Supervisor's Office, Kalispell, Mont.

. 1981b. Economic and Social Analysis; proposed policy, FSM 1970. Fed. Reg. 46(74): 22351-22558.

. 1981c. The Northern Region plan. August, Northern Region Office, Missoula, Mont.

. 198ld. Ketchikan Sale Prospectus, Appraisal Summary, and Sample Contract. On file at Glacier View Ranger Dist., Columbia Falls, Mont.

. 19B1e. Flathead large sale data computer print-out dated 11/5/81. On file in Programming, Planning and Budgeting, Northern Region Office, Missoula, Mont.

USDOC Bureau of Economic Analysis. 1979-1982. Surv. Cur. Bus. 59(9), 6 0 ( 1 ) , 6 0 ( 2 ) , 6 2 ( 2 ) .

USDOT Federal Highway Administration. 1982. Draft environmental impact statement for reconstruction of Montana Forest Highway Route 61, Flathead County Route 486, Flathead County (portion). Jan. 8. Denver. Federal Highway Administration.

Wellner, C.A. 1978. Management problems resulting from mountain pine beetles in lodgepole pine forests. In Kibbee, D.L., ed.. Theory and practice of mountain pine beetle management in lodgepole pine forests, pp. 9-15. Forest, Wildlife and Range Esp. Sta., Univ. of Id., Moscow, Id.

Wilson, George. 1981. Ketchikan Sale stand diagnosis and prescription. Worksheets on file at Glacier View Ranger Dist., USDA Forest Service, Columbia Falls, Mont.

. 1982. Silviculturalist, Glacier View Ranger Dist., USDA Forest Service, Columbia Falls, Mont. Per. Com., 2/5/82.