does a helping hand put others at risk - affirmative action, police departments, and crime (2000) by...

39
DOES A HELPING HAND PUT OTHERS AT RISK?: AFFIRMATIVE ACTION, POLICE DEPARTMENTS, AND CRIME JOHN R. LOTT, JR. Will increasing the number of minority and women police officers make law enforcement more effecti e by drawing on abilities that ha e gone untapped and creating better contact with communities and ictims? Or will standards ha e to be lowered too far before large numbers of minorities and women can be hired? Using cross-sectional time-series data for U.S. cities for 1987, 1990, and 1993, I find that hiring more black and minority police officers increases crime rates, but this apparently arises because lower hiring standards in ol ed in recruiting more minority officers reduces the quality of both new minority and new nonminority officers. The most ad erse effects of these hiring policies ha e occurred in the areas most hea ily populated by blacks. There is no consistent e idence that crime rates rise when more women are hired, and this raises questions about whether norming tests or altering their content to create equal pass rates is preferable. The article examines how the changing composition of police departments affects such measures as the murder of Ž . and assaults against police officers. JEL J72, K14, H42 I. INTRODUCTION Using preferential standards to aid minor- ity groups is frequently justified as rectifying past wrongs. Yet, since Richmond . Croson 1 Co. 1989 , the U.S. Supreme Court has held that these preferences must pass the *I would like to thank Stephen Bronars, Tom Collingwood, Richard Epstein, Gertrud Fremling, Ed Glaeser, Linda Gottfredson, Robert Hansen, Dan Ka- han, Larry Kenny, Dan Klerman, Bill Landes, Stan Liebowitz, Scott Masten, Sam Peltzman, two very help- ful referees from this journal, and the participants in seminars at UCLA, the University of Chicago, Cornell University, George Mason University, Heritage Founda- tion, the NBER Law and Economics Summer Institute, University of Michigan, Michigan State University, SUNY Binghamton, University of Southern California, University of Washington, the American Law and Eco- nomics Association, the Western Economic Association Meetings, the Southern Economic Association meetings, and my students at the University of Chicago for their helpful comments. Stephen Bronars also deserves more than normal thanks for the tremendous amount of work that he has put in helping me put this data set together. John Whitley also provided valuable research assistance. Lott: Senior Research Scholar, Yale University School of Law, New Haven, Conn., Phone 1-203-432-2366, Fax 1-203-432-8260, E-mail [email protected] 1. See also Epstein 1992, 42933 . Coate and Loury 1993 provide an important discussion on the costs and benefits of affirmative action policies. They rigorously list out conditions under which these policies will break down negative stereotypes and those cases where they will make them even worse. 2. Adarand overturned the decision in Metro Broad- casting, Inc. . Federal Communications Commission. difficult ‘‘strict scrutiny test’’ and will be in- validated unless they promote a ‘‘compelling’’ governmental interest. Correcting ‘‘societal discrimination’’ was not viewed as a com- pelling interest. Remedial efforts to rectify past discrimination will only be approved if narrowly tailored to correct specific instances of discrimination. The question of what goals constitute a sufficiently ‘‘compelling’’ inter- est has never been clearly specified by the Supreme Court, though in a very closely decided case it reversed its own past decision that Federal Communication Commission Ž . FCC allocation of licenses by race is ac- ceptable to promote diversity in entertain- ment and news programming and applied these high standards of strict scrutiny and ‘‘compelling’’ interest to federal building pro- jects. 2 The standards set by the Supreme Court in Richmond and Adarand were motivated by the desire that ‘‘The strict scrutiny test also ensures that the means chosen ‘fit’ this ABBREVIATIONS FBI: Federal Bureau of Investigation FCC: Federal Communication Commission LEMAS: Law Enforcement Management and Administration Statistics 239 Economic Inquiry Ž . ISSN 0095-2583 Vol. 38, No. 2, April 2000, 239277 Western Economic Association International

Upload: steven-howell

Post on 12-Sep-2015

10 views

Category:

Documents


3 download

DESCRIPTION

Does a Helping Hand Put Others at Risk

TRANSCRIPT

  • DOES A HELPING HAND PUT OTHERS AT RISK?:AFFIRMATIVE ACTION, POLICE DEPARTMENTS, AND CRIME

    JOHN R. LOTT, JR.

    Will increasing the number of minority and women police officers make lawenforcement more effectie by drawing on abilities that hae gone untapped andcreating better contact with communities and ictims? Or will standards hae to belowered too far before large numbers of minorities and women can be hired? Usingcross-sectional time-series data for U.S. cities for 1987, 1990, and 1993, I find thathiring more black and minority police officers increases crime rates, but thisapparently arises because lower hiring standards inoled in recruiting more minorityofficers reduces the quality of both new minority and new nonminority officers. Themost aderse effects of these hiring policies hae occurred in the areas most heailypopulated by blacks. There is no consistent eidence that crime rates rise when morewomen are hired, and this raises questions about whether norming tests or alteringtheir content to create equal pass rates is preferable. The article examines how thechanging composition of police departments affects such measures as the murder of

    .and assaults against police officers. JEL J72, K14, H42

    I. INTRODUCTION

    Using preferential standards to aid minor-ity groups is frequently justified as rectifyingpast wrongs. Yet, since Richmond . Croson

    1Co. 1989 , the U.S. Supreme Court hasheld that these preferences must pass the

    *I would like to thank Stephen Bronars, TomCollingwood, Richard Epstein, Gertrud Fremling, EdGlaeser, Linda Gottfredson, Robert Hansen, Dan Ka-han, Larry Kenny, Dan Klerman, Bill Landes, StanLiebowitz, Scott Masten, Sam Peltzman, two very help-ful referees from this journal, and the participants inseminars at UCLA, the University of Chicago, CornellUniversity, George Mason University, Heritage Founda-tion, the NBER Law and Economics Summer Institute,University of Michigan, Michigan State University,SUNY Binghamton, University of Southern California,University of Washington, the American Law and Eco-nomics Association, the Western Economic AssociationMeetings, the Southern Economic Association meetings,and my students at the University of Chicago for theirhelpful comments. Stephen Bronars also deserves morethan normal thanks for the tremendous amount of workthat he has put in helping me put this data set together.John Whitley also provided valuable research assistance.Lott: Senior Research Scholar, Yale University School

    of Law, New Haven, Conn., Phone 1-203-432-2366,Fax 1-203-432-8260, E-mail [email protected]

    1. See also Epstein 1992, 42933 . Coate and Loury 1993 provide an important discussion on the costs andbenefits of affirmative action policies. They rigorouslylist out conditions under which these policies will breakdown negative stereotypes and those cases where theywill make them even worse.

    2. Adarand overturned the decision in Metro Broad-casting, Inc. . Federal Communications Commission.

    difficult strict scrutiny test and will be in-validated unless they promote a compellinggovernmental interest. Correcting societaldiscrimination was not viewed as a com-pelling interest. Remedial efforts to rectifypast discrimination will only be approved ifnarrowly tailored to correct specific instancesof discrimination. The question of what goalsconstitute a sufficiently compelling inter-est has never been clearly specified by theSupreme Court, though in a very closelydecided case it reversed its own past decisionthat Federal Communication Commission .FCC allocation of licenses by race is ac-ceptable to promote diversity in entertain-ment and news programming and appliedthese high standards of strict scrutiny andcompelling interest to federal building pro-jects.2

    The standards set by the Supreme Courtin Richmond and Adarand were motivated

    by the desire that The strict scrutiny testalso ensures that the means chosen fit this

    ABBREVIATIONS

    FBI: Federal Bureau of InvestigationFCC: Federal Communication CommissionLEMAS: Law Enforcement Management and

    Administration Statistics

    239Economic Inquiry .ISSN 0095-2583Vol. 38, No. 2, April 2000, 239277 Western Economic Association International

  • ECONOMIC INQUIRY240

    compelling goal so closely that there is littleor no possibility that the motive for theclassification was illegitimate racial prejudiceor stereotype.3 One can hypothesize whatcompelling goals would meet these standardswhere there is little or no possibility thatan ulterior race-based motive might be thetrue motivation behind an affirmative actionrule, but the most obvious case would bewhen the racial preferences actually help tofurther the central purpose of the govern-mental agency.4 In the case of police, thismeans that minority police officers are beingemployed not because diversity is intrinsi-cally valued but because it is believed to helplower the crime rate.

    The potential law enforcement advan-tages from multiracial or female officers seemobvious. Minority police officers may be moreeffective in minority areas simply becauseresidents could be more forthcoming aboutinformation that will lead to arrests and con-victions or because of the officers ability toserve as undercover agents. Trust is alsoimportant for other reasons, as reports ofriots erupting after white police officers haveshot a black man may attest.5 Officers from a

    3. Adarand.4. A distinction must be drawn between two differ-

    ent types of affirmative action programs: quotas andpreferential treatment. While preferential treatment al-ready must meet a very high threshold to be approved,the requirements are if anything even more difficult forquotas. It is doubtful that even a federal law establish-ing an affirmative action racial classification would be

    upheld if the law used a racial quota system Nowak and Rotunda 1995, 695 .

    5. For example, in 1996 riots errupted in St. Peters-burg Florida, after a white police officer shot and killedan 18-year-old black man driving a stolen car and inLeland, Mississippi, after a white police officer fatally

    shot a black businessman named Aaron White Kis-simmee chief wants riot gear for police: The city shouldlearn from St. Petersburgs riots, John Sutphin said,Orlando Sentinel, Saturday, April 26, 1997, p. 1, andBartholomew Sullivan, Shooting death prior to Leland

    riot ruled accidental, Commercial Appeal Memphis,. .Tenn , Friday, April 18, 1997, p. A15 . Further back In

    1980, one of the worst recent U.S. race riots erupted inLiberty City and spread through Miami after an all-whitejury acquitted white police officers accused of killing a

    black man Angus MacSwan, Drug gangs rule, chil-dren suffer in Miamis Liberty City, Reuters World

    .Service, Friday, February 14, 1997 . Of course, probablythe worst recent riots occurred in 1992 after whitepolice officers were found not guilty in the Rodney Kingbeating. On the other hand, having a racially diversepolice department does not guarantee that these riotswill be prevented. The Los Angeles Police Departmentsshare of blacks very closely matched the citys.

    community may also be better at understand-ing the behavior of criminals in those areasor even something as basic as understandingthe language of immigrants.6 In any event,police efforts to reduce crime are surely de-pendent on the help that they receive from

    .the community Wilson 1983 .Rape victims or women abused by their

    spouses plausibly find it easier to discuss thetraumatic events with women officers. With-out female officers, many attacks againstwomen may go undetectedthus loweringthe expected penalty from attacking womenand resulting in even more attacks. Policingis a rare case where the government outputis likely to be advanced by race- or sex-basedpreferences. Indeed, reducing reliance oncognitive tests for police entrance examina-tions has been justified with the motivationthat police departments cannot functioneffectively in minority neighborhoods whenvirtually all police officers are white males .Dunnette et. al. 1996 .

    Another case might be education, where afrequently made claim is that a diverse stu-dent body better prepares students for adiverse world.7 These goals have also beenused to justify weighting applicants by raceor sex along with their test scores. By con-trast, how people use roads or machinesseems likely to be unrelated to the race ofthose who built them. Even the case of firedepartments, obtaining racial diversity seemstangential to the ultimate goal of extinguish-ing a fire.

    Although the foregoing benefits are clear,there are countervailing factors that must betaken into account. Most important iswhether explicit race or sex preferences re-sult in less-capable individuals being hired.For women, this might result because of

    6. Community leaders frequently claim that Wewant police who know the community. We want them to

    spend time and become part of the community. Quotefrom Dennis L. Chinn, founder of the Asian Plaza

    Youth Foundation, as reported by Phat X. Chiem 1995,B1 . The same article reports on the importance of

    having bilingual officers. 7. For example, see Katyal 1995 and Keohane

    1995 .

  • LOTT: DOES A HELPING HAND PUT OTHERS AT RISK? 241

    less-stringent physical requirements.8 Slowerrunning speed might make it more difficultfor women to catch criminals.9 Weaker phys-ical strength might cause police departmentsto substitute away from single officer patrol

    .units either foot or car and into units withtwo officers. If criminals believe that theyhave a greater chance of resisting arrest whenofficers are weaker, more assaults may becommitted by criminals against women of-ficers. In compensating for their weakerstrength, women may substitute into otherways of controlling criminalsthe most ob-vious method being guns. Although guns area great equalizer, they may not completely

    8. Testing of the physical strengths of men andwomen public safety employees consistently finds largedifferences. These studies indicate that womens

    strength rang es from 44 to 68% of mens in the upper body and 55 to 82% in the lower body Landy 1992,

    .456 . The norming adopted by most police depart-ments for physical fitness tests creates equal probabili-

    .ties for passing by men and women Flannery, 1995, 2 .The same types of rules are adopted by the militarywhere women recruits must run two miles in 18 min-utes, 54 seconds, which is three minutes slower than the

    required time for men. Women must do 18 push-ups intwo minutes and 50 sit-ups in two minutes, while menmust do 42 push-ups and 52 sit-ups in the same time.Tom Collingwood, a consultant on physical testing stan-dards in Dallas, estimates that between 70% and 80% ofpolice departments explicitly use norming of physicalstandards in their hiring practices. However, he believesthat most of the departments that use objective stan-dards do not enforce these rules. Women who fail tomeet the absolute standards during academy trainingare unlikely to be failed out of the program. This beliefwas confirmed by conversations with other experts in

    this area e.g., Mike Bahrke at Fitforce in Champaign,.Illinois . This creates a difficult problem for testing the

    impact of norming physical standards because it impliesthat all cities really have the same standards whether

    they explicitly claim so or not See also Bahrke and .Hoffman 1997 . Courts have also disallowed other types

    of tests that produce differential pass rates betweenmen and women. For example, in a 1980 case involvingthe Philadelphia Police Department, the district courtruled that it was unlawful to discharge women whofailed to achieve a passing score on the firearms quali-

    .fying test 499 F. Supp. 1196 .9. The New York City Police Department is said to

    illustrate this point. The department abandoned allphysical screening of applicants in the 80s out fear oflawsuits by minority applicants and women. Some offi-cers hired under relaxed testing lack the strength to pullthe trigger on a gun, said Michael Julian, former NYPDchief of personnel. There are hundreds, if not thou-sands, of police officers on the streets today who, whena suspect runs from them, have no other option than tocall another cop, because they do not have the physical

    ability to pursue them, Julian said Marzulli and Lewis, .1997, 7 .

    offset differences in strength.10 Being lessable to fall back on their physical strength toprotect themselves when faced with a possi-ble attack, women may have to determinewhether they will fire their gun before thepossible attacker gets into physical contactwith them. If true, shorter reaction times riskresulting in more accidental shootings.

    Although the U.S. Department of Justicestates that the appropriate testing proce-dures nearly eliminate disparate impact while

    . 11improving merit hiring Gottfredson 1997 ,critics of affirmative action in policing arguethat these tests lower reliance on importantcognitive skills. According to a 1993 surveyof 23 large police and sheriff departmentsconducted for the Department of Justice

    .and Nassau County, New York , the cogni-tive portion of police tests have been com-pletely removed in three cases, in an attemptto increase minority recruitment. Even theremaining 20 had reduced their emphasis oncognitive skills, with all the respondents indi-cating that adverse impact was consideredwhen determining the selection process .Dunnette et. al. 1993, 18 . Using this sur-vey to help justify its decision, Nassau Countyremoved all cognitive tests except for a read-ing comprehension test, which is gradedpass-fail and requires that applicants had toscore only as well as the bottom 1% ofcurrent police officers. The Louisiana StatePolice replaced a cognitive exam with a testthat initially contained six parts: three per-sonality, one biographical, and two cognitive,

    10. A gun might not be as much of an equalizer forfemale officers as it is for women who use a gundefensively. Officers are frequently called on to havephysical contact with the criminals that they are pursu-ing, whereas women who use a gun defensively merelyuse the gun to keep a threatening person at bay.

    11. Some testing consultants back up the Depart-ment of Justices position, and note the different waysthat questions can be worded which will hurt minorityapplicants. In particular, the use of double-negatives,homonyms, questions reflecting middle-class experi-ences, or complex sentence structures toward the end

    of an exam all work to lower minority scores Wilson, .1996, A . President Clintons recent nominee as assis-

    .tant attorney general for civil rights Bill Lann Leeargues that admission standards for schooling maynot disproportionately exclude members of any race,ethnicity, or gender unless justified by an educationalnecessity and no less discriminatory but equally effectivealternatives to the practice exist. Lee argued that University of California cannot demonstrate any edu-

    cational necessity for standardized tests. Clint Bolick,A Vote for Lee Is a Vote for Preferences, Wall Street

    .Journal October 27, 1997, p. A23 .

  • ECONOMIC INQUIRY242

    but later threw out one of the cognitivesections to further reduce the impact on

    . 12minorities Price 1997 . After spending$5.1 million to have consultants developunbiased exams, only to have minorities farepoorly again, Chicago moved to a heavilyweighted seniority system for promoting po-lice officers and a lottery system for hiring

    . 13firefighters Spielman 1996, 16 . The De-partment of Justice has used legal action or

    .so-called consent decrees to force policedepartments to adopt these rules.

    Some academics have charged that thenew tests are consciously designed to worklittle better than simply picking applicants atrandom so that the pass rate is the same

    across different racial groups Gottfredson .1997, 1996 . If minority applicants with lowcognitive skills are hired and if these skillspredict how good a police officer a candidatewould be, preferential treatment adverselyaffects the effectiveness of police depart-ments. Indeed, some shocking reports havebeen made about the importance of cogni-tive skills. Expressing concerns about thepoor English skills of new police recruits, a

    Washington Post editorial 1993 claimed thatbetween 1986 and 1990, 311 of the 938murder cases the D.C. police brought to theU.S. attorneys officeroughly a thirdweredismissed. . . . One local prosecutor saysmany D.C cases were thrown out becauseprosecutors couldnt read or understand the

    12. The Louisiana case provides a good example ofhow these cases work. As part of an agreement with theDepartment of Justice, the Louisiana State Police agreedto set aside $1 million to pay African Americans whofailed the test and hire new troopers from among quali-

    fied African Americans who failed the test Shinkle,.1996, B1B2 . The test that was developed by the Coop-

    erative Personnel Services, Inc., had been used in otherjurisdictions where it had been upheld as not discrimi-nating against minority applicants by a federal judge ina Torrance, California case. The Louisiana State Policedenied the allegations of discrimination, but agreed tosettle the case with the federal government to avoid theburdens of contested litigation. The Department ofJustice pointed to the disparate impact that the testwas having on blacks and that the test was not job-related. From August 1991 to May 1996, Of the 2,721white applicants who took the test, 66 percent passed; ofthe 1,293 African Americans who took the test, just 25percent passed.

    13. The number of people participating in the lotteryis to be adjusted so as to ensure that enough minoritiesare found in the pool from which the new hires will be

    .chosen Kass and OConnor, 1995, A1 . Other storieson the affirmative action process and its consequences

    .in Chicago are provided by Martin 1997, A4 and .Oclander 1995, 22 .

    14arrest reports written by the police . Still,some designers of the new tests defend thechanges: the validity of the cognitive ability

    .test was not high Dunnette et. al. 1996 .The basic economics of these affirmative

    action regulations is fairly straightforward.Voters value many objectives but face lim-ited resources. The question is whether vot-ers were previously discriminating againstcertain politically unfavored groups of poten-tial police officers at the cost of higher crimerates or whether affirmative action laws areforcing departments to accept higher crimerates as the cost of changing hiring policies.

    This article examines the relationship be-tween the changing racial and gender com-position of police departments and the crimerate. As mentioned above, there are possiblyopposing forces, and the net effect is notobvious and it may not be the same for allcrime categories. For example, women policeofficers may deter rapists better than theydeter armed robbers.

    Affirmative action can also affect crimerates in many different ways, for example,through changing the marginal quality ofnew officers or affecting which officers arepromoted and thus altering the incentives ofthe existing police force. If the critics of thenew rules are correct that the replacementsfor cognitive tests simply introduce random-ness into the hiring process, all new officers,and not simply the officers the new testswere designed to encourage, could be oflower quality. After first examining how courtorders altering the hiring and promotionprocess affect the crime rate, this articleseeks to provide a comprehensive picture forhow the changing demographic characteris-tics of police departments affect crime rates.The evidence will try to sort out the differ-ential impact of affirmative action on newhires and the existing police force as well astry to test whether the changes in effective-ness are due to the minority officers that arehired or the changing quality of all officers.

    14. The Washington Post editorial went on to claimthat: Of the murder suspects who are indicted, manyend up being acquitted because of weak cases preparedby police. Washingtons Pretrial Services Agency reportsthat only 44 percent of the murder cases filed in 1990and closed by the first part of 1992 resulted in convic-tions.

  • LOTT: DOES A HELPING HAND PUT OTHERS AT RISK? 243

    Alternative explanations for the resultsare examined, such as whether any observedhigher crime rates merely reflect higher re-porting rates and whether police experiencelevels are affected by the altered hiring poli-cies. I also examine how changing genderand racial compositions alter how police de-partments operate and other measures ofeffectiveness such as arrest rates.

    II. THE CHANGING COMPOSITION OFPOLICE DEPARTMENTS

    During 1987, 1990, and 1993, the U.S.Department of Justice conducted a compre-hensive national survey of state and local lawenforcement agencies with 100 or more of-ficers, known as the Law EnforcementManagement and Administrative Statistics .LEMAS . My study focuses on city policedepartment data because they allow a moreprecise study of the relationship betweenhow police departments were organized andthe crime rate. By contrast, state and countydepartments are more difficult to investigate,because they have jurisdiction over largerbut overlapping areas.

    .I separated the data into two sets: 1 the .entire Justice Department Survey and 2 a

    subset in which demographic data are alsoavailable. The results that I report are con-siderably more significant statistically andimportant empirically when using the entireDepartment of Justice survey, yet I will focuson the subset with the demographic data,because changing demographics are relatedto both the changing hiring patterns by po-lice departments and crime.

    Two characteristics stand out from thesurvey: city police departments vary greatlyin their racial and gender makeup, and therehave been large increases in the proportionof black and women officers. Tables I and IIillustrate these two points, with Table I illus-trating the distribution of the racial and gen-der composition of police departments andTable II examining the distribution of thechange in the composition. The first tableshows that although most departments haveno blacks, Hispanics, or Asians, the range islarge with the tenth and ninetieth percentiledepartments, respectively, employing 0% and18% blacks. The diversity for women officersis not quite as large, ranging from 0% at thetenth percentile to 14% at the ninetieth.

    It is possible to subdivide these categorieseven further, but some of the racial and sexcategories have very small changes in the

    TABLE 1The Race and Gender Composition of Police Departments

    Distribution of Race and Gender Characteristics for Police Departments

    10th Percentile Median 90th Percentile

    Sample for Sample for Sample forWhich Yearly which Yearly which YearlyDemographic Demographic Demographic

    Entire Estimates are Entire Estimates are Entire Estimates areSample available Sample available Sample available

    % of the police 0% 0% 0% 0% .63% 1.5%force that isAsian Pacific% of the police 0% 1.3% 0% 7.8% 18.3% 26%force that is black% of the police 0% 0% 0% 2.1% 8% 14.5%force that isHispanic% of the police 72% 65% 98.5% 85.5% 100% 96.5%force that is white% of the police 86% 86% 97% 91.7% 100% 96.6%force that is male

    Notes: The entire sample has 4,158 city year observations for 1987, 1990 and 1993. The sample for which yearlydemographic estimates are available from the Current Population Survey Contains 664 cityyear observations: 204Police Departments in 1987, 240 in 1990, 220 in 1993.

  • ECONOMIC INQUIRY244

    TABLE IIThe Changing Racial Composition of Police Departments

    Change at the Change at the10th Percentile Change at the Median 90th Percentile

    No Consent Consent No Consent Consent No Consent ConsentDecree Decree Decree Decree Decree Decree

    A. Changes in the Racial Composition of Police Departments With and Without Consent DecreesThat Occurred from 1987 to 1993.Percentage Point .6 .23 0 .2 1.0 1.8Change in the % ofthe Police Force that isAsian PacificPercentage Point 6.8 .2 .73 3.2 6.0 18.2Change in the % ofthe Police Force that isBlackPercentage Point .14 .12 .7 1.1 5.4 7.0Change in the % ofthe Police Force that isHispanicPercentage Point 11.5 21 2.3 5.9 .98 .7Change in the % ofthe Police Force that isWhiteB. Changes in the Sex Composition of Police Departments With and Without Consent Decrees From 1987 to 1993Percentage Point 5.3 6.3 1.1 2.8 6.4 0Change in the % of thePolice Force that isMale

    Notes: Panel A again breaks down the sample on the basis of the complete LEMAS Survey and those cities forwhich information on changing city demographics are available. The table shows the change in the racial and gendercompositions of police departments. The entire sample contains 333 cities without consent decrees for whichinformation is available for the same city for all three years. Twenty one cities with consent decrees meet this criteria.By contrast, the restricted sample that is used for the regressions contains 163 and 19 cities in these two categories,though it provides very similar results.

    Panel B again breaks down the sample on the basis of the complete LEMAS Survey and those cities for whichinformation on changing city demographics are available. The entire sample contains 343 cities without consentdecrees for which information is available for the same city for all three years. Fourteen cities with consent decreesmeet this criteria. By contrast, the restricted sample that is used for the regressions contains 163 and 19 cities in thesetwo categories, though it produces very similar results.

    total number of officers. In my restrictedsample, 189 cities had detailed employmentdata within each race category by sex forboth 1987 and 1990. These cities employed

    .155,071 or 40% of the 387,534 sworn full-time officers employed by local governmentsin 1990. As examples of the small number ofofficers in some of these subgroups, thenumber of male American Indian officersbetween 1987 and 1990 grew from 280 to 378officers; for female American Indians, thechange was from 47 to 91; and for femaleAsian Americans, 83 to 203. Even Hispanicfemales, the next-largest category, saw anincrease of only 378 officers. The number ofmale white officers, the only category to de-cline, fell by 6,912.

    The second table illustrates the differentrates of changes over time as well as theimpact of the consent decrees which theDepartment of Justice entered into with citypolice departments regarding a citys hiringand promotion practices.15 Past work hasstudied the effect of these decrees on hiringof black men and found that indeed they do

    .have an impact Lewis 1989 . The Depart-ment of Justices Civil Rights Division pro-vided information on both racial andorgender-based consent decrees over the pe-

    15. These decrees are contracts that the Departmentof Justice and cities have signed that have been ap-proved by a court, which obligate the city to act incertain ways in the future.

  • LOTT: DOES A HELPING HAND PUT OTHERS AT RISK? 245

    riod from 1972 to 1994: 19 of these 189 citieswere covered by consent decrees during the198793 period, though only three of thesecities had consent decrees that were imposedas late as the end of 1987. The 19 cities wereBirmingham, Ala.; Montgomery, Ala.; LosAngles, Calif.; San Francisco, Calif.; Ft.Lauderdale, Fla.; Pompano Beach, Fla.; Mi-ami, Fla.; Tallahassee, Fla.; Macon, Ga.;Chicago, Ill.; Indianapolis, Ind.; Jackson,Miss.; Omaha, Neb.; Las Vegas, N.V.; Syra-cuse, N. Y. Cincinnati, Ohio.; Philadelphia,Penn.; Memphis, Tenn.; and Milwaukee,Wisc.

    Many cities are adopting affirmative ac-tion rules on their own either because oftheir own support for such rules or becauseof the threat of Justice Department actions.Any examination of consent decrees is thuslikely to underestimate the impact of suchpolicies. Yet, consent decrees appear to haveclear impacts for both blacks and women.The median change in the percent of blackpolice officers was 2.5 percentage points morein cities with consent decrees than thosewithout them, and for women the medianincrease was 1.7 percentage points. Thesemay seem like small changes in the share ofpolice employment going to these groups,but compared to the median percent of blackand women officers over this seven-year pe-riod, these changes represent at least a 57%increase over past employment practices.

    Finally, despite the large difference insample sizes between the entire sample andthe restricted one, both sets experienced re-markably similar changes in types of officersemployed during this seven-year period. Thissimilarity occurs despite the cities in thesmaller sample averaging about 40% morepeople.

    III. EXPLAINING CHANGING CRIME RATESAS A FUNCTION OF THE RACIAL AND

    GENDER COMPOSITION OF POLICEDEPARTMENTS

    The Direct Impact of Consent Decrees

    The FBIs Uniform Crime Report allowsus to study violent and property crimes, with

    seven primary crime categories murder,rape, robbery, aggravated assault, burglary,

    .larceny, and motor vehicle theft , and tenother subcategories manslaughter, forcible

    rape, attempted rape, gun robbery, knife

    robbery, other robbery, strong-arm robbery,assault with a gun, assault with a knife, and

    .other assault . The results from most of thesesubcategories will not be reported, becausethey differ little from the results shown forthe primary categories. Data on arrest ratesfor these broader categories as well as thecity populations were obtained directly fromthe FBI.

    The Current Population Survey was usedto determine the changing demographicmakeup of cities over the 198793 period.The percent of the population in differentdemographic categories was broken down by

    age less than 30 years of age, 3054 years of. age, and 55 and older , race black, white,

    . .and other , and sex male and female , thusyielding 18 demographic categories. This sur-vey also provided information on the averageweekly wage and the unemployment rate.The National Conference of Black Mayorsprovided me with copies of their entire na-tional roster by year so that the race of acitys mayor could be identified. Finally, theLEMAS survey provides information on theracial and gender composition of police de-partments, as well as on the per capita num-ber of sworn police officers, and other de-partmental characteristics. The means andstandard deviations for these variables areshown in the appendix.

    Table III shows simple preliminary regres-sions that use a simple time trend for thenumber of years after a consent decree hasbeen imposed and a similar time trend forthe years before the decree to pick upchanges in before and after trends in crimerates. To do this, I used yearly violent andproperty crime data for 198594 for 495cities, a longer period than is available forthe LEMAS survey. Data prior to 1985 wasnot included because of severe problems withthe consistency between 1984 and 1985 inthe city-level crime data. Two sets of fixedeffects were used for these simple regres-sions: city and year fixed effects and cityfixed effects along with separate year fixedeffects for each state to control for any indi-vidual state trends. These regressions useordinary least squares weighted by city popu-lation. The results for both violent and prop-erty crime rates imply that crime rates weredeclining in cities before consent decreeswere imposed and were rising thereafter.Violent crimes were rising after the consent

  • ECONOMIC INQUIRY246

    TABLE IIIChanges in Crime Rates for Cities with and without Consent Decrees for the Period 198594;

    Using Only Fixed Effects

    Crime Rates Per 100,000 People

    Time Trend for Time Trend forYears before Consent Years after Consent

    Decree Went Into Decree Went Into F-test( ( ( )Effect negative values Effect positive values Prob F

    imply that crime imply that crime that beforewas falling until was rising after and afterthe decree went the decree went time trends Adjacent No. of

    2) )into effect into effect are different R Observations

    Controlling for City and Year Fixed EffectsViolent Crime Rate 138.6 126.1 36.35 .7939 4,947

    .5.3% 4.8% .0000 . .4.204 11.433

    Property Crime Rate 593.4 172.2 57.37 .7719 4,947 .9.4% 2.7% .0000

    . .6.257 9.346Controlling for City Fixed Effects and Separate Year Fixed Effects for Each StateViolent Crime Rate 60.85 86.05 7.10 .8738 4,947

    .2.3% 3.3% .0078 . .1.195 7.901

    Property Crime Rate 464.0 133.76 50.94 .8845 4,947 .7.4% 2.1% .0000

    . .5.998 8.085

    Notes: The first number is the annual change in crimes per 100,000 people, while the second number is the changeas a percent of the mean crime rate. Absolute t-statistics are shown in parentheses. The regressions use weightedleast squares.

    decrees by at least 3.3% per year, and forproperty crimes it was at least 2.1% per year.The differences in trends are all statisticallysignificant at the .01 level.

    Given the significant declines in precon-sent decree crime rates, the results for threeof the four regressions raise the questionabout whether the decrees just happen to beimposed when the crime rates were at theirlow ebb and the post-decree increase is sim-ply a result of mean reversion. At least forthe cities with new consent decrees imposedduring 1987, the increases in violent crimeduring the period studied are 2.4 to 3.7 timeslarger than preceeding declines and thus ex-ceed any increase that could simply be at-tributed to mean reversion.16 The evidence

    16. I tried a regression that predicted which citieswould have consent decrees imposed on them. The mostimportant factors were city size, whether the city wasthe largest in a state, and the type of administration.Republican presidential administrations tended to im-pose consent decrees on relatively Democratic states,whereas Democrat presidential administrations tendedto impose consent decrees on relatively Republicanstates.

    is not clear cut for property crimes, wherethe declines and increases are of approxi-mately equal size.

    Using the smaller sample that matchesthe LEMAS survey and just the time trendfor years after the imposition of the consentdecree produces similar, though smaller andless statistically significant increases in crime.Controlling for changing city-level demo-graphics as well as the average weekly wage,unemployment, per capita number of policeofficers, city population, and populationsquared, and city and year fixed effects im-

    plies: violent crime rises by 1.9% t-statistic. 2.16 and property crime by 2.1% t-statis-

    .tic 2.99 for each additional year the con-sent decree is in effect.

    Figure 1 reports this same data slightlydifferently by including separate dummyvariables for the years before and after theimposition of the consent decree. The yearsincluded range from three years before thedecree to year 4 afterward, with anotherdummy variable that equals one for years 5or more after the decree. The estimates use

  • LOTT: DOES A HELPING HAND PUT OTHERS AT RISK? 247

    FIGURE 1Using Year Dummies for the Years

    before and after the Implementation ofa Consent Decree

    the full sample and correspond to thoseshown in Table III that account for city fixedeffects as well as separate year fixed effectsfor each state. The pattern is similar to thatimplied by the table with crime rates fallingimmediately before the consent decree is

    imposed and rising after that. Recently, ex-tending this data set back to 1977 and ex-panding the number of years studied by seven

    produced similar results Lott 2000, chapter. .9 .

    An Initial Assessment of How Consent DecreesAffect Crime through the Typeof Officers Hired

    Consent decrees change hiring policies,and changing hiring policies may affect thecrime rate. The consent decrees favor somegroups more than others, but the link be-tween these group-specific changes and the

    crime rate are unclear. Even if the new hir-ing procedures introduce randomness, thedistribution of skills is not necessarily thesame across potential applicants in all groups.To make matters more complicated, the typesof officers hired may depend on the crimerate. For example, if departments hired mi-norities because of growing crime problemsin minority areas or hired women because ofgreater crimes against women, simple ordi-nary least squares estimates risk improperlyblaming some of the higher crime rates onthe new police who were hired to help solvethe problem.17 To explain this problem dif-ferently, crime rates may have risen eventhough a city hired black officers, and if theyhad hired white officers who were less capa-ble of policing minority areas, the crime ratecould have risen by even more. Unfortu-nately, an alternative explanation exists:higher crime rates may signal less concern bycity governments about crime and thus agreater willingness to indulge other objec-tives when hiring police officers.18

    The opposite relationship between crimerates and hiring practices is also possible.Additional law enforcement efforts have agreater effect on crime in high-crime areas .Lott and Mustard 1997, 28, 29 . If affir-mative action actually increases crime, high-crime areas would find it more costly toengage in affirmative action, and thus, every-thing else equal, one suspects that they wouldengage in less such hiring. Failure to controlfor why the particular composition of policeofficers was chosen would underestimate thenegative impact from this policy.

    To guard against this problem, I initiallyemploy two-stage least squares where thefirst equation attempts to explain the propor-

    tion of black, minority black, Hispanic, and.American Indian , or male officers employed

    17. While the hiring of minority officers is motivatedby the desire to assign these new officers to minorityneighborhoods, the legal prohibition against giving of-ficers assignments based on their race require that anynew minority officers be evenly distributed across dis-tricts. It is very easy for minority officers to bringdiscrimination suits if they feel that they are beingdisproportionately assigned to more dangerous neigh-borhoods. Black officers have no more desire than whiteofficers to be assigned to dangerous high crime areas.For another perspective with respect to New York City,

    .see Fyfe 1981 .18. There are also questions about whether some

    officers have stronger preferences for policing certaintypes of communities based on their level of crime.

  • ECONOMIC INQUIRY248

    by a city. As discussed in Section II, I expectthat the imposition of a consent decree and,particularly, the length of time that the de-cree has been in effect to serve as the instru-ments and help explain the levels of minorityor female employment, depending on whattype of employment the consent decree dealswith. The number of years that a consentdecree has been in effect is an excellentinstrument since it is extremely unlikely thatthe causation runs from future crime rates tothe number of years since a consent decreehas been entered. I also account for thedemographic composition of the citys popu-lation; the average weekly wage and unem-ployment rate; whether its mayor was black;the citys population and population squared;and the per capita number of sworn policeofficers. The second equation that explainseach one of the individual crime rates in-cluded all the variables except for whetherthere was the consent decree and the mayorsrace. Weighted least squares, where the esti-mates were weighted by city population, wasused to deal with heteroskedasticity.19

    The coefficients on the percent of thepolice force that is black, minority, or malein the second regression are thus adding theimpact on the crime rate of the consentdecree together with that particular groupbeing studied. I will disaggregate these twoeffects later when I report the reduced formregressions in Table VIII and Appendix 2.Because the instruments that I have for racialor gender hiring consent decrees are veryheavily correlated, the impacts of the racialand gender compositions of police depart-ments are initially estimated separately forthese two-stage least squares regressions.

    Admittedly, there are many location-specific and year-specific differences in crimerates that are not captured by the variablescontrolling for demographic, income, andpopulation differences. One simple way ofdealing with this is the use of location andtime fixed effects, where a separate dummyvariable is used for each city and year. How-ever, this approach also has its drawbacks:although it may correctly measure left-outvariables, it may also cause us to falsely

    19. Similar estimates are produced if unweightedestimates are employed, but these data exhibit definiteheteroskedasticity, with the smaller cities reporting amuch greater variation in crime rates over time.

    attribute some of the impact of changes inour in our other variables for example, the

    impact of changing racial or gender composi-.tion of police departments to these fixed

    effects. Nevertheless, all the regressions re-port either city and year fixed effects orcounty fixed effects with separate year fixedeffects for each state.20

    As an example, the two-stage least squaresestimates examining the percentage of thepolice force that is black with city and yearfixed effects take the following form:

    .1 % Police Force That Is Black g Consent Decree in

    Effect, Number of Years Decree inEffect, Dummy for Whether Mayor IsBlack, Per Capita Number ofSworn Officers, Citys DemographicComposition, Population andPopulation Squared, AverageWeekly Wage, Unemployment Rate,Fixed Year and City

    .Effects . .2 In Crime Rate

    f % Police Force That Is Black,Per Capita Number of Sworn Officers,Citys Demographic Composition,Population and Population Squared,Average Weekly Wage, Unemployment

    .Rate, Fixed Year and City Effects

    The results from the second equation arereported in Table IV separated out by thetype of fixed effects employed. All crime

    20. I tried three different types of location fixedeffects: city, county, and state. Generally, using thebroader measures of location produced estimates thatagreed in sign with the city fixed effects, but the esti-mates were larger and more statistically significant. Todeal with possible state-level trends in laws, I also triedallowing a separate fixed effect for each state for eachyear, though when combined with county or city fixedeffects this dramatically reduces the degrees of freedomin each regression. Only the time-varying state fixedeffects are reported with the county fixed effects be-cause none of the estimates on any of the focus orcontrol coefficients was statistically significant with cityfixed effects.

  • LOTT: DOES A HELPING HAND PUT OTHERS AT RISK? 249

    rates are in natural logs, where .1 is added tozero values before the natural log is taken.With the exception of manslaughter, aggra-vated assault, and motor vehicle theft, anincrease in the percentage of a police forcethat is black is consistently associated withsignificant increases in crime. The effect is solarge that 18 of the specifications imply thata one standard deviation change in the per-cent of the police force that is black in-creases the corresponding crime rates by at

    least 5% of its mean value see the percent-.ages listed next to the coefficients . The ef-

    fects are dramatic no matter how one exam-ines these estimates. For example, increasingblack officers share by one percentage pointincreases property crimes by 4%, and thesame increase raises the murder rate by 1.9%and overall violent crime by 4.8%. As therelative median increase in black officersshare of police departments over this seven-year period because of consent decrees was2.5 pge points, I conclude that if nothing elsehad changed, the average citys murder ratewould have risen by 4.7%.21

    One point should be made very clear atthis point. We are talking about the impacton crime of hiring additional blacks, manyof whom would not have been hired withoutthe consent decree. As mentioned in theintroduction, changes in testing that are usedto encourage hiring more minorities can ex-plain why these blacks are not of the samequality as previously hired blacks. It can stillbe true that qualified black officers are moreeffective but that the new less-qualified of-

    21. One concern raised to me by Ed Glaeser iswhether the results are being driven solely by time-serieschanges in the data and whether these results are con-sistent across the years being studied. To test this, Ireran the regressions shown in Table IV with fixed stateeffects separately on the data for each of the threedifferent years. For blacks the coefficient signs are simi-lar to those already reported, though the results forthese smaller subsets of data are not always statisticallysignificant. The results for 1987 are as follows: for

    .violent crimes the coefficient is 4.3 t-stat 1.822 ; .property crimes, 3.34 t-stat 1.811 ; and murder 5.52

    .t-stat 1.254 . The results for 1990 are as follows: for .violent crimes the coefficient is 3.08 t-stat 1.071 ;

    .property crimes, 5.46 t-stat 2.358 ; and murder, 3.45 .t-stat 0.872 . The results for 1993 are as follows: for

    .violent crimes the coefficient is 3.025 t-stat 1.900 ; .property crimes, 2.509 t-stat 2.847 ; and murder,

    .1.711 t-stat 0.815 . Similar results are also producedfor the percentage male and the percentage minorityspecifications.

    ficers are associated with more crime. Thelarge impact suggests that more than just thequality of new minority recruits or new mi-nority promotions is affected. Changing teststo employ a greater percentage of blacks canmake it more difficult to screen out lower-quality candidates generally, including whitesand other racial groups. Independent of theconsent decree, the size of the change inblack employment may thus proxy forchanges in the level of standards used to hireemployees in general. Similarly, changingpromotion rules that favor seniority overachievement can affect morale and incen-tives across all categories of police officers.

    For the next set of regressions, blacks,Hispanics, and American Indians were com-bined to represent the share of minorities ina department. The groups included in theminority classification was decided by using aseries of reduced-form equations where Itested to see whether the predicted impactof the different racial groups were statisti-cally different from each other. Generally,the coefficients for blacks, Hispanics, andAmerican Indians were not statistically dif-ferent from each other, and the whites andAsians usually fit together in a separategroup.22 More precisely, whites and Asians

    22. More precisely, when the omitted group in the .reduced form regression represented by the intercept

    is Hispanics, the probability that the coefficients forwhites and Asians are statistically significantly differentfrom each other at the following levels as: for violentcrimes is 34%; property crimes, 73%; murder, 39%;manslaughter, 41%; rape, 78%; forcible rape, 79%; at-tempted rape, 5.6%; robbery, 31%; gun robbery, 15%;knife robbery, 4.9%; other robbery, 0%; strong-armrobbery, 79%; assault, 66%; burglary, 77%; larceny,68%; and motor vehicle theft, 98%. The probability thatthe coefficients for blacks and Hispanics are statisticallysignificantly different from each other is: for violentcrimes it is 36%; property crimes, 51%; murder, 14%;manslaughter, 37%; rape, 77%; forcible rape, 56%; at-tempted rape, 73%; robbery, 1.6%; gun robbery, 1.5%;knife robbery, 46%; other robbery, 56%; strong-armrobbery, 74%; assault, 99%; burglary, 3%; larceny, 60%;and motor vehicle theft, 22%. The probability that thecoefficients for blacks and whites are statistically signif-icantly different from each other is: for violent crimes itis 5%; property crimes, 4.5%; murder, .12%; manslaugh-ter, .01%; rape, 43%; forcible rape, 39%; attemptedrape, 57%; robbery, .16%; gun robbery, .37%; kniferobbery, 58%; other robbery, 8%; strong-arm robbery,62%; assault, 3%; burglary, 6%; larceny, 34%; andmotor vehicle theft, .17%. State fixed effects were usedfor these estimates. A related set of regressions isreported in Section VII, though these regressions do nothave all these categories included at the same time.

  • ECONOMIC INQUIRY250

    TA

    BL

    EIV

    Usi

    ngT

    wo-

    Stag

    eL

    east

    Squa

    res

    toT

    ake

    Into

    Acc

    ount

    the

    Impa

    ctT

    hatC

    onse

    ntD

    ecre

    esan

    dth

    ePr

    esen

    ceof

    aB

    lack

    May

    orH

    ave

    onth

    eC

    ompo

    sitio

    nof

    Polic

    eD

    epar

    tmen

    ts

    %of

    the

    Pol

    ice

    For

    ceth

    atis

    (%

    ofth

    eP

    olic

    eF

    orce

    Min

    orit

    yB

    lack

    ,His

    pani

    c,%

    ofth

    eP

    olic

    eF

    orce

    )th

    atis

    Bla

    ckan

    dA

    mer

    ican

    Indi

    anth

    atis

    Mal

    e

    Cou

    nty

    Fix

    edC

    ount

    yF

    ixed

    Cou

    nty

    Fix

    edE

    ffec

    tsan

    dE

    ffec

    tsan

    dE

    ffec

    tsan

    dSe

    para

    teY

    ear

    Sepa

    rate

    Yea

    rSe

    para

    teY

    ear

    Fix

    edE

    ffec

    tsC

    ity

    and

    Yea

    rF

    ixed

    Eff

    ects

    Cit

    yan

    dY

    ear

    Cit

    yan

    dY

    ear

    Fix

    edE

    ffec

    tsfo

    rea

    chSt

    ate

    Fix

    edE

    ffec

    tsfo

    rea

    chSt

    ate

    Fix

    edE

    ffec

    tsF

    ixed

    Eff

    ects

    for

    each

    Stat

    e(

    )(

    )(

    )(

    )(

    )(

    )1

    23

    45

    6

    coef

    fici

    ent

    %of

    coef

    fici

    ent

    %of

    coef

    fici

    ent

    %of

    coef

    fici

    ent

    %of

    Coe

    ffici

    ent

    %of

    Coe

    ffici

    ent

    %of

    Cri

    me

    and

    t-m

    ean

    and

    t-m

    ean

    and

    t-m

    ean

    and

    t-m

    ean

    and

    t-m

    ean

    and

    t-m

    ean

    Rat

    esSt

    atis

    tic

    expl

    aine

    dSt

    atis

    tic

    expl

    aine

    dSt

    atis

    tic

    expl

    aine

    dSt

    atis

    tic

    expl

    aine

    dSt

    atis

    tic

    expl

    aine

    dSt

    atis

    tic

    expl

    aine

    d

    Vio

    lent

    4.79

    8%7.

    1412

    %3.

    016%

    6.06

    813

    %

    8.19

    9%

    10.2

    812

    %

    .

    .

    .

    .

    .

    .cr

    ime

    2.38

    3.57

    2.52

    3.85

    1.97

    1.67

    Prop

    erty

    4.27

    5%3.

    965%

    2.58

    4%3.

    205%

    6.

    425%

    6.

    576%

    .

    .

    .

    .

    .

    .

    crim

    e2.

    513.

    082.

    593.

    181.

    181.

    69M

    urde

    r1.

    8711

    %9.

    4356

    %1.

    4611

    %8.

    0361

    %

    6.41

    26%

    8.

    2633

    %

    .

    .

    .

    .

    .

    .1.

    642.

    881.

    823.

    200.

    961.

    18M

    an6.

    3940

    %6.

    3339

    %2.

    5020

    %5.

    8446

    %

    13.0

    655

    %

    3.69

    15%

    .

    .

    .

    .

    .

    .

    slau

    ghte

    r0.

    781.

    110.

    511.

    310.

    860.

    35R

    ape

    13.2

    741

    %4.

    0712

    %5.

    9723

    %3.

    1412

    %

    8.98

    19%

    6.

    6714

    %

    .

    .

    .

    .

    .

    .1.

    781.

    981.

    421.

    960.

    731.

    37T

    otal

    7.86

    16%

    9.55

    20%

    4.57

    12%

    7.67

    20%

    11

    .06

    15%

    13

    .53

    19%

    .

    .

    .

    .

    .

    .

    robb

    ery

    3.07

    4.08

    3.18

    4.25

    1.22

    1.78

    Tot

    al2.

    104%

    6.06

    11%

    1.83

    4%5.

    5513

    %

    6.64

    8%

    8.54

    10%

    .

    .

    .

    .

    .

    .

    assa

    ult

    0.90

    2.71

    1.30

    3.13

    1.07

    1.44

    Bur

    glar

    y7.

    0511

    %6.

    199%

    3.99

    8%4.

    999

    10%

    9.

    239%

    10

    .45

    11%

    .

    .

    .

    .

    .

    .

    3.12

    3.88

    3.23

    3.95

    1.22

    1.79

    Lar

    ceny

    4.83

    6%3.

    535%

    3.24

    5%3.

    055%

    8.

    688%

    6.

    386%

    .

    .

    .

    .

    .

    .

    2.76

    2.77

    3.10

    3.01

    1.24

    1.69

    Mot

    or

    0.81

    1%6.

    3011

    %

    1.11

    2%4.

    6610

    %3.

    794%

    7.

    088%

    .

    .

    .

    .

    .

    .

    vehi

    cle

    0.34

    2.69

    0.76

    2.57

    0.81

    1.34

    thef

    tF

    elon

    ious

    4.

    2620

    %5.

    8228

    %

    4.39

    27%

    3.84

    622

    %11

    .96

    29%

    10

    .31

    35%

    .

    .

    .

    .

    .

    .

    killi

    ngs

    of1.

    222.

    231.

    992.

    141.

    311.

    58po

    lice

    offic

    ers

  • LOTT: DOES A HELPING HAND PUT OTHERS AT RISK? 251

    TA

    BL

    EIV

    Usi

    ngT

    wo-

    Stag

    eL

    east

    Squa

    res

    toT

    ake

    Into

    Acc

    ount

    the

    Impa

    ctT

    hatC

    onse

    ntD

    ecre

    esan

    dth

    ePr

    esen

    ceof

    aB

    lack

    May

    orH

    ave

    onth

    eC

    ompo

    sitio

    nof

    Polic

    eD

    epar

    tmen

    ts

    %of

    the

    Pol

    ice

    For

    ceth

    atis

    (%

    ofth

    eP

    olic

    eF

    orce

    Min

    orit

    yB

    lack

    ,His

    pani

    c,%

    ofth

    eP

    olic

    eF

    orce

    )th

    atis

    Bla

    ckan

    dA

    mer

    ican

    Indi

    anth

    atis

    Mal

    e

    Cou

    nty

    Fix

    edC

    ount

    yF

    ixed

    Cou

    nty

    Fix

    edE

    ffec

    tsan

    dE

    ffec

    tsan

    dE

    ffec

    tsan

    dSe

    para

    teY

    ear

    Sepa

    rate

    Yea

    rSe

    para

    teY

    ear

    Fix

    edE

    ffec

    tsC

    ity

    and

    Yea

    rF

    ixed

    Eff

    ects

    Cit

    yan

    dY

    ear

    Cit

    yan

    dY

    ear

    Fix

    edE

    ffec

    tsfo

    rea

    chSt

    ate

    Fix

    edE

    ffec

    tsfo

    rea

    chSt

    ate

    Fix

    edE

    ffec

    tsF

    ixed

    Eff

    ects

    for

    each

    Stat

    e(

    )(

    )(

    )(

    )(

    )(

    )1

    23

    45

    6

    coef

    fici

    ent

    %of

    coef

    fici

    ent

    %of

    coef

    fici

    ent

    %of

    coef

    fici

    ent

    %of

    Coe

    ffici

    ent

    %of

    Coe

    ffici

    ent

    %of

    Cri

    me

    and

    t-m

    ean

    and

    t-m

    ean

    and

    t-m

    ean

    and

    t-m

    ean

    and

    t-m

    ean

    and

    t-m

    ean

    Rat

    esSt

    atis

    tic

    expl

    aine

    dSt

    atis

    tic

    expl

    aine

    dSt

    atis

    tic

    expl

    aine

    dSt

    atis

    tic

    expl

    aine

    dSt

    atis

    tic

    expl

    aine

    dSt

    atis

    tic

    expl

    aine

    d

    Ass

    aults

    on78

    .14

    128%

    .823

    1%61

    .84

    131%

    6.35

    13%

    18

    .716

    %

    15.3

    118

    %

    .

    .

    .

    .

    .

    .po

    lice

    3.49

    .095

    4.47

    1.00

    1.89

    1.69

    offic

    ers

    Acc

    iden

    tal

    .5

    433%

    .315

    1%

    .097

    1%

    .179

    1%

    2.00

    5%

    4.80

    16%

    .

    .

    .

    .

    .

    .

    deat

    hsof

    0.29

    .242

    .083

    .190

    .742

    1.60

    polic

    eof

    ficer

    s

    .

    Not

    es:

    The

    regr

    essi

    ones

    timat

    esfo

    req

    uatio

    n2

    for

    the

    two-

    stag

    ele

    ast

    squa

    res

    that

    are

    repo

    rted

    abov

    eac

    coun

    tfo

    rth

    esa

    me

    vari

    able

    sco

    ntro

    lled

    for

    inth

    efir

    st-s

    tage

    regr

    essi

    onex

    cept

    for

    the

    cons

    ent

    decr

    ee,t

    henu

    mbe

    rof

    year

    ssi

    nce

    the

    cons

    ent

    decr

    eew

    ent

    into

    effe

    ct,a

    ndw

    heth

    erth

    eci

    tys

    May

    oris

    blac

    k,w

    hich

    wer

    ein

    stea

    din

    clud

    edin

    th

    efir

    st-s

    tage

    regr

    essi

    on.T

    heot

    her

    vari

    able

    sco

    ntro

    lled

    for

    wer

    eth

    epe

    rcen

    tage

    ofth

    epo

    pula

    tion

    indi

    ffer

    ent

    dem

    ogra

    phic

    cate

    gori

    esth

    atw

    ere

    brok

    endo

    wn

    byag

    ele

    ssth

    an.

    .

    .

    30ye

    ars

    ofag

    e,30

    54ye

    ars

    ofag

    e,an

    d55

    and

    olde

    r,r

    ace

    blac

    k,w

    hite

    ,and

    othe

    r,a

    ndse

    xm

    ale

    and

    fem

    ale

    soth

    atth

    isin

    form

    atio

    nw

    asav

    aila

    ble

    for

    18ca

    tego

    ries

    ,th

    eav

    erag

    ew

    eekl

    yw

    age,

    the

    unem

    ploy

    men

    trat

    e,an

    dci

    typo

    pula

    tion

    and

    popu

    latio

    nsq

    uare

    d.T

    heab

    solu

    tet-s

    tatis

    tics

    are

    show

    nin

    the

    pare

    nthe

    ses

    belo

    wth

    eco

    effic

    ient

    estim

    ate,

    with

    the

    perc

    ent

    ofth

    een

    doge

    nous

    vari

    able

    sm

    ean

    that

    can

    beex

    plai

    ned

    bya

    one-

    stan

    dard

    -dev

    iatio

    nch

    ange

    inth

    eex

    ogen

    ous

    vari

    able

    show

    nin

    the

    adja

    cent

    colu

    mn.

    All

    regr

    essi

    ons

    use

    wei

    ghte

    dle

    ast

    squa

    res

    whe

    reth

    eva

    riab

    les

    are

    wei

    ghte

    dby

    the

    city

    popu

    latio

    n.F

    orth

    epe

    rcen

    tage

    ofof

    ficer

    sth

    atar

    ebl

    ack

    orm

    inor

    ity,t

    hesa

    mpl

    esi

    zes

    is64

    1an

    dco

    vers

    the

    year

    s19

    87,1

    990,

    and

    1993

    .For

    the

    perc

    ent

    ofof

    ficer

    sth

    atar

    em

    ale

    over

    that

    peri

    od,t

    hesa

    mpl

    esi

    zeis

    648.

  • ECONOMIC INQUIRY252

    had different effects on crime in only threeof the 19 crime categories when the broad-

    .est set of categories was used , whereasblacks and Hispanics were statistically dif-ferent in five cases. In the three cases wherewhites and Asians differed in their impact on

    crime attempted rape, knife robbery, and.other robbery , Asians had a greater deter-

    rent impact on crime. Hiring additional His-panics and American Indians did not tend toincrease crime by the magnitude shown byhiring additional black officers.

    The two-stage least square estimates con-tinue to confirm this pattern. Putting to-gether blacks, Hispanics, and American Indi-ans continued to produce very similar, thoughsmaller, results compared to what I foundfor blacks alone. The minority portion of apolice force in column 3 explains about75%80% as much of the percent of themean violent and property crimes as did theregressions in column 1 for the percent ofthe police force that is black. Nineteen ofthe 20 crime regressions imply that increas-ing the percentage share of minorities in adepartment increase crime, and the relation-ship is statistically significant for three-quarters of the estimates.

    The last two columns in Table IV implythat increasing the share of males in thepolice force decreases crime in 19 of the 20specifications shown, though the aggregateproperty crime category implies a statisticallysignificant relationship only for the timevarying state fixed effects that include thecounty fixed effects. The specifications formurder, manslaughter, and rape provide nosignificant evidence that increasing womensshare of the police force increases thesecrimes. Using either simple county or stateand year fixed effects produces a much moreconsistent negative relationship betweenhigher males shares of the police force andcrime.23

    23. Limits on the number of variables that could behandled using two-stage least-squares with STATA re-stricted the regressions on the larger data set to the

    state fixed effects specifications. This is the data setthat was not restricted to those cities for which demo-

    .graphic data was available. Estimates using these dataremain similar to those already reported in Table IV.The sample size for this larger data set is 1,015 observa-tions for the regressions explaining the percentage ofthe police force that is black or minority and 1,026 forthe percentage of the police force that is male.

    Table V reports some of the first equationresults from the two-stage least squares esti-mation of the percent of the police forcethat is black, minority, or male used in theregressions analyzing violent crime with cityfixed effects. The results imply that for theracial components, the number of years thata consent decree has been in effect dramati-cally increases the percentage of minoritiesin police forces. Every 10 years after theconsent decree goes into effect increases thenumber of blacks by another 4.1 percentagepoints and minorities by 4.8 percentagepoints. These results are comparable in mag-nitude with those shown in Table II. I alsotried these estimates with a squared term forthe number of years that the consent decreehad been in effect, but including this did notnoticeably alter the results. One city in thesample had consent decrees as long as 21

    years with both the sample median and the.mean being about 10 years , and the esti-

    mates indicate the percentage of the policeforce that is black is still rising at that time.

    Interestingly, the election of a black mayordoes not appear to significantly change thenumber of minority police officers, with thecorresponding coefficient even being nega-tive is the minorities specification. There isalso surprisingly little relationship betweenpast crime rates and the composition of thepolice force, and the t-statistics are quitesmall. Only past violent crimes imply moreblacks on a police force with a t-statisticeven greater than 1. The Hausman endo-geneity test indicates that the numberof years a consent decree is in effect is avalid instrument for the black and minorityregressions.

    A possible concern with these results isthat the consent decree not only directlyaffects the number of minorities or womenwho are hired but may also implicitly signalconcerns about future crime rates. If oneexpects that higher crime rates can be bestcombated with more minority police officers,there is also the concern that this motivatedthe adoption of the consent decree. Whilethis is possible, it is not clear why the De-partment of Justice has better informationon a particular citys future crime rate thanthe city itself. In any case, as a check, Ireestimated the regressions in Table IV by

  • LOTT: DOES A HELPING HAND PUT OTHERS AT RISK? 253

    TA

    BL

    EV

    Exp

    lain

    ing

    the

    Perc

    enta

    geof

    the

    Polic

    eF

    orce

    that

    isB

    lack

    ,Min

    ority

    ,or

    Mal

    e:

    .T

    heR

    egre

    ssio

    nsfo

    rE

    quat

    ion

    2fo

    rth

    eC

    ityan

    dY

    ear

    Fix

    edE

    ffec

    tsR

    egre

    ssio

    nsin

    Tab

    leIV

    .

    Con

    sent

    Dec

    ree

    Dum

    my

    ( adi

    ffer

    ent

    dum

    my

    Num

    ber

    ofY

    ears

    that

    isus

    edfo

    rw

    heth

    erC

    onse

    ntD

    ecre

    eIs

    inE

    ffec

    t(

    the

    cons

    ent

    decr

    eein

    volv

    esco

    nsen

    tde

    cree

    sin

    volv

    ing

    race

    sex

    orra

    ceca

    ses

    and

    sex

    are

    sepa

    rate

    dou

    t(

    and

    ism

    atch

    edw

    ith

    and

    are

    mat

    ched

    wit

    hth

    eC

    ity

    Has

    lnV

    iole

    ntC

    rim

    eth

    eap

    prop

    riat

    ere

    gres

    sion

    appr

    opri

    ate

    regr

    essi

    onli

    sted

    aB

    lack

    Rat

    epe

    r2

    ))

    )li

    sted

    belo

    wbe

    low

    May

    or10

    0,00

    0pe

    ople

    F-S

    tati

    stic

    Adj

    acen

    tR

    %of

    the

    polic

    e.0

    14.0

    041

    .0

    0028

    .0

    100

    53.4

    6.9

    581

    .

    .

    .

    .

    forc

    eth

    atis

    1.00

    33.

    289

    .049

    1.73

    1bl

    ack

    %of

    the

    polic

    e.0

    556

    .004

    8

    .001

    8

    .008

    940

    .26

    .944

    6

    .

    .

    .

    .fo

    rce

    that

    is2.

    150

    2.89

    90.

    237

    1.14

    5

    min

    ority

    blac

    k,hi

    span

    ic,a

    ndo

    ram

    eric

    anin

    dian

    %of

    the

    polic

    e

    .031

    .0

    015

    .0

    026

    .0

    061

    2.15

    .330

    7

    .

    .

    .

    .fo

    rce

    that

    is0.

    708

    0.44

    50.

    192

    0.22

    2m

    ale N

    otes

    :The

    regr

    essi

    ons

    liste

    dab

    ove

    repr

    esen

    tju

    stth

    ree

    ofth

    edi

    ffer

    ent

    first

    -sta

    gere

    gres

    sion

    s.In

    addi

    tion

    toth

    ela

    gged

    viol

    ent

    and

    prop

    erty

    .

    crim

    era

    tes,

    the

    regr

    essi

    ons

    from

    equa

    tion

    2al

    soin

    clud

    edal

    lth

    eth

    eot

    her

    vari

    able

    slis

    ted

    for

    the

    wei

    ghte

    dle

    ast

    squa

    res

    estim

    ates

    .The

    fixed

    effe

    cts

    used

    inth

    edi

    ffer

    ent

    first

    -sta

    gere

    gres

    sion

    sco

    rres

    pond

    edw

    ithth

    ose

    used

    inth

    ese

    cond

    stag

    e.T

    hees

    timat

    esre

    port

    edab

    ove

    use

    city

    and

    year

    fixed

    effe

    cts.

  • ECONOMIC INQUIRY254

    including the consent decree dummy vari-able directly into the second equation thatestimates the crime rate. This change hasvirtually no effect on the results reportedpreviously. As a further test of the sensitivityof the results, I also tried reestimating theresults in Table IV by removing the crimerate variables from the first equation and thepattern of results remained similar to thosealready reported.24

    The question of whether more black po-lice officers had a differential impact in moreheavily black areas can be examined by in-teracting the percent of the police force thatis black with the percent of the populationthat is black. The violent and property crimeestimates corresponding to the regressions inTable IV, and the estimates that did notinclude the crime rates in the first regressionall imply that the increase in crime from hiringblack officers is greatest in communities withthe most blacks. For example, the violent andproperty crime estimates that correspond tocity fixed effects estimates in Table IV arepositive and have t-statistics of 4.8 and 4.2,respectively.

    Finally, data on whether a police depart-ment was unionized and the gross salary paidper sworn officer were available, though foronly 1987 and 1990. Using these two vari-ables and the smaller data set, I reestimatedthe results reported in Table IV and foundvery little change in results. For the mostpart neither of these variables was significantin explaining changes in the crime rate.

    24. For example, after excluding the crime ratesfrom the first-stage regression, the city fixed effectsregressions produced estimates for the percentage of

    .the police force that is black of 2.43 t-statistic 1.741 .for violent crimes and 2.25 t-statistic 1.864 for prop-

    erty crimes. For the percentage of the police force thatis minority, the city fixed effect results were: 1.98 t-sta-

    . tistic 1.810 for violent crimes and 1.86 t-statistic .2.055 for property crimes. For the percentage of the

    police force that is male, the city fixed effect results .were: 7.73 t-statistic 1.012 for violent crimes and

    .7.9 t-statistic 1.042 for property crimes. As wastrue in Table IV, the level of significance tended to behigher for county fixed effect regressions. The first-stageregression results also remain similar to those alreadyreported. For the regression estimating the percentageof the police force that is black, the consent decree

    .coefficient is .017 t-statistics .899 and the number of .years that it is in effect is .0042 t-statistic 3.376 . For

    the regression for minorities, the consent decree coef- .ficient is .059 t-statistics 2.274 and the number of

    .years that it is in effect is .0049 t-statistic 2.962 . Forthe regression for males, the coefficients are again sta-tistically insignificant.

    IV. ARE HIGHER CRIME RATES A RESULTOF LESS-EFFECTIVE POLICE OR GREATER

    REPORTING RATES?

    Unfortunately, the FBIs Uniform CrimeReport Data relies on reported, not actual,crimes. The problem is potentially critical forthis study, because the racial or gender char-acteristics of the police officers could eitherbe altering the behavior of criminals andorthe rate at which victims report crimes. Theproblem is made even worse by the fact thatboth sides of the debate can provide expla-nations for the preceding results. Those fa-voring affirmative action can argue that thehigher reported crime rates when more mi-norities are hired implies that the commu-nity feels more comfortable about report-ing crimes. In contrast, those who believethat lower standards mainly result in less-qualified officers can say that the resultsconfirm the poor performance of the less-qualified officers.

    There are several ways of investigatingwhether the results are being driven byhigher reporting rates. The simplest ap-proach is to look at murder and manslaugh-ter, where underreporting is essentiallynonexistent. Thus, the race or sex of thepolice officer does not produce additionalreporting. For both murder and manslaugh-ter, the results are very consistent. Moreminority, black, or female officers are associ-ated with higher murder and manslaughterrates, while more white and male officersimply fewer deaths. These two crimes arealso the most accurately reported for an-other reason: if multiple offenses are perpe-trated at the same time, only the most seri-ous offense is reported. Thus, if an armedrobbery resulted in murder, only the murderand not the robbery is recorded.

    Further, the importance of the reportingproblem should vary systematically acrosscrime categories as the loss from the crimevaries. For example, suppose that a blackperson is making a decision on whether toreport a theft to a predominantly white po-lice department. His decision to report thecrime depends on the value of the itemstolen, the probability that the item will berecovered, and the cost involved in going tothe police station, including whatever diffi-culties might arise in how the black manmight be treated by white police officers.The victim would only report crimes where

  • LOTT: DOES A HELPING HAND PUT OTHERS AT RISK? 255

    either the value of the item stolen or theprobability of recovery is relatively high.Lowering the cost of the black person report-ing the crime by introducing more black of-ficers would result in more reporting of rela-tively low-value, low-probability-of-detectioncrimes. Since the cost of making the com-plaint constitutes a much bigger percentageof the return to acting on relatively smallharms, actions that reduce those costs have amuch bigger effect on reporting minorcrimes.

    For at least broad categories of propertycrimes it is possible to make this comparison.

    .Miller, Cohen, and Wiersema 1996 claimedthat in 1992 the average larceny involvedproperty loss of $270, burglary $970, andauto theft $3,300. By comparison, the dif-ferences in the arrest rates are small: larceny30%, burglary 21%, and auto theft 25%.These figures would imply that the biggestincrease in reporting from changing the racialmix of police should occur for larceny, next

    for burglary, and least for auto theft. Autotheft and burglary should also tend to haverelatively high reporting rates compared tolarceny simply because these crimes must bereported as a condition of obtaining reim-

    .bursement from insurance companies. Yet,all of the two-stage least squares estimates inTable IV indicate that the racial or gendercompositions of the police department havealways smaller impacts on larceny than onburglary, and half the time the impact onlarceny is smaller than on auto theft. Noneof the estimates are consistent with the ear-lier results arising from increased reportingrates.

    V. DISAGGREGATING FURTHER BY RACEAND SEX

    For 1987 and 1990, the Department ofJustice survey determined the percent of eachracial group that was male or female. Thetwo-stage least squares regressions reportedearlier were therefore reestimated with twochanges: the previous racial or sex break-downs were replaced one at a time with theeight new race and sex categories and thefirst equation in the two-stage least squaresincluded a dummy variable that equals 1when the consent decree dealt with eitherrace or sex.

    Table VI reports the county fixed effectswith separate year fixed effects for each state.

    Despite the sample size being about one-third smaller, the results are similar to thosealready reported. Gender plays an evensmaller role than it did in the earlier results.The effectiveness of different types of policeofficers lies more along racial than genderlines, though there are notable exceptionsfor Asians, where males are associated withfewer crimes and females more. Murder di-vides along racial lines, with more whites .both males and females coinciding withlower death rates but the reverse being truefor blacks and Hispanics. In all but a few ofcases, more blacks and Hispanics are associ-ated with higher crime rates.

    The variables explaining rape provide verylittle evidence that the gender of the policeofficer affects this crime differently. Forwhites and blacks, the different gender racialgroups have the same coefficient signs andare statistically indistinguishable. Althoughdifferences do exist for Hispanics and Asians,even here the effects do not suggest a consis-tent pattern with the relative impacts of maleand female officers having the opposite im-pacts in the two cases. The strength of theseresults make it very difficult to believe thatmale and female officers have much of adifferential impact on deterring rapes. Al-though it is still quite likely that male andfemale officers have different skills in deal-

    ing with rape e.g., female officers may bebetter able at getting rape victims to reveal

    .details , the tests do not allow us to differ-entiate what the skill differences are foreach gender. Victims or potential victimsmay also value more than simply deterrence.For example, they may value how they feelgoing through the process, and that is an-other dimension that we are unable to mea-sure. However, even if these other attributesare significantly valued, the results presentedhere allow us to discuss the trade-off be-tween the number of rapes and these otherpossible dimensions.

    As another attempt to control for differ-ences in law enforcement across states, I alsoreestimated the regressions shown in TableVI with city and year fixed effects and in-cluding variables for both the per capita stateemployment in corrections and the judicialsystem.25 Including these variables had nodiscernible impact on the results reported.

    25. See Lott and Mustard 1997 , for a discussion ofthese data.

  • ECONOMIC INQUIRY256

    TA

    BL

    EV

    IU

    sing

    Tw

    o-st

    age

    Lea

    stSq

    uare

    sto

    Fur

    ther

    Exa

    min

    eth

    eD

    iffer

    ence

    sby

    Rac

    ean

    dSe

    x:C

    ontr

    ollin

    gfo

    rC

    ount

    yF

    ixed

    Eff

    ects

    and

    Stat

    eF

    ixed

    Eff

    ects

    that

    Var

    yby

    Yea

    r

    Cat

    egor

    y%

    ofP

    olic

    eof

    Cri

    me

    %of

    Pol

    ice

    %of

    Pol

    ice

    For

    ce%

    ofP

    olic

    e%

    ofP

    olic

    e%

    ofP

    olic

    eF

    orce

    Asi

    an%

    ofP

    olic

    eF

    orce

    Bei

    ng%

    ofP

    olic

    eF

    orce

    Bla

    ckH

    ispa

    nic

    For

    ceH

    ispa

    nic

    For

    ceW

    hite

    For

    ceW

    hite

    Pac

    ific

    Asi

    anP

    acifi

    cE

    xpla

    ined

    For

    ceB

    lack

    Mal

    eF

    emal

    eM

    ale

    Fem

    ale

    Mal

    eF

    emal

    eM

    ale

    Fem

    ale

    Vio

    lent

    10.4

    314

    %38

    .62

    14%

    13.9

    818

    %23

    4.02

    27%

    6.

    2813

    %4.

    545

    2%

    56.1

    231

    %24

    1.91

    10%

    .

    .

    .

    .

    .

    .

    .

    .

    crim

    e2.

    672

    2.65

    72.

    065

    0.89

    02.

    858

    0.29

    00.

    735

    2.16

    0Pr

    oper

    ty3.

    954%

    15.0

    24%

    5.36

    65%

    93.9

    48%

    2.

    434%

    3.80

    41%

    28

    .03

    12%

    97.2

    53%

    .

    .

    .

    .

    .

    .

    .

    .

    crim

    e1.

    723

    1.82

    71.

    444

    0.84

    91.

    883

    0.38

    90.

    621

    1.55

    4M

    urde

    r19

    .72

    60%

    66.9

    155

    %18

    .46

    56%

    79.2

    874

    %

    10.3

    778

    %

    2.45

    54%

    54

    .34

    68%

    340.

    9450

    %

    .

    .

    .

    .

    .

    .

    .

    .2.

    742.

    719

    1.75

    80.

    911

    2.73

    80.

    095

    0.98

    21.

    904

    Man

    -26

    .074

    60%

    101.

    5763

    %27

    .21

    63%

    148.

    7330

    %

    16.4

    761

    %33

    .60

    28%

    95

    .46

    64%

    682.

    163

    49%

    .

    .

    .

    .

    .

    .

    .

    .

    slau

    ghte

    r2.

    317

    2.57

    11.

    976

    0.87

    42.

    649

    0.67

    00.

    839

    2.10

    1R

    ape

    4.26

    910

    %15

    .50

    10%

    6.18

    215

    %90

    .44

    19%

    2.

    588

    10%

    1.

    221

    1%

    6.33

    36%

    97.0

    257%

    .

    .

    .

    .

    .

    .

    .

    .

    1.34

    51.

    354

    1.10

    10.

    732

    1.40

    40.

    088

    0.10

    31.

    090

    Tot

    al11

    .40

    18%

    41.7

    418

    %13

    .90

    22%

    252.

    8236

    %

    6.66

    517

    %6.

    354%

    82

    .098

    56%

    251.

    9713

    %

    .

    .

    .

    .

    .

    .

    .

    .ro

    bber

    y2.

    583

    2.57

    81.

    951

    0.88

    72.

    728

    0.36

    00.

    910

    2.10

    4T

    otal

    9.80

    214

    %37

    .28

    14%

    15.4

    922

    %22

    7.57

    29%

    6.

    2614

    %3.

    015

    2%

    21.0

    7113

    %25

    1.05

    11%

    .

    .

    .

    .

    .

    .

    .

    .

    assa

    ult

    2.38

    72.

    445

    2.02

    40.

    881

    2.64

    20.

    174

    0.27

    72.

    047

    Bur

    glar

    y7.

    101

    8%27

    .87

    9%9.

    553

    11%

    181.

    0619

    %

    4.44

    68%

    12.0

    665%

    70

    .765

    35%

    185.

    997%

    .

    .

    .

    .

    .

    .

    .

    .

    2.44

    42.

    534

    1.87

    90.

    896

    2.70

    30.

    868

    1.05

    12.

    284

    Lar

    ceny

    2.31

    92%

    11.7

    53%

    6.49

    07%

    86.8

    58%

    2.

    096

    4%9.

    061

    3%

    3.77

    32%

    110.

    964%

    .

    .

    .

    .

    .

    .

    .

    .

    1.10

    11.

    534

    1.69

    40.

    843

    1.69

    50.

    839

    0.09

    61.

    803

    Mot

    or13

    .30

    18%

    39.4

    615

    %3.

    090

    4%20

    1.95

    25%

    5.

    3795

    12%

    6.

    265

    3%

    193.

    2454

    %11

    2.87

    5%

    .

    .

    .

    .

    .

    .

    .

    .ve

    hicl

    e2.

    558

    2.17

    00.

    457

    0.85

    32.

    018

    0.33

    81.

    289

    0.93

    2th

    eft

    Ass

    ault

    24

    .16

    36%

    24.2

    17%

    38

    .05

    27%

    133.

    068%

    3.

    0512

    %16

    .68

    14%

    35

    .32

    3%33

    4.5

    2%

    .

    .

    .

    .

    .

    .

    .

    .on

    polic

    e1.

    292

    0.41

    81.

    280.

    905

    2.29

    5.2

    801.

    671

    0.90

    5of

    ficer

    s

    Not

    es:T

    hese

    cond

    -sta

    gere

    gres

    sion

    estim

    ates

    that

    are

    repo

    rted

    abov

    eac

    coun

    tfo

    rth

    esa

    me

    vari

    able

    sco

    ntro

    lled

    for

    inth

    efir

    st-s

    tage

    regr

    essi

    onex

    cept

    for

    the

    cons

    ent

    decr

    ee,t

    henu

    mbe

    rof

    year

    ssi

    nce

    the

    cons

    ent

    decr

    eew

    ent

    into

    effe

    ct,a

    ndw

    heth

    erth

    eci

    tys

    may

    oris

    blac

    k.C

    ount

    yfix

    edef

    fect

    sar

    eus

    ed,w

    ithad

    ditio

    nal

    sepa

    rate

    fixed

    effe

    cts

    for

    each

    stat

    eby

    year

    topi

    ckup

    any

    chan

    ges

    atth

    est

    ate

    leve

    lth

    atm

    ight

    expl

    ain

    chan

    ges

    incr

    ime

    rate

    sov

    ertim

    e.A

    llre

    gres

    sion

    sus

    ew

    eigh

    ted

    leas

    tsq

    uare

    sw

    here

    the

    vari

    able

    sar

    ew

    eigh

    ted

    byth

    eci

    typo

    pula

    tion.

    The

    abso

    lute

    t-sta

    tistic

    sar

    esh

    own

    inth

    epa

    rent

    hese

    sbe

    low

    the

    coef

    ficie

    ntes

    timat

    e,w

    ithth

    epe

    rcen

    tof

    the

    endo

    geno

    usva

    riab

    les

    mea

    nth

    atca

    nbe

    expl

    aine

    dby

    aon

    e-st

    anda

    rd-d

    evia

    tion

    chan

    gein

    the

    exog

    enou

    sva

    riab

    lesh

    own

    inth

    ead

    jace

    ntco

    lum

    n.Sa

    mpl

    esi

    zeis

    439

    and

    cove

    rsth

    eye

    ars

    1987

    and

    1990

    .

  • LOTT: DOES A HELPING HAND PUT OTHERS AT RISK? 257

    While the impact of hiring more people incorrections and the judicial system usuallyreduced crime, the effect was never statisti-cally significant. Variables to account forconcealed handgun laws, waiting periods andthe length of those waiting periods in buyinga gun, penalties for using guns in commis-sions of crimes, and cocaine prices were alsoincluded,26 but only the variable for thepresence of concealed handgun laws reducedcrime and none of these variables apprecia-bly altered the other findings. Passage ofconcealed handgun laws reduced murderrates by about 10.5%.27 Controlling for theuse of Lojack automobile anti-theft devicestended to make the results for black andminority officers more positive and statisti-cally significant though the coefficient forLojack was not significant.28

    VI. FELONIOUS KILLING OF POLICE,ACCIDENTAL POLICE DEATHS, ASSAULTS

    ON POLICE, AND SHOOTING CIVILIANS

    Many studies have focused on whetherblacks and other minorities civilians havebeen shot by police at disproportionately

    .higher rates Matulia 1985, 7 . The stan-dard view is that the higher rates at which

    26. See Lott and Mustard 1997 , for a discussion ofthese data.

    27. Given the possible relationship between drugprices and crime, I reran the regressions in Table IV byincluding an additional variable for cocaine prices. Oneargument linking drug prices and crime is that if thedemand for drugs is inelastic and if people commitcrimes in order to finance their habits, higher drugprices might lead to increased levels of crime. Using theDrug Enforcement Administrations STRIDE data set

    from 1977 to 1992 with the exceptions of 1988 and.1989 , Michael Grossman, Frank J. Chaloupka, and

    Charles C. Brown 1996 estimate the price of cocaine asa function of its purity, weight, year dummies, yeardummies interacted with eight regional dummies, andindividual city dummies. However, these data are notperfect. Because of the lack of observations for 1993, Iused the drug prices for 1992. While the drug pricevariable was positive it was not statistically significantand its inclusion had very little impact on the relation-ship between the type of police