direct and indirect channels for regulation … · direct and indirect channels for regulation to...

18
OECD Technical Workshop on Trade Barrier Assessment Methodology Paris, 12 December 2008 DIRECT AND INDIRECT CHANNELS FOR REGULATION TO AFFECT TRADE IN SERVICES THE CASE OF BUSINESS SERVICES, CONSTRUCTION AND TELECOMMUNICATIONS by Margit Molnar, Kensuke Tanaka ** and Mark van Duijn OECD Trade and Agriculture Directorate ** Development Centre, OECD

Upload: phungmien

Post on 15-May-2018

263 views

Category:

Documents


1 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: DIRECT AND INDIRECT CHANNELS FOR REGULATION … · DIRECT AND INDIRECT CHANNELS FOR REGULATION TO AFFECT TRADE IN ... Economic theories ... Owing to the high degree of information

OECD Technical Workshop on Trade Barrier Assessment Methodology

Paris, 12 December 2008

DIRECT AND INDIRECT CHANNELS FOR

REGULATION TO AFFECT TRADE IN SERVICES – THE CASE OF BUSINESS

SERVICES, CONSTRUCTION AND TELECOMMUNICATIONS

by Margit Molnar, Kensuke Tanaka** and Mark van Duijn

OECD Trade and Agriculture Directorate

** Development Centre, OECD

Page 2: DIRECT AND INDIRECT CHANNELS FOR REGULATION … · DIRECT AND INDIRECT CHANNELS FOR REGULATION TO AFFECT TRADE IN ... Economic theories ... Owing to the high degree of information

2

TABLE OF CONTENTS

Executive summary ......................................................................................................................................... 3

Introduction ..................................................................................................................................................... 5 Services in general are not traded as much as goods are, but there is large disparity across the service

sector ........................................................................................................................................................ 5

How does regulation affect trade in services? – Some insights from theory ................................................... 7 Information plays a more central role in trade in services ....................................................................... 7 Stringent domestic regulation may, in some cases, increase trade in services ......................................... 8 Market structure is an important factor affecting the relationship between regulation and trade flows .. 8

How does regulation affect trade in services? – An empirical investigation................................................... 8 Services imports are affected by domestic regulations only indirectly .................................................... 9 Do regulations affect services exports directly? ..................................................................................... 13

Major lessons and further steps ..................................................................................................................... 17

References ..................................................................................................................................................... 18

Tables

Table 1. Economy-wide sectoral regulation affects import flows indirectly ................................................ 11 Table 2. Sector-specific regulation affects imports through demand elasticities (imports) ......................... 12 Table 3. Product market regulation in export markets boosts export potential ............................................ 14 Table 4. Regulation in export markets boosts exports while that in the exporter’s markets has no effect ... 14 Table 5. Sector-specific regulation increases the demand elasticities and conduct regulation directly

affects trade (exports) .................................................................................................................... 16

Figures

Figure 1. Services sector output as percentage of GDP in OECD Countries, 1971-2006 .............................. 5 Figure 2. Share of services in global trade, 1994-2006 .................................................................................. 6 Figure 3. Finance, construction, business services and transportation are major producers .......................... 6 Figure 4. Business services and transportation are more traded than other services ...................................... 7

Page 3: DIRECT AND INDIRECT CHANNELS FOR REGULATION … · DIRECT AND INDIRECT CHANNELS FOR REGULATION TO AFFECT TRADE IN ... Economic theories ... Owing to the high degree of information

3

DIRECT AND INDIRECT CHANNELS FOR REGULATION TO AFFECT TRADE IN

SERVICES – THE CASE OF BUSINESS SERVICES, CONSTRUCTION AND

TELECOMMUNICATIONS

Margit Molnar, Kensuke Tanaka

** and Mark van Duijn

***

Executive summary

This paper proposes an error correction framework to analyse the relationship between domestic

regulation and international trade taking into account dynamic and long-term relationships as well as

various channels - direct and indirect - through which regulation may affect trade. Economic theories

suggest an economic equilibrium between imports (exports), domestic (world) demand and

competitiveness, i.e. in statistical terms there is a co-integration relationship between them. In practice,

however, adjustment lags and unanticipated shocks entail deviation from such long-run paths. If such

deviation exists, forces tend to pull back the variables towards equilibrium. This basic framework is

augmented by indicators of product market regulation to investigate the impact of regulations on services

trade flows. In addition to checking the direct impact of regulation on trade flows, an extended framework

– by controlling for interactions between regulation and major variables of the model – allows for testing

several other possible channels through which regulation may affect trade such as (i) whether regulation

changes the demand elasticity of trade flows, (ii) whether regulation changes the price elasticity of demand

in the sector in which regulation takes place, and (iii) whether regulation changes the speed at which trade

in that sector is adjusted following changes in demand and competitiveness. The testing of such channels

would not be possible with the gravity model that has long prevailed as the dominant framework for

examining international trade issues.

The estimation results suggest that on the one hand, economy-wide regulation in the importing

country affects imports only indirectly, with greater levels of regulation increasing the demand elasticity of

imports and accelerated speed of import adjustment following demand and competitiveness shocks. More

extensive sector-specific regulation, on the other hand, affects imports only via its increasing of demand

elasticites. More extensive regulation in export markets at first appears to boost exports, though after

controlling for indirect channels of regulatory impact on exports, this is cancelled out. Economy-wide

regulation in export markets does not appear to have a bearing on exports, while sector-specific regulation

in export markets increases the demand elasticity for exports in all model specifications. Regulations

related to conduct and market structure in the export markets in addition to directly boosting exports,

increase export demand elasticities and decrease the speed at which exports react to changes in external

demand and competitiveness.

A major lesson learnt from the analyses is that simple correlations of regulation and trade may not

provide a full picture of their relationship, therefore a more nuanced approach is needed. The above error-

correction framework allowed for the examination of indirect channels through which regulations may

affect trade and the results proved the existence of such channels. Although domestic regulations are

Corresponding author, Senior Economist, Trade and Agriculture Directorate, OECD. T: +33 1 4524 8949. E-

mail: [email protected].

** Development Centre, OECD.

*** Trade and Agriculture Directorate, OECD.

Page 4: DIRECT AND INDIRECT CHANNELS FOR REGULATION … · DIRECT AND INDIRECT CHANNELS FOR REGULATION TO AFFECT TRADE IN ... Economic theories ... Owing to the high degree of information

4

usually adopted with other considerations than boosting international trade in services, having in mind their

potential indirect impact on international trade may be useful when formulating such regulations. A further

refinement of the variables and an extension to more sectors would provide further insight into the

relationship between regulation and trade.

Page 5: DIRECT AND INDIRECT CHANNELS FOR REGULATION … · DIRECT AND INDIRECT CHANNELS FOR REGULATION TO AFFECT TRADE IN ... Economic theories ... Owing to the high degree of information

5

Introduction

Trade policies in general have an important bearing on the formation of domestic prices and hence on

the decision to produce or invest. Such policies in service sectors comprise not only explicit trade policies,

but also many domestic regulations that affect trade. Industries that are protected by entry restrictions, for

instance, do not face competition, and therefore tend to orient their production toward the domestic market.

Producing for a protected market, in turn, will reduce pressure to upgrade skills or increase efficiency,

resulting in a loss of competitiveness.

To provide an environment facilitating trade, it is therefore important to adopt the appropriate

regulations. To do that, in turn, it is indispensable to better understand the relationship between domestic

regulation and international trade. Notwithstanding the importance of services for the economy, little

research has been done on the impact of domestic regulations on international trade in services. In lack of

such literature, this paper is based on the assumption that given the different purpose of domestic

regulations than impacting international trade, their impact may rather work through indirect channels.

Intuitively, domestic regulation, if excessively restrictive, reduces the degree of flexibility of the economy

and hence its ability to react to shocks. With this in mind, some possible indirect channels for regulation to

affect trade in services are checked. Trade in this paper is limited to cross-border transactions and other

modes - such as sales of foreign affiliates or a large part of services provided by natural persons - are not

covered (in this latter case, with the exception of services provided by natural persons that recorded in

Balance of Payments statistics).

This paper, after a snapshot of trade and output structures in OECD services industries, gives an

insight into theoretical issues characteristic in particular to services. The main part of the paper consists of

the analyses of various channels through which regulation affects trade. Finally, some ways to improve the

present analyses are suggested.

Services in general are not traded as much as goods are, but there is large disparity across the

service sector

While the service sector produces almost three quarters of GDP in OECD countries (Figure 1) and

roughly half in developing countries, its share in global trade flows is far less than the share for goods

(Figure 2). Comparing the trends, the contribution of services to output growth has been increasing (over

about 35 years its share increased 17 percentage points from about 56% to 73%), nevertheless the share of

services in total trade has been constant at around 20% over the past decade and a half in the OECD area.

Figure 5. Services sector output as percentage of GDP in OECD Countries, 1971-2006

Source: WDI.

55%

60%

65%

70%

75%

19

71

19

72

19

73

19

74

19

75

19

76

19

77

19

78

19

79

19

80

19

81

19

82

19

83

19

84

19

85

19

86

19

87

19

88

19

89

19

90

19

91

19

92

19

93

19

94

19

95

19

96

19

97

19

98

19

99

20

00

20

01

20

02

20

03

20

04

20

05

20

06

Page 6: DIRECT AND INDIRECT CHANNELS FOR REGULATION … · DIRECT AND INDIRECT CHANNELS FOR REGULATION TO AFFECT TRADE IN ... Economic theories ... Owing to the high degree of information

6

Figure 6. Share of services in global trade, 1994-2006

Source: OECD Trade in Services Database.

In addition, shares of services in both output and trade mask significant differences across the sector.

On the output side, construction has traditionally been the largest service industry in OECD economies and

has only recently been overtaken by financial services (Figure 3), a sector that tripled its share in the last

30 years. Alongside financial services, “other business activities” (category 74 under the ISIC Rev. 3

classification) have been the most rapidly growing services sector. Computer services have also expanded

rapidly, though from a very low base.

Figure 7. Finance, construction, business services and transportation are major producers

Percentage of sectoral output in total output, OECD average, 1970-2006

Source: OECD STAN Database.

On the trade side, transportation and business services are far the most traded (Figure 4). To maintain

their share in total services trade, both of these industries have rapidly increased trade recently. In the past

couple of years there has been acceleration in financial services trade, leading to an increase of this sector’s

share in total trade. Trade in communication services although doubled in the past decade, this rate of

growth only allowed for a slight increase in its share in total trade and the almost constant size of trade in

construction services led to a diminishing share of this sector in total services trade.

19%

20%

20%

21%

21%

22%

22%

1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006

0.0%

2.0%

4.0%

6.0%

8.0%

10.0%

12.0%

19

70

19

71

19

72

19

73

19

74

19

75

19

76

19

77

19

78

19

79

19

80

19

81

19

82

19

83

19

84

19

85

19

86

19

87

19

88

19

89

19

90

19

91

19

92

19

93

19

94

19

95

19

96

19

97

19

98

19

99

20

00

20

01

20

02

20

03

20

04

20

05

20

06

Construction Retail Trade Transport

Communications Finance Computer activities

Other business activities

Page 7: DIRECT AND INDIRECT CHANNELS FOR REGULATION … · DIRECT AND INDIRECT CHANNELS FOR REGULATION TO AFFECT TRADE IN ... Economic theories ... Owing to the high degree of information

7

Figure 8. Business services and transportation are more traded than other services

Share of services sectors in total services trade, OECD average 1994-2006

Source: OECD Trade in Services Database.

The findings from the joint examination of output and trade share of services suggests that (i) some

services that are of great importance for the economy, such as construction, are among the least traded,

while (ii) other services of great importance for the economy such as transportation or business services

also have a corresponding share in trade. There are also services like computer services that contribute to a

much lesser extent to output than for instance, construction, nevertheless their share in total services trade

is much higher than that of construction.

How does regulation affect trade in services? – Some insights from theory

While barriers to goods trade are preliminarily tariffs and quotas, barriers to trade in services

predominantly take the form of domestic regulations such as entry barriers to local markets, rules on

conduct and rules of competition. Although highly regulated environments imply higher costs in terms of

production and transactions, governments intervene in the market with the purpose of addressing market

failures related to externalities, information asymmetry, or other undesirable developments. .

Information plays a more central role in trade in services

From a theoretical point of view, trade in services has several distinct features, although it shares

many characteristics with trade in goods. One of the most distinct features is the role of information for

trade in services. Owing to the high degree of information asymmetry, the price of a service is not serving

as a device to infer the quality of the service, therefore consumers need more information to make a

decision. It may, however, be too costly for suppliers to communicate the necessary information to each

individual consumer.

In such cases, in addition to educating consumers on how to recognise service quality (which can be a

long process), an appropriate regulatory framework to encourage information disclosure may prove to be

effective. These measures can help consumers to access and process information as they make expenditure

decisions. At the same time, the existence of information asymmetry provides incentives for good firms to

reveal their quality and thus maintain their reputation. Such efforts by firms to provide signalling reduce

the regulatory costs of mitigating information asymmetry.

0%

5%

10%

15%

20%

25%

30%

1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006

Other business services Transportation Financial services

Computer & Information services Communication services Construction services

Page 8: DIRECT AND INDIRECT CHANNELS FOR REGULATION … · DIRECT AND INDIRECT CHANNELS FOR REGULATION TO AFFECT TRADE IN ... Economic theories ... Owing to the high degree of information

8

Stringent domestic regulation may, in some cases, increase trade in services

Although in services markets transactions may take place amid high degrees of information

asymmetry, dismantling of barriers may not always boost trade. Paradoxically, in some cases, stringent

regulations may even encourage cross-border transactions. Requirements to prove qualifications by a

certificate, for instance, reduce information asymmetry and hence also transaction costs. An environment

with lower transaction costs may spur demand and encourage foreigners to provide the service. Therefore,

instead of dismantling certificate requirements, a harmonisation of qualifications and mutual recognitions

may be the right measures to adopt to boost trade in certain services.

Market structure is an important factor affecting the relationship between regulation and trade flows

Potential gains from services trade liberalisation are tied closely to market structure. Depending on the

market structure, regulation may induce different impacts on trade flows. The effect of improving market

access depends on market structures that differ across services industries. Markets for standardised

products, where prices play an important signalling role, tend to be ceteris paribus more competitive than

services markets, where tailor-made products are more common.

In several services industries (e.g. legal services and consultancy services), owing to the prevalence of

customer-specific products, markets are highly segmented. In segmented markets, suppliers have a certain

degree of monopoly power due to switching costs that are manifest in discretionary price setting. Both

customers and suppliers have incentives to maintain the segmented state of markets: customers because of

switching costs and suppliers owing to reputation effects as reputation takes time to build.

Some service industries depend on networks (e.g. telecommunications, electricity, gas, railways)

involving large sunk and fixed costs while also delivering valuable network externalities. Although the

products are more standardised than in some other industries, the nature of the activity may inhibit the

development of competitive markets.

How does regulation affect trade in services? – An empirical investigation

Gravity models have long prevailed as the dominant framework for examining international trade

issues and with the emergence of the empirical literature on services trade, they have swiftly been adopted

for services. While gravity models are useful for certain purposes, they may be limited in their ability to

capture some important issues with respect to services. Domestic regulation is a case to the point as it is

considered to be the major impediment to services trade.

Economic theories suggest an economic equilibrium between imports (exports), domestic (world)

demand and competitiveness, i.e. in statistical terms there is a co-integration relationship between them. In

practice, however, adjustment lags and unanticipated shocks entail deviation from such long-run paths.

This deviation of the co-integrating linear combination from its long-run mean reflects the distance from

equilibrium and if such deviation exists, forces tend to pull the variables back toward equilibrium. This

basic framework is applied to investigate the impact of domestic regulations on services trade flows.

Indicators of product market regulation are used to augment otherwise conventional trade demand

relationships in which trade in a sector is related to demand, a measure of competitiveness and a sector-

specific time trend to allow for technical progress.1 Two sets of relationships are estimated for each model.

1. In standard models estimating goods imports/exports it is not always assumed that trade flows depend on

demand but not supply, given that imports, for instance, could arise because of domestic producers’ inability to

produce the exact good demanded by consumers. Therefore, to control for supply constraints, a capacity

utilisation variable is included. Such data, however, are not available for services sectors.

Page 9: DIRECT AND INDIRECT CHANNELS FOR REGULATION … · DIRECT AND INDIRECT CHANNELS FOR REGULATION TO AFFECT TRADE IN ... Economic theories ... Owing to the high degree of information

9

The first simply tests whether there is an association between regulation and trade after controlling for

demand and competitiveness. The second enables tests to check (i) whether regulation changes the demand

elasticity of trade flows, (ii) whether regulation changes the price elasticity of demand in the sector in

which regulation takes place, and (iii) whether regulation changes the speed at which trade in that sector is

adjusted following changes in demand and competitiveness.

Regulation is captured by the OECD product market regulation (PMR) indicators that contain general

regulatory policies for the entire economy and sector-specific policies for several services sectors including

network services, retail trade and professional services. Given the limited availability of PMR indicators in

time series, only certain series of PMR indicators are suitable to test long-term relationships between

regulation and trade flows. The sectoral PMR indicators are available from 1975 onwards for the seven

sectors of telecommunications, posts, electricity, gas, railways, airlines and roads and their sub-

components, therefore they are suitable for such tests. The general PMR is only available from 1998, (and

only for the three years of 1998, 2003 and 2007) therefore its components are suitable only for short-term

tests.2 While the sector-specific indicators related to the sectors covered in the study are readily available, it

is also useful to test the effect of more general regulatory measures. In lack of a readily available general

PMR in long time series, the average of the 7-industry (telecommunications, posts, electricity, gas,

railways, airlines and roads) sectoral indicator (the electricity, transport and communication regulatory

indicator or ETCR) is used to capture economy-wide regulation. Also the gas sector indicator is used as a

substitute for the average ETCR as the gas sector is among the latest liberalised network industries,

therefore this indicator may be useful to assess economy-wide regulation.

Services imports are affected by domestic regulations only indirectly

The conventional import demand equation - where the size of import flows depends on import

demand, competitiveness and a time trend to allow for technological progress – is augmented by regulatory

indicators as in equation (1):

∆𝑚𝑖,𝑡 = 𝛼0 + 𝛼1Δ𝑑𝑖,𝑡 + 𝛼2Δ𝑐𝑜𝑚𝑝𝑖,𝑡+

+𝛼3 𝑚𝑖,𝑡−1 + 𝜌1𝑑𝑖,𝑡−1 + 𝜌2𝑐𝑜𝑚𝑝𝑖,𝑡−1 + 𝜌3𝑃𝑀𝑅𝑖,𝑡−1+𝜌4𝑇 + 𝜀𝑖,𝑡 (1)

where ∆ indicates growth rates, m is imports, d is demand for imports, comp is the competitiveness

variable, all in logarithmic forms, T is the time trend and PMR is the product market regulation indicator.

The demand for imports is captured by domestic output3 and competitiveness by the three variables of

unit labour costs, hourly wages in the sector and the real effective exchange rate. Domestic output is

deflated by the sector-specific output deflator, both obtained from the OECD STAN database updated by

the EU KLEMS, the 60-industry database of the Groningen Growth and Development Centre and national

sources. Real effective exchange rates were obtained from the International Financial Statistics database of

the IMF, unit labour costs from the OECD Unit Labour Cost database and sector-specific hourly wages

were computed as the ratio of the sectoral wage bill to the hours worked in the sector, both obtained from

the OECD STAN database. Product market regulation is measured by the OECD PMR indicators, the

effect of both the sector-specific indicators and indicators attempting to capture economy-wide regulation

are examined.

2. The overall PMR and its components did not appear to affect trade flows in the short term.

3. Demand is usually defined as total aggregate demand, including exports, rather than GDP to allow for taking

into account the import content of exports. In the case of services, however, information on “processing

exports” is not available as readily as in the case of goods.

Page 10: DIRECT AND INDIRECT CHANNELS FOR REGULATION … · DIRECT AND INDIRECT CHANNELS FOR REGULATION TO AFFECT TRADE IN ... Economic theories ... Owing to the high degree of information

10

The basic setting of the model works relatively well given that the availability and quality of data for

service sectors in general is inferior to those for goods. The dynamic coefficient is always negative and

significant, indicating that there is indeed a co-integration relationship between the major variables of

interest. The demand variable is mostly significant in the long run, though not always in the short run. The

competitiveness variable, although measured by three variants, does not appear with a significant

coefficient, most likely owing to the fact that the relative prices may not be best captured by labour costs

even in services.

After controlling for demand and competitiveness, there does not seem to be a significant relationship

between regulation and import flows (results subtracted). This finding of a lack of direct impact of

regulation on import flows, however, does not mean that regulations have no impact on trade at all. To

investigate further possible channels through which regulation may impact trade, a series of hypotheses

were tested: (i) whether regulation changes the demand elasticity of imports (ii) whether regulation

changes the price elasticity of imports and (iii) whether regulation impacts on the speed at which imports

adjust following changes in demand and competitiveness. To check these hypotheses, the following

equation is estimated:

∆𝑚𝑖,𝑡 = 𝛼0 + 𝛼1Δ𝑑𝑖,𝑡 + 𝛼2Δ𝑐𝑜𝑚𝑝𝑖,𝑡 + 𝛼3 + 𝛾1𝑃𝑀𝑅𝑖,𝑡−1 𝑚𝑖,𝑡−1 + {𝜌1 + 𝛾2𝑃𝑀𝑅𝑖,𝑡−1}𝑑𝑖,𝑡−1 +

+{𝜌2+𝛾3𝑃𝑀𝑅𝑖,𝑡−1}𝑐𝑜𝑚𝑝𝑖,𝑡−1+𝜌3𝑃𝑀𝑅𝑖,𝑡−1+𝜌4𝑇+𝜀𝑖,𝑡 (2)

where ∆ indicates growth rates, m is imports, d is demand for imports, comp is the competitiveness

variable, all in logarithmic forms, T is the time trend and PMR is the product market regulation indicator.

Regulation appears indeed to have an impact on import flows, albeit not directly. This is not so

surprising given that domestic regulations were adopted for different purposes than controlling

international trade; nevertheless by making the economy less flexible, such regulations may have a bearing

on trade flows. The results show that domestic regulation increases the demand elasticity of imports

(Table 1). This effect may work through the increased rigidity of domestic production implied by

regulation and hence more responsiveness of imports to demand changes when the domestic market is

regulated. This finding is robust to model specification: it is confirmed in a model where regulation is

measured by the average ETCR (which includes 7 network industries) or regulation in the gas sector.

Furthermore, it is robust to different specifications of the competitiveness variable. In addition to its impact

on increasing demand elasticity, regulation also increases the speed at which imports adjust to changes in

demand or competitiveness. This finding may again be explained by the fact that regulation in general

implies less flexibility in domestic production, and due to this limited domestic flexibility, increased

domestic demand, for instance, needs to be met by increased imports rather than increased domestic

production. By the same token, imports adjust faster to changes in competitiveness owing to the rigidity of

domestic production as a result of regulation.

Page 11: DIRECT AND INDIRECT CHANNELS FOR REGULATION … · DIRECT AND INDIRECT CHANNELS FOR REGULATION TO AFFECT TRADE IN ... Economic theories ... Owing to the high degree of information

11

Table 6. Economy-wide sectoral regulation affects import flows indirectly

Note: ETCR is the average of PMR indicators in the seven network industries of telecommunications, posts, air, road and rail transport, electricity and gas. For the regulatory indicators an unpublished preliminary version of the 2008 PMR database is used. REER stands for real effective exchange rate, wage for sector-specific hourly wages and ULC for unit labour costs. For the estimation, an unbalanced dataset of OECD countries was used with data available from 1975.

Source: Authors’ estimation.

Not all types of regulations impact trade flows in the same way. As seen above, even regulations that

affect the entire economy, although do not appear to have a direct impact on imports, may impact trade

flows via increasing the elasticity of demand and accelerating the speed of adjustment. Regulations which

are specific to the sector, similarly, do not tend to impact imports in the sector directly, but via increasing

the elasticity of demand (Table 2). This finding is the same when regulation is captured by the highest-

level sectoral PMR, two variations of the entry component of the sectoral PMR and the sectoral market

structure/conduct component.

Although the coefficient on the short-run demand term is always positive and statistically significant,

its size is not very large, hovering around 0.3. This indicates that the “leaks” of demand shocks to trading

partners are not too large, i.e. they do not limit too much the stimulative impact of such shocks on domestic

activity. The long-run estimate is close to unitary elasticity. The time trend is positive and often significant,

implying that imports are increasingly controlling for demand and competitiveness. The time trend serves

as a proxy for variables that are difficult to quantify such as increasing openness and specialisation or the

growing influence of multinational firms.

reer wage ulc reer wage ulc

Long-run coefficients

Demand 0.829** 0.773* 0.721* 1.368** 1.28* 1.429**

(0.40) (0.41) (0.39) (0.69) (0.71) (0.72)

Competitiveness 1.297 0.141** -2.125 -0.302 0.196 -3.431

(2.22) (0.07) (1.99) (3.29) (0.15) (2.94)

Regulation (in import market) 1.362 0.145 0.412 -0.405 0.929 2.907

(2.58) (1.17) (1.18) (4.31) (2.75) (2.66)

Trend 0.082** 0.065* 0.089** 0.072 0.061 0.087

(0.03) (0.04) (0.04) (0.04) (0.04) (0.05)

Short-run coefficients

Demand 0.186 0.258 0.155 0.23* 0.254 0.194

(0.14) (0.19) (0.14) (0.14) (0.19) (0.14)

Competitiveness 0.001 0.002 -0.399 0.026 0.001 -0.405

(0.23) (0.004) (0.46) (0.23) (0.004) (0.46)

Dynamic coefficent -0.201*** -0.205*** -0.199*** -0.124*** -0.126*** -0.124***

(0.03) (0.04) (0.04) (0.04) (0.04) (0.04)

Interaction term coefficients

Regulation-import -0.022*** -0.026*** -0.021*** -0.043*** -0.047*** -0.042***

(0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01)

Regulation-demand 0.639*** 0.616*** 0.561*** 0.631*** 0.645*** 0.585***

(0.20) (0.19) (0.18) (0.19) (0.18) (0.17)

Regulation-competitiveness 0.295 -0.025 -0.571 0.707 -0.001 -0.348

(0.57) (0.02) (0.46) (0.55) (0.02) (0.40)

No. Obs. 1097 990 1085 1097 990 1085

R-sq 0.140 0.148 0.139 0.152 0.160 0.150

ETCR GAS

Page 12: DIRECT AND INDIRECT CHANNELS FOR REGULATION … · DIRECT AND INDIRECT CHANNELS FOR REGULATION TO AFFECT TRADE IN ... Economic theories ... Owing to the high degree of information

12

Table 7. Sector-specific regulation affects imports through demand elasticities (imports)

Note: Sectoral PMR is the sector-specific PMR indicator, sectoral PMR entry is the entry restriction component of this indicator, sectoral PMR entry 2 is a variant of it, sectoral PMR conduct is an indicator where either the component related to conduct or market structure is used in a given sector, depending on availability. For the regulatory indicators an unpublished preliminary version of the 2008 PMR database is used. REER stands for real effective exchange rate, wage for sector-specific hourly wages and ULC for unit labour costs. For the estimation, an unbalanced dataset of OECD countries was used with data available from 1975.

Source: Authors’ estimation.

reer wage ulc reer wage ulc reer wage ulc reer wage ulc

Long-run coefficients

Demand 0.857*** 0.858*** 0.868*** 0.882*** 0.918*** 0.854*** 0.881*** 0.919*** 0.853*** 0.861*** 0.81*** 0.85***

0.23 0.27 0.22 0.23 0.27 0.22 0.23 0.27 0.22 0.23 0.25 0.21

Competitiveness 1.332* -0.031 -1.708** 1.207 -0.007 -1.679*** 1.202 -0.007 -1.688*** 1.386* -0.024 -1.805***

0.79 0.05 0.67 0.76 0.03 0.64 0.76 0.03 0.64 0.8 0.05 0.67

Regulation (import market) 1.848 0.851 1.059 1.381 0.189 0.47 1.353 0.174 0.475 2.264* 0.176 0.533

1.43 0.95 0.83 1.3 0.83 0.59 1.27 0.76 0.57 1.3 0.74 0.64

Trend 0.019 0.005 0.042** 0.021 0.005 0.044** 0.021 0.005 0.044** 0.02 0.008 0.05**

0.02 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.02

Short-run coefficients

Demand 0.328** 0.346* 0.305** 0.334** 0.368* 0.299** 0.335** 0.368* 0.299** 0.333** 0.345* 0.305**

0.14 0.2 0.15 0.14 0.2 0.15 0.14 0.2 0.15 0.14 0.19 0.14

Competitiveness 0.044 -0.0005 -1.306** 0.029 -0.0003 -1.25** 0.029 -0.0003 -1.254** 0.046 -0.001 -1.159**

0.25 0.004 0.53 0.25 0.004 0.52 0.25 0.004 0.52 0.24 0.004 0.5

Dynamic coefficent -0.244*** -0.246*** -0.256*** -0.244*** -0.243*** -0.255*** -0.244*** -0.243*** -0.255*** -0.244*** -0.244*** -0.253***

0.02 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.02

Interaction term coefficients

Regulation-import 0.003 0.01 -0.003 -0.003 0.004 -0.004 -0.002 0.004 -0.003 0.005 0.003 -0.008

0.01 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.01

Regulation-demand 0.827*** 0.836*** 0.806*** 0.866*** 0.919*** 0.824*** 0.863*** 0.921*** 0.823*** 0.836*** 0.802*** 0.797***

0.22 0.27 0.2 0.22 0.26 0.2 0.22 0.26 0.2 0.22 0.24 0.19

Regulation-competitiveness 1.036 -0.017 -1.436** 0.908 -0.001 -1.443** 0.9 -0.003 -1.443** 0.905 -0.014 -1.462***

0.7 0.04 0.56 0.67 0.03 0.56 0.67 0.03 0.56 0.69 0.03 0.52

No. Obs. 1015 889 979 1032 904 996 1032 904 996 1043 919 1019

R-sq 0.124 0.117 0.129 0.124 0.116 0.128 0.124 0.116 0.128 0.124 0.117 0.128

Sectoral PMR Sectoral PMR entry Sectoral PMR entry 2 Sectoral PMR conduct

Page 13: DIRECT AND INDIRECT CHANNELS FOR REGULATION … · DIRECT AND INDIRECT CHANNELS FOR REGULATION TO AFFECT TRADE IN ... Economic theories ... Owing to the high degree of information

13

The joint estimations mask some sector-specific variation. The very different nature of construction,

telecommunications, computer and other business services suggests that they may react to the same

regulations in different manners. Indeed, regulation increases the speed of adjustment following demand

and competitiveness shocks in the computer services industry. Given that this industry is one of the least

regulated services industries, it is not surprising that increased regulation in the economy as a whole

induces swifter reaction by this flexible sector. This finding remains unchanged whether the average ETCR

or the gas-sector PMR are used to capture overall domestic regulation and when three different types of

competitiveness measures are applied.

Do regulations affect services exports directly?

The equation estimated for exports follows the structure of the equation for imports, where the size of

export flows depends on export demand, competitiveness and a time trend. This basic export demand

equation is augmented by regulatory indicators to examine their impact on export flows:

∆𝑥𝑖,𝑡 = 𝛼0 + 𝛼1Δ𝑑𝑖,𝑡 + 𝛼2Δ𝑐𝑜𝑚𝑝𝑖,𝑡+

+𝛼3 𝑚𝑖,𝑡−1 + 𝜌1𝑑𝑖,𝑡−1 + 𝜌2𝑐𝑜𝑚𝑝𝑖,𝑡−1 + 𝜌3𝑃𝑀𝑅𝑖,𝑡−1 + 𝜌4𝑇 + 𝜀𝑖 ,𝑡 (3)

where ∆ indicates growth rates, x is exports, d is demand for exports, comp is the competitiveness

variable, all in logarithmic forms, T is the time trend and PMR is the product market regulation indicator.

The demand for exports is usually captured by world output; however, given the lack of such data in

this case, it is proxied by output of the rest of OECD countries. For competitiveness, similarly to the import

demand equation, three variants are used: unit labour costs, sector-specific hourly wages and real effective

exchange rates. OECD output is deflated by the average of the sector-specific output deflator, both

obtained from the OECD STAN database. Real effective exchange rates were obtained from the

International Financial Statistics database of the IMF, unit labour costs from the OECD Unit Labour Cost

database, and sector-specific hourly wages were computed as the ratio of the sectoral wage bill to the hours

worked in the sector, both obtained from the OECD STAN database.

Just like the case of the import equation, the basic setting of the model seems to work relatively well

given the quality and availability of data for services. The dynamic coefficient is negative and statistically

highly significant in all model specifications, indicating a co-integrating relationship between the variables

of interest.

After controlling for export demand and competitiveness, sector-specific regulation, including the

overall sector-specific regulation and entry regulations captured by two different variables, in the export

markets has a positive impact on exports (Table 3). That is, if production is constrained by regulation in the

export markets, the exporter directly benefits from it through higher export demand. This finding is robust

to the specifications using the three variants of the competitiveness variable and remains unchanged with

the addition of the exporter’s product market regulatory indicator, which never appears significant

(Table 4).

Page 14: DIRECT AND INDIRECT CHANNELS FOR REGULATION … · DIRECT AND INDIRECT CHANNELS FOR REGULATION TO AFFECT TRADE IN ... Economic theories ... Owing to the high degree of information

14

Table 8. Product market regulation in export markets boosts export potential

Note: Sectoral PMR is the sector-specific PMR indicator, sectoral PMR entry is the entry restriction component of this indicator, sectoral PMR entry 2 is a variant of it. For the regulatory indicators an unpublished preliminary version of the 2008 PMR database is used. REER stands for real effective exchange rate, wage for sector-specific hourly wages and ULC for unit labour costs. For the estimation, an unbalanced dataset of OECD countries was used with data available from 1975.

Source: Authors’ estimation.

Table 9. Regulation in export markets boosts exports while that in the exporter’s markets has no effect

Note: Sectoral PMR is the sector-specific PMR indicator, sectoral PMR entry is the entry restriction component of this indicator, sectoral PMR entry 2 is a variant of it. For the regulatory indicators an unpublished preliminary version of the 2008 PMR database is used. REER stands for real effective exchange rate, wage for sector-specific hourly wages and ULC for unit labour costs. For the estimation, an unbalanced dataset of OECD countries was used with data available from 1975.

Source: Authors’ estimation.

reer wage ulc reer wage ulc reer wage ulc

Long-run coefficients

Demand 1.05*** 1.029*** 1.202*** 1.093*** 1.051*** 1.21*** 1.085*** 1.048*** 1.207***

0.29 0.22 0.250 0.302 0.228 0.258 0.298 0.225 0.256

Competitiveness 0.487 -0.018 -0.719 0.459 -0.019 -0.663** 0.463 -0.019 -0.656**

0.62 0.018 0.264 0.619 0.02 0.263 0.619 0.02 0.253

Regulation (in export market) 0.357*** 0.253** 0.434*** 0.275** 0.192** 0.321*** 0.270** 0.190** 0.314***

0.141 0.110 0.126 0.107 0.082 0.095 0.104 0.080 0.093

Trend 0.058*** 0.042*** 0.079*** 0.058*** 0.04*** 0.077*** 0.057*** 0.04*** 0.076***

0.01 0.01 0.02 0.01 0.01 0.02 0.01 0.01 0.02

Short-run coefficients

Demand -0.06** -0.095* -0.04 -0.06* -0.093* -0.037 -0.06* -0.1* -0.04

0.03 0.05 0.03 0.03 0.05 0.03 0.03 0.05 0.03

Competitiveness 0.276 -0.001 -0.207 0.284* -0.001 -0.157 0.283** -0.001 -0.193

0.17 0.003 0.357 0.17 0.003 0.35 0.17 0.003 0.354

Dynamic coefficent -0.177*** -0.256*** -0.192*** -0.176*** -0.255*** -0.190*** -0.175*** -0.255*** -0.190***

0.02 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.02

No. Obs. 1230 1056 1207 1245 1069 1222 1245 1069 1222

R-sq 0.108 0.156 0.113 0.107 0.156 0.112 0.108 0.16 0.112

Sectoral PMR Sectoral PMR entry Sectoral PMR entry 2

reer wage ulc reer wage ulc reer wage ulc

Long-run coefficients

Demand 1.05*** 1.038*** 1.201*** 1.092*** 1.054*** 1.214*** 1.085*** 1.052*** 1.204***

0.29 0.22 0.250 0.302 0.23 0.260 0.298 0.227 0.258

Competitiveness 0.477 -0.02 -0.734*** 0.462 -0.019 -0.657** 0.463 -0.02 -0.652**

0.62 0.018 0.26 0.621 0.02 0.266 0.221 0.018 0.266

Regulation (own) 0.038 0.036 0.036 -0.04 0.004 -0.008 -0.001 0.005 -0.005

0.101 0.082 0.097 0.053 0.040 0.052 0.052 0.040 0.051

Regulation (in export markets) 0.317* 0.217 0.401** 0.279** 0.188** 0.328*** 0.271** 0.185** 0.318***

0.176 0.136 0.156 0.119 0.089 0.106 0.112 0.087 0.103

Trend 0.058*** 0.042*** 0.079*** 0.055*** 0.04*** 0.077*** 0.057*** 0.04*** 0.076***

0.01 0.01 0.02 0.01 0.01 0.02 0.01 0.01 0.02

Short-run coefficients

Demand -0.06* -0.095* -0.04 -0.06* -0.093* -0.037 -0.06* -0.1* -0.04

0.03 0.05 0.03 0.03 0.05 0.03 0.03 0.05 0.03

Competitiveness 0.275 -0.001 -0.21 0.285* -0.001 -0.185 0.284 -0.001 -0.191

0.17 0.003 0.357 0.17 0.003 0.354 0.173 0.003 0.354

Dynamic coefficent -0.177*** -0.256*** -0.192*** -0.176*** -0.255*** -0.190*** -0.176*** -0.255*** -0.190***

0.02 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.02

No. Obs. 1230 1056 1207 1245 1069 1222 1245 1069 1222

R-sq 0.108 0.156 0.113 0.107 0.156 0.112 0.108 0.16 0.112

Sectoral PMR Sectoral PMR entry Sectoral PMR entry 2

Page 15: DIRECT AND INDIRECT CHANNELS FOR REGULATION … · DIRECT AND INDIRECT CHANNELS FOR REGULATION TO AFFECT TRADE IN ... Economic theories ... Owing to the high degree of information

15

Following the confirmation of the trade-boosting impact of product market regulation in export

markets, the next step in the analysis is to check whether in addition to this impact, regulations also affect

trade through other channels. To do so, the following equation is estimated:

∆𝑥𝑖,𝑡 = 𝛼0 + 𝛼1Δ𝑑𝑖,𝑡 + 𝛼2Δ𝑐𝑜𝑚𝑝𝑖,𝑡 + 𝛼4 + 𝛾1𝑃𝑀𝑅𝑖,𝑡−1 𝑚𝑖,𝑡−1 + {𝜌1 + 𝛾2𝑃𝑀𝑅𝑖,𝑡−1}𝑑𝑖,𝑡−1 +

{𝜌2+𝛾3𝑃𝑀𝑅𝑖,𝑡−1}𝑐𝑜𝑚𝑝𝑖,𝑡−1+𝜌3𝑃𝑀𝑅𝑖,𝑡−1+𝜌4𝑇+𝜀𝑖,𝑡 (4)

where ∆ indicates growth rates, x is exports, d is demand for exports, comp is the competitiveness

variable, all in logarithmic forms, T is the time trend and PMR is the product market regulation indicator.

The estimates show that the direct impact of regulation on exports that was confirmed previously,

fades out once the effect through other channels is controlled for (Table 5), with the exception of conduct

regulation (for which no significant effect was found earlier). In all model specifications regulation in

export markets increases the demand elasticity of exports. This works through the same logic as in the case

of imports: as regulation in a market decreases the flexibility of production in that market, changes in

demand will result in more exports by partners to this market. This is basically the only channel through

which sectoral regulation in export markets affects exports, with the exception that conduct regulation (in

export markets) also reinforces the direct (positive) impact of regulation in the export markets on exports.

In addition, sector specific conduct regulation decreases the speed at which exports change as a result to

changes in export demand and competitiveness. This may be related to more cumbersome procedures in

more regulated markets.

The finding that when controlling for indirect channels, the direct impact of regulation on exports

cancels out, has an important implication on the way the issue of regulation and trade flows needs to be

approached. First of all, the lack of a finding of any impact of regulation on trade in a setting without

controlling for indirect channels should not necessarily mean that regulation has no impact on trade. By the

same token, even if significant relationships are confirmed in a simple setting, they may be misleading as

important explanatory variables may be missing. Overall, the relationship between regulation and trade

should be treated in a more nuanced way, exploring various possible channels. This implication should not

be surprising given that domestic regulations are usually adopted for other purposes than to affect trade and

therefore their impact may work through other variables such as demand or competitiveness.

Estimation at the industry level shows that economy-wide regulation in export markets reduces

exports of professional services. This finding is robust whether the unit labour cost or the real effective

exchange rate is used as a measure of competitiveness and whether the average ETCR or the gas sector

ETCR is used as a measure of economy-wide regulation. This may be explained by the fact that the cross-

border provision of professional services usually involves the movement of natural persons that provide the

service and it may be more difficult for such suppliers to operate in more restrictive environments.

Page 16: DIRECT AND INDIRECT CHANNELS FOR REGULATION … · DIRECT AND INDIRECT CHANNELS FOR REGULATION TO AFFECT TRADE IN ... Economic theories ... Owing to the high degree of information

16

Table 10. Sector-specific regulation increases the demand elasticities and conduct regulation directly affects trade (exports)

Note: Sectoral PMR is the sector-specific PMR indicator, sectoral PMR entry is the entry restriction component of this indicator, sectoral PMR entry 2 is a variant of it, sectoral PMR conduct is an indicator where either the component related to conduct or market structure is used in a given sector, depending on availability. For the regulatory indicators an unpublished preliminary version of the 2008 PMR database is used. REER stands for real effective exchange rate, wage for sector-specific hourly wages and ULC for unit labour costs. For the estimation, an unbalanced dataset of OECD countries was used with data available from 1975.

Source: Authors’ estimation.

reer wage ulc reer wage ulc reer wage ulc reer wage ulc

Long-run coefficients

Demand 1.1*** 0.919*** 1.227*** 0.935** 0.839*** 1.023*** 0.916** 0.829*** 0.996*** 1.367*** 0.946*** 1.235***

0.42 0.32 0.4 0.41 0.3 0.38 0.4 0.3 0.38 0.42 0.33 0.4

Competitiveness 0.491 -0.037 -0.838 0.552 -0.03 -0.681 0.569 -0.031 -0.639 0.308 -0.03 -0.823

0.92 0.03 0.7 0.9 0.02 0.7 0.91 0.02 0.7 0.89 0.03 0.68

Regulation (in export market) 1.143 -0.75 1.675 -0.73 -1.924 -0.469 -0.813 -1.996 -0.635 3.91* 3.524* 4.858**

2.17 1.81 2.3 1.84 1.44 1.99 1.85 1.44 2 2.23 1.88 2.34

Trend 0.058*** 0.042*** 0.081*** 0.055*** 0.04*** 0.075*** 0.054*** 0.04*** 0.073*** 0.061*** 0.045*** 0.083***

0.01 0.01 0.02 0.01 0.01 0.02 0.01 0.01 0.02 0.01 0.01 0.02

Short-run coefficients

Demand -0.06** -0.098** -0.041 -0.06* -0.099* -0.041 -0.06** -0.1* -0.04 -0.058* -0.107** -0.048

0.03 0.05 0.03 0.03 0.05 0.03 0.03 0.05 0.03 0.03 0.05 0.03

Competitiveness 0.276 -0.001 -0.215 0.292* -0.001 -0.172 0.291** -0.001 -0.174 0.278 -0.002 -0.162

0.17 0.003 0.37 0.17 0.003 0.37 0.17 0.003 0.37 0.17 0.003 0.35

Dynamic coefficent -0.179*** -0.258*** -0.197*** -0.176*** -0.259*** -0.192*** -0.175*** -0.259*** -0.192*** -0.183*** -0.255*** -0.197***

0.02 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.02

Interaction term coefficients

Regulation-import 0.003 -0.005 0.006 -0.001 -0.01 0.002 -0.001 -0.01 0.002 0.01 0.031*** 0.019***

0.01 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.01

Regulation-demand 1.086*** 0.948*** 1.208*** 0.977*** 0.897*** 1.065*** 0.964*** 0.894*** 1.045*** 1.263*** 0.875*** 1.114***

0.37 0.27 0.35 0.36 0.26 0.34 0.36 0.25 0.33 0.37 0.31 0.37

Regulation-competitiveness 0.494 -0.027 -0.826 0.517 -0.023 -0.686 0.527 -0.023 -0.651 0.339 -0.029 -0.833

0.76 0.02 0.59 0.74 0.02 0.59 0.73 0.02 0.58 0.76 0.03 0.62

No. Obs. 1230 1056 1207 1245 1069 1222 1245 1069 1222 1256 1087 1248

R-sq 0.108 0.157 0.114 0.108 0.159 0.113 0.108 0.16 0.113 0.11 0.15 0.11

Sectoral PMR Sectoral PMR entry Sectoral PMR entry 2 Sectoral PMR conduct

Page 17: DIRECT AND INDIRECT CHANNELS FOR REGULATION … · DIRECT AND INDIRECT CHANNELS FOR REGULATION TO AFFECT TRADE IN ... Economic theories ... Owing to the high degree of information

17

Major lessons and further steps

This paper suggested an error-correction framework to analyse the relationship between domestic

product market regulation and international services trade. Apart from certain deficiencies related to data

availability, the model performs relatively well and provides insights into so far undiscovered aspects of

the relationship between regulation and services trade flows. The paper departs from the widely used

approach of gravity modeling as these models do not allow for testing long-term relationships or indirect

effects. To capture regulation, the OECD PMR indicators are used that are available for all OECD

countries and some series are sufficiently long to test long-term relationships. The impact of regulation on

both imports and exports was checked in separate frameworks.

The estimation results suggest that different types of regulations affect imports and exports in

different ways. On the one hand, economy-wide regulation in the importing country tends to affect imports

only indirectly, via increasing the demand elasticity of imports and accelerating the speed of import

adjustment following demand and competitiveness shocks. Sector-specific regulation, on the other hand,

tends to affect imports only via its increasing of demand elasticites. Regulation in export markets appears

to boost exports, though after controlling for indirect channels of regulatory impact on exports, this is

cancelled out. Economy-wide regulation in export markets does not appear to have a bearing on exports,

while sector-specific regulation in export markets tends to increase the demand elasticity for exports in all

model specifications. Regulations related to conduct and market structure in the export markets in addition

to directly boosting exports, tend to increase export demand elasticities and decrease the speed at which

exports react to changes in external demand and competitiveness.

A major lesson learnt from the analyses is that simple correlations of domestic regulation and

international trade may not provide a full picture of their relationship, therefore a more nuanced approach

is needed. The above error-correction framework allowed for the examination of indirect channels through

which regulations may affect trade and the results proved the existence of such channels. Although

domestic regulations are usually adopted with other considerations than boosting international trade in

services, having in mind their potential indirect impact on international trade may be useful when

formulating such regulations. A further refinement of the variables and an extension to more sectors would

provide further insights into the relationship between domestic regulation and international trade in

services.

Page 18: DIRECT AND INDIRECT CHANNELS FOR REGULATION … · DIRECT AND INDIRECT CHANNELS FOR REGULATION TO AFFECT TRADE IN ... Economic theories ... Owing to the high degree of information

18

REFERENCES

Deardorff, A.V. and R.M. Stern (2004), “Empirical Analysis of Barriers to International Services

Transactions and the Consequences of Liberalisation”, Research Seminar in International

Economics Discussion Paper No. 505, Gerald R. Ford School of Public Policy, The University of

Michigan.

Nguyen-Hong, D. (2005), “Techniques for estimating services barriers” in Dee, P. and M. Ferrantino (eds.)

Quantitative Methods for Assessing The Effects of Non-Tariff Measures and Trade Facilitation, Asia

Pacific Economic Cooperation, Committee on Trade and Investment.