debt restructuring costs and bankruptcy risk: …...debt restructuring costs and bankruptcy risk:...

41
Debt Restructuring Costs and Bankruptcy Risk: Evidence from CDS Spreads Abstract We examine the effects of a recent change to the US tax code that reduced the costs lenders incur when restructuring loans out of court (Regulation TD9599). The regulation contemplated particular types of loans, allowing us to use a triple-differences approach to identify the degree to which borrow- ers are differentially affected by the shift in restructuring costs. We model these changes and show how CDS market responses allow us to disentangle the relative costs of in-court versus out-of-court restructuring. Our evidence is consistent with markets anticipating more out-of-court workouts after the passage of TD9599. CDS spreads decline by record-low figures on the regulation’s announcement and the drop is concentrated among distressed firms with high syndicated loans-to-total debt ratios — those borrowers most affected by the reduction in renegotiation costs. Stock returns of these distressed firms as well as of their syndicate lenders outperform the market on the announcement of TD9599. As a result of the reduction in bankruptcy likelihood, distressed firms’ access to syndicated loans expands and their financing costs decline. Our analysis provides insights into how altering regulatory constraints can improve welfare in financial distress. Key words: Debt renegotiation, bankruptcy, credit default swaps, corporate taxes, credit access. JEL classification: G33, G32.

Upload: others

Post on 11-Apr-2020

8 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Debt Restructuring Costs and Bankruptcy Risk: …...Debt Restructuring Costs and Bankruptcy Risk: Evidence from CDS Spreads Abstract We examine the e ects of a recent change to the

Debt Restructuring Costs and Bankruptcy Risk:Evidence from CDS Spreads

Abstract

We examine the effects of a recent change to the US tax code that reduced the costs lenders incurwhen restructuring loans out of court (Regulation TD9599). The regulation contemplated particulartypes of loans, allowing us to use a triple-differences approach to identify the degree to which borrow-ers are differentially affected by the shift in restructuring costs. We model these changes and showhow CDS market responses allow us to disentangle the relative costs of in-court versus out-of-courtrestructuring. Our evidence is consistent with markets anticipating more out-of-court workouts afterthe passage of TD9599. CDS spreads decline by record-low figures on the regulation’s announcementand the drop is concentrated among distressed firms with high syndicated loans-to-total debt ratios— those borrowers most affected by the reduction in renegotiation costs. Stock returns of thesedistressed firms as well as of their syndicate lenders outperform the market on the announcement ofTD9599. As a result of the reduction in bankruptcy likelihood, distressed firms’ access to syndicatedloans expands and their financing costs decline. Our analysis provides insights into how alteringregulatory constraints can improve welfare in financial distress.

Key words: Debt renegotiation, bankruptcy, credit default swaps, corporate taxes, credit access.

JEL classification: G33, G32.

Page 2: Debt Restructuring Costs and Bankruptcy Risk: …...Debt Restructuring Costs and Bankruptcy Risk: Evidence from CDS Spreads Abstract We examine the e ects of a recent change to the

1 Introduction

Firms unable to meet their financial obligations often attempt to negotiate with their cred-

itors out of court (Gertner and Scharfstein (1991) and Franks and Torous (1994)). These

negotiations are thought to be beneficial because early, mutually-agreed restructurings avoid

the deadweight costs of drawn-out court battles (Gilson (1997)). Yet, these negotiations are

costly, fraught with coordination problems, and do not always succeed (Bolton and Scharfstein

(1996)). Arguably, the relative costs of in- and out-of-court restructurings are likely to deter-

mine whether distressed firms file for bankruptcy. But disentangling these costs is difficult,

and there exists only limited evidence on the extent they truly affect distress resolution.

In this paper, we examine a statutory-induced shift to debt renegotiation costs, showing a

well-identified connection between the relative costs of in-court versus out-of-court restructur-

ings and the likelihood that renegotiation of distressed debt takes place. Our analysis exploits

a number of features of a recent piece of regulation adopted in the U.S. that substantially

reduced the tax payments that certain lenders owe upon restructuring debt out of court. Reg-

ulation TD9599 (which we describe in detail shortly) was adopted on September 12, 2012 and

significantly reduced restructuring costs for syndicated loans, but not for other types of debt.

Notably, TD9599 has unusual legal powers over loans that were issued in the past — years

before the regulation was passed — but restructured after its implementation.

Taxes present an important obstacle to out-of-court renegotiation and are a major deter-

minant of the choice between bankruptcy and restructurings (Gilson (1997)). Lenders incur

large tax costs on restructured loans, and those costs erode the continuation value upon which

lenders and borrowers can bargain out of court. Prior to TD9599 the tax treatment on renego-

tiated syndicated loans was highly punitive, as lenders would owe taxes on so-called “phantom

gains,” which far exceeded any income earned from renegotiations.1

To identify how this reduction in out-of-court costs affected debt renegotiation, we look

at the market price reaction of an instrument directly linked to renegotiation: credit default

swaps (CDS). In a standard CDS contract, a buyer and a seller write an agreement that ref-

erences either a specific debt issue or firm. The buyer pays the seller a periodic fee (the CDS

spread), and the seller makes a lump-sum payment if the underlying reference experiences a

1Prior to TD 9599, creditors who acquired syndicated debt and restructured it out of court would owe taxesbased on the difference between the secondary market purchase price and the loan’s par value — which is higherthan the distressed debt’s market value. The creditor would therefore owe taxes on large unrealized gains. Assuch, the more deeply distressed the borrower, the higher the lender’s tax burden on a loan restructuring.

1

Page 3: Debt Restructuring Costs and Bankruptcy Risk: …...Debt Restructuring Costs and Bankruptcy Risk: Evidence from CDS Spreads Abstract We examine the e ects of a recent change to the

credit event.2 CDS spreads thus directly relate to bankruptcy risk: they represent the amount

buyers are willing to pay to insure against corporate default (see Longstaff et al. (2005)).

Examining changes in CDS spreads around TD9599’s announcement gives unique insights into

the effects of reducing out-of-court renegotiation costs on bankruptcy risk. Our identification

strategy is further strengthened by the fact that TD9599 only affected syndicated loans. As

such, one can measure the relative impact of that regulation on firm bankruptcy risk according

to the weight of those specific types of loans on the firm’s overall debt profile.

To guide our examination, we analytically model the effect of changes in renegotiation costs

on CDS spreads as a way to generate testable predictions about the 2012 IRS ruling. The model

endogenizes CDS insurance and shows how the IRS ruling facilitated out-of-court renegotia-

tion for firms that are distressed. In the model, a borrower raises financing from competitive

lenders, and upon experiencing distress can either declare bankruptcy or try to renegotiate out

of court. If the borrower files for bankruptcy, lenders that bought CDS insurance receive the

full value of debt, while uninsured lenders are exposed to default and to additional losses. If

out-of-court renegotiation occurs, lenders owe taxes. The tax is based on the difference between

the debt purchase price and either (1) the par value of the renegotiated issue, or (2) the market

value of the renegotiated payment. Our modeling is predicated on IRS tax standards. In par-

ticular, prior to TD9599, the IRS classified syndicated loans as non-publicly traded debt with

tax value determined by the loan’s par. The new regulation, however, reclassified syndicated

loans as publicly-traded debt, with tax value based on market prices at time of renegotiation.

One key insight of the model is that the effect of taxes on renegotiation depends on whether

lenders purchase CDS insurance. If lenders are uninsured, the borrower will offer a payment

equal to the lenders’ recovery in bankruptcy. The market value of this payment is lower than

the debt’s face value, so taxable income is lower and renegotiation is easier when taxes are

levied on market values, such as is the case of taxes under TD9599. If lenders are insured,

however, the borrower’s offer must exceed the face value of debt; else lenders trigger their CDS

insurance. In this case, the tax burden is larger when taxes apply to market values, as in the

case of TD9599, making renegotiation harder.

Our model is unique in demonstrating how CDS markets, taxes, and alternative distress

resolution mechanisms are connected in the real economy. When the borrower’s fundamentals

2A credit event is defined by the International Swaps and Derivatives Association (ISDA) as a default onthe underlying debt issue, debt acceleration, failure to pay, repudiation, or bankruptcy filing. Since April2009, the standard CDS contract does not recognize out-of-court restructuring as a credit event.

2

Page 4: Debt Restructuring Costs and Bankruptcy Risk: …...Debt Restructuring Costs and Bankruptcy Risk: Evidence from CDS Spreads Abstract We examine the e ects of a recent change to the

are strong, bankruptcy risk is low regardless of the tax rule and lenders’ insurance decision.

However, when the borrower’s financial situation is weak, bankruptcy is avoided when the

fraction of uninsured lenders is sufficiently large. In this case, taxes based on market val-

ues can significantly decrease the size of the out-of-court payment and reduce the probability

of bankruptcy. This, in turn, lowers CDS spreads. Our model goes further in generating

predictions for the impact of changes in renegotiation costs on credit access.

We test our model’s predictions using a triple-differences strategy focusing on how CDS

spreads change around the announcement of TD9599. We do so using a sample of non-financial

firms for which trading of CDSs is liquid. Since TD9599 only affects syndicated loans, we com-

pare spread changes for firms with high versus low ratios of syndicated loans to total debt.

To better identify our effects, we add another layer of contrasts to our tests and verify our

model’s prediction that the regulation’s effect on spreads is stronger for firms with weaker

fundamentals. We do so by comparing distressed and non-distressed firms; where we classify

firms according to metrics such as Altman’s Z-Score and distance-to-default (Merton (1974).

We show that CDS spreads drop by 27 basis points in the two-week window around the

announcement of TD9599. This is the single largest two-week drop in spreads since the depths

of the Financial Crisis in 2009. Furthermore, this drop is exactly concentrated among firms

for which renegotiation costs presumably decrease the most: spreads decline by 36 basis points

for distressed firms at the top tercile of the syndicated loans–debt ratio, but only by 15 points

for distressed firms at the bottom of that ratio.3 At the other hand of the spectrum, for non-

distressed firms the difference in spread changes across high versus low syndicated loans–debt

ratio is close to zero. Indeed, our tests show that the spread difference between high versus

low loans–debt ratio increases monotonically with measures of financial distress around the

inception of TD9599.

We look for additional externalities of TD9599 and find that the increase in renegotiation

likelihood created shareholder value gains for both borrowers and lenders. In particular, dis-

tressed firms with high syndicated loans–debt ratios experienced a 1.6% abnormal return in the

3-day window around the regulation’s announcement. The tax change also benefits syndicated

lenders: they outperform the market by 4.3%.

Next, we analyze how the market for new financing responds to a reduction in renegotia-

tion costs. Consistent with our model’s predictions, we find that markups on new syndicated

loans issued to distressed firms drop by 28 basis points (13% of the sample mean) relative

3Notably, distressed and undistressed firms have similar syndicated loans–debt ratio distributions.

3

Page 5: Debt Restructuring Costs and Bankruptcy Risk: …...Debt Restructuring Costs and Bankruptcy Risk: Evidence from CDS Spreads Abstract We examine the e ects of a recent change to the

to non-distressed firms following TD9599’s announcement. We also find that distressed firms

are 12% more likely to obtain a new loan after TD9599’s announcement. Notably, access and

financing terms improve primarily for long-term loans, which most expose lenders to deterio-

ration in borrower financial conditions and hence likely benefitted most from the tax change.

Our results indicate that reducing out-of-court renegotiation costs leads distressed borrowers

to obtain greater access to the syndicated loan market and cheaper funding.

One potential concern is that CDS spreads of distressed/high-loan firms could have been

decreasing relative to spreads of other firms even before TD9599, due to market trends and dy-

namics that we do not observe; in other words, our underlying “parallel trends assumption” may

be violated. To investigate this possibility, we re-estimate our specification over a large num-

ber of experimental windows from January 2010 through December 2012, assigning a “placebo

event” to each window. We find that among distressed firms, the drop in spreads following the

actual TD9599 announcement is larger than all but one of the 50 placebo events we simulate.

Notably, spread changes for 44 of the 50 placebo events are either statistically insignificant

or positive. Furthermore, our triple-differences tests present a high threshold for other unob-

servable variables that could bias our results. To contaminate our inference, bankruptcy risk

would have to decrease for non-tax related reasons on the TD9599 announcement, precisely

for firms that are distressed and have high loans–debt ratios. Broad macroeconomic shocks,

for example, are unlikely to produce such a nuanced confounder.

Our paper is related to recent literature showing how CDS trading affects firms’ credit risk.

Saretto and Tookes (2013), Ashcraft and Santos (2009), and Hirtle (2009) show that firms

with CDSs written on their debt observe lower interest rates on their bank loans and increased

corporate leverage and debt maturity. Our study also relates to theoretical and empirical anal-

yses showing that CDS trading increases distressed firms’ probability of bankruptcy through

the “empty creditor problem” (Bolton and Oehmke (2011), Campello and Matta (2012), and

Subrahmanyam et al. (2014)). Our work adds to this new literature by using CDS markets to

show how debt renegotiation costs affect bankruptcy risk and financing costs.

Our paper is also related to empirical work investigating how the relative costs of in- versus

out-of-court renegotiation affect debt restructuring and financing.4 This work suggests that

out-of-court renegotiation likelihood is decreasing in the number and dispersion of lenders,

borrowers’ asset tangibility, and secured debt, among other factors. Precisely identifying such

4Papers that contribute to this literature include Gilson et al. (1990), Asquith et al. (1994), Gilson (1997),Benmelech and Bergman (2008), Roberts and Sufi (2009), and Morellec et al. (2013).

4

Page 6: Debt Restructuring Costs and Bankruptcy Risk: …...Debt Restructuring Costs and Bankruptcy Risk: Evidence from CDS Spreads Abstract We examine the e ects of a recent change to the

linkages is, nonetheless, complicated by lack of variation in renegotiation costs. Some recent

papers attempt to overcome this problem by examining the effect of changes to bankruptcy

codes and procedures on financing costs (see Giambona et al. (2013) and Benmelech et al.

(2005)). We contribute to this literature by showing how a reduction to out-of-court renego-

tiation costs increases the odds of renegotiation, subsequently increasing distressed borrowers’

financing conditions, shareholder value, and access to credit.

Lastly, our study contains important implications for economic policymakers. Crucially, all

of our findings are derived from an arbitrary relaxation of regulatory tax constraints. We show

that both borrowers and lenders benefited from TD9599, providing an estimate of the dead-

weight loss from taxing renegotiated debt at par values (which is customary worldwide). Our

results imply that policies that reduce renegotiation costs can improve contracting efficiency

and the availability of credit at lower costs.

The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 describes the tax treatment of

renegotiated debt, explaining the statutory changes introduced by Regulation TD9599. Sec-

tion 3 contains our model. Section 4 discusses our data and presents our main results on CDS

spreads, equity values, and access to credit. Section 5 contains robustness checks. Section 6

concludes. All proofs are in the Appendix.

2 Background on the IRS Redefinition of Public Debt

In this section, we briefly describe the tax treatment of out-of-court debt restructuring. We

then discuss the critical features of Regulation TD9599 redefining public debt.

2.1 Tax Treatment of Debt Restructuring

When a debt issue is significantly modified outside of the bankruptcy procedure, the IRS treats

the modification as an exchange of the old debt issue for a new one. An extension of the issue’s

maturity or a change in the interest payments are examples of significant modifications. A debt

exchange qualifies as a taxable event, with implications for lenders, borrowers, and investors

who purchase debt on the secondary market.

Debtholders must report income to the IRS when restructuring debt, and their tax obliga-

tions depend on whether the IRS classifies the debt as publicly or privately traded. For private

debt, tax is based on the spread between the par value of the original debt contract and the

debt’s secondary market price when the debtholder purchased it; alternatively, on the issue’s

5

Page 7: Debt Restructuring Costs and Bankruptcy Risk: …...Debt Restructuring Costs and Bankruptcy Risk: Evidence from CDS Spreads Abstract We examine the e ects of a recent change to the

Figure 1. Tax Treatment of Debt Restructuring

Panel A. Debt is privately traded

Scenario 1 Scenario 2

• Original debt issue has par of 100 • Same as 1, except lender retains• Investor buys debt on secondarymarket for 40

debt

• Renegotiated debt has marketvalue of 50 and par of 100

Debtholder’staxes:

τ × (100− 40)→ tax on unrealized“phantom gains”

τ × (100− 100)→ no tax owed

Panel B. Debt is publicly traded

Scenario 1 Scenario 2

• Original debt issue has par of 100 • Same as 1, except lender retains• Investor buys debt on secondarymarket for 40

debt

• Renegotiated debt has marketvalue of 50 and par of 100

Debtholder’staxes:

τ×(50−40)→ lower tax obligation τ × (50− 100)→ receive tax credit

original purchase price if the debtholder is the first (original) lender. Debt restructurings often

modify the maturity date or coupon rate while leaving the par value unchanged. For distressed

firms, the original par value is generally far higher than the loan’s market price. Accordingly, a

distressed-debt investor may owe taxes on “phantom gains” that exceed actual profits earned

from trading the debt.

For public debt, however, debtholders owe tax on the spread between the fair market value

of the modified debt and the purchase price of the original issue. In this case, investors owe tax

on just the profits that they can realize by selling the restructured debt. Furthermore, when

the first lender retains the debt and renegotiates it, the lender receives a tax credit reflecting

the loss they have incurred. This makes debt restructuring even more attractive.

Figure 1 displays an example of the tax obligations that debtholders face when restructur-

ing debt. In Panel A, a privately traded debt issue is restructured so that its new market value

is 50, while its par value remains 100. If a distressed-debt investor purchases the debt before

it is restructured for 40, they will owe tax of τ(100− 40). Because the debt is private, the IRS

6

Page 8: Debt Restructuring Costs and Bankruptcy Risk: …...Debt Restructuring Costs and Bankruptcy Risk: Evidence from CDS Spreads Abstract We examine the e ects of a recent change to the

regards the event as if the investor bought a debt issue for 40 and exchanged it for debt worth

100. The investor owes a tax payment that may be substantially larger than any gains they

obtain from trading the firm’s debt. The figure also shows that if the primary lender retains

the debt, it will receive no tax credit, but it will also not owe taxes.

Panel B shows that the debtholder is better off when the issue is public. In this case, an

investor would owe tax of just τ(50−40). The gain of 10 is the actual profit the investor would

receive from selling the modified debt at its market price. If the primary lender retains the

debt, it receives a tax credit based on the write-down from the restructuring.

Debt restructuring is a taxable event also for borrowers and the taxes owed depend on how

the IRS classifies the debt. Borrowers owe no tax when a private debt issue is restructured so

that the par value does not change.5 For public debt, borrowers incur “cancellation of debt

income” equal to the spread between the issue’s original par value and the market price of the

modified issue. This leads to a tax payment in the typical case that the modified debt is worth

less than the original issue. However, in this case the borrower’s tax payments are offset by an

equal-sized tax credit, called an “original issue discount.” The main difference is in the timing

of the tax payments: the income tax is immediately recognized, while the credit is spread out

over the years to maturity of the modified debt issue.6

2.2 Change in Debt Classification under TD9599

In parallel to developments in the debt markets during the Financial Crisis, government offi-

cials announced in various forums their plans to update the tax definition of public debt. At a

Practicing Law Institute Conference held on October, 2009, Treasury Deputy Tax Legislative

Counsel Jeffrey Van Hove and Treasury Deputy Assistant for Tax Policy Emily McMahon gave

presentations discussing the update. The public debt definition update was also listed as one

item in the department’s 2009-10 Priority Guidance Plan, released the following month. On

September 12, 2012 the IRS announced Regulation TD9599 redefining public debt, with an

effective date of November 13, 2012.

Before TD9599’s adoption, taxes were based on a 1994 regulation that classified debt as

publicly traded if it satisfied one of three conditions:

5Specifically, for private debt restructuring borrowers owe tax on the spread between the par value of theoriginal issue and the par value of the modified issue. When the par value does not change, this spread is zero.

6The 2009 American Reinvestment and Recovery Act delayed this tax by allowing firms that restructureddebt in 2009 or 2010 to spread out the cancellation of debt income from 2014 to 2018. This provision, however,expired in 2010 and does not affect our results.

7

Page 9: Debt Restructuring Costs and Bankruptcy Risk: …...Debt Restructuring Costs and Bankruptcy Risk: Evidence from CDS Spreads Abstract We examine the e ects of a recent change to the

1. The issue is listed on a securities exchange or traded in a market such as the interbank

market.

2. The issue’s price appears in a quotation medium.

3. A price quote can be obtained from dealers or traders.

TD9599 added to these conditions that debt would be classified as public also if a “soft”

price quote could be obtained from at least one broker, dealer, or pricing service. Most syn-

dicated loans satisfied this new condition and were reclassified from private to public debt.7

Notably, TD9599 also specifies a size threshold: debt can only be considered public if the

original issue amount exceeds $100 million. Issues smaller than this threshold were reclassified

as private, even if traded on an exchange.

The IRS applies the tax treatment for public debt to a restructuring if either the original or

modified debt issue meets the conditions outlined in TD9599. Therefore, a syndicated loan that

is issued before November 2012, but restructured afterward, is considered public for tax pur-

poses. This feature of the tax laws mitigates selection bias in our analysis, as the tax treatment

under TD9599 effects loans that were issued well before the regulation was even proposed.

3 The Model

The economy lasts for three periods t = 0, 1, 2. There is a borrower and a continuum of lenders

indexed by i ∈ I. The borrower needs financing and issues a measure 1 of debt securities in

t = 0. Each security promises to pay 1 unit of funds in t = 2 in exchange for a price p paid

in t = 0. Each lender has a unit demand for securities and the borrower raises funds from a

subset of mass 1 of lenders. All players are risk neutral and there is no discounting.

With probability λ the borrower is “sound” and generates a verifiable cash flow of y > 1

in t = 2. With probability 1 − λ the borrower is in “distress” in which case the value of

the borrower’s assets depends on whether he renegotiates the debt out of court or files for

bankruptcy (in-court restructuring). If the debt is restructured in court, the assets have a

verifiable recovery ratio of r < 1. In the event of an out-of-court renegotiation, the assets are

worth a positive amount v (θ), which is continuous and strictly increasing in θ. The borrower’s

7At the time, Cleary Gottlieb, a leading international law firm stated: “The final regulations are likely tocause most syndicated loans to be treated as publicly traded, especially as a result of the fact that indicativequotes — a term that is very broadly defined — may cause a loan to be publicly traded.”

8

Page 10: Debt Restructuring Costs and Bankruptcy Risk: …...Debt Restructuring Costs and Bankruptcy Risk: Evidence from CDS Spreads Abstract We examine the e ects of a recent change to the

Figure 2. Model Timing

t = 0 t = 1 t = 21. Borrower issues debt of 1. Lenders receive signals xi 1. If cash flow y is realized1 in exchange for p about the fundamental θ the borrower is sound

2. Lenders choose whether 2. Otherwise there isto buy CDS protection renegotiation:

(i) if renegotiation succeedsassets are worth v (θ)(ii) otherwise they yield r

continuation value θ is unknown to all participants until t = 2 and is drawn from a continuously

differentiable and strictly positive density k with support on the real line. We assume that

v (θ) is nonverifiable in t = 0 and 1, but becomes verifiable to the borrower and participating

lenders in t = 2. This opens room for out-of-court renegotiation between the parties in t = 2.

We also assume that v (θ) is non-verifiable to outside lenders, so the borrower cannot pledge

existing assets to obtain outside financing.

Renegotiation proceeds as follows. The borrower offers to each lender i an amount qi. If a

lender rejects the borrower’s offer, then renegotiation fails. In this case each lender i is entitled

to receive r in court. If all lenders accept the borrower’s offer, assets are worth v (θ) and each

lender i receives qi. The borrower receives v (θ)−∫qidi.

We also assume lenders are exposed to the borrower’s risk of bankruptcy, which creates

the need for insurance. In particular, we assume that lenders suffer an additional loss ` > 0

if they are not insured when the borrower files for bankruptcy. This loss can be thought as

regulatory penalty for the bank’s capital going below a required threshold (Thompson (2010))

or a deadweight loss that results from the lender approaching insolvency (Duffee and Zhou

(2001)). This is a simple way to model the bank’ exposure without having to model its capital

structure.

Each lender i’s insurance decision is made in t = 1, after receiving a noisy signal about the

borrower’s fundamental given by

xi = θ + σηi, (1)

where σ > 0 and the noisy terms are i.i.d. according to continuous and integrable density h

with support on the real line. Given their signals, lenders chose whether to buy CDS insurance

from a CDS provider. There is continuum of providers that act as price takers, and each of

9

Page 11: Debt Restructuring Costs and Bankruptcy Risk: …...Debt Restructuring Costs and Bankruptcy Risk: Evidence from CDS Spreads Abstract We examine the e ects of a recent change to the

them offers a CDS contract that pays 1 unit if there is a credit event in t = 2, in exchange

for a fee of f or “spread” paid up front. A credit event occurs only if the project fails and the

borrower declares bankruptcy. The CDS market is populated by liquidity traders that always

buy CDS and that CDS providers do not know whether the buyers of CDS are debt holders.

As we will show, the probability of bankruptcy depends only on lenders’ CDS positions. This

implies that CDS providers cannot learn about the probability of a credit event from CDS

demand. We assume that although lenders’ insurance positions are known to all participants

in t = 2, they cannot be contracted upon.

Finally, and importantly for our purposes, we model the real-world feature that lenders pay

a tax rate of τ on the gains from renegotiations that occur out of court. Following TD9599,

the amount of taxes paid depends on whether debt securities are classified as private or public.

If private, taxes are levied on the difference between the par value and the purchase price:

τ (1− p). If public, the tax rate applies to the difference between the debt’s value upon

renegotiation and the purchase price: τ (qi − p).

3.1 Equilibrium and Results

Our analysis proceeds as follows. We focus on the case in which the borrower is in distress in

t = 2. We first solve for the borrower’s offer to lenders that induces renegotiation, separately

for each tax classification of debt. Next, we show how the relationship between taxes and

renegotiation likelihood depends on the fraction of lenders that purchase insurance. We then

apply “global games” analysis to study lenders’ decisions about whether to purchase insurance,

and the resulting equilibrium CDS spread f and debt price p.8

Lenders agree to renegotiate if the borrower offers a stake in the continuation firm that

exceeds their outside option, which is 1 if the lender is insured and r otherwise. The borrower

optimally offers each lender i a stake that just meets this outside option. Let qpari and qmkti be

the offers made to lender i when the tax rate applies to the par (1 − p) and market (qi − p)taxable incomes, respectively. Then

qpari − τ (1− p) = qmkti − τ(qmkti − p

)= max r, 1− si , (2)

where si = 1 if lender i does not have a CDS and 0 if otherwise. Rearranging Eq. (2) yields

qmkti = (max r, 1− si − τp) (1− τ)−1 and qpari = qmkti + τ(1− qmkti

).

8See Carlsson and van Damme (1993a,b) and Morris and Shin (2003) for a comprehensive discussion onglobal games.

10

Page 12: Debt Restructuring Costs and Bankruptcy Risk: …...Debt Restructuring Costs and Bankruptcy Risk: Evidence from CDS Spreads Abstract We examine the e ects of a recent change to the

These expressions show that when qmkti < 1, the borrower must make a higher offer to

induce renegotiation when taxes apply to par values (where debt is classified as private) than

when taxes apply to market values (debt is classified as public). Note that qmkti < 1 leads to

renegotiation only when lenders are not insured. When lenders are insured, the borrower must

offer a net-of-tax payment qmkti > 1 — otherwise the lender will force bankruptcy and claim the

CDS payout of 1. However, in this case lenders owe more tax when debt is public (τ(qmkti − p

))

than when debt is private (τ (1− p)). This outcome can occur when the borrower does not

have sufficient cash to repay the debt, but can offer an equity stake in the going concern v (θ)

that exceeds debt owed.9

The impact of TD9599 on out-of-court renegotiation depends on lenders’ decisions to pur-

chase CDS insurance on the borrower. We now solve for the relationship between renegotia-

tion outcome and the fraction of insured lenders. Out-of-court renegotiation under tax rule

j = par,mkt fails if and only if:

v (θ) < Qj ≡∫qji di. (3)

Let l be the fraction of lenders that do not insure. When l = 1, renegotiation can succeed

for offers below 1, and Qmkt ≤ Qpar. Conversely, when all lenders insure (l = 0) the borrower

must offer more when taxes are levied on market values, so Qmkt ≥ Qpar. Since taxes are the

same when the out-of-court offer equals the face value of debt, there exists a critical level of

uninsured lenders such that Qmkt = Qpar = 1.

Expression (3) can be re-written as:

v (θ) < l qji (si = 0) + (1− l) qji (si = 1) (4)

Re-arranging (4) yields the threshold fraction of insured lenders P j (θ) that cause renegotiation

to fail under each tax classification:

Pmkt (θ) = [1− v (θ) + τ (v (θ)− p)] (1− r)−1 , (5)

and

P par (θ) = Pmkt (θ) + τ (1− v (θ)) (1− r)−1 . (6)

When l < P j (θ), the borrowers’ asset value v (θ) is too low to generate net-of-tax offers that

match insured lenders’ CDS payout. One implication is that when the borrower’s continuation

9In this case, lenders’ tax obligations would continue to be determined by the trading status of debt. TheIRS considers any property received in lieu of debt payments to be subject to tax if the property’s valueexceeds the purchase price of the debt.

11

Page 13: Debt Restructuring Costs and Bankruptcy Risk: …...Debt Restructuring Costs and Bankruptcy Risk: Evidence from CDS Spreads Abstract We examine the e ects of a recent change to the

value in distress is low (v (θ) < 1), the threshold value P par (θ) is higher than Pmkt (θ). The

opposite holds when the borrower’s continuation value in distress is high (v (θ) > 1). Expres-

sions (5) and (6) therefore show that the effect of TD9599 on renegotiation likelihood depends

on lenders’ decisions whether to purchase CDS. We discuss this link in greater detail after

solving for the full equilibrium below.

To generate testable predictions, we need to endogenize the CDS spread f and price of

debt p. This is a challenging problem, because each individual lender’s demand for insurance

(and hence the CDS spread) depends on both the borrower’s continuation value and other

lenders’ decisions whether to buy CDS. To see why, consider the payoffs to any lender i. If the

lender purchases insurance, they receive a constant payout π ≡ 1 − f whether a credit event

occurs or not. If the lender remains uninsured, the payoff is π = λ+ (1− λ) r when P j (θ) ≤ l

(renegotiation succeeds) and π = λ+ (1− λ) (r − `) when P j (θ) > l (renegotiation fails).

We use techniques developed by the global games literature to solve for the equilibrium. We

briefly describe the process here, and present the full details of the analysis in the Appendix.

The steps we follow to solve for equilibrium are:

1. We focus on the situation when lenders’ signals about θ become nearly precise. This

allows the equilibrium to depend only on strategic uncertainty about other lenders’ de-

cisions, and not fundamental uncertainty about the borrowers’ continuation value.

2. For the threshold lender who is indifferent between insuring and not insuring given beliefs

about l, the expected payoff from not insuring equals the constant payoff from buying

CDS. We use this fact to compute the equilibrium cutoff θ∗j for which the threshold lender

buys insurance: ∫ P j(θ∗j )

0

π dl +

∫ 1

P j(θ∗j )π dl = 1− f , (7)

3. We use expression (A.2) in the Appendix to solve for the equilibrium demand for CDS.

To solve for equilibrium CDS supply, we use the fact that CDS providers are com-

petitive so the fee they charge allows them to break even in expectation. This yields

fj = (1− λ)K(θ∗j), where K

(θ∗j)

is the quantity demanded of CDS.10

4. We substitute the above expression for fj into expression (A.2) to derive the equilibrium

CDS spread.

10Note that demand in expression (A.2) depends on f , which is endogenous. We first take f as givenand solve for the equilibrium demand and supply of CDS. Then, we show in the full characterization of theequilibrium with endogenous CDS fees that there is a unique cutoff satisfying (A.2).

12

Page 14: Debt Restructuring Costs and Bankruptcy Risk: …...Debt Restructuring Costs and Bankruptcy Risk: Evidence from CDS Spreads Abstract We examine the e ects of a recent change to the

This process leads to the following proposition on the equilibrium CDS spread, and its

relationship to tax classification of debt:

Proposition 1 Suppose lenders’ exposure to bankruptcy risk ` and recovery ratio r are suf-

ficiently large. In the limit σ → 0, the unique equilibrium of the game starting in t = 1 is

characterized as follows: (i) lenders follow monotone strategies with cutoff θ∗∗j such that no

lender insures if θ > θ∗∗j and all lenders insure if θ < θ∗∗j and (ii) CDS providers charge a CDS

fee given by f ∗j , where

θ∗∗j = P j−1 ([K(θ∗∗j)− (1− r)

]`−1)

(8)

f ∗j = (1− λ)K(θ∗∗j). (9)

In addition, θ∗∗par ≥ θ∗∗mkt if the probability that v (θ) ≤ 1 is sufficiently high, with reverse

inequality if otherwise.

This result shows that equilibrium effect of regulation TD9599 on the probability of bankruptcy

occurs through P j (defined in (5) and (6)), which determines the difficulty to renegotiate the

debt out of court. As discussed earlier, P par ≥ Pmkt when v (θ) ≤ 1 and P par > Pmkt other-

wise. If the borrower is likely to be in a critical situation in the event of distress (v (θ) ≤ 1),

then renegotiation only succeeds when a large fraction of lenders do not insure. Yet when

lenders do not insure, the tax burden of renegotiating debt is lower when taxes are based on

market prices, reducing the offer the borrower must make to induce renegotiation. Proposition

1 shows that these two effects interact so that lenders coordinate to not insure when v (θ) ≤ 1

and taxes are based on market values.

To complete the equilibrium, our last step is to determine the price of debt p∗j . Since lenders

are competitive, the equilibrium p∗j satisfies the following breakeven condition in t = 0:

p∗j = K(θ∗∗j (p∗)

) [1− f ∗j

]+(1−K

(θ∗∗j(p∗j)))

[λ+ (1− λ) r] , (10)

The right-hand side of (10) is positive and less than 1, so there exists p∗j in the unit interval that

satisfies the equality. Moreover, the equilibrium price of debt p∗j is decreasing in the probability

of bankruptcy given distress. Therefore, the borrower’s cost of financing is affected by the tax

rule through θ∗∗j (pj). From the results in Proposition 1, we conclude that the equilibrium fi-

nancing cost is lower when taxes apply to market values and the borrower’s continuation value

upon distress is likely to be low (v (θ) ≤ 1). Conversely, if the borrower’s continuation value

in distress is likely to be high, then taxes levied on par values result in a relatively lower cost

of debt.

13

Page 15: Debt Restructuring Costs and Bankruptcy Risk: …...Debt Restructuring Costs and Bankruptcy Risk: Evidence from CDS Spreads Abstract We examine the e ects of a recent change to the

We now characterize the full equilibrium of the game starting in t = 0 through the following

proposition:

Proposition 2 Suppose lenders’ exposure to bankruptcy risk ` and recovery ratio r are suf-

ficiently large. In the limit σ → 0, the unique equilibrium of the game starting in t = 0 is

characterized as follows: (i) the borrower issues debt at price p∗j , (ii) lenders follow monotone

strategies with cutoff θ∗∗j(p∗j)

such that no lender insures if θ > θ∗∗j(p∗j)

and all lenders insure

if θ < θ∗∗j(p∗j), and (iii) CDS providers charge a CDS fee given by f ∗j

(p∗j), where

θ∗∗j(p∗j)

= P j−1 ([K(θ∗∗j(p∗j))− (1− r)

]`−1)

,

f ∗j(p∗j)

= (1− λ)K(θ∗∗j(p∗j))

, (11)

p∗j = λ+ (1− λ) r − (1− λ)K(θ∗∗j(p∗j)) [

K(θ∗∗j(p∗j))− (1− r)

]. (12)

In addition, p∗par ≤ p∗mkt, θ∗∗par

(p∗par

)≥ θ∗∗mkt (p∗mkt), and f ∗par

(p∗par

)≥ f ∗mkt (p∗mkt) if the probabil-

ity that v (θ) ≤ 1 is sufficiently high, with reverse inequalities if otherwise.

Before we finish the model analysis, we derive an important result on the effect of taxes

on the borrower’s equity value. Since the borrower is the residual claimant, his payoff in

equilibrium (equal to v (θ)−Qj) is equivalent to equity value in our economy. If the borrower

is in distress in t = 2, he gets v (θ) − Qj(l, p∗j

), which equals v (θ) − Qj

(1, p∗j

)if θ > θ∗∗j

(p∗j)

and equals v (θ)−Qj(0, p∗j

)if otherwise. Therefore, his ex-ante payoff in t = 0 is

λ (y − 1)+(1− λ)

[∫ θ∗∗j (p∗j)

−∞

[v (θ)−Qj

(0, p∗j

)]k (θ) dθ +

∫ ∞θ∗∗j (p∗j)

[v (θ)−Qj

(1, p∗j

)]k (θ) dθ

],

(13)

which can be rewritten as

λ (y − 1) + (1− λ)[E (v (θ))−

(K(θ∗∗j(p∗j))Qj(0, p∗j

)+(1−K

(θ∗∗j(p∗j)))

Qj(1, p∗j

))].

(14)

Expression (14) shows that bankruptcy risk reduces the borrower’s equity value. Which

tax rule affects equity most depends on the expected fraction of lenders that do not insure

in equilibrium under each regime. If the probability that lenders do not insure is high when

taxes apply to par, then equity is likely to increase following a change to a tax regime based on

market values. The reason is that the average tax burden faced by lenders is lower for market

values. This lead us to the following proposition:

14

Page 16: Debt Restructuring Costs and Bankruptcy Risk: …...Debt Restructuring Costs and Bankruptcy Risk: Evidence from CDS Spreads Abstract We examine the e ects of a recent change to the

Proposition 3 The following holds for the borrower’s ex-ante payoff under different tax rules:

1. Suppose the probability that v (θ) ≤ 1 is sufficiently high. If the equilibrium expected

fraction of lenders that do not insure when taxes apply to par values is large enough(1−K

(θ∗∗par

(p∗par

))≥ l∗

(p∗par

)), the borrower’s equilibrium payoff in t = 0 is higher if

taxes apply to market values vs par values.

2. Suppose the probability that v (θ) ≤ 1 is sufficiently low. If the equilibrium expected

fraction of lenders that do not insure when taxes apply to market values is small enough

(1−K (θ∗∗mkt (p∗mkt)) ≤ l∗ (p∗mkt)), the borrower’s payoff in t = 0 is higher if taxes apply to

par values vs market values.

3.2 Testable Hypotheses

One can derive several results based on our model. They are summarized in the following set

of hypotheses.

Hypothesis 1: The CDS spread associated with the debt of a distressed borrower is lower than

that of an non-distressed borrower when taxes apply to market values. The converse is true

when taxes apply to par values.

Hypothesis 2: The equity value of a distressed borrower is lower than that of an non-distressed

borrower when taxes apply to market values. The converse is true when taxes apply to par val-

ues.

Hypothesis 3: The cost of financing of a distressed borrower is lower than that of an non-

distressed borrower when taxes apply to market values. The converse is true when taxes apply

to par values.

These results motivate the empirical tests of the next section, where we use the adoption

of TD9599 as a surrogate for a change from a system in which debt restructing taxes are based

on par values to a system in which those taxes are based on market values.

4 Empirical Results

In this section, we present our main results establishing that TD9599 made renegotiation more

likely, and thereby increased firm value. We first describe our data. We then present our

empirical model and identification strategy. Next, we show empirical evidence confirming our

15

Page 17: Debt Restructuring Costs and Bankruptcy Risk: …...Debt Restructuring Costs and Bankruptcy Risk: Evidence from CDS Spreads Abstract We examine the e ects of a recent change to the

model’s predictions that the tax change led distressed firms’ CDS spreads to decrease, their

equity values to increase, and their financing costs to decline.

4.1 Data

The starting point for our sample is a set of firms for which the most CDS contracts are

written. We identify these firms by collecting data from the Depository Trust & Clearing

Corporation (DTCC) on the thousand firms with the most outstanding CDS contracts. The

DTCC has published this list of firms on a weekly basis since October 2008, along with gross

and net notional CDS positions on each firm.11 We restrict our analysis to these firms because

secondary trading of their CDS contracts is substantially more liquid than for smaller firms

(Oehmke and Zawadowski (2013)).

We merge the DTCC sample with several other databases. We collect CDS spreads for

standard, five-year CDS contracts from Thomson Reuters’s Datastream. Data on syndicated

loans are from LPC–Dealscan. These data include loan signing and maturity dates, principal,

pricing, and other terms such as covenants. We use Compustat for firm fundamental data and

CRSP for stock price data.

Our sample starts with 1,215 firms that appear in the DTCC database between October

2008 and March 2013 with CDS spreads available from Datastream. We exclude 445 firms that

are either foreign-based or state-owned, and 116 financial institutions. We drop 152 with no

information in LPC–Dealscan and 242 firms with missing Compustat data. We are left with

a sample of 260 unique firms.

4.2 Empirical Specification and Identification Strategy

Our model predicts that redefining the status of debt from private to public under the US tax

law could lead to a decline in CDS spreads. TD9599 works as a surrogate for such change. The

regulatory piece, however, only affected the tax status of syndicated loans. As such, its effects

should be larger for firms whose overall debt obligations contained more syndicated loans. This

observation allows us to build our baseline difference-in-differences specification for firm i in

11Gross notional is the sum of all CDS contracts written on the reference entity. Net notional positions arecalculated after canceling out offsetting positions, such as when a party buys CDS contracts on a particularfirm and then later sells contracts on the same firm.

16

Page 18: Debt Restructuring Costs and Bankruptcy Risk: …...Debt Restructuring Costs and Bankruptcy Risk: Evidence from CDS Spreads Abstract We examine the e ects of a recent change to the

week t:

CDSSpreadi,t = α + βHighSyndicatedi,t + µPostTDt

+ γ(HighSyndicatedi,t × PostTDt) + δXi,t + εi,t (15)

CDSSpreadi,t is the CDS spread on the firm’s debt. HighSyndicatedi,t is an indicator that

equals 1 if the firm’s syndicated loans-to-total debt ratio at the start of fiscal year 2012 is in

the highest tercile of the sample, and 0 if it is in the lowest tercile (we omit firms in the middle

tercile). The indicator PostTDt equals 1 for weeks after the announcement of TD9599, and 0

for weeks before, where we show results for alternative time windows.

Xi,t is a vector of control firm-level variables that affect the level of CDS spreads (see Tang

and Yan (2013)), as well as time-varying macroeconomic variables that could influence spread

changes. Firm-level controls include: Firm Leverage, measured as current liabilities and long-

term debt over total assets; Firm Volatility, the standard deviation of daily stock returns from

the past year; Tobin’s Q, the ratio between the market and the book value of the firm; Log

Assets ; Return on Assets, measured as net income before interest on debt over total assets;

Tangibility, measured as property, plant and equipment over total assets; Liquidity Needs, the

ratio of current to total debt; and Credit Rating, the S&P rating on the firm’s long-term debt.

Market-level controls include: Market Volatility, the weekly level of the VIX index; and Term

Slope, the weekly difference between the yield on a 10-year U.S. Treasury bond and 2-year

Treasury Note. Complete definitions for each variable are in the Data Appendix.

The primary coefficient of interest in Eq. ((15)) is γ. A negative γ indicates that CDS

spreads decline more for firms with high syndicated loans–debt ratios than firms with low

loans–debt ratios after TD9599 is announced. Also of interest is µ, which estimates the av-

erage change across all firms in CDS spreads after that same announcement. Unobservable

shocks could affect spread levels for several weeks, so we cluster standard errors at the firm

level to account for possible serial correlation.12

According to our analysis, the tax-induced changes in debt restructuring costs will be more

relevant for borrowers with weaker fundamentals — borrowers on the verge of going bankrupt,

triggering CDSs. We test this prediction empirically by adding yet another layer of contrasts

to Eq. (15), which is based on measures of financial distress. In doing so, we essentially pur-

sue a triple-difference estimation approach, but we do so under a more parsimonious model

12Our results do not change when we estimate our base tests on spreads averaged across the weeks beforeand after the announcement.

17

Page 19: Debt Restructuring Costs and Bankruptcy Risk: …...Debt Restructuring Costs and Bankruptcy Risk: Evidence from CDS Spreads Abstract We examine the e ects of a recent change to the

representation. To wit, we estimate Eq. ((15)) separately for distressed and non-distressed

firms, contrasting the interaction terms of interest, γ. In these estimations financial distress is

measured by both the Altman Z-Score and distance-to-default (based on the Merton (1974)).

Table 1 presents summary statistics for the variables used in our tests. Data on firm funda-

mentals are from the start of fiscal year 2012. Panel A separates the sample into distressed and

non-distressed firms, based on whether a firm’s 2012 Altman Z-Score is above or below 3. Un-

surprisingly, distressed firms have higher CDS spreads and leverage ratios. They also have lower

growth opportunities (as measured by Tobin’s Q) and a lower return on assets. Importantly

for our identification strategy, distressed and non-distressed firms have very similar summary

statistics for the syndicated loans–debt distribution. This suggests that these treatment as-

signment variables are largely orthogonal and unconfounded with each other. As such, whether

a firm has a high or low loans–debt ratio says nothing about whether or not it is in distress.

Table 1 About Here

Panel B compares firms with syndicated loans–debt ratios in the highest and lowest terciles

of the sample distribution (firms with HighSyndicated equal to 1 or 0). High- and low-loan

firms are similar along many key firm-level characteristics, including Z-Score, leverage, growth

opportunities, and recent performance. However, firms that use more syndicated loans are

smaller than firms using other types of debt. This is consistent with prior literature and

underscores the importance of controlling for firm size in our regressions.

In order for Type I error to affect our estimation, an omitted variable must cause CDS

spreads to drop exactly on TD9599’s announcement date. Further, in light of our triple-

difference approach, the omitted variable would bias our interpretation of the interaction co-

efficient γ only if it was correlated with firms’ financial conditions and syndicated loans–debt

ratios. This is a high bar for a plausible omitted variables case.

4.3 Changes in CDS Spreads

4.3.1 Graphical Evidence

We start out by testing whether CDS spreads generally respond to the announcement of

TD9599 by the IRS on September 12, 2012. Our model predicts that spreads should de-

cline for at least some firms in the market. Figure 3 shows that the sample average CDS

spreads dropped by 27 basis points when the IRS announced the new regulation. This is the

single largest drop for our sample firms since mid-2009.

18

Page 20: Debt Restructuring Costs and Bankruptcy Risk: …...Debt Restructuring Costs and Bankruptcy Risk: Evidence from CDS Spreads Abstract We examine the e ects of a recent change to the

Figure 3. Effect of TD9599 on Aggregate CDS Spreads

This figure compares the drop in CDS spreads after the Sept. 12, 2012 TD9599announcement to the average change in CDS spreads across other 2-week blockssince 2010. Spread changes are calculated for the entire sample of firms in theintersection of the LPC–Dealscan, CRSP, and DTCC databases.

Following our theoretical priors, we partition our sample firms according to their level

of financial distress (based on Z-scores) and their use of syndicated loans. Specifically, we

use a 2 × 2 partition where we classify firms into 4 buckets: Distressed–High Syndicated

Loans, Distressed–Low Syndicated Loans, Non-Distressed–High Syndicated Loans, and Non-

Distressed–Low Syndicated Loans. For each of these four groups, Figure 4 illustrates the

behavior of characteristic-adjusted spreads from 15 weeks prior through 10 weeks after the

IRS announcement. To be precise, for each group we regress weekly CDS spreads on Firm

Leverage, Log Assets, and week-fixed effects. We then plot the coefficients of the weekly effects,

with each group starting from a common base in week -15 to emphasize how spreads diverged

19

Page 21: Debt Restructuring Costs and Bankruptcy Risk: …...Debt Restructuring Costs and Bankruptcy Risk: Evidence from CDS Spreads Abstract We examine the e ects of a recent change to the

after that point.

Figure 4 shows that CDS spreads drop by 48 basis points at the announcement for Distressed–

High Syndicated Loans. Spreads drop by a much smaller 18 basis points for Distressed–Low

Syndicated Loans firms, 20 basis points for Non-Distressed–High Syndicated Loans firms, and

by just 13 basis points for Non-Distressed–Low Syndicated Loans firms. These are rough es-

timates of the impact of Regulation TD9599 on spreads of various sample firm partitions, but

the patterns depicted are striking.

4.3.2 Regression Results

In Table 2 we estimate regressions based on Eq. ((15)), separately for distressed and non-

distressed firms, where distress is measured by Z-Scores and firms are deemed as financially

distressed when Z-Score is less than 3. We use 7-week and 2-week windows around the IRS

announcement (alternative windows yield consistent results and are available upon request).

The main variable of interest is the interaction term HighSyndicated×PostTD. The negative

coefficient in columns (1) and (2) indicates that in the 7-week window spreads decreased about

30 basis points for those firms at the highest tercile of syndicated loans–debt ratio relative to

firms at the lowest tercile. These coefficients are statistically significant at the 1% test level.

In contrast, comparable coefficients for non-distressed firms are much smaller and statistically

indistinguishable from 0. Notably, the coefficient on PostTD is negative and highly significant

only for distressed firms. The results in the narrower 2-week window around the rule change

are similar (columns (5) through (8)). Finally, the coefficients on our control variables are

consistent with the findings of other work on CDS spreads. Firms with higher leverage and

firm-specific volatility have significantly higher spreads. Increases in the term slope, which

may indicate improving macroeconomic conditions, lead spreads to drop.

Table 3 repeats the analysis using distance-to-default to measure firm distress. In the

Merton (1974) model, a firm defaults when the value of its assets falls below the book value

of debt. Distance-to-default is the number of standard deviations by which the log of (asset

market value)/(debt book value) must fall in order for default to occur. In Table 3, distressed

firms are those with a below-median distance-to-default measure, and non-distressed firms are

those with an above-median measure.

Table 3 About Here

The results are largely similar to those in Table 2. Spreads decrease more for distressed than

20

Page 22: Debt Restructuring Costs and Bankruptcy Risk: …...Debt Restructuring Costs and Bankruptcy Risk: Evidence from CDS Spreads Abstract We examine the e ects of a recent change to the

Figure 4. CDS Spreads Sorted by Distress and Loans–Debt Ratio

This figure plots CDS spreads in the weeks surrounding the Sept. 12, 2012 TD9599announcement. All spreads are adjusted for leverage and firm size. Sample firmsare sorted into four buckets based on firm distress and syndicated loans–debt ratio.Distressed firms have 2012 Altman Z-Score < 3, and Non-distressed firms have Z-Score ≥ 3. HighSyndicated firms have a syndicated loans–debt ratio in the highesttercile of the sample distribution, and LowSyndicated firms have a loans–debt ratioin the lowest tercile. The loans–debt ratio is principal for all syndicated loansoutstanding in 2011 divided by total debt in 2011. The sample is all firms in theintersection of the LPC–Dealscan, CRSP, and DTCC databases.

for non-distressed firms, and the decrease is larger for high-loan–debt firms than low-loan–debt

firms. In the narrower 2-week window, spreads decrease by 24 basis points for distressed firms,

compared to just 6.7 basis points for non-distressed firms. Distressed/high-loan firms experi-

ence a further 19.6 basis point-drop in spreads relative to distressed/low-loan firms. As in Table

2, among non-distressed firms spreads do not change for high-loan–debt versus low-loan–debt

firms.

21

Page 23: Debt Restructuring Costs and Bankruptcy Risk: …...Debt Restructuring Costs and Bankruptcy Risk: Evidence from CDS Spreads Abstract We examine the e ects of a recent change to the

The results in both Table 2 and 3 support the predictions of our model, and indicate that

the change in tax status of syndicated loans increased out-of-court renegotiation likelihood.

Our theoretical model predicts that lenders’ tax burdens decrease when syndicated loans are

reclassified from private to public, and that this reduces the minimum offer that distressed

borrowers must pledge for renegotiation to succeed. The observed drop in CDS spreads on

TD9599’s announcement is consistent with lenders demanding less insurance after the tax

change. Notably, spreads decrease relatively more for distressed firms, as our model predicts.13

Because we obtain the same results using Z-Score and distance-to-default, throughout the

rest of the paper we report results for distress measured using just Z-Score. This conserves

space, yet results for distance-to-default are available from the authors upon request.

4.4 Stock Returns

Next, we examine how TD9599 affected the market value of borrower and lender firms. Hy-

pothesis 2 predicts that the tax change increases the equity value of borrowers with weak

fundamentals, relative to other borrowers. This should obtain because bankruptcy filings typ-

ically wipe out shareholders’ equity in the firm, while shareholders usually retain a stake in

the going concern after out-of-court renegotiation. We test this empirically by examining

borrowers’ stock returns surrounding TD9599’s announcement date.

Panel A of Table 4 presents borrower firms’ cumulative abnormal returns (CARs) from 1

day before to 2 days after the announcement, and also from a wider 3-day window around

the announcement. We keep only firms that have at least one syndicated loan outstanding at

the start of fiscal year 2012, sorting firms into four portfolios based on financial condition and

syndicated loans–debt ratio. Daily abnormal returns are calculated based on the Fama-French

three-factor model (Fama and French (1993)). CARs are the sum of returns over each event

window. We account for the fact that all firms share a common event date by using the Brown

and Warner (1980) portfolio method to calculate t-statistics.

Table 4 About Here

The table shows that only distressed/high-loan firms outperform the market around the

13We further observe a monotonic relationship between firm distress and the decrease in CDS spreads,which supports our model’s predication that the effect of the tax change is related to firm fundamentals.In unreported results, we re-estimate column (6) of Table 2 for highly-distressed firms (Z-Score below 1.23)versus “gray zone” firms (Z-Score between 1.23 and 3). The coefficient on HighSyndicated × PostTD issignificant in both subsamples, but it is twice as large for highly-distressed firms. The coefficient on PostTDalso monotonically decreases with firm distress.

22

Page 24: Debt Restructuring Costs and Bankruptcy Risk: …...Debt Restructuring Costs and Bankruptcy Risk: Evidence from CDS Spreads Abstract We examine the e ects of a recent change to the

regulation announcement. These firms earned a 1.16% abnormal return in the shorter window,

and a 1.57% abnormal return in the 3-day window. Both CARs are statistically significant.

Over the same period, distressed/low-loan firms underperformed the market by close to 1%,

and non-distressed firms did not outperform the market. These results suggest that TD9599

led to a significant increase in the market value of the borrower firms most affected by the

regulation. It is unlikely that an unobserved contemporaneous shock led to this value increase,

as the value of other distressed borrowers simultaneously decreased.

We also examine whether TD9599 created value for major syndicated lenders. Gains for

these lenders would stem from regulation-induced increases in their distressed-debt recoveries

and a drop in their tax obligations on renegotiated loans. In this analysis, we consider a port-

folio of 21 syndicated lenders that each were lead arrangers for at least 50 syndicated loans

outstanding in 2012. Together, these lenders arranged 95% of outstanding loan principal in

our sample. We find that a size-weighted portfolio of these lenders earned a 4.3% CAR in the

3-day window around the announcement of TD 9599 (t-stat of 2).

Our results indicate that taxing renegotiated debt based on market instead of par values

generates a substantial increase in value for lenders. Not only did TD9599 affect the CDS

market by decreasing bankruptcy likelihood, but it also benefitted shareholders of both lender

and borrower firms. Furthermore, this result shows that a completely different group of firms

also benefitted from the regulation in a way that is consistent with our model. An alternative

explanation for our results would need to account for the decrease in CDS spreads for borrowers

and the simultaneous increase in stock returns for lenders.

4.5 Financing Access and Costs

Our model predicts that borrowers’ financing costs decrease following a reduction in the tax

burden of renegotiating debt. This is because the increase in renegotiation likelihood leads to

higher payoffs from distressed borrowers to lenders, and in response lenders reduce the price

of new financing. In this section, we test this prediction empirically by examining whether

borrowers affected by the rule change subsequently gain access to cheaper funding.

We use a difference-in-differences specification that compares new financing terms for dis-

tressed vs. non-distressed borrowers, in a 12-month window before and after the TD9599

announcement. Our sample includes new syndicated loans issued to all U.S. non-financial

firms in the intersection of Compustat, LPC–Dealscan, and CRSP. We exclude syndicated

loans with issue-date principal below $100M, because TD9599 did not change the tax status

23

Page 25: Debt Restructuring Costs and Bankruptcy Risk: …...Debt Restructuring Costs and Bankruptcy Risk: Evidence from CDS Spreads Abstract We examine the e ects of a recent change to the

of these loans. We use a 12-month window because firms may not take new loans immediately

after the tax change, and also to account for seasonal patterns in loan issuance (see Murfin

and Peterson (2013)).

Table 5 contains our results. Columns (1) and (2) test whether distressed borrowers were

more likely to obtain a new loan after the TD9599 announcement. These columns present

results from logistic regressions with two observations per firm, one for the 12-month period

before and one for the 12-month period after the announcement (we omit September 2012 in

all tests). For each period, Obtained Loan equals 1 if the firm signed a syndicated loan, and 0

if it did not. This analysis is akin to a simple, characteristic-adjusted cross-tabulation of the

fraction of distressed and non-distressed borrowers that obtained a loan in each 12-month pe-

riod. The key explanatory variable is the interaction term Distressed× PostTD, which tests

whether distressed borrowers are more likely to obtain a new loan after the TD9599 announce-

ment than non-distressed borrowers. Column (1) compares distressed borrowers with Z-Score

< 3 to non-distressed borrowers with Z-Score ≥ 3, and column (2) compares highly-distressed

borrowers with Z-Score < 1.86 to non-distressed borrowers.14 Using different Z-Score cutoffs

allows us to examine whether financing terms improved for borrowers with different levels of

distress. The regressions also control for the same firm and macroeconomic characteristics as

in the previous section.

Table 5 About Here

The results show that distressed borrowers are more likely to obtain a new loan after

TD9599, relative to non-distressed borrowers. Coefficients in columns (1) and (2) represent

the marginal effects of each variable. The coefficient on Distressed× PostTD in column (1)

indicates that distressed borrowers are 11% more likely to obtain a new loan after TD9599.

Column (2) shows that the likelihood of obtaining a new loan is even greater for highly dis-

tressed borrowers, and statistically significant at the 1% level. The negative coefficient on

PostTD indicates an overall tightening in the loan market after late 2012.

Next, columns (3) and (4) show that markups on new syndicated loans decreased for dis-

tressed borrowers after TD9599. The table shows results from OLS regressions, with each

observation corresponding to a new loan in the 12-month window around the announcement.

The dependent variable New Loan Markup is the percentage-point all-in drawn spread. This

14Z-Score cutoffs of 1.86 and 3 are widely used in the literature to define firms as highly distressed, “grayzone”, or non-distressed (see e.g. Altman (2000)).

24

Page 26: Debt Restructuring Costs and Bankruptcy Risk: …...Debt Restructuring Costs and Bankruptcy Risk: Evidence from CDS Spreads Abstract We examine the e ects of a recent change to the

variable equals the spread that borrowers pay on top of a floating base rate, and thus directly

measures borrowers’ financing costs. PostTD equals 1 for loans signed after September 2012

and 0 for loans signed before. The regressions also control for market volatility and the term

slope of interest rates from the loan’s signing week.

The results show that markups decreased by 26 to 30 basis points for distressed firms after

TD9599, relative to non-distressed firms. This drop represents a 14% decrease over the mean

pre-announcement markup of 2.2%. These estimates are statistically significant at the 5%

level, with p-value below .02 in column (3). The decrease is similar for all distressed firms and

highly distressed firms.

One potential concern is that the decrease in markups could be due to more high-quality

borrowers obtained loans after TD9599, instead of decreases in out-of-court renegotiation

costs. Our results indicate that instead loans were increasingly issued to riskier borrowers

after TD9599, making the observed decrease in markups even more striking. Furthermore, we

re-estimate columns (3) and (4) using a sample of borrowers that obtained loans both before

and after TD9599. In unreported results, we find that loan markups decrease for the same

distressed borrower after the tax change.

The evidence presented in this section supports Hypothesis 3 of our model. An increase in

renegotiation likelihood allows more distressed firms to enter the syndicated loan market, and

to borrow at lower cost. These results are consistent with our model’s prediction that higher

renegotiation likelihood increases lenders’ payoffs, allowing them to increase their up-front

lending commitments to distressed borrowers.

5 Robustness Checks

We conclude our analysis by testing whether unobserved heterogeneity across firms, and not

reduced out-of-court renegotiation costs, could explain the decrease in CDS spreads around

TD9599’s announcement. One potential concern with our specification in tables 2 and 3 is

that the parallel trends assumption may not hold: prior to TD9599 spreads may have been

decreasing relatively more for distressed/high-loan firms, due to macroeconomic or other ef-

fects unrelated to debt restructuring costs. It is also possible that distressed/high-loan firms

have more volatile CDS spreads in general, so that any positive shock coinciding with TD9599

could produce larger declines in the spreads of these firms. It is therefore important to rule

out the possibility that structural differences alone could lead to the results we observe.

25

Page 27: Debt Restructuring Costs and Bankruptcy Risk: …...Debt Restructuring Costs and Bankruptcy Risk: Evidence from CDS Spreads Abstract We examine the e ects of a recent change to the

Figure 5. CDS Spread Changes, TD9599 Announcement vs.Placebo Events

This figure compares the decrease in CDS spreads around the Sept. 12, 2012TD9599 announcement to the change in spreads around a series of placebo events.Placebo estimates are constructed by splitting the sample into non-contiguous 4-week blocks ranging from January 2010 to December 2012. Each placebo eventestimates the regression from Column 6 of Table 2, with PostTD redefined to equal1 on the third and fourth week of each block. Bars are the coefficients on HighSyn-dicated x PostTD for each block, and are sorted from largest to smallest coefficient.The sample comprises all distressed firms (2012 Altman Z-Score < 3) in the inter-section of the LPC–Dealscan, CRSP, and DTCC databases.

We do so by conducting a placebo analysis. We split the period from January 2010 to

December 2012 into non-contiguous 4-week blocks. In each block we repeat the regression

from Table 2 Column 6, however we re-define PostTD to equal 1 in the third and fourth week

of each block. We focus our test on just distressed firms. Figure 5 plots the distribution of

the resulting coefficients on the interaction term HighSyndicated×PostTD from each block,

26

Page 28: Debt Restructuring Costs and Bankruptcy Risk: …...Debt Restructuring Costs and Bankruptcy Risk: Evidence from CDS Spreads Abstract We examine the e ects of a recent change to the

sorted from largest to smallest coefficient. We find that the change in CDS spreads around

TD9599’s announcement is the second-largest decrease out of all 50 blocks. Furthermore, in

only 6 of the blocks is the interaction term coefficient negative and statistically significant at

conventional levels.

These results indicate that the set of firms most affected by TD9599 experienced an un-

precedentedly large decrease in CDS spreads right when the regulation was announced. This

provides further support that bankruptcy risk decreased for these firms due to the reduction

in taxes owed upon out-of-court renegotiation. Any alternative explanation must include an

unobserved variable that coincides with TD9599 and produces an abnormally large decrease

in bankruptcy risk for distressed/high-loan firms.

6 Conclusion

Firms experiencing distress usually attempt to renegotiate debt out of court (Gertner and

Scharfstein (1991) and Franks and Touros (1994)). These negotiations are thought to be value-

enhancing as mutually-agreed resolutions should preserve more value than costly restructuring

in bankruptcy under court supervision. Out-of-court debt modifications contemplated by dis-

tressed firms are significantly large and they must compensate creditors for both their outside

options and taxes associated with the exchange.

In this paper, we model and test the effect of changes in debt restructuring costs on

bankruptcy risk, financing costs, and shareholder value of borrowers and lenders. We do so

examining a change in the US tax code that reduces the taxes lenders pay when restructuring

syndicated loans out of court, but does not affect other types of debt (Regulation TD9599).

This modification allows us to disentangle the relative costs of in-court and out-of-court re-

structuring. Using data from CDS contracts, we show that renegotiation becomes more likely

following a relative decrease in out-of-court costs, and this in turn increases the market value

of both firms and banks. We further show that the capital markets respond by granting firms

access to cheaper bank credit and by increasing up-front commitments to long-term funding.

Our paper presents well-identified evidence that taxes are a major transaction cost in debt

renegotiation of distressed firms. In all, the analysis provides insights into how altering regu-

latory constraints can improve welfare in financial distress.

27

Page 29: Debt Restructuring Costs and Bankruptcy Risk: …...Debt Restructuring Costs and Bankruptcy Risk: Evidence from CDS Spreads Abstract We examine the e ects of a recent change to the

Appendix A

We first explain some technical details regarding the procedure we follow to solve our propo-

sitions, and then present proofs.

Lender i’s net payoff of not insuring over insuring is

Πi =

π − π, if P j (θ) ≤ lπ − π, if P j (θ) > l

. (A.1)

The net payoff Πi is increasing in the fraction of lenders that do not insure (strategic com-

plementarity) and in the fundamental θ (state monotonicity), which determines the value of

the borrower’s assets out of court. Specifically, if π > π and π < π, lenders face an enormous

coordination problem as their decision to insure or not crucially depends on their beliefs about

both the fundamental θ and the fraction l of lenders that do not insure.

Suppose lenders follow a monotone strategy with a cutoff k, that is, they do not insure

if their signal is above k and insure otherwise. Lender i’s expectation about the fraction of

lenders that do not insure conditional on θ is simply the probability that any lender observes

a signal above k, that is, 1−H(k−θσ

). This proportion is less than z if θ ≤ k − σH−1 (1− z).

Each lender i calculates this probability using the estimated distribution of θ conditional on

his signal xi. A well known result in the literature of global games is that as σ → 0 this

probability equals z for xi = k. That is, the threshold type believes that the proportion of

lenders that do not insure follows the uniform distribution on the unit interval.

By focusing on the situation when signals become nearly precise, we focus on strategic

uncertainty rather than on fundamental uncertainty. The equilibrium cutoff can then be com-

puted by using the fact that the threshold type must be indifferent between insuring and not

insuring given his beliefs about l. Let θ∗j be the cutoff under tax regime j .Then θ∗j is such that∫ P j(θ∗j )

0

(π − π) dl +

∫ 1

P j(θ∗j )(π − π) dl = 0, (A.2)

which yields the condition

P j(θ∗j)

= (π − π) [(1− λ) `]−1 . (A.3)

The threshold in (A.3) exists and is unique for π > π and π < π. However, these payoff

depend on the CDS fee f , which is endogenous. Our strategy is to assume these conditions

hold and solve for the equilibrium demand for CDS taking f as given. Then we show in the

full characterization of the equilibrium with endogenous CDS fees that there is a unique cutoff

satisfying (A.2). These results for a fixed CDS fee f are formalized in Lemma 1 below.

Lemma 1 Suppose there exists ε such that π−π > ε > 0 > −ε ≥ π−π. In the limit σ → 0,

the unique equilibrium of the game starting in t = 1 for a given f is in monotone strategies

with cutoff θ∗j and has all lenders not insuring if θ > θ∗j and insuring if θ < θ∗j , where

θ∗j = P j−1 ((π − π) [(1− λ) `]−1) (A.4)

28

Page 30: Debt Restructuring Costs and Bankruptcy Risk: …...Debt Restructuring Costs and Bankruptcy Risk: Evidence from CDS Spreads Abstract We examine the e ects of a recent change to the

Proof of Lemma 1. Morris and Shin (2003) prove this result for a general class of global

games that satisfies the following conditions: (i) Πi increasing in θ, (ii) Πi increasing in l, (iii)

there exists a unique θ∗ that satisfies∫ 1

0Πidl = 0, (iv) there exists θ, θ, and ε > 0 such that

Πi ≤ −ε for all l ∈ [0, 1] and θ ≤ θ and Πi > ε for all l ∈ [0, 1] and θ ≥ θ, (v) continuity of∫ 1

0g (l) Πidl with respect signal xi and density g, and (vi) the expected value of ηi is finite. The

assumption π − π > ε > 0 > −ε ≥ π − π stated in the proposition implies (i), (ii), (iii), (iv).

Condition (v) is clearly satisfied. Condition (vi) is assumed in the description of the model.

The results above characterized lenders’ demand for insurance for a given CDS fee f . In

order to find the equilibrium demand for CDS we need to determine its supply. CDS providers

are competitive and the fee they charge is such that the break even in expectation. This

requirement implies that

fj = (1− λ)K(θ∗j)

. (A.5)

Therefore, the CDS fee fj charged by CDS providers is increasing in “quantity demanded”

K (θ∗), that is, the probability of a credit event conditional on distress. The equilibrium CDS

fee is the one that simultaneously satisfies supply and demand. Plugging (A.5) into (A.2) gives

the following condition for the equilibrium cutoff θ∗∗j :∫ P j(θ∗∗j )

0

(1− λ)[K(θ∗∗j)− (1− r)− `

]dl +

∫ 1

P j(θ∗∗j )(1− λ)

[K(θ∗∗j)− (1− r)

]dl = 0.

(A.6)

This equation simplifies to

K(θ∗∗j)− (1− r)− P j

(θ∗∗j)` = 0. (A.7)

This leads to the proof of Proposition 1.

Proof of Proposition 1. With endogenous f (θ) we no longer need the assumption

π−π > ε > 0 > −ε ≥ π−π made in Lemma 1. Now, Πi clearly satisfies (i), (ii), (iv), and (v).

Condition (vi) is assumed in the model. Therefore, it suffices to show (iii). We show that this

condition holds for ` and r sufficiently large.

First, let us derive some properties of the aggregate offer Qj (0). We have that Qmkt (0) ≥Qpar (0) ≥ 1 if all lenders buy CDS and Qmkt (1) ≤ Qpar (1) if no lender insures. Thus, there

exists l∗ such that Qmkt (l∗) = Qpar (l∗) = 1. Because the aggregate offer when taxes apply to

market values is more sensitive to the fraction of lenders that do not insure, Qmkt ≥ Qpar for

l ≤ l∗ and Qmkt ≤ Qpar for l ≥ l∗.

As θ → v−1 (Qj (1)), P j (θ)→ 1 and the left-hand side of (A.7) becomes Ωj ≡ K (v−1 (Qj (1)))−(1− r)− `, which is negative for ` sufficiently large. If θ → v−1 (Qj (0)), P j (θ)→ 0, and it ap-

29

Page 31: Debt Restructuring Costs and Bankruptcy Risk: …...Debt Restructuring Costs and Bankruptcy Risk: Evidence from CDS Spreads Abstract We examine the e ects of a recent change to the

proaches Ωj ≡ K (v−1 (Qj (0)))− (1− r), which is positive for r large enough. This establishes

(iii).

Finally, we show the comparative statics relative to the cutoffs θ∗∗mkt and θ∗∗par. For θ →v−1 (Qj (l∗)), the left-hand side of (A.7) converges to Ω ≡ K (v−1 (1))− (1− r)− l∗`.

If Ω ≥ 0, then the unique θ∗∗j that satisfies (A.7) is such that v−1 (Qj (1)) ≤ θ∗∗j ≤ v−1 (1).

Since Qpar (1) ≥ Qmkt (1), if v (θ∗∗mkt) < Qpar (1) it directly follows that θ∗∗mkt < θ∗∗par. If v (θ∗∗mkt) ≥Qpar (1), then for all θ such that v−1 (Qpar (1)) ≤ θ ≤ v−1 (1) we have that P par (θ) ≥ Pmkt (θ).

Along with (A.7), this implies that θ∗∗mkt ≤ θ∗∗par.

If Ω < 0, then the unique θ∗∗j that satisfies (A.7) is such that v−1 (1) < θ∗∗j ≤ v−1 (Qj (0)).

Since Qmkt (0) ≥ Qpar (0), if v (θ∗∗mkt) > Qpar (0) it directly follows that θ∗∗mkt > θ∗∗par. If v (θ∗∗mkt) ≤Qpar (0), then for all θ such that v−1 (1) < θ ≤ v−1 (Qpar (0)) we have that P par (θ) ≤ Pmkt (θ).

Along with (A.7), this implies that θ∗∗mkt ≥ θ∗∗par.

Proof of Proposition 2. This follows straight from Proposition 1 and from the expression

for the price of debt provided in (10).

Proof of Proposition 3. Remember that the aggregate offer Qj (l, p) is a weighted

average of the extreme offers when no lender insures and when all lenders insure. That is,

Qj (l, p) = (1− l)Qj (0, p) + lQj (1, p). Therefore, the negative term in brackets in (14) can be

written as

Qj(1−K

(θ∗∗j(p∗j)), p∗j)

=(K(θ∗∗j(p∗j))Qj(0, p∗j

)+(1−K

(θ∗∗j(p∗j)))

Qj(1, p∗j

)).

We also have that

Qpar(1−K

(θ∗∗par

(p∗par

)), p)≥ Qmkt

(K(θ∗∗par

(p∗par

)), p)

if 1−K(θ∗∗par

(p∗par

))≥ l∗ (p) and

Qpar(1−K

(θ∗∗par

(p∗par

)), p)≤ Qmkt

(K(θ∗∗par

(p∗par

)), p)

if 1−K(θ∗∗par

(p∗par

))≤ l∗ (p).

Therefore, if K (v−1 (1)) is sufficiently high and 1−K(θ∗∗par

(p∗par

))≥ l∗

(p∗par

),

Qpar(1−K

(θ∗∗par

(p∗par

)), p∗par

)≥ Qmkt

(1−K

(θ∗∗par

(p∗par

)), p∗par

)≥ Qmkt (1−K (θ∗∗mkt (p∗mkt)) , p

∗mkt) ,

where the last inequality follows from Proposition 2.

If K (v−1 (1)) is sufficiently low and 1−K (θ∗∗mkt (p∗mkt)) ≤ l∗ (p∗mkt), then

Qmkt (1−K (θ∗∗mkt (p∗mkt)) , p∗mkt) ≥ Qpar (1−K (θ∗∗mkt (p∗mkt)) , p

∗mkt)

≥ Qpar(1−K

(θ∗∗par

(p∗par

)), p∗par

),

where the last inequality follows from Proposition 2.

30

Page 32: Debt Restructuring Costs and Bankruptcy Risk: …...Debt Restructuring Costs and Bankruptcy Risk: Evidence from CDS Spreads Abstract We examine the e ects of a recent change to the

References

[1] Altman, E., 1968, “Financial Ratios, Discriminant Analysis and the Prediction of Corpo-rate Bankruptcy,” Journal of Finance 23, 589–609.

[2] Altman, E., 2000, “Predicting Financial Distress of Companies: Revisiting the Z-Scoreand ZETA Models,” NYU Working Paper.

[3] Ashcraft, A.B. and J. Santos, 2009, “Has the CDS Market Lowered the Cost of CorporateDebt?,” Journal of Monetary Economics 56, 514-523.

[4] Asquith, P., Gertner, R. and D. Scharfstein, 1994, “Anatomy of Financial Distress: AnExamination of Junk-Bond Issuers,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 109, 625-658.

[5] Benmelech, E., Garmaise, M.J., and T. Moskowitz, 2005, “Do Liquidation Values AffectFinancial Contracts? Evidence from Commercial Loan Contracts and Zoning Regulation,”Quarterly Journal of Economics 120, 1121–1154.

[6] Benmelech, E. and N. Bergman, 2008, “Liquidation Values and the Credibility of FinancialContract Renegotiation: Evidence from U.S. Airlines,” Quarterly Journal of Economics123, 1635–1677.

[7] Blanco, R., Brennan, S. and I.W. Marsh, 2005, “An Empirical Analysis of the DynamicRelation between Investment-Grade Bonds and Credit Default Swaps,” Journal of Finance60, 2255–2281.

[8] Bolton, P. and M. Oehmke, 2011, “Credit Default Swaps and the Empty Creditor Prob-lem,” Review of Financial Studies 24, 2617–2655.

[9] Bolton, P. and D. Scharfstein, 1996, “Optimal Debt Structure and the Number of Credi-tors,” Journal of Political Economy 104, 1–25.

[10] Campello, M., and R. Matta, 2012, “Credit default swaps and risk-shifting,”EconomicsLetters 117, 639–641.

[11] Campello, M., and R. Matta, 2013, “Credit Default Swaps, Firm Financing and theEconomy,” Working Paper, Cornell University and University of Amsterdam.

[12] Carhart, M.M., 1997, “On Persistence in Mutual Fund Performance,” Journal of Finance52, 57–82.

[13] Carlsson, H., and E. van Damme, 1993, “Global Games and Equilibrium Selection,”Econometrica 61, 989–1018.

[14] Diamond, D., 2004, “Committing to Commit: Short-Term Debt When Enforcement isCostly,” Journal of Finance 59, 1447–1479.

[15] Duffee, G. R., and C. Zhou, 2001, “Credit Derivatives in Banking: Useful Tools forManaging Risk?,” Journal of Monetary Economics 48, 25–54.

[16] Fama, E. and K. French, 1993, “Common risk factors in the returns on stocks and bonds,”Journal of Financial Economics 33, 3–56.

[17] Franks, J. and W. Torous, 1994, “A comparison of financial recontracting in distressedexchanges and Chapter 11 reorganizations,” Journal of Financial Economics 35, 349–370.

31

Page 33: Debt Restructuring Costs and Bankruptcy Risk: …...Debt Restructuring Costs and Bankruptcy Risk: Evidence from CDS Spreads Abstract We examine the e ects of a recent change to the

[18] Gertner, R. and D. Scharfstein, 1991, “A Theory of Workouts and the Effects of Reorga-nization Law,” Journal of Finance 46, 1189–1222.

[19] Giambona, E., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., and R. Matta, 2013, “Improved Creditor Protectionand Verifiability in the U.S.,” University of Amsterdam Working Paper.

[20] Gilson, S., John, K. and L.H.P. Lang, 1990, “Troubled debt restructurings: An empiricalstudy of private reorganization of firms in default,” Journal of Financial Economics 27,315–353.

[21] Gilson, S., 1997, “Transaction Costs and Capital Structure Choice: Evidence from Finan-cially Distressed Firms,” Journal of Finance 52, 161–196.

[22] Hirtle, B., 2009, “Credit Derivatives and Bank Credit Supply,” Journal of Financial In-termediation 18, 125–150.

[23] Kolari, J.W. and S. Pynnonen, 2010, “Event Study Testing with Cross-sectional Correla-tion of Abnormal Returns,” Review of Financial Studies 23, 3996–4025.

[24] Longstaff, F., Mithal, S. and E. Neis, 2005, “Corporate Yield Spreads: Default Risk orLiquidity? New Evidence from the Credit Default Swap Market,” Journal of Finance 60,2213–2253.

[25] Merton, R. C., 1974, “On the pricing of corporate debt: The risk structure of interestrates,” Journal of Finance 29, 449–470.

[26] Morellec, E., 2013, “Financing investment: the choice between bonds and bank loans,”Swiss Finance Istitute Working Paper.

[27] Morris, S., and H. Shin, 2003, “Global Games: Theory and Applications,” in Dewatripont,M., Hansen, M., Turnovsky, S. (Eds), Advances in Economics and Econometrics (Proceed-ings of the Eighth World Congress of the Econometric Society), Cambridge UniversityPress.

[28] Murfin, J., and M. Peterson, 2013, “Loans on sale: Credit market seasonality, borrowerneed, and lender rent seeking,” Yale University and Northwestern University WorkingPaper.

[29] Oehmke, M. and A. Zawadowski, 2013, “The Anatomy of the CDS Market,” ColumbiaUniversity Working Paper.

[30] Parlour, C. A., and G. Plantin, 2008, “Loan Sales and Relationship Banking,” Journal ofFinance 63, 1291–1314.

[31] Parlour, C., and A. Winton, 2008, “Laying off Credit Risk: Loan Sales versus CreditDefault Swaps,” Working Paper, University of California at Berkeley.

[32] Roberts, M.R. and A. Sufi, 2009, “Renegotiation of financial contracts: Evidence fromprivate credit agreements,” Journal of Financial Economics 93, 159–184.

[33] Saretto, A. and H. Tookes, 2013, “Corporate Leverage, Debt Maturity and Credit Supply:The Role of Credit Default Swaps,” Review of Financial Studies 26, 1190–1247.

[34] Subrahmanyam, M., Tang, D. Y., and S.Q. Wang, 2014, “Does the Tail Wag the Dog? TheEffect of Credit Default Swaps on Credit Risk,” Review of Financial Studies, Forthcoming.

32

Page 34: Debt Restructuring Costs and Bankruptcy Risk: …...Debt Restructuring Costs and Bankruptcy Risk: Evidence from CDS Spreads Abstract We examine the e ects of a recent change to the

[35] Tang, D.Y. and H. Yan, 2013, “What Moves CDS Spreads,” University of Hong KongWorking Paper.

[36] Thompson, J.R., 2010, “Counterparty Risk in Financial Contracts: Should the InsuredWorry About the Insurer?,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 90 , 1195–1252.

[37] Vassalou, M. and Y. Xing, 2004, “Default Risk in Equity Returns,” Journal of Finance59, 831–868.

33

Page 35: Debt Restructuring Costs and Bankruptcy Risk: …...Debt Restructuring Costs and Bankruptcy Risk: Evidence from CDS Spreads Abstract We examine the e ects of a recent change to the

Data Appendix: Variable Definitions and Sources

This appendix contains definitions of the variables used in this paper. Programs to derive the dataset are available on request.

Variable Name Definition Data Source

1. Dependent Variables

CDS Spread The weekly spread on a firm’s five-year CDS contracts. This vari-able is winsorized at the 1-99 level.

Thomson ReutersDatastream

Obtained Loan An indicator equal to 1 if a firm obtained a new syndicated loanin the corresponding 12-month period.

LPC–Dealscan

New Loan Markup The markup on new syndicated loan issues, measured in percent-age points. This variable is LPC data item ALLINDRAWN.

LPC–Dealscan

2. Key Independent Variables

HighSyndicated Equals 1 if a firm’s syndicated loans–debt ratio at the start of fis-cal year 2012 is in the highest tercile of the sample distribution,and 0 if the loans–debt ratio is in the lowest tercile. This variableis set to missing for firms with syndicated loans–debt ratio in themiddle tercile. The syndicated loans–debt ratio is the issue-dateprincipal of all syndicated loans oustanding at the start of fiscalyear 2012 divided by total debt in 2012. Issue-date principal isLPC data item FACILITYAMT summed over all observations foreach individual loan. Total debt is measured as total liabilities(Compustat data item LT ). A loan is outstanding if its issue dateis before the end of fiscal year 2011, and its maturity date is afterthe end of fiscal year 2011. Our sample excludes loans that aresyndicated outside the United States or that are rumored, sus-pended, or cancelled. The loans/debt ratio is bounded from aboveby 1.

LPC–Dealscan,Compustat

LowSyndicated Equals 1 if a firm’s syndicated loans–debt ratio at the start of fiscalyear 2012 is in the lowest tercile of the sample distribution, and0 if the syndicated loans–debt ratio is in the lowest tercile. Thisvariable is set to missing for firms with syndicated loans–debt ratioin the middle tercile. The syndicated loans–debt ratio is measuredin the same way as for HighSyndicated.

LPC–Dealscan,Compustat

PostTD Equals 1 for weekly observations after September 12, 2012, and 0otherwise.

Distressed Equals 1 if the firm’s 2012 Altman Z-Score < 3, and 0 otherwise. Compustat

Altman Z-Score This variable equals 1.2*(Current Assets - Current Liabili-ties)/Total Assets + 1.4*Retained Earnings/Total Assets +3.3*EBIT/Total Assets + 0.6*Market Capitalization/Total Lia-bilities + Total Sales/Total Assets. Current Assets is Compustatdata item ACT, Current Liabilities is LCT, Total Assets is AT,Retained Earnings is RE, EBIT is data item EBIT, Total Lia-bilities is LT, and Total Sales is SALE. Market Capitalization isdefined as for Market Leverage. All Z-Score component variablesare measured in the most recent quarter ending before September2012, and are winsorized at the 1-99 level. The Z-Score is set tomissing if any of the component variables is missing.

Compustat

Page 36: Debt Restructuring Costs and Bankruptcy Risk: …...Debt Restructuring Costs and Bankruptcy Risk: Evidence from CDS Spreads Abstract We examine the e ects of a recent change to the

3. Control Variables

Firm Leverage The sum of debt in current liabilities (Compustat data item DLC ),long-term debt (DLTT ), and preferred stock (PSTK ), dividedby this number plus market capitalization. We measure mar-ket capitalization by matching monthly stock data from CRSPto Compustat fiscal-year-end datadate. Market capitalization isthe firm’s month-end stock price (CRSP data item PRC ) multi-plied by month-end shares outstanding (SHROUT ), and expressedin millions of dollars. This variable is measured at the end of thefirm’s fiscal year, and is winsorized at the 1-99 level.

Compustat, CRSP

Firm Volatility The annualized standard deviation of daily stock returns from theprevious fiscal year. This variable is missing for firms with fewerthan 50 trading days, and is winsorized at the 1-99 level.

CRSP

Market Volatility The weekly closing value of the VIX index. Yahoo! Finance

Tobin’s Q Market capitalization plus total assets minus book value of equity,all divided by total assets. Market capitalization is defined in thesame way as for the variable Market Leverage. Total assets isCompustat data item AT, and book value of equity is Compustatdata item SEQ. This variable is measured at the end of the firm’sfiscal year, and is winsorized at the 1-99 level.

Compustat, CRSP

Log Assets The natural logarithm of 1 plus the firm’s total assets (Compustatdata item AT ). This variable is measured at the end of the firm’sfiscal year, and is winsorized at the 1-99 level.

Compustat

Return on Assets The ratio of net income before interest expenses to total assets.Net income before interest expenses is the sum of Compustat dataitems NI and XINT. Total assets is data item AT. This variableis measured at the end of the firm’s fiscal year, and is winsorizedat the 1-99 level.

Compustat

Tangibility The ratio of plant, property and equipment (Compustat data itemPPENT ) to total assets (AT ). This variable is measured at theend of the firm’s fiscal year, and is winsorized at the 1-99 level.

Compustat

Liquidity Needs The ratio of debt in current liabilities (Compustat data item DLC)to this number plus long-term debt (DLTT). This variable is mea-sured at the end of the firm’s fiscal year, and is winsorized at the1-99 level.

Compustat

Term Slope The weekly difference between the yield on a 10-year U.S. Treasurybond and a 2-year U.S. Treasury Note.

U.S. TreasuryDept.

Credit Rating A numeric index of Standard & Poor’s credit rating for the firm’slong-term debt (Compustat data item SPLTICRM ). The indexranges from 1 for a “AAA” rating to 21 for a “D” or “SD” rating.

Compustat

Page 37: Debt Restructuring Costs and Bankruptcy Risk: …...Debt Restructuring Costs and Bankruptcy Risk: Evidence from CDS Spreads Abstract We examine the e ects of a recent change to the

Tab

le1.

Su

mm

ary

Sta

tist

ics

Pan

elA

.Sum

mar

ySta

tist

ics

by

Fir

mF

inan

cial

Con

dit

ions

Dis

tres

sed

Fir

ms

Non

-dis

tres

sed

Fir

ms

Dis

tres

sed

–t-

stat

NM

ean

St.

Dev

.25

thP

erc.

Med

ian

75th

Per

c.N

Mea

nSt.

Dev

.25

thP

erc.

Med

ian

75th

Per

c.N

on-d

istr

esse

d

Avg

.C

DS

Spr

ead

160

217.

6924

0.21

77.8

313

5.97

249.

6047

105.

8689

.51

56.3

467

.82

114.

0011

1.84

3.12

***

Syn

dica

ted

loan

s–de

bt18

00.

300.

280.

110.

210.

3847

0.31

0.22

0.15

0.22

0.47

0.00

0.05

Z-S

core

180

1.46

0.74

0.98

1.45

1.91

474.

081.

013.

343.

744.

63-2

.61

-19.

85**

*F

irm

Lev

erag

e17

00.

390.

190.

230.

360.

5047

0.17

0.10

0.11

0.15

0.20

0.21

7.25

***

Fir

mV

olat

ilit

y17

036

.42

16.5

925

.46

34.2

744

.23

4730

.45

10.9

123

.93

28.5

736

.71

5.97

2.33

**T

obin

’sQ

170

1.32

0.41

1.08

1.23

1.51

472.

070.

891.

371.

972.

46-0

.75

-8.3

4***

Ass

ets

180

35,6

3546

,763

8,25

519

,678

40,3

0047

20,7

9916

,899

7,42

114

,983

31,6

1814

,836

2.14

**R

etu

rnon

Ass

ets

180

0.06

0.05

0.04

0.06

0.09

470.

110.

060.

080.

110.

14-0

.04

-5.5

8***

Tan

gibi

lity

180

0.40

0.25

0.17

0.39

0.62

470.

310.

210.

140.

250.

480.

092.

24**

Liq

uid

ity

Nee

ds17

90.

100.

110.

010.

060.

1447

0.12

0.11

0.02

0.10

0.16

-0.0

2-1

.01

Cre

dit

Rat

ing

178

9.56

3.17

89

1247

7.21

2.37

66

92.

35-4

.74*

**

Pan

elB

.Sum

mar

ySta

tist

ics

by

Syndic

ated

Loa

ns–

Deb

tR

atio

Hig

hSyn

dica

ted

Low

Syn

dica

ted

Hig

hSyn

dica

ted

–t-

stat

NM

ean

St.

Dev

.25

thP

erc.

Med

ian

75th

Per

c.N

Mea

nSt.

Dev

.25

thP

erc.

Med

ian

75th

Per

c.L

owS

yndi

cate

d

Avg

.C

DS

Spr

ead

7627

3.97

280.

6510

6.70

169.

5739

7.28

7015

3.57

204.

0559

.53

88.7

114

9.37

120.

402.

94**

*S

yndi

cate

dlo

ans–

debt

840.

600.

240.

400.

530.

7879

0.07

0.05

0.00

0.08

0.11

0.53

19.5

4***

Z-S

core

782.

061.

361.

161.

782.

9873

1.74

1.19

0.94

1.42

2.35

0.32

1.56

Fir

mL

ever

age

790.

380.

220.

220.

340.

5674

0.36

0.23

0.17

0.32

0.47

0.03

0.70

Fir

mV

olat

ilit

y79

41.8

420

.09

30.2

538

.87

49.2

274

32.1

711

.72

24.2

030

.22

38.4

19.

673.

61**

*T

obin

’sQ

791.

440.

611.

071.

221.

6074

1.36

0.50

1.08

1.29

1.51

0.08

0.85

Ass

ets

8412

,245

10,6

495,

128

8,56

116

,589

7949

,199

55,3

5714

,382

32,9

9355

,099

-36,

954

-6**

*R

etu

rnon

Ass

ets

840.

060.

060.

040.

070.

0979

0.07

0.04

0.05

0.07

0.09

-0.0

1-0

.61

Tan

gibi

lity

830.

370.

250.

180.

330.

5979

0.39

0.28

0.12

0.38

0.65

-0.0

2-0

.49

Liq

uid

ity

Nee

ds84

0.08

0.11

0.01

0.05

0.13

780.

100.

120.

020.

060.

13-0

.02

-1.1

9C

redi

tR

atin

g83

10.6

73.

329

1014

788.

362.

987

810

2.32

-4.6

5***

Th

ista

ble

pre

sents

sum

mary

stati

stic

sfr

om

fisc

al

yea

r2012

for

ou

rsa

mp

le,

wh

ich

conta

ins

257

non

-fin

an

cial

firm

sin

the

inte

rsec

tion

of

the

Com

pu

stat,

LP

C–D

eals

can

,an

dD

TC

Cd

ata

base

s.O

bse

rvati

on

sin

this

tab

leare

at

the

firm

level

.In

Pan

elA

,“D

istr

esse

dF

irm

s”are

those

wit

h2012

Alt

man

Z-S

core<

3,

an

d“N

on

-dis

tres

sed

Fir

ms”

are

those

wit

hZ

-Sco

re≥

3.

InP

an

elB

,HighSyndicated

isfi

rms

wit

hsy

nd

icate

dlo

an

s–d

ebt

rati

oin

the

hig

hes

tte

rcile,

an

dLowSyndicated

isfi

rms

wit

hlo

an

s–d

ebt

rati

oin

the

low

est

terc

ile.

Avg.CDS

Spread

isth

efi

rm’s

wee

kly

CD

Ssp

read

,aver

aged

over

2011

an

d2012.Syndicatedloans–debt

isth

eis

sue-

date

pri

nci

pal

of

all

syn

dic

ate

dlo

an

son

afi

rm’s

books

at

the

start

of

fisc

al

yea

r2012,

div

ided

by

tota

ld

ebt

in2012.

Firm

Leverage

isth

esu

mof

deb

tin

curr

ent

liab

ilit

ies,

lon

g-t

erm

deb

t,and

pre

ferr

edst

ock

,d

ivid

edby

this

nu

mb

erp

lus

mark

etca

pit

aliza

tion

.Firm

Volatility

isth

eannu

alize

dst

an

dard

dev

iati

on

of

daily

stock

retu

rns

from

the

pre

vio

us

fisc

al

yea

r.Tobin’sQ

ism

ark

etca

pit

aliza

tion

plu

sb

ook

valu

eof

ass

ets

min

us

book

valu

eof

equ

ity,

all

div

ided

by

book

valu

eof

ass

ets.

Return

on

Assets

isn

etin

com

eb

efore

inte

rest

exp

ense

s,d

ivid

edby

tota

lass

ets.

Tangibility

isth

era

tio

of

pro

per

ty,

pla

nt,

an

deq

uip

men

tto

tota

lass

ets.

LiquidityNeeds

isth

era

tio

of

deb

tin

curr

ent

liab

ilit

ies

toto

tal

deb

t.Credit

Rating

isa

nu

mer

icin

dex

of

the

firm

’slo

ng-t

erm

cred

itra

tin

gfr

om

Sta

nd

ard

&P

oor’

s,w

ith

1re

pre

senti

ng

“A

AA

”,

2re

pre

senti

ng

“A

A+

”,

etc.

All

vari

ab

les

are

win

sori

zed

at

the

1-9

9le

vel

.*,

**,

an

d***

rep

rese

nt

stati

stic

al

sign

ifica

nce

at

the

10,

5,

an

d1%

level

s.

Page 38: Debt Restructuring Costs and Bankruptcy Risk: …...Debt Restructuring Costs and Bankruptcy Risk: Evidence from CDS Spreads Abstract We examine the e ects of a recent change to the

Table 2. CDS Spreads Around TD9599, Firms Sorted by Z-Score

Dependent Variable CDS SpreadsWindow around Announcement 7 weeks 2 weeks

Type of Firm Distressed Non-distressed Distressed Non-distressed

HighSyndicated 235.37*** 96.00*** 146.22** 36.50 224.65*** 90.26*** 140.55** 26.08(5.13) (2.86) (2.51) (1.10) (5.00) (2.66) (2.32) (0.57)

PostTD -15.23*** -11.22*** -2.58 3.65 -10.16*** -15.46*** -6.95*** -10.88***(-5.96) (-4.43) (-0.46) (0.42) (-5.59) (-6.59) (-2.98) (-3.52)

HighSyndicated x PostTD -31.25*** -29.52*** -0.04 -15.17 -23.01*** -20.99*** -1.97 -1.24(-3.30) (-2.87) (-0.00) (-1.41) (-3.25) (-2.72) (-0.66) (-0.42)

Firm Leverage 280.69*** 633.15*** 280.09*** 578.12**(3.07) (4.07) (2.95) (2.71)

Firm Volatility 8.04*** 5.08*** 8.10*** 5.52**(5.90) (3.02) (5.73) (2.18)

Market Volatility -0.59 1.16 -0.50 1.39(-1.19) (1.28) (-0.59) (1.20)

Tobin’s Q 91.19*** 2.26 93.92*** -10.02(2.91) (0.18) (2.90) (-0.60)

Log Assets 54.68** -2.42 52.97** -2.69(2.46) (-0.18) (2.34) (-0.18)

Return on Assets -600.98** 55.52 -613.01* 174.73(-2.10) (0.16) (-1.94) (0.42)

Tangibility 6.73 -28.06 1.48 -18.66(0.12) (-0.28) (0.03) (-0.18)

Liquidity Needs 82.08 116.89 82.75 142.80(0.59) (1.12) (0.57) (1.11)

Term Slope -76.18*** -27.26* -98.23*** -61.07***(-6.25) (-1.88) (-5.53) (-3.23)

Credit Rating 28.54*** -5.86 26.66** -12.28(2.87) (-0.66) (2.55) (-1.18)

Industry Fixed Effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes YesObservations 1,545 1,410 457 457 412 376 123 123Adjusted R2 0.282 0.827 0.409 0.806 0.255 0.820 0.360 0.769

This table examines the changes in CDS spreads around the Sept. 12, 2012 TD9599 announcement. The sample contains 257 non-financial firms in the intersection of the Compustat, LPC–Dealscan, and DTCC databases. Each regression is at the firm-week levelfor 7- and 2-week windows around the announcement. “Distressed” firms have 2012 Altman Z-Score< 3, and “Non-distressed” firmshave Z-Score ≥ 3. The dependent variable in each regression is weekly CDS spreads, winsorized at the 1-99 level. HighSyndicatedequals 1 if the firm’s syndicated loans–debt ratio is in the highest tercile of the sample distribution, and 0 if the ratio is in thelowest tercile. (Firms in the middle tercile are omitted.) PostTD is an indicator equal to 1 for weeks after Sept. 12, 2012, and 0otherwise. Firm Leverage is the sum of debt in current liabilities, long-term debt, and preferred stock, divided by this number plusmarket capitalization. Firm Volatility is the annualized standard deviation of daily stock returns from the previous fiscal year.Market Volatility is the weekly closing value of the VIX index. Tobin’s Q is market capitalization plus book value of assets minusbook value of equity, all divided by book value of assets. Log Assets is the natural logarithm of total assets. Return on Assetsis net income plus interest expense, divided by total assets. Tangibility is the ratio of property, plant, and equipment to totalassets. Liquidity Needs is the ratio of debt in current liabilities to total debt. All control variables are winsorized at the 1-99 level.Term Slope is the weekly difference between the yield on a 10-year U.S. Treasury bond and 2-year U.S. Treasury note. CreditRating is a numeric index of the firm’s long-term credit rating from Standard & Poor’s, with 1 representing “AAA”, 2 representing“AA+”, etc. All regressions include industry fixed effects based on the Fama-French 12-industry classification. t-statistics are inparentheses. Standard errors are clustered at the firm level. *, **, and *** represent statistical significance at the 10, 5, and 1%levels.

Page 39: Debt Restructuring Costs and Bankruptcy Risk: …...Debt Restructuring Costs and Bankruptcy Risk: Evidence from CDS Spreads Abstract We examine the e ects of a recent change to the

Table 3. CDS Spreads Around TD9599, Firms Sorted by Distance-to-Default

Dependent Variable CDS SpreadsWindow around Announcement 7 weeks 2 weeks

Type of Firm Distressed Non-distressed Distressed Non-distressed

HighSyndicated 289.24*** 148.07*** 11.04 1.87 271.72*** 132.23*** 10.23 1.25(4.09) (3.70) (0.87) (0.19) (3.84) (3.07) (0.81) (0.13)

PostTD -11.95** -7.62 -10.03*** -8.26*** -15.20*** -24.02*** -5.84*** -6.70***(-2.32) (-1.50) (-4.56) (-4.14) (-3.84) (-5.32) (-4.76) (-5.21)

HighSyndicated x PostTD -36.28*** -41.55*** 0.33 0.33 -19.41** -19.60** -0.05 0.03(-2.73) (-3.21) (0.10) (0.10) (-2.14) (-2.07) (-0.03) (0.02)

Firm Leverage 309.92** 118.23* 313.12** 124.00*(2.54) (1.88) (2.41) (1.91)

Firm Volatility 7.49*** 0.41 7.49*** 0.32(4.74) (0.58) (4.34) (0.43)

Market Volatility 0.54 -0.47* 1.23 -1.02**(0.61) (-1.74) (0.86) (-2.33)

Tobin’s Q -21.26 -1.62 -33.13 -0.63(-0.36) (-0.16) (-0.52) (-0.06)

Log Assets 58.33* 1.39 60.05* 1.43(1.92) (0.16) (1.86) (0.16)

Return on Assets -525.12* 321.37* -472.54 328.64*(-1.86) (1.78) (-1.52) (1.75)

Tangibility -10.56 -48.49* -24.54 -50.50*(-0.12) (-1.72) (-0.27) (-1.77)

Liquidity Needs 67.98 41.14 68.95 34.15(0.35) (1.61) (0.33) (1.26)

Term Slope -107.63*** -25.98*** -151.17*** -23.26***(-5.25) (-5.09) (-5.47) (-6.30)

Credit Rating 35.89*** 10.48*** 34.75*** 9.91***(3.03) (3.06) (2.68) (2.77)

Industry Fixed Effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes YesObservations 894 879 793 793 240 236 211 211Adjusted R2 0.199 0.834 0.270 0.572 0.156 0.816 0.226 0.537

This table examines the changes in CDS spreads around the Sept. 12, 2012 TD9599 announcement. In this table, “Distressed”firms are those with below-median distance-to-default, and ”Non-distressed” firms are those with above-median distance-to-default.The sample contains 257 non-financial firms in the intersection of the Compustat, LPC–Dealscan, and DTCC databases. Eachregression is at the firm-week level for 7- and 2-week windows around the announcement. The dependent variable in each regressionis weekly CDS spreads, winsorized at the 1-99 level. HighSyndicated equals 1 if the firm’s syndicated loans–debt ratio is in thehighest tercile of the sample distribution, and 0 if the ratio is in the lowest tercile. (Firms in the middle tercile are omitted.)PostTD is an indicator equal to 1 for weeks after Sept. 12, 2012, and 0 otherwise. Firm Leverage is the sum of debt in currentliabilities, long-term debt, and preferred stock, divided by this number plus market capitalization. Firm Volatility is the annualizedstandard deviation of daily stock returns from the previous fiscal year. Market Volatility is the weekly closing value of the VIXindex. Tobin’s Q is market capitalization plus book value of assets minus book value of equity, all divided by book value of assets.Log Assets is the natural logarithm of total assets. Return on Assets is net income plus interest expense, divided by total assets.Tangibility is the ratio of property, plant, and equipment to total assets. Liquidity Needs is the ratio of debt in current liabilitiesto total debt. All control variables are winsorized at the 1-99 level. Term Slope is the weekly difference between the yield on a10-year U.S. Treasury bond and 2-year U.S. Treasury note. Credit Rating is a numeric index of the firm’s long-term credit ratingfrom Standard & Poor’s, with 1 representing “AAA”, 2 representing “AA+”, etc. All regressions include industry fixed effectsbased on the Fama-French 12-industry classification. t-statistics are in parentheses. Standard errors are clustered at the firm level.*, **, and *** represent statistical significance at the 10, 5, and 1% levels.

Page 40: Debt Restructuring Costs and Bankruptcy Risk: …...Debt Restructuring Costs and Bankruptcy Risk: Evidence from CDS Spreads Abstract We examine the e ects of a recent change to the

Table 4. Shareholder Effects of TD9599 Announcement

Type of Firm Distressed Non-distressed

Event Window (-1, +2) (-3, +3) (-1, +2) (-3, +3)

HighSyndicated 1.16%** 1.57%** -0.51% 0.11%(2.11) (2.15) (-1.23) (0.20)

LowSyndicated -0.86%*** -0.98%** -0.12% -0.05%(-2.64) (-2.27) (-0.10) (-0.32)

Difference 2.02%*** 2.55%*** -0.39% 0.16%(4.79) (2.77) (-0.80) (0.19)

This table examines borrower stock returns around the Sept. 12, 2012 TD9599 announcement. The sample contains all firms in theintersection of Compustat, LPC–Dealscan, and CRSP databases that have at least one syndicated loan outstanding at the start offiscal year 2012. “Distressed” firms have 2012 Altman Z-Score < 3, and “Non-distressed” firms have Z-Score ≥ 3. HighSyndicatedis a portfolio of firms that have a syndicated loans–debt ratio in the highest tercile of the sample distribution, and LowSyndicatedis a portfolio of firms that have a loans–debt ratio in the lowest tercile. The loans–debt ratio is principal for all syndicated loansoutstanding in 2011 divided by total debt in 2011. All portfolios are size-weighted based on firms’ total assets in 2012. Abnormalstock returns are based on the Fama-French 3-factor model. Cumulative Abnormal Returns (CARs) are the sum of abnormal dailystock returns over each event window, with Sept. 12, 2012 set as date 0. Below the CARs are t-statistics based on the Brown andWarner (1980) portfolio method for event-date clustering. The estimation window for the benchmark Fama-French model is 7 to1 months prior to the TD9599 announcement. Firms with fewer than 60 days of stock return data in the estimation window aredropped. *, **, and *** represent statistical significance at the 10, 5, and 1% levels, respectively.

Page 41: Debt Restructuring Costs and Bankruptcy Risk: …...Debt Restructuring Costs and Bankruptcy Risk: Evidence from CDS Spreads Abstract We examine the e ects of a recent change to the

Table 5. TD9599 and Financing Terms on New Syndicated Loans

Dependent Variable Obtained Loan New Loan MarkupModel Logistic OLS

Diff-in-Diff ComparisonDistressed Highly Distressed Distressed Highly Distressed

vs. Non-Distressed vs. Non-Distressed vs. Non-Distressed vs. Non-Distressed

Distressed -0.10** -0.12** 0.22** 0.18(-2.11) (-2.22) (2.27) (1.61)

PostTD -0.10** -0.10* 0.18 0.11(-1.97) (-1.96) (1.47) (0.90)

Distressed x PostTD 0.11* 0.16*** -0.30** -0.26**(1.80) (2.71) (-2.43) (-1.98)

Firm Leverage 0.18** 0.18* 0.86*** 0.97***(2.02) (1.74) (3.70) (3.47)

Firm Volatility <-0.01*** <-0.01*** -0.00 -0.00(-3.73) (-3.36) (-0.86) (-0.11)

Market Volatility -0.00 -0.01*(-0.82) (-1.90)

Tobin’s Q 0.00 0.01 0.18*** 0.20***(0.10) (0.19) (2.80) (2.92)

Log Assets 0.02 0.02 -0.03 -0.02(1.46) (1.16) (-1.05) (-0.68)

Return on Assets 0.13 0.15 -0.86 -1.37**(0.54) (0.58) (-1.34) (-2.45)

Tangibility 0.06 0.05 -0.41** -0.24(0.83) (0.56) (-2.31) (-1.22)

Liquidity Needs -0.01 -0.05 0.46** 0.20(-0.08) (-0.48) (1.99) (1.11)

Term Slope -0.18* -0.16(-1.81) (-1.42)

Credit Rating -0.01* -0.01 0.26*** 0.25***(-1.66) (-1.18) (14.28) (11.87)

Industry Fixed Effects Yes Yes Yes YesObservations 1,730 1,292 1,316 1,028Pseudo/Adjusted R2 0.024 0.030 0.460 0.480

This table examines whether firms’ financing terms improved after the Sept. 12, 2012 TD9599 announcement. The samplecontains all firms that are in the intersection of the Compustat, LPC–Dealscan, and CRSP databases. Financial firms are excluded.Columns (1) and (2) are logistic regressions, and coefficients represent the marginal effects of each variable. Each regression has twoobservations per firm, one each for the 12-month period before and 12-month period after the TD9599 announcement (September2012 is excluded in all columns). The dependent variable Obtained Loan equals 1 for firms that obtained a syndicated loan inthe respective 12-month period, and 0 otherwise. Columns (3) and (4) are OLS regressions, with one observation for each newsyndicated loan signed by a firm in the 12-month window around the TD9599 announcement. Syndicated loans with principal lessthan $100M (unaffected by TD9599) are excluded. The dependent variable New Loan Markup is the percentage-point all-in drawnspread on new syndicated loan issues. Columns (1) and (3) show results from a difference-in-differences regression comparingdistressed (2012 Altman Z-Score < 3) and non-distressed (Z-Score ≥ 3) borrowers. Columns (2) and (4) compare highly distressed(Z-Score < 1.86) and non-distressed (Z-Score ≥ 3) borrowers. Distressed equals 1 for firms with Z-Score < 3 (or < 1.86), and 0 forfirms with Z-Score ≥ 3. PostTD equals 1 for observations after September 2012, and 0 for observations before September 2012.Firm Leverage is the sum of debt in current liabilities, long-term debt, and preferred stock, divided by this number plus marketcapitalization. Firm Volatility is the annualized standard deviation of daily stock returns from the previous fiscal year. MarketVolatility is the weekly closing value of the VIX index. Tobin’s Q is market capitalization plus book value of assets minus bookvalue of equity, all divided by book value of assets. Log Assets is the natural logarithm of total assets. Return on Assets is netincome plus interest expense, divided by total assets. Tangibility is the ratio of property, plant, and equipment to total assets.Liquidity Needs is the ratio of debt in current liabilities to total debt. Term Slope is the weekly difference between the yield on a10-year U.S. Treasury bond and 2-year U.S. Treasury note. Credit Rating is a numeric index of the firm’s long-term credit ratingfrom Standard & Poor’s, with 1 representing “AAA”, 2 representing “AA+”, etc. All regressions include industry fixed effectsbased on the Fama-French 12-industry classification. All firm-level control variables are measured at the end of the previous fiscalyear and are winsorized at the 1-99 level. t-statistics are in parentheses. Standard errors are adjusted for heteroskedasticity. *,**, and *** represent statistical significance at the 10, 5, and 1% levels.