consumption insurance between japanese households

11
This article was downloaded by: [Georgia Tech Library] On: 15 November 2014, At: 10:39 Publisher: Routledge Informa Ltd Registered in England and Wales Registered Number: 1072954 Registered office: Mortimer House, 37-41 Mortimer Street, London W1T 3JH, UK Applied Economics Publication details, including instructions for authors and subscription information: http://www.tandfonline.com/loi/raec20 Consumption insurance between Japanese households Miki Kohara Published online: 05 Oct 2010. To cite this article: Miki Kohara (2001) Consumption insurance between Japanese households, Applied Economics, 33:6, 791-800, DOI: 10.1080/00036840121946 To link to this article: http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/00036840121946 PLEASE SCROLL DOWN FOR ARTICLE Taylor & Francis makes every effort to ensure the accuracy of all the information (the “Content”) contained in the publications on our platform. However, Taylor & Francis, our agents, and our licensors make no representations or warranties whatsoever as to the accuracy, completeness, or suitability for any purpose of the Content. Any opinions and views expressed in this publication are the opinions and views of the authors, and are not the views of or endorsed by Taylor & Francis. The accuracy of the Content should not be relied upon and should be independently verified with primary sources of information. Taylor and Francis shall not be liable for any losses, actions, claims, proceedings, demands, costs, expenses, damages, and other liabilities whatsoever or howsoever caused arising directly or indirectly in connection with, in relation to or arising out of the use of the Content. This article may be used for research, teaching, and private study purposes. Any substantial or systematic reproduction, redistribution, reselling, loan, sub-licensing, systematic supply, or distribution in any form to anyone is expressly forbidden. Terms & Conditions of access and use can be found at http:// www.tandfonline.com/page/terms-and-conditions

Upload: miki

Post on 16-Mar-2017

213 views

Category:

Documents


1 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Consumption insurance between Japanese households

This article was downloaded by: [Georgia Tech Library]On: 15 November 2014, At: 10:39Publisher: RoutledgeInforma Ltd Registered in England and Wales Registered Number: 1072954 Registered office: MortimerHouse, 37-41 Mortimer Street, London W1T 3JH, UK

Applied EconomicsPublication details, including instructions for authors and subscription information:http://www.tandfonline.com/loi/raec20

Consumption insurance between JapanesehouseholdsMiki KoharaPublished online: 05 Oct 2010.

To cite this article: Miki Kohara (2001) Consumption insurance between Japanese households, Applied Economics,33:6, 791-800, DOI: 10.1080/00036840121946

To link to this article: http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/00036840121946

PLEASE SCROLL DOWN FOR ARTICLE

Taylor & Francis makes every effort to ensure the accuracy of all the information (the “Content”)contained in the publications on our platform. However, Taylor & Francis, our agents, and our licensorsmake no representations or warranties whatsoever as to the accuracy, completeness, or suitability for anypurpose of the Content. Any opinions and views expressed in this publication are the opinions and viewsof the authors, and are not the views of or endorsed by Taylor & Francis. The accuracy of the Contentshould not be relied upon and should be independently verified with primary sources of information.Taylor and Francis shall not be liable for any losses, actions, claims, proceedings, demands, costs,expenses, damages, and other liabilities whatsoever or howsoever caused arising directly or indirectly inconnection with, in relation to or arising out of the use of the Content.

This article may be used for research, teaching, and private study purposes. Any substantial or systematicreproduction, redistribution, reselling, loan, sub-licensing, systematic supply, or distribution in anyform to anyone is expressly forbidden. Terms & Conditions of access and use can be found at http://www.tandfonline.com/page/terms-and-conditions

Page 2: Consumption insurance between Japanese households

Consumption insurance between Japanese

households

MIKI KOHARA

National Graduate Institute for Policy Studies, 2-2 Wakamatsu-cho , Shinjuku, Tokyo,

162-8677, Japan

e-mail: [email protected]

This paper examines the implication of the full insurance hypothesis and diŒerences

in its applicability across groups of households in Japan. Using a rare Japanese

individual panel data set called the Japanese Panel Survey of Consumption, the

paper ® rst shows that the full insurance hypothesis is strongly rejected for the coun-

try as a whole. The paper further shows that the rich as well as the poor, and also

college graduates as well as non-college graduates cannot insure their consumptionagainst income shocks. In sharp contrast, urban residents can pool income shocks

completely, whereas rural residents cannot. Rural residents suŒer from income risks

more seriously than urban residents in Japan.

I . INTRODUCTION

There has been recent interest in the empirical investigation

of the hypothesis that households insure their consumption

against income uncertainty by means including risk sharing

and risk pooling. If individuals can achieve full insurance

within a country, change in an individual’s consumption

level is aŒected only by aggregate shocks and not by indi-

vidual income shocks. As a result, the consumption growth

rates should be equal among individuals in that country

and should be independent of individual income growth

rates.

Although it is hard to believe that all the people in a

country can access complete markets of the securities for

all the future possible states and completely avoid any

risks, some households might succeed in consuming the

optimal amount which they had planned even if they

faced serious income shocks. This raises the following ques-

tions: are there any groups who live in the world of full

insurance? If there are, what kinds of groups are they? The

goal of this paper is to verify the existence of insured

groups in Japan.

A great deal of empirical work has investigated the full

insurance implications and mostly rejected the hypothesis.

Cochrane (1991) partly and McCarthy (1995) strongly

reject the full insurance hypothesis for households in the

USA, using the Panel Survey of Income Dynamics (PSID).

Developing the analysis of full insurance for the entire

country, a few papers have investigated the existence of

consumption insurance within explicit and implicit groups

in the USA. McCarthy (1995) ® nds evidence supporting

full insurance for households with high wealth holdings.

He explains that rich households obtain enough savings

or borrowings to ® nance their consumption as their income

declines. As another example, Hayashi et al. (1996) show

that they cannot ® nd full insurance within a family, which

is the risk sharing between parents’ households and their

children’s households, using the PSID data.

In sharp contrast, there have been very few empirical

studies on consumption insurance for Japanese house-

holds. This is because few individual panel data sets have

been available in Japan. The published paper which comes

close to a full insurance test for Japan is Wincoop (1995)

who investigates risk sharing between Japanese prefectures.

He shows a low correlation between consumption and

income volatilities, using Japanese prefectural panel data,

and suggests that there might be risk sharing among pre-

fectures. Kohara (1997) has tested full insurance between

Japanese prefectures, using prefectural data similar to

Wincoop (1995) but applying a more direct method to

test for full insurance. Unlike Wincoop (1995), Kohara

(1997) strongly rejects full insurance between Japanese

Applied Economics ISSN 0003± 6846 print/ISSN 1466± 4283 online # 2001 Taylor & Francis Ltd

http://www.tandf.co.uk/journals

Applied Economics, 2001, 33, 791 ± 800

791

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

Geo

rgia

Tec

h L

ibra

ry]

at 1

0:39

15

Nov

embe

r 20

14

Page 3: Consumption insurance between Japanese households

prefectures. However, when prefectural level data are used,

an implicit but strong assumption that the full insurance

theory is applicable among individual households within a

given prefecture is imposed. This aggregation assumption

seems inappropriate. Attanatio and Davis (1996) shows

that a large speci® cation error rises when this aggregate

assumption is incorrectly imposed. To avoid this problem,

it is necessary to use panel data on households which do

not require this assumption of within-prefecture insurance.

One of the main contributions of this paper is to test full

insurance for the ® rst time using Japanese individual panel

data set. The data used in the paper are from the Japanese

Panel Survey of Consumption (JPSC, Shohiseikatsu nikan-

suru panel chosa in Japanese), which are rare panel data in

Japan.1 The use of the JPSC also contributes to comple-

menting the results on full insurance found in the USA,

since the JPSC contains a comprehensive concept of con-

sumption although PSID, which is used in most of the past

studies in the USA, reports only food consumption.

Another contribution of this paper is to verify the existence

of insured and uninsured groups in Japan. The veri® cation

is conducted by comparing the implications of full in-

surance between two sub-sample groups such as rich and

poor groups, college graduates and non-college graduate

groups, and urban and rural residential groups. The ver-

i® cation of insured and uninsured groups is important

since diŒerentials in insurance among groups in a country

can have diŒerent implications, for example, on welfare or

developments in the country. The uninsured group should

be assisted by the government’ s redistribution policy.

The main ® ndings of this paper are summarized as fol-

lows. When the test of full insurance is conducted for the

country as a whole, the paper strongly rejects the hypoth-

esis. As for the diŒerence in the full insurance implication

between rich and poor groups, it is found that the rich as

well as the poor cannot insure consumption against in-

come shocks, which is totally diŒerent from the result

McCarthy (1995) shows for the USA. At the same time,

college graduates as well as non-college graduates cannot

avoid the impact of income shocks on consumption. In

contrast, it is found that urban residents can insure fully

against income shocks, whereas rural residents cannot.

Further investigation shows that this urban± rural diŒer-

ence remains even after controlling for wealth diŒerences

and education diŒerences between urban and rural groups.

The next section reviews the theoretical implications of

the full insurance hypothesis in the literature to date. This

section also explains how to verify the existence of insuredand uninsured groups in Japan. Section III introduces the

data used and presents the regression results. It includes a

detailed discussion of the reasons for diŒerentials betweeninsured and uninsured groups. The ® nal section presents

some conclusions. The details of the data are given in the

data appendix.

II . THEORETICAL IMPLICATIONS

Full insurance

We ® rst illustrate the test implication of full insurance.

Under full insurance, households can access able contin-

gent claims for every possible state. Trading those contin-

gent claims, they can attain the optimal consumption theyhad planned initially, when state, st, is realized in period t.

Let p…st† be the price of a contingent claim for st in the

initial period. Suppose that there are S possible states in the

world, and that agents live for T periods. The optimal

consumption plan is derived from the household’s maximi-

zation of a time separable intertemporal utility functionsuch as:

T

tˆ1

1

1 ‡ »

t S

stˆ1

º…st†u…ci…st†; ¯i…st†† …1†

subject to:

T

tˆ1

S

stˆ1

p…st†ci…st† ˆT

tˆ1

S

stˆ1

p…st†ei…st† …2†

where » is the time preference rate, º…st† is the probability

of the state, both of which are identical over all agents,

u…c; ¯† is a single period utility function that depends onconsumption, c, and a preference shift parameter, ¯, and

ei…st† is agent i’ s exogenous income and transfers.

The ® rst order condition for consumption of agent i at

time t is:

1

1 ‡ »

t

uc…cit; ¯it† ˆ ¶i ¢ pt

ºt

…3†

where ¶i is a Lagrange multiplier for agent i’ s budget con-straint given by Equation 2. A subscript t simpli® es the

description of variables conditional on the state, st.

Dividing the ® rst order condition (Equation 3) at t ‡ 1

by the ® rst order condition at t, we obtain

1

1 ‡ »¢uc…cit‡1; ¯it‡1†

uc…cit; ¯it†ˆ

pt‡1=ºt‡1

pt=ºt

…4†

This states that the change in consumption for household i

from time t to t ‡ 1 should be proportional to the aggre-gate change in the economy, …pt‡1=ºt‡1†=…pt=ºt†, and to the

change in his preference shifts, but not be proportional to

the change in individual incomes. Since the aggregate

change in the world is identical over agents, Equation 4implies that under full insurance, consumption changes

792 M. Kohara

1Although there exists another household panel data called Family Income and Expenditure Survey which surveys the same households

every months for six months, it suŒers from strict limitations on its use.

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

Geo

rgia

Tec

h L

ibra

ry]

at 1

0:39

15

Nov

embe

r 20

14

Page 4: Consumption insurance between Japanese households

are identical over agents after controlling for individual

preference shifts.In order to derive the speci® c empirical models, a single

period utility function is further de® ned as a power func-

tion with a constant relative risk aversion parameter

® and a multiplicative preference shift ¯it, u…cit; ¯it† ˆ¯it…cit†1¡®=1 ¡ ®. Under null hypothesis of full insurance,individual consumption and individual income should be

independent. Adding the change in individual income,

ln…yit‡1=yit†, into the log of Equation 4 using a speci® ed

utility function, the estimated equation becomes:

lncit‡1

cit

ˆ ¬0

·t‡1

·t

‡ ¬1 ln¯it‡1

¯it

‡ ­ lnyit‡1

yit

‡ uit‡1 …5†

where uit‡1 is an error term that includes unobservedpreference shifts and consumption measurement errors.

The term ·t‡1=·t summarizes the aggregate changes in

the economy, which is written in terms of p and º in

Equation 4. A time dummy or aggregate consumption

change can be used for this change. The term ln¯it‡1=¯it

describes a shift of a household’ s preference. The exact

variables for the preference shifts are speci® ed in the data

appendix. If the individual income change is cross-

sectionally independent of the error term in the estimatedEquation 5, it has no eŒects on the growth rate of con-

sumption under full insurance: ­ ˆ 0. The alternative

hypothesis is no full insurance for the economy as a

whole: ­ 6ˆ 0.

Insured and uninsured groups

Rejection of the null of full insurance for the country as a

whole does not always mean that there are no households

living under full insurance in the country. Some households

may hold insurance against various kinds of income risksand succeed in smoothing consumption. For a group of

these households, it can be found that full insurance

applies. That is, there exists a diŒerence in full insurance

between the group of households who are expected to be

insured and the group of the remaining households.Tests of full insurance for split groups was ® rst con-

ducted by McCarthy (1995) when he examined the diŒer-

ence between groups of households with high and low

wealth holdings (hereafter, referred to as rich and poor

groups) in the USA. Applying his analysis, the present

paper attempts to ® nd diŒerences in insurance betweenvarious groups, and specify insured and uninsured groups

in Japan. The speci® c regression equation is:

lncijt‡1

cijt

ˆ ¬0j ‡ ¬1j ln¯ijt‡1

¯ijt

‡ ­ j lnyijt‡1

yijt

‡ uijt‡1

…6†

j ˆ

j1 if a household is categorized in a possibly

insured groupj2 if a household is categorized in a reference

group

The null of full insurance, ­ j ˆ 0, is tested against no full

insurance, ­ j 6ˆ 0, for the groups j1 and j2 separately. If

insured and uninsured groups are split correctly, the null

hypothesis would be accepted for group j1 but not for j2.

When the null is rejected in both groups, the degree ofcompleteness of full insurance is further compared between

the two groups, comparing the estimates of the two coe� -

cients on income change, ­ j1 and ­ j2; since the coe� cients

indicate how sensitive consumption changes are to income

changes.

The speci® c groups to be examined are rich and poorgroups, college graduates and non-college graduates

groups, and urban and rural residential groups. Since

rich households may be more capable of buying insurances

and/or borrowing money for income losses, one expects to

accept the full insurance implication for a rich group butnot for a poor group. This is the result actually found in the

USA by McCarthy (1995). The education one has attained

may also be correlated to the capability and tendency of

buying insurance. King and Leape (1987) demonstrate the

tendency that more educated people have more informa-tion on insurance so that they tend to insure against risks

more completely. If this was true in Japan, one would ® nd

the applicability of full insurance theory for the households

with longer periods of education. A diŒerence in insurance

may also arise between urban and rural groups for geogra-

phical reasons. What makes the urban and rural diŒerent isdiscussed later when the regression results are discussed.

III . DATA AND THE RESULTS

Data

This paper uses the JPSC, conducted by the Institute for

Household Economy in Japan. The survey started in 1993,

and the 1993 and 1994 waves are currently available. Thesample consists of married and unmarried women aged

between 24 and 34 in 1993. The survey asks married

women about their family members as well as themselves.

In this paper, the sample is limited to the married women.

This is because the test of a relationship between consump-tion and income for single women could be biased;

although Japanese single young women mostly live with

their parents and often live on parents’ income, the survey

does not ask the single women about their parents’ income

or consumption. The total number of married women is

1002. After eliminating observations with insu� cientresponses relating to all the variables required in the regres-

sions, the sample is reduced to 577.

Consumption insurance 793

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

Geo

rgia

Tec

h L

ibra

ry]

at 1

0:39

15

Nov

embe

r 20

14

Page 5: Consumption insurance between Japanese households

794 M. Kohara

Tab

le1.

Mea

ns

and

standard

dev

iati

ons

of

the

vari

able

s

Sp

lit

gro

ups

No

n-c

olleg

eC

olleg

eR

ura

lU

rban

Full

sam

ple

Th

ep

oor

Th

eri

chgra

duate

sgra

duate

sre

sid

ents

resi

den

ts

Th

eaver

age

of:

Con

sum

pti

on

1993

19.7

5(7

.27)

19.5

5(7

.45)

19.8

5(7

.18)

18.9

6(6

.87)

20.4

8(7

.56)

19.6

0(7

.27)

20.2

8(7

.29)

Con

sum

pti

on

1994

20.9

1(8

.6)

20.0

6(7

.77)

21.3

3(9

.11)

20.1

9(8

.05)

21.5

7(9

.23)

20.4

1(8

.26)

22.6

6(9

.97)

Co

nsu

mp

tio

ngro

wth

rate

s0.0

44

(0.4

)0.0

17

(0.4

)0.0

57

(0.3

98)

0.0

47

(0.4

06)

0.0

40

(0.3

93)

0.0

29

(0.4

09)

0.0

95

(0.3

55)

Inco

me

1993

30.1

2(1

5.0

6)

29.5

9(1

6.1

9)

30.3

8(1

4.4

9)

29.7

5(1

7.7

8)

30.4

5(1

2.0

5)

29.8

6(1

6.3

4)

31.0

3(9

.19)

Inco

me

1994

31.3

0(1

4.9

7)

29.8

6(9

.38)

32.0

1(1

7.0

3)

30.4

4(1

3.9

4)

32.0

9(1

5.8

3)

31.0

2(1

6.0

6)

32.2

8(1

0.1

8)

Inco

me

gro

wth

rate

s0.0

41

(0.3

1)

0.0

23

(0.3

66)

0.0

49

(0.2

84)

0.0

43

(0.3

18)

0.0

39

(0.3

1)

0.0

42

(0.3

36)

0.0

35

(0.2

15)

Co

rrel

ati

on

bet

wee

nin

com

ean

dco

nsu

mp

tion

gro

wth

rate

s0.1

52

0.1

99

0.1

21

0.1

39

0.1

64

0.1

66

0.0

74

Nu

mber

of

sam

ple

577

191

386

277

300

450

127

Note

s:T

he

unit

sfo

rco

nsu

mp

tion

an

din

com

eare

10

tho

usa

nd

yen

.G

row

thra

tes

are

inp

erce

nta

ges

;A

ge

isth

eaver

age

are

of

the

wif

eand

the

hu

sban

d;S

tan

dard

dev

iati

on

sare

inpare

nth

eses

.

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

Geo

rgia

Tec

h L

ibra

ry]

at 1

0:39

15

Nov

embe

r 20

14

Page 6: Consumption insurance between Japanese households

The details of the data used in the following regressions are

summarized in data appendix. Table 1 presents the means

and standard deviations of consumption and income. For

the entire sample, the average monthly consumption and

income are about 200 and 310 thousand yen, respectively.

Although the sample ages are not exactly same, the Family

Income and Expenditure Survey (Kakei chosa in Japanese)

shows for the age group from 25 to 34, average consump-

tion and income are 250 and 360 thousand yen, respect-

ively, while for Basic Survey on the Life of the People

(Kokumin Seikatsu Kiso chosa in Japanese) for the age

group from 30 to 39, the averages are 240 and 370 thou-

sand yen, respectively. The averages in the JPSC are smal-

ler probably because the sample in the JPSC is younger and

the sample used in this paper excludes rich single women.

Compared to the poor, the rich attain higher consump-

tion and income both in levels and growth rates. The fact

that the correlation of consumption and income is much

smaller for the rich than for the poor may suggest that the

rich can pool income shocks more successfully. As

expected, the average income for college graduates is

higher than for non-college graduates. The consumption

and income growth rates, however, are almost the same

between college graduates and the others. Also, the corre-

lation rate is not very diŒerent compared to the diŒerences

in the other groups. This leads one to expect that there is

no diŒerence in the full insurance implication between edu-

cation groups. Urban residents earn and consume more on

average than rural residents. The correlation between con-

sumption and income growth rates is much smaller for

urban residents than for rural residents, so one might expect

that full insurance is possibly attained in the urban group.

The results

Full insurance. First the full insurance implication for the

country as a whole is tested by estimating Equation 5 by

ordinary least squares (OLS).2 The results are shown in

Table 2. The coe� cient on income change, ­ , is focused

on which shows the per centage change in consumption

as income changes by one per cent. The coe� cient of ­ is

0.237 and is signi® cantly diŒerent from zero at the 1%

signi® cance level. Hence, the full insurance hypothesis is

rejected. The estimated coe� cient is a little bit larger

than that in the United States, which is about 0.18 in the

literature to date.

Instead of actual income changes, the paper also

attempts to use the changes in unemployment status’

which is a variable indicating whether or not either the

husband or the wife in a family `became unemployed’.

The results, however, are unchanged: the coe� cient on

the changes in unemployment status is negative and signif-

icantly diŒerent from zero at the 10% signi® cance level.This shows that consumption expenditure would be

reduced when someone in a family became unemployed

and that the full insurance implication is rejected. The

result, however, may be biased since there are few `hus-

bands’ who were unemployed in either 1993 or 1994.

Thus, the change in unemployment status principallyre¯ ects changes in the unemployment status of wives. The

eŒect of a wife being unemployed (or employed) on her

household’s expenditure seems diŒerent from the eŒect of

husband being unemployed (or employed). It is often

pointed out that the wife’ s income is just pocket money:it is not the main income which her household live on but

rather an additional income source to the main income of

her husband. If this is true, the wife’ s becoming unem-

ployed does not aŒect the household’s consumption ser-

iously, making the result look suggestive for the nullhypothesis of full insurance. Thus, the change in unem-

ployment status might not be a good proxy for income

shocks. Hence, any results using the index of changes in

unemployed status will not be reported in the following

regressions.

Insured and uninsured groups. The study will next investi-gate the diŒerence in full insurance between groups. First

of all, Table 3a shows the results for rich and poor

Consumption insurance 795

2If the error term in the regressed equation is correlated to the change in individual income, the instrumental variable (IV) estimation

should be used. This paper, however, uses OLS, because su� cient instruments for individual income cannot be found. This is probablybecause the number of the observations used in this paper is quite limited both in terms of the cross section and time. The use ofinstrumental variable estimation is left as topic for future research.

Table 2. Test of full insurance for the entire country

Regression of consumption growth

Estimated coe� cient of:Constant 0.273*

(0.151)Age 70.006

(0.005)Family needs 70.151

(0.121)Child 70.032Parents 70.085**

(0.038)Income 0.196***

(0.052)

r-squared 0.038Sample number 577

Notes: Standard errors are in parentheses; The dependent variableis the Consumption growth rates (the change in logarithms ofconsumption). Income is also taken as the change in logarithms.Details of the variables are described in the appendix, and thename of the variables are explained in the footnote of Table 1;Asterisks means that coe� cients are signi® cantly diŒerent fromzero at the 10% level (*), 5% level (**) and 1% level (***).

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

Geo

rgia

Tec

h L

ibra

ry]

at 1

0:39

15

Nov

embe

r 20

14

Page 7: Consumption insurance between Japanese households

796 M. Kohara

Tab

le3.

Insu

red

and

unin

sure

dgro

ups:

regre

ssio

ns

of

consu

mpti

on

gro

wth

and

test

sof

diV

eren

tials

bet

wee

ngro

ups

Tab

le3a

Table

3b

Tab

le3c

Po

or

Ric

hN

on

-coll

ege

Co

lleg

eR

ura

lU

rban

gro

up

gro

up

gra

du

ate

sgra

duate

sgro

up

gro

up

Est

imate

dco

e�ci

ent

of:

Co

nst

ant

70.1

74

0.4

67**

0.2

98

0.2

18

0.3

56**

0.0

26

(0.2

73)

(0.1

89)

(0.2

28)

(0.2

28)

(0.1

78)

(0.2

79)

Age

0.0

04

70.0

11*

70.0

07

70.0

04

70.0

08

0.0

01

(0.0

08)

(0.0

06)

(0.0

06)

(0.0

07)

(0.0

05)

(0.0

09)

Fam

ily

nee

ds

70.1

97

0.1

25

70.1

83

70.1

18

70.1

43

70.2

92

(0.1

79)

(0.1

69)

(0.1

82)

(0.1

66)

(0.1

32)

(0.3

09)

Ch

ild

0.1

13

70.0

59

70.0

12

70.0

52

70.0

45

0.0

30

(0.1

24)

(0.0

64)

(0.1

11)

(0.0

66)

(0.0

66)

(0.0

96)

Pare

nts

70.1

12

70.0

74

70.1

25**

70.0

45

70.1

16***

0.1

39*

(0.0

72)

(0.0

46)

(0.0

55)

(0.0

54)

(0.0

43)

(0.0

9)

Inco

me

0.2

18***

0.1

66**

0.1

96***

0.1

98***

0.2

06***

0.0

82

(0.0

78)

(0.0

71)

(0.0

77)

(0.0

73)

(0.0

56)

(0.1

49)

r-sq

uare

d0.0

67

0.0

35

0.0

45

0.0

35

0.0

52

0.0

31

Sam

ple

nu

mb

er191

386

277

300

450

127

The

diŒ

eren

cete

st:

Wald

stati

stic

s(P

-valu

e)0.4

93

0.0

19

(0.6

24)

(0.9

84)

Note

s:See

the

foo

tnote

sin

Tab

le2;

Th

ediŒ

eren

cete

stis

ate

sto

fth

ed

iŒer

ence

of

the

coe�

cien

tso

nIn

com

eb

etw

een

the

two

gro

ups

and

isco

ndu

cted

when

the

coe�

cien

tson

inco

me

are

acc

epte

das

bei

ng

diŒ

eren

tfr

om

zero

inb

oth

two

gro

up

s.F

or

the

test

,th

eP

-valu

efr

om

the

stan

dard

no

rmal

dis

trib

uti

on

issh

ow

nin

pare

nth

eses

.

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

Geo

rgia

Tec

h L

ibra

ry]

at 1

0:39

15

Nov

embe

r 20

14

Page 8: Consumption insurance between Japanese households

households. According to Table 3a, the null hypothesis of

full insurance is rejected for both rich and poor groups.

In addition, the coe� cients on income changes are the

same between two groups: the hypothesis of identical

coe� cients cannot be rejected at the 10% signi® cance

level. That is, full insurance is not attained in either the

rich group or the poor group in Japan.

This result is totally diŒerent from what McCarthy

(1995) shows for USA households, where rich households

can insure against income shocks more completely than

poor households. It is not the case in Japan that the rich

can participate more completely in insurance markets

which the poor cannot access. Also it is not the case in

Japan that rich households can pool income shocks by

using their own savings or borrowings.

Table 3b shows the results on the diŒerence between

college graduates and non-college graduates. The null

hypothesis of full insurance is rejected in both groups. In

addition, the hypothesis of identical coe� cients on income

changes between two groups cannot be rejected at the 10%

signi® cance level. Thus, no diŒerence in consumption

insurance is found between college graduates and non-col-

lege graduates. Educated people as well as less educated

people cannot insure completely their consumption against

income risks in Japan.

Table 3c presents the results on the diŒerence between

urban and rural groups. Unlike the results in Table 3a and

Table 3b, the coe� cient on income changes is signi® cantly

diŒerent from zero in rural areas at the 1% signi® cance

level, but not in urban areas at all. Thus, urban residents

insure their consumption against income risks completely,

although rural residents cannot. Rural residents suŒer

more seriously from the eŒect of income shocks on their

consumption than urban residents.

There are several explanations to account for the result.

First of all, access to insurance markets might be more

convenient in urban areas than in rural areas. The limited

access prevents rural residents from participating in insur-

ance markets. Secondly, urban residents might be relatively

rich, holding larger levels of wealth.3 It has been already

explained that the rich have a higher possibility of living

under full insurance. Although the rich and poor diŒerence

in full insurance was not statistically signi® cant in Table 3a,

the rich± poor diŒerence possibly remains between two

groups. It is true that urban residents are richer than

rural residents in Japan. The JPSC shows that the average

amount of liquid assets (saving account deposits, time

deposits, and bonds) are around 3.21 million yen in the

urban group and 2.90 million yen in the rural group.

Thirdly, it is often said that urban residents achieve higher

education levels than rural residents. According to the

JPSC, the percentage of husbands who are college gradu-

ates is 47.98% in the urban group and 31.42% in the ruralgroup. It has already been explained why college graduates

have a higher possibility of living under full insurance.

Although the educational group diŒerence did not appear

statistically signi® cant in Table 3b, the educational diŒer-

ence may still remain between two area groups, raising theurban± rural diŒerence.

The further investigation on urban± rural diVerence

If the second and/or the third explanation in the last para-

graph is true, the urban± rural diŒerence found in Table 3c

would disappear or be diminished after controlling forwealth or educational diŒerences between urban and

rural groups. The full insurance implication is re-examined

for urban and rural groups, controlling for wealth and

education diŒerences between the residential groups. The

speci® c estimated equation is:

lnciat‡1

ciat

ˆ ¬0a ‡ ¬1a ln¯iat‡1

¯iat

‡ ­ 1a lnyiat‡1

yiat

‡ ­ 2a lnyiat‡1

yiat

¢ Dhiat‡1 ‡ uiat‡1

a ˆu (urban residents)

r (rural residents)…7†

The diŒerence from the previous regression equation is themultiplicative term (cross term) of a household’s income

growth and a dummy variable, Dhia, which takes the value

one if household i living in area a is de® ned to be rich and

zero otherwise. That is, the coe� cient on income growth

becomes ­ 1a ‡ ­ 2a for the rich and ­ 1a for the poor. If thereis no diŒerence in the insurance implications between rich

and poor households, ­ 2a would be zero. Thus, the null

hypothesis of no diŒerence in the full insurance implication

between rich and poor households, ­ 2a ˆ 0, is tested for

each residential group. The hypothesis of full insurance,

­ 1a ˆ 0 and ­ 1a ‡ ­ 2a ˆ 0, is then tested for each residential

group. Moreover, the diŒerence between urban and rural

groups is examined, checking the diŒerence in test implica-

tions of full insurance and the estimated coe� cients, ­ 1u

and ­ 1r for the poor, and ­ 1u ‡ ­ 2u and ­ 1r ‡ ­ 2r for the

rich. The same method is used to control for educationaldiŒerences.

Table 4a shows the results when rich and poor diŒer-

ences are controlled for. Attention focuses on the results

for the rural group on the left half in Table 4a. The eŒect of

income changes on consumption changes for the poor is0.223 and for the rich, the sum of the coe� cient on in-

come and on cross term of income and wealth, is 0.191.

Consumption insurance 797

3The result of urban and rural diŒerence does not depend on what kinds of wealth are used. For example, the result is unchanged even if

total wealth is used including real assets such as houses and lands.

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

Geo

rgia

Tec

h L

ibra

ry]

at 1

0:39

15

Nov

embe

r 20

14

Page 9: Consumption insurance between Japanese households

Both values are signi® cantly diŒerent from zero at the 1%

level. In contrast, in the right half in Table 4a, the

coe� cients are 0.235 and 0.030, respectively for poor and

rich households living in urban areas. Neither of these

coe� cients are signi® cantly diŒerent from zero, supporting

the null of full insurance for both rich and poor households

in the urban group. The fact that the coe� cients for the

rural group are signi® cant but those for the urban group

are insigni® cant indicates that urban± rural diŒerences in

full insurance remains even after controlling for wealth

diŒerences. Note that the eŒect of income changes on con-

sumption changes becomes extremely small for rich house-

holds living in urban areas. Su� cient wealth holdings as

well as good access to insurance markets might make it

possible for the rich in urban areas to pool idiosyncratic

income shocks completely, and realize the amount of con-

sumption they planned.

We next attempt to control for education diŒerences

between regional groups. Table 4b shows that the coe� -

cients on the cross term of income and college dummies are

not signi® cant either in rural nor urban groups. That is, we

cannot ® nd a statistical diŒerence in consumption insur-

ance between college graduates and non-college graduates.

The coe� cients on income changes are 0.197 and 0.214 for

college graduates and non-college graduates living in rural

areas, respectively. Both coe� cients are statistically signi® -

cant from zero at the 1% level. In contrast, the respective

coe� cients are 0.302 and ¡0:064 in the urban group, and

neither is statistically signi® cant. Thus, we reemphasize the

existence of the urban± rural diŒerence even after control-

ling for education diŒerences between two area groups.

Note that the coe� cients on income changes for college

graduates in both urban and rural areas are small, which

suggests that college graduates, regardless of their location,

tend to insure consumption against idiosyncratic income

shocks.

To complete the discussion, the constraint that estimated

Equation 7 imposes is checked. The constraint is that the

coe� cients on preference shifts, ¬a1, in the estimated

Equation 7 are identical over rich and poor groups (college

graduates and non-college graduates) in a given region. If

the constraint is incorrect, for example, if an increase in

number of family members aŒects the family’s consump-

tion expenditure seriously only for the poor, the estimated

coe� cients would be biased. To test the restriction of iden-

tical coe� cients in preference shifts, one speci® cally adds,

798 M. Kohara

Table 4a. Urban vs rural controlling for the wealth diVerence Table 4b. Urban vs rural, controlling for the education diVerence

Rural Urban Rural Urbangroup group group group

Estimated coe� cient of: Estimated coe� cient of:Constant 0.360** 0.013 Constant 0.353** 0.076

(0.178) (0.28) (0.179) (0.281)Age 70.008 0.001 Age 70.008 0.000

(0.005) (0.009) (0.006) (0.009)Family needs 70.144 70.290 Family needs 70.143 70.358

(0.133) (0.31) (0.133) (0.313)Child 70.046 0.03 Child 70.044 0.027

(0.066) (0.096) (0.066) (0.096)Parents 70.116*** 0.142 Parents 70.116*** 0.148*

(0.043) (0.09) (0.043) (0.089)Income¤wealth 70.032 70.205 Income¤college 0.017 70.366

(0.113) (0.337) ((0.113) (0.309)Income 0.223*** 0.235 Income 0.197** 0.302

(0.082) (0.293) (0.080) (0.238)

r-squared 0.053 0.034 r-squred 0.052 0.042Sample number 450 127 Sample number 450 127

Test for income¤wealth ‡ incomeˆ 0’ 6.04 0.03 Test for income¤college ‡ incomeˆ 0’ 7.18 0.11(0.014) (0.861) (0.008) (0.742)

Test for the same coe� cients: F-statistics 0.44 0.37 Test for the same coe� cients: F-statistics 0.59 0.75(0.778) (0.869) (0.667) (0.586)

Notes: See the footnote in Table 2; Income¤Wealth and Income¤Education are cross terms of income growth rates multiplied by a wealthor education dummy. The wealth dummy takes the value one if a household is de® ned as rich and zero otherwise. The education dummytakes the value one if a household is grouped in the college graduates group and zero otherwise; For the tests for (in-come¤wealth ‡ income) and for (income¤college ‡ income), F-statistics and P-value are shown; The test of identical coe� cients indicatesthe test of identical coe� cients on age, family needs, child and parents over the rich and the poor (college graduates and not collegegraduates) groups. F-statistics and P-value are shown.

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

Geo

rgia

Tec

h L

ibra

ry]

at 1

0:39

15

Nov

embe

r 20

14

Page 10: Consumption insurance between Japanese households

to Equation 7, cross terms of preference shifts and a

dummy variable indicating a rich household (college grad-uate) and tests whether the coe� cients on the cross terms

are zero or not. If the null of identical coe� cients is

accepted, which indicates no diŒerence in the eŒects of

preference shifts on consumption changes between rich

and poor groups (college graduates and non-college grad-uates), the estimation of Equation 7 is justi® ed. On the

other hand, if the null is rejected, a correct restriction of

heterogeneous coe� cients for rich and poor groups needs

to be put separately. That is, ­ needs to be estimated sepa-

rately in the four groups composed of a combination of

urban, rural, rich and poor.The squared sum of residuals in the regressions in Table

4a and Table 4b with and without the constraint of the

identical coe� cients on preference shifts in each residential

group is obtained. Then F-statistics of 0.44 and 0.37 in

Table 4a, and 0.44 and 0.75 in Table 4b are calculated,respectively, for the rural and urban group, accepting the

null of identical coe� cients on preference shifts both

between rich and poor groups and between college gradu-

ates and non-college graduates in both urban and rural

groups. Thus, the constraint is correct and the results ofthe regression with the constraint shown in Table 4a and 4b

are appropriate.4

IV. CONCLUSION

This paper examined the applicability of full insurance in

Japan, using the JPSC which has recently become avail-

able. It was found that the full insurance implication was

rejected for households in the country as a whole, givingthe same result as found for households in the USA by

Cochrane (1991) and McCarthy (1995).

The present paper investigated the diŒerence in the

applicability of full insurance between rich and poor house-

holds, college graduates and non-college graduates, andurban and rural residents. It was found that the rich as

well as the poor were not able to insure consumption

against idiosyncratic income shocks, which was totally dif-

ferent from the result found in the USA where the rich can

insure more su� ciently than the poor. For groups withdiŒerent education levels, it was found that the college

graduates as well as non-college graduates were not able

to insure consumption against their own income shocks.

In contrast, a serious diŒerence in consumption insur-

ance was found between rural and urban groups: full insur-

ance was supported for urban residents but not for rural

residents. Moreover, the urban± rural diŒerence remained

even after the diŒerence in wealth holdings and educationlevels between urban and rural residents was controlled for.

The extended analysis showed that the poor living in rural

areas and the non-college graduates living in rural areas

most seriously suŒer from idiosyncratic income shocks.

The results suggest that the present reallocation policywhich gives subsidies to rural areas from metropolitan

areas might be justi® ed, whereas an income reallocation

from rich households to poor households may not be sup-

ported at least in the sense of consumption insurance. It is

meaningful to take the urban and rural diŒerence seriously

when the reallocation problem in Japan is considered.One remaining problem is that the number of observa-

tions is quite limited in the regressions in the present paper,

especially after splitting the sample into various groups. As

long as alternative individual panel data are not available

in Japan, it is necessary to continue re-analysing the resultsusing the new waves of the JPSC data which will be coming

available for the next eight years.

ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS

The author is grateful to Charles Horioka, Atsushi Maki,

Colin McKenzie, Hajime Miyazaki, Kazuo Ogawa, Fumio

Hayashi, Fumio Ohtake, Makoto Saito and seminar parti-cipants at Ritsumeikan University for helpful comments.

REFERENCES

Attanatio, O. and Davis, S. (1996) Relative wage movements andthe distribution of consumption, Journal of PoliticalEconomy, 104, 1227± 62.

Cochrane, J. (1991) A simple test of consumption insurance,Journal of Political Economy, 99, 957± 76.

Hayashi, F., Altonji, J. and L. KotlikoŒ(1996) Risk sharingbetween and within families, Econometrica, 64, 261± 94.

Institute for Household Economy, Japanese Panel Survey ofConsumers, 1993 and 1994.

King, M. and Leape, J. (1987); Asset accumulation, information,and the life cycle, NBER Working Paper, No. 2392.

Kohara, M. (1997) Consumption insurance between and withinprefectures, unpublished Masters Thesis, Osaka University.

Mace, B. (1991) Full insurance in the presence of aggregate uncer-tainty, Journal of Political Economy, 99, 928± 56.

McCarthy, J. (1995) Imperfect insurance and diŒering propensi-ties to consume across households, Journal of MonetaryEconomics, 36, 301± 27.

Wincoop, E. (1995) Regional risk sharing, European EconomicReview, 37, 1545± 67.

Zeldes, S. (1989) Consumption and liquidity constraints: anempirical investigation, Journal of Political Economy, 97,305± 46.

Consumption insurance 799

4Although the constraint is accepted, the example is split into four groups and regressions conducted relaxing the constraint. It was

found that full insurance was rejected only for poor households living in rural areas and for college graduates and non-college graduatesin rural areas. That is, the urban residents, regardless of wealth and education diŒerence, and the rich rural residents can insure theirconsumption against idiosyncratic income shocks. Note, however, that the power of these tests is low, since the regressions do not use thecorrect information.

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

Geo

rgia

Tec

h L

ibra

ry]

at 1

0:39

15

Nov

embe

r 20

14

Page 11: Consumption insurance between Japanese households

APPENDIX

Consumption and income

For consumption, the total spending of all household

members in September, which is the surveyed month, is

used. In the regressions, its growth rates are used. For

income, the JPSC contains several measures of income,

such as annual (total) income, annual labour income and

monthly labour income. Annual (total) income and annual

labour income include taxes so that the after tax value of

income has to be calculated: the full insurance test requires

one to know how much take-home income a household can

consume. The calculation of an after tax value, however,

reduces the number of observations dramatically since the

number of the observations who respond to question about

annual tax paid in both two years is fairly limited. Hence,

the paper uses after-tax monthly income. The use of

monthly income also has a merit that the periods of earning

and consuming are matched. The mismatch is not prefer-

able because annual income may look too stable relative to

monthly consumption, which underestimates the degree of

applicability of full insurance. For the regressions, the total

income of all household members is summed and its

growth rate computed. For the index of changes in unem-

ployed status, a variable is de® ned which is one if either the

husband or the wife became unemployed from 1993 to

1994, minus one if he/she became employed from 1993 to

1994, and zero otherwise.

Preference shifts

For preference shifts (household’s characteristics), the

average age for the couple, Age, its square term, Age2,

and the household needs, FamilyNeeds which is taken as

the number of family members, are used. In addition, vari-

ables are included which possibly change the pattern of

consumption: whether or not a household has at least

one child of school-year age and whether or not a house-

hold lives with its parents. For the former group, a dummy

variable, Child, is de® ned, which is one if at least one of the

children in the family is of school-year age, and zero other-

wise, and for the latter group, we de® ne a dummy variable,

Parent which equals one if the family lives with at least one

parent, and zero otherwise. The variable Parent is included

because many elderly live with one of their children’s

households in Japan, which could change household’s con-

sumption patterns between households living with and

without the elderly. Although Age and FamilyNeeds are

taken as changes, Child and Parent are taken as levels at

the second survey year since the latter two seem aŒect

consumption path by the level themselves. Descriptive sta-

tistics on the preference shifts are summarized in the table

appendix.

Sample split

JPSC reports the amount of deposits a household holds in

saving accounts and time deposits. A liquid assets variableis computed, summing up those two values for each house-

hold and bonds. To split the sample into the rich and poor

groups, ® rst the ratio of liquid assets is computed to total

annual income. A household with the fraction over one

sixth is split into the rich group and the others into thepoor group. This follows Zeldes (1989) who uses this

split to test for the existence of borrowing constraints. To

split the sample into college graduates and others, informa-

tion is used on whether or not the husband graduated from

a university.For the urban± rural split, the JPSC categorizes the resi-

dential areas into three groups, depending on the size of the

area; the ® rst group is composed of Tokyo plus twelve

ordinance-designated cities,5 the second is composed of

so-called `cities’ , each of which is registered as a city in

the Basic Resident Registers, and the third is composedof other small towns and villages. The ® rst group is de® ned

as metropolitan or urban areas, and the second and the

third groups are merged and de® ned as small-city or

rural areas. The residents in metropolitan areas are

assigned as `urban’ residents throughout this paper sinceall of statistically metropolitan cities in Japan are located in

urban areas. Likewise, residents in small-cities could be

assigned as rural’ residents since many of small cities are

located in rural areas.6 Thus, rural residents designates

sample households living in rural areas throughout Japanand urban residents are those living in urban areas

throughout the country.

800 M. Kohara

Table appendix. Summary of households ’ characteristics used forpreference shifts over full (577) sample

Average of

Age 31.197 (3.567)Family needs 0.037 (0.137)Child 0.901 (0.299)Parent 0.241 (0.428)

Notes: Standard errors are in parentheses; Age is the average ageof the wife and the husband in 1993, family needs is the rate ofchange of the number of family members. Child shows the per-centage of households who have a child over 6 years old. Parentshows the percentage of households who live with their parents.Details of the data are contained in the data appendix.

5The twelve ordinance-designated cities are Sapporo, Sendai, Chiba, Yokohama, Kawasaki, Nagoya, Kyoto, Osaka, Kobe, Hiroshima,

Kita-Kyushu and Fukuoka.6

Note, however, that in reality some small cities are located in urban areas.

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

Geo

rgia

Tec

h L

ibra

ry]

at 1

0:39

15

Nov

embe

r 20

14