commission notice guidelines on the application of article 81 of

41
COMMISSION NOTICE Guidelines on the application of Article 81 of the EC Treaty to technology transfer agreements (2004/C 101/02) (Text with EEA relevance) I. INTRODUCTION 1. These guidelines set out the principles for the assessment of technology transfer agreements under Article 81 of the Treaty. Technology transfer agreements concern the licensing of technology where the licensor permits the licensee to exploit the licensed technology for the production of goods or services, as defined in Article 1(1)(b) of Commission Regulation (EC) No 773/2004 on the application of Article 81(3) of the Treaty to categories of technology transfer agreements (the TTBER) ( 1 ). 2. The purpose of the guidelines is to provide guidance on the application of the TTBER as well as on the application of Article 81 to technology transfer agreements that fall outside the scope of the TTBER. The TTBER and the guidelines are without prejudice to the possible parallel application of Article 82 of the Treaty to licensing agreements ( 2 ). 3. The standards set forth in these guidelines must be applied in light of the circumstances specific to each case. This excludes a mechanical application. Each case must be assessed on its own facts and the guidelines must be applied reasonably and flexibly. Examples given serve as illustrations only and are not intended to be exhaustive. The Commission will keep under review the functioning of the TTBER and the guidelines in the new enforcement system created by Regulation 1/2003 ( 3 ) to consider whether changes need to be made. 4. The present guidelines are without prejudice to the inter- pretation of Article 81 and the TTBER that may be given by the Court of Justice and the Court of First Instance. II. GENERAL PRINCIPLES 1. Article 81 and intellectual property rights 5. The aim of Article 81 as a whole is to protect competition on the market with a view to promoting consumer welfare and an efficient allocation of resources. Article 81(1) prohibits all agreements and concerted practices between undertakings and decisions by associations of undertakings ( 4 ) which may affect trade between Member States ( 5 ) and which have as their object or effect the prevention, restriction or distortion of competition ( 6 ). As an exception to this rule Article 81(3) provides that the prohibition contained in Article 81(1) may be declared inapplicable in the case of agreements between undertakings which contribute to improving the production or distribution of products or to promoting technical or economic progress, while allowing consumers a fair share of the resulting benefits and which do not impose restrictions which are not indispensable to the attainment of these objectives and do not afford such undertakings the possibility of elim- inating competition in respect of a substantial part of the products concerned. 6. Intellectual property laws confer exclusive rights on holders of patents, copyright, design rights, trademarks and other legally protected rights. The owner of intel- lectual property is entitled under intellectual property laws to prevent unauthorised use of his intellectual property and to exploit it, inter alia, by licensing it to third parties. Once a product incorporating an intellectual property right has been put on the market inside the EEA by the holder or with his consent, the intellectual property right is exhausted in the sense that the holder can no longer use it to control the sale of the product ( 7 ) (principle of Community exhaustion). The right holder has no right under intellectual property laws to prevent sales by licensees or buyers of such products incor- porating the licensed technology ( 8 ). The principle of Community exhaustion is in line with the essential function of intellectual property rights, which is to grant the holder the right to exclude others from exploiting his intellectual property without his consent. 7. The fact that intellectual property laws grant exclusive rights of exploitation does not imply that intellectual property rights are immune from competition law inter- vention. Articles 81 and 82 are in particular applicable to agreements whereby the holder licenses another under- taking to exploit his intellectual property rights ( 9 ). Nor does it imply that there is an inherent conflict between intellectual property rights and the Community competition rules. Indeed, both bodies of law share the same basic objective of promoting consumer welfare and an efficient allocation of resources. Innovation constitutes an essential and dynamic component of an open and competitive market economy. Intellectual property rights promote dynamic competition by encouraging undertakings to invest in developing new or improved products and processes. So does competition by putting pressure on undertakings to innovate. Therefore, both intellectual property rights and competition are necessary to promote innovation and ensure a competitive exploitation thereof. EN C 101/2 Official Journal of the European Union 27.4.2004

Upload: others

Post on 12-Sep-2021

1 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: COMMISSION NOTICE Guidelines on the application of Article 81 of

COMMISSION NOTICE

Guidelines on the application of Article 81 of the EC Treaty to technology transfer agreements

(2004/C 101/02)

(Text with EEA relevance)

I. INTRODUCTION

1. These guidelines set out the principles for the assessmentof technology transfer agreements under Article 81 of theTreaty. Technology transfer agreements concern thelicensing of technology where the licensor permits thelicensee to exploit the licensed technology for theproduction of goods or services, as defined in Article1(1)(b) of Commission Regulation (EC) No 773/2004on the application of Article 81(3) of the Treaty tocategories of technology transfer agreements (theTTBER) (1).

2. The purpose of the guidelines is to provide guidance onthe application of the TTBER as well as on theapplication of Article 81 to technology transferagreements that fall outside the scope of the TTBER.The TTBER and the guidelines are without prejudice tothe possible parallel application of Article 82 of theTreaty to licensing agreements (2).

3. The standards set forth in these guidelines must beapplied in light of the circumstances specific to eachcase. This excludes a mechanical application. Each casemust be assessed on its own facts and the guidelines mustbe applied reasonably and flexibly. Examples given serveas illustrations only and are not intended to beexhaustive. The Commission will keep under review thefunctioning of the TTBER and the guidelines in the newenforcement system created by Regulation 1/2003 (3) toconsider whether changes need to be made.

4. The present guidelines are without prejudice to the inter-pretation of Article 81 and the TTBER that may be givenby the Court of Justice and the Court of First Instance.

II. GENERAL PRINCIPLES

1. Article 81 and intellectual property rights

5. The aim of Article 81 as a whole is to protectcompetition on the market with a view to promotingconsumer welfare and an efficient allocation of resources.Article 81(1) prohibits all agreements and concertedpractices between undertakings and decisions byassociations of undertakings (4) which may affect tradebetween Member States (5) and which have as theirobject or effect the prevention, restriction or distortionof competition (6). As an exception to this rule Article81(3) provides that the prohibition contained in Article

81(1) may be declared inapplicable in the case ofagreements between undertakings which contribute toimproving the production or distribution of products orto promoting technical or economic progress, whileallowing consumers a fair share of the resulting benefitsand which do not impose restrictions which are notindispensable to the attainment of these objectives anddo not afford such undertakings the possibility of elim-inating competition in respect of a substantial part of theproducts concerned.

6. Intellectual property laws confer exclusive rights onholders of patents, copyright, design rights, trademarksand other legally protected rights. The owner of intel-lectual property is entitled under intellectual propertylaws to prevent unauthorised use of his intellectualproperty and to exploit it, inter alia, by licensing it tothird parties. Once a product incorporating an intellectualproperty right has been put on the market inside the EEAby the holder or with his consent, the intellectualproperty right is exhausted in the sense that the holdercan no longer use it to control the sale of the product (7)(principle of Community exhaustion). The right holderhas no right under intellectual property laws to preventsales by licensees or buyers of such products incor-porating the licensed technology (8). The principle ofCommunity exhaustion is in line with the essentialfunction of intellectual property rights, which is togrant the holder the right to exclude others fromexploiting his intellectual property without his consent.

7. The fact that intellectual property laws grant exclusiverights of exploitation does not imply that intellectualproperty rights are immune from competition law inter-vention. Articles 81 and 82 are in particular applicable toagreements whereby the holder licenses another under-taking to exploit his intellectual property rights (9). Nordoes it imply that there is an inherent conflict betweenintellectual property rights and the Communitycompetition rules. Indeed, both bodies of law share thesame basic objective of promoting consumer welfare andan efficient allocation of resources. Innovation constitutesan essential and dynamic component of an open andcompetitive market economy. Intellectual propertyrights promote dynamic competition by encouragingundertakings to invest in developing new or improvedproducts and processes. So does competition by puttingpressure on undertakings to innovate. Therefore, bothintellectual property rights and competition arenecessary to promote innovation and ensure acompetitive exploitation thereof.

ENC 101/2 Official Journal of the European Union 27.4.2004

Page 2: COMMISSION NOTICE Guidelines on the application of Article 81 of

8. In the assessment of licence agreements under Article 81it must be kept in mind that the creation of intellectualproperty rights often entails substantial investment andthat it is often a risky endeavour. In order not to reducedynamic competition and to maintain the incentive toinnovate, the innovator must not be unduly restrictedin the exploitation of intellectual property rights thatturn out to be valuable. For these reasons the innovatorshould normally be free to seek compensation forsuccessful projects that is sufficient to maintaininvestment incentives, taking failed projects intoaccount. Technology licensing may also require thelicensee to make significant sunk investments in thelicensed technology and production assets necessary toexploit it. Article 81 cannot be applied withoutconsidering such ex ante investments made by theparties and the risks relating thereto. The risk facingthe parties and the sunk investment that must becommitted may thus lead to the agreement fallingoutside Article 81(1) or fulfilling the conditions ofArticle 81(3), as the case may be, for the period oftime required to recoup the investment.

9. In assessing licensing agreements under Article 81, theexisting analytical framework is sufficiently flexible totake due account of the dynamic aspects of technologylicensing. There is no presumption that intellectualproperty rights and licence agreements as such give riseto competition concerns. Most licence agreements do notrestrict competition and create pro-competitive effi-ciencies. Indeed, licensing as such is pro-competitive asit leads to dissemination of technology and promotesinnovation. In addition, even licence agreements that dorestrict competition may often give rise topro-competitive efficiencies, which must be consideredunder Article 81(3) and balanced against the negativeeffects on competition (10). The great majority of licenceagreements are therefore compatible with Article 81.

2. The general framework for applying Article 81

10. Article 81(1) prohibits agreements which have as theirobject or effect the restriction of competition. Article81(1) applies both to restrictions of competitionbetween the parties to an agreement and to restrictionsof competition between any of the parties and thirdparties.

11. The assessment of whether a licence agreement restrictscompetition must be made within the actual context inwhich competition would occur in the absence of theagreement with its alleged restrictions (11). In makingthis assessment it is necessary to take account of thelikely impact of the agreement on inter-technologycompetition (i.e. competition between undertakingsusing competing technologies) and on intra-technologycompetition (i.e. competition between undertakingsusing the same technology) (12). Article 81(1) prohibitsrestrictions of both inter-technology competition andintra-technology competition. It is therefore necessaryto assess to what extent the agreement affects or islikely to affect these two aspects of competition on themarket.

12. The following two questions provide a useful frameworkfor making this assessment. The first question relates tothe impact of the agreement on inter-technologycompetition while the second question relates to theimpact of the agreement on intra-technologycompetition. As restraints may be capable of affectingboth inter-technology competition and intra-technologycompetition at the same time, it may be necessary toanalyse a restraint in the light of both questions beforeit can be concluded whether or not competition withinthe meaning of Article 81(1) is restricted:

(a) Does the licence agreement restrict actual or potentialcompetition that would have existed without thecontemplated agreement? If so, the agreement maybe caught by Article 81(1). In making this assessmentit is necessary to take into account competitionbetween the parties and competition from thirdparties. For instance, where two undertakings estab-lished in different Member States cross licencecompeting technologies and undertake not to sellproducts in each other's home markets, (potential)competition that existed prior to the agreement isrestricted. Similarly, where a licensor imposes obli-gations on his licensees not to use competing tech-nologies and these obligations foreclose third partytechnologies, actual or potential competition thatwould have existed in the absence of the agreementis restricted.

(b) Does the agreement restrict actual or potentialcompetition that would have existed in the absenceof the contractual restraint(s)? If so, the agreementmay be caught by Article 81(1). For instance, wherea licensor restricts its licensees from competing witheach other, (potential) competition that could haveexisted between the licensees absent the restraints isrestricted. Such restrictions include vertical pricefixing and territorial or customer sales restrictionsbetween licensees. However, certain restraints mayin certain cases not be caught by Article 81(1)when the restraint is objectively necessary for theexistence of an agreement of that type or thatnature (13). Such exclusion of the application ofArticle 81(1) can only be made on the basis ofobjective factors external to the parties themselvesand not the subjective views and characteristics ofthe parties. The question is not whether the partiesin their particular situation would not have acceptedto conclude a less restrictive agreement, but whether,given the nature of the agreement and the charac-teristics of the market, a less restrictive agreementwould not have been concluded by undertakings ina similar setting. For instance, territorial restraints inan agreement between non-competitors may falloutside Article 81(1) for a certain duration if therestraints are objectively necessary for a licensee topenetrate a new market. Similarly, a prohibitionimposed on all licensees not to sell to certaincategories of end users may not be restrictive ofcompetition if such a restraint is objectivelynecessary for reasons of safety or health related tothe dangerous nature of the product in question.

EN27.4.2004 Official Journal of the European Union C 101/3

Page 3: COMMISSION NOTICE Guidelines on the application of Article 81 of

Claims that in the absence of a restraint the supplierwould have resorted to vertical integration are notsufficient. Decisions on whether or not to verticallyintegrate depend on a broad range of complexeconomic factors, a number of which are internalto the undertaking concerned.

13. In the application of the analytical framework set out inthe previous paragraph it must be taken into accountthat Article 81(1) distinguishes between those agreementsthat have a restriction of competition as their object andthose agreements that have a restriction of competitionas their effect. An agreement or contractual restraint isonly prohibited by Article 81(1) if its object or effect is torestrict inter-technology competition and/or intra-tech-nology competition.

14. Restrictions of competition by object are those that bytheir very nature restrict competition. These arerestrictions which in light of the objectives pursued bythe Community competition rules have such a highpotential for negative effects on competition that it isnot necessary for the purposes of applying Article81(1) to demonstrate any actual effects on themarket (14). Moreover, the conditions of Article 81(3)are unlikely to be fulfilled in the case of restrictions byobject. The assessment of whether or not an agreementhas as its object a restriction of competition is based on anumber of factors. These factors include, in particular,the content of the agreement and the objective aimspursued by it. It may also be necessary to consider thecontext in which it is (to be) applied or the actualconduct and behaviour of the parties on the market (15).In other words, an examination of the facts underlyingthe agreement and the specific circumstances in which itoperates may be required before it can be concludedwhether a particular restriction constitutes a hardcorerestriction of competition. The way in which anagreement is actually implemented may reveal arestriction by object even where the formal agreementdoes not contain an express provision to that effect.Evidence of subjective intent on the part of the partiesto restrict competition is a relevant factor but not anecessary condition. For licence agreements, theCommission considers that the restrictions covered bythe list of hardcore restrictions of competitioncontained in Article 4 of the TTBER are restrictive bytheir very object.

15. If an agreement is not restrictive of competition by objectit is necessary to examine whether it has restrictive effectson competition. Account must be taken of both actualand potential effects (16). In other words the agreementmust have likely anti-competitive effects. For licenceagreements to be restrictive of competition by effectthey must affect actual or potential competition to suchan extent that on the relevant market negative effects onprices, output, innovation or the variety or quality ofgoods and services can be expected with a reasonable

degree of probability. The likely negative effects oncompetition must be appreciable (17). Appreciable anti-competitive effects are likely to occur when at least oneof the parties has or obtains some degree of marketpower and the agreement contributes to the creation,maintenance or strengthening of that market power orallows the parties to exploit such market power. Marketpower is the ability to maintain prices above competitivelevels or to maintain output in terms of productquantities, product quality and variety or innovationbelow competitive levels for a not insignificant periodof time. The degree of market power normally requiredfor a finding of an infringement under Article 81(1) isless than the degree of market power required for afinding of dominance under Article 82.

16. For the purposes of analysing restrictions of competitionby effect it is normally necessary to define the relevantmarket and to examine and assess, inter alia, the nature ofthe products and technologies concerned, the marketposition of the parties, the market position ofcompetitors, the market position of buyers, theexistence of potential competitors and the level of entrybarriers. In some cases, however, it may be possible toshow anti-competitive effects directly by analysing theconduct of the parties to the agreement on the market.It may for example be possible to ascertain that anagreement has led to price increases.

17. Licence agreements, however, also have substantialpro-competitive potential. Indeed, the vast majority oflicence agreements are pro-competitive. Licenceagreements may promote innovation by allowinginnovators to earn returns to cover at least part oftheir research and development costs. Licence agreementsalso lead to a dissemination of technologies, which maycreate value by reducing the production costs of thelicensee or by enabling him to produce new orimproved products. Efficiencies at the level of thelicensee often stem from a combination of the licensor'stechnology with the assets and technologies of thelicensee. Such integration of complementary assets andtechnologies may lead to a cost/output configuration thatwould not otherwise be possible. For instance, the combi-nation of an improved technology of the licensor withmore efficient production or distribution assets of thelicensee may reduce production costs or lead to theproduction of a higher quality product. Licensing mayalso serve the pro-competitive purpose of removingobstacles to the development and exploitation of thelicensee's own technology. In particular in sectorswhere large numbers of patents are prevalent licensingoften occurs in order to create design freedom byremoving the risk of infringement claims by thelicensor. When the licensor agrees not to invoke hisintellectual property rights to prevent the sale of thelicensee's products, the agreement removes an obstacleto the sale of the licensee's product and thus generallypromotes competition.

ENC 101/4 Official Journal of the European Union 27.4.2004

Page 4: COMMISSION NOTICE Guidelines on the application of Article 81 of

18. In cases where a licence agreement is caught by Article81(1) the pro-competitive effects of the agreement mustbe balanced against its restrictive effects in the context ofArticle 81(3). When all four conditions of Article 81(3)are satisfied, the restrictive licence agreement in questionis valid and enforceable, no prior decision to that effectbeing required (18). Hardcore restrictions of competitiononly fulfil the conditions of Article 81(3) in exceptionalcircumstances. Such agreements generally fail (at least)one of the first two conditions of Article 81(3). Theygenerally do not create objective economic benefits orbenefits for consumers. Moreover, these types ofagreements generally also fail the indispensability testunder the third condition. For example, if the partiesfix the price at which the products produced under thelicence must be sold, this will generally lead to a loweroutput and a misallocation of resources and higher pricesfor consumers. The price restriction is also not indis-pensable to achieve the possible efficiencies resultingfrom the availability to both competitors of the two tech-nologies.

3. Market definition

19. The Commission's approach to defining the relevantmarket is laid down in its market definitionguidelines (19). The present guidelines only addressaspects of market definition that are of particularimportance in the field of technology licensing.

20. Technology is an input, which is integrated either into aproduct or a production process. Technology licensingcan therefore affect competition both in input marketsand in output markets. For instance, an agreementbetween two parties which sell competing products andwhich cross license technologies relating to theproduction of these products may restrict competitionon the product market concerned. It may also restrictcompetition on the market for technology and possiblyalso on other input markets. For the purposes ofassessing the competitive effects of licence agreementsit may therefore be necessary to define relevant goodsand service markets (product markets) as well as tech-nology markets (20). The term ‘product market’ used inArticle 3 of the TTBER refers to relevant goods andservice markets in both their geographic and productdimension. As is clear from Article 1(1)(j) of theTTBER, the term is used merely to distinguish relevantgoods and service markets from relevant technologymarkets.

21. The TTBER and these guidelines are concerned witheffects both on product markets for final products andon product markets for intermediate products. Therelevant product market includes products which areregarded by the buyers as interchangeable with orsubstitutable for the contract products incorporating the

licensed technology, by reason of the products' charac-teristics, their prices and their intended use.

22. Technology markets consist of the licensed technologyand its substitutes, i.e. other technologies which areregarded by the licensees as interchangeable with orsubstitutable for the licensed technology, by reason ofthe technologies' characteristics, their royalties and theirintended use. The methodology for defining technologymarkets follows the same principles as the definition ofproduct markets. Starting from the technology which ismarketed by the licensor, one needs to identify thoseother technologies to which licensees could switch inresponse to a small but permanent increase in relativeprices, i.e. the royalties. An alternative approach is tolook at the market for products incorporating thelicensed technology (cf. paragraph below).

23. Once relevant markets have been defined, market sharescan be assigned to the various sources of competition inthe market and used as an indication of the relativestrength of market players. In the case of technologymarkets one way to proceed is to calculate marketshares on the basis of each technology's share of totallicensing income from royalties, representing a tech-nology's share of the market where competing tech-nologies are licensed. However, this may often be amere theoretical and not a practical way to proceedbecause of lack of clear information on royalties etc.An alternative approach, which is the one used inArticle 3(3) of the TTBER, is to calculate market shareson the technology market on the basis of sales ofproducts incorporating the licensed technology on down-stream product markets (see paragraph 70 below). Underthis approach all sales on the relevant product market aretaken into account, irrespective of whether the productincorporates a technology that is being licensed. In thecase of technology markets the approach of Article 3(3)to take into account technologies that are (only) beingused in-house, is justified. Indeed, this approach is ingeneral a good indicator of the strength of the tech-nology. First, it captures any potential competitionfrom undertakings that are producing with their owntechnology and that are likely to start licensing in theevent of a small but permanent increase in the price forlicenses. Secondly, even where it is unlikely that othertechnology owners would start licensing, the licensordoes not necessarily have market power on the tech-nology market even if he has a high share of licensingincome. If the downstream product market iscompetitive, competition at this level may effectivelyconstrain the licensor. An increase in royalties upstreamaffects the costs of the licensee, making him lesscompetitive, causing him to lose sales. A technology'smarket share on the product market also captures thiselement and is thus normally a good indicator of licensormarket power. In individual cases outside the safeharbour of the TTBER it may be necessary, wherepractically possible, to apply both of the describedapproaches in order to assess more accurately themarket strength of the licensor.

EN27.4.2004 Official Journal of the European Union C 101/5

Page 5: COMMISSION NOTICE Guidelines on the application of Article 81 of

24. Moreover, outside the safe harbour of the TTBER it mustalso be taken into account that market share may notalways be a good indication of the relative strength ofavailable technologies. The Commission will therefore,inter alia, also have regard to the number of inde-pendently controlled technologies available in additionto the technologies controlled by the parties to theagreement that may be substitutable for the licensed tech-nology at a comparable cost to the user (see paragraph131 below).

25. Some licence agreements may affect innovation markets.In analysing such effects, however, the Commission willnormally confine itself to examining the impact of theagreement on competition within existing product andtechnology markets (21). Competition on such marketsmay be affected by agreements that delay the intro-duction of improved products or new products thatover time will replace existing products. In such casesinnovation is a source of potential competition whichmust be taken into account when assessing the impactof the agreement on product markets and technologymarkets. In a limited number of cases, however, it maybe useful and necessary to also define innovationmarkets. This is particularly the case where theagreement affects innovation aiming at creating newproducts and where it is possible at an early stage toidentify research and development poles (22). In suchcases it can be analysed whether after the agreementthere will be a sufficient number of competing researchand development poles left for effective competition ininnovation to be maintained.

4. The distinction between competitors and non-competitors

26. In general, agreements between competitors pose agreater risk to competition than agreements betweennon-competitors. However, competition between under-takings that use the same technology (intra-technologycompetition between licensees) constitutes an importantcomplement to competition between undertakings thatuse competing technologies (inter-technologycompetition). For instance, intra-technology competitionmay lead to lower prices for the products incorporatingthe technology in question, which may not only producedirect and immediate benefits for consumers of theseproducts, but also spur further competition betweenundertakings that use competing technologies. In thecontext of licensing it must also be taken into accountthat licensees are selling their own product. They are notre-selling a product supplied by another undertaking.There may thus be greater scope for product differ-entiation and quality-based competition betweenlicensees than in the case of vertical agreements for theresale of products.

27. In order to determine the competitive relationshipbetween the parties it is necessary to examine whetherthe parties would have been actual or potentialcompetitors in the absence of the agreement. If withoutthe agreement the parties would not have been actual orpotential competitors in any relevant market affected bythe agreement they are deemed to be non-competitors.

28. Where the licensor and the licensee are both active onthe same product market or the same technology marketwithout one or both parties infringing the intellectualproperty rights of the other party, they are actualcompetitors on the market concerned. The parties aredeemed to be actual competitors on the technologymarket if the licensee is already licensing out his tech-nology and the licensor enters the technology market bygranting a license for a competing technology to thelicensee.

29. The parties are considered to be potential competitors onthe product market if in the absence of the agreementand without infringing the intellectual property rights ofthe other party it is likely that they would haveundertaken the necessary additional investment to enterthe relevant market in response to a small but permanentincrease in product prices. In order to constitute arealistic competitive constraint entry has to be likely tooccur within a short period. Normally a period of one totwo years is appropriate. However, in individual caseslonger periods can be taken into account. The periodof time needed for undertakings already on the marketto adjust their capacities can be used as a yardstick todetermine this period. For instance, the parties are likelyto be considered potential competitors on the productmarket where the licensee produces on the basis of itsown technology in one geographic market and startsproducing in another geographic market on the basisof a licensed competing technology. In such circum-stances, it is likely that the licensee would have beenable to enter the second geographic market on thebasis of its own technology, unless such entry isprecluded by objective factors, including the existenceof blocking patents (see paragraph 32 below).

30. The parties are considered to be potential competitors onthe technology market where they own substitutabletechnologies if in the specific case the licensee is notlicensing his own technology, provided that he wouldbe likely to do so in the event of a small butpermanent increase in technology prices. However, forthe application of the TTBER potential competition onthe technology market is not taken into account (seeparagraph 66 below).

ENC 101/6 Official Journal of the European Union 27.4.2004

Page 6: COMMISSION NOTICE Guidelines on the application of Article 81 of

31. In some cases the parties may become competitorssubsequent to the conclusion of the agreement becausethe licensee develops and starts exploiting a competingtechnology. In such cases it must be taken into accountthat the parties were non-competitors at the time ofconclusion of the agreement and that the agreementwas concluded in that context. The Commission willtherefore mainly focus on the impact of the agreementon the licensee's ability to exploit his own (competing)technology. In particular, the list of hardcore restrictionsapplying to agreements between competitors will not beapplied to such agreements unless the agreement issubsequently amended in any material respect after theparties have become competitors (cf. Article 4(3) of theTTBER). The undertakings party to an agreement mayalso become competitors subsequent to the conclusionof the agreement where the licensee was already activeon the product market prior to the licence and where thelicensor subsequently enters the product market either onthe basis of the licensed technology or a new technology.Also in this case the hardcore list relevant for agreementsbetween non-competitors will continue to apply to theagreement unless the agreement is subsequently amendedin any material respect (cf. article 4(3) of the TTBER.

32. If the parties own technologies that are in a one-way ortwo-way blocking position, the parties are considered tobe non-competitors on the technology market. Aone-way blocking position exists when a technologycannot be exploited without infringing upon anothertechnology. This is for instance the case where onepatent covers an improvement of a technology coveredby another patent. In that case the exploitation of theimprovement patent pre-supposes that the holder obtainsa licence to the basic patent. A two-way blockingposition exists where neither technology can beexploited without infringing upon the other technologyand where the holders thus need to obtain a licence or awaiver from each other. In assessing whether a blockingposition exists the Commission will rely on objectivefactors as opposed to the subjective views of theparties. Particularly convincing evidence of the existenceof a blocking position is required where the parties mayhave a common interest in claiming the existence of ablocking position in order to be qualified asnon-competitors, for instance where the claimedtwo-way blocking position concerns technologies thatare technological substitutes. Relevant evidence includescourt decisions including injunctions and opinions ofindependent experts. In the latter case the Commissionwill, in particular, closely examine how the expert hasbeen selected. However, also other convincing evidence,including expert evidence from the parties that they haveor had good and valid reasons to believe that a blockingposition exists or existed, can be relevant to substantiatethe existence of a blocking position.

33. In some cases it may also be possible to conclude thatwhile the licensor and the licensee produce competingproducts, they are non-competitors on the relevant

product market and the relevant technology marketbecause the licensed technology represents such adrastic innovation that the technology of the licenseehas become obsolete or uncompetitive. In such casesthe licensor's technology either creates a new market orexcludes the licensee's technology from the market.Often, however, it is not possible to come to thisconclusion at the time the agreement is concluded. It isusually only when the technology or the products incor-porating it have been available to consumers for sometime that it becomes apparent that the older technologyhas become obsolete or uncompetitive. For instance,when CD technology was developed and players anddiscs were put on the market, it was not obvious thatthis new technology would replace LP technology. Thisonly became apparent some years later. The parties willtherefore be considered to be competitors if at the timeof the conclusion of the agreement it is not obvious thatthe licensee's technology is obsolete or uncompetitive.However, given that both Articles 81(1) and Article81(3) must be applied in light of the actual context inwhich the agreement occurs, the assessment is sensitiveto material changes in the facts. The classification of therelationship between the parties will therefore changeinto a relationship of non-competitors, if at a laterpoint in time the licensee's technology becomesobsolete or uncompetitive on the market.

III. APPLICATION OF THE BLOCK EXEMPTION REGULATION

1. The effects of the Block Exemption Regulation

34. Technology transfer agreements that fulfil the conditionsset out in the TTBER are block exempted from theprohibition rule contained in Article 81(1). Blockexempted agreements are legally valid and enforceable.Such agreements can only be prohibited for the futureand only upon withdrawal of the block exemption by theCommission or a Member State competition authority.Block exempted agreements cannot be prohibited underArticle 81 by national courts in the context of privatelitigation.

35. Block exemption of categories of technology transferagreements is based on the presumption that suchagreements — to the extent that they are caught byArticle 81(1) — fulfil the four conditions laid down inArticle 81(3). It is thus presumed that the agreementsgive rise to economic efficiencies, that the restrictionscontained in the agreements are indispensable to theattainment of these efficiencies, that consumers withinthe affected markets receive a fair share of the efficiencygains and that the agreements do not afford the under-takings concerned the possibility of eliminating

EN27.4.2004 Official Journal of the European Union C 101/7

Page 7: COMMISSION NOTICE Guidelines on the application of Article 81 of

competition in respect of a substantial part of theproducts in question. The market share thresholds(Article 3), the hardcore list (Article 4) and theexcluded restrictions (Article 5) set out in the TTBERaim at ensuring that only restrictive agreements thatcan reasonably be presumed to fulfil the four conditionsof Article 81(3) are block exempted.

36. As set out in section IV below, many licence agreementsfall outside Article 81(1), either because they do notrestrict competition at all or because the restriction ofcompetition is not appreciable (23). To the extent thatsuch agreements would anyhow fall within the scope ofthe TTBER, there is no need to determine whether theyare caught by Article 81(1) (24).

37. Outside the scope of the block exemption it is relevant toexamine whether in the individual case the agreement iscaught by Article 81(1) and if so whether the conditionsof Article 81(3) are satisfied. There is no presumptionthat technology transfer agreements falling outside theblock exemption are caught by Article 81(1) or fail tosatisfy the conditions of Article 81(3). In particular, themere fact that the market shares of the parties exceed themarket share thresholds set out in Article 3 of the TTBERis not a sufficient basis for finding that the agreement iscaught by Article 81(1). Individual assessment of thelikely effects of the agreement is required. It is onlywhen agreements contain hardcore restrictions ofcompetition that it can normally be presumed that theyare prohibited by Article 81.

2. Scope and duration of the Block Exemption Regulation

2.1. Agreements between two parties

38. According to Article 2(1) of the TTBER, the Regulationcovers technology transfer agreements ‘between twoundertakings’. Technology transfer agreements betweenmore than two undertakings are not covered by theTTBER (25). The decisive factor in terms of distinguishingbetween agreements between two undertakings andmultiparty agreements is whether the agreement inquestion is concluded between more than two under-takings.

39. Agreements concluded by two undertakings fall withinthe scope of the TTBER even if the agreement stipulatesconditions for more than one level of trade. For instance,the TTBER applies to a licence agreement concerning notonly the production stage but also the distribution stage,stipulating the obligations that the licensee must or mayimpose on resellers of the products produced under thelicence (26).

40. Licence agreements concluded between more than twoundertakings often give rise to the same issues aslicence agreements of the same nature concludedbetween two undertakings. In its individual assessmentof licence agreements which are of the same nature asthose covered by the block exemption but which areconcluded between more than two undertakings, theCommission will apply by analogy the principles setout in the TTBER.

2.2. Agreements for the production of contract products

41. It follows from Article 2 that for licence agreements to becovered by the TTBER they must concern ‘the productionof contract products’, i.e. products incorporating orproduced with the licensed technology. In other words,to be covered by the TTBER the licence must permit thelicensee to exploit the licensed technology for productionof goods or services (see recital 7 of the TTBER). TheTTBER does not cover technology pools. The notion oftechnology pools covers agreements whereby two ormore parties agree to pool their respective technologiesand license them as a package. The notion of technologypools also covers arrangements whereby two or moreundertakings agree to license a third party andauthorise him to license on the package of technologies.Technology pools are dealt with in section IV.4 below.

42. The TTBER applies to licence agreements for theproduction of contract products whereby the licensee isalso permitted to sublicense the licensed technology tothird parties provided, however, that the production ofcontract products constitutes the primary object of theagreement. Conversely, the TTBER does not apply toagreements that have sublicensing as their primaryobject. However, the Commission will apply by analogythe principles set out in the TTBER and these guidelinesto such ‘master licensing’ agreements between licensorand licensee. Agreements between the licensee andsub-licensees are covered by the TTBER.

43. The term ‘contract products’ encompasses goods andservices produced with the licensed technology. This isthe case both where the licensed technology is used inthe production process and where it is incorporated intothe product itself. In these guidelines the term ‘productsincorporating the licensed technology’ covers bothsituations. The TTBER applies in all cases where tech-nology is licensed for the purposes of producing goodsand services. It is sufficient in this respect that thelicensor undertakes not to exercise his intellectualproperty rights against the licensee. Indeed, the essenceof a pure patent licence is the right to operate inside thescope of the exclusive right of the patent. It follows thatthe TTBER also covers so-called non-assertion agreementsand settlement agreements whereby the licensor permitsthe licensee to produce within the scope of the patent.

ENC 101/8 Official Journal of the European Union 27.4.2004

Page 8: COMMISSION NOTICE Guidelines on the application of Article 81 of

44. The TTBER covers ‘subcontracting’ whereby the licensorlicenses technology to the licensee who undertakes toproduce certain products on the basis thereof exclusivelyfor the licensor. Subcontracting may also involve thesupply of equipment by the licensor to be used in theproduction of the goods and services covered by theagreement. For the latter type of subcontracting to becovered by the TTBER, the licensed technology and notthe supplied equipment must constitute the primaryobject of the agreement. Subcontracting is also coveredby the Commission's Notice concerning the assessment ofcertain subcontracting agreements in relation to Article81(1) of the Treaty (27). According to this notice, whichremains applicable, subcontracting agreements wherebythe subcontractor undertakes to produce certainproducts exclusively for the contractor generally falloutside Article 81(1). However, other restrictionsimposed on the subcontractor such as the obligationnot to conduct or exploit his own research and devel-opment may be caught by Article 81 (28).

45. The TTBER also applies to agreements whereby thelicensee must carry out development work beforeobtaining a product or a process that is ready forcommercial exploitation, provided that a contractproduct has been identified. Even if such further workand investment is required, the object of the agreement isthe production of an identified contract product. On theother hand, the TTBER and the guidelines do not coveragreements whereby a technology is licensed for thepurpose of enabling the licensee to carry out furtherresearch and development in various fields. Forinstance, the TTBER and the guidelines do not coverthe licensing of a technological research tool used inthe process of further research activity. The frameworkof the TTBER and the guidelines is based on the premisethat there is a direct link between the licensed technologyand an identified contract product. In cases where nosuch link exists the main object of the agreement isresearch and development as opposed to bringing aparticular product to the market; in that case theanalytical framework of the TTBER and the guidelinesmay not be appropriate. For the same reasons theTTBER and the guidelines do not cover research anddevelopment sub-contracting whereby the licenseeundertakes to carry out research and development inthe field of the licensed technology and to hand backthe improved technology package to the licensor. Themain object of such agreements is the provision ofresearch and development services aimed at improvingthe technology as opposed to the production of goodsand services on the basis of the licensed technology.

2.3. The concept of technology transfer agreements

46. The TTBER and these guidelines cover agreements for thetransfer of technology. According to Article 1(1)(b) and(h) of the TTBER the concept of ‘technology’ coverspatents and patent applications, utility models and

applications for utility models, design rights, plantbreeders rights, topographies of semiconductorproducts, supplementary protection certificates formedicinal products or other products for which suchsupplementary protection certificates may be obtained,software copyright, and know-how. The licensed tech-nology should allow the licensee with or without otherinputs to produce the contract products.

47. Know-how is defined in Article 1(1)(i) as a package ofnon-patented practical information, resulting fromexperience and testing, which is secret, substantial andidentified. ‘Secret’ means that the know-how is notgenerally known or easily accessible. ‘Substantial’ meansthat the know-how includes information which issignificant and useful for the production of theproducts covered by the licence agreement or theapplication of the process covered by the licenceagreement. In other words, the information mustsignificantly contribute to or facilitate the production ofthe contract products. In cases where the licensedknow-how relates to a product as opposed to aprocess, this condition implies that the know-how isuseful for the production the contract product. Thiscondition is not satisfied where the contract productcan be produced on the basis of freely available tech-nology. However, the condition does not require thatthe contract product is of higher value than productsproduced with freely available technology. In the caseof process technologies, this condition implies that theknow-how is useful in the sense that it can reasonably beexpected at the date of conclusion of the agreement to becapable of significantly improving the competitiveposition of the licensee, for instance by reducing hisproduction costs. ‘Identified’ means that it is possible toverify that the licensed know-how fulfils the criteria ofsecrecy and substantiality. This condition is satisfiedwhere the licensed know-how is described in manualsor other written form. However, in some cases thismay not be reasonably possible. The licensedknow-how may consist of practical knowledgepossessed by the licensor's employees. For instance, thelicensor's employees may possess secret and substantialknowledge about a certain production process which ispassed on to the licensee in the form of training of thelicensee's employees. In such cases it is sufficient todescribe in the agreement the general nature of theknow-how and to list the employees that will be orhave been involved in passing it on to the licensee.

48. The concept of ‘transfer’ implies that technology mustflow from one undertaking to another. Such transfersnormally take the form of licensing whereby thelicensor grants the licensee the right to use his tech-nology against payment of royalties. It can also takethe form of sub-licensing, whereby a licensee, havingbeen authorised to do so by the licensor, grantslicenses to third parties (sub-licensees) for the exploitationof the technology.

EN27.4.2004 Official Journal of the European Union C 101/9

Page 9: COMMISSION NOTICE Guidelines on the application of Article 81 of

49. The TTBER only applies to agreements that have as theirprimary object the transfer of technology as defined inthat Regulation as opposed to the purchase of goods andservices or the licensing of other types of intellectualproperty. Agreements containing provisions relating tothe purchase and sale of products are only covered bythe TTBER to the extent that those provisions do notconstitute the primary object of the agreement and aredirectly related to the application of the licensed tech-nology. This is likely to be the case where the tiedproducts take the form of equipment or process inputwhich is specifically tailored to efficiently exploit thelicensed technology. If, on the other hand, the productis simply another input into the final product, it must becarefully examined whether the licensed technologyconstitutes the primary object of the agreement. Forinstance, in cases where the licensee is already manufac-turing a final product on the basis of another technology,the licence must lead to a significant improvement of thelicensee's production process, exceeding the value of theproduct purchased from the licensor. The requirementthat the tied products must be related to the licensingof technology implies that the TTBER does not cover thepurchase of products that have no relation with theproducts incorporating the licensed technology. This isfor example the case where the tied product is notintended to be used with the licensed product, butrelates to an activity on a separate product market.

50. The TTBER only covers the licensing of other types ofintellectual property such as trademarks and copyright,other than software copyright, to the extent that they aredirectly related to the exploitation of the licensed tech-nology and do not constitute the primary object of theagreement. This condition ensures that agreementscovering other types of intellectual property rights areonly block exempted to the extent that these other intel-lectual property rights serve to enable the licensee tobetter exploit the licensed technology. The licensor mayfor instance authorise the licensee to use his trademarkon the products incorporating the licensed technology.The trademark licence may allow the licensee to betterexploit the licensed technology by allowing consumers tomake an immediate link between the product and thecharacteristics imputed to it by the licensed technology.An obligation on the licensee to use the licensor'strademark may also promote the dissemination of tech-nology by allowing the licensor to identify himself as thesource of the underlying technology. However, where thevalue of the licensed technology to the licensee is limitedbecause he already employs an identical or very similartechnology and the main object of the agreement is thetrademark, the TTBER does not apply (29).

51. The licensing of copyright for the purpose of repro-duction and distribution of the protected work, i.e. theproduction of copies for resale, is considered to besimilar to technology licensing. Since such licenceagreements relate to the production and sale of

products on the basis of an intellectual property right,they are considered to be of a similar nature as tech-nology transfer agreements and normally raisecomparable issues. Although the TTBER does not covercopyright other than software copyright, the Commissionwill as a general rule apply the principles set out in theTTBER and these guidelines when assessing suchlicensing of copyright under Article 81.

52. On the other hand, the licensing of rights inperformances and other rights related to copyright isconsidered to raise particular issues and it may not bewarranted to assess such licensing on the basis of theprinciples developed in these guidelines. In the case ofthe various rights related to performances value is creatednot by the reproduction and sale of copies of a productbut by each individual performance of the protectedwork. Such exploitation can take various formsincluding the performance, showing or the renting ofprotected material such as films, music or sportingevents. In the application of Article 81 the specificitiesof the work and the way in which it is exploited must betaken into account (30). For instance, resale restrictionsmay give rise to less competition concerns whereasparticular concerns may arise where licensors imposeon their licensees to extend to each of the licensorsmore favourable conditions obtained by one of them.The Commission will therefore not apply the TTBERand the present guidelines by way of analogy to thelicensing of these other rights.

53. The Commission will also not extend the principlesdeveloped in the TTBER and these guidelines totrademark licensing. Trademark licensing often occursin the context of distribution and resale of goods andservices and is generally more akin to distributionagreements than technology licensing. Where atrademark licence is directly related to the use, sale orresale of goods and services and does not constitute theprimary object of the agreement, the licence agreement iscovered by Commission Regulation (EC) No 2790/1999on the application of Article 81(3) of the Treaty tocategories of vertical agreements and concertedpractices (31).

2.4. Duration

54. Subject to the duration of the TTBER, the blockexemption applies for as long as the licensed propertyright has not lapsed, expired or been declared invalid. Inthe case of know-how the block exemption applies aslong as the licensed know-how remains secret, exceptwhere the know-how becomes publicly known as aresult of action by the licensee, in which case theexemption shall apply for the duration of theagreement (cf. Article 2 of the TTBER).

ENC 101/10 Official Journal of the European Union 27.4.2004

Page 10: COMMISSION NOTICE Guidelines on the application of Article 81 of

55. The block exemption applies to each licensed propertyright covered by the agreement and ceases to apply onthe date of expiry, invalidity or the coming into thepublic domain of the last intellectual property rightwhich constitutes ‘technology’ within the meaning ofthe TTBER (cf. paragraph above).

2.5. Relationship with other block exemption regulations

56. The TTBER covers agreements between two undertakingsconcerning the licensing of technology for the purpose ofthe production of contract products. However, tech-nology can also be an element of other types ofagreements. In addition, the products incorporating thelicensed technology are subsequently sold on the market.It is therefore necessary to address the interface betweenthe TTBER and Commission Regulation (EC) No2658/2000 on the application of Article 81(3) of theTreaty to categories of specialisation agreements (32),Commission Regulation 2659/2000 on the applicationof Article 81(3) to categories of research and devel-opment agreements (33) and Commission Regulation(EC) No 2790/1999 on the application of Article 81(3)of the Treaty to categories of vertical agreements andconcerted practices (34).

2.5.1. The Block Exemption Regulations on specialisation and R&Dagreements

57. According to Article 1(1)(c) of Regulation 2658/2000 onspecialisation agreements, that Regulation covers, interalia, joint production agreements by virtue of whichtwo or more undertakings agree to produce certainproducts jointly. The Regulation extends to provisionsconcerning the assignment or use of intellectualproperty rights, provided that they do not constitutethe primary object of the agreement, but are directlyrelated to and necessary for its implementation.

58. Where undertakings establish a production joint ventureand license the joint venture to exploit technology, whichis used in the production of the products produced bythe joint venture, such licensing is subject to Regulation2658/2000 and not the TTBER. Accordingly, licensing inthe context of a production joint venture normally fallsto be considered under Regulation 2658/2000. However,where the joint venture engages in licensing of the tech-nology to third parties, the activity is not linked toproduction by the joint venture and therefore notcovered by that Regulation. Such licensing arrangements,which bring together the technologies of the parties,constitute technology pools, which are dealt with insection IV.4 below.

59. Regulation 2659/2000 on research and developmentagreements covers agreements whereby two or moreundertakings agree to jointly carry out research anddevelopment and to jointly exploit the results thereof.According to Article 2(11), research and developmentand the exploitation of the results are carried outjointly where the work involved is carried out by a

joint team, organisation or undertakings, jointly entrustedto a third party or allocated between the parties by wayof specialisation in research, development, productionand distribution, including licensing.

60. It follows that Regulation 2659/2000 covers licensingbetween the parties and by the parties to a joint entityin the context of a research and development agreement.In the context of such agreements the parties can alsodetermine the conditions for licensing the fruits of theresearch and development agreement to third parties.However, since third party licensees are not party tothe research and development agreement, the individuallicence agreement concluded with third parties is notcovered by Regulation 2659/2000. Such licenceagreements are block exempted by the TTBER wherethey fulfil the conditions of that Regulation.

2.5.2. The Block Exemption Regulation on vertical agreements

61. Commission Regulation (EC) No 2790/1999 on verticalagreements covers agreements entered into between twoor more undertakings each operating, for the purposes ofthe agreement, at different levels of the production ordistribution chain, and relating to the conditions underwhich the parties may purchase, sell or resell certaingoods or services. It thus covers supply and distributionagreements (35).

62. Given that the TTBER only covers agreements betweentwo parties and that a licensee, selling products incor-porating the licensed technology, is a supplier for thepurposes of Regulation 2790/1999, these two blockexemption regulations are closely related. Theagreement between licensor and licensee is subject tothe TTBER whereas agreements concluded between alicensee and buyers are subject to Regulation2790/1999 and the Guidelines on Vertical Restraints (36).

63. The TTBER also block exempts agreements between thelicensor and the licensee where the agreement imposesobligations on the licensee as to the way in which hemust sell the products incorporating the licensed tech-nology. In particular, the licensee can be obliged toestablish a certain type of distribution system such asexclusive distribution or selective distribution. However,the distribution agreements concluded for the purposesof implementing such obligations must, in order to be

EN27.4.2004 Official Journal of the European Union C 101/11

Page 11: COMMISSION NOTICE Guidelines on the application of Article 81 of

block exempted, comply with Regulation 2790/1999. Forinstance, the licensor can oblige the licensee to establish asystem based on exclusive distribution in accordance withspecified rules. However, it follows from Article 4(b) ofRegulation 2790/1999 that distributors must be free tomake passive sales into the territories of other exclusivedistributors.

64. Furthermore, distributors must in principle be free to sellboth actively and passively into territories covered by thedistribution systems of other licensees producing theirown products on the basis of the licensed technology.This is because for the purposes of Regulation2790/1999 each licensee is a separate supplier.However, the reasons underlying the block exemptioncontained in that Regulation may also apply where theproducts incorporating the licensed technology are soldby the licensees under a common brand belonging to thelicensor. When the products incorporating the licensedtechnology are sold under a common brand identitythere may be the same efficiency reasons for applyingthe same types of restraints between licensees'distribution systems as within a single verticaldistribution system. In such cases the Commissionwould be unlikely to challenge restraints where byanalogy the requirements of Regulation 2790/1999 arefulfilled. For a common brand identity to exist theproducts must be sold and marketed under a commonbrand, which is predominant in terms of conveyingquality and other relevant information to the consumer.It does not suffice that in addition to the licensees' brandsthe product carries the licensor's brand, which identifieshim as the source of the licensed technology.

3. The safe harbour established by the Block ExemptionRegulation

65. According to Article 3 of the TTBER the blockexemption of restrictive agreements is subject to marketshare thresholds, confining the scope of the blockexemption to agreements that although they may berestrictive of competition can generally be presumed tofulfil the conditions of Article 81(3). Outside the safeharbour created by the market share thresholds individualassessment is required. The fact that market shares exceedthe thresholds does not give rise to any presumptioneither that the agreement is caught by Article 81(1) orthat the agreement does not fulfil the conditions ofArticle 81(3). In the absence of hardcore restrictions,market analysis is required.

66. The market share threshold to be applied for the purposeof the safe harbour of the TTBER depends on whetherthe agreement is concluded between competitors ornon-competitors. For the purposes of the TTBER under-takings are competitors on the relevant technologymarket when they license competing technologies.Potential competition on the technology market is not

taken into account for the application of the marketshare threshold or the hardcore list. Outside the safeharbour of the TTBER potential competition on the tech-nology market is taken into account but does not lead tothe application of the hardcore list relating to agreementsbetween competitors (see also paragraph 31 above).

67. Undertakings are competitors on the relevant productmarket where both undertakings are active on the sameproduct and geographic market(s) on which the productsincorporating the licensed technology are sold (actualcompetitors). They are also considered competitorswhere they would be likely, on realistic grounds, toundertake the necessary additional investments or othernecessary switching costs to enter the relevant productand geographic market(s) within a reasonably shortperiod of time (37) in response to a small andpermanent increase in relative prices (potentialcompetitors).

68. It follows from paragraphs 66 and 67 that two under-takings are not competitors for the purposes of theTTBER where the licensor is neither an actual nor apotential supplier of products on the relevant marketand the licensee, already present on the productmarket, is not licensing out a competing technologyeven if he owns a competing technology and produceson the basis of that technology. However, the partiesbecome competitors if at a later point in time thelicensee starts licensing out his technology or thelicensor becomes an actual or potential supplier ofproducts on the relevant market. In that case thehardcore list relevant for agreements betweennon-competitors will continue to apply to theagreement unless the agreement is subsequentlyamended in any material respect, see Article 4(3) of theTTBER and paragraph 31 above.

69. In the case of agreements between competitors themarket share threshold is 20 % and in the case ofagreements between non-competitors it is 30 % (cf.Article 3(1) and (2) of the TTBER). Where the under-takings party to the licensing agreement are notcompetitors the agreement is covered if the marketshare of neither party exceeds 30 % on the affectedrelevant technology and product markets. Where theundertakings party to the licensing agreement arecompetitors the agreement is covered if the combinedmarket shares of the parties do not exceed 20 % on therelevant technology and product markets. The marketshare thresholds apply both to technology markets andmarkets for products incorporating the licensed tech-nology. If the applicable market share threshold isexceeded on an affected relevant market, the blockexemption does not apply to the agreement for thatrelevant market. For instance, if the licence agreementconcerns two separate product markets or two separategeographic markets, the block exemption may apply toone of the markets and not to the other.

ENC 101/12 Official Journal of the European Union 27.4.2004

Page 12: COMMISSION NOTICE Guidelines on the application of Article 81 of

70. In the case of technology markets, it follows from Article3(3) of the TTBER that the licensor's market share is tobe calculated on the basis of the sales of the licensor andall his licensees of products incorporating the licensedtechnology and this for each relevant market sepa-rately (38). Where the parties are competitors on the tech-nology market, sales of products incorporating thelicensee's own technology must be combined with thesales of the products incorporating the licensed tech-nology. In the case of new technologies that have notyet generated any sales, a zero market share is assigned.When sales commence the technology will start accumu-lating market share.

71. In the case of product markets, the licensee's marketshare is to be calculated on the basis of the licensee'ssales of products incorporating the licensor's technologyand competing products, i.e. the total sales of the licenseeon the product market in question. Where the licensor isalso a supplier of products on the relevant market, thelicensor's sales on the product market in question mustalso be taken into account. In the calculation of marketshares for product markets, however, sales made by otherlicensees are not taken into account when calculating thelicensee's and/or licensor's market share.

72. Market shares should be calculated on the basis of salesvalue data where such data are available. Such datanormally provide a more accurate indication of thestrength of a technology than volume data. However,where value based data are not available, estimatesbased on other reliable market information may beused, including market sales volume data.

73. The principles set out above can be illustrated by thefollowing examples:

Licensing between non-competitors

Example 1

Company A is specialised in developing bio-tech-nological products and techniques and hasdeveloped a new product Xeran. It is not active as aproducer of Xeran, for which it has neither theproduction nor the distribution facilities. Company Bis one of the producers of competing products,produced with freely available non-proprietary tech-nologies. In year 1, B was selling EUR 25 millionworth of products produced with the freely availabletechnologies. In year 2, A gives a licence to B toproduce Xeran. In that year B sells EUR 15 millionproduced with the help of the freely available tech-nologies and EUR 15 million of Xeran. In year 3 andthe following years B produces and sells only Xeranworth EUR 40 million annually. In addition in year 2,A is also licensing to C. C was not active on thatproduct market before. C produces and sells onlyXeran, EUR 10 million in year 2 and EUR 15million in year 3 and thereafter. It is establishedthat the total market of Xeran and its substituteswhere B and C are active is worth EUR 200 millionin each year.

In year 2, the year the licence agreement is concluded,A's market share on the technology market is 0 % asits market share has to be calculated on the basis ofthe total sales of Xeran in the preceding year. In year3 A's market share on the technology market is12,5 %, reflecting the value of Xeran produced by Band C in the preceding year 2. In year 4 andthereafter A's market share on the technologymarket is 27,5 %, reflecting the value of Xeranproduced by B and C in the preceding year.

In year 2 B's market share on the product market is12,5 %, reflecting B's EUR 25 million sales in year 1.In year 3 B's market share is 15 % because its saleshave increased to EUR 30 million in year 2. In year 4and thereafter B's market share is 20 % as its sales areEUR 40 million annually. C's market share on theproduct market is 0 % in year 1 and 2, 5 % in year3 and 7, 5 % thereafter.

As the licence agreements are betweennon-competitors and the individual market shares ofA, B and C are below 30 % each year, the agreementsfall within the safe harbour of the TTBER.

EN27.4.2004 Official Journal of the European Union C 101/13

Page 13: COMMISSION NOTICE Guidelines on the application of Article 81 of

Example 2

The situation is the same as in example 1, howevernow B and C are operating in different geographicmarkets. It is established that the total market ofXeran and its substitutes is worth EUR 100 millionannually in each geographic market.

In this case, A's market share on the technologymarket has to be calculated for each of the twogeographic markets. In the market where B is activeA's market share depends on the sale of Xeran by B.As in this example the total market is assumed to beEUR 100 million, i.e. half the size of the market inexample 1, the market share of A is 0 % in year 2,15 % in year 3 and 40 % thereafter. B's market shareis 25 % in year 2, 30 % in year 3 and 40 % thereafter.In year 2 and 3 both A's and B's market share doesnot exceed the 30 % threshold. The threshold ishowever exceeded from year 4 and this means that,in line with Article 8(2) of the TTBER, after year 6 thelicence agreement between A and B can no longerbenefit from the safe harbour but has to be assessedon an individual basis.

In the market where C is active A's market sharedepends on the sale of Xeran by C. A's marketshare on the technology market, based on C's salesin the previous year, is therefore 0 % in year 2, 10 %in year 3 and 15 % thereafter. The market share of Con the product market is the same: 0 % in year 2,10 % in year 3 and 15 % thereafter. The licenceagreement between A and C therefore falls withinthe safe harbour for the whole period.

Licensing between competitors

Example 3

Companies A and B are active on the same relevantproduct and geographic market for a certain chemicalproduct. They also each own a patent on differenttechnologies used to produce this product. In year 1A and B sign a cross licence agreement licensing eachother to use their respective technologies. In year 1 Aand B produce only with their own technology and Asells EUR 15 million of the product and B sellsEUR 20 million of the product. From year 2 theyboth use their own and the other's technology.From that year onward A sells EUR 10 million ofthe product produced with its own technology andEUR 10 million of the product produced with B'stechnology. B sells from year 2 EUR 15 million ofthe product produced with its own technology andEUR 10 million of the product produced with A'stechnology. It is established that the total market ofthe product and its substitutes is worth EUR 100million in each year.

To assess the licence agreement under the TTBER, themarket shares of A and B have to be calculated bothon the technology market and the product market.The market share of A on the technology marketdepends on the amount of the product sold in thepreceding year that was produced, by both A and B,with A's technology. In year 2 the market share of Aon the technology market is therefore 15 %, reflectingits own production and sales of EUR 15 million inyear 1. From year 3 A's market share on the tech-nology market is 20 %, reflecting the EUR 20 millionsale of the product produced with A's technology andproduced and sold by A and B (EUR 10 million each).Similarly, in year 2 B's market share on the tech-nology market is 20 % and thereafter 25 %.

The market shares of A and B on the product marketdepend on their respective sales of the product in theprevious year, irrespective of the technology used. Themarket share of A on the product market is 15 % inyear 2 and 20 % thereafter. The market share of B onthe product market is 20 % in year 2 and 25 %thereafter.

As the agreement is between competitors, theircombined market share, both on the technology andon the product market, has to be below the 20 %market share threshold in order to benefit from thesafe harbour. It is clear that this is not the case here.The combined market share on the technology marketand on the product market is 35 % in year 2 and45 % thereafter. This agreement between competitorswill therefore have to be assessed on an individualbasis.

4. Hardcore restrictions of competition under the BlockExemption Regulation

4.1. General principles

74. Article 4 of the TTBER contains a list of hardcorerestrictions of competition. The classification of arestraint as a hardcore restriction of competition isbased on the nature of the restriction and experienceshowing that such restrictions are almost always anti-competitive. In line with the case law of theCommunity Courts (39) such a restriction may resultfrom the clear objective of the agreement or from thecircumstances of the individual case (cf. paragraph 14above).

ENC 101/14 Official Journal of the European Union 27.4.2004

Page 14: COMMISSION NOTICE Guidelines on the application of Article 81 of

75. When a technology transfer agreement contains ahardcore restriction of competition, it follows fromArticle 4(1) and 4(2) of the TTBER that the agreementas a whole falls outside the scope of the block exemption.For the purposes of the TTBER hardcore restrictionscannot be severed from the rest of the agreement.Moreover, the Commission considers that in thecontext of individual assessment hardcore restrictions ofcompetition will only in exceptional circumstances fulfilthe four conditions of Article 81(3) (cf. paragraph 18above).

76. Article 4 of the TTBER distinguishes between agreementsbetween competitors and agreements betweennon-competitors.

4.2. Agreements between competitors

77. Article 4(1) lists the hardcore restrictions for licensingbetween competitors. According to Article 4(1), theTTBER does not cover agreements which, directly orindirectly, in isolation or in combination with otherfactors under the control of the parties, have as theirobject:

(a) The restriction of a party's ability to determine itsprices when selling products to third parties;

(b) The limitation of output, except limitations on theoutput of contract products imposed on thelicensee in a non-reciprocal agreement or imposedon only one of the licensees in a reciprocalagreement;

(c) The allocation of markets or customers except

(i) the obligation on the licensee(s) to produce withthe licensed technology only within one or moretechnical fields of use or one or more productmarkets;

(ii) the obligation on the licensor and/or thelicensee, in a non-reciprocal agreement, not toproduce with the licensed technology within oneor more technical fields of use or one or moreproduct markets or one or more exclusive terri-tories reserved for the other party;

(iii) the obligation on the licensor not to license thetechnology to another licensee in a particularterritory;

(iv) the restriction, in a non-reciprocal agreement, ofactive and/or passive sales by the licensee and/or

the licensor into the exclusive territory or to theexclusive customer group reserved for the otherparty;

(v) the restriction, in a non-reciprocal agreement, ofactive sales by the licensee into the exclusiveterritory or to the exclusive customer groupallocated by the licensor to another licenseeprovided that the latter was not a competingundertaking of the licensor at the time of theconclusion of its own licence;

(vi) the obligation on the licensee to produce thecontract products only for its own useprovided that the licensee is not restricted inselling the contract products actively andpassively as spare parts for its own products;

(vii) the obligation on the licensee in anon-reciprocal agreement to produce thecontract products only for a particularcustomer, where the licence was granted inorder to create an alternative source of supplyfor that customer;

(d) The restriction of the licensee's ability to exploit itsown technology or the restriction of the ability of anyof the parties to the agreement to carry out researchand development, unless such latter restriction isindispensable to prevent the disclosure of thelicensed know-how to third parties.

78. For a number of hardcore restrictions the TTBER makes adistinction between reciprocal and non-reciprocalagreements. The hardcore list is stricter for reciprocalagreements than for non-reciprocal agreements betweencompetitors. Reciprocal agreements are cross-licensingagreements where the licensed technologies arecompeting technologies or can be used for theproduction of competing products. A non-reciprocalagreement is an agreement where only one of theparties is licensing its technology to the other party orwhere in case of cross-licensing the licensed technologiesare not competing technologies and cannot be used forthe production of competing products. An agreement isnot reciprocal merely because the agreement contains agrant back obligation or because the licensee licensesback own improvements of the licensed technology. Incase at a later point in time a non-reciprocal agreementbecomes a reciprocal agreement due to the conclusion ofa second licence between the same parties, they may haveto revise the first licence in order to avoid that theagreement contains a hardcore restriction. In theassessment of the individual case the Commission willtake into account the time lapsed between the conclusionof the first and the second licence.

EN27.4.2004 Official Journal of the European Union C 101/15

Page 15: COMMISSION NOTICE Guidelines on the application of Article 81 of

79. The hardcore restriction of competition contained inArticle 4(1)(a) concerns agreements between competitorsthat have as their object the fixing of prices for productssold to third parties, including the products incorporatingthe licensed technology. Price fixing between competitorsconstitutes a restriction of competition by its very object.Price fixing can for instance take the form of a directagreement on the exact price to be charged or on a pricelist with certain allowed maximum rebates. It is imma-terial whether the agreement concerns fixed, minimum,maximum or recommended prices. Price fixing can alsobe implemented indirectly by applying disincentives todeviate from an agreed price level, for example, byproviding that the royalty rate will increase if productprices are reduced below a certain level. However, anobligation on the licensee to pay a certain minimumroyalty does not in itself amount to price fixing.

80. When royalties are calculated on the basis of individualproduct sales, the amount of the royalty has a directimpact on the marginal cost of the product and thus adirect impact on product prices (40). Competitors cantherefore use cross licensing with reciprocal runningroyalties as a means of co-ordinating prices on down-stream product markets (41). However, the Commissionwill only treat cross licences with reciprocal runningroyalties as price fixing where the agreement is devoidof any pro-competitive purpose and therefore does notconstitute a bona fide licensing arrangement. In suchcases where the agreement does not create any valueand therefore has no valid business justification, thearrangement is a sham and amounts to a cartel.

81. The hardcore restriction contained in Article 4(1)(a) alsocovers agreements whereby royalties are calculated on thebasis of all product sales irrespective of whether thelicensed technology is being used. Such agreements arealso caught by Article 4(1)(d) according to which thelicensee must not be restricted in his ability to use hisown technology (see paragraph 95 below). In generalsuch agreements restrict competition since theagreement raises the cost of using the licensee's owncompeting technology and restricts competition thatexisted in the absence of the agreement (42). This is soboth in the case of reciprocal and non-reciprocalarrangements. Exceptionally, however, an agreementwhereby royalties are calculated on the basis of allproduct sales may fulfil the conditions of Article 81(3)in an individual case where on the basis of objectivefactors it can be concluded that the restriction is indis-pensable for pro-competitive licensing to occur. This maybe the case where in the absence of the restraint it wouldbe impossible or unduly difficult to calculate and monitorthe royalty payable by the licensee, for instance becausethe licensor's technology leaves no visible trace on thefinal product and practicable alternative monitoringmethods are unavailable.

82. The hardcore restriction of competition set out in Article4(1)(b) concerns reciprocal output restrictions on theparties. An output restriction is a limitation on howmuch a party may produce and sell. Article 4(1)(b)does not cover output limitations on the licensee in anon-reciprocal agreement or output limitations on one ofthe licensees in a reciprocal agreement provided that theoutput limitation only concerns products produced withthe licensed technology. Article 4(1)(b) thus identifies ashardcore restrictions reciprocal output restrictions on theparties and output restrictions on the licensor in respectof his own technology. When competitors agree toimpose reciprocal output limitations, the object andlikely effect of the agreement is to reduce output in themarket. The same is true of agreements that reduce theincentive of the parties to expand output, for example byobliging each other to make payments if a certain level ofoutput is exceeded.

83. The more favourable treatment of non-reciprocalquantity limitations is based on the consideration that aone-way restriction does not necessarily lead to a loweroutput on the market while also the risk that theagreement is not a bona fide licensing arrangement isless when the restriction is non-reciprocal. When alicensee is willing to accept a one-way restriction, it islikely that the agreement leads to a real integration ofcomplementary technologies or an efficiency enhancingintegration of the licensor's superior technology with thelicensee's productive assets. In a reciprocal agreement anoutput restriction on one of the licensees is likely toreflect the higher value of the technology licensed byone of the parties and may serve to promotepro-competitive licensing.

84. The hardcore restriction of competition set out in Article4(1)(c) concerns the allocation of markets and customers.Agreements whereby competitors share markets andcustomers have as their object the restriction ofcompetition. It is a hardcore restriction wherecompetitors in a reciprocal agreement agree not toproduce in certain territories or not to sell activelyand/or passively into certain territories or to certaincustomers reserved for the other party.

85. Article 4(1)(c) applies irrespective of whether the licenseeremains free to use his own technology. Once thelicensee has tooled up to use the licensor's technologyto produce a given product, it may be costly to maintaina separate production line using another technology inorder to serve customers covered by the restrictions.Moreover, given the anti-competitive potential of therestraint the licensee may have little incentive toproduce under his own technology. Such restrictionsare also highly unlikely to be indispensable forpro-competitive licensing to occur.

ENC 101/16 Official Journal of the European Union 27.4.2004

Page 16: COMMISSION NOTICE Guidelines on the application of Article 81 of

86. Under Article 4(1)(c)(ii) it is not a hardcore restriction forthe licensor in a non-reciprocal agreement to grant thelicensee an exclusive licence to produce on the basis ofthe licensed technology in a particular territory and thusagree not to produce himself the contract products in orprovide the contract products from that territory. Suchexclusive licences are block exempted irrespective of thescope of the territory. If the licence is world-wide, theexclusivity implies that the licensor abstains fromentering or remaining on the market. The blockexemption also applies where the licence is limited toone or more technical fields of use or one or moreproduct markets. The purpose of agreements coveredby Article 4(1)(c)(ii) may be to give the licensee anincentive to invest in and develop the licensed tech-nology. The object of the agreement is therefore notnecessarily to share markets.

87. According to Article 4(1)(c)(iv) and for the same reason,the block exemption also applies to non-reciprocalagreements whereby the parties agree not to sellactively or passively (43) into an exclusive territory or toan exclusive customer group reserved for the other party.

88. According to Article 4(1)(c)(iii) it is also not a hardcorerestriction if the licensor appoints the licensee as his solelicensee in a particular territory, implying that thirdparties will not be licensed to produce on the basis ofthe licensor's technology in the territory in question. Inthe case of such sole licences the block exemption appliesirrespective of whether the agreement is reciprocal or notgiven that the agreement does not affect the ability of theparties to fully exploit their own technology in therespective territories.

89. Article 4(1)(c)(v) excludes from the hardcore list and thusblock exempts up to the market share thresholdrestrictions in a non-reciprocal agreement on activesales by a licensee into the territory or to the customergroup allocated by the licensor to another licensee. It is acondition, however, that the protected licensee was not acompetitor of the licensor when the agreement wasconcluded. It is not warranted to hardcore suchrestrictions. By allowing the licensor to grant a licensee,who was not already on the market, protection againstactive sales by licensees which are competitors of thelicensor and which for that reason are already establishedon the market, such restrictions are likely to induce thelicensee to exploit the licensed technology moreefficiently. On the other hand, if the licensees agreebetween themselves not to sell actively or passively intocertain territories or to certain customer groups, theagreement amounts to a cartel amongst the licensees.Given that such agreements do not involve any transferof technology they fall outside the scope of the TTBER.

90. According to Article 4(1)(c)(i) restrictions in agreementsbetween competitors that limit the licence to one ormore product markets or technical fields of use (44) arenot hardcore restrictions. Such restrictions are blockexempted up to the market share threshold of 20 %irrespective of whether the agreement is reciprocal ornot. It is a condition for the application of the blockexemption, however, that the field of use restrictionsdo not go beyond the scope of the licensed technologies.It is also a condition that licensees are not limited in theuse of their own technology (see Article 4(1)(d)). Wherelicensees are limited in the use of their own technologythe agreement amounts to market sharing.

91. The block exemption applies irrespective of whether thefield of use restriction is symmetrical or asymmetrical. Anasymmetrical field of use restriction in a reciprocallicence agreement implies that both parties are allowedto use the respective technologies that they license inonly within different fields of use. As long as theparties are unrestricted in the use of their own tech-nologies, it is not assumed that the agreement leads theparties to abandon or refrain from entering the field(s)covered by the licence to the other party. Even if thelicensees tool up to use the licensed technology withinthe licensed field of use, there may be no impact onassets used to produce outside the scope of the licence.It is important in this regard that the restriction relates todistinct product markets or fields of use and not tocustomers, allocated by territory or by group, whopurchase products falling within the same productmarket or technical field of use. The risk of marketsharing is considered substantially greater in the lattercase (see paragraph 85 above). In addition, field of userestrictions may be necessary to promote pro-competitivelicensing (see paragraph 182 below).

92. Article 4(1)(c)(vi) contains a further exception, namelycaptive use restrictions, i.e. a requirement whereby thelicensee may produce the products incorporating thelicensed technology only for his own use. Where thecontract product is a component the licensee can thusbe obliged to produce that component only for incor-poration into his own products and can be obliged not tosell the components to other producers. The licenseemust be able, however, to sell the components as spareparts for his own products and must thus be able tosupply third parties that perform after sale services onthese products. Captive use restrictions as defined may benecessary to encourage the dissemination of technology,particularly between competitors, and are covered by theblock exemption. Such restrictions are also dealt with insection IV.2.5 below.

EN27.4.2004 Official Journal of the European Union C 101/17

Page 17: COMMISSION NOTICE Guidelines on the application of Article 81 of

93. Finally, Article 4(1)(c)(vii) excludes from the hardcore listan obligation on the licensee in a non-reciprocalagreement to produce the contract products only for aparticular customer with a view to creating an alternativesource of supply for that customer. It is thus a conditionfor the application of Article 4(1)(c)(vii) that the licence islimited to creating an alternative source of supply for thatparticular customer. It is not a condition, however, thatonly one such licence is granted. Article 4(1)(c)(vii) alsocovers situations where more than one undertaking islicensed to supply the same specified customer. Thepotential of such agreements to share markets is limitedwhere the licence is granted only for the purpose ofsupplying a particular customer. In particular, in suchcircumstances it cannot be assumed that the agreementwill cause the licensee to cease exploiting his own tech-nology.

94. The hardcore restriction of competition set out in Article4(1)(d) covers firstly restrictions on any of the parties'ability to carry out research and development. Bothparties must be free to carry out independent researchand development. This rule applies irrespective ofwhether the restriction applies to a field covered by thelicence or to other fields. However, the mere fact that theparties agree to provide each other with futureimprovements of their respective technologies does notamount to a restriction on independent research anddevelopment. The effect on competition of suchagreements must be assessed in light of the circumstancesof the individual case. Article 4(1)(d) also does not extendto restrictions on a party to carry out research and devel-opment with third parties, where such restriction isnecessary to protect the licensor's know-how againstdisclosure. In order to be covered by the exception, therestrictions imposed to protect the licensor's know-howagainst disclosure must be necessary and proportionate toensure such protection. For instance, where theagreement designates particular employees of thelicensee to be trained in and responsible for the use ofthe licensed know-how, it may be sufficient to oblige thelicensee not to allow those employees to be involved inresearch and development with third parties. Othersafeguards may be equally appropriate.

95. According to Article 4(1)(d) the licensee must also beunrestricted in the use of his own competing technologyprovided that in so doing he does not make use of thetechnology licensed from the licensor. In relation to hisown technology the licensee must not be subject to limi-tations in terms of where he produces or sells, how muchhe produces or sells and at what price he sells. He mustalso not be obliged to pay royalties on products producedon the basis of his own technology (cf. paragraph 81above). Moreover, the licensee must not be restricted inlicensing his own technology to third parties. When

restrictions are imposed on the licensee's use of hisown technology or to carry out research and devel-opment, the competitiveness of the licensee's technologyis reduced. The effect of this is to reduce competition onexisting product and technology markets and to reducethe licensee's incentive to invest in the development andimprovement of his technology.

4.3. Agreements between non-competitors

96. Article 4(2) lists the hardcore restrictions for licensingbetween non-competitors. According to this provision,the TTBER does not cover agreements which, directlyor indirectly, in isolation or in combination with otherfactors under the control of the parties, have as theirobject:

(a) the restriction of a party's ability to determine itsprices when selling products to third parties,without prejudice to the possibility to impose amaximum sale price or recommend a sale price,provided that it does not amount to a fixed orminimum sale price as a result of pressure from, orincentives offered by, any of the parties;

(b) the restriction of the territory into which, or of thecustomers to whom, the licensee may passively sellthe contract products, except:

(i) the restriction of passive sales into an exclusiveterritory or to an exclusive customer groupreserved for the licensor;

(ii) the restriction of passive sales into an exclusiveterritory or to an exclusive customer groupallocated by the licensor to another licenseeduring the first two years that this otherlicensee is selling the contract products in thatterritory or to that customer group;

(iii) the obligation to produce the contract productsonly for its own use provided that the licensee isnot restricted in selling the contract productsactively and passively as spare parts for its ownproducts;

(iv) the obligation to produce the contract productsonly for a particular customer, where the licencewas granted in order to create an alternativesource of supply for that customer;

ENC 101/18 Official Journal of the European Union 27.4.2004

Page 18: COMMISSION NOTICE Guidelines on the application of Article 81 of

(v) the restriction of sales to end users by a licenseeoperating at the wholesale level of trade;

(vi) the restriction of sales to unauthoriseddistributors by the members of a selectivedistribution system;

(c) the restriction of active or passive sales to end usersby a licensee which is a member of a selectivedistribution system and which operates at the retaillevel, without prejudice to the possibility ofprohibiting a member of the system from operatingout of an unauthorised place of establishment.

97. The hardcore restriction of competition set out in Article4(2)(a) concerns the fixing of prices charged when sellingproducts to third parties. More specifically, this provisioncovers restrictions which have as their direct or indirectobject the establishment of a fixed or a minimum sellingprice or a fixed or minimum price level to be observedby the licensor or the licensee when selling products tothird parties. In the case of agreements that directlyestablish the selling price, the restriction is clear-cut.However, the fixing of selling prices can also beachieved through indirect means. Examples of the latterare agreements fixing the margin, fixing the maximumlevel of discounts, linking the sales price to the salesprices of competitors, threats, intimidation, warnings,penalties, or contract terminations in relation toobservance of a given price level. Direct or indirectmeans of achieving price fixing can be made moreeffective when combined with measures to identify price-cutting, such as the implementation of a price moni-toring system, or the obligation on licensees to reportprice deviations. Similarly, direct or indirect price fixingcan be made more effective when combined withmeasures that reduce the licensee's incentive to lowerhis selling price, such as the licensor obliging thelicensee to apply a most-favoured-customer clause, i.e.an obligation to grant to a customer any more favourableterms granted to any other customer. The same meanscan be used to make maximum or recommended priceswork as fixed or minimum selling prices. However, theprovision of a list of recommended prices to or theimposition of a maximum price on the licensee by thelicensor is not considered in itself as leading to fixed orminimum selling prices.

98. Article 4(2)(b) identifies as hardcore restrictions ofcompetition agreements or concerted practices thathave as their direct or indirect object the restriction ofpassive sales by licensees of products incorporating thelicensed technology (45). Passive sales restrictions on thelicensee may be the result of direct obligations, such asthe obligation not to sell to certain customers or tocustomers in certain territories or the obligation torefer orders from these customers to other licensees. It

may also result from indirect measures aimed at inducingthe licensee to refrain from making such sales, such asfinancial incentives and the implementation of a moni-toring system aimed at verifying the effective destinationof the licensed products. Quantity limitations may be anindirect means to restrict passive sales. The Commissionwill not assume that quantity limitations as such servethis purpose. However, it will be otherwise wherequantity limitations are used to implement an underlyingmarket partitioning agreement. Indications thereofinclude the adjustment of quantities over time to coveronly local demand, the combination of quantity limi-tations and an obligation to sell minimum quantities inthe territory, minimum royalty obligations linked to salesin the territory, differentiated royalty rates depending onthe destination of the products and the monitoring of thedestination of products sold by individual licensees. Thegeneral hardcore restriction covering passive sales bylicensees is subject to a number of exceptions, whichare dealt with below.

99. Article 4(2)(b) does not cover sales restrictions on thelicensor. All sales restrictions on the licensor are blockexempted up to the market share threshold of 30 %. Thesame applies to all restrictions on active sales by thelicensee, with the exception of what is said on activeselling in paragraphs 105 and 106 below. The blockexemption of restrictions on active selling is based onthe assumption that such restrictions promoteinvestments, non-price competition and improvementsin the quality of services provided by the licensees bysolving free rider problems and hold-up problems. Inthe case of restrictions of active sales between licensees'territories or customer groups, it is not a condition thatthe protected licensee has been granted an exclusiveterritory or an exclusive customer group. The blockexemption also applies to active sales restrictions wheremore than one licensee has been appointed for aparticular territory or customer group. Efficiencyenhancing investment is likely to be promoted where alicensee can be ensured that he will only face active salescompetition from a limited number of licensees insidethe territory and not also from licensees outside theterritory.

100. Restrictions on active and passive sales by licensees intoan exclusive territory or to an exclusive customer groupreserved for the licensor do not constitute hardcorerestrictions of competition (cf. Article 4(2)(b)(i)). Indeed,they are block exempted. It is presumed that up to themarket share threshold such restraints, where restrictiveof competition, promote pro-competitive disseminationof technology and integration of such technology intothe production assets of the licensee. For a territory orcustomer group to be reserved for the licensor, it is notrequired that the licensor is actually producing with thelicensed technology in the territory or for the customergroup in question. A territory or customer group canalso be reserved by the licensor for later exploitation.

EN27.4.2004 Official Journal of the European Union C 101/19

Page 19: COMMISSION NOTICE Guidelines on the application of Article 81 of

101. Restrictions on passive sales by licensees into an exclusiveterritory or customer group allocated to another licenseeare block exempted for two years calculated from thedate on which the protected licensee first markets theproducts incorporating the licensed technology insidehis exclusive territory or to his exclusive customergroup (cf. Article 4(2)(b)(ii)). Licensees often have tocommit substantial investments in production assetsand promotional activities in order to start up anddevelop a new territory. The risks facing the newlicensee are therefore likely to be substantial, in particularsince promotional expenses and investment in assetsrequired to produce on the basis of a particular tech-nology are often sunk, i.e. they cannot be recovered ifthe licensee exits the market. In such circumstances, it isoften the case that licensees would not enter into thelicence agreement without protection for a certainperiod of time against (active and) passive sales intotheir territory by other licensees. Restrictions on passivesales into the exclusive territory of a licensee by otherlicensees therefore often fall outside Article 81(1) for aperiod of up to two years from the date on which theproduct incorporating the licensed technology was firstput on the market in the exclusive territory by thelicensee in question. However, to the extent that in indi-vidual cases such restrictions are caught by Article 81(1)they are block exempted. After the expiry of thistwo-year period restrictions on passive sales betweenlicensees constitute hardcore restrictions. Suchrestrictions are generally caught by Article 81(1) andare unlikely to fulfil the conditions of Article 81(3). Inparticular, passive sales restrictions are unlikely to beindispensable for the attainment of efficiencies (46).

102. Article 4(2)(b)(iii) brings under the block exemption arestriction whereby the licensee is obliged to produceproducts incorporating the licensed technology only forhis own (captive) use. Where the contract product is acomponent the licensee can thus be obliged to use thatproduct only for incorporation into his own productsand can be obliged not to sell the product to otherproducers. The licensee must however be able toactively and passively sell the products as spare partsfor his own products and must thus be able to supplythird parties that perform after sale services on theseproducts. Captive use restrictions are also dealt with insection IV.2.5 below.

103. As in the case of agreements between competitors (cf.paragraph 93 above) the block exemption also appliesto agreements whereby the licensee is obliged toproduce the contract products only for a particularcustomer in order to provide that customer with an alter-native source of supply (cf. Article 4(2)(b)(iv)). In the caseof agreements between non-competitors, such restrictionsare unlikely to be caught by Article 81(1).

104. Article 4(2)(b)(v) brings under the block exemption anobligation on the licensee not to sell to end users andthus only to sell to retailers. Such an obligation allowsthe licensor to assign the wholesale distribution functionto the licensee and normally falls outside Article81(1) (47).

105. Finally Article 4(2)(b)(vi) brings under the blockexemption a restriction on the licensee not to sell tounauthorised distributors. This exception allows thelicensor to impose on the licensees an obligation toform part of a selective distribution system. In thatcase, however, the licensees must according to Article4(2)(c) be permitted to sell both actively and passivelyto end users, without prejudice to the possibility torestrict the licensee to a wholesale function as foreseenin Article 4(2)(b)(v) (cf. the previous paragraph).

106. It is recalled (cf. paragraph 39 above) that the blockexemption covers licence agreements whereby thelicensor imposes obligations which the licensee must ormay impose on his buyers, including distributors.However, these obligations must comply with thecompetition rules applicable to supply and distributionagreements. Since the TTBER is limited to agreementsbetween two parties the agreements concluded betweenthe licensee and his buyers implementing such obli-gations are not covered by the TTBER. Such agreementsare only block exempted when they comply with Regu-lation 2790/1999 (cf. section 2.5.2 above).

5. Excluded restrictions

107. Article 5 of the TTBER lists four types of restrictions thatare not block exempted and which thus require indi-vidual assessment of their anti-competitive andpro-competitive effects. It follows from Article 5 thatthe inclusion in a licence agreement of any of therestrictions contained in these provisions does notprevent the application of the block exemption to therest of the agreement. It is only the individual restrictionin question that is not block exempted, implying thatindividual assessment is required. Accordingly, the ruleof severability applies to the restrictions set out inArticle 5.

108. Article 5(1) provides that the block exemption shall notapply to the following three obligations:

(a) Any direct or indirect obligation on the licensee togrant an exclusive licence to the licensor or to a thirdparty designated by the licensor in respect of its ownseverable improvements to or its new applications ofthe licensed technology.

ENC 101/20 Official Journal of the European Union 27.4.2004

Page 20: COMMISSION NOTICE Guidelines on the application of Article 81 of

(b) Any direct or indirect obligation on the licensee toassign to the licensor or to a third party designatedby the licensor rights to severable improvements toor new applications of the licensed technology.

(c) Any direct or indirect obligation on the licensee notto challenge the validity of intellectual property rightsheld by the licensor in the common market.However, the TTBER does cover the possibility forthe licensor to terminate the licence agreement inthe event that the licensee challenges the validity ofthe licensed technology.

The purpose of Article 5(1)(a), (b) and (c) is to avoidblock exemption of agreements that may reduce theincentive of licensees to innovate.

109. Article 5(1)(a) and 5(1)(b) concerns exclusive grant backsor assignments to the licensor of severable improvementsof the licensed technology. An improvement is severableif it can be exploited without infringing upon the licensedtechnology. An obligation to grant the licensor anexclusive licence to severable improvements of thelicensed technology or to assign such improvements tothe licensor is likely to reduce the licensee's incentive toinnovate since it hinders the licensee in exploiting hisimprovements, including by way of licensing to thirdparties. This is the case both where the severableimprovement concerns the same application as thelicensed technology and where the licensee developsnew applications of the licensed technology. Accordingto Article 5(1)(a) and (b) such obligations are not blockexempted. However, the block exemption does covernon-exclusive grant back obligations in respect ofseverable improvements. This is so even where thegrant back obligation is non-reciprocal, i.e. onlyimposed on the licensee, and where under theagreement the licensor is entitled to feed-on theseverable improvements to other licensees. Anon-reciprocal grant back obligation may promote inno-vation and the dissemination of new technology bypermitting the licensor to freely determine whether andto what extent to pass on his own improvements to hislicensees. A feed-on clause may also promote the dissemi-nation of technology because each licensee knows at thetime of contracting that he will be on an equal footingwith other licensees in terms of the technology on thebasis of which he is producing. Exclusive grant backs andobligations to assign non-severable improvements are notrestrictive of competition within the meaning of Article81(1) since non-severable improvements cannot beexploited by the licensee without the licensor'spermission.

110. The application of Article 5(1)(a) and (b) does not dependon whether or not the licensor pays consideration in

return for acquiring the improvement or for obtaining anexclusive licence. However, the existence and level ofsuch consideration may be a relevant factor in thecontext of an individual assessment under Article 81.When grant backs are made against consideration it isless likely that the obligation creates a disincentive for thelicensee to innovate. In the assessment of exclusive grantbacks outside the scope of the block exemption themarket position of the licensor on the technologymarket is also a relevant factor. The stronger theposition of the licensor, the more likely it is thatexclusive grant back obligations will have restrictiveeffects on competition in innovation. The stronger theposition of the licensor's technology the more likely itis that the licensee will be an important source of inno-vation and future competition. The negative impact ofgrant back obligations can also be increased in case ofparallel networks of licence agreements containing suchobligations. When available technologies are controlledby a limited number of licensors that impose exclusivegrant back obligations on licensees, the risk of anti-competitive effects is greater than where there are anumber of technologies only some of which arelicensed on exclusive grant back terms.

111. The risk of negative effects on innovation is higher in thecase of cross licensing between competitors where agrant back obligation on both parties is combined withan obligation on both parties to share with the otherparty improvements of his own technology. Thesharing of all improvements between competitors mayprevent each competitor from gaining a competitivelead over the other (see also paragraph 208 below).However, the parties are unlikely to be prevented fromgaining a competitive lead over each other where thepurpose of the licence is to permit them to developtheir respective technologies and where the licence doesnot lead them to use the same technological base in thedesign of their products. This is the case where thepurpose of the licence is to create design freedomrather than to improve the technological base of thelicensee.

112. The excluded restriction set out in Article 5(1)(c)concerns non-challenge clauses, i.e. obligations not tochallenge the validity of the licensor's intellectualproperty. The reason for excluding non-challengeclauses from the scope of the block exemption is thefact that licensees are normally in the best position todetermine whether or not an intellectual property right isinvalid. In the interest of undistorted competition and inconformity with the principles underlying the protectionof intellectual property, invalid intellectual property rightsshould be eliminated. Invalid intellectual property stiflesinnovation rather than promoting it. Article 81(1) islikely to apply to non-challenge clauses where thelicensed technology is valuable and therefore creates acompetitive disadvantage for undertakings that are

EN27.4.2004 Official Journal of the European Union C 101/21

Page 21: COMMISSION NOTICE Guidelines on the application of Article 81 of

prevented from using it or are only able to use it againstpayment of royalties (48). In such cases the conditions ofArticle 81(3) are unlikely to be fulfilled (49). However, theCommission takes a favourable view of non-challengeclauses relating to know-how where once disclosed it islikely to be impossible or very difficult to recover thelicensed know-how. In such cases, an obligation on thelicensee not to challenge the licensed know-howpromotes dissemination of new technology, in particularby allowing weaker licensors to license stronger licenseeswithout fear of a challenge once the know-how has beenabsorbed by the licensee.

113. The TTBER covers the possibility for the licensor toterminate the licence agreement in the event of achallenge of the licensed technology. Accordingly, thelicensor is not forced to continue dealing with alicensee that challenges the very subject matter of thelicence agreement, implying that upon termination anyfurther use by the licensee of the challenged technologyis at the challenger's own risk. Article 5(1)(c) ensures,however, that the TTBER does not cover contractual obli-gations obliging the licensee not to challenge the licensedtechnology, which would permit the licensor to sue thelicensee for breach of contract and thereby create afurther disincentive for the licensee to challenge thevalidity of the licensor's technology. The provisionthereby ensures that the licensee is in the sameposition as third parties.

114. Article 5(2) excludes from the scope of the blockexemption, in the case of agreements betweennon-competitors, any direct or indirect obligationlimiting the licensee's ability to exploit his own tech-nology or limiting the ability of the parties to theagreement to carry out research and development,unless such latter restriction is indispensable to preventthe disclosure of licensed know-how to third parties. Thecontent of this condition is the same as that of Article4(1)(d) of the hardcore list concerning agreementsbetween competitors, which is dealt with in paragraphs94 and 95 above. However, in the case of agreementsbetween non-competitors it cannot be considered thatsuch restrictions generally have negative effects oncompetition or that the conditions of Article 81(3) aregenerally not satisfied (50). Individual assessment isrequired.

115. In the case of agreements between non-competitors, thelicensee normally does not own a competing technology.

However, there may be cases where for the purposes ofthe block exemption the parties are considerednon-competitors in spite of the fact that the licenseedoes own a competing technology. This is the casewhere the licensee owns a technology but does notlicense it and the licensor is not an actual or potentialsupplier on the product market. For the purposes of theblock exemption the parties are in such circumstancesneither competitors on the technology market norcompetitors on the product market (51). In such cases itis important to ensure that the licensee is not restrictedin his ability to exploit his own technology and furtherdevelop it. This technology constitutes a competitiveconstraint in the market, which should be preserved. Insuch a situation restrictions on the licensee's use of hisown technology or on research and development arenormally considered to be restrictive of competitionand not to satisfy the conditions of Article 81(3). Forinstance, an obligation on the licensee to pay royaltiesnot only on the basis of products it produces with thelicensed technology but also on the basis of products itproduces with its own technology will generally limit theability of the licensee to exploit its own technology andthus be excluded from the scope of the block exemption.

116. In cases where the licensee does not own a competingtechnology or is not already developing such a tech-nology, a restriction on the ability of the parties tocarry out independent research and development maybe restrictive of competition where only a few tech-nologies are available. In that case the parties may bean important (potential) source of innovation in themarket. This is particularly so where the parties possessthe necessary assets and skills to carry out furtherresearch and development. In that case the conditionsof Article 81(3) are unlikely to be fulfilled. In othercases where several technologies are available andwhere the parties do not possess special assets or skills,the restriction on research and development is likely toeither fall outside Article 81(1) for lack of an appreciablerestrictive effect or satisfy the conditions of Article 81(3).The restraint may promote the dissemination of newtechnology by assuring the licensor that the licencedoes not create a new competitor and by inducing thelicensee to focus on the exploitation and development ofthe licensed technology. Moreover, Article 81(1) onlyapplies where the agreement reduces the licensee'sincentive to improve and exploit his own technology.This is for instance not likely to be the case where thelicensor is entitled to terminate the licence agreementonce the licensee commences to produce on the basisof his own competing technology. Such a right doesnot reduce the licensee's incentive to innovate, sincethe agreement can only be terminated when acommercially viable technology has been developed andproducts produced on the basis thereof are ready to beput on the market.

ENC 101/22 Official Journal of the European Union 27.4.2004

Page 22: COMMISSION NOTICE Guidelines on the application of Article 81 of

6. Withdrawal and disapplication of the Block ExemptionRegulation

6.1. Withdrawal procedure

117. According to Article 6 of the TTBER, the Commissionand the competition authorities of the Member Statesmay withdraw the benefit of the block exemption inrespect of individual agreements that do not fulfil theconditions of Article 81(3). The power of thecompetition authorities of the Member States towithdraw the benefit of the block exemption is limitedto cases where the relevant geographic market is nowider than the territory of the Member State in question.

118. The four conditions of Article 81(3) are cumulative andmust all be fulfilled for the exception rule to beapplicable (52). The block exemption can therefore bewithdrawn where a particular agreement fails one ormore of the four conditions.

119. Where the withdrawal procedure is applied, the with-drawing authority bears the burden of proving that theagreement falls within the scope of Article 81(1) and thatthe agreement does not satisfy all four conditions ofArticle 81(3). Given that withdrawal implies that theagreement in question restricts competition within themeaning of Article 81(1) and does not fulfil theconditions of Article 81(3), withdrawal is necessarilyaccompanied by a negative decision based on Articles5, 7 or 9 of Regulation 1/2003.

120. According to Article 6, withdrawal may in particular bewarranted in the following circumstances:

1. access of third parties' technologies to the market isrestricted, for instance by the cumulative effect ofparallel networks of similar restrictive agreementsprohibiting licensees from using third party tech-nology;

2. access of potential licensees to the market is restricted,for instance by the cumulative effect of parallelnetworks of similar restrictive agreements preventinglicensors from licensing to other licensees;

3. without any objectively valid reason the parties refrainfrom exploiting the licensed technology.

121. Articles 4 and 5 of the TTBER, containing the list ofhardcore restrictions of competition and excludedrestrictions, aim at ensuring that block exemptedagreements do not reduce the incentive to innovate, donot delay the dissemination of technology, and do not

unduly restrict competition between the licensor andlicensee or between licensees. However, the list ofhardcore restrictions and the list of excluded restrictionsdo not take into account all the possible impacts oflicence agreements. In particular, the block exemptiondoes not take account of any cumulative effect ofsimilar restrictions contained in networks of licenceagreements. Licence agreements may lead to foreclosureof third parties both at the level of the licensor and at thelevel of the licensee. Foreclosure of other licensors maystem from the cumulative effect of networks of licenceagreements prohibiting the licensees from exploitingcompeting technologies, leading to the exclusion ofother (potential) licensors. Foreclosure of licensors islikely to arise in cases where most of the undertakingson the market that could (efficiently) take a competinglicence are prevented from doing so as a consequence ofrestrictive agreements and where potential licensees facerelatively high barriers to entry. Foreclosure of otherlicensees may stem from the cumulative effect oflicence agreements prohibiting licensors from licensingother licensees and thereby preventing potentiallicensees from gaining access to the necessary tech-nology. The issue of foreclosure is examined in moredetail in section IV.2.7 below. In addition, theCommission is likely to withdraw the benefit of theblock exemption where a significant number oflicensors of competing technologies in individualagreements impose on their licensees to extend to themmore favourable conditions agreed with other licensors.

122. The Commission is also likely to withdraw the benefit ofthe block exemption where the parties refrain fromexploiting the licensed technology, unless they have anobjective justification for doing so. Indeed, when theparties do not exploit the licensed technology, no effi-ciency enhancing activity takes place, in which case thevery rationale of the block exemption disappears.However, exploitation does not need to take the formof an integration of assets. Exploitation also occurswhere the licence creates design freedom for thelicensee by allowing him to exploit his own technologywithout facing the risk of infringement claims by thelicensor. In the case of licensing between competitors,the fact that the parties do not exploit the licensed tech-nology may be an indication that the arrangement is adisguised cartel. For these reasons the Commission willexamine very closely cases of non-exploitation.

6.2. Disapplication of the Block Exemption Regulation

123. Article 7 of the TTBER enables the Commission toexclude from the scope of the TTBER, by means of regu-lation, parallel networks of similar agreements wherethese cover more than 50 % of a relevant market. Sucha measure is not addressed to individual undertakings butconcerns all undertakings whose agreements are definedin the regulation disapplying the TTBER.

EN27.4.2004 Official Journal of the European Union C 101/23

Page 23: COMMISSION NOTICE Guidelines on the application of Article 81 of

124. Whereas withdrawal of the benefit of the TTBER by theCommission under Article 6 implies the adoption of adecision under Articles 7 or 9 of Regulation 1/2003, theeffect of a Commission disapplication regulation underArticle 7 of the TTBER is merely to remove, in respectof the restraints and the markets concerned, the benefitof the TTBER and to restore the full application of Article81(1) and (3). Following the adoption of a regulationdeclaring the TTBER inapplicable for a particularmarket in respect of agreements containing certainrestraints, the criteria developed by the relevant caselaw of the Community Courts and by notices andprevious decisions adopted by the Commission will giveguidance on the application of Article 81 to individualagreements. Where appropriate, the Commission willtake a decision in an individual case, which canprovide guidance to all the undertakings operating onthe market concerned.

125. For the purpose of calculating the 50 % market coverageratio, account must be taken of each individual networkof licence agreements containing restraints, or combi-nations of restraints, producing similar effects on themarket.

126. Article 7 does not entail an obligation on the part of theCommission to act where the 50 % market-coverage ratiois exceeded. In general, disapplication is appropriatewhen it is likely that access to the relevant market orcompetition therein is appreciably restricted. In assessingthe need to apply Article 7, the Commission will considerwhether individual withdrawal would be a more appro-priate remedy. This may depend, in particular, on thenumber of competing undertakings contributing to acumulative effect on a market or the number ofaffected geographic markets within the Community.

127. Any regulation adopted under Article 7 must clearly setout its scope. This means, first, that the Commissionmust define the relevant product and geographicmarket(s) and, secondly, that it must identify the typeof licensing restraint in respect of which the TTBERwill no longer apply. As regards the latter aspect, theCommission may modulate the scope of its regulationaccording to the competition concern which it intendsto address. For instance, while all parallel networks ofnon-compete arrangements will be taken into accountfor the purpose of establishing the 50 % marketcoverage ratio, the Commission may neverthelessrestrict the scope of the disapplication regulation onlyto non-compete obligations exceeding a certainduration. Thus, agreements of a shorter duration or ofa less restrictive nature might be left unaffected, due tothe lesser degree of foreclosure attributable to suchrestraints. Where appropriate, the Commission may alsoprovide guidance by specifying the market share levelwhich, in the specific market context, may be regardedas insufficient to bring about a significant contribution byan individual undertaking to the cumulative effect. In

general, when the market share of the products incor-porating a technology licensed by an individual licensordoes not exceed 5 %, the agreement or network ofagreements covering that technology is not consideredto contribute significantly to a cumulative foreclosureeffect (53).

128. The transitional period of not less than six months thatthe Commission will have to set under Article 7(2)should allow the undertakings concerned to adapt theiragreements to take account of the regulation disapplyingthe TTBER.

129. A regulation disapplying the TTBER will not affect theblock exempted status of the agreements concerned forthe period preceding its entry into force.

IV. APPLICATION OF ARTICLE 81(1) AND 81(3) OUTSIDE THESCOPE OF THE BLOCK EXEMPTION REGULATION

1. The general framework for analysis

130. Agreements that fall outside the block exemption, forexample because the market share thresholds areexceeded or the agreement involves more than twoparties, are subject to individual assessment. Agreementsthat either do not restrict competition within themeaning of Article 81(1) or which fulfil the conditionsof Article 81(3) are valid and enforceable. It is recalledthat there is no presumption of illegality of agreementsthat fall outside the scope of the block exemptionprovided that they do not contain hardcore restrictionsof competition. In particular, there is no presumptionthat Article 81(1) applies merely because the marketshare thresholds are exceeded. Individual assessmentbased on the principles described in these guidelines isrequired.

131. In order to promote predictability beyond the applicationof the TTBER and to confine detailed analysis to casesthat are likely to present real competition concerns, theCommission takes the view that outside the area ofhardcore restrictions Article 81 is unlikely to beinfringed where there are four or more independentlycontrolled technologies in addition to the technologiescontrolled by the parties to the agreement that may besubstitutable for the licensed technology at a comparablecost to the user. In assessing whether the technologies aresufficiently substitutable the relative commercial strengthof the technologies in question must be taken intoaccount. The competitive constraint imposed by a tech-nology is limited if it does not constitute a commerciallyviable alternative to the licensed technology. For instance,if due to network effects in the market consumers have astrong preference for products incorporating the licensed

ENC 101/24 Official Journal of the European Union 27.4.2004

Page 24: COMMISSION NOTICE Guidelines on the application of Article 81 of

technology, other technologies already on the market orlikely to come to market within a reasonable period oftime may not constitute a real alternative and maytherefore impose only a limited competitive constraint.The fact that an agreement falls outside the safe harbourdescribed in this paragraph does not imply that theagreement is caught by Article 81(1) and, if so, thatthe conditions of Article 81(3) are not satisfied. As forthe market share safe harbour of the TTBER, thisadditional safe harbour merely creates a negativepresumption that the agreement is not prohibited byArticle 81. Outside the safe harbour individualassessment of the agreement based on the principlesdeveloped in these guidelines is required.

1.1. The relevant factors

132. In the application of Article 81 to individual cases it isnecessary to take due account of the way in whichcompetition operates on the market in question. Thefollowing factors are particularly relevant in this respect:

(a) the nature of the agreement;

(b) the market position of the parties;

(c) the market position of competitors;

(d) the market position of buyers of the licensedproducts;

(e) entry barriers;

(f) maturity of the market; and

(g) other factors.

The importance of individual factors may vary from caseto case and depends on all other factors. For instance, ahigh market share of the parties is usually a goodindicator of market power, but in the case of low entrybarriers it may not be indicative of market power. It istherefore not possible to provide firm rules on theimportance of the individual factors.

133. Technology transfer agreements can take many shapesand forms. It is therefore important to analyse thenature of the agreement in terms of the competitiverelationship between the parties and the restraints thatit contains. In the latter regard it is necessary to gobeyond the express terms of the agreement. Theexistence of implicit restraints may be derived from theway in which the agreement has been implemented bythe parties and the incentives that they face.

134. The market position of the parties provides an indicationof the degree of market power, if any, possessed by thelicensor, the licensee or both. The higher their marketshare the greater their market power is likely to be.This is particularly so where the market share reflectscost advantages or other competitive advantagesvis-à-vis competitors. These competitive advantages mayfor instance result from being a first mover in the market,from holding essential patents or from having superiortechnology.

135. In analysing the competitive relationship between theparties it is sometimes necessary to go beyond theanalysis set out in the above sections II.3 on marketdefinition and II.4 on the distinction between competitorsand non-competitors. Even where the licensor is not anactual or potential supplier on the product market andthe licensee is not an actual or potential competitor onthe technology market, it is relevant to the analysiswhether the licensee owns a competing technology,which is not being licensed. If the licensee has a strongposition on the product market, an agreement grantinghim an exclusive licence to a competing technology canrestrict competition significantly compared to thesituation where the licensor does not grant an exclusivelicence or licences other undertakings.

136. Market shares and possible competitive advantages anddisadvantages are also used to assess the market positionof competitors. The stronger the actual competitors andthe greater their number the less risk there is that theparties will be able to individually exercise market power.However, if the number of competitors is rather smalland their market position (size, costs, R&D potential, etc.)is rather similar, this market structure may increase therisk of collusion.

137. The market position of buyers provides an indication ofwhether or not one or more buyers possess buyer power.The first indicator of buying power is the market share ofthe buyer on the purchase market. This share reflects theimportance of his demand for possible suppliers. Otherindicators focus on the position of the buyer on his resalemarket, including characteristics such as a widegeographic spread of his outlets, and his brand imageamongst final consumers. In some circumstances buyerpower may prevent the licensor and/or the licensee fromexercising market power on the market and thereby solvea competition problem that would otherwise haveexisted. This is particularly so when strong buyers havethe capacity and the incentive to bring new sources ofsupply on to the market in the case of a small butpermanent increase in relative prices. Where the strongbuyers merely extract favourable terms from the supplieror simply pass on any price increase to their customers,the position of the buyers is not such as to prevent theexercise of market power by the licensee on the productmarket and therefore not such as to solve thecompetition problem on that market (54).

EN27.4.2004 Official Journal of the European Union C 101/25

Page 25: COMMISSION NOTICE Guidelines on the application of Article 81 of

138. Entry barriers are measured by the extent to whichincumbent companies can increase their price abovethe competitive level without attracting new entry. Inthe absence of entry barriers, easy and quick entrywould render price increases unprofitable. Wheneffective entry, preventing or eroding the exercise ofmarket power, is likely to occur within one or twoyears, entry barriers can, as a general rule, be said tobe low. Entry barriers may result from a wide varietyof factors such as economies of scale and scope,government regulations, especially where they establishexclusive rights, state aid, import tariffs, intellectualproperty rights, ownership of resources where thesupply is limited due to for instance natural limitations,essential facilities, a first mover advantage or brandloyalty of consumers created by strong advertising overa period of time. Restrictive agreements entered into byundertakings may also work as an entry barrier bymaking access more difficult and foreclosing (potential)competitors. Entry barriers may be present at all stages ofthe research and development, production anddistribution process. The question whether certain ofthese factors should be described as entry barriersdepends particularly on whether they entail sunk costs.Sunk costs are those costs which have to be incurred toenter or be active on a market but which are lost whenthe market is exited. The more costs are sunk, the morepotential entrants have to weigh the risks of entering themarket and the more credibly incumbents can threatenthat they will match new competition, as sunk costsmake it costly for incumbents to leave the market. Ingeneral, entry requires sunk costs, sometimes minorand sometimes major. Therefore, actual competition isin general more effective and will weigh more heavilyin the assessment of a case than potential competition.

139. A mature market is a market that has existed for sometime, where the technology used is well known and wide-spread and not changing very much and in whichdemand is relatively stable or declining. In such amarket restrictions of competition are more likely tohave negative effects than in more dynamic markets.

140. In the assessment of particular restraints other factorsmay have to be taken into account. Such factorsinclude cumulative effects, i.e. the coverage of themarket by similar agreements, the duration of theagreements, the regulatory environment and behaviourthat may indicate or facilitate collusion like priceleadership, pre-announced price changes and discussionson the ‘right’ price, price rigidity in response to excesscapacity, price discrimination and past collusivebehaviour.

1.2. Negative effects of restrictive licence agreements

141. The negative effects on competition on the market thatmay result from restrictive technology transferagreements include the following:

1. reduction of inter-technology competition betweenthe companies operating on a technology market oron a market for products incorporating the tech-nologies in question, including facilitation ofcollusion, both explicit and tacit;

2. foreclosure of competitors by raising their costs,restricting their access to essential inputs orotherwise raising barriers to entry; and

3. reduction of intra-technology competition betweenundertakings that produce products on the basis ofthe same technology.

142. Technology transfer agreements may reduce inter-tech-nology competition, i.e. competition between under-takings that license or produce on the basis ofsubstitutable technologies. This is particularly so wherereciprocal obligations are imposed. For instance, wherecompetitors transfer competing technologies to eachother and impose a reciprocal obligation to provideeach other with future improvements of their respectivetechnologies and where this agreement prevents eithercompetitor from gaining a technological lead over theother, competition in innovation between the parties isrestricted (see also paragraph 208 below).

143. Licensing between competitors may also facilitatecollusion. The risk of collusion is particularly high inconcentrated markets. Collusion requires that the under-takings concerned have similar views on what is in theircommon interest and on how the co-ordination mech-anisms function. For collusion to work the undertakingsmust also be able to monitor each other's marketbehaviour and there must be adequate deterrents toensure that there is an incentive not to depart from thecommon policy on the market, while entry barriers mustbe high enough to limit entry or expansion by outsiders.Agreements can facilitate collusion by increasing trans-parency in the market, by controlling certain behaviourand by raising barriers to entry. Collusion can also excep-tionally be facilitated by licensing agreements that lead toa high degree of commonality of costs, because under-takings that have similar costs are more likely to havesimilar views on the terms of coordination (55).

ENC 101/26 Official Journal of the European Union 27.4.2004

Page 26: COMMISSION NOTICE Guidelines on the application of Article 81 of

144. Licence agreements may also affect inter-technologycompetition by creating barriers to entry for andexpansion by competitors. Such foreclosure effects maystem from restraints that prevent licensees from licensingfrom third parties or create disincentives for them to doso. For instance, third parties may be foreclosed whereincumbent licensors impose non-compete obligations onlicensees to such an extent that an insufficient number oflicensees are available to third parties and where entry atthe level of licensees is difficult. Suppliers of substitutabletechnologies may also be foreclosed where a licensorwith a sufficient degree of market power ties togethervarious parts of a technology and licenses themtogether as a package while only part of the package isessential to produce a certain product.

145. Licence agreements may also reduce intra-technologycompetition, i.e. competition between undertakings thatproduce on the basis of the same technology. Anagreement imposing territorial restraints on licensees,preventing them from selling into each other's territoryreduces competition between them. Licence agreementsmay also reduce intra-technology competition by facili-tating collusion between licensees. Moreover, licenceagreements that reduce intra-technology competitionmay facilitate collusion between owners of competingtechnologies or reduce inter-technology competition byraising barriers to entry.

1.3. Positive effects of restrictive licence agreements andthe framework for analysing such effects

146. Even restrictive licence agreements mostly also producepro-competitive effects in the form of efficiencies, whichmay outweigh their anti-competitive effects. Thisassessment takes place within the framework of Article81(3), which contains an exception from the prohibitionrule of Article 81(1). For this exception to be applicablethe licence agreement must produce objective economicbenefits, the restrictions on competition must be indis-pensable to attain the efficiencies, consumers mustreceive a fair share of the efficiency gains, and theagreement must not afford the parties the possibility ofeliminating competition in respect of a substantial part ofthe products concerned.

147. The assessment of restrictive agreements under Article81(3) is made within the actual context in which theyoccur (56) and on the basis of the facts existing at anygiven point in time. The assessment is sensitive tomaterial changes in the facts. The exception rule ofArticle 81(3) applies as long as the four conditions arefulfilled and ceases to apply when that is no longer thecase (57). However, when applying Article 81(3) inaccordance with these principles it is necessary to takeinto account the initial sunk investments made by any ofthe parties and the time needed and the restraintsrequired to commit and recoup an efficiency enhancinginvestment. Article 81 cannot be applied withoutconsidering the ex ante investment and the risks relatingthereto. The risk facing the parties and the sunk

investment that must be committed to implement theagreement can thus lead to the agreement fallingoutside Article 81(1) or fulfilling the conditions ofArticle 81(3), as the case may be, for the period oftime required to recoup the investment.

148. The first condition of Article 81(3) requires anassessment of what are the objective benefits in termsof efficiencies produced by the agreement. In thisrespect, licence agreements have the potential ofbringing together complementary technologies andother assets allowing new or improved products to beput on the market or existing products to be produced atlower cost. Outside the context of hardcore cartels,licensing often occurs because it is more efficient forthe licensor to licence the technology than to exploit ithimself. This may particularly be the case where thelicensee already has access to the necessary productionassets. The agreement allows the licensee to gain accessto a technology that can be combined with these assets,allowing him to exploit new or improved technologies.Another example of potentially efficiency enhancinglicensing is where the licensee already has a technologyand where the combination of this technology and thelicensor's technology gives rise to synergies. When thetwo technologies are combined the licensee may beable to attain a cost/output configuration that wouldnot otherwise be possible. Licence agreements may alsogive rise to efficiencies at the distribution stage in thesame way as vertical distribution agreements. Such effi-ciencies can take the form of cost savings or theprovision of valuable services to consumers. Thepositive effects of vertical agreements are described inthe Guidelines on Vertical Restraints (58). A furtherexample of possible efficiency gains is agreementswhereby technology owners assemble a technologypackage for licensing to third parties. Such poolingarrangements may in particular reduce transactioncosts, as licensees do not have to conclude separatelicence agreements with each licensor. Pro-competitivelicensing may also occur to ensure design freedom. Insectors where large numbers of intellectual propertyrights exist and where individual products may infringeupon a number of existing and future property rights,licence agreements whereby the parties agree not toassert their property rights against each other are oftenpro-competitive because they allow the parties to developtheir respective technologies without the risk ofsubsequent infringement claims.

149. In the application of the indispensability test contained inArticle 81(3) the Commission will in particular examinewhether individual restrictions make it possible toperform the activity in question more efficiently thanwould have been the case in the absence of therestriction concerned. In making this assessment themarket conditions and the realities facing the partiesmust be taken into account. Undertakings invoking thebenefit of Article 81(3) are not required to considerhypothetical and theoretical alternatives. They must,however, explain and demonstrate why seeminglyrealistic and significantly less restrictive alternatives

EN27.4.2004 Official Journal of the European Union C 101/27

Page 27: COMMISSION NOTICE Guidelines on the application of Article 81 of

would be significantly less efficient. If the application ofwhat appears to be a commercially realistic and lessrestrictive alternative would lead to a significant loss ofefficiencies, the restriction in question is treated as indis-pensable. In some cases, it may also be necessary toexamine whether the agreement as such is indispensableto achieve the efficiencies. This may for example be so inthe case of technology pools that include complementarybut non-essential technologies (59), in which case it mustbe examined to what extent such inclusion gives rise toparticular efficiencies or whether, without a significantloss of efficiencies, the pool could be limited to tech-nologies for which there are no substitutes. In the caseof simple licensing between two parties it is generally notnecessary to go beyond an examination of the indispen-sability of individual restraints. Normally there is no lessrestrictive alternative to the licence agreement as such.

150. The condition that consumers must receive a fair share ofthe benefits implies that consumers of the productsproduced under the licence must at least be compensatedfor the negative effects of the agreement (60). This meansthat the efficiency gains must fully off-set the likelynegative impact on prices, output and other relevantfactors caused by the agreement. They may do so bychanging the cost structure of the undertakingsconcerned, giving them an incentive to reduce price, orby allowing consumers to gain access to new orimproved products, compensating for any likely priceincrease (61).

151. The last condition of Article 81(3), according to whichthe agreement must not afford the parties the possibilityof eliminating competition in respect of a substantial partof the products concerned, presupposes an analysis ofremaining competitive pressures on the market and theimpact of the agreement on such sources of competition.In the application of the last condition of Article 81(3)the relationship between Article 81(3) and Article 82must be taken into account. According to settled caselaw, the application of Article 81(3) cannot prevent theapplication of Article 82 of the Treaty (62). Moreover,since Articles 81 and 82 both pursue the aim of main-taining effective competition on the market, consistencyrequires that Article 81(3) be interpreted as precludingany application of the exception rule to restrictiveagreements that constitute an abuse of a dominantposition (63).

152. The fact that the agreement substantially reduces onedimension of competition does not necessarily meanthat competition is eliminated within the meaning ofArticle 81(3). A technology pool, for instance, canresult in an industry standard, leading to a situation inwhich there is little competition in terms of the tech-nological format. Once the main players in the marketadopt a certain format, network effects may make it verydifficult for alternative formats to survive. This does not

imply, however, that the creation of a de facto industrystandard always eliminates competition within themeaning of the last condition of Article 81(3). Withinthe standard, suppliers may compete on price, qualityand product features. However, in order for theagreement to comply with Article 81(3), it must beensured that the agreement does not unduly restrictcompetition and does not unduly restrict future inno-vation.

2. The application of Article 81 to various types oflicensing restraints

153. This section deals with various types of restraints that arecommonly included in licence agreements. Given theirprevalence it is useful to provide guidance as to howthey are assessed outside the safe harbour of theTTBER. Restraints that have already been dealt with inthe preceding parts of these guidelines, in particularsections III.4 and III.5, are only dealt with briefly in thepresent section.

154. This section covers both agreements betweennon-competitors and agreements between competitors.In respect of the latter a distinction is made — whereappropriate — between reciprocal and non-reciprocalagreements. No such distinction is required in the caseof agreements between non-competitors. When under-takings are neither actual nor potential competitors ona relevant technology market or on a market for productsincorporating the licensed technology, a reciprocallicence is for all practical purposes no different fromtwo separate licences. Arrangements whereby theparties assemble a technology package, which is thenlicensed to third parties, are technology pools, whichare dealt with in section 4 below.

155. This section does not deal with obligations in licenceagreements that are generally not restrictive ofcompetition within the meaning of Article 81(1). Theseobligations include but are not limited to:

(a) confidentiality obligations;

(b) obligations on licensees not to sub-license;

(c) obligations not to use the licensed technology afterthe expiry of the agreement, provided that thelicensed technology remains valid and in force;

(d) obligations to assist the licensor in enforcing thelicensed intellectual property rights;

ENC 101/28 Official Journal of the European Union 27.4.2004

Page 28: COMMISSION NOTICE Guidelines on the application of Article 81 of

(e) obligations to pay minimum royalties or to produce aminimum quantity of products incorporating thelicensed technology; and

(f) obligations to use the licensor's trade mark orindicate the name of the licensor on the product.

2.1. Royalty obligations

156. The parties to a licence agreement are normally free todetermine the royalty payable by the licensee and itsmode of payment without being caught by Article81(1). This principle applies both to agreementsbetween competitors and agreements betweennon-competitors. Royalty obligations may for instancetake the form of lump sum payments, a percentage ofthe selling price or a fixed amount for each productincorporating the licensed technology. In cases wherethe licensed technology relates to an input which isincorporated into a final product it is as a general rulenot restrictive of competition that royalties are calculatedon the basis of the price of the final product, providedthat it incorporates the licensed technology. In the case ofsoftware licensing royalties based on the number of usersand royalties calculated on a per machine basis aregenerally compatible with Article 81(1).

157. In the case of licence agreements between competitors itis recalled, see paragraphs and above, that in a limitednumber of circumstances royalty obligations may amountto price fixing, which is a hardcore restriction (cf. Article4(1)(a)). It is a hardcore restriction under Article 4(1)(a) ifcompetitors provide for reciprocal running royalties incircumstances where the licence is a sham, in that itspurpose is not to allow an integration of complementarytechnologies or to achieve another pro-competitive aim.It is also a hardcore restriction under Article 4(1)(a) and4(1)(d) if royalties extend to products produced solelywith the licensee's own technology.

158. Other types of royalty arrangements between competitorsare block exempted up to the market share threshold of20 % even if they restrict competition. Outside the safeharbour of the block exemption Article 81(1) may beapplicable where competitors cross license and imposerunning royalties that are clearly disproportionatecompared to the market value of the licence and wheresuch royalties have a significant impact on market prices.In assessing whether the royalties are disproportionate itis relevant to have regard to the royalties paid by otherlicensees on the product market for the same orsubstitute technologies. In such cases it is unlikely thatthe conditions of Article 81(3) are satisfied. Article 81(1)may also apply where reciprocal running royalties perunit increase as output increases. If the parties have asignificant degree of market power, such royalties mayhave the effect of limiting output.

159. Notwithstanding the fact that the block exemption onlyapplies as long as the technology is valid and in force, theparties can normally agree to extend royalty obligationsbeyond the period of validity of the licensed intellectualproperty rights without falling foul of Article 81(1). Oncethese rights expire, third parties can legally exploit thetechnology in question and compete with the parties tothe agreement. Such actual and potential competition willnormally suffice to ensure that the obligation in questiondoes not have appreciable anti-competitive effects.

160. In the case of agreements between non-competitors theblock exemption covers agreements whereby royalties arecalculated on the basis of both products produced withthe licensed technology and products produced withtechnologies licensed from third parties. Sucharrangements may facilitate the metering of royalties.However, they may also lead to foreclosure by increasingthe cost of using third party inputs and may thus havesimilar effects as a non-compete obligation. If royaltiesare paid not just on products produced with the licensedtechnology but also on products produced with thirdparty technology, then the royalties will increase thecost of the latter products and reduce demand for thirdparty technology. Outside the scope of the blockexemption it must therefore be examined whether therestriction has foreclosure effects. For that purpose it isappropriate to use the analytical framework set out insection 2.7 below. In the case of appreciable foreclosureeffects such agreements are caught by Article 81(1) andunlikely to fulfil the conditions of Article 81(3), unlessthere is no other practical way of calculating and moni-toring royalty payments.

2.2. Exclusive licensing and sales restrictions

161. For the present purposes it is useful to distinguishbetween restrictions as to production within a giventerritory (exclusive or sole licences) and restrictions onthe sale of products incorporating the licensed tech-nology into a given territory and to a given customergroup (sales restrictions).

2.2.1. Exclusive and sole licences

162. A licence is deemed to be exclusive if the licensee is theonly one who is permitted to produce on the basis of thelicensed technology within a given territory. The licensorthus undertakes not to produce itself or license others toproduce within a given territory. This territory may coverthe whole world. Where the licensor undertakes only notto licence third parties to produce within a giventerritory, the licence is a sole licence. Often exclusiveor sole licensing is accompanied by sales restrictionsthat limit the parties in where they may sell productsincorporating the licensed technology.

EN27.4.2004 Official Journal of the European Union C 101/29

Page 29: COMMISSION NOTICE Guidelines on the application of Article 81 of

163. Reciprocal exclusive licensing between competitors fallsunder Article 4(1)(c), which identifies market sharingbetween competitors as a hardcore restriction. Reciprocalsole licensing between competitors is block exempted upto the market share threshold of 20 %. Under such anagreement the parties mutually commit not to licensetheir competing technologies to third parties. In caseswhere the parties have a significant degree of marketpower such agreements may facilitate collusion byensuring that the parties are the only sources of outputin the market based on the licensed technologies.

164. Non-reciprocal exclusive licensing between competitors isblock exempted up to the market share threshold of20 %. Above the market share threshold it is necessaryto analyse what are the likely anti-competitive effects ofsuch exclusive licensing. Where the exclusive licence isworld-wide it implies that the licensor leaves the market.In cases where exclusivity is limited to a particularterritory such as a Member State the agreement impliesthat the licensor abstains from producing goods andservices inside the territory in question. In the contextof Article 81(1) it must in particular be assessed what isthe competitive significance of the licensor. If the licensorhas a limited market position on the product market orlacks the capacity to effectively exploit the technology inthe licensee's territory, the agreement is unlikely to becaught by Article 81(1). A special case is where thelicensor and the licensee only compete on the technologymarket and the licensor, for instance being a researchinstitute or a small research based undertaking, lacksthe production and distribution assets to effectivelybring to market products incorporating the licensed tech-nology. In such cases Article 81(1) is unlikely to beinfringed.

165. Exclusive licensing between non-competitors — to theextent that it is caught by Article 81(1) (64) — is likelyto fulfil the conditions of Article 81(3). The right to grantan exclusive licence is generally necessary in order toinduce the licensee to invest in the licensed technologyand to bring the products to market in a timely manner.This is in particular the case where the licensee mustmake large investments in further developing thelicensed technology. To intervene against the exclusivityonce the licensee has made a commercial success of thelicensed technology would deprive the licensee of thefruits of his success and would be detrimental tocompetition, the dissemination of technology and inno-vation. The Commission will therefore only exceptionallyintervene against exclusive licensing in agreementsbetween non-competitors, irrespective of the territorialscope of the licence.

166. The main situation in which intervention may bewarranted is where a dominant licensee obtains anexclusive licence to one or more competing technologies.Such agreements are likely to be caught by Article 81(1)and unlikely to fulfil the conditions of Article 81(3). It is

a condition however that entry into the technologymarket is difficult and the licensed technology constitutesa real source of competition on the market. In suchcircumstances an exclusive licence may foreclose thirdparty licensees and allow the licensee to preserve hismarket power.

167. Arrangements whereby two or more parties cross licenceeach other and undertake not to licence third parties giverise to particular concerns when the package of tech-nologies resulting from the cross licences creates a defacto industry standard to which third parties musthave access in order to compete effectively on themarket. In such cases the agreement creates a closedstandard reserved for the parties. The Commission willassess such arrangements according to the same prin-ciples as those applied to technology pools (see section4 below). It will normally be required that the tech-nologies which support such a standard be licensed tothird parties on fair, reasonable and non-discriminatoryterms (65). Where the parties to the arrangement competewith third parties on an existing product market and thearrangement relates to that product market a closedstandard is likely to have substantial exclusionaryeffects. This negative impact on competition can onlybe avoided by licensing also to third parties.

2.2.2. Sales restrictions

168. Also as regards sales restrictions there is an importantdistinction to be made between licensing betweencompetitors and between non-competitors.

169. Restrictions on active and passive sales by one or bothparties in a reciprocal agreement between competitorsare hardcore restrictions of competition under Article4(1)(c). Sales restrictions on either party in a reciprocalagreement between competitors are caught by Article81(1) and are unlikely to fulfil the conditions of Article81(3). Such restrictions are generally considered marketsharing, since they prevent the affected party from sellingactively and passively into territories and to customergroups which he actually served or could realisticallyhave served in the absence of the agreement.

170. In the case of non-reciprocal agreements betweencompetitors the block exemption applies to restrictionson active and passive sales by the licensee or the licensorinto the exclusive territory or to the exclusive customergroup reserved for the other party (cf. Article 4(1)(c)(iv).Above the market share threshold of 20 % salesrestrictions between licensor and licensee are caught by

ENC 101/30 Official Journal of the European Union 27.4.2004

Page 30: COMMISSION NOTICE Guidelines on the application of Article 81 of

Article 81(1) when one or both of the parties have asignificant degree of market power. Such restrictions,however, may be indispensable for the dissemination ofvaluable technologies and therefore fulfil the conditionsof Article 81(3). This may be the case where the licensorhas a relatively weak market position in the territorywhere he exploits himself the technology. In suchcircumstances restrictions on active sales in particularmay be indispensable to induce the licensor to grantthe licence. In the absence thereof the licensor wouldrisk facing active competition in his main area ofactivity. Similarly, restrictions on active sales by thelicensor may be indispensable, in particular, where thelicensee has a relatively weak market position in theterritory allocated to him and has to make significantinvestments in order to efficiently exploit the licensedtechnology.

171. The block exemption also covers restrictions on activesales into the territory or to the customer groupallocated to another licensee, who was not a competitorof the licensor at the time when he concluded the licenceagreement with the licensor. It is a condition, however,that the agreement between the parties in question isnon-reciprocal. Above the market share threshold suchactive sales restrictions are likely to be caught by Article81(1) when the parties have a significant degree ofmarket power. However, the restraint is likely to be indis-pensable within the meaning of Article 81(3) for theperiod of time required for the protected licensee topenetrate a new market and establish a marketpresence in the allocated territory or vis-à-vis theallocated customer group. This protection against activesales allows the licensee to overcome the asymmetry,which he faces due to the fact that some of thelicensees are competing undertakings of the licensorand thus already established on the market. Restrictionson passive sales by licensees into a territory or to acustomer group allocated to another licensee arehardcore restrictions under Article 4(1)(c) of the TTBER.

172. In the case of agreements between non-competitors salesrestrictions between the licensor and a licensee are blockexempted up to the market share threshold of 30 %.Above the market share threshold restrictions on activeand passive sales by licensees to territories or customergroups reserved for the licensor may fall outside Article81(1) where on the basis of objective factors it can beconcluded that in the absence of the sales restrictionslicensing would not occur. A technology owner cannotnormally be expected to create direct competition withhimself on the basis of his own technology. In othercases sales restrictions on the licensee may be caughtby Article 81(1) both where the licensor individuallyhas a significant degree of market power and in thecase of a cumulative effect of similar agreementsconcluded by licensors which together hold a strongposition on the market.

173. Sales restrictions on the licensor, when caught by Article81(1), are likely to fulfil the conditions of Article 81(3)unless there are no real alternatives to the licensor's tech-nology on the market or such alternatives are licensed bythe licensee from third parties. Such restrictions and inparticular restrictions on active sales are likely to beindispensable within the meaning of Article 81(3) inorder to induce the licensee to invest in the production,marketing and sale of the products incorporating thelicensed technology. It is likely that the licensee'sincentive to invest would be significantly reduced if hewould face direct competition from the licensor whoseproduction costs are not burdened by royalty payments,possibly leading to sub-optimal levels of investment.

174. As regards restrictions on sales between licensees inagreements between non-competitors, the TTBER blockexempts restrictions on active selling between territoriesor customer groups. Above the market share thresholdrestrictions on active sales between licensees' territoriesand customer groups limit intra-technology competitionand are likely to be caught by Article 81(1) when theindividual licensee has a significant degree of marketpower. Such restrictions, however, may fulfil theconditions of Article 81(3) where they are necessary toprevent free riding and to induce the licensee to make theinvestment necessary for efficient exploitation of thelicensed technology inside his territory and to promotesales of the licensed product. Restrictions on passive salesare covered by the hardcore list of Article 4(2)(b), cf.paragraph 101 above, when they exceed two yearsfrom the date on which the licensee benefiting fromthe restrictions first put the product incorporating thelicensed technology on the market inside his exclusiveterritory. Passive sales restrictions exceeding thistwo-year period are unlikely to fulfil the conditions ofArticle 81(3).

2.3. Output restrictions

175. Reciprocal output restrictions in licence agreementsbetween competitors constitute a hardcore restrictioncovered by Article 4(1)(b) of the TTBER (cf. point 82above). Article 4(1)(b) does not cover output restrictionsimposed on the licensee in a non-reciprocal agreement oron one of the licensees in an reciprocal agreement. Suchrestrictions are block exempted up to the market sharethreshold of 20 %. Above the market share threshold,output restrictions on the licensee may restrictcompetition where the parties have a significant degreeof market power. However, Article 81(3) is likely toapply in cases where the licensor's technology issubstantially better than the licensee's technology andthe output limitation substantially exceeds the output ofthe licensee prior to the conclusion of the agreement. In

EN27.4.2004 Official Journal of the European Union C 101/31

Page 31: COMMISSION NOTICE Guidelines on the application of Article 81 of

that case the effect of the output limitation is limitedeven in markets where demand is growing. In theapplication of Article 81(3) it must also be taken intoaccount that such restrictions may be necessary in orderto induce the licensor to disseminate his technology aswidely as possible. For instance, a licensor may bereluctant to license his competitors if he cannot limitthe licence to a particular production site with aspecific capacity (a site licence). Where the licenceagreement leads to a real integration of complementaryassets, output restrictions on the licensee may thereforefulfil the conditions of Article 81(3). However, this isunlikely to be the case where the parties have substantialmarket power.

176. Output restrictions in licence agreements betweennon-competitors are block exempted up to the marketshare threshold of 30 %. The main anti-competitive riskflowing from output restrictions on licensees inagreements between non-competitors is reduced intra-technology competition between licensees. Thesignificance of such anti-competitive effects depends onthe market position of the licensor and the licensees andthe extent to which the output limitation prevents thelicensee from satisfying demand for the products incor-porating the licensed technology.

177. When output restrictions are combined with exclusiveterritories or exclusive customer groups, the restrictiveeffects are increased. The combination of the two typesof restraints makes it more likely that the agreementserves to partition markets.

178. Output limitations imposed on the licensee in agreementsbetween non-competitors may also have pro-competitiveeffects by promoting the dissemination of technology. Asa supplier of technology, the licensor should normally befree to determine the output produced with the licensedtechnology by the licensee. If the licensor were not freeto determine the output of the licensee, a number oflicence agreements might not come into existence inthe first place, which would have a negative impact onthe dissemination of new technology. This is particularlylikely to be the case where the licensor is also a producer,since in that case the output of the licensees may findtheir way back into the licensor's main area of operationand thus have a direct impact on these activities. On theother hand, it is less likely that output restrictions arenecessary in order to ensure dissemination of thelicensor's technology when combined with salesrestrictions on the licensee prohibiting him from sellinginto a territory or customer group reserved for thelicensor.

2.4. Field of use restrictions

179. Under a field of use restriction the licence is eitherlimited to one or more technical fields of applicationor one or more product markets. There are many casesin which the same technology can be used to makedifferent products or can be incorporated into productsbelonging to different product markets. A new mouldingtechnology may for instance be used to make plasticbottles and plastic glasses, each product belonging toseparate product markets. However, a single productmarket may encompass several technical fields of use.For instance a new engine technology may beemployed in four cylinder engines and six cylinderengines. Similarly, a technology to make chipsets maybe used to produce chipsets with up to four CPUs andmore than four CPUs. A licence limiting the use of thelicensed technology to produce say four cylinder enginesand chipsets with up to four CPUs constitutes a technicalfield of use restriction.

180. Given that field of use restrictions are block exemptedand that certain customer restrictions are hardcorerestrictions under Articles 4(1)(c) and 4(2)(b) of theTTBER, it is important to distinguish the two categoriesof restraints. A customer restriction presupposes thatspecific customer groups are identified and that theparties are restricted in selling to such identifiedgroups. The fact that a technical field of use restrictionmay correspond to certain groups of customers within aproduct market does not imply that the restraint is to beclassified as a customer restriction. For instance, the factthat certain customers buy predominantly or exclusivelychipsets with more than four CPUs does not imply that alicence which is limited to chipsets with up to four CPUsconstitutes a customer restriction. However, the field ofuse must be defined objectively by reference to identifiedand meaningful technical characteristics of the licensedproduct.

181. A field of use restriction limits the exploitation of thelicensed technology by the licensee to one or moreparticular fields of use without limiting the licensor'sability to exploit the licensed technology. In addition,as with territories, these fields of use can be allocatedto the licensee under an exclusive or sole licence. Fieldof use restrictions combined with an exclusive or solelicence also restrict the licensor's ability to exploit hisown technology, by preventing him from exploiting ithimself, including by way of licensing to others. In thecase of a sole license only licensing to third parties isrestricted. Field of use restrictions combined withexclusive and sole licences are treated in the same wayas the exclusive and sole licenses dealt with in section2.2.1 above. In particular, for licensing betweencompetitors, this means that reciprocal exclusivelicensing is hardcore under Article 4(1)(c).

ENC 101/32 Official Journal of the European Union 27.4.2004

Page 32: COMMISSION NOTICE Guidelines on the application of Article 81 of

182. Field of use restrictions may have pro-competitive effectsby encouraging the licensor to license his technology forapplications that fall outside his main area of focus. If thelicensor could not prevent licensees from operating infields where he exploits the technology himself or infields where the value of the technology is not yet wellestablished, it would be likely to create a disincentive forthe licensor to license or would lead him to charge ahigher royalty. It must also be taken into account thatin certain sectors licensing often occurs to ensure designfreedom by preventing infringement claims. Within thescope of the licence the licensee is able to develop hisown technology without fearing infringement claims bythe licensor.

183. Field of use restrictions on licensees in agreementsbetween actual or potential competitors are blockexempted up to the market share threshold of 20 %.The main competitive concern in the case of suchrestrictions is the risk that the licensee ceases to be acompetitive force outside the licensed field of use. Thisrisk is greater in the case of cross licensing betweencompetitors where the agreement provides for asym-metrical field of use restrictions. A field of use restrictionis asymmetrical where one party is permitted to use thelicensed technology within one product market ortechnical field of use and the other party is permittedto use the other licensed technology within anotherproduct market or technical field of use. Competitionconcerns may in particular arise where the licensee'sproduction facility, which is tooled up to use thelicensed technology, is also used to produce with hisown technology products outside the licensed field ofuse. If the agreement is likely to lead the licensee toreduce output outside the licensed field of use, theagreement is likely to be caught by Article 81(1).Symmetrical field of use restrictions, i.e. agreementswhereby the parties are licensed to use each other's tech-nologies within the same field(s) of use, are unlikely to becaught by Article 81(1). Such agreements are unlikely torestrict competition that existed in the absence of theagreement. Article 81(1) is also unlikely to apply in thecase of agreements that merely enable the licensee todevelop and exploit his own technology within thescope of the licence without fearing infringementclaims by the licensor. In such circumstances field ofuse restrictions do not in themselves restrict competitionthat existed in the absence of the agreement. In theabsence of the agreement the licensee also riskedinfringement claims outside the scope of the licensedfield of use. However, if the licensee without businessjustification terminates or scales back his activities inthe area outside the licensed field of use this may bean indication of an underlying market sharingarrangement amounting to a hardcore restriction underArticle 4(1)(c) of the TTBER.

184. Field of use restrictions on licensee and licensor inagreements between non-competitors are blockexempted up to the market share threshold of 30 %.Field of use restrictions in agreements betweennon-competitors whereby the licensor reserves one or

more product markets or technical fields of use forhimself are generally either non-restrictive of competitionor efficiency enhancing. They promote dissemination ofnew technology by giving the licensor an incentive tolicense for exploitation in fields in which he does notwant to exploit the technology himself. If the licensorcould not prevent licensees from operating in fieldswhere the licensor exploits the technology himself, itwould be likely to create a disincentive for the licensorto licence.

185. In agreements between non-competitors the licensor isnormally also entitled to grant sole or exclusive licencesto different licensees limited to one or more fields of use.Such restrictions limit intra-technology competitionbetween licensees in the same way as exclusivelicensing and are analysed in the same way (cf. section2.2.1 above).

2.5. Captive use restrictions

186. A captive use restriction can be defined as an obligationon the licensee to limit his production of the licensedproduct to the quantities required for the production ofhis own products and for the maintenance and repair ofhis own products. In other words, this type of userestriction takes the form of an obligation on thelicensee to use the products incorporating the licensedtechnology only as an input for incorporation into hisown production; it does not cover the sale of the licensedproduct for incorporation into the products of otherproducers. Captive use restrictions are block exemptedup to the respective market share thresholds of 20 %and 30 %. Outside the scope of the block exemption itis necessary to examine what are the pro-competitive andanti-competitive effects of the restraint. In this respect itis necessary to distinguish agreements betweencompetitors from agreements between non-competitors.

187. In the case of licence agreements between competitors arestriction that imposes on the licensee to produce underthe licence only for incorporation into his own productsprevents him from being a supplier of components tothird party producers. If prior to the conclusion of theagreement, the licensee was not an actual or likelypotential supplier of components to other producers,the captive use restriction does not change anythingcompared to the pre-existing situation. In those circum-stances the restriction is assessed in the same way as inthe case of agreements between non-competitors. If, onthe other hand, the licensee is an actual or likelycomponent supplier, it is necessary to examine what isthe impact of the agreement on this activity. If by toolingup to use the licensor's technology the licensee ceases touse his own technology on a stand alone basis and thusto be a component supplier, the agreement restrictscompetition that existed prior to the agreement. It mayresult in serious negative market effects when the licensorhas a significant degree of market power on thecomponent market.

EN27.4.2004 Official Journal of the European Union C 101/33

Page 33: COMMISSION NOTICE Guidelines on the application of Article 81 of

188. In the case of licence agreements betweennon-competitors there are two main competitive risksstemming from captive use restrictions: (a) a restrictionof intra-technology competition on the market for thesupply of inputs and (b) an exclusion of arbitragebetween licensees enhancing the possibility for thelicensor to impose discriminatory royalties on licensees.

189. Captive use restrictions, however, may also promotepro-competitive licensing. If the licensor is a supplier ofcomponents, the restraint may be necessary in order forthe dissemination of technology betweennon-competitors to occur. In the absence of therestraint the licensor may not grant the licence or maydo so only against higher royalties, because otherwise hewould create direct competition to himself on thecomponent market. In such cases a captive use restrictionis normally either not restrictive of competition orcovered by Article 81(3). It is a condition, however,that the licensee is not restricted in selling the licensedproduct as replacement parts for his own products. Thelicensee must be able to serve the after market for hisown products, including independent service organi-sations that service and repair the products producedby him.

190. Where the licensor is not a component supplier on therelevant market, the above reason for imposing captiveuse restrictions does not apply. In such cases a captiveuse restriction may in principle promote the dissemi-nation of technology by ensuring that licensees do notsell to producers that compete with the licensor on othermarkets. However, a restriction on the licensee not to sellinto certain customer groups reserved for the licensornormally constitutes a less restrictive alternative.Consequently, in such cases a captive use restriction isnormally not necessary for the dissemination of tech-nology to take place.

2.6. Tying and bundling

191. In the context of technology licensing tying occurs whenthe licensor makes the licensing of one technology (thetying product) conditional upon the licensee taking alicence for another technology or purchasing a productfrom the licensor or someone designated by him (the tiedproduct). Bundling occurs where two technologies or atechnology and a product are only sold together as abundle. In both cases, however, it is a condition thatthe products and technologies involved are distinct inthe sense that there is distinct demand for each of theproducts and technologies forming part of the tie or thebundle. This is normally not the case where the tech-nologies or products are by necessity linked in such away that the licensed technology cannot be exploitedwithout the tied product or both parts of the bundlecannot be exploited without the other. In the followingthe term ‘tying’ refers to both tying and bundling.

192. Article 3 of the TTBER, which limits the application ofthe block exemption by market share thresholds, ensures

that tying and bundling are not block exempted abovethe market share thresholds of 20 % in the case ofagreements between competitors and 30 % in the caseof agreements between non-competitors. The marketshare thresholds apply to any relevant technology orproduct market affected by the licence agreement,including the market for the tied product. Above themarket share thresholds it is necessary to balance theanti-competitive and pro-competitive effects of tying.

193. The main restrictive effect of tying is foreclosure ofcompeting suppliers of the tied product. Tying mayalso allow the licensor to maintain market power inthe market for the tying product by raising barriers toentry since it may force new entrants to enter severalmarkets at the same time. Moreover, tying may allowthe licensor to increase royalties, in particular when thetying product and the tied product are partlysubstitutable and the two products are not used infixed proportion. Tying prevents the licensee fromswitching to substitute inputs in the face of increasedroyalties for the tying product. These competitionconcerns are independent of whether the parties to theagreement are competitors or not. For tying to producelikely anti-competitive effects the licensor must have asignificant degree of market power in the tying productso as to restrict competition in the tied product. In theabsence of market power in the tying product thelicensor cannot use his technology for the anti-competitive purpose of foreclosing suppliers of the tiedproduct. Furthermore, as in the case of non-competeobligations, the tie must cover a certain proportion ofthe market for the tied product for appreciable fore-closure effects to occur. In cases where the licensor hasmarket power on the market for the tied product ratherthan on the market for the tying product, the restraint isanalysed as non-compete or quantity forcing, reflectingthe fact that any competition problem has its origin onthe market for the ‘tied’ product and not on the marketfor the ‘tying’ product (66).

194. Tying can also give rise to efficiency gains. This is forinstance the case where the tied product is necessary fora technically satisfactory exploitation of the licensed tech-nology or for ensuring that production under the licenceconforms to quality standards respected by the licensorand other licensees. In such cases tying is normally eithernot restrictive of competition or covered by Article 81(3).Where the licensees use the licensor's trademark or brandname or where it is otherwise obvious to consumers thatthere is a link between the product incorporating thelicensed technology and the licensor, the licensor has alegitimate interest in ensuring that the quality of theproducts are such that it does not undermine the valueof his technology or his reputation as an economicoperator. Moreover, where it is known to consumersthat the licensees (and the licensor) produce on thebasis of the same technology it is unlikely thatlicensees would be willing to take a licence unless thetechnology is exploited by all in a technically satisfactoryway.

ENC 101/34 Official Journal of the European Union 27.4.2004

Page 34: COMMISSION NOTICE Guidelines on the application of Article 81 of

195. Tying is also likely to be pro-competitive where the tiedproduct allows the licensee to exploit the licensed tech-nology significantly more efficiently. For instance, wherethe licensor licenses a particular process technology theparties can also agree that the licensee buys a catalystfrom the licensor which is developed for use with thelicensed technology and which allows the technology tobe exploited more efficiently than in the case of othercatalysts. Where in such cases the restriction is caught byArticle 81(1), the conditions of Article 81(3) are likely tobe fulfilled even above the market share thresholds.

2.7. Non-compete obligations

196. Non-compete obligations in the context of technologylicensing take the form of an obligation on the licenseenot to use third party technologies which compete withthe licensed technology. To the extent that anon-compete obligation covers a product or additionaltechnology supplied by the licensor the obligation isdealt with in the preceding section on tying.

197. The TTBER exempts non-compete obligations both in thecase of agreements between competitors and in the caseof agreements between non-competitors up to the marketshare thresholds of 20 % and 30 % respectively.

198. The main competitive risk presented by non-competeobligations is foreclosure of third party technologies.Non-compete obligations may also facilitate collusionbetween licensors in the case of cumulative use. Fore-closure of competing technologies reduces competitivepressure on royalties charged by the licensor andreduces competition between the incumbent technologiesby limiting the possibilities for licensees to substitutebetween competing technologies. As in both cases themain problem is foreclosure, the analysis can in generalbe the same in the case of agreements betweencompetitors and agreements between non-competitors.However, in the case of cross licensing betweencompetitors where both agree not to use third partytechnologies the agreement may facilitate collusionbetween them on the product market, thereby justifyingthe lower market share threshold of 20 %.

199. Foreclosure may arise where a substantial part ofpotential licensees are already tied to one or, in thecase of cumulative effects, more sources of technologyand are prevented from exploiting competing tech-nologies. Foreclosure effects may result from agreementsconcluded by a single licensor with a significant degree ofmarket power or by a cumulative effect of agreementsconcluded by several licensors, even where each indi-vidual agreement or network of agreements is coveredby the TTBER. In the latter case, however, a seriouscumulative effect is unlikely to arise as long as lessthan 50 % of the market is tied. Above this thresholdsignificant foreclosure is likely to occur when there arerelatively high barriers to entry for new licensees. Ifbarriers to entry are low, new licensees are able toenter the market and exploit commercially attractivetechnologies held by third parties and thus represent areal alternative to incumbent licensees. In order todetermine the real possibility for entry and expansionby third parties it is also necessary to take account ofthe extent to which distributors are tied to licensees bynon-compete obligations. Third party technologies onlyhave a real possibility of entry if they have access to thenecessary production and distribution assets. In otherwords, the ease of entry depends not only on the avail-ability of licensees but also the extent to which they haveaccess to distribution. In assessing foreclosure effects atthe distribution level the Commission will apply theanalytical framework set out in section IV.2.1 of theGuidelines on Vertical Restraints (67).

200. When the licensor has a significant degree of marketpower, obligations on licensees to obtain the technologyonly from the licensor can lead to significant foreclosureeffects. The stronger the market position of the licensorthe higher the risk of foreclosing competing technologies.For appreciable foreclosure effects to occur thenon-compete obligations do not necessarily have tocover a substantial part of the market. Even in theabsence thereof, appreciable foreclosure effects mayoccur where non-compete obligations are targeted atundertakings that are the most likely to licensecompeting technologies. The risk of foreclosure isparticularly high where there is only a limited numberof potential licensees and the licence agreement concernsa technology which is used by the licensees to make aninput for their own use. In such cases the entry barriersfor a new licensor are likely to be high. Foreclosure maybe less likely in cases where the technology is used tomake a product that is sold to third parties; although inthis case the restriction also ties production capacity forthe input in question, it does not tie demand for theproduct incorporating the input produced with thelicensed technology. To enter the market in the lattercase licensors only need access to one or more licensee(s)that have suitable production capacity and unless onlyfew undertakings possess or are able to obtain theassets required to take a licence, it is unlikely that byimposing non-compete obligations on its licensees thelicensor is able to deny competitors access to efficientlicensees.

EN27.4.2004 Official Journal of the European Union C 101/35

Page 35: COMMISSION NOTICE Guidelines on the application of Article 81 of

201. Non-compete obligations may also producepro-competitive effects. First, such obligations maypromote dissemination of technology by reducing therisk of misappropriation of the licensed technology, inparticular know-how. If a licensee is entitled to licensecompeting technologies from third parties, there is a riskthat particularly licensed know-how would be used in theexploitation of competing technologies and thus benefitcompetitors. When a licensee also exploits competingtechnologies, it normally also makes monitoring ofroyalty payments more difficult, which may act as adisincentive to licensing.

202. Second, non-compete obligations possibly in combi-nation with an exclusive territory may be necessary toensure that the licensee has an incentive to invest in andexploit the licensed technology effectively. In cases wherethe agreement is caught by Article 81(1) because of anappreciable foreclosure effect, it may be necessary inorder to benefit from Article 81(3) to choose a lessrestrictive alternative, for instance to impose minimumoutput or royalty obligations, which normally have lesspotential to foreclose competing technologies.

203. Third, in cases where the licensor undertakes to makesignificant client specific investments for instance intraining and tailoring of the licensed technology to thelicensee's needs, non-compete obligations or alternativelyminimum output or minimum royalty obligations maybe necessary to induce the licensor to make theinvestment and to avoid hold-up problems. However,normally the licensor will be able to charge directly forsuch investments by way of a lump sum payment,implying that less restrictive alternatives are available.

3. Settlement and non-assertion agreements

204. Licensing may serve as a means of settling disputes oravoiding that one party exercises his intellectual propertyrights to prevent the other party from exploiting his owntechnology. Licensing including cross licensing in thecontext of settlement agreements and non-assertionagreements is not as such restrictive of competitionsince it allows the parties to exploit their technologiespost agreement. However, the individual terms andconditions of such agreements may be caught byArticle 81(1). Licensing in the context of settlementagreements is treated like other licence agreements. Inthe case of technologies that from a technical point ofview are substitutes, it is therefore necessary to assess towhat extent it is likely that the technologies in questionare in a one-way or two-way blocking position (cf.paragraph 32 above). If so, the parties are not deemedto be competitors.

205. The block exemption applies provided that the agreementdoes not contain any hardcore restrictions of competitionas set out in Article 4 of the TTBER. The hardcore list ofArticle 4(1) may in particular apply where it was clear tothe parties that no blocking position exists and thatconsequently they are competitors. In such cases thesettlement is merely a means to restrict competitionthat existed in the absence of the agreement.

206. In cases where it is likely that in the absence of thelicence the licensee could be excluded from the market,the agreement is generally pro-competitive. Restrictionsthat limit intra-technology competition between thelicensor and the licensee are often compatible withArticle 81, see section 2 above.

207. Agreements whereby the parties cross license each otherand impose restrictions on the use of their technologies,including restrictions on the licensing to third parties,may be caught by Article 81(1). Where the parties havea significant degree of market power and the agreementimposes restrictions that clearly go beyond what isrequired in order to unblock, the agreement is likely tobe caught by Article 81(1) even if it is likely that amutual blocking position exists. Article 81(1) isparticularly likely to apply where the parties sharemarkets or fix reciprocal running royalties that have asignificant impact on market prices.

208. Where under the agreement the parties are entitled to useeach other's technology and the agreement extends tofuture developments, it is necessary to assess what isthe impact of the agreement on the parties' incentiveto innovate. In cases where the parties have a significantdegree of market power the agreement is likely to becaught by Article 81(1) where the agreement preventsthe parties from gaining a competitive lead over eachother. Agreements that eliminate or substantially reducethe possibilities of one party to gain a competitive leadover the other reduce the incentive to innovate and thusadversely affect an essential part of the competitiveprocess. Such agreements are also unlikely to satisfy theconditions of Article 81(3). It is particularly unlikely thatthe restriction can be considered indispensable within themeaning of the third condition of Article 81(3). Theachievement of the objective of the agreement, namelyto ensure that the parties can continue to exploit theirown technology without being blocked by the otherparty, does not require that the parties agree to sharefuture innovations. However, the parties are unlikely tobe prevented from gaining a competitive lead over eachother where the purpose of the licence is to allow theparties to develop their respective technologies and where

ENC 101/36 Official Journal of the European Union 27.4.2004

Page 36: COMMISSION NOTICE Guidelines on the application of Article 81 of

the licence does not lead them to use the same tech-nological solutions. Such agreements merely createdesign freedom by preventing future infringementclaims by the other party.

209. In the context of a settlement and non-assertionagreement, non-challenge clauses are generally consideredto fall outside Article 81(1). It is inherent in suchagreements that the parties agree not to challenge expost the intellectual property rights covered by theagreement. Indeed, the very purpose of the agreementis to settle existing disputes and/or to avoid futuredisputes.

4. Technology pools

210. Technology pools are defined as arrangements wherebytwo or more parties assemble a package of technologywhich is licensed not only to contributors to the pool butalso to third parties. In terms of their structure tech-nology pools can take the form of simple arrangementsbetween a limited number of parties or elaborate organi-sational arrangements whereby the organisation of thelicensing of the pooled technologies is entrusted to aseparate entity. In both cases the pool may allowlicensees to operate on the market on the basis of asingle licence.

211. There is no inherent link between technology pools andstandards, but in some cases the technologies in the poolsupport (wholly or partly) a de facto or de jure industrystandard. When technology pools do support an industrystandard they do not necessarily support a singlestandard. Different technology pools may supportcompeting standards (68).

212. Agreements establishing technology pools and setting outthe terms and conditions for their operation are not —irrespective of the number of parties — covered by theblock exemption (cf. section III.2.2 above). Suchagreements are addressed only by these guidelines.Pooling arrangements give rise to a number of particularissues regarding the selection of the included technologiesand the operation of the pool, which do not arise in thecontext of other types of licensing. The individuallicences granted by the pool to third party licensees,however, are treated like other licence agreements,which are block exempted when the conditions set outin the TTBER are fulfilled, including the requirements ofArticle 4 of the TTBER containing the list of hardcorerestrictions.

213. Technology pools may be restrictive of competition. Thecreation of a technology pool necessarily implies joint

selling of the pooled technologies, which in the case ofpools composed solely or predominantly of substitutetechnologies amounts to a price fixing cartel. Moreover,in addition to reducing competition between the parties,technology pools may also, in particular when theysupport an industry standard or establish a de factoindustry standard, result in a reduction of innovationby foreclosing alternative technologies. The existence ofthe standard and the related technology pool may makeit more difficult for new and improved technologies toenter the market.

214. Technology pools can also produce pro-competitiveeffects, in particular by reducing transaction costs andby setting a limit on cumulative royalties to avoiddouble marginalisation. The creation of a pool allowsfor one-stop licensing of the technologies covered bythe pool. This is particularly important in sectors whereintellectual property rights are prevalent and where inorder to operate on the market licences need to beobtained from a significant number of licensors. Incases where licensees receive on-going servicesconcerning the application of the licensed technology,joint licensing and servicing can lead to further costreductions.

4.1. The nature of the pooled technologies

215. The competitive risks and the efficiency enhancingpotential of technology pools depend to a large extenton the relationship between the pooled technologies andtheir relationship with technologies outside the pool.Two basic distinctions must be made, namely (a)between technological complements and technologicalsubstitutes and (b) between essential and non-essentialtechnologies.

216. Two technologies (69) are complements as opposed tosubstitutes when they are both required to produce theproduct or carry out the process to which the tech-nologies relate. Conversely, two technologies aresubstitutes when either technology allows the holder toproduce the product or carry out the process to whichthe technologies relate. A technology is essential asopposed to non-essential if there are no substitutes forthat technology inside or outside the pool and the tech-nology in question constitutes a necessary part of thepackage of technologies for the purposes of producingthe product(s) or carrying out the process(es) to whichthe pool relates. A technology for which there are nosubstitutes, remains essential as long as the technologyis covered by at least one valid intellectual property right.Technologies that are essential are by necessity alsocomplements.

EN27.4.2004 Official Journal of the European Union C 101/37

Page 37: COMMISSION NOTICE Guidelines on the application of Article 81 of

217. When technologies in a pool are substitutes, royalties arelikely to be higher than they would otherwise be, becauselicensees do not benefit from rivalry between the tech-nologies in question. When the technologies in the poolare complements the arrangement reduces transactioncosts and may lead to lower overall royalties becausethe parties are in a position to fix a common royaltyfor the package as opposed to each fixing a royaltywhich does not take account of the royalty fixed byothers.

218. The distinction between complementary and substitutetechnologies is not clear-cut in all cases, since tech-nologies may be substitutes in part and complementsin part. When due to efficiencies stemming from theintegration of two technologies licensees are likely todemand both technologies the technologies are treatedas complements even if they are partly substitutable. Insuch cases it is likely that in the absence of the poollicensees would want to licence both technologies dueto the additional economic benefit of employing bothtechnologies as opposed to employing only one of them.

219. The inclusion in the pool of substitute technologiesrestricts inter-technology competition and amounts tocollective bundling. Moreover, where the pool issubstantially composed of substitute technologies, thearrangement amounts to price fixing betweencompetitors. As a general rule the Commissionconsiders that the inclusion of substitute technologiesin the pool constitutes a violation of Article 81(1). TheCommission also considers that it is unlikely that theconditions of Article 81(3) will be fulfilled in the caseof pools comprising to a significant extent substitutetechnologies. Given that the technologies in questionare alternatives, no transaction cost savings accrue fromincluding both technologies in the pool. In the absence ofthe pool licensees would not have demanded both tech-nologies. It is not sufficient that the parties remain free tolicense independently. In order not to undermine thepool, which allows them to jointly exercise marketpower, the parties are likely to have little incentive todo so.

220. When a pool is composed only of technologies that areessential and therefore by necessity also complements,the creation of the pool as such generally falls outsideArticle 81(1) irrespective of the market position of theparties. However, the conditions on which licences aregranted may be caught by Article 81(1).

221. Where non-essential but complementary patents areincluded in the pool there is a risk of foreclosure ofthird party technologies. Once a technology is includedin the pool and is licensed as part of the package,licensees are likely to have little incentive to license acompeting technology when the royalty paid for thepackage already covers a substitute technology.Moreover, the inclusion of technologies which are notnecessary for the purposes of producing the product(s)or carrying out the process(es) to which the technologypool relates also forces licensees to pay for technologythat they may not need. The inclusion of complementarypatents thus amounts to collective bundling. When apool encompasses non-essential technologies, theagreement is likely to be caught by Article 81(1) wherethe pool has a significant position on any relevantmarket.

222. Given that substitute and complementary technologiesmay be developed after the creation of the pool, theassessment of essentiality is an on-going process. A tech-nology may therefore become non-essential after thecreation of the pool due to the emergence of new thirdparty technologies. One way to ensure that such thirdparty technologies are not foreclosed is to exclude fromthe pool technologies that have become non-essential.However, there may be other ways to ensure that thirdparty technologies are not foreclosed. In the assessmentof technology pools comprising non-essential tech-nologies, i.e. technologies for which substitutes existoutside the pool or which are not necessary in order toproduce one or more products to which the pool relates,the Commission will in its overall assessment, inter alia,take account of the following factors:

(a) whether there are any pro-competitive reasons forincluding the non-essential technologies in the pool;

(b) whether the licensors remain free to license theirrespective technologies independently. Where thepool is composed of a limited number of tech-nologies and there are substitute technologiesoutside the pool, licensees may want to puttogether their own technological package composedpartly of technology forming part of the pool andpartly of technology owned by third parties;

ENC 101/38 Official Journal of the European Union 27.4.2004

Page 38: COMMISSION NOTICE Guidelines on the application of Article 81 of

(c) whether, in cases where the pooled technologies havedifferent applications some of which do not requireuse of all of the pooled technologies, the pool offersthe technologies only as a single package or whetherit offers separate packages for distinct applications. Inthe latter case it is avoided that technologies whichare not essential to a particular product or processare tied to essential technologies;

(d) whether the pooled technologies are available only asa single package or whether licensees have the possi-bility of obtaining a licence for only part of thepackage with a corresponding reduction of royalties.The possibility to obtain a licence for only part of thepackage may reduce the risk of foreclosure of thirdparty technologies outside the pool, in particularwhere the licensee obtains a correspondingreduction in royalties. This requires that a share ofthe overall royalty has been assigned to each tech-nology in the pool. Where the licence agreementsconcluded between the pool and individual licenseesare of relatively long duration and the pooled tech-nology supports a de facto industry standard, it mustalso be taken into account that the pool mayforeclose access to the market of new substitute tech-nologies. In assessing the risk of foreclosure in suchcases it is relevant to take into account whether ornot licensees can terminate at reasonable notice partof the licence and obtain a corresponding reductionof royalties.

4.2. Assessment of individual restraints

223. The purpose of this section is to address a certainnumber of restraints that in one form or another arecommonly found in technology pools and which needto be assessed in the overall context of the pool. It isrecalled, cf. paragraph 212 above, that the TTBER appliesto licence agreements concluded between the pool andthird party licensees. This section is therefore limited toaddressing the creation of the pool and licensing issuesthat are particular to licensing in the context of tech-nology pools.

224. In making its assessment the Commission will be guidedby the following main principles:

1. The stronger the market position of the pool thegreater the risk of anti-competitive effects.

2. Pools that hold a strong position on the marketshould be open and non-discriminatory.

3. Pools should not unduly foreclose third party tech-nologies or limit the creation of alternative pools.

225. Undertakings setting up a technology pool that iscompatible with Article 81, and any industry standardthat it may support, are normally free to negotiate andfix royalties for the technology package and each tech-nology's share of the royalties either before or after thestandard is set. Such agreement is inherent in the estab-lishment of the standard or pool and cannot in itself beconsidered restrictive of competition and may in certaincircumstances lead to more efficient outcomes. In certaincircumstances it may be more efficient if the royalties areagreed before the standard is chosen and not after thestandard is decided upon, to avoid that the choice of thestandard confers a significant degree of market power onone or more essential technologies. On the other hand,licensees must remain free to determine the price ofproducts produced under the licence. Where theselection of technologies to be included in the pool iscarried out by an independent expert this may furthercompetition between available technological solutions.

226. Where the pool has a dominant position on the market,royalties and other licensing terms should be fair andnon-discriminatory and licences should be non-exclusive.These requirements are necessary to ensure that the poolis open and does not lead to foreclosure and other anti-competitive effects on down stream markets. Theserequirements, however, do not preclude differentroyalties for different uses. It is in general not consideredrestrictive of competition to apply different royalty ratesto different product markets, whereas there should be nodiscrimination within product markets. In particular, thetreatment of licensees should not depend on whetherthey are licensors or not. The Commission willtherefore take into account whether licensors are alsosubject to royalty obligations.

227. Licensors and licensees must be free to developcompeting products and standards and must also befree to grant and obtain licences outside the pool.These requirements are necessary in order to limit therisk of foreclosure of third party technologies and ensurethat the pool does not limit innovation and preclude thecreation of competing technological solutions. Where apool supports a (de facto) industry standard and where theparties are subject to non-compete obligations, the poolcreates a particular risk of preventing the development ofnew and improved technologies and standards.

EN27.4.2004 Official Journal of the European Union C 101/39

Page 39: COMMISSION NOTICE Guidelines on the application of Article 81 of

228. Grant back obligations should be non-exclusive and belimited to developments that are essential or important tothe use of the pooled technology. This allows the pool tofeed on and benefit from improvements to the pooledtechnology. It is legitimate for the parties to ensure thatthe exploitation of the pooled technology cannot be heldup by licensees that hold or obtain essential patents.

229. One of the problems identified with regard to patentpools is the risk that they shield invalid patents.Pooling raises the costs/risks for a successful challenge,because the challenge fails if only one patent in the poolis valid. The shielding of invalid patents in the pool mayoblige licensees to pay higher royalties and may alsoprevent innovation in the field covered by an invalidpatent. In order to limit this risk any right to terminatea licence in the case of a challenge must be limited to thetechnologies owned by the licensor who is the addresseeof the challenge and must not extend to the technologiesowned by the other licensors in the pool.

4.3. The institutional framework governing the pool

230. The way in which a technology pool is created, organisedand operated can reduce the risk of it having the objector effect of restricting competition and provideassurances to the effect that the arrangement ispro-competitive.

231. When participation in a standard and pool creationprocess is open to all interested parties representingdifferent interests it is more likely that technologies forinclusion into the pool are selected on the basis of price/quality considerations than when the pool is set up by alimited group of technology owners. Similarly, when therelevant bodies of the pool are composed of personsrepresenting different interests, it is more likely thatlicensing terms and conditions, including royalties, willbe open and non-discriminatory and reflect the value ofthe licensed technology than when the pool is controlledby licensor representatives.

232. Another relevant factor is the extent to which inde-pendent experts are involved in the creation andoperation of the pool. For instance, the assessment ofwhether or not a technology is essential to a standardsupported by a pool is often a complex matter thatrequires special expertise. The involvement in theselection process of independent experts can go a longway in ensuring that a commitment to include onlyessential technologies is implemented in practice.

233. The Commission will take into account how experts areselected and what are the exact functions that they are toperform. Experts should be independent from the under-takings that have formed the pool. If experts areconnected to the licensors or otherwise depend onthem, the involvement of the expert will be given lessweight. Experts must also have the necessary technicalexpertise to perform the various functions with whichthey have been entrusted. The functions of independentexperts may include, in particular, an assessment ofwhether or not technologies put forward for inclusioninto the pool are valid and whether or not they areessential.

234. It is also relevant to consider the arrangements forexchanging sensitive information among the parties. Inoligopolistic markets exchanges of sensitive informationsuch as pricing and output data may facilitatecollusion (70). In such cases the Commission will takeinto account to what extent safeguards have been putin place, which ensure that sensitive information is notexchanged. An independent expert or licensing body mayplay an important role in this respect by ensuring thatoutput and sales data, which may be necessary for thepurposes of calculating and verifying royalties is notdisclosed to undertakings that compete on affectedmarkets.

235. Finally, it is relevant to take account of the disputeresolution mechanism foreseen in the instrumentssetting up the pool. The more dispute resolution isentrusted to bodies or persons that are independent ofthe pool and the members thereof, the more likely it isthat the dispute resolution will operate in a neutral way.

(1) OJ L 123, 27.4.2004. The TTBER replaces Commission Regulation (EC) No 240/96 of 31 January 1996 on theapplication of Article 85(3) of the Treaty to certain categories of technology transfer agreements (OJ L 31, 9.2.1996,p. 2).

(2) See Joined Cases C-395/96 P and C-396/96 P, Compagnie Maritime Belge, [2000] ECR I-1365, paragraph 130, andparagraph 106 of the Commission Guidelines on the application of Article 81(3) of the Treaty, not yet published.

(3) Council Regulation (EC) No 1/2003 on the implementation of the rules on competition laid down in Articles 81and 82 of the Treaty (OJ L 1, 4.1.2003, p. 1).

(4) In the following the term ‘agreement’ includes concerted practices and decisions of associations of undertakings.

(5) See Commission Notice on the concept of effect on trade between Member States contained in Articles 81 and 82of the Treaty, not yet published.

ENC 101/40 Official Journal of the European Union 27.4.2004

Page 40: COMMISSION NOTICE Guidelines on the application of Article 81 of

(6) In the following the term ‘restriction’ includes the prevention and distortion of competition.

(7) This principle of Community exhaustion is for example enshrined in Article 7(1) of Directive 104/89/EEC toapproximate the laws of the Member States relating to trade marks (OJ L 40, 11.2.1989, p. 1), which providesthat the trade mark shall not entitle the proprietor to prohibit its use in relation to goods which have been put onthe market in the Community under that trade mark by the proprietor or with his consent.

(8) On the other hand, the sale of copies of a protected work does not lead to the exhaustion of performance rights,including rental rights, in the work, see in this respect Case 158/86, Warner Brothers and Metronome Video, [1988]ECR 2605, and Case C-61/97, Foreningen af danske videogramdistributører, [1998] ECR I-5171.

(9) See e.g. Joined Cases 56/64 and 58/64, Consten and Grundig, [1966] ECR 429.

(10) The methodology for the application of Article 81(3) is set out in the Commission Guidelines on the application ofArticle 81(3) of the Treaty cited in note 2.

(11) See Case 56/65, Société Technique Minière, [1966] ECR 337, and Case C-7/95 P, John Deere, [1998] ECR I-3111,paragraph 76.

(12) See in this respect e.g. judgment in Consten and Grundig cited in note 9.

(13) See in this respect the judgment in Société Technique Minière cited in note 11 and Case 258/78, Nungesser, [1982]ECR 2015.

(14) See in this respect e.g. Case C-49/92 P, Anic Partecipazioni, [1999] ECR I-4125, paragraph 99.

(15) See Joined Cases 29/83 and 30/83, CRAM and Rheinzink, [1984] ECR 1679, paragraph 26, and Joined Cases 96/82and others, ANSEAU-NAVEWA, [1983] ECR 3369, paragraphs 23-25.

(16) See the judgment in John Deere, [1998] cited in note 11.

(17) Guidance on the issue of appreciability can be found in Commission notice on agreements of minor importancewhich do not appreciably restrict competition under Article 81(1) of the Treaty (OJ C 368, 22.12.2001, p. 13). Thenotice defines appreciability in a negative way. Agreements, which fall outside the scope of the de minimis notice, donot necessarily have appreciable restrictive effects. An individual assessment is required.

(18) See Article 1(2) of Council Regulation No 1/2003 cited in note 3.

(19) Commission notice on the definition of the relevant market for the purposes of Community competition law (OJ C372, 9.12.1997, p. 5).

(20) As to these distinctions see also Commission Guidelines on the applicability of Article 81 of the EC Treaty tohorizontal cooperation agreements (OJ C 3, 6.1.2001, p. 2, paragraphs 44 to 52).

(21) See to that effect paragraphs 50 to 52 of the Guidelines on horizontal cooperation agreements, cited in the previousnote.

(22) Idem, paragraph 51.

(23) See in this respect the Notice on agreements of minor importance cited in note 17.

(24) According to Article 3(2) of Regulation 1/2003, agreements which may affect trade between Member States butwhich are not prohibited by Article 81 cannot be prohibited by national competition law.

(25) Under Council Regulation 19/65, OJ Special Edition Series I 1965-1966, p. 35, the Commission is not empoweredto block exempt technology transfer agreements concluded between more than two undertakings.

(26) See recital 19 of the TTBER and further section 2.5 below.

(27) OJ C 1, 3.1.1979, p. 2.

(28) See paragraph 3 of the subcontracting notice.

(29) See in this respect Commission Decision in Moosehead/Whitbread (OJ L 100, 20.4.1990, p. 32).

(30) See in this respect Case 262/81, Coditel (II), [1982] ECR 3381.

(31) OJ L 336, 29.12.1999, p. 21.

(32) OJ L 304, 5.12.2000, p. 3.

(33) OJ L 304, 5.12.2000, p. 7.

(34) See note 31.

(35) See the guide ‘Competition policy in Europe — The competition rules for supply and distribution agreements’,2002.

(36) OJ C 291, 13.10.2000, p. 1, and note 31.

(37) See paragraph 29 above.

EN27.4.2004 Official Journal of the European Union C 101/41

Page 41: COMMISSION NOTICE Guidelines on the application of Article 81 of

(38) The reasons for this calculation rule are explained in paragraph 23 above.

(39) See e.g. the case law cited in note 15.

(40) See in this respect paragraph 98 of the Guidelines on the application of Article 81(3) of the Treaty cited in note 2.

(41) This is also the case where one party grants a licence to the other party and accepts to buy a physical input fromthe licensee. The purchase price can serve the same function as the royalty.

(42) See in this respect Case 193/83, Windsurfing International, [1986] ECR 611, paragraph 67.

(43) For a general definition of active and passive sales, reference is made to paragraph 50 of the Guidelines on verticalrestraints cited in note 36.

(44) Field of use restrictions are further dealt with in section IV.2.4 below.

(45) This hardcore restriction applies to licence agreements concerning trade within the Community. As regardsagreements concerning exports outside the Community or imports/re-imports from outside the Community seeCase C-306/96, Javico, [1998] ECR I-1983.

(46) See in this respect paragraph 77 of the judgment in Nungesser cited in note 13.

(47) See in this respect Case 26/76, Metro (I), [1977] ECR 1875.

(48) If the licensed technology is outdated no restriction of competition arises, see in this respect Case 65/86, Bayer vSüllhofer, [1988] ECR 5249.

(49) As to non-challenge clauses in the context of settlement agreements see point 209 below.

(50) See paragraph 14 above.

(51) See paragraphs 66 and 67 above.

(52) See in this respect paragraph 42 of the Guidelines on the application of Article 81(3) of the Treaty, cited in note 2.

(53) See in this respect paragraph 8 of the Commission Notice on agreements of minor importance, cited in note 17.

(54) See in this respect Case T-228/97, Irish Sugar, [1999] ECR II-2969, paragraph 101.

(55) See in this respect paragraph 23 of the Guidelines on horizontal cooperation agreements, cited in note 20.

(56) See Joined Cases 25/84 and 26/84, Ford, [1985] ECR 2725.

(57) See in this respect for example Commission Decision in TPS (OJ L 90, 2.4.1999, p. 6). Similarly, the prohibition ofArticle 81(1) also only applies as long as the agreement has a restrictive object or restrictive effects.

(58) Cited in note 36. See in particular paragraphs 115 et seq.

(59) As to these concepts see section IV.4.1 below.

(60) See paragraph 85 of the Guidelines on the application of Article 81(3) of the Treaty, cited in note 2.

(61) Idem, paragraphs 98 and 102.

(62) See paragraph 130 of the judgment cited in note 2. Similarly, the application of Article 81(3) does not prevent theapplication of the Treaty rules on the free movement of goods, services, persons and capital. These provisions are incertain circumstances applicable to agreements, decisions and concerted practices within the meaning of Article81(1), see to that effect Case C-309/99, Wouters, [2002] ECR I-1577, paragraph 120.

(63) See in this respect Case T-51/89, Tetra Pak (I), [1990] ECR II-309. See also paragraph 106 of the Guidelines on theapplication of Article 81(3) of the Treaty cited in note 2 above.

(64) See the judgment in Nungesser cited in note 13.

(65) See in this respect the Commission's Notice in the Canon/Kodak Case (OJ C 330, 1.11.1997, p. 10) and the IGRStereo Television Case mentioned in the XI Report on Competition Policy, paragraph 94.

(66) For the applicable analytical framework see section 2.7 below and paragraphs 138 et seq. of the Guidelines onVertical Restraints cited in note 36.

(67) See note 36.

(68) See in this respect the Commission's press release IP/02/1651 concerning the licensing of patents for thirdgeneration (3G) mobile services. This case involved five technology pools creating five different technologies,each of which could be used to produce 3G equipment.

(69) The term ‘technology’ is not limited to patents. It covers also patent applications and intellectual property rightsother than patents.

(70) See in this respect the judgment in John Deere cited in note 11.

ENC 101/42 Official Journal of the European Union 27.4.2004