collusive price rigidity under price- matching...

29
ISSN 1745-9648 Collusive Price Rigidity under Price- Matching Punishments Luke Garrod School of Business and Economics, Loughborough University CCP Working Paper 11-14 Abstract: In this paper we provide game theoretic support for the results of the kinked demand curve. By analysing an infinitely repeated game where unit costs fluctuate stochastically between a low and a high state over time and where firms follow a price-matching punishment strategy, we demonstrate that price rigidity can occur in the best collusive subgame perfect Nash equilibrium for small fluctuations in costs. The critical level of high costs under which the best collusive prices are rigid is shown to depend upon the expected duration of a sequence of high-cost periods, the number of firms in the market, and the degree of product differentiation. September 2011 JEL Codes: L11; L13; L41 Keywords: Tacit collusion; kinked demand curve; price rigidity. Acknowledgements: I am grateful for comments from Iwan Bos, Steve Davies, Joe Harrington, Morten Hviid, Roman Inderst, Kai-Uwe Kühn, Bruce Lyons, Patrick Rey, Paul Seabright, Christopher M. Wilson, and seminar participants at the International Industrial Organization Conference 2011 and the European Association of Research in Industrial Economics Conference 2011. The support of the Economic and Social Research Council (UK) is gratefully acknowledged. The usual disclaimer applies.

Upload: others

Post on 31-May-2020

8 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Collusive Price Rigidity under Price- Matching Punishmentscompetitionpolicy.ac.uk/documents/107435/0/ccp11-14.pdf · Keywords: Tacit collusion, kinked demand curve, price rigidity

ISSN 1745-9648

Collusive Price Rigidity under Price-

Matching Punishments

Luke Garrod School of Business and Economics, Loughborough

University

CCP Working Paper 11-14

Abstract: In this paper we provide game theoretic support for the results of the kinked demand curve. By analysing an infinitely repeated game where unit costs fluctuate stochastically between a low and a high state over time and where firms follow a price-matching punishment strategy, we demonstrate that price rigidity can occur in the best collusive subgame perfect Nash equilibrium for small fluctuations in costs. The critical level of high costs under which the best collusive prices are rigid is shown to depend upon the expected duration of a sequence of high-cost periods, the number of firms in the market, and the degree of product differentiation. September 2011

JEL Codes: L11; L13; L41 Keywords: Tacit collusion; kinked demand curve; price rigidity. Acknowledgements: I am grateful for comments from Iwan Bos, Steve Davies, Joe Harrington, Morten Hviid, Roman Inderst, Kai-Uwe Kühn, Bruce Lyons, Patrick Rey, Paul Seabright, Christopher M. Wilson, and seminar participants at the International Industrial Organization Conference 2011 and the European Association of Research in Industrial Economics Conference 2011. The support of the Economic and Social Research Council (UK) is gratefully acknowledged. The usual disclaimer applies.

Page 2: Collusive Price Rigidity under Price- Matching Punishmentscompetitionpolicy.ac.uk/documents/107435/0/ccp11-14.pdf · Keywords: Tacit collusion, kinked demand curve, price rigidity

2

Contact Details: Luke Garrod, School of Business and Economics, Loughborough University, Loughborough, Leicestershire, LE11 3TU, United Kingdom, email: [email protected]

Page 3: Collusive Price Rigidity under Price- Matching Punishmentscompetitionpolicy.ac.uk/documents/107435/0/ccp11-14.pdf · Keywords: Tacit collusion, kinked demand curve, price rigidity

Collusive Price Rigidity under Price-Matching

Punishments�

Luke Garrody

September 2011

Abstract

In this paper we provide game theoretic support for the results of the kinked

demand curve. By analysing an in�nitely repeated game where unit costs �uc-

tuate stochastically between a low and a high state over time and where �rms

follow a price-matching punishment strategy, we demonstrate that price rigidity

can occur in the best collusive subgame perfect Nash equilibrium for small �uc-

tuations in costs. The critical level of high costs under which the best collusive

prices are rigid is shown to depend upon the expected duration of a sequence of

high-cost periods, the number of �rms in the market, and the degree of product

di¤erentiation.

Keywords: Tacit collusion, kinked demand curve, price rigidity

JEL: L11, L13, L41

1 Introduction

There has been a long-standing belief in industrial economics that tacit collusion

and price rigidity are linked. This belief was �rst formalised by the old theory of the

kinked demand curve (Hall and Hitch, 1939; and Sweezy, 1939). This theory assumes

that a �rm expects its rivals will continue to set a certain focal price if it charges

more than this focal level, but expects its rivals will match any price set below this

focal level. Consequently, the �rm�s demand curve is kinked at the focal price, and

the resultant discontinuity in its marginal revenue curve implies that prices remain

at the focal level for small cost �uctuations. Although the assumed rivalry has an

�I am grateful for comments from Iwan Bos, Steve Davies, Joe Harrington, Morten Hviid, RomanInderst, Kai-Uwe Kühn, Bruce Lyons, Patrick Rey, Paul Seabright, Christopher M. Wilson, andseminar participants at the International Industrial Organization Conference 2011 and the EuropeanAssociation of Research in Industrial Economics Conference 2011. The support of the Economicand Social Research Council (UK) is gratefully acknowledged. The usual disclaimer applies.

ySchool of Business and Economics, Loughborough University, Loughborough, Leicestershire,LE11 3TU, United Kingdom, email: [email protected]

1

Page 4: Collusive Price Rigidity under Price- Matching Punishmentscompetitionpolicy.ac.uk/documents/107435/0/ccp11-14.pdf · Keywords: Tacit collusion, kinked demand curve, price rigidity

intuitive appeal and some anecdotal support, the kinked demand curve has been

heavily criticised (for example see Tirole, 1988, p.243-245).

More recently, the way in which dynamic oligopolistic interaction has been mod-

elled di¤ers in two respects with the kinked demand curve. First, it is modelled as

an explicit dynamic game using the theory of repeated games, where collusive prices

are sustainable when the short-term bene�t from any deviation is outweighed by

a credible and su¢ ciently harsh long-term retaliation. Second, �rms usually more

than match lower deviation prices, because the most commonly analysed retaliations

are �Nash reversion�(see Friedman, 1971) and �optimal punishment strategies�(see

Abreu, 1986, 1988). Since market conditions can a¤ect the deviant�s gains and its

rivals�retaliation, there is a theoretical literature that analyses how market �uctua-

tions a¤ect the best collusive prices that achieve the highest levels of pro�t possible

(for example see Rotemberg and Saloner, 1986; Haltiwanger and Harrington, 1991).1

One feature of this literature is that, barring the special circumstances when incen-

tives are perfectly aligned, the best collusive prices vary with �uctuations of any

size. This is in contrast with the belief that tacit collusion and price rigidity are

linked, and it is at odds with the results of the kinked demand curve.

In contrast to the previous repeated game literature, in this paper we provide

game theoretic support for the results of the kinked demand curve by showing that

the best collusive prices can be rigid in an in�nitely repeated game for small industry-

wide cost �uctuations. We derive this result by extending Lu and Wright (2010)

who analyse an in�nitely repeated game under price-matching punishments where,

similar to the rivalry of the kinked demand curve, �rms match lower deviation

prices (provided they are above the one-shot Nash price). They show that price-

matching punishments can support collusive prices when products are symmetrically

di¤erentiated and market conditions do not vary over time. We extend their model

so that unit costs �uctuate stochastically between a high and a low state over time,

and show that the best collusive prices can be rigid over time.

The intuition is that when costs are temporarily high today but are permanently

low in the future, for any price today that is above the future�s price there is a

unilateral incentive to set the future�s price today (provided today�s one-shot Nash

price is below the future�s price). This is because under price-matching punishments

the future�s price is set in the future whether there is such a deviation today or not.

When high costs persist into the future, price matching such a deviation does reduce

pro�ts in future high-cost periods, and the pro�tability of such a deviation decreases

as the high-cost level increases. As a result, procyclical prices are supportable when

cost �uctuations are su¢ ciently large. Since an increased likelihood of future high-

1Although much of the previous literature focuses on demand �uctuations, many of the resultsgeneralise to cost �uctuations.

2

Page 5: Collusive Price Rigidity under Price- Matching Punishmentscompetitionpolicy.ac.uk/documents/107435/0/ccp11-14.pdf · Keywords: Tacit collusion, kinked demand curve, price rigidity

cost periods also makes such a deviation less pro�table, the critical level of high

costs under which the best collusive prices are rigid is monotonically decreasing in

the expected duration of a sequence of high-cost periods, and prices are not rigid

when costs are permanently high in the future.

Given our model is based on game theoretic foundations, it generates richer

predictions than the kinked demand curve regarding how prices and pro�ts respond

to the other parameters of the model. There exists a unique price that achieves the

highest level of pro�t given the constraint that the price does not vary with costs.

This price de�nes the best collusive price in both cost states when �uctuations are

small, and it is always between the high-cost one-shot Nash price and the low-cost

monopoly level under such conditions. It monotonically increases with the level of

high costs, but only a small proportion of the high costs are passed through via a

higher price. Consequently, as �uctuations become more pronounced, low-cost per-

period pro�ts increase but high-cost per-period pro�ts decrease. When considered

over time, this increase in pro�t is outweighed by the decrease, so each �rm�s present

discounted value of collusive pro�ts is decreasing in the level of high costs despite

the higher price.

Our model also generates predictions regarding the relationship between price

rigidity and the number of �rms in the market, which has been investigated by several

empirical studies (for example see Carlton, 1986, 1989). This relationship ultimately

depends upon the degree of product di¤erentiation. Based on an example where

demand is derived from the constant elasticity of substitution version of Spence-

Dixit-Stiglitz preferences (Spence, 1976; and Dixit and Stiglitz, 1977), we show

that the best collusive prices are rigid for reasonably large cost �uctuations when

products are di¤erentiated by a intermediate degree. This is because price-matching

punishments do not support collusive prices when products are homogeneous and

since �rms are unconcerned by rivals�responses when they are local monopolies. This

example also shows that the best collusive prices are rigid for larger cost �uctuations

as the number of �rms decreases when products are su¢ ciently substitutable.

The rest of the paper is structured as follows. Section 2 reviews the related

literature and provides anecdotal support for a link between price matching and

price rigidity. Section 3 outlines the assumptions on demand and costs, and it

formally de�nes the price-matching punishment strategy. In section 4 we derive the

conditions where the best collusive prices are rigid, and investigate the relationship

between price rigidity and the expected duration of a sequence of high-cost periods,

as well as considering the e¤ects of cost �uctuations and price rigidity on the best

collusive pro�ts. Section 5 places more structure on demand to investigate how price

rigidity relates to both the number of �rms in the market and the degree of product

di¤erentiation, and section 6 concludes. All proofs are relegated to the appendix.

3

Page 6: Collusive Price Rigidity under Price- Matching Punishmentscompetitionpolicy.ac.uk/documents/107435/0/ccp11-14.pdf · Keywords: Tacit collusion, kinked demand curve, price rigidity

2 Related Literature and Evidence

In this paper we propose that the expectation that deviation prices will be matched

can lead to price rigidity during collusive phases, and there is some anecdotal support

for this. Slade (1987, 1992) analysed a price war between gasoline retailers during

1983 in Vancouver (see also Slade, 1990). During the price war, she found there was

�a high degree of (lagged) price matching�and �prices before and after the war were

uniform across �rms and stable over time� (1992, p.264). In fact, �after the price

war came to an end, prices were stable for nearly a year�(1987, p.515). Slade (1989,

p.295) also argues that other Canadian markets (including nickel and cigarette, as

well as gasoline) had three stylised facts: �First, price is the choice variable and it

can be observed by all. Second, price wars are occasional events and are separated

by periods of stable prices. Third, during a war there is considerable matching of

prices�. Similarly, Kalai and Sattherwaite (1994) state that between 1900 and 1958

small �rms in the US steel industry believed the largest producer would match their

prices if they undercut it, and observed that �Before World War II certain classes

of steel products showed remarkable price rigidity�(p.31).2

Although informal reasoning suggests that �rms would prefer the harshest pun-

ishment, since it makes collusion easier to sustain, the above evidence suggests that,

in at least some situations, price matching is a relevant form of �rm behaviour. Of

particular importance in this regard is Slade�s (1987) empirical evidence that �nds

some support for punishment strategies, similar to price matching, where �small

deviations lead to small punishments�over Nash reversion (p.499). The above evi-

dence also suggests that our price rigidity result may be of some empirical relevance

for such situations where price matching is prevalent. This contrasts with previous

attempts to model the kinked demand curve in dynamic settings, because they do

not �nd a link between price matching and price rigidity.3

Our model also contrasts with the literature that analyses collusion under market

�uctuations. Rotemberg and Saloner (1986) show that collusion under Nash rever-

sion is harder to support in a period of boom than bust when future �uctuations

are independently and identically distributed. This is because the deviant�s gains

2Levenstein (1997) and Genesove and Mullin (2001) also �nd that some cartel price wars consistedof mild punishments and price matching, respectively, but due to infrequent price observations it isnot possible to determine the extent to which prices �uctuate over time.

3Bhaskar (1988) and Kalai and Satterthwaite (1994) show that price rigidity does not occur ina one-shot game when lower prices can be matched immediately before pro�ts are realised. In anin�nitely repeated game where a dupoly alternates between commiting to price for two periods,Maskin and Tirole (1988) argue that price rigidity can occur to avoid a price war when costs fallpermanently. However, this is because rivals more than match lower prices. In another relatedin�nitely repeated game, Slade (1989) captures the three stylised facts discussed above when anunexpected change in demand is anticipated to be permanent, but stable prices only occur in hermodel when the new equilibrium is reached.

4

Page 7: Collusive Price Rigidity under Price- Matching Punishmentscompetitionpolicy.ac.uk/documents/107435/0/ccp11-14.pdf · Keywords: Tacit collusion, kinked demand curve, price rigidity

are largest in a boom but the punishment remains the same. This implies that the

best collusive prices move procyclically with costs, because any price that is just

supportable in a high-cost period is not be supportable in a low-cost period. Due

to a similar reason, the incentive to deviate from a rigid price under price-matching

punishments is greatest in low-cost periods when future �uctuations are independent

of or positively correlated with the current level. However, this incentive does not

always translate into procyclical prices. This is because deviating from a procyclical

price in a high-cost period by setting the low-cost price limits the punishment a

�rm receives to future high-cost periods. Therefore, the deviant�s gains for a small

deviation from a price only slightly above the low-cost price is e¤ectively the same

as that for a small deviation from the low-cost price, but the punishment can be

much weaker. As a result, the low-cost price is supportable in a high-cost period,

but a price only slightly above the low-cost price may not be.

Finally, this paper is also related to Athey et al (2004) who develop an alter-

native model of collusive price rigidity where prices are publically observable but

�rms experience privately observed shocks to unit costs in each period. They show

that under Nash reversion the best collusive prices may be rigid over time because,

although demand is not allocated to the most e¢ cient �rm, this ine¢ ciency can be

outweighed by the bene�t of detecting deviations easily.4 Their model is similar

to Green and Porter (1984) since, due to some information asymmetry, price wars

occur on the equilibrium path when �rms receive a bad signal. In contrast, there is

symmetric information in our model, so price wars do not occur on the equilibrium

path. Instead, the successfulness of collusion is a¤ected by market conditions in a

similar way as Rotemberg and Saloner (1986). Our model adds to our understand-

ing of price rigidity because it is the �rst (to the author�s knowledge) to consider

the relationship between price rigidity and the degree of product di¤erentiation,

and given it does not rely on parameters that are likely to be unobservable to an

econometrician, it can be tested empirically.

3 The Model

3.1 Basic assumptions

Consider a market where a �xed number of n � 2 �rms each produce a single

di¤erentiated product and compete in observable prices over an in�nite number of

periods. In any period t, �rms have identical unit costs, ct � 0, face no �xed costs,and have a common discount factor, � 2 (0; 1). They simultaneously choose price in

4 In a similar model, Hanazono and Yang (2007) show that price rigidity can also occur withunobservable demand �uctuations.

5

Page 8: Collusive Price Rigidity under Price- Matching Punishmentscompetitionpolicy.ac.uk/documents/107435/0/ccp11-14.pdf · Keywords: Tacit collusion, kinked demand curve, price rigidity

each period and the demand of �rm i = 1; : : : ; n in period t is qi(pit;p�it; n) where

pit is its own price and p�it is the vector of its rivals�prices. Demand is symmetric,

strictly decreasing in pit and limpit!1 qi(pit;p�it; n) = 0. Since �rms are symmetric,

at equal prices pit = pt for all i, qi(pt; pt; n) = q(pt)=n where q(pt) is independent of

n. For every price vector pt=(pit;p�it) where qi(pit;p�it; n) > 0 for all i, demand

is twice continuously di¤erentiable and from Vives (2001, p.148-152) we assume it

has the following standard properties:

Assumption 1.��� @qi@pit

��� >Pj 6=i@qi@pjt

> 0

Assumption 2. @2qi@pit@pjt

� 0 8 j 6= i

Assumption 3. @2qi@p2it

+Pj 6=i

@2qi@pit@pjt

< 0.

These assumptions imply that products are imperfect substitutes, demand ex-

hibits increasing di¤erences in (pit; pjt) and the own e¤ect of a price change domi-

nates the cross e¤ect both in terms of the level and slope of demand.

Firm i�s per-period pro�t in period t is �it(pit;p�it; ct; n) = (pit�ct)qi(pit;p�it; n)where at equal prices pit = pt for all i write �it(pt; pt; ct; n) = �t(pt; ct; n). Assump-

tions 1 and 2 imply that prices are strategic complements:

@2�it@pit@pjt

> 0 8 j 6= i 8 t. (1)

Since unit costs are constant, Assumptions 1 and 3 are su¢ cient to ensure the best

reply mapping is a contraction (see Vives, 2001, p.150):

@2�it@p2it

+Xj 6=i

@2�it@pit@pjt

< 0 8 t. (2)

This guarantees the existence of a unique one-shot Nash equilibrium in pure strate-

gies, denoted pN (ct; n). It follows from (1) and (2) that each �rm�s pro�t is strictly

concave in its own price (i.e. @2�it=@p2it < 0), which implies that if rivals charge

above pN (ct; n), then a �rm can strictly increase its pro�t by unilaterally lowering

its price towards the one-shot Nash price (i.e. @�it=@pit < 0 8 pjt > pN (ct; n) j 6= i).Assumption 1 guarantees that pN (ct; n) is strictly increasing in ct and to ensure that

pN (ct; n) is strictly decreasing in n we assume the following su¢ cient condition:

Assumption 4. @2qi@pit@n

< 0.

6

Page 9: Collusive Price Rigidity under Price- Matching Punishmentscompetitionpolicy.ac.uk/documents/107435/0/ccp11-14.pdf · Keywords: Tacit collusion, kinked demand curve, price rigidity

Finally, to ensure that the monopoly price, pm(ct), is unique with pm(ct) >

pN (ct; n) we assume:

Assumption 5. d2�tdp2t

= @2�it@p2it

+ 2Pj 6=i

@2�it@pit@pjt

+ @2�it@p2jt

< 0 8 t.

An implication of Assumption 5 is that if all �rms set the same price below the

monopoly level, then they would strictly increase pro�ts if all set a higher price

(i.e. d�t=dpt > 0 8 pN (ct; n) � pt < pm(ct)). Assumption 1 ensures that pm(ct) isstrictly increasing in ct, while symmetric demand and costs guarantee that pm(ct)

is independent of n.

3.2 Cost �uctuations

In any period, unit costs can be low or high such that ct = 0 or ct = c > 0. To

simplify notation, write pN (0; n) = pN (n), pm(0) = pm and �it(pit;p�it; 0; n) =

�it(pit;p�it;n). The current level is common knowledge before �rms set prices, and

expectations of future levels of ct for all t follow a Markov process such that:

� � Pr (ct = cj ct�1 = 0) 2 (0; 1)� � Pr (ct = 0j ct�1 = c) 2 (0; 1)� � Pr (c0 = c) 2 [0; 1].

Thus, � is the transition probability associated with moving from a low-cost period

to one of high costs, and � is the probability that corresponds with a transition from

high costs to low costs. The parameter � describes how the system begins.

This process implies that the probability that costs will be high in the next

period is � if they are currently low, otherwise it is 1� �. Thus, when 1� ��� = 0,future cost are independent of the current level, and this simple case provides a

benchmark for our analysis. In many industries it is natural to expect future costs

will be positively correlated with the current level. Consequently, we also allow for

the case where 1 � � � � > 0, which implies that it is more likely that the currentlevel will continue into the next period than change. Following the terminology of

Bagwell and Staiger (1997), we refer to the former as zero correlation (1���� = 0)and the latter as positive correlation (1� � � � > 0).

3.3 Collusive prices and pro�ts

Due to the Markov process that determines future cost levels, collusive pro�ts are

the same in any high-cost period regardless of the speci�c date, other things equal,

and likewise for any low-cost period. Thus, the best collusive prices emerge as a pair,

7

Page 10: Collusive Price Rigidity under Price- Matching Punishmentscompetitionpolicy.ac.uk/documents/107435/0/ccp11-14.pdf · Keywords: Tacit collusion, kinked demand curve, price rigidity

and we wish to �nd the conditions under which these are equal. Analysing the best

collusive prices is consistent with the prominent papers in the collusion literature

(for example see Rotemberg and Saloner, 1986; Haltiwanger and Harringtion, 1991),

and it is also consistent with the kinked demand curve since the most pro�table

equilibrium is often argued to be the most logical (see Tirole, 1988, p.244).

To derive the present discounted values of collusive pro�ts, denote H(p(c); p(0))

as a �rm�s pro�t in period t and thereafter if period t has high costs and �rms

set p(c) and p(0) in all high- and low-cost periods, respectively. Similarly, denote

L(p(0); p(c)) as a �rm�s pro�t in period t and thereafter if period t has low costs and

�rms set p(0) and p(c) in all low- and high-cost periods, respectively. Surpressing

notation slightly, it is possible to write such pro�ts as:

H = �(p(c); c; n) + ��L + �(1� �)HL = �(p(0);n) + ��H + �(1� �)L.

Solving for H and L enables us to write �rm i�s present discounted value of

collusive pro�ts in a high-cost period and a low-cost period as, respectively:

H(p(c); p(0)) = �(p(c); c; n) +�1��

��!�(p(0);n) + (1�

�! )�(p(c); c; n)

�L(p(0); p(c)) = �(p(0);n) +

�1�� [

�!�(p(c); c; n) + (1�

�! )�(p(0);n)],

where ! � 1� �(1� � � �) > 0, 0 < �! < 1 and 0 <

�! < 1. The �rst terms on the

right hand-side of the above equations represent the pro�ts from the initial periods,

and the second terms represent the pro�ts from all future periods conditional on

expectations of future cost levels.

3.4 Punishment strategy

Drawing on the insights of Lu and Wright (2010), we assume that �rm i�s price-

matching punishment strategy pro�le for all t is of the form:

pi0 = p0(c0) = p(c0)

pit = pt(ct) =

(p(ct) if pj� = p� (c� ) 8 j 8 � 2 f0; : : : ; t� 1gmax(pN (ct; n);min(p

dt ; p(ct))) otherwise

(3)

where pdt is a vector of the history of deviation prices at period t (i.e. it includes all

prices where pj� 6= p� (c� ) 8 j 8 � 2 f0; : : : ; t� 1g). This strategy calls for each �rmto set the initial collusive prices until a deviation. Following a deviation, the lowest

ever deviation price is matched in periods where it is above the period�s one-shot

8

Page 11: Collusive Price Rigidity under Price- Matching Punishmentscompetitionpolicy.ac.uk/documents/107435/0/ccp11-14.pdf · Keywords: Tacit collusion, kinked demand curve, price rigidity

price

time

pN(c,n)

t+1

Z

pN(n)

Z

YY

X

pt(c)

t+2 t+3 t+4 t+5 t+6t

X XX

Y Y Y Y Y

Z Z

pt(0)

Figure 1: pricing after a one-stage deviation to X, Y and Z in period t

Nash price and below the period�s initial collusive level. The one-shot Nash price is

set in any period when the lowest ever deviation price is below the one-shot Nash

price. Similarly, the initial collusive level is set in any period when the lowest ever

deviation price is above the period�s initial collusive level. This is repeated for future

deviations.

Figure 1 illustrates the implications for pricing for various one-stage deviations

(i.e. where a �rm deviates for one period, then conforms to (3) thereafter). Un-

derstanding such deviations are important for our purposes, because we use the

one-stage deviation principle (see Fudenberg and Tirole, 1991, p.108-110) to solve

for subgame perfect Nash equilibria. This principle states that a strategy pro�le in-

duces an equilibrium in every subgame if there is no history that leads to a subgame

in which a player will chose an action that di¤ers to that prescribed by the strategy,

then conforms to the strategy thereafter (assuming the deviant believes others will

also conform to the strategy). Thus, to prove subgame perfection, it su¢ ces to show

that a �rm will not deviate once from the initial collusive subgame and nor will it do

so from every possible punishment subgame (where deviating once is synonymous

with a one-stage deviation). We say that p(ct) is supportable if the strategy pro�le

in (3) is a subgame perfect Nash equilibrium for all i = 1; : : : ; n.

In the particular example of Figure 1, �rms set pt(c) and pt(0) in high- and low-

cost periods, respectively, if there is no deviation over the period, so intitially prices

are procyclical. If a �rm deviates once in period t to Y , then Y is matched in all

future periods. If the deviation price is Z, however, then Z is matched in all future

low-cost periods but pN (c; n) is set in all others. Departing slightly from the kinked

demand curve but consistent with Lu and Wright (2010), �rms do not match prices

9

Page 12: Collusive Price Rigidity under Price- Matching Punishmentscompetitionpolicy.ac.uk/documents/107435/0/ccp11-14.pdf · Keywords: Tacit collusion, kinked demand curve, price rigidity

below pN (ct; n) in period t because doing so seems unreasonable. This assumption

is not crucial in determining when the best collusive prices are rigid, because a

deviation to Z in a low-cost period is always less pro�table than one to Y when the

best collusive prices are rigid, and a deviation to Z in a high-cost period never occurs

even for prices that are unsupportable by (3). This assumption ensures that it is

possible to check that any price between pN (n) and pN (c; n) de�nes an equilibrium

in such low-cost punishment subgames, and that (3) induces an equilibrium in a

subgame for histories where the price is below pN (ct; n).

The strategy pro�le (3) also has a similar feature for one-stage deviations to

prices above the lowest initial collusive price, because if the deviation price is X,

then X is matched in future high-cost periods, but pt(0) is set in all others. Figure

1 illustrates the case for procyclical prices, but it equally applies to the case of

countercyclical prices (where pt(c) is set in low-cost periods and pt(0) in high-cost).

This resembles the rivalry of the kinked demand curve where �rms are unwilling

to match a price increase above the focal level. The only di¤erence in the rivalry

modelled here is that this unwillingness to match prices above the initial collusive

level occurs regardless of whether a �rm deviates up from pt(0) to X or down from

pt(c) to X. However, the rationale for the strategy is the same: each �rm expects

to lose sales if it were to set X in periods when it expects its rivals to set pt(0).5

4 Price Rigidity under Price-Matching Punishments

4.1 A Theory of Price Rigidity

We wish to �nd the conditions under which the best collusive prices are rigid.

Prices are procyclical for large cost �uctuations where pN (c; n) > pm, so we ini-

tially consider cost �uctuations such that c 2 (0; c] where pN (c; n) = pm. Similarly,price rigidity does not occur unless �rms can support pN (c; n) and p, such that

pN (n) < p � pN (c; n), in high- and low-cost periods, respectively. Otherwise, thereare some punishment subgames where �rms will not conform to (3). Clearly a �rm

will not deviate once from pN (c; n) in a high-cost period, so consider �rm i�s incen-

tive to deviate once from p in a low-cost period. Firm i�s present discounted value

of deviation pro�t if it sets the same or a lower price pi 2 (pN (n); p] in a low-cost5An alternative strategy is one where downward deviations from pt(c) to X are matched in all

future periods, other things equal. Since this alternative and (3) are equivalent for rigid prices, thecharacteristics of the best rigid price are the same. We focus on (3) because there is an asymmetryin this alternative strategy since �rms are unable to lead low-cost prices up from pt(0) to X in alow-cost period, but they are able to do so by a downward deviation from pt(c) to X in a high-costperiod. A consequence of this asymmetry is that the parameter space where the best collusive pricesare rigid under (3) is a strict subset of that under this alternative strategy, so it is robust to both.

10

Page 13: Collusive Price Rigidity under Price- Matching Punishmentscompetitionpolicy.ac.uk/documents/107435/0/ccp11-14.pdf · Keywords: Tacit collusion, kinked demand curve, price rigidity

period and then conforms to (3) thereafter is:

ziL(pi; p; pN (c; n)) � �i(pi; p;n) + �

1�� [�!�(p

N (c; n); c; n) + (1� �! )�(pi;n)]. (4)

Lemma 1 For every n � 2 and � 2 (0; 1) where 1� ��� � 0, there exists a uniquebc 2 (0; c) such that pN (c; n) and p, where pN (n) < p � pN (c; n), are supportable by(3) in high- and low-cost periods, respectively, if and only if c 2 (0;bc].

When cost �uctuations are su¢ ciently small, pN (c; n) is close enough to pN (n)

such that the punishment from matching any lower price in future low-cost periods

ensures a �rm will not deviate once from pN (c; n) in a low-cost period. The pun-

ishment is also credible since a �rm will not deviate once from any lower price p

between pN (n) and pN (c; n) in low-cost punishment subgames. This is because the

condition for a �rm to want to deviate once from p is the same as that of pN (c; n)

except that p is lower than pN (c; n), and the standard properties of the underlying

competition game imply that it is less pro�table to deviate once from a price close

to pN (n) than a higher price.

In the next subsection we limit our attention to equilibria with the same price

pc > pN (c; n) in both cost states. This allows us to characterise the best rigid price

that achieves the highest level of pro�t given that the price does not vary with costs.

In the subsection after, we �nd the conditions under which �rms can do no better

than set the best rigid price in both cost states.

4.1.1 Best rigid price

Under the conditions of Lemma 1, price rigidity can occur when �rms can support

a rigid price pc > pN (c; n) and any rigid price between pc and pN (c; n). Otherwise

there is at least one collusive/punishment subgame where a �rm will not conform

to (3). Since a �rm�s incentives to deviate depend upon the current cost level, we

must ensure that a �rm will not deviate once from such prices in high- and low-cost

periods. Depending upon whether costs are initially high or low, �rm i�s present

discounted value of deviation pro�ts if it sets the same or lower price p 2 [pN (c; n); pc]in the initial period and then conforms to (3) thereafter are, respectively:

yiH(p; pc) � �i(p; pc; c; n) + �

1����!�(p;n) + (1�

�! )�(p; c; n)

�(5)

yiL(p; pc) � �i(p; pc;n) + �

1�� [�!�(p; c; n) + (1�

�! )�(p;n)]. (6)

The �rst terms on the right-hand side of (5) and (6) are the pro�t from the deviation

period. This pro�t is lower in (5) than (6), because per-period pro�ts are decreasing

in unit costs. The second terms represent the pro�t from future periods conditional

11

Page 14: Collusive Price Rigidity under Price- Matching Punishmentscompetitionpolicy.ac.uk/documents/107435/0/ccp11-14.pdf · Keywords: Tacit collusion, kinked demand curve, price rigidity

on expectations of future cost levels and given a lower price will be matched in all

future periods. If there is zero correlation, future �uctuations in costs are indepen-

dent of the current level, so the second terms of (5) and (6) are equal. If there is

positive correlation, the current cost state is more likely to continue into the future,

so the second term is lower in (5) than (6). Thus, such a one-stage deviation is less

pro�table in a high-cost period than a low-cost period, other things equal.

Lemma 2 For every n � 2 and � 2 (0; 1) where 1� ��� � 0, there exists a uniquebest rigid price, pyL(c; n; �; �; �), that is supportable by (3) if and only if c 2 (0;bc],where pN (c; n) < pyL(c; n; �; �; �) < pm(c). Any rigid price pc such that pN (c; n) �pc � pyL(c; n; �; �; �) is also supportable by (3).

When costs are small, there is some rigid price pc above pN (c; n) where the

punishment from matching a small deviation in all future periods ensures a �rm

will not deviate once from pc in a low-cost collusive subgame. Given a one-stage

deviation is most pro�table when costs are low, a �rm will also not deviate once from

pc in a high-cost collusive subgame. The punishment is credible since a �rm will

also not deviate once from any lower rigid price p between pN (c; n) and pc in low-

and high-cost punishment subgames. A �rm will not deviate once from p in low-cost

punishment subgames, because the condition for a �rm to want to deviate once from

p is the same as that of pc except that p is lower than pc, and the standard properties

of the underlying competition game imply that it is less pro�table to deviate once

from a price close to pN (c; n) than a higher price.6 This also ensures a �rm will not

deviate once from p in high-cost punishment subgames, due to the same reason as

for the initial collusive subgame.

The best rigid price has the property that its associated (unconstrained) optimal

�deviation�price in a low-cost period equals the best rigid price (i.e. the argument

maximising (6) equals pc). Since it is less pro�table to deviate once in a high-cost

period than one of low costs, its (constrained) optimal �deviation�price in a high-

cost period also equals the best rigid price.7 The best rigid price is equivalent to the

best collusive price analysed by Lu and Wright (2010) when costs do not �uctuate,

but in contrast to Lu and Wright (2010) it can be equal to or above the low-cost

monopoly level when costs do �uctuate over time. This is because a small deviation

from pm that is matched in all future periods generates a �rst-order decrease in

6Under the conditions of Lemma 1, a one-stage deviation from any rigid price p > pN (c; n) to aprice below pN (c; n) in a low-cost period is less pro�table than one to pN (c; n).

7A �rm would want to deviate once to a price above the best rigid price in a high-cost periodif such a deviation price were matched in all future periods. However, this would not be a crediblestrategy even if upward deviations were matched, because a �rm will deviate once from rigid pricesabove the best rigid price in such future low-cost punishment subgames.

12

Page 15: Collusive Price Rigidity under Price- Matching Punishmentscompetitionpolicy.ac.uk/documents/107435/0/ccp11-14.pdf · Keywords: Tacit collusion, kinked demand curve, price rigidity

future high-cost periods only (since the low-cost pro�t function is �at at pm), and

this can outweigh the �rst-order increase in the initial deviation pro�t.

4.1.2 Best collusive prices and price rigidity

The best collusive prices are rigid if �rms can do no better than the best rigid price

by setting procyclical or countercyclical prices. The best collusive prices are never

countercyclical, because the condition for a �rm to want to deviate once from a price

above the best rigid price in a low-cost period is the same for countercyclical prices

as it is for rigid prices except that for countercyclical prices a small deviation is only

matched in future low-cost periods. Thus, since there is an incentive to deviate once

from such a price when the price is matched in all future periods, there is also an

incentive to deviate once when prices are countercyclical. Therefore, �rms can only

do better than rigid prices by setting procyclical prices.

The best collusive prices are procyclical when �rms can support p(c) in a high-

cost period that is above the best collusive price in a low-cost period, denoted

p�(0) 2 [pN (c; n); pm]. Otherwise a �rm will deviate once from procyclical prices in

a high-cost period, and the best collusive prices are rigid. The pro�t from a small

one-stage deviation from p�(0) in a low-cost period is equivalent to (6), so consider

�rm i�s present discounted value of deviation pro�ts in a high-cost period if it sets

the same or a lower price p 2 [p�(0); p(c)] in the initial period, then conforms to (3)thereafter:

xiH(p; p(c); p�(0)) � �i(p; p(c); c; n) + �

1����!�(p

�(0);n) + (1� �! )�(p; c; n)

�.

(7)

To see why procyclical prices may not be supportable under price-matching punish-

ments, consider a one-stage deviation from p(c) to p = p�(0). When such a deviation

is matched in future periods, the punishment is limited to future periods of high-

costs (because �rms set p�(0) in low-cost periods regardless of a deviation). When

�rms expect all future periods to be low-cost (i.e. � = 1 and � = 0), there is no

punishment for such a deviation. Thus, each �rm will have a dominant strategy to

deviate once from any p(c) 2 (p�(0); pm(c)] for all c 2 (0;bc], and the best rigid priceis the best collusive price for both cost states.

Proposition 1 shows the best collusive price can be rigid when costs persist into

the future.

Proposition 1 For every n � 2 and � 2 (0; 1) where 1 � �� � � 0, there exists aunique c� 2 (0;bc) such that the best rigid price, pyL(c; n; �; �; �), is the best collusiveprice in both cost states if and only if c 2 (0; c�], where pN (c; n) < pyL(c; n; �; �; �) <pm.

13

Page 16: Collusive Price Rigidity under Price- Matching Punishmentscompetitionpolicy.ac.uk/documents/107435/0/ccp11-14.pdf · Keywords: Tacit collusion, kinked demand curve, price rigidity

Under the conditions of Lemma 1, the best collusive price in low-cost periods

is the lower of the best rigid price and the low-cost monopoly price regardless of

whether prices are rigid or procyclical. This is because for any p(0) above the

best rigid price there are some low-cost punishment subgames where a rigid price

between pyL(c; n; �; �; �) and p(0) should be matched in all future periods, but a �rm

will deviate once. Consequently, prices above the best rigid price are not supportable

even though it is easier to support the best rigid price in low-cost periods when prices

are procyclical than when they are rigid.

The best collusive prices are rigid when a �rm has an incentive to deviate once

from a price slightly above the best rigid price in a high-cost period. This occurs

for small cost �uctuations, because as c ! 0 the condition for a �rm to want to

deviate once from any price above the best rigid price in a high-cost period is the

same as that of a low-cost period except that a small deviation is only matched in

high-cost periods. Thus, since there is an incentive to deviate once from such prices

in a low-cost period when a small deviation is matched in all future periods, there is

also an incentive to deviate once when costs are high. As c increases, it becomes less

pro�table to deviate once from a price slightly above the best rigid price in high-cost

periods (even though this price strictly increases with c), and procyclical prices are

supportable by (3) when cost �uctuations are su¢ ciently large.

When �uctuations are so large that the low-cost monopoly price is the best

collusive price in low-cost periods, the best collusive prices are procyclical. This is

because a small deviation from pm in a low-cost period that is matched in all future

periods only generates a �rst-order decrease in subsequent high-cost periods. This is

(weakly) smaller than the �rst-order decrease in subsequent high-cost periods due to

a small deviation from a price slightly above pm in a high-cost period. Thus, given

the initial deviation pro�t is higher in a low-cost period than one of high costs, a

�rm will not deviate once from a price slightly above pm in a high-cost period if it

will not deviate once from pm in a low-cost period.

4.2 Price rigidity and the expected duration of a high-cost phase

The best collusive prices are rigid when costs are su¢ ciently small, but the critical

level depends upon how long high costs persist into the future. To see this point,

de�ne a high-cost phase as a sequence of high-cost periods that begins in a period

where costs change from low to high costs and ends the period before they change

back. The expected duration of a high-cost phase is �1t=1t�(1� �)t�1 = 1=�, whichimplies the lower the probability that costs will change from high level to the low

level, the longer the expected duration of a high-cost phase. Similarly, de�ne a

low-cost phase with an expected duration of 1=�.

14

Page 17: Collusive Price Rigidity under Price- Matching Punishmentscompetitionpolicy.ac.uk/documents/107435/0/ccp11-14.pdf · Keywords: Tacit collusion, kinked demand curve, price rigidity

Proposition 2 For every n � 2 and � 2 (0; 1) where 1��� � � 0, the critical levelof high costs under which the best collusive prices are rigid, c�, is strictly decreasing

in the expected duration of a high-cost phase whether future levels are independent

of or positively correlated with the current level.

An increase in the expected duration of a high-cost phase has a direct e¤ect

that implies, it is less pro�table to deviate once from a price slightly above the best

rigid price in a high-cost period. This is because a small deviation leads to a larger

�rst-order decrease in future pro�ts than before, since future punishment periods

are more likely to be a (less pro�table) high-cost periods. However, there is also an

indirect e¤ect because the best rigid price increases with the expected duration of

a high-cost phase due to the same reason. This and the standard properties of the

underlying competition game imply that it is more pro�table to deviate once from

a price slightly above the best rigid price in a high-cost period. The direct e¤ect

dominates, so the best collusive prices are rigid for smaller cost �uctuations as the

expected duration of a high-cost phase increases. When there is zero correlation

both the direct and indirect e¤ects are larger than under positive correlation (since

the expected duration of a low-cost phase decreases as the expected duration of a

high-cost phase increases), but the direct e¤ect still dominates.

We have already seen that when a high-cost phase is expected to only last one

period, there is price rigidity as long as the high-cost one-shot Nash price can be

supported in a low-cost period (i.e. c� ! bc as � ! 1 and � ! 0). At the other

extreme, as the expected duration of a high-cost phase tends to in�nity, the best

collusive prices are procyclical regardless of the expected duration of a low-cost phase

(i.e. c� ! 0 as � ! 0 8 0 < � < 1). This is because a low-cost period can be followedby low- and high-cost periods, but a high-cost period will only be followed by other

high-cost periods. Consequently, a small deviation from a price slightly above the

rigid price in a high-cost period leads to a larger decrease in subsequent collusive

pro�t than a small deviation from a rigid price in a low-cost period. Therefore, given

the initial deviation pro�t is also lower in a high-cost period than one of low costs,

procyclical prices are supportable by (3).

4.3 Price rigidity and pro�t over the �uctuations

The preceding analysis showed that the best rigid price is larger for more pronounced

�uctuations. This is because a small deviation from a rigid price in a low-cost

period that is matched in all future periods generates a larger �rst-order decrease in

subsequent high-cost periods as the level of high costs increase. Proposition 3 shows

that this implies that there are also general properties for the best collusive pro�ts

15

Page 18: Collusive Price Rigidity under Price- Matching Punishmentscompetitionpolicy.ac.uk/documents/107435/0/ccp11-14.pdf · Keywords: Tacit collusion, kinked demand curve, price rigidity

as �uctuations become more pronounced.

Proposition 3 For any c 2 (0; c�], the best collusive high-cost (low-cost) per-periodpro�t is strictly decreasing (increasing) in c, and the present discounted value of the

best collusive pro�ts is strictly decreasing in c regardless of whether costs are initially

high or low.

As high costs increase, the best rigid price increases which ensures low-cost per-

period pro�ts are strictly increasing in c. However, only a small proportion of

the higher costs are passed on via a higher price, so high-cost per-period pro�ts

are strictly decreasing in c. When the e¤ect is considered over time, the increase

in expected low-cost pro�ts is outweighed by the expected loss in high-cost pro�ts

regardless of whether such pro�ts are considered from a high-cost or low-cost period.

Thus, when costs �uctuate by a moderate degree over time the collusive price is

higher but collusive pro�ts are lower than when they �uctuate to a lesser extent.

This contrasts with cost �uctuations under Nash reversion where prices and pro�ts

can increase with cost �uctuations (see Rimler, 2005).

5 An Example

We complement the above analysis by assuming that demand is derived from the con-

stant elasticity of substitution version of Spence-Dixit-Stiglitz preferences (Spence,

1976; and Dixit and Stiglitz, 1977). We do this for three reasons. First, we want

to show that price rigidity can occur for reasonably large �uctuations in unit costs.

Second, we want to investigate how the degree of product di¤erentiation a¤ects price

rigidity. To the author�s knowledge, there is no other model of collusive price rigidity

that considers this, since both Athey et al (2004) and Hanazono and Yang (2007)

analyse homogeneous products. Third, we want to investigate the relationship be-

tween price rigidity and the number �rms, and this ultimately depends upon the

degree of product di¤erentiation. We use Spence-Dixit-Stiglitz preferences, because

it falls into the class of our general model and it isolates the competitive e¤ects of

product di¤erentiation since there is no market expansion e¤ect.8

A representative consumer�s utility function is U(x) = n1��

1��

�1n�x

1���i

� 1��1���

+m,

where x is the vector of consumption of the n products, m is expenditure on other

goods, � 2 (0; 1) measures the degree of product di¤erentiation, where products are8Spence-Dixit-Stiglitz preferences is one example of di¤erentiated demand analysed by Kühn

and Rimler (2007) for collusion models under Nash reversion and optimal punishment strategies.It has not been analysed for collusion under price-matching punishments before.

16

Page 19: Collusive Price Rigidity under Price- Matching Punishmentscompetitionpolicy.ac.uk/documents/107435/0/ccp11-14.pdf · Keywords: Tacit collusion, kinked demand curve, price rigidity

less di¤erentiated the closer � is to zero, and � 2 (0; 1) is a parameter. It followsfrom this that the direct demand function for �rm i is:

qi(pi;p�i; �; n) =1

np� 1�

i

"n

�j (pi=pj)1�����

# 1��1���

This implies that at equal prices total demand is independent of both the degree of

product di¤erentiation and the number of �rms, i.e. q(p) = p�1=�. It is straightfor-

ward to show that the monopoly price is pm(ct) = ct=(1� �) and that the one-shotNash price is pN (ct; n; �) = ct=

h1� �=

�1 + 1��

�n�1n

�i. To ensure the monopoly

level is above the one-shot Nash price when costs are low, we assume that the level

of low costs is c 2 (0; c), and normalise the high cost relative to the low cost later.For this example, the best rigid price is:

pyL(c; n; �; �; �; �) =c

1��=�1+(1��) 1��

�n�1n

� + ��(c�c)!�1��+(1��) 1��

�n�1n

� (8)

which applies for c < c � bc.9 The �rst term on the right hand-side of (8) is equivalentto the best collusive price analysed in Lu and Wright (2010) and the second term

captures the e¤ect of cost �uctuations. It equals c when products are homogeneous,

and it is everywhere strictly increasing in the degree of product di¤erentiation, �. It

is above the low-cost one-shot Nash price for all 0 < � � 1, and it is above the low-cost monopoly level when products are not substitutable. It is everywhere strictly

decreasing in the number of �rms, n, but it is always above the low-cost one-shot

Nash price even when there is a large number of �rms in the market.10

The price in (8) de�nes the best collusive price in both cost states when costs

are su¢ ciently small. It follows from Proposition 1 that c� = c1�K 2 (c;bc) where:

K =� ��!(1��) 1��

�n�1n�

(1��)(1� ��!)+(1��) 1��

�n�1n

��1� ��

!+(1��) 1��

�n�1n

� 2 (0; 1).

To illustrate the properties of c�, Figure 2 plots �c� � c��cc = K

1�K as a function

of � for three levels of n. This has two intrepretations. First, �c� is the critical

proportion that high costs can be above low costs under which the best collusive

prices are rigid. Second, it measures the proportion to which prices would vary if

the market were monopolised (i.e. [pm(c�)�pm(c)]=pm(c) = �c�). Parameter valuesare chosen such that the low-cost monopoly level is equal to unity, and that future

costs are independent of the current level and are equally likely.

The Figure shows that there is a non-monotonic relationship between �c� and

9Following Lemma 1, bc = �1� �= h1 + 1���

n�1n

i�c

1��(1� ��!)=h(1��)

�1+ 1��

�n�1n

�+�(1� �

!)i .

10The reason is that the underlying competition game is one of monopolistic competition.

17

Page 20: Collusive Price Rigidity under Price- Matching Punishmentscompetitionpolicy.ac.uk/documents/107435/0/ccp11-14.pdf · Keywords: Tacit collusion, kinked demand curve, price rigidity

Figure 2: (c = 0:5; � = 1� � = 0:5, � = 0:5, � = 0:9)

the degree of product di¤erentiation. For intermediate degrees of di¤erentiation, the

best collusive prices are rigid when the high-cost monopoly level is 16% higher than

the low-cost monopoly price, and price rigidity can occur for even larger �uctuations

when the expected duration of a high-cost phase is shorter.11 When products are

close to perfect substitutes or when they are barely substitutable, the best collusive

prices are rigid for small �uctuations. This is because the punishment strategy does

not support collusive prices if the products are homogeneous, since an in�ntesimally

small deviation from the collusive price captures the whole market and the price-

matching strategy provides virtually no punishment. Consequently, �rms price at

the one-shot Nash level in each cost state and prices are procyclical. In contrast,

when �rms are local monopolies there is not price rigidity, because each monopoly

is unconcerned with the reactions of the other �rms, so they price at the relevant

monopoly levels in each cost state.

The Figure also shows that �c� decreases with the number of �rms for low

levels of di¤erentiation, but the opposite relationship can exist otherwise. This

non-monotonic relationship between price rigidity and the number of �rms is con-

sistent with Hanazono and Yang (2007), and it is not inconsistent with empirical

research that shows the responsiveness of prices to �uctuations is negatively corre-

lated with concentration in some cases (see Dixon, 1983; Carlton, 1986; Bedrossian

and Moschos, 1988; Geroski, 1992; Weiss, 1995) and the opposite relationship exists

11For example, if � = 0:01 and � = 0:99, the shape of �c� is similar to that of Figure 2 exceptthat the best collusive prices are rigid when the high-cost monopoly price is 40% higher than thelow-cost monopoly price.

18

Page 21: Collusive Price Rigidity under Price- Matching Punishmentscompetitionpolicy.ac.uk/documents/107435/0/ccp11-14.pdf · Keywords: Tacit collusion, kinked demand curve, price rigidity

in others (see Domberger, 1979; and Kardasz and Stollery, 1988). In our general

framework, the relationship is unsignable, because a direct e¤ect increases a �rm�s

incentive to deviate once from a price slightly above the best rigid price in a high-

cost period, but an indirect e¤ect works in the opposite direction because the best

rigid price is strictly decreasing in n (due to Assumptions 4 and 5). When more

structure is placed on demand, the indirect e¤ect at the homogeneous goods limit

is equal to the change in a �rm�s incentive to deviate once from the best rigid price

in a low-cost period. Given an in�nitesimally small deviation attracts the whole

market, the changes in punishment pro�ts are arbitrarily small. Thus, the indirect

e¤ect dominates, because due to lower costs an extra �rm has a larger e¤ect on the

initial deviation pro�t in a low-cost period than that in a high-cost period. As a

result, procyclical prices are easier to support at the homogeneous good limit as the

number of �rms increases.

6 Concluding remarks

In this paper we have analysed an in�nitely repeated game where unit costs �uctuate

stochastically over time and �rms employ a price-matching punishment strategy.

We showed that the best collusive prices can be rigid over time when the cost

�uctuations are su¢ ciently small. This provides game theoretic support for the

results of the kinked demand curve. Speci�cally, when a period of high costs is

expected to be followed by low-cost periods only, a price above the low-cost price

cannot be supported when the high-cost one-shot Nash equilibrium is below the low-

cost price. The critical level of high costs under which the best collusive prices are

rigid is monitonically decreasing in the expected duration of a high-cost phase, and

price rigidity does not occur when costs are expected to increase permanently in the

future. Each �rm�s present discounted value of the best collusive pro�ts decreases as

the cost �uctuations become more pronounced, despite an increase in the best rigid

price. When demand is derived from the constant elasticity of substitution version

of Spence-Dixit-Stiglitz preferences, the best collusive prices are rigid for reasonably

large cost �uctuations when products are di¤erentiated by an intermediate degree;

and when products are su¢ ciently substitutable, price rigidity occurs for larger cost

�uctuations as the number of �rms in the market decreases.

Throughout the paper we have considered only two cost states, but periods of

price rigidity are not restricted to this special case. For instance, when a medium

cost state is added and the probabilities of future costs are independent of the

current level, the best rigid price is una¤ected by the introduction of the third state

if the expected level of future costs is unchanged compared to the two-state model.

This also implies that the punishment from high-cost periods is lower than before,

19

Page 22: Collusive Price Rigidity under Price- Matching Punishmentscompetitionpolicy.ac.uk/documents/107435/0/ccp11-14.pdf · Keywords: Tacit collusion, kinked demand curve, price rigidity

because from holding the expected level of future costs constant, future high-cost

periods are less likely in the three-state model than the two-state. As a result, it is

more di¢ cult to support a procyclical price in high-cost periods than before. Thus,

for �uctuations where best collusive prices are rigid in the two-state model, the best

collusive prices in the three-state model will either be rigid for every cost state or

partially rigid (where there is price rigidity in medium and high costs states but

at a price above that set in a low-cost period). Applying this logic to more than

three cost states implies that it is even more di¢ cult to support procyclical prices

in the highest-cost state, so periods of price rigidity can also occur for any number

of states.

Finally, an important avenue for future research is to investigate whether there

exist any circumstances under which �rms will choose to support collusive prices

through a weaker punishment, such as price matching, rather than revert to harsher

punishment strategies, such as Nash reversion or optimal punishment strategies.

As well as resolving the tension between the informal reasoning that �rms would

prefer to follow the harshest punishment possible with the evidence that, at least in

some situations, tacitly colluding �rms (and even some cartels) do not follow harsh

punishments, a theoretical justi�cation for price matching may provide a better

indication of the industry characteristics where price rigidity is likely to prevail.

References

[1] Abreu, D (1986) �Extremal Equilibria of Oligopolistic Supergames,�Journal ofEconomic Theory, 39, 191-225

[2] Abreu, D (1988) �On the Theory of In�nitely Repeated Games with Discount-ing,�Econometrica, 56, 383-396

[3] Athey, S, Bagwell, K and Sanchirico, C (2004) �Collusion and Price Rigidity,�Review of Economic Studies, 71(2), 317-349

[4] Bagwell, K and Staiger, R (1997) �Collusion over the Business Cycle,�RANDJournal of Economics, 28(1), 82-106

[5] Bedrossian, A and Moschos, D (1988) �Industrial Structure, Concentration andthe Speed of Price Adjustments,�Journal of Industrial Economics, 36, 459-475

[6] Bhaskar, V (1988) �The Kinked Demand Curve: A Game Theoretic Approach,�International Journal of Industrial Organization, 6, 373-384

[7] Carlton, D (1986) �The Rigidity of Prices,�American Economic Review, 76(4),637-658

[8] Carlton, D (1989) �The Theory and the Facts of How Markets Clear: IsIndustrial Organization Valuable for Understanding Macroeconomics?� in

20

Page 23: Collusive Price Rigidity under Price- Matching Punishmentscompetitionpolicy.ac.uk/documents/107435/0/ccp11-14.pdf · Keywords: Tacit collusion, kinked demand curve, price rigidity

Schmalensee, R and Willig, R (eds) Handbook of Industrial Organization, Ox-ford: North-Holland

[9] Dixit, A and Stiglitz, J (1977) �Monopolistic Competition and Optimum Prod-uct Diversity,�American Economic Review, 67, 63-78

[10] Dixon, R (1983) �Industry Structure and the Speed of Price Adjustments,�Journal of Industrial Economics, 31, 25-37

[11] Domberger, S (1979) �Price Adjustment and Market Structure,� EconomicJournal, 89, 96-108

[12] Friedman, J (1971) �A Non-Cooperative Equilibrium for Supergames,�Reviewof Economic Studies, 28, 1-12

[13] Fudenberg, D and Tirole, J (1991) Game Theory, Cambridge: MIT Press

[14] Genesove, D and Mullin, M. (2001) �Rules, Communication, and Collusion:Narrative Evidence from the Sugar Institute Case,�American Economic Re-view, 91, 379-398

[15] Geroski, P (1992) �Price Dynamics in UK Manufacturing: A MicroeconomicView,�Economica, 59, 403-19

[16] Green, E and Porter, R (1984) �Non-cooperative Collusion under ImperfectPrice Information,�Econometrica, 52, 87-100

[17] Hall, R and Hitch, C (1939) �Price Theory and Business Behaviour,�OxfordEconomic Papers, 2, 12-45

[18] Haltiwanger, J and Harrington, J (1991) �The Impact of Cyclical DemandMovements on Collusive Behavior,�RAND Journal of Economics, 22(1), 89-106

[19] Hanazono, M and Yang, H (2007) �Collusion, Fluctuating Demand, and PriceRigidity,�International Economic Review, 48(2) 483-515

[20] Kalai, E and Satterwaite, M (1994) �The Kinked Demand Curve, Facilitat-ing Practices, and Oligopolistic Coordination,� in Gilles, R and Ruys, P (eds)Imperfections and Behavior in Economic Organizations, Kluwer Academic Pub-lishers

[21] Kardasz, S and Stollery, K (1988) �Market Structure and Price Adjustment inCanadian Manufacturing Industries,�Journal of Economics and Business, 40,335-342

[22] Kühn K-U and Rimler, M (2007) �The Comparative Statics of Collusion Mod-els,�mimeo, University of Michigan

[23] Levenstein, M. (1997) �Price Wars and the Stability of Collusion: A Study ofthe Pre-World War I Bromine Industry,�Journal of Industrial Economics, 45,117-136

21

Page 24: Collusive Price Rigidity under Price- Matching Punishmentscompetitionpolicy.ac.uk/documents/107435/0/ccp11-14.pdf · Keywords: Tacit collusion, kinked demand curve, price rigidity

[24] Lu, Y and Wright, J (2010) �Tacit Collusion with Price-Matching Punish-ments,�International Journal of Industrial Organization, 28, 298-306

[25] Maskin, E and Tirole, J (1988) �A Theory of Dynamic Oligopoly II: PriceCompetition, Kinked Demand Curves and Edgeworth Cycles,�Econometrica,56(3), 571-599

[26] Rimler, M (2005) �Preventing Price Collusion with Evidence from MarketData,�mimeo, Xavier University

[27] Rotemberg, J and Saloner, G (1986) �A Supergame-Theoretic Model of PriceWars during Booms,�American Economic Review, 76, 390-407

[28] Slade, M (1987) �Inter�rm Rivalry in a Repeated Game: An Empirical Test ofTacit Collusion,�Journal of Industrial Economics, 35, 499-516

[29] Slade, M (1989) �Price Wars in Price Setting Supergames,�Economica, 223,295-310

[30] Slade, M (1990) �Strategic Pricing Models and Interpretation of Price WarData,�European Economic Review, 34, 524-537

[31] Slade, M (1992) �Vancouver�s Gasoline Price Wars: An Empirical Exercise inUncovering Supergame Strategies,�Review of Economic Studies, 59, 257-276

[32] Spence, M (1976) �Product Di¤erentiation and Welfare,�American EconomicReview, 66, 407-414

[33] Sweezy, P (1939) �Demand Under Conditions of Oligopoly,�Journal of PoliticalEconomy, 47, 568-573

[34] Tirole, J (1988) Theory of Industrial Organization, Cambridge: MIT Press

[35] Vives, X (2001) Oligopoly Pricing: Old Ideas and New Tools, Cambridge: MITPress

[36] Weiss, C (1995) �Determinants of Price Flexibility in Oligopolistic Markets:Evidence from Austrian Manufacturing,� Journal of Economics & Business,47, 423-439

A Proofs

Proof of Lemma 1. To �nd the conditions under which setting pN (c; n) in both

cost states is supportable by (3), it su¢ ces to check that a �rm will not deviate

once in the collusive subgame and nor will it do so in every possible punishment

subgame. For every history that starts with �rms setting pN (c; n) in both cost

states, the relevant deviation price at some period � is min(pd� ; pN (c; n)). In high-

cost subgames, (3) trivally de�nes an equilibrium. Likewise, in low-cost subgames,

(3) de�nes an equilibrium if min(pd� ) � pN (n). Otherwise, all other histories lead to

22

Page 25: Collusive Price Rigidity under Price- Matching Punishmentscompetitionpolicy.ac.uk/documents/107435/0/ccp11-14.pdf · Keywords: Tacit collusion, kinked demand curve, price rigidity

subgames equivalent to one where �rms should set pN (c; n) and min(pd� ; pN (c; n)) 2

(pN (n); pN (c; n)] in high- and low-cost periods, respectively.

Since (3) de�nes an equilibrium in every high-cost subgame, suppose we consider

a low-cost subgame where prices are p 2 (pN (n); pN (c; n)] and pN (c; n) in low- andhigh-cost periods, respectively. From (4) de�ne:

�zL(p) �h@�i(pi;p;n)

@pi+ �

1�� (1��! )

d�(pi;n)dpi

ipi=p

.

A �rm will not deviate once from pN (c; n) in the low-cost collusive subgame if

�zL(pN (c; n)) � 0, otherwise it can increase its pro�t by unilaterally lowering its

price from pN (c; n). We wish to show that �zL(p) � 0 8 p 2 (pN (n); pN (c; n)).Di¤erentiating �zL(p) with respect to p yields:

d(�zL(p))dp =

h@2�i(pi;p;n)

@p2i+Pj 6=i

@2�i(pi;p;n)@pi@pj

+ �1�� (1�

�! )

d2�(pi;n)dp2i

ipi=pj=p

.

It follows from (2) and Assumption 5 that d(�zL(p))=dp < 0. Hence, if�zL(p

N (c; n)) �0, then �zL(p) > 0 8 p 2 (pN (n); pN (c; n)). Thus, a �rm will not deviate once froma price between pN (n) and pN (c; n) in any low-cost punishment subgame.

There exists a unique bc 2 (0; c) such that�zL(pN (bc; n)) = 0 because�zL(pN (n)) >0, �zL(p

N (c; n)) = �zL(pm) < 0 and:

d(�zL(pN ))

dc =hd(�zL(p))

dpdpN

dc

ip=pN (c;n)

< 0,

since d(�zL(p))=dp < 0 and dpN=dc > 0. Therefore, �zL(p

N (c; n)) � 0 if and onlyif c 2 (0;bc]. The above analysis implies, any prices where �rms set pN (c; n) andp, such that pN (n) < p � pN (c; n), in high- and low-cost periods, respectively, aresupportable by (3) if and only if c 2 (0;bc].Proof of Lemma 2. To �nd the conditions under which setting pc in both

cost states is supportable by (3), it su¢ ces to check that a �rm will not deviate

once in the collusive subgame and nor will it do so in every possible punishment

subgame. For every history that starts with �rms setting pc in both cost states, the

relevant deviation price at some period � is min(pd� ; pc). If min(pd� ; p

c) � pN (c; n),(3) de�nes an equilibrium in such subgames if and only if c 2 (0;bc] (see Lemma 1).Otherwise, all other histories lead to subgames equivalent to one where �rms should

set min(pd� ; pc) 2 (pN (c; n); pc] in high- and low-cost periods.

Suppose we consider a subgame where c 2 (0;bc] and the price is p 2 (pN (c; n); pc]in both cost states. When costs are low, it is more pro�table to deviate once from p

to pN (c; n) than to any price below pN (c; n), because �zL(pN (c; n)) � 0 and prices

are strategic complements. Thus, consider �rm i�s incentives to set pi 2 [pN (c; n); p]

23

Page 26: Collusive Price Rigidity under Price- Matching Punishmentscompetitionpolicy.ac.uk/documents/107435/0/ccp11-14.pdf · Keywords: Tacit collusion, kinked demand curve, price rigidity

in low- and high-cost subgames. From (5) and (6), respectively, de�ne:

�yH(p) �h@�i(pi;p;c;n)

@pi+ �

1��

��!d�(pi;n)dpi

+ [1� �! ]d�(pi;c;n)

dpi

�ipi=p

�yL(p) �h@�i(pi;p;n)

@pi+ �

1��

��!d�(pi;c;n)

dpi+ [1� �

! ]d�(pi;n)dpi

�ipi=p

.

A �rm will not deviate once from pc in the low-cost collusive subgame if�yL(pc) � 0,

otherwise it can increase its pro�t by unilaterally lowering its price from pc. We wish

to show that �yL(p) � 0 and �yH(p) � 0 8 p 2 (pN (c; n); pc]. First, di¤erentiating

�yL(p) with respect to p yields:

d(�yL(p))dp =

h@2�i(pi;p;n)

@p2i+Pj 6=i

@2�i(pi;p;n)@pi@pj

+ �1��

��!d2�(pi;c;n)

dp2i+ [1� �

! ]d2�(pi;n)dp2i

�ipi=pj=p

.

It follows from (2) and Assumption 5 that d(�yL(p))=dp < 0. Hence, if �yL(p

c) �0, then �yL(p) > 0 8 p 2 (pN (c; n); pc). Next, consider:

�yH(p)��yL(p) = �

hc@qi(pi;p;n)@pi

+ �! (1� � � �)

cndq(pi)dpi

ipi=p

.

Assumption 1 and 1���� � 0 imply that the above is positive. So, if �yL(pc) � 0,then �yH(p) > �

yL(p) � 0 8 p 2 (pN (c; n); pc]. Thus, a �rm also will not deviate

once from pc in the high-cost collusive subgame, and nor will it do so from a price

between pN (c; n) and pc in any low- or high-cost punishment subgame.

Given d(�yL(p))=dp < 0, there exists a unique best rigid price, pyL(c; n; �; �; �),

that solves �yL(p) = 0. It satis�es pN (c; n) < pyL(c; n; �; �; �) < pm(c) since

�yL(pN (c; n)) > �zL(p

N (c; n)) � 0 8 c 2 (0;bc] and �yL(pm(c)) < 0. The aboveanalysis implies, any rigid price pc such that pN (c; n) < pc � pyL(c; n; �; �; �) is

supportable by (3) if and only if c 2 (0;bc].Proof of Proposition 1. To �nd the conditions under which setting p(0) and

p(c) > p(0) in low- and high-cost periods, respectively, is supportable by (3), it suf-

�ces to check that a �rm will not deviate once in the collusive subgame and nor will it

do so in every possible punishment subgame. For every history that starts with �rms

setting p(0) and p(c) > p(0) in low- and high-cost periods, the relevant deviation

price at some period � is min(pd� ; p(c� )). If min(pd� ) � p(0), then for any c 2 (0;bc],

(3) de�nes an equilibrium in such subgames if and only if p(0) � pyL(c; n; �; �; �) (seeLemma 2). Otherwise, all other histories lead to subgames equivalent to one where

�rms should set max(pN (c; n);min(pd� ; p(c))) 2 (max(pN (c; n); p(0)); p(c)] and p(0)in high- and low-cost periods, respectively.

Suppose we consider a low-cost subgame where c 2 (0;bc] and the prices arep 2 (p(0); p(c)] and p(0) in high- and low-cost periods, respectively, where without

24

Page 27: Collusive Price Rigidity under Price- Matching Punishmentscompetitionpolicy.ac.uk/documents/107435/0/ccp11-14.pdf · Keywords: Tacit collusion, kinked demand curve, price rigidity

loss of generality let p(0) � pN (c; n). A �rm cannot increase its pro�t by deviating

once to a price above p(0), and deviating once to a price below p(0) is less pro�table

when prices are procyclical than when they are rigid. Thus, any p(0) such that

pN (c; n) < p(0) � pyL(c; n; �; �; �) is supportable by (3), and the best collusive pricein low-cost periods is p�(0) = min(pyL(c; n; �; �; �); p

m) 8 c 2 (0;bc].Now consider a high-cost subgame where c 2 (0;bc] and the prices are p 2

(p�(0); p(c)] and p�(0) in high- and low-cost periods, respectively. It is more prof-

itable to deviate once from p to p�(0) than to a price below p�(0) in a high-cost

period, because �yH(p�(0)) > �yL(p

�(0)) � 0 and prices are strategic comple-

ments. Thus, consider �rm i�s incentive to set pi 2 [p�(0); p]. From (7), de�ne:

�xH(p) �h@�i(pi;p;c;n)

@pi+ �

1�� (1��! )

d�(pi;c;n)dpi

ipi=p

.

A �rm will not deviate once from p(c) in the high-cost subgame if �xH(p(c)) � 0,otherwise it increases its pro�t by unilaterally lowering its price from p(c). We wish

to �nd conditions under which �xH(p) � 0 8 p 2 (p�(0); p(c)]. Di¤erentiating

�xH(p) with respect to p yields:

d(�xH(p))dp =

h@2�i(pi;p;c;n)

@p2i+Pj 6=i

@2�i(pi;p;c;n)@pi@pj

+ �1�� (1�

�! )

d2�(pi;c;n)dp2i

ipi=pj=p

.

It follows from (2) and Assumption 5 that d(�xH(p))=dp < 0. Hence, if�xH(p(c)) �

0, then �xH(p) > 0 8 p 2 (p�(0); p(c)]. Thus, a �rm also will not deviate once from

a price between p�(0) and p(c) in any high-cost punishment subgame. This implies,

the best rigid price is also the best collusive price in a high-cost period if and only

if �xH(pyL(c; n; �; �; �)) � 0, where p

yL(c; n; �; �; �) < p

m since �xH(pm) > 0 when

�yL(pm) � 0.

To prove there exists a unique c� 2 (0;bc) such that �xH(pyL(c�; n; �; �; �)) = 0,�rst notice that c� > 0 since limc!0�xH(p

c) < limc!0�yL(p

c) 8 pc 2 [pN (c; n); pm].Next, consider:

d(�xH(pyL))

dc = �h@qi(pi;p;n)

@pi+ �

(1��)1n [1�

�! ]dq(pi)dpi

� d(�xH(p))dp

dpyLdc

ipi=p=p

yL(c;n;�;�;�)

= �h@qi(pi;p;n)

@pi+ �

(1��)1n [1�

�! � �

�! ]dq(pi)dpi

ipi=p=p

yL(c;n;�;�;�)

where � � [d(�xH(p))=dp]=[d(�yL(p))=dp] > 0 and:

dpyLdc =

1d(�

yL(p))

dp

�(1��)

1n�!dq(pi)dpi

���pi=p=p

yL(c;n;�;�;�)

> 0.

If [1� �! � �

�! ] > 0, then d(�

xH(p

yL))=dc > 0 and � � 1 is su¢ cient for this to be

25

Page 28: Collusive Price Rigidity under Price- Matching Punishmentscompetitionpolicy.ac.uk/documents/107435/0/ccp11-14.pdf · Keywords: Tacit collusion, kinked demand curve, price rigidity

true. Subtracting d(�yL(p))=dp from d(�xH(p))=dp yields:

�hc�@2qi(pi;p;n)

@p2i+Pj 6=i

@2qi(pi;p;n)@pi@pj

�+ �

1�� (1��! )

d2�(pi;n)dp2i

+ �! (1� � � �)

d2�(pi;c;n)dp2i

ipi=pj=p

,

(9)

which is positive from Assumptions 3 and 5, and 1 � � � � � 0, so � < 1. Hence,d(�xH(p

yL))=dc > 0, which implies c� is unique and �xH(p

yL(c; n; �; �; �)) < 0 8

c 2 (0; c�). Finally, to see that c� < bc, consider:�xH(p)��

yL(p) =

h@�i(pi;p;c;n)

@pi+ �

! (1� � � �)d�(pi;c;n)

dpi��zL(p)

ipi=p

. (10)

When evaluated at pyL(c; n; �; �; �), (10) is non-positive 8 c 2 (0; c�]. Di¤erentiating(10) with respect to p yields (9), which is positive. This implies that (10) is negative

8 p 2 [pN (c; n); pyL(c; n; �; �; �)). Thus, for (10) to be negative when evaluated atpN (c; n), it follows that �zL(p

N (c; n)) > 0 since the �rst term on the right-hand

side of (10) is zero and the second is non-negative when 1 � � � � � 0. Given

�zL(pN (bc; n)) = 0, then c� < bc since d(�zL(pN ))=dc < 0 (see Lemma 1).

Proof of Proposition 2. Totalling di¤erentiating �xH(pyL(c; n; �; �; �)) = 0

yields:dc�

d� = � 1d(�x

H(pyL))

dc

d(�xH(pyL))

d�

dc�

d� = � 1d(�x

H(pyL))

dc

d(�xH(pyL))

d�

where d(�xH(pyL))=dc > 0 from Proposition 1.

The total derivative of �xH(pyL(c; n; �; �; �)) with respect to � when � = 1 � �

is:d(�xH(p

yL))

d� =h�1��

d�(pi;c;n)dpi

+d(�xH(p))

dpdpyLd�

ipi=p

yL(c;n;�;�;�)

= �1��

hd�(pi;n)dpi

� (1� �) cndq(pi)dpi

ipi=p

yL(c;n;�;�;�)

where:dpyLd� =

1d(�

yL(p))

dp

�(1��)

cndq(pi)dpi

���pi=p=p

yL(c;n;�;�)

> 0.

The total derivative of �xH(pyL(c; n; �; �; �)) with respect to � is:

d(�xH(pyL))

d� = �h�(1��(1��))(1��)!2

d�(pi;c;n)dpi

� d(�xH(p))dp

dpyLd�

ipi=p

yL(c;n;�;�;�)

= � �(1��)!2

h(1� �[1� �(1� �)])d�(pi;c;n)dpi

+ ���d�(pi;n)dpi

ipi=p

yL(c;n;�;�;�)

where:dpyLd� = �

1d(�

yL(p))

dp

�2�(1��)!2

cndq(pi)dpi

���pi=p=p

yL(c;n;�;�;�)

< 0.

Thus, it follows from Assumptions 1 and 5, and 0 < � < 1 (see Proposition 1) that

26

Page 29: Collusive Price Rigidity under Price- Matching Punishmentscompetitionpolicy.ac.uk/documents/107435/0/ccp11-14.pdf · Keywords: Tacit collusion, kinked demand curve, price rigidity

d(�xH(pyL))=d� > 0 and d(�

xH(p

yL))=d� < 0, so dc

�=d� < 0 when � = 1 � � anddc�=d� > 0.

Proof of Proposition 3. Assumptions 1, 3 and 5 imply that dpyL=dc 2 (0; �=!).This guarantees that when per-period pro�ts are evaluated at pyL(c; n; �; �; �), they

are strictly increasing in c when costs are low but they are strictly decreasing in c

when costs are high.

Next, evaluate p and pc in (6) at pyL(c; n; �; �; �) and totally di¤erentiate with

respect to c. After some rearranging, this yields:

� �1��

�!

"q(p)n + (p�c)

ndq(p)dp

1

�d(�

yL(p))

dp

�j 6=i@q(p;p;n)@pj

#p=pyL(c;n;�;�;�)

.

The above is negative since d�(p;c;n)dp = q(p)

n + (p�c)n

dq(p)dp > 0 when p is evaluated

at pyL(c; n; �; �; �) 2 (pN (c; n); pm), and���d(�yL(p))dp

��� > ���dq(pi)dpi

��� > �j 6=i@q(p;p;n)@pj

. This

implies, each �rm�s present discounted value of collusive pro�ts in a low-cost period

is decreasing in c.

Finally, evaluate p and pc in (5) at pyL(c; n; �; �; �) and totally di¤erentiate with

respect to c. After some rearranging, this yields:

�hq(p)n

�1� dpyL

dc

�+ q(p)

n�1��

�1� �=! � dpyL

dc

�� dq(p)

dp

�(p� c) + �

1�� (p� (1��! )c)

�dpyLdc

ip=pyL(c;n;�;�;�)

.

It follows from Assumption 1 and from 0 < dpyL=dc < �=! � (1 � �=!) < 1 when

1���� � 0 that the above is negative. This implies, each �rm�s present discountedvalue of collusive pro�ts in a high-cost period is decreasing in c.

27