chapter 2: demand theory - faculty.ses.wsu.edufaculty.ses.wsu.edu/espinola/demand...

108
Demand Theory

Upload: others

Post on 07-Jul-2020

22 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Demand Theory

Utility Maximization Problem

โ€ข Consumer maximizes his utility level by selecting a bundle ๐‘ฅ (where ๐‘ฅ can be a vector) subject to his budget constraint:

max๐‘ฅโ‰ฅ0

๐‘ข(๐‘ฅ)

s. t. ๐‘ โˆ™ ๐‘ฅ โ‰ค ๐‘ค

โ€ข Weierstrass Theorem: for optimization problems defined on the reals, if the objective function is continuous and constraints define a closed and bounded set, then the solution to such optimization problem exists.

2

Utility Maximization Problem

โ€ข Existence: if ๐‘ โ‰ซ 0 and ๐‘ค > 0 (i.e., if ๐ต๐‘,๐‘ค is closed and bounded), and if ๐‘ข(โˆ™) is continuous, then there exists at least one solution to the UMP.โ€“ If, in addition, preferences are strictly convex, then the

solution to the UMP is unique.

โ€ข We denote the solution of the UMP as the argmax of the UMP (the argument, ๐‘ฅ, that solves the optimization problem), and we denote it as ๐‘ฅ(๐‘, ๐‘ค). โ€“ ๐‘ฅ(๐‘, ๐‘ค) is the Walrasian demand correspondence, which

specifies a demand of every good in โ„+๐ฟ for every possible

price vector, ๐‘, and every possible wealth level, ๐‘ค.

3

Utility Maximization Problem

โ€ข Walrasian demand ๐‘ฅ(๐‘, ๐‘ค)at bundle A is optimal, as the consumer reaches a utility level of ๐‘ข2 by exhausting all his wealth.

โ€ข Bundles B and C are not optimal, despite exhausting the consumerโ€™s wealth. They yield a lower utility level ๐‘ข1, where ๐‘ข1 < ๐‘ข2.

โ€ข Bundle D is unaffordable and, hence, it cannot be the argmax of the UMP given a wealth level of ๐‘ค.

4

Properties of Walrasian Demand

โ€ข If the utility function is continuous and preferences satisfy LNS over the consumption set ๐‘‹ = โ„+

๐ฟ , then the Walrasian demand ๐‘ฅ(๐‘, ๐‘ค) satisfies:

1) Homogeneity of degree zero:

๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค = ๐‘ฅ(๐›ผ๐‘, ๐›ผ๐‘ค) for all ๐‘, ๐‘ค, and for all ๐›ผ > 0

That is, the budget set is unchanged!

๐‘ฅ โˆˆ โ„+๐ฟ : ๐‘ โˆ™ ๐‘ฅ โ‰ค ๐‘ค = ๐‘ฅ โˆˆ โ„+

๐ฟ : ๐›ผ๐‘ โˆ™ ๐‘ฅ โ‰ค ๐›ผ๐‘ค

Note that we donโ€™t need any assumption on the preference relation to show this. We only rely on the budget set being affected.

5

x1

x2

wp2

ฮฑ wฮฑ p2

=

wp1

ฮฑ wฮฑ p1

=

x (p,w), unaffected

Properties of Walrasian Demand

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 6

โ€“ Note that the preference relation can be linear, and homog(0) would still hold.

2) Walrasโ€™ Law:

๐‘ โˆ™ ๐‘ฅ โ‰ค ๐‘ค for all ๐‘ฅ = ๐‘ฅ(๐‘, ๐‘ค)

It follows from LNS: if the consumer selects a Walrasian demand ๐‘ฅ โˆˆ ๐‘ฅ(๐‘, ๐‘ค), where ๐‘ โˆ™ ๐‘ฅ < ๐‘ค, then it means we can still find other bundle ๐‘ฆ, which is ฮตโ€“close to ๐‘ฅ, where consumer can improve his utility level.

If the bundle the consumer chooses lies on the budget line, i.e., ๐‘ โˆ™ ๐‘ฅโ€ฒ = ๐‘ค, we could then identify bundles that are strictly preferred to ๐‘ฅโ€ฒ, but these bundles would be unaffordable to the consumer.

Properties of Walrasian Demand

7

x

x2

x1

Properties of Walrasian Demand

8

โ€“ For ๐‘ฅ โˆˆ ๐‘ฅ(๐‘, ๐‘ค), there is a bundle ๐‘ฆ, ฮตโ€“close to ๐‘ฅ, such that ๐‘ฆ โ‰ป ๐‘ฅ. Then, ๐‘ฅ โˆ‰ ๐‘ฅ(๐‘, ๐‘ค).

Properties of Walrasian Demand

3) Convexity/Uniqueness:

a) If the preferences are convex, then the Walrasian demand correspondence ๐‘ฅ(๐‘, ๐‘ค)defines a convex set, i.e., a continuum of bundles are utility maximizing.

b) If the preferences are strictly convex, then the Walrasian demand correspondence ๐‘ฅ(๐‘, ๐‘ค)contains a single element.

9

Properties of Walrasian Demand

Convex preferences Strictly convex preferences

10

( , )x x p w

Unique ( , )x p w

UMP: Necessary Condition

max๐‘ฅโ‰ฅ0

๐‘ข ๐‘ฅ s. t. ๐‘ โˆ™ ๐‘ฅ โ‰ค ๐‘ค

โ€ข We solve it using Kuhn-Tucker conditions over the Lagrangian ๐ฟ = ๐‘ข ๐‘ฅ + ๐œ†(๐‘ค โˆ’ ๐‘ โˆ™ ๐‘ฅ),

๐œ•๐ฟ

๐œ•๐‘ฅ๐‘˜=

๐œ•๐‘ข(๐‘ฅโˆ—)

๐œ•๐‘ฅ๐‘˜โˆ’ ๐œ†๐‘๐‘˜ โ‰ค 0 for all ๐‘˜, = 0 if ๐‘ฅ๐‘˜

โˆ— > 0

๐œ•๐ฟ

๐œ•๐œ†= ๐‘ค โˆ’ ๐‘ โˆ™ ๐‘ฅโˆ— = 0

โ€ข That is in the interior optimum, ๐œ•๐‘ข(๐‘ฅโˆ—)

๐œ•๐‘ฅ๐‘˜= ๐œ†๐‘๐‘˜ for every

good ๐‘˜, which implies๐œ•๐‘ข(๐‘ฅโˆ—)

๐œ•๐‘ฅ๐‘™๐œ•๐‘ข(๐‘ฅโˆ—)

๐œ•๐‘ฅ๐‘˜

=๐‘๐‘™

๐‘๐‘˜โ‡” ๐‘€๐‘…๐‘† ๐‘™,๐‘˜ =

๐‘๐‘™

๐‘๐‘˜โ‡”

๐œ•๐‘ข(๐‘ฅโˆ—)

๐œ•๐‘ฅ๐‘™

๐‘๐‘™=

๐œ•๐‘ข(๐‘ฅโˆ—)

๐œ•๐‘ฅ๐‘˜

๐‘๐‘˜

11

UMP: Sufficient Condition

โ€ข When are Kuhn-Tucker (necessary) conditions, also sufficient?

โ€“ That is, when can we guarantee that ๐‘ฅ(๐‘, ๐‘ค) is the max of the UMP and not the min?

โ€ข Answer: if ๐‘ข(โˆ™) is quasiconcave and monotone, and has Hessian ๐›ป๐‘ข(๐‘ฅ) โ‰  0 for ๐‘ฅ โˆˆ โ„+

๐ฟ , then the Kuhn-Tucker FOCs are also sufficient.

12

UMP: Sufficient Condition

โ€ข Kuhn-Tucker conditions are sufficient for a max if:

1) ๐‘ข(๐‘ฅ) is quasiconcave, i.e., convex upper contour set (UCS).

2) ๐‘ข(๐‘ฅ) is monotone.3) ๐›ป๐‘ข(๐‘ฅ) โ‰  0 for ๐‘ฅ โˆˆ โ„+

๐ฟ .โ€“ If ๐›ป๐‘ข ๐‘ฅ = 0 for some ๐‘ฅ,

then we would be at the โ€œtop of the mountainโ€ (i.e., blissing point), which violates both LNS and monotonicity.

13

x1

x2

wp2

wp1

x * โˆˆ x (p,w)

slope = - p2

p1

Ind. Curve

UMP: Violations of Sufficient Condition

1) ๐’–(โˆ™) is non-monotone:

โ€“ The consumer chooses bundle A (at a corner) since it yields the highest utility level given his budget constraint.

โ€“ At point A, however, the tangency condition

๐‘€๐‘…๐‘† 1,2 =๐‘1

๐‘2does not

hold.

14

UMP: Violations of Sufficient Condition

15

x2

x1

A

B

C

Budget line

โ€“ The upper contour sets (UCS) are not convex.

โ€“ ๐‘€๐‘…๐‘† 1,2 =๐‘1

๐‘2is not a

sufficient condition for a max.

โ€“ A point of tangency (C) gives a lower utility level than a point of non-tangency (B).

โ€“ True maximum is at point A.

2) ๐’–(โˆ™) is not quasiconcave:

UMP: Corner Solution

โ€ข Analyzing differential changes in ๐‘ฅ๐‘™ and ๐‘ฅ๐‘™, that keep individualโ€™s utility unchanged, ๐‘‘๐‘ข = 0,

๐‘‘๐‘ข(๐‘ฅ)

๐‘‘๐‘ฅ๐‘™๐‘‘๐‘ฅ๐‘™ +

๐‘‘๐‘ข(๐‘ฅ)

๐‘‘๐‘ฅ๐‘˜๐‘‘๐‘ฅ๐‘˜ = 0 (total diff.)

โ€ข Rearranging,

๐‘‘๐‘ฅ๐‘˜

๐‘‘๐‘ฅ๐‘™= โˆ’

๐‘‘๐‘ข ๐‘ฅ๐‘‘๐‘ฅ๐‘™

๐‘‘๐‘ข ๐‘ฅ๐‘‘๐‘ฅ๐‘˜

= โˆ’๐‘€๐‘…๐‘†๐‘™,๐‘˜

โ€ข Corner Solution: ๐‘€๐‘…๐‘†๐‘™,๐‘˜ >๐‘๐‘™

๐‘๐‘˜, or alternatively,

๐‘‘๐‘ข ๐‘ฅโˆ—

๐‘‘๐‘ฅ๐‘™

๐‘๐‘™>

๐‘‘๐‘ข ๐‘ฅโˆ—

๐‘‘๐‘ฅ๐‘˜

๐‘๐‘˜, i.e.,

the consumer prefers to consume more of good ๐‘™.

16

UMP: Corner Solution

โ€ข In the FOCs, this implies:

a)๐œ•๐‘ข(๐‘ฅโˆ—)

๐œ•๐‘ฅ๐‘˜โ‰ค ๐œ†๐‘๐‘˜ for the goods whose consumption is

zero, ๐‘ฅ๐‘˜โˆ—= 0, and

b)๐œ•๐‘ข(๐‘ฅโˆ—)

๐œ•๐‘ฅ๐‘™= ๐œ†๐‘๐‘™ for the good whose consumption is

positive, ๐‘ฅ๐‘™โˆ—> 0.

โ€ข Intuition: the marginal utility per dollar spent on good ๐‘™ is still larger than that on good ๐‘˜.

๐œ•๐‘ข(๐‘ฅโˆ—)

๐œ•๐‘ฅ๐‘™

๐‘๐‘™= ๐œ† โ‰ฅ

๐œ•๐‘ข(๐‘ฅโˆ—)

๐œ•๐‘ฅ๐‘˜

๐‘๐‘˜

17

UMP: Corner Solution

โ€ข Consumer seeks to consume good 1 alone.

โ€ข At the corner solution, the indifference curve is steeper than the budget line, i.e.,

๐‘€๐‘…๐‘†1,2 >๐‘1

๐‘2or

๐‘€๐‘ˆ1

๐‘1>

๐‘€๐‘ˆ2

๐‘2

โ€ข Intuitively, the consumer would like to consume more of good 1, even after spending his entire wealth on good 1 alone.

18

x1

x2

wp2

wp1

slope of the B.L. = - p2

p1

slope of the I.C. = MRS1,2

UMP: Lagrange Multiplier

โ€ข ๐œ† is referred to as the โ€œmarginal values of relaxing the constraintโ€ in the UMP (a.k.a.โ€œshadow price of wealthโ€).

โ€ข If we provide more wealth to the consumer, he is capable of reaching a higher indifference curve and, as a consequence, obtaining a higher utility level.

โ€“ We want to measure the change in utility resulting from a marginal increase in wealth.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 19

x1

x2

w 0

p2

{x +: u(x) = u 1}2

{x +: u(x) = u 0}2

w 1

p2

w 0

p1

w 1

p1

UMP: Lagrange Multiplier

โ€ข Analyze the change in utility from change in wealth using chain rule (since ๐‘ข ๐‘ฅ does not contain wealth),

๐›ป๐‘ข ๐‘ฅ(๐‘, ๐‘ค) โˆ™ ๐ท๐‘ค๐‘ฅ(๐‘, ๐‘ค)

โ€ข Substituting ๐›ป๐‘ข ๐‘ฅ(๐‘, ๐‘ค) = ๐œ†๐‘ (in interior solutions),

๐œ†๐‘ โˆ™ ๐ท๐‘ค๐‘ฅ(๐‘, ๐‘ค)

20

UMP: Lagrange Multiplier

โ€ข From Walrasโ€™ Law, ๐‘ โˆ™ ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค = ๐‘ค, the change in expenditure from an increase in wealth is given by

๐ท๐‘ค ๐‘ โˆ™ ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค = ๐‘ โˆ™ ๐ท๐‘ค๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค = 1

โ€ข Hence, ๐›ป๐‘ข ๐‘ฅ(๐‘, ๐‘ค) โˆ™ ๐ท๐‘ค๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค = ๐œ† ๐‘ โˆ™ ๐ท๐‘ค๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค

1

= ๐œ†

โ€ข Intuition: If ๐œ† = 5, then a $1 increase in wealth implies an increase in 5 units of utility.

21

Walrasian Demand

โ€ข We found the Walrasian demand function, ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค , as the solution to the UMP.

โ€ข Properties of ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค :1) Homog(0), for any ๐‘, ๐‘ค, ๐›ผ > 0,

๐‘ฅ ๐›ผ๐‘, ๐›ผ๐‘ค = ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค(Budget set is unaffected by changes in ๐‘ and ๐‘ค of the same size)

2) Walrasโ€™ Law: for every ๐‘ โ‰ซ 0, ๐‘ค > 0 we have ๐‘ โˆ™ ๐‘ฅ = ๐‘ค for all ๐‘ฅ โˆˆ ๐‘ฅ(๐‘, ๐‘ค)

(This is because of LNS)

22

Walrasian Demand: Wealth Effects

โ€ข Normal vs. Inferior goods

๐œ•๐‘ฅ ๐‘,๐‘ค

๐œ•๐‘ค

><

0 normalinferior

โ€ข Examples of inferior goods:

โ€“ Two-buck chuck (a really cheap wine)

โ€“ Walmart during the economic crisis

23

Walrasian Demand: Wealth Effects

โ€ข An increase in the wealth level produces an outward shift in the budget line.

โ€ข ๐‘ฅ2 is normal as ๐œ•๐‘ฅ2 ๐‘,๐‘ค

๐œ•๐‘ค> 0, while

๐‘ฅ1 is inferior as ๐œ•๐‘ฅ ๐‘,๐‘ค

๐œ•๐‘ค< 0.

โ€ข Wealth expansion path: โ€“ connects the optimal consumption

bundle for different levels of wealth

โ€“ indicates how the consumption of a good changes as a consequence of changes in the wealth level

24

Walrasian Demand: Wealth Effects

โ€ข Engel curve depicts the consumption of a particular good in the horizontal axis and wealth on the vertical axis.

โ€ข The slope of the Engel curve is:

โ€“ positive if the good is normal

โ€“ negative if the good is inferior

โ€ข Engel curve can be positively slopped for low wealth levels and become negatively slopped afterwards.

25

x1

Wealth, w

ลต

Engel curve for a normal good (up to income ลต), but inferior

good for all w > ลต

Engel curve of a normal good, for all w.

Walrasian Demand: Price Effects

โ€ข Own price effect:๐œ•๐‘ฅ๐‘˜ ๐‘, ๐‘ค

๐œ•๐‘๐‘˜

<>

0UsualGiffen

โ€ข Cross-price effect:๐œ•๐‘ฅ๐‘˜ ๐‘, ๐‘ค

๐œ•๐‘๐‘™

><

0Substitutes

Complements

โ€“ Examples of Substitutes: two brands of mineral water, such as Aquafine vs. Poland Springs.

โ€“ Examples of Complements: cars and gasoline.

26

Walrasian Demand: Price Effects

โ€ข Own price effect

27

Usual good Giffen good

Walrasian Demand: Price Effects

28

โ€ข Cross-price effect

Substitutes Complements

Indirect Utility Function

โ€ข The Walrasian demand function, ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค , is the solution to the UMP (i.e., argmax).

โ€ข What would be the utility function evaluated at the solution of the UMP, i.e., ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค ?

โ€“ This is the indirect utility function (i.e., the highest utility level), ๐‘ฃ ๐‘, ๐‘ค โˆˆ โ„, associated with the UMP.

โ€“ It is the โ€œvalue functionโ€ of this optimization problem.

29

Properties of Indirect Utility Function

โ€ข If the utility function is continuous and preferences satisfy LNS over the consumption set ๐‘‹ = โ„+

๐ฟ , then the indirect utility function ๐‘ฃ ๐‘, ๐‘ค satisfies:

1) Homogenous of degree zero: Increasing ๐‘ and ๐‘คby a common factor ๐›ผ > 0 does not modify the consumerโ€™s optimal consumption bundle,๐‘ฅ(๐‘, ๐‘ค), nor his maximal utility level, measured by ๐‘ฃ ๐‘, ๐‘ค .

30

Properties of Indirect Utility Function

31

x1

x2

wp2

ฮฑ wฮฑ p2

=

wp1

ฮฑ wฮฑ p1

=

x (p,w) = x (ฮฑp,ฮฑ w)

v (p,w) = v (ฮฑp,ฮฑ w)

Bp,w = Bฮฑp,ฮฑw

Properties of Indirect Utility Function

2) Strictly increasing in ๐‘ค:

๐‘ฃ ๐‘, ๐‘คโ€ฒ > ๐‘ฃ(๐‘, ๐‘ค) for ๐‘คโ€ฒ > ๐‘ค.

3) non-increasing (i.e., weakly decreasing) in ๐‘๐‘˜

32

Properties of Indirect Utility Function

33

W

P1

w2

w1

4) Quasiconvex: The set ๐‘, ๐‘ค : ๐‘ฃ(๐‘, ๐‘ค) โ‰ค าง๐‘ฃ is convex for any าง๐‘ฃ.

- Interpretation I: If (๐‘1, ๐‘ค1) โ‰ฟโˆ— (๐‘2, ๐‘ค2), then (๐‘1, ๐‘ค1) โ‰ฟโˆ— (๐œ†๐‘1 +(1 โˆ’ ๐œ†)๐‘2, ๐œ†๐‘ค1 + (1 โˆ’ ๐œ†)๐‘ค2); i.e., if ๐ด โ‰ฟโˆ— ๐ต, then ๐ด โ‰ฟโˆ— ๐ถ.

Properties of Indirect Utility Function

- Interpretation II: ๐‘ฃ(๐‘, ๐‘ค) is quasiconvex if the set of (๐‘, ๐‘ค) pairs for which ๐‘ฃ ๐‘, ๐‘ค < ๐‘ฃ(๐‘โˆ—, ๐‘คโˆ—) is convex.

34

W

P1

w*

p*

v(p,w) < v(p*,w

*)

v(p,w) = v1

Properties of Indirect Utility Function

- Interpretation III: Using ๐‘ฅ1 and ๐‘ฅ2 in the axis, perform following steps:

1) When ๐ต๐‘,๐‘ค, then ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค

2) When ๐ต๐‘โ€ฒ,๐‘คโ€ฒ, then ๐‘ฅ ๐‘โ€ฒ, ๐‘คโ€ฒ

3) Both ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค and ๐‘ฅ ๐‘โ€ฒ, ๐‘คโ€ฒ induce an indirect utility of ๐‘ฃ ๐‘, ๐‘ค = ๐‘ฃ ๐‘โ€ฒ, ๐‘คโ€ฒ = เดค๐‘ข

4) Construct a linear combination of prices and wealth:

เต ๐‘โ€ฒโ€ฒ = ๐›ผ๐‘ + (1 โˆ’ ๐›ผ)๐‘โ€ฒ

๐‘คโ€ฒโ€ฒ = ๐›ผ๐‘ค + (1 โˆ’ ๐›ผ)๐‘คโ€ฒ ๐ต๐‘โ€ฒโ€ฒ,๐‘คโ€ฒโ€ฒ

5) Any solution to the UMP given ๐ต๐‘โ€ฒโ€ฒ,๐‘คโ€ฒโ€ฒ must lie on a lower indifference curve (i.e., lower utility)

๐‘ฃ ๐‘โ€ฒโ€ฒ, ๐‘คโ€ฒโ€ฒ โ‰ค เดค๐‘ข

35

Properties of Indirect Utility Function

36

x1

x2

Bp,wBpโ€™,wโ€™Bpโ€™โ€™,wโ€™โ€™

x (p,w)

x (pโ€™,wโ€™ )

Ind. Curve {x โˆˆโ„2:u(x) = ลซ}

WARP and Walrasian Demand

โ€ข Relation between Walrasian demand ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘คand WARP

โ€“ How does the WARP restrict the set of optimal consumption bundles that the individual decision-maker can select when solving the UMP?

37

WARP and Walrasian Demand

โ€ข Take two different consumption bundles ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค and ๐‘ฅ ๐‘โ€ฒ, ๐‘คโ€ฒ , both being affordable ๐‘, ๐‘ค , i.e.,

๐‘ โˆ™ ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค โ‰ค ๐‘ค and ๐‘ โˆ™ ๐‘ฅ ๐‘โ€ฒ, ๐‘คโ€ฒ โ‰ค ๐‘ค

โ€ข When prices and wealth are ๐‘, ๐‘ค , the consumer chooses ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค despite ๐‘ฅ ๐‘โ€ฒ, ๐‘คโ€ฒ is also affordable.

โ€ข Then he โ€œrevealsโ€ a preference for ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค over ๐‘ฅ ๐‘โ€ฒ, ๐‘คโ€ฒwhen both are affordable.

โ€ข Hence, we should expect him to choose ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค over ๐‘ฅ ๐‘โ€ฒ, ๐‘คโ€ฒ when both are affordable. (Consistency)

โ€ข Therefore, bundle ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค must not be affordable at ๐‘โ€ฒ, ๐‘คโ€ฒ because the consumer chooses ๐‘ฅ ๐‘โ€ฒ, ๐‘คโ€ฒ . That is,

๐‘โ€ฒ โˆ™ ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค > ๐‘คโ€ฒ.

38

WARP and Walrasian Demand

โ€ข In summary, Walrasian demand satisfies WARP, if, for two different consumption bundles, ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค โ‰  ๐‘ฅ ๐‘โ€ฒ, ๐‘คโ€ฒ ,

๐‘ โˆ™ ๐‘ฅ ๐‘โ€ฒ, ๐‘คโ€ฒ โ‰ค ๐‘ค โ‡’ ๐‘โ€ฒ โˆ™ ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค > ๐‘คโ€ฒ

โ€ข Intuition: if ๐‘ฅ ๐‘โ€ฒ, ๐‘คโ€ฒ is affordable under budget set ๐ต๐‘,๐‘ค, then ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค cannot be affordable

under ๐ต๐‘โ€ฒ,๐‘คโ€ฒ.

39

Checking for WARP

โ€ข A systematic procedure to check if Walrasian demand satisfies WARP:โ€“ Step 1: Check if bundles ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค and ๐‘ฅ ๐‘โ€ฒ, ๐‘คโ€ฒ are

both affordable under ๐ต๐‘,๐‘ค. That is, graphically ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค and ๐‘ฅ ๐‘โ€ฒ, ๐‘คโ€ฒ have to lie on

or below budget line ๐ต๐‘,๐‘ค.

If step 1 is satisfied, then move to step 2.

Otherwise, the premise of WARP does not hold, which does not allow us to continue checking if WARP is violated or not. In this case, we can only say that โ€œWARP is not violatedโ€.

40

Checking for WARP

- Step 2: Check if bundles ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค is affordable under ๐ต๐‘โ€ฒ,๐‘คโ€ฒ.

That is, graphically ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค must lie on or below budge line ๐ต๐‘โ€ฒ,๐‘คโ€ฒ.

If step 2 is satisfied, then this Walrasian demand violates WARP.

Otherwise, the Walrasian demand satisfies WARP.

41

Checking for WARP: Example 1

โ€ข First, ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค and ๐‘ฅ ๐‘โ€ฒ, ๐‘คโ€ฒ are both affordable under ๐ต๐‘,๐‘ค.

โ€ข Second, ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค is not affordable under ๐ต๐‘โ€ฒ,๐‘คโ€ฒ.

โ€ข Hence, WARP is satisfied!

42

x1

x2

w p2

wp1

Bp,w

Bp ,w

x (p,w)

x (p ,w )

Checking for WARP: Example 2

โ€ข The demand ๐‘ฅ ๐‘โ€ฒ, ๐‘คโ€ฒunder final prices and wealth is not affordable under initial prices and wealth, i.e., ๐‘ โˆ™ ๐‘ฅ ๐‘โ€ฒ, ๐‘คโ€ฒ > ๐‘ค.โ€“ The premise of WARP

does not hold.

โ€“ Violation of Step 1!

โ€“ WARP is not violated.

43

Checking for WARP: Example 3

โ€ข The demand ๐‘ฅ ๐‘โ€ฒ, ๐‘คโ€ฒunder final prices and wealth is not affordable under initial prices and wealth, i.e., ๐‘ โˆ™ ๐‘ฅ ๐‘โ€ฒ, ๐‘คโ€ฒ > ๐‘ค.โ€“ The premise of WARP

does not hold.

โ€“ Violation of Step 1!

โ€“ WARP is not violated.

44

Checking for WARP: Example 4

โ€ข The demand ๐‘ฅ ๐‘โ€ฒ, ๐‘คโ€ฒunder final prices and wealth is not affordable under initial prices and wealth, i.e., ๐‘ โˆ™ ๐‘ฅ ๐‘โ€ฒ, ๐‘คโ€ฒ > ๐‘ค.โ€“ The premise of WARP

does not hold.

โ€“ Violation of Step 1!

โ€“ WARP is not violated.

45

Checking for WARP: Example 5

46

x1

x2

w p2

wp1

Bp,w

Bp ,w x (p,w)x (p ,w )

โ€ข First, ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค and ๐‘ฅ ๐‘โ€ฒ, ๐‘คโ€ฒ are both affordable under ๐ต๐‘,๐‘ค.

โ€ข Second, ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค is affordable under ๐ต๐‘โ€ฒ,๐‘คโ€ฒ, i.e., ๐‘โ€ฒ โˆ™ ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค < ๐‘คโ€ฒ

โ€ข Hence, WARP is NOTsatisfied!

Implications of WARP

โ€ข How do price changes affect the WARP predictions?โ€ข Assume a reduction in ๐‘1

โ€“ the consumerโ€™s budget lines rotates (uncompensated price change)

47

Implications of WARP

โ€ข Adjust the consumerโ€™s wealth level so that he can consume his initial demand ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค at the new prices.

โ€“ shift the final budget line inwards until the point at which we reach the initial consumption bundle ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค (compensated price change)

48

Implications of WARP

โ€ข What is the wealth adjustment?๐‘ค = ๐‘ โˆ™ ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค under ๐‘, ๐‘ค

๐‘คโ€ฒ = ๐‘โ€ฒ โˆ™ ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค under ๐‘โ€ฒ, ๐‘คโ€ฒ

โ€ข Then,โˆ†๐‘ค = โˆ†๐‘ โˆ™ ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค

where โˆ†๐‘ค = ๐‘คโ€ฒ โˆ’ ๐‘ค and โˆ†๐‘ = ๐‘โ€ฒ โˆ’ ๐‘.

โ€ข This is the Slutsky wealth compensation: โ€“ the increase (decrease) in wealth, measured by โˆ†๐‘ค, that we

must provide to the consumer so that he can afford the same consumption bundle as before the price change, i.e., ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค .

49

Implications of WARP: Law of Demand

โ€ข Suppose that the Walrasian demand ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค satisfies homog(0) and Walrasโ€™ Law. Then, ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค satisfies WARP iff:

โˆ†๐‘ โˆ™ โˆ†๐‘ฅ โ‰ค 0

whereโ€“ โˆ†๐‘ = ๐‘โ€ฒ โˆ’ ๐‘ and โˆ†๐‘ฅ = ๐‘ฅ ๐‘โ€ฒ, ๐‘คโ€ฒ โˆ’ ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค

โ€“ ๐‘คโ€ฒ is the wealth level that allows the consumer to buy the initial demand at the new prices, ๐‘คโ€ฒ = ๐‘โ€ฒ โˆ™ ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค

โ€ข This is the Law of Demand: quantity demanded and price move in different directions.

50

Implications of WARP: Law of Demand

โ€ข Does WARP restrict behavior when we apply Slutsky wealth compensations? โ€“ Yes!

โ€ข What if we were not applying the Slutsky wealth compensation, would WARP impose any restriction on allowable locations for ๐‘ฅ ๐‘โ€ฒ, ๐‘คโ€ฒ ?โ€“ No!

51

Implications of WARP: Law of Demand

52

โ€ข See the discussions on the next slide

Implications of WARP: Law of Demand

โ€ข Can ๐‘ฅ ๐‘โ€ฒ, ๐‘คโ€ฒ lie on segment A?1) ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค and ๐‘ฅ ๐‘โ€ฒ, ๐‘คโ€ฒ are both affordable under

๐ต๐‘,๐‘ค.

2) ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค is affordable under ๐ต๐‘โ€ฒ,๐‘คโ€ฒ. โ‡’ WARP is violated if ๐‘ฅ ๐‘โ€ฒ, ๐‘คโ€ฒ lies on segment A

โ€ข Can ๐‘ฅ ๐‘โ€ฒ, ๐‘คโ€ฒ lie on segment B?1) ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค is affordable under ๐ต๐‘,๐‘ค, but ๐‘ฅ ๐‘โ€ฒ, ๐‘คโ€ฒ is

not. โ‡’ the premise of WARP does not holdโ‡’ WARP is not violated if ๐‘ฅ ๐‘โ€ฒ, ๐‘คโ€ฒ lies on segment B

53

Implications of WARP: Law of Demand

โ€ข What did we learn from this figure?1) We started from ๐›ป๐‘1, and compensated the wealth of

this individual (reducing it from ๐‘ค to ๐‘คโ€ฒ) so that he could afford his initial bundle ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค under the new prices. From this wealth compensation, we obtained budget line ๐ต๐‘โ€ฒ,๐‘คโ€ฒ.

2) From WARP, we know that ๐‘ฅ ๐‘โ€ฒ, ๐‘คโ€ฒ must contain more of good 1. That is, graphically, segment B lies to the right-hand side of

๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค .

3) Then, a price reduction, ๐›ป๐‘1, when followed by an appropriate wealth compensation leads to an increase in the quantity demanded of this good, โˆ†๐‘ฅ1. This is the compensated law of demand (CLD).

54

Implications of WARP: Law of Demand

โ€ข Practice problem:โ€“ Can you repeat this analysis but for an increase in

the price of good 1? First, pivot budget line ๐ต๐‘,๐‘ค inwards to obtain ๐ต๐‘โ€ฒ,๐‘ค.

Then, increase the wealth level (wealth compensation) to obtain ๐ต๐‘โ€ฒ,๐‘คโ€ฒ.

Identify the two segments in budget line ๐ต๐‘โ€ฒ,๐‘คโ€ฒ, one to the right-hand side of ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค and other to the left.

In which segment of budget line ๐ต๐‘โ€ฒ,๐‘คโ€ฒ can the Walrasian demand ๐‘ฅ(๐‘โ€ฒ, ๐‘คโ€ฒ) lie?

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 55

Implications of WARP: Law of Demand

โ€ข Is WARP satisfied under the uncompensated law of demand (ULD)?โ€“ ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค is affordable under

budget line ๐ต๐‘,๐‘ค, but ๐‘ฅ(๐‘โ€ฒ, ๐‘ค) is not. Hence, the premise of WARP is

not satisfied. As a result, WARP is not violated.

โ€“ But, is this result imply something about whether ULD must hold? No! Although WARP is not violated,

ULD is: a decrease in the price of good 1 yields a decrease in the quantity demanded.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 56

Implications of WARP: Law of Demand

โ€ข Distinction between the uncompensated and the compensated law of demand:โ€“ quantity demanded and price can move in the same

direction, when wealth is left uncompensated, i.e.,

โˆ†๐‘1 โˆ™ โˆ†๐‘ฅ1 > 0as โˆ†๐‘1 โ‡’ โˆ†๐‘ฅ1

โ€ข Hence, WARP is not sufficient to yield law of demand for price changes that are uncompensated, i.e.,

WARP โ‡Ž ULD, butWARP โ‡” CLD

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 57

Implications of WARP: Slutsky Matrix

โ€ข Let us focus now on the case in which ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค is differentiable.

โ€ข First, note that the law of demand is ๐‘‘๐‘ โˆ™ ๐‘‘๐‘ฅ โ‰ค 0(equivalent to โˆ†๐‘ โˆ™ โˆ†๐‘ฅ โ‰ค 0).

โ€ข Totally differentiating ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค ,๐‘‘๐‘ฅ = ๐ท๐‘๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค ๐‘‘๐‘ + ๐ท๐‘ค๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค ๐‘‘๐‘ค

โ€ข And since the consumerโ€™s wealth is compensated, ๐‘‘๐‘ค = ๐‘ฅ(๐‘, ๐‘ค) โˆ™ ๐‘‘๐‘ (this is the differential analog of โˆ†๐‘ค = โˆ†๐‘ โˆ™ ๐‘ฅ(๐‘, ๐‘ค)).โ€“ Recall that โˆ†๐‘ค = โˆ†๐‘ โˆ™ ๐‘ฅ(๐‘, ๐‘ค) was obtained from the

Slutsky wealth compensation.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 58

Implications of WARP: Slutsky Matrix

โ€ข Substituting,๐‘‘๐‘ฅ = ๐ท๐‘๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค ๐‘‘๐‘ + ๐ท๐‘ค๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค ๐‘ฅ(๐‘, ๐‘ค) โˆ™ ๐‘‘๐‘

๐‘‘๐‘ค

โ€ข or equivalently,

๐‘‘๐‘ฅ = ๐ท๐‘๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค + ๐ท๐‘ค๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค ๐‘ฅ(๐‘, ๐‘ค)๐‘‡ ๐‘‘๐‘

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 59

Implications of WARP: Slutsky Matrix

โ€ข Hence the law of demand, ๐‘‘๐‘ โˆ™ ๐‘‘๐‘ฅ โ‰ค 0, can be expressed as

๐‘‘๐‘ โˆ™ ๐ท๐‘๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค + ๐ท๐‘ค๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค ๐‘ฅ(๐‘, ๐‘ค)๐‘‡ ๐‘‘๐‘

๐‘‘๐‘ฅ

โ‰ค 0

where the term in brackets is the Slutsky (or substitution) matrix

๐‘† ๐‘, ๐‘ค =๐‘ 11 ๐‘, ๐‘ค โ‹ฏ ๐‘ 1๐ฟ ๐‘, ๐‘ค

โ‹ฎ โ‹ฑ โ‹ฎ๐‘ ๐ฟ1 ๐‘, ๐‘ค โ‹ฏ ๐‘ ๐ฟ๐ฟ ๐‘, ๐‘ค

where

๐‘ ๐‘™๐‘˜ ๐‘, ๐‘ค =๐œ•๐‘ฅ๐‘™(๐‘, ๐‘ค)

๐œ•๐‘๐‘˜+

๐œ•๐‘ฅ๐‘™ ๐‘, ๐‘ค

๐œ•๐‘ค๐‘ฅ๐‘˜(๐‘, ๐‘ค)

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 60

Implications of WARP: Slutsky Matrix

โ€ข Proposition: If ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค is differentiable, satisfies WL, homog(0), and WARP, then ๐‘† ๐‘, ๐‘ค is negative semi-definite,

๐‘ฃ โˆ™ ๐‘† ๐‘, ๐‘ค ๐‘ฃ โ‰ค 0 for any ๐‘ฃ โˆˆ โ„๐ฟ

โ€ข Implications:โ€“ ๐‘ ๐‘™๐‘˜ ๐‘, ๐‘ค : substitution effect of good ๐‘™ with respect to

its own price is non-positive (own-price effect)โ€“ Negative semi-definiteness does not imply that

๐‘† ๐‘, ๐‘ค is symmetric (except when ๐ฟ = 2). Usual confusion: โ€œthen ๐‘† ๐‘, ๐‘ค is not symmetricโ€, NO!

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 61

Implications of WARP: Slutsky Matrix

โ€ข Proposition: If preferences satisfy LNS and strict convexity, and they are represented with a continuous utility function, then the Walrasian demand ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘คgenerates a Slutsky matrix, ๐‘† ๐‘, ๐‘ค , which is symmetric.

โ€ข The above assumptions are really common. โ€“ Hence, the Slutsky matrix will then be symmetric.

โ€ข However, the above assumptions are not satisfied in the case of preferences over perfect substitutes (i.e., preferences are convex, but not strictly convex).

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 62

Implications of WARP: Slutsky Matrix

โ€ข Non-positive substitution effect, ๐‘ ๐‘™๐‘™ โ‰ค 0:

๐‘ ๐‘™๐‘™ ๐‘, ๐‘คsubstitution effect (โˆ’)

=๐œ•๐‘ฅ๐‘™(๐‘, ๐‘ค)

๐œ•๐‘๐‘™

Total effect:โˆ’ usual good

+ Giffen good

+๐œ•๐‘ฅ๐‘™ ๐‘, ๐‘ค

๐œ•๐‘ค๐‘ฅ๐‘™(๐‘, ๐‘ค)

Income effect:+ normal good

โˆ’ inferior good

โ€ข Substitution Effect = Total Effect + Income Effect

โ‡’ Total Effect = Substitution Effect - Income Effect

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 63

Implications of WARP: Slutsky Equation

๐‘ ๐‘™๐‘™ ๐‘, ๐‘คsubstitution effect (โˆ’)

=๐œ•๐‘ฅ๐‘™(๐‘, ๐‘ค)

๐œ•๐‘๐‘™

Total effect

+๐œ•๐‘ฅ๐‘™ ๐‘, ๐‘ค

๐œ•๐‘ค๐‘ฅ๐‘™(๐‘, ๐‘ค)

Income effect

โ€ข Total Effect: measures how the quantity demanded is affected by a change in the price of good ๐‘™, when we leave the wealth uncompensated.

โ€ข Income Effect: measures the change in the quantity demanded as a result of the wealth adjustment.

โ€ข Substitution Effect: measures how the quantity demanded is affected by a change in the price of good ๐‘™, after the wealth adjustment.โ€“ That is, the substitution effect only captures the change in demand due to variation

in the price ratio, but abstracts from the larger (smaller) purchasing power that the consumer experiences after a decrease (increase, respectively) in prices.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 64

โ€ข Reduction in the price of ๐‘ฅ1. โ€“ It enlarges consumerโ€™s set of feasible

bundles. โ€“ He can reach an indifference curve

further away from the origin.

โ€ข The Walrasian demand curve indicates that a decrease in the price of ๐‘ฅ1 leads to an increase in the quantity demanded.โ€“ This induces a negatively sloped

Walrasian demand curve (so the good is โ€œnormalโ€).

โ€ข The increase in the quantity demanded of ๐‘ฅ1 as a result of a decrease in its price represents the total effect (TE).

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 65

Implications of WARP: Slutsky EquationX2

X1

I2

I1

p1

X1

p1

A

B

a

b

โ€ข Reduction in the price of ๐‘ฅ1.โ€“ Disentangle the total effect into the

substitution and income effectsโ€“ Slutsky wealth compensation?

โ€ข Reduce the consumerโ€™s wealth so that he can afford the same consumption bundle as the one before the price change (i.e., A).โ€“ Shift the budget line after the price change

inwards until it โ€œcrossesโ€ through the initial bundle A.

โ€“ โ€œConstant purchasing powerโ€ demand curve (CPP curve) results from applying the Slutsky wealth compensation.

โ€“ The quantity demanded for ๐‘ฅ1 increases from ๐‘ฅ1

0 to ๐‘ฅ13.

โ€ข When we do not hold the consumerโ€™s purchasing power constant, we observe relatively large increase in the quantity demanded for ๐‘ฅ1 (i.e., from ๐‘ฅ1

0 to ๐‘ฅ12 ).

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 66

Implications of WARP: Slutsky Equationx2

x1

I2

I1

p1

x1

p1

I3

CPP demand

A

B

C

a

bc

โ€ข Reduction in the price of ๐‘ฅ1.โ€“ Hicksian wealth compensation (i.e.,

โ€œconstant utilityโ€ demand curve)?

โ€ข The consumerโ€™s wealth level is adjusted so that he can still reach his initial utility level (i.e., the same indifference curve ๐ผ1as before the price change).โ€“ A more significant wealth reduction than

when we apply the Slutsky wealth compensation.

โ€“ The Hicksian demand curve reflects that, for a given decrease in p1, the consumer slightly increases his consumption of good one.

โ€ข In summary, a given decrease in ๐‘1produces: โ€“ A small increase in the Hicksian demand for

the good, i.e., from ๐‘ฅ10 to ๐‘ฅ1

1. โ€“ A larger increase in the CPP demand for the

good, i.e., from ๐‘ฅ10 to ๐‘ฅ1

3. โ€“ A substantial increase in the Walrasian

demand for the product, i.e., from ๐‘ฅ10 to ๐‘ฅ1

2.Advanced Microeconomic Theory 67

Implications of WARP: Slutsky Equationx2

x1

I2

I1

p1

x1

p1

I3

CPP demand

Hicksian demand

โ€ข A decrease in price of ๐‘ฅ1 leads the consumer to increase his consumption of this good, โˆ†๐‘ฅ1, but:

โ€“ The โˆ†๐‘ฅ1 which is solely due to the price effect (either measured by the Hicksian demand curve or the CPP demand curve) is smaller than the โˆ†๐‘ฅ1 measured by the Walrasian demand, ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค , which also captures wealth effects.

โ€“ The wealth compensation (a reduction in the consumerโ€™s wealth in this case) that maintains the original utility level (as required by the Hicksian demand) is larger than the wealth compensation that maintains his purchasing power unaltered (as required by the Slutsky wealth compensation, in the CPP curve).

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 68

Implications of WARP: Slutsky Equation

Substitution and Income Effects: Normal Goods

โ€ข Decrease in the price of the good in the horizontal axis (i.e., food).

โ€ข The substitution effect (SE) moves in the opposite direction as the price change.

โ€“ A reduction in the price of food implies a positive substitution effect.

โ€ข The income effect (IE) is positive (thus it reinforces the SE).

โ€“ The good is normal.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 69

Clothing

FoodSE IE

TE

A

B

C

I2

I1

BL2

BL1

BLd

Substitution and Income Effects: Inferior Goods

โ€ข Decrease in the price of the good in the horizontal axis (i.e., food).

โ€ข The SE still moves in the opposite direction as the price change.

โ€ข The income effect (IE) is now negative (which partially offsets the increase in the quantity demanded associated with the SE). โ€“ The good is inferior.

โ€ข Note: the SE is larger than the IE.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 70

I2

I1

BL1 BLd

Substitution and Income Effects: Giffen Goods

โ€ข Decrease in the price of the good in the horizontal axis (i.e., food).

โ€ข The SE still moves in the opposite direction as the price change.

โ€ข The income effect (IE) is still negative but now completely offsets the increase in the quantity demanded associated with the SE. โ€“ The good is Giffen good.

โ€ข Note: the SE is less than the IE.

71

I2

I1BL1

BL2

Substitution and Income Effects

SE IE TE

Normal Good + + +Inferior Good + - +Giffen Good + - -

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 72

โ€ข NG: Demand curve is negatively sloped (as usual)

โ€ข GG: Demand curve is positively sloped

Substitution and Income Effects

โ€ข Summary:1) SE is negative (since โ†“ ๐‘1 โ‡’ โ†‘ ๐‘ฅ1)

SE < 0 does not imply โ†“ ๐‘ฅ1

2) If good is inferior, IE < 0. Then,

TE = เธ“SEโˆ’ เธ•

โˆ’ เธ“IEโˆ’

+

โ‡’ if IE><

SE , then TE(โˆ’)TE(+)

For a price decrease, this impliesTE(โˆ’)TE(+)

โ‡’โ†“ ๐‘ฅ1

โ†‘ ๐‘ฅ1

Giffen goodNonโˆ’Giffen good

3) Hence,a) A good can be inferior, but not necessarily be Giffenb) But all Giffen goods must be inferior.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 73

Expenditure Minimization Problem

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 74

Expenditure Minimization Problem

โ€ข Expenditure minimization problem (EMP):min๐‘ฅโ‰ฅ0

๐‘ โˆ™ ๐‘ฅ

s.t. ๐‘ข(๐‘ฅ) โ‰ฅ ๐‘ข

โ€ข Alternative to utility maximization problem

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 75

Expenditure Minimization Problem

โ€ข Consumer seeks a utility level associated with a particular indifference curve, while spending as little as possible.

โ€ข Bundles strictly above ๐‘ฅโˆ— cannot be a solution to the EMP:โ€“ They reach the utility level ๐‘ขโ€“ But, they do not minimize total

expenditure

โ€ข Bundles on the budget line strictly below ๐‘ฅโˆ— cannot be the solution to the EMP problem:โ€“ They are cheaper than ๐‘ฅโˆ—

โ€“ But, they do not reach the utility level ๐‘ข

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 76

X2

X1

*x

*UCS( )x

u

Expenditure Minimization Problem

โ€ข Lagrangian๐ฟ = ๐‘ โˆ™ ๐‘ฅ + ๐œ‡ ๐‘ข โˆ’ ๐‘ข(๐‘ฅ)

โ€ข FOCs (necessary conditions)๐œ•๐ฟ

๐œ•๐‘ฅ๐‘˜= ๐‘๐‘˜ โˆ’ ๐œ‡

๐œ•๐‘ข(๐‘ฅโˆ—)

๐œ•๐‘ฅ๐‘˜โ‰ค 0

๐œ•๐ฟ

๐œ•๐œ‡= ๐‘ข โˆ’ ๐‘ข ๐‘ฅโˆ— = 0

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 77

[ = 0 for interior solutions ]

Expenditure Minimization Problem

โ€ข For interior solutions,

๐‘๐‘˜ = ๐œ‡๐œ•๐‘ข(๐‘ฅโˆ—)

๐œ•๐‘ฅ๐‘˜or

1

๐œ‡=

๐œ•๐‘ข(๐‘ฅโˆ—)

๐œ•๐‘ฅ๐‘˜

๐‘๐‘˜

for any good ๐‘˜. This implies, ๐œ•๐‘ข(๐‘ฅโˆ—)

๐œ•๐‘ฅ๐‘˜

๐‘๐‘˜=

๐œ•๐‘ข(๐‘ฅโˆ—)

๐œ•๐‘ฅ๐‘™

๐‘๐‘™or

๐‘๐‘˜

๐‘๐‘™=

๐œ•๐‘ข(๐‘ฅโˆ—)

๐œ•๐‘ฅ๐‘˜๐œ•๐‘ข(๐‘ฅโˆ—)

๐œ•๐‘ฅ๐‘™

โ€ข The consumer allocates his consumption across goods until the point in which the marginal utility per dollar spent on each good is equal across all goods (i.e., same โ€œbang for the buckโ€).

โ€ข That is, the slope of indifference curve is equal to the slope of the budget line.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 78

EMP: Hicksian Demand

โ€ข The bundle ๐‘ฅโˆ— โˆˆ argmin ๐‘ โˆ™ ๐‘ฅ (the argument that solves the EMP) is the Hicksian demand, which depends on ๐‘ and ๐‘ข,

๐‘ฅโˆ— โˆˆ โ„Ž(๐‘, ๐‘ข)

โ€ข Recall that if such bundle ๐‘ฅโˆ— is unique, we denote it as ๐‘ฅโˆ— = โ„Ž(๐‘, ๐‘ข).

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 79

Properties of Hicksian Demand

โ€ข Suppose that ๐‘ข(โˆ™) is a continuous function, satisfying LNS defined on ๐‘‹ = โ„+

๐ฟ . Then for ๐‘ โ‰ซ0, โ„Ž(๐‘, ๐‘ข) satisfies:1) Homog(0) in ๐‘, i.e., โ„Ž ๐‘, ๐‘ข = โ„Ž(๐›ผ๐‘, ๐‘ข) for any ๐‘, ๐‘ข,

and ๐›ผ > 0. If ๐‘ฅโˆ— โˆˆ โ„Ž(๐‘, ๐‘ข) is a solution to the problem

min๐‘ฅโ‰ฅ0

๐‘ โˆ™ ๐‘ฅ

then it is also a solution to the problemmin๐‘ฅโ‰ฅ0

๐›ผ๐‘ โˆ™ ๐‘ฅ

Intuition: a common change in all prices does not alter the slope of the consumerโ€™s budget line.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 80

Properties of Hicksian Demand

โ€ข ๐‘ฅโˆ— is a solution to the EMP when the price vector is ๐‘ = (๐‘1, ๐‘2).

โ€ข Increase all prices by factor ๐›ผ

๐‘โ€ฒ = (๐‘1โ€ฒ , ๐‘2

โ€ฒ ) = (๐›ผ๐‘1, ๐›ผ๐‘2)

โ€ข Downward (parallel) shift in the budget line, i.e., the slope of the budget line is unchanged.

โ€ข But I have to reach utility level ๐‘ข to satisfy the constraint of the EMP?

โ€ข Spend more to buy bundle ๐‘ฅโˆ—(๐‘ฅ1

โˆ—, ๐‘ฅ2โˆ—), i.e.,

๐‘1โ€ฒ ๐‘ฅ1

โˆ— + ๐‘2โ€ฒ ๐‘ฅ2

โˆ— > ๐‘1๐‘ฅ1โˆ— + ๐‘2๐‘ฅ2

โˆ—

โ€ข Hence, โ„Ž ๐‘, ๐‘ข = โ„Ž(๐›ผ๐‘, ๐‘ข)

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 81

x2

x1

Properties of Hicksian Demand

2) No excess utility:

for any optimal consumption bundle ๐‘ฅ โˆˆ โ„Ž ๐‘, ๐‘ข , utility level satisfies ๐‘ข ๐‘ฅ = ๐‘ข.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 82

x1

x2

wp2

wp1

x โ€™

x โˆˆ h (p,u)

uu 1

Properties of Hicksian Demand

โ€ข Intuition: Suppose there exists a bundle ๐‘ฅ โˆˆ โ„Ž ๐‘, ๐‘ข for which the consumer obtains a utility level ๐‘ข ๐‘ฅ = ๐‘ข1 > ๐‘ข, which is higher than the utility level ๐‘ข he must reach when solving EMP.

โ€ข But we can then find another bundle ๐‘ฅโ€ฒ = ๐‘ฅ๐›ผ, very close to ๐‘ฅ (๐›ผ โ†’ 1), for which ๐‘ข(๐‘ฅโ€ฒ) > ๐‘ข.

โ€ข Bundle ๐‘ฅโ€ฒ:โ€“ is cheaper than ๐‘ฅโ€“ exceeds the minimal utility level ๐‘ข that the consumer must

reach in his EMP

โ€ข For a given utility level ๐‘ข that you have to reach in the EMP, bundle โ„Ž ๐‘, ๐‘ข does not exceed ๐‘ข, since otherwise you could find a cheaper bundle that exactly reaches ๐‘ข.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 83

Properties of Hicksian Demand

3) Convexity:

If the preference relation is convex, then โ„Ž ๐‘, ๐‘ข is a convex set.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 84

Properties of Hicksian Demand

4) Uniqueness:

If the preference relation is strictly convex, then โ„Ž ๐‘, ๐‘ขcontains a single element.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 85

Properties of Hicksian Demand

โ€ข Compensated Law of Demand: for any change in prices ๐‘ and ๐‘โ€ฒ,

(๐‘โ€ฒโˆ’๐‘) โˆ™ โ„Ž ๐‘โ€ฒ, ๐‘ข โˆ’ โ„Ž ๐‘, ๐‘ข โ‰ค 0

โ€“ Implication: for every good ๐‘˜,(๐‘๐‘˜

โ€ฒ โˆ’ ๐‘๐‘˜) โˆ™ โ„Ž๐‘˜ ๐‘โ€ฒ, ๐‘ข โˆ’ โ„Ž๐‘˜ ๐‘, ๐‘ข โ‰ค 0

โ€“ This is definitely true for compensated demand.

โ€“ But, not necessarily for Walrasian demand (which is uncompensated):

โ€ข Recall the figures on Giffen goods, where a decrease in ๐‘๐‘˜ in fact decreases ๐‘ฅ๐‘˜ ๐‘, ๐‘ข when wealth was uncompensated.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 86

The Expenditure Function

โ€ข Plugging the result from the EMP, โ„Ž ๐‘, ๐‘ข , into the objective function, ๐‘ โˆ™ ๐‘ฅ, we obtain the value function of this optimization problem,

๐‘ โˆ™ โ„Ž ๐‘, ๐‘ข = ๐‘’(๐‘, ๐‘ข)

where ๐‘’(๐‘, ๐‘ข) represents the minimal expenditure that the consumer needs to incur in order to reach utility level ๐‘ข when prices are ๐‘.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 87

Properties of Expenditure Function

โ€ข Suppose that ๐‘ข(โˆ™) is a continuous function, satisfying LNS defined on ๐‘‹ = โ„+

๐ฟ . Then for ๐‘ โ‰ซ0, ๐‘’(๐‘, ๐‘ข) satisfies:1) Homog(1) in ๐‘, i.e.,

๐‘’ ๐›ผ๐‘, ๐‘ข = ๐›ผ ๐‘ โˆ™ ๐‘ฅโˆ—

๐‘’(๐‘,๐‘ข)

= ๐›ผ โˆ™ ๐‘’(๐‘, ๐‘ข)

for any ๐‘, ๐‘ข, and ๐›ผ > 0.

We know that the optimal bundle is not changed when all prices change, since the optimal consumption bundle in โ„Ž(๐‘, ๐‘ข) satisfies homogeneity of degree zero.

Such change just makes it more or less expensive to buy the same bundle.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 88

Properties of Expenditure Function

2) Strictly increasing in ๐’–: For a given prices, reaching a higher utility requires higher expenditure:

๐‘1๐‘ฅ1โ€ฒ + ๐‘2๐‘ฅ2

โ€ฒ > ๐‘1๐‘ฅ1 + ๐‘2๐‘ฅ2

where (๐‘ฅ1, ๐‘ฅ2) = โ„Ž(๐‘, ๐‘ข)and (๐‘ฅ1

โ€ฒ , ๐‘ฅ2โ€ฒ ) = โ„Ž(๐‘, ๐‘ขโ€ฒ).

Then,๐‘’ ๐‘, ๐‘ขโ€ฒ > ๐‘’ ๐‘, ๐‘ข

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 89

x2

x1

x2

x1

Properties of Expenditure Function

3) Non-decreasing in ๐’‘๐’Œ for any good ๐’Œ:Higher prices mean higher expenditure to reach a given utility level. โ€ข Let ๐‘โ€ฒ = (๐‘1, ๐‘2, โ€ฆ , ๐‘๐‘˜

โ€ฒ , โ€ฆ , ๐‘๐ฟ) and ๐‘ =(๐‘1, ๐‘2, โ€ฆ , ๐‘๐‘˜, โ€ฆ , ๐‘๐ฟ), where ๐‘๐‘˜

โ€ฒ > ๐‘๐‘˜.โ€ข Let ๐‘ฅโ€ฒ = โ„Ž ๐‘โ€ฒ, ๐‘ข and ๐‘ฅ = โ„Ž ๐‘, ๐‘ข from EMP under

prices ๐‘โ€ฒ and ๐‘, respectively.โ€ข Then, ๐‘โ€ฒ โˆ™ ๐‘ฅโ€ฒ = ๐‘’(๐‘โ€ฒ, ๐‘ข) and ๐‘ โˆ™ ๐‘ฅ = ๐‘’(๐‘, ๐‘ข).

๐‘’ ๐‘โ€ฒ, ๐‘ข = ๐‘โ€ฒ โˆ™ ๐‘ฅโ€ฒ โ‰ฅ ๐‘ โˆ™ ๐‘ฅโ€ฒ โ‰ฅ ๐‘ โˆ™ ๐‘ฅ = ๐‘’(๐‘, ๐‘ข)

โ€“ 1st inequality due to ๐‘โ€ฒ โ‰ฅ ๐‘โ€“ 2nd inequality: at prices ๐‘, bundle ๐‘ฅ minimizes EMP.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 90

Properties of Expenditure Function

4) Concave in ๐’‘:

Let ๐‘ฅโ€ฒ โˆˆ โ„Ž ๐‘โ€ฒ, ๐‘ข โ‡’ ๐‘โ€ฒ๐‘ฅโ€ฒ โ‰ค ๐‘โ€ฒ๐‘ฅโˆ€๐‘ฅ โ‰  ๐‘ฅโ€ฒ, e.g., ๐‘โ€ฒ๐‘ฅโ€ฒ โ‰ค ๐‘โ€ฒ าง๐‘ฅand ๐‘ฅโ€ฒโ€ฒ โˆˆ โ„Ž ๐‘โ€ฒโ€ฒ, ๐‘ข โ‡’ ๐‘โ€ฒโ€ฒ๐‘ฅโ€ฒโ€ฒ โ‰ค ๐‘โ€ฒโ€ฒ๐‘ฅโˆ€๐‘ฅ โ‰  ๐‘ฅโ€ฒโ€ฒ, e.g., ๐‘โ€ฒโ€ฒ๐‘ฅโ€ฒโ€ฒ โ‰ค ๐‘โ€ฒโ€ฒ าง๐‘ฅ

This implies๐›ผ๐‘โ€ฒ๐‘ฅโ€ฒ + 1 โˆ’ ๐›ผ ๐‘โ€ฒโ€ฒ๐‘ฅโ€ฒโ€ฒ

โ‰ค ๐›ผ๐‘โ€ฒ าง๐‘ฅ + 1 โˆ’ ๐›ผ ๐‘โ€ฒโ€ฒ าง๐‘ฅ

๐›ผ เธ‘๐‘โ€ฒ๐‘ฅโ€ฒ

๐‘’(๐‘โ€ฒ,๐‘ข)

+ 1 โˆ’ ๐›ผ ๐‘โ€ฒโ€ฒ๐‘ฅโ€ฒโ€ฒ

๐‘’(๐‘โ€ฒโ€ฒ,๐‘ข)

โ‰ค [๐›ผ๐‘โ€ฒ + 1 โˆ’ ๐›ผ ๐‘โ€ฒโ€ฒ

าง๐‘

] าง๐‘ฅ

๐›ผ๐‘’(๐‘โ€ฒ, ๐‘ข) + 1 โˆ’ ๐›ผ ๐‘’(๐‘โ€ฒโ€ฒ, ๐‘ข) โ‰ค ๐‘’( าง๐‘, ๐‘ข)concavity

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 91

x2

x1

x

x

Connections

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 92

Relationship between the Expenditure and Hicksian Demand

โ€ข Letโ€™s assume that ๐‘ข(โˆ™) is a continuous function, representing preferences that satisfy LNS and are strictly convex and defined on ๐‘‹ = โ„+

๐ฟ . For all ๐‘ and ๐‘ข,

๐œ•๐‘’ ๐‘,๐‘ข

๐œ•๐‘๐‘˜= โ„Ž๐‘˜ ๐‘, ๐‘ข for every good ๐‘˜

This identity is โ€œShepardโ€™s lemmaโ€: if we want to find โ„Ž๐‘˜ ๐‘, ๐‘ข and we know ๐‘’ ๐‘, ๐‘ข , we just have to differentiate ๐‘’ ๐‘, ๐‘ข with respect to prices.

โ€ข Proof: three different approaches1) the support function2) first-order conditions 3) the envelop theorem (See Appendix 2.2)

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 93

Relationship between the Expenditure and Hicksian Demand

โ€ข The relationship between the Hicksian demand and the expenditure function can be further developed by taking first order conditions again. That is,

๐œ•2๐‘’(๐‘, ๐‘ข)

๐œ•๐‘๐‘˜2 =

๐œ•โ„Ž๐‘˜(๐‘, ๐‘ข)

๐œ•๐‘๐‘˜

or๐ท๐‘

2๐‘’ ๐‘, ๐‘ข = ๐ท๐‘โ„Ž(๐‘, ๐‘ข)

โ€ข Since ๐ท๐‘โ„Ž(๐‘, ๐‘ข) provides the Slutsky matrix, ๐‘†(๐‘, ๐‘ค), then

๐‘† ๐‘, ๐‘ค = ๐ท๐‘2๐‘’ ๐‘, ๐‘ข

where the Slutsky matrix can be obtained from the observable Walrasian demand.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 94

Relationship between the Expenditure and Hicksian Demand

โ€ข There are three other important properties of ๐ท๐‘โ„Ž(๐‘, ๐‘ข), where ๐ท๐‘โ„Ž(๐‘, ๐‘ข) is ๐ฟ ร— ๐ฟ derivative matrix of the hicksian demand, โ„Ž ๐‘, ๐‘ข :1) ๐ท๐‘โ„Ž(๐‘, ๐‘ข) is negative semidefinite

Hence, ๐‘† ๐‘, ๐‘ค is negative semidefinite.

2) ๐ท๐‘โ„Ž(๐‘, ๐‘ข) is a symmetric matrix Hence, ๐‘† ๐‘, ๐‘ค is symmetric.

3) ๐ท๐‘โ„Ž ๐‘, ๐‘ข ๐‘ = 0, which implies ๐‘† ๐‘, ๐‘ค ๐‘ = 0.

Not all goods can be net substitutes ๐œ•โ„Ž๐‘™(๐‘,๐‘ข)

๐œ•๐‘๐‘˜> 0 or net

complements ๐œ•โ„Ž๐‘™(๐‘,๐‘ข)

๐œ•๐‘๐‘˜< 0 . Otherwise, the multiplication

of this vector of derivatives times the (positive) price vector ๐‘ โ‰ซ 0 would yield a non-zero result.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 95

Relationship between Hicksian and Walrasian Demand

โ€ข When income effects are positive (normal goods), then the Walrasian demand ๐‘ฅ(๐‘, ๐‘ค) is above the Hicksian demand โ„Ž(๐‘, ๐‘ข) .โ€“ The Hicksian demand

is steeper than the Walrasian demand.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 96

x1

x2

wp2

wp1

x1

p1

wp1

p1

p1

x*1 x1

1 x21

h (p,ลซ)

x (p,w)

p1

I1

I3

I2x1

x 3x 2

x*

SE IE

Relationship between Hicksian and Walrasian Demand

โ€ข When income effects are negative (inferior goods), then the Walrasian demand ๐‘ฅ(๐‘, ๐‘ค) is below the Hicksian demand โ„Ž(๐‘, ๐‘ข) .โ€“ The Hicksian demand

is flatter than the Walrasian demand.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 97

x1

x2

wp2

wp1

x1

p1

wp1

p1

p1

x*1 x1

1x21

h (p,ลซ)

x (p,w)

p1

I1

I2

x1

x 2x*

SE

IE

a

bc

Relationship between Hicksian and Walrasian Demand

โ€ข We can formally relate the Hicksian and Walrasian demand as follows:โ€“ Consider ๐‘ข(โˆ™) is a continuous function, representing

preferences that satisfy LNS and are strictly convex and defined on ๐‘‹ = โ„+

๐ฟ .โ€“ Consider a consumer facing ( าง๐‘, เดฅ๐‘ค) and attaining utility

level เดค๐‘ข.โ€“ Note that เดฅ๐‘ค = ๐‘’( าง๐‘, เดค๐‘ข). In addition, we know that for any

(๐‘, ๐‘ข), โ„Ž๐‘™ ๐‘, ๐‘ข = ๐‘ฅ๐‘™(๐‘, ๐‘’ ๐‘, ๐‘ข๐‘ค

). Differentiating this

expression with respect to ๐‘๐‘˜, and evaluating it at ( าง๐‘, เดค๐‘ข), we get:

๐œ•โ„Ž๐‘™( าง๐‘, เดค๐‘ข)

๐œ•๐‘๐‘˜=

๐œ•๐‘ฅ๐‘™( าง๐‘, ๐‘’( าง๐‘, เดค๐‘ข))

๐œ•๐‘๐‘˜+

๐œ•๐‘ฅ๐‘™( าง๐‘, ๐‘’( าง๐‘, เดค๐‘ข))

๐œ•๐‘ค

๐œ•๐‘’( าง๐‘, เดค๐‘ข)

๐œ•๐‘๐‘˜Advanced Microeconomic Theory 98

Relationship between Hicksian and Walrasian Demand

โ€ข Using the fact that ๐œ•๐‘’( าง๐‘,เดฅ๐‘ข)

๐œ•๐‘๐‘˜= โ„Ž๐‘˜( าง๐‘, เดค๐‘ข),

๐œ•โ„Ž๐‘™( าง๐‘,เดฅ๐‘ข)

๐œ•๐‘๐‘˜=

๐œ•๐‘ฅ๐‘™( าง๐‘,๐‘’( าง๐‘,เดฅ๐‘ข))

๐œ•๐‘๐‘˜+

๐œ•๐‘ฅ๐‘™( าง๐‘,๐‘’( าง๐‘,เดฅ๐‘ข))

๐œ•๐‘คโ„Ž๐‘˜( าง๐‘, เดค๐‘ข)

โ€ข Finally, since เดฅ๐‘ค = ๐‘’( าง๐‘, เดค๐‘ข) and โ„Ž๐‘˜ าง๐‘, เดค๐‘ข =

๐‘ฅ๐‘˜ าง๐‘, ๐‘’ าง๐‘, เดค๐‘ข = ๐‘ฅ๐‘˜ าง๐‘, เดฅ๐‘ค , then

๐œ•โ„Ž๐‘™( าง๐‘,เดฅ๐‘ข)

๐œ•๐‘๐‘˜=

๐œ•๐‘ฅ๐‘™( าง๐‘, เดฅ๐‘ค)

๐œ•๐‘๐‘˜+

๐œ•๐‘ฅ๐‘™( าง๐‘, เดฅ๐‘ค)

๐œ•๐‘ค๐‘ฅ๐‘˜( าง๐‘, เดฅ๐‘ค)

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 99

Relationship between Hicksian and Walrasian Demand

โ€ข But this coincides with ๐‘ ๐‘™๐‘˜ ๐‘, ๐‘ค that we discussed in the Slutsky equation.

โ€“ Hence, we have ๐ท๐‘โ„Ž ๐‘, ๐‘ข

๐ฟร—๐ฟ

= ๐‘† ๐‘, ๐‘ค .

โ€“ Or, more compactly, ๐‘†๐ธ = ๐‘‡๐ธ + ๐ผ๐ธ.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 100

Relationship between Walrasian Demand and Indirect Utility Function

โ€ข Letโ€™s assume that ๐‘ข(โˆ™) is a continuous function, representing preferences that satisfy LNS and are strictly convex and defined on ๐‘‹ = โ„+

๐ฟ . Support also that ๐‘ฃ(๐‘, ๐‘ค) is differentiable at any (๐‘, ๐‘ค) โ‰ซ 0. Then,

โˆ’

๐œ•๐‘ฃ ๐‘,๐‘ค

๐œ•๐‘๐‘˜๐œ•๐‘ฃ ๐‘,๐‘ค

๐œ•๐‘ค

= ๐‘ฅ๐‘˜(๐‘, ๐‘ค) for every good ๐‘˜

โ€ข This is Royโ€™s identity.

โ€ข Powerful result, since in many cases it is easier to compute the derivatives of ๐‘ฃ ๐‘, ๐‘ค than solving the UMP with the system of FOCs.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 101

Summary of Relationships

โ€ข The Walrasian demand, ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค , is the solution of the UMP.โ€“ Its value function is the indirect utility function, ๐‘ฃ ๐‘, ๐‘ค .

โ€ข The Hicksian demand, โ„Ž(๐‘, ๐‘ข), is the solution of the EMP. โ€“ Its value function is the expenditure function, ๐‘’(๐‘, ๐‘ข).

โ€ข Relationship between the value functions of the UMP and the EMP:โ€“ ๐‘’ ๐‘, ๐‘ฃ ๐‘, ๐‘ค = ๐‘ค, i.e., the minimal expenditure needed in

order to reach a utility level equal to the maximal utility that the individual reaches at his UMP, ๐‘ข = ๐‘ฃ ๐‘, ๐‘ค , must be ๐‘ค.

โ€“ ๐‘ฃ ๐‘, ๐‘’(๐‘, ๐‘ข) = ๐‘ข, i.e., the indirect utility that can be reached when the consumer is endowed with a wealth level w equal to the minimal expenditure he optimally uses in the EMP, i.e., ๐‘ค =๐‘’(๐‘, ๐‘ข), is exactly ๐‘ข.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 102

Summary of Relationships

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 103

Summary of Relationships

โ€ข Relationship between the argmax of the UMP (the Walrasian demand) and the argmin of the EMP (the Hicksian demand):โ€“ ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘’(๐‘, ๐‘ข) = โ„Ž ๐‘, ๐‘ข , i.e., the (uncompensated)

Walrasian demand of a consumer endowed with an adjusted wealth level ๐‘ค (equal to the expenditure he optimally uses in the EMP), ๐‘ค = ๐‘’ ๐‘, ๐‘ข , coincides with his Hicksian demand, โ„Ž ๐‘, ๐‘ข .

โ€“ โ„Ž ๐‘, ๐‘ฃ(๐‘, ๐‘ค) = ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค , i.e., the (compensated) Hicksian demand of a consumer reaching the maximum utility of the UMP, ๐‘ข = ๐‘ฃ (๐‘, ๐‘ค), coincides with his Walrasian demand, ๐‘ฅ ๐‘, ๐‘ค .

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 104

Summary of Relationships

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 105

Summary of Relationships

โ€ข Finally, we can also use:โ€“ The Slutsky equation:

๐œ•โ„Ž๐‘™(๐‘, ๐‘ข)

๐œ•๐‘๐‘˜=

๐œ•๐‘ฅ๐‘™(๐‘, ๐‘ค)

๐œ•๐‘๐‘˜+

๐œ•๐‘ฅ๐‘™(๐‘, ๐‘ค)

๐œ•๐‘ค๐‘ฅ๐‘˜(๐‘, ๐‘ค)

to relate the derivatives of the Hicksian and the Walrasian demand.โ€“ Shepardโ€™s lemma:

๐œ•๐‘’ ๐‘, ๐‘ข

๐œ•๐‘๐‘˜= โ„Ž๐‘˜ ๐‘, ๐‘ข

to obtain the Hicksian demand from the expenditure function.โ€“ Royโ€™s identity:

โˆ’

๐œ•๐‘ฃ ๐‘, ๐‘ค๐œ•๐‘๐‘˜

๐œ•๐‘ฃ ๐‘, ๐‘ค๐œ•๐‘ค

= ๐‘ฅ๐‘˜(๐‘, ๐‘ค)

to obtain the Walrasian demand from the indirect utility function.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 106

Summary of Relationships

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 107

x(p,w)

v(p,w) e(p,u)

h(p,u)

The UMP The EMP

e(p,v(p,w))=w

v(p,e(p,w))=u

(1) (1)

(2)

3(a)

3(b)

4(a) Slutsky equation

(Using derivatives)

Summary of Relationships

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 108

x(p,w)

v(p,w) e(p,u)

h(p,u)

The UMP The EMP

e(p,v(p,w))=w

v(p,e(p,w))=u

(1) (1)

(2)

3(a)

3(b)

4(a) Slutsk equation

(For derivatives)

4(b) Roy s

Identity 4(c)

Shepard s lemma