chapter 15: estimation of dynamic causal effects · is not the usual one from cross-sectional...

43
Chapter 15: Estimation of Dynamic Causal Effects Copyright © 2011 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 15-1 1-1

Upload: dinhdieu

Post on 26-Jun-2018

222 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Chapter 15: Estimation of Dynamic Causal Effects · is not the usual one from cross-sectional (i.i.d.) data, because uis serially correlated, not i.i.d

Chapter 15: Estimation of Dynamic Causal Effects

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 15-11-1

Page 2: Chapter 15: Estimation of Dynamic Causal Effects · is not the usual one from cross-sectional (i.i.d.) data, because uis serially correlated, not i.i.d

Outline

1. Dynamic Causal Effects and the Orange Juice Data

2. Estimation of Dynamic Causal Effects with Exogenous Regressors: The Distributed Lag Model

3. HAC Standard Errors

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 15-2

3. HAC Standard Errors

4. Application to Orange Juice Prices

5. More on Exogeneity

Page 3: Chapter 15: Estimation of Dynamic Causal Effects · is not the usual one from cross-sectional (i.i.d.) data, because uis serially correlated, not i.i.d

Dynamic Causal Effects & Orange Juice Data

A dynamic causal effect is the effect on Y of a change in X over time.

For example:

• The effect of an increase in cigarette taxes on cigarette

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 15-3

• The effect of an increase in cigarette taxes on cigarette consumption this year, next year, in 5 years;

• The effect of a change in the Fed Funds rate on inflation, this month, in 6 months, and 1 year;

• The effect of a freeze in Florida on the price of orange juice concentrate in 1 month, 2 months, 3 months…

Page 4: Chapter 15: Estimation of Dynamic Causal Effects · is not the usual one from cross-sectional (i.i.d.) data, because uis serially correlated, not i.i.d

The Orange Juice Data

• Monthly, Jan. 1950 – Dec. 2000 (T = 612)

• Price = price of frozen OJ (a sub-component of the producer price index; US Bureau of Labor Statistics)

• %ChgP = percentage change in price at an annual rate, so %ChgP = 1200∆ln(Price )

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 15-4

%ChgPt = 1200∆ln(Pricet)

• FDD = number of freezing degree-days during the month, recorded in Orlando FL

– Example: If November has 2 days with lows < 32o, one at 30o and at 25o, then FDDNov = 2 + 7 = 9

Page 5: Chapter 15: Estimation of Dynamic Causal Effects · is not the usual one from cross-sectional (i.i.d.) data, because uis serially correlated, not i.i.d

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 15-5

Page 6: Chapter 15: Estimation of Dynamic Causal Effects · is not the usual one from cross-sectional (i.i.d.) data, because uis serially correlated, not i.i.d

Initial OJ regression

= -.40 + .47FDDt(.22) (.13)

• Statistically significant positive relation

• More freezing degree days � price increase

�%t

ChgP

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 15-6

• Standard errors are heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation-consistent (HAC) SE’s (more on this later)

• But what is the effect of FDD over time?

Page 7: Chapter 15: Estimation of Dynamic Causal Effects · is not the usual one from cross-sectional (i.i.d.) data, because uis serially correlated, not i.i.d

Dynamic Causal Effects

Example: What is the effect of fertilizer on tomato yield?

An ideal randomized controlled experiment

• Fertilize some plots, not others (random assignment)

• Measure yield over time – over repeated harvests – to estimate causal effect of fertilizer on:

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 15-7

estimate causal effect of fertilizer on:

– Yield in year 1 of experiment

– Yield in year 2, etc.

• The result (in a large experiment) is the causal effect of fertilizer on yield k years later.

Page 8: Chapter 15: Estimation of Dynamic Causal Effects · is not the usual one from cross-sectional (i.i.d.) data, because uis serially correlated, not i.i.d

Dynamic causal effects, ctd.

In applications, we cannot conduct such ideal randomized controlled experiments. Here:

• We only have one US OJ market (unlike multiple plots)

• We cannot randomly assign FDD to different replicates of the US OJ market (what does this even mean?)

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 15-8

US OJ market (what does this even mean?)

• We cannot measure the average (across “subjects”) outcome at different times – there is only one “subject”!

So we cannot estimate the causal effect at different times using the differences estimator

Page 9: Chapter 15: Estimation of Dynamic Causal Effects · is not the usual one from cross-sectional (i.i.d.) data, because uis serially correlated, not i.i.d

Dynamic causal effects, ctd.

An alternative thought experiment:

• Randomly give the same subject different treatments (FDDt) at different times

• Measure the outcome variable (%ChgPt)

• The “population” of subjects consists of the same subject (OJ

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 15-9

• The “population” of subjects consists of the same subject (OJ market) but at different dates

• If the “subjects” (the subject at different times) are drawn from the same distribution – that is, if Yt, Xt are stationary– then the dynamic causal effect can be deduced by OLS regression of Yt on lagged values of Xt.

• This estimator (regression of Yt on Xt and lags of Xt) is called the distributed lag estimator.

Page 10: Chapter 15: Estimation of Dynamic Causal Effects · is not the usual one from cross-sectional (i.i.d.) data, because uis serially correlated, not i.i.d

Dynamic Causal Effects and the Distributed Lag Model

The distributed lag model is:

Yt = β0 + β1Xt + … + βrXt–r + ut

• β1 = impact effect of change in X = effect of change in Xt

on Yt, holding constant past Xt

• β = 1-period dynamic multiplier = effect of change in X

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 15-10

• β2 = 1-period dynamic multiplier = effect of change in Xt–1

on Yt, holding constant Xt, Xt–2, Xt–3,…

• β3 = 2-period dynamic multiplier (etc.) = effect of change in Xt–2 on Yt, holding constant Xt, Xt–1, Xt–3,…

• Cumulative dynamic multipliers– The h-period cumulative dynamic multiplier is β1 + … + βh+1 = impact

effect + … + (h+1)-period effect

– The long-run cumulative dynamic multiplier is β1 + … + βr+1 (note, r = last lag in model)

Page 11: Chapter 15: Estimation of Dynamic Causal Effects · is not the usual one from cross-sectional (i.i.d.) data, because uis serially correlated, not i.i.d

Exogeneity in Time Series Regression

Exogeneity (past and present)

X is exogenous if E(ut|Xt, Xt–1, Xt–2,…) = 0.

So error term is uncorrelated with regressor in present and past

Strict Exogeneity (past, present, and future)

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 15-11

X is strictly exogenous if E(ut|…, Xt+1, Xt, Xt–1, …) = 0

So error term is uncorrelated with regressor at all times

• Strict exogeneity implies exogeneity

• For now we suppose that X is exogenous – “strict” later

• If X is exogenous, then OLS is appropriate to estimate the dynamic causal effect on Y of a change in X….

Page 12: Chapter 15: Estimation of Dynamic Causal Effects · is not the usual one from cross-sectional (i.i.d.) data, because uis serially correlated, not i.i.d

Estimation of Dynamic Causal Effects with Exogenous Regressors

Distributed Lag Model:

Yt = β0 + β1Xt + … + βr+1Xt–r + ut

The Distributed Lag Model Assumptions

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 15-12

1. E(ut|Xt, Xt–1, Xt–2,…) = 0 (X is exogenous)

2. (a) Y and X have stationary distributions;(b) (Yt, Xt) and (Yt–j, Xt–j) become independent as j�∞

3. Y and X have eight nonzero finite moments

4. There is no perfect multicollinearity.

Page 13: Chapter 15: Estimation of Dynamic Causal Effects · is not the usual one from cross-sectional (i.i.d.) data, because uis serially correlated, not i.i.d

The distributed lag model, ctd.

• Assumptions 1 and 4 are familiar

• Assumption 3 is familiar, except for 8 (not four) finite moments – this has to do with HAC estimators

• Assumption 2 is different – before it was (Xi, Yi) are i.i.d. –with time series data, temporal dependence is a reality

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 15-13

2. (a) Y and X have stationary distributions;

• If so, the coefficients do not change within the sample (internal validity);

• and the results can be extrapolated outside the sample (external validity).

• This is the time series counterpart of the “identically distributed” part of i.i.d.

Page 14: Chapter 15: Estimation of Dynamic Causal Effects · is not the usual one from cross-sectional (i.i.d.) data, because uis serially correlated, not i.i.d

The distributed lag model, ctd.

2. (b) (Yt,Xt) and (Yt–j, Xt–j) become independent as j�∞

– Intuitively, this says that we have separate experiments for time periods that are widely separated.

– For cross-sectional data, we assumed that Y and X were i.i.d., justified by simple random sampling … enabling CLT

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 15-14

i.i.d., justified by simple random sampling … enabling CLT

– A version of the CLT holds for time series variables that become independent as their temporal separation increases –2(b) is the analogue of the “independently distributed” part of i.i.d.

Page 15: Chapter 15: Estimation of Dynamic Causal Effects · is not the usual one from cross-sectional (i.i.d.) data, because uis serially correlated, not i.i.d

Under the Distributed Lag Model Assumptions:

• OLS yields consistent estimators of β1, β2,…, βr• In large samples, the sampling distribution of is normal

• Yet the formula for the variance of this sampling distribution is not the usual one from cross-sectional (i.i.d.) data, because u is serially correlated, not i.i.d.

iβ̂

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 15-15

because ut is serially correlated, not i.i.d.

• So the usual OLS standard errors are wrong (as in STATA printout under “r” option)

• We need SEs that are robust to autocorrelation and to heteroskedasticity…

Page 16: Chapter 15: Estimation of Dynamic Causal Effects · is not the usual one from cross-sectional (i.i.d.) data, because uis serially correlated, not i.i.d

Heteroskedasticity and Autocorrelation-Consistent (HAC) Standard Errors

The math, for a single regressor Xt: Yt = β0 + β1Xt + utThe OLS estimator: From SW, App. 4.3,

– β1 =

1

T( X

t− X )u

tt=1

T

1( X − X )

2T

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 15-16

≅ (in large samples)

where vt = (Xt – )ut.

T( X

t− X )

2

t=1

1

Tv

tt=1

T

σX

2

X

Page 17: Chapter 15: Estimation of Dynamic Causal Effects · is not the usual one from cross-sectional (i.i.d.) data, because uis serially correlated, not i.i.d

HAC standard errors, ctd.

Thus, in large samples,

var( ) = /

= /

var1

Tv

tt=1

T

(σ X

2)

2

1

T2

cov(vt,v

s)

s=1

T

∑t=1

T

∑ (σ X

2)

2

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 15-17

In i.i.d. cross sectional data, cov(vt, vs) = 0 for t ≠ s, so

var( ) = )/ =

This is our usual cross-sectional result (SW App. 4.3).

T s=1t=1

1

T2

var(vt)

t=1

T

∑ (σ X

2)

2

σv

2

T (σx

2)

2

Page 18: Chapter 15: Estimation of Dynamic Causal Effects · is not the usual one from cross-sectional (i.i.d.) data, because uis serially correlated, not i.i.d

HAC standard errors, ctd.

But in time series data, cov(vt, vs) ≠ 0 is typical.

Consider T = 2:

= ¼[var(v1) + var(v2) + 2cov(v1,v2)]

= ½ + ½ρ1 (ρ1 = corr(v1,v2))

var1

Tv

tt=1

T

σ v

2

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 15-18

= ½ ×f2, where f2 = (1+ρ1)

• In i.i.d. data, ρ1 = 0 so f2 = 1, yielding the usual formula

• In time series data, if usual formula off by factor f2

σ v

2

Page 19: Chapter 15: Estimation of Dynamic Causal Effects · is not the usual one from cross-sectional (i.i.d.) data, because uis serially correlated, not i.i.d

Expression for var( ), general T

Let be the jth-autocorrelation of

var( ) = × fT

where

1

T

σv

2

(σX

2)

2

),(: jttj vvcorr −=ρ ttt uXXv )(: −=

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 15-19

where

fT = (SW, eq. (15.13))

In short, usual formula for SE is corrected by including factor fT !

X

1+ 2T − j

T

ρ

jj=1

T −1

Page 20: Chapter 15: Estimation of Dynamic Causal Effects · is not the usual one from cross-sectional (i.i.d.) data, because uis serially correlated, not i.i.d

HAC Standard Errors

• Problem: We do not know the correction factor!

• It involves the population’s autocorrelations

• Now,

– In panel data, the factor fT is (implicitly) estimated by using “cluster” – requires n large.

– In time series data, we need a different formula – we

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 15-20

– In time series data, we need a different formula – we must estimate fT explicitly

• Need a consistent estimator of fT• Heteroskedasticity and Autocorrelation Consistent (HAC)

standard errors are those that use consistent estimators of fT

Page 21: Chapter 15: Estimation of Dynamic Causal Effects · is not the usual one from cross-sectional (i.i.d.) data, because uis serially correlated, not i.i.d

HAC standard errors, ctd.

var( ) = ×fT , where fT =

The most commonly used estimator of fT is:

= (Newey-West)

1

T

σv

2

(σX

2)

2

1+ 2T − j

T

ρ

jj=1

T −1

ˆT

f1

1

1 2m

j

j

m j

=

− + ∑ �

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 15-21

where

• This is the “Newey-West” HAC SE estimator

• m is called the truncation parameter

• What m should we choose? Rule of thumb: m = 0.75T1/3

1j m=

ttt

T

t

t

T

jt

jttj uXXvvvv ˆ)(:ˆ with ˆ/ˆˆ:~

1

2

1

−== ∑∑=+=

−ρ

Page 22: Chapter 15: Estimation of Dynamic Causal Effects · is not the usual one from cross-sectional (i.i.d.) data, because uis serially correlated, not i.i.d

Example: OJ and HAC estimators

. reg dlpoj fdd if tin(1950m1,2000m12), r; NOT HAC SEs

Linear regression Number of obs = 612

F( 1, 610) = 12.12

Prob > F = 0.0005

R-squared = 0.0937

Root MSE = 4.8261

------------------------------------------------------------------------------

| Robust

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 15-22

| Robust

dlpoj | Coef. Std. Err. t P>|t| [95% Conf. Interval]

-------------+----------------------------------------------------------------

fdd | .4662182 .1339293 3.48 0.001 .2031998 .7292367

_cons | -.4022562 .1893712 -2.12 0.034 -.7741549 -.0303575

------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Page 23: Chapter 15: Estimation of Dynamic Causal Effects · is not the usual one from cross-sectional (i.i.d.) data, because uis serially correlated, not i.i.d

Rerun regression, with Newey-West SE:

newey dlpoj fdd if tin(1950m1,2000m12), lag(7);

Number of obs = 612

maximum lag: 7 F( 1, 610) = 12.23

Prob > F = 0.0005

------------------------------------------------------------------------------

| Newey-West

dlpoj | Coef. Std. Err. t P>|t| [95% Conf. Interval]

-------------+----------------------------------------------------------------

fdd | .4662182 .1333142 3.50 0.001 .2044077 .7280288

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 15-23

fdd | .4662182 .1333142 3.50 0.001 .2044077 .7280288

_cons | -.4022562 .2159802 -1.86 0.063 -.8264112 .0218987

------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Uses autocorrelations up to m = 7 to compute the SEs

rule-of-thumb: 0.75*(612)^(1/3) = 6.4 » 7, rounded up a little.

Difference in SEs turned out small – in 4th decimal

. gen l0fdd = fdd; generate lag #0

. gen l1fdd = L1.fdd; generate lag #1

. gen l2fdd = L2.fdd; generate lag #2

. gen l3fdd = L3.fdd; .

. gen l4fdd = L4.fdd; .

. gen l5fdd = L5.fdd; .

. gen l6fdd = L6.fdd;

Page 24: Chapter 15: Estimation of Dynamic Causal Effects · is not the usual one from cross-sectional (i.i.d.) data, because uis serially correlated, not i.i.d

Example: OJ and HAC estimators in STATA, ctd.

. global lfdd6 "fdd l1fdd l2fdd l3fdd l4fdd l5fdd l6fdd”;

. newey dlpoj $lfdd6 if tin(1950m1,2000m12), lag(7);

Number of obs = 612

maximum lag : 7 F( 7, 604) = 3.56

Prob > F = 0.0009

------------------------------------------------------------------------------

| Newey-West

dlpoj | Coef. Std. Err. t P>|t| [95% Conf. Interval]

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 15-24

dlpoj | Coef. Std. Err. t P>|t| [95% Conf. Interval]

-------------+----------------------------------------------------------------

fdd | .4693121 .1359686 3.45 0.001 .2022834 .7363407

l1fdd | .1430512 .0837047 1.71 0.088 -.0213364 .3074388

l2fdd | .0564234 .0561724 1.00 0.316 -.0538936 .1667404

l3fdd | .0722595 .0468776 1.54 0.124 -.0198033 .1643223

l4fdd | .0343244 .0295141 1.16 0.245 -.0236383 .0922871

l5fdd | .0468222 .0308791 1.52 0.130 -.0138212 .1074657

l6fdd | .0481115 .0446404 1.08 0.282 -.0395577 .1357807

_cons | -.6505183 .2336986 -2.78 0.006 -1.109479 -.1915578

------------------------------------------------------------------------------

global lfdd6 defines a string which is all the additional lags

Run in this way, output includes coefficients on older lags as well

What are the estimated dynamic multipliers (dynamic effects)? Just add!

Page 25: Chapter 15: Estimation of Dynamic Causal Effects · is not the usual one from cross-sectional (i.i.d.) data, because uis serially correlated, not i.i.d

FAQ: Do I need to use HAC SEs when I estimate an AR or an ADL model?

A: NO

• The problem to which HAC SEs are the solution only arises when ut is serially correlated: if ut is serially uncorrelated, then OLS SE’s are fine

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 15-25

• In AR and ADL models, (X = past Y), the errors are serially uncorrelated if you have included enough lags of Y

If you include enough lags of Y, then the error term can’t be predicted using past Y, or equivalently by past u – so u is serially uncorrelated

Page 26: Chapter 15: Estimation of Dynamic Causal Effects · is not the usual one from cross-sectional (i.i.d.) data, because uis serially correlated, not i.i.d

Estimation of Dynamic Causal Effects with Strictly Exogenous Regressors

• X is strictly exogenous if E(ut|…,Xt+1, Xt, Xt–1, …) = 0

• If X is strictly exogenous, there are more efficient ways to estimate dynamic causal effects than by a distributed lag regression:

– Generalized Least Squares (GLS) estimation

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 15-26

– Autoregressive Distributed Lag (ADL) estimation

• But strict exogeneity is rarely plausible in practice

• So we won’t cover GLS or ADL estimation of dynamic causal effects – for details, see SW Section 15.5.

Page 27: Chapter 15: Estimation of Dynamic Causal Effects · is not the usual one from cross-sectional (i.i.d.) data, because uis serially correlated, not i.i.d

No strict exogeneity in weather/OJ data

• X is strictly exogenous if E(ut|…,Xt+1, Xt, Xt–1, …) = 0

• Error terms supposed to be uncorrelated with future X’s

• This is false in the weather/OJ data

• The error term is the difference between OJ price and its population prediction based on r=18 months of weather.

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 15-27

population prediction based on r=18 months of weather.

• One cause of the error is that traders in OJ futures use forecasts of weather

• So if a cold winter is forecasted, traders would drive up OJ futures price, which would exceed its predicted value based on the population regression … error term ut is positive

• Now, if forecast is accurate, future weather will be cold & fdd>0 (Xt+1 positve)

• Thus cov(ut, Xt+1) > 0, violating strict exogeneity

Page 28: Chapter 15: Estimation of Dynamic Causal Effects · is not the usual one from cross-sectional (i.i.d.) data, because uis serially correlated, not i.i.d

Orange Juice Prices and Cold Weather

What is the dynamic causal effect of increase in FDD on OJ prices?

%ChgPt = β0 + β1FDDt + … + βr+1FDDt–r + ut

•What r to use? How about r = 18 months? (Guess)

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 15-28

•We use the rule of thumb for the Newey-West truncation:

m = .75×6121/3 = 6.4 ≅ 7

Page 29: Chapter 15: Estimation of Dynamic Causal Effects · is not the usual one from cross-sectional (i.i.d.) data, because uis serially correlated, not i.i.d

Digression: Computation of cumulative multipliers and their standard errors

The cumulative multipliers can be computed by estimating the distributed lag model, then adding up the coefficients.

However, you should also compute standard errors for the cumulative multipliers. Though this can be done directly from the distributed lag model, some modifications are required.

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 15-29

Because cumulative multipliers are linear combinations of regression coefficients, the methods of Section 7.3 can be applied to compute their standard errors.

Page 30: Chapter 15: Estimation of Dynamic Causal Effects · is not the usual one from cross-sectional (i.i.d.) data, because uis serially correlated, not i.i.d

Computing cumulative multipliers, ctd.

A trick in Section 7.3 is to rewrite the regression so that the

coefficients in the rewritten regression are the coefficients of

interest – here, the cumulative multipliers.

Example: Rewrite the distributed lag model with 1 lag:

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 15-30

Yt = β0 + β1Xt + β2Xt–1 + ut= β0 + β1Xt – β1Xt–1 + β1Xt–1 + β2Xt–1 + ut= β0 + β1(Xt –Xt–1) + (β1 + β2)Xt–1 + ut

or

Yt = β0 + β1∆Xt + (β1+ β2) Xt–1 + ut

Page 31: Chapter 15: Estimation of Dynamic Causal Effects · is not the usual one from cross-sectional (i.i.d.) data, because uis serially correlated, not i.i.d

Computing cumulative multipliers, ctd.

So, let W1t = ∆Xt and W2t = Xt–1 and estimate the regression,

Yt = β0 + δ1 W1t + δ2W2t + ui

Then

δ1= β1 = impact effect

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 15-31

δ1= β1 = impact effect

δ2= β1 + β2 = the first cumulative multiplier

Fact: The (HAC) standard errors on δ1 and δ2 are the standard errors for the two cumulative multipliers.

Page 32: Chapter 15: Estimation of Dynamic Causal Effects · is not the usual one from cross-sectional (i.i.d.) data, because uis serially correlated, not i.i.d

Computing cumulative multipliers, ctd.

In general, the ADL model can be rewritten as,

Yt = δ0 + δ1∆Xt + δ2∆Xt–1 + … + δq–1∆Xt–q+1 + δqXt–q + utwhere

δ1 = β1

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 15-32

1 1

δ2 = β1 + β2

δ3 = β1 + β2 + β3

δq = β1 + β2 + … + βq

Fact: Cumulative multipliers and their HAC SEs can be computed directly using this transformed regression

Page 33: Chapter 15: Estimation of Dynamic Causal Effects · is not the usual one from cross-sectional (i.i.d.) data, because uis serially correlated, not i.i.d

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 15-33

Page 34: Chapter 15: Estimation of Dynamic Causal Effects · is not the usual one from cross-sectional (i.i.d.) data, because uis serially correlated, not i.i.d

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 15-34

Page 35: Chapter 15: Estimation of Dynamic Causal Effects · is not the usual one from cross-sectional (i.i.d.) data, because uis serially correlated, not i.i.d

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 15-35

Page 36: Chapter 15: Estimation of Dynamic Causal Effects · is not the usual one from cross-sectional (i.i.d.) data, because uis serially correlated, not i.i.d

Are the OJ dynamic effects stable?

Recall from Section 14.7 that we can test for stability of time series regression coefficients using the QLR statistic. So, we can compute QLR for regression (1) in Table 15.1:

• Use HAC SEs

• How specifically would you compute the Chow statistic?

• How would you compute the QLR statistic?

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 15-36

• How would you compute the QLR statistic?

• d.f. q=20 (fdd+18 lags+intercept), 1% critical value = 2.43

• Result: QLR = 21.19.

This significant at 1% level – reject constancy of coeff’s

• How to interpret the result substantively? Estimate the dynamic multipliers on subsamples and see how they have changed over time…

Page 37: Chapter 15: Estimation of Dynamic Causal Effects · is not the usual one from cross-sectional (i.i.d.) data, because uis serially correlated, not i.i.d

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 15-37

Page 38: Chapter 15: Estimation of Dynamic Causal Effects · is not the usual one from cross-sectional (i.i.d.) data, because uis serially correlated, not i.i.d

OJ: Do the breaks matter substantively?

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 15-38

The cumulative effect of a FDD has declined over time. Why? Orange groves moved south, so northern frosts less damaging:

Page 39: Chapter 15: Estimation of Dynamic Causal Effects · is not the usual one from cross-sectional (i.i.d.) data, because uis serially correlated, not i.i.d

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 15-39

Fact: After losing many trees to freezes in northern Florida, Florida orange growers planted farther south.

Page 40: Chapter 15: Estimation of Dynamic Causal Effects · is not the usual one from cross-sectional (i.i.d.) data, because uis serially correlated, not i.i.d

Is Exogeneity Plausible? Some Examples

If X is exogenous (and ass’ns 2-4 hold), then a distributed lag model provides consistent estimators of dynamic causal effects.

As in multiple regression with cross-sectional data, we must think critically about whether X is exogenous in any application:

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 15-40

• is X exogenous, i.e. E(ut|Xt, Xt–1, …) = 0?

• is X strictly exogenous, i.e. E(ut|…, Xt+1, Xt, Xt–1, …) = 0?

Page 41: Chapter 15: Estimation of Dynamic Causal Effects · is not the usual one from cross-sectional (i.i.d.) data, because uis serially correlated, not i.i.d

In the following, is exogeneity plausible?

1. Y = OJ prices, X = FDD in Orlando

2. Y = Australian exports, X = US GDP (simultaneous causality, but AU economy small relative to US)

3. Y = EU exports, X = US GDP (EU economy not small relative to US)

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 15-41

relative to US)

4. Y = US rate of inflation, X = percentage change in world oil prices (as set by OPEC) (endogenous effect of OPEC oil price increase on inflation)

5. Y = GDP growth, X =Federal Funds rate (endogenous effect of monetary policy on output growth)

6. Y = change in the rate of inflation, X = unemployment rate on inflation (the Phillips curve)

Page 42: Chapter 15: Estimation of Dynamic Causal Effects · is not the usual one from cross-sectional (i.i.d.) data, because uis serially correlated, not i.i.d

Exogeneity, ctd.

• Evaluate exogeneity & strict exogeneity, case by case

• Exogeneity is often not plausible in time series data because of simultaneous causality

• Strict exogeneity is rarely plausible in time series data because of feedbacks

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 15-42

Page 43: Chapter 15: Estimation of Dynamic Causal Effects · is not the usual one from cross-sectional (i.i.d.) data, because uis serially correlated, not i.i.d

Estimation of Dynamic Causal Effects: Summary

• In theory, dynamic causal effects are measurable using a randomized controlled experiment with repeated measurements over time.

• In practice, when X is exogenous, we can consistently estimate dynamic causal effects by distributed lag regression

• If u is serially correlated, conventional OLS SEs are

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 15-43

• If u is serially correlated, conventional OLS SEs are incorrect; we use HAC SEs

• Think carefully in application as to whether X is exogenous