can cross-border pollution reduce pollution? panos ... · department of economics university of...

26
DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS UNIVERSITY OF CYPRUS CAN CROSS-BORDER POLLUTION REDUCE POLLUTION? Panos Hatzipanayotou, Sajal Lahiri and Michael S. Michael Discussion Paper 2001-07 P.O. Box 20537, 1678 Nicosia, CYPRUS Tel.: ++357-2-892430, Fax: ++357-2-892432 Web site: http://www.econ.ucy.ac.cy

Upload: others

Post on 30-Apr-2020

1 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: CAN CROSS-BORDER POLLUTION REDUCE POLLUTION? Panos ... · DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS UNIVERSITY OF CYPRUS CAN CROSS-BORDER POLLUTION REDUCE POLLUTION? Panos Hatzipanayotou, Sajal Lahiri

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICSUNIVERSITY OF CYPRUS

CAN CROSS-BORDER POLLUTION REDUCE POLLUTION?

Panos Hatzipanayotou, Sajal Lahiri andMichael S. Michael

Discussion Paper 2001-07

P.O. Box 20537, 1678 Nicosia, CYPRUS Tel.: ++357-2-892430, Fax: ++357-2-892432Web site: http://www.econ.ucy.ac.cy

Page 2: CAN CROSS-BORDER POLLUTION REDUCE POLLUTION? Panos ... · DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS UNIVERSITY OF CYPRUS CAN CROSS-BORDER POLLUTION REDUCE POLLUTION? Panos Hatzipanayotou, Sajal Lahiri

Can Cross-border Pollution Reduce Pollution?

By

Panos Hatzipanayotou Athens University of Economics and Business

Sajal Lahiri

University of Essex

Michael S. Michael University of Cyprus

July 2001

Abstract We develop a two-country model of foreign aid and cross-border pollution resulting from production activities in the recipient country. There is both private and public abatement of pollution, the latter being financed through emissions tax revenue and foreign aid. We characterise a Nash equilibrium where the donor country chooses the amount of aid, and the recipient chooses the fraction of aid allocated to pollution abatement and/or the emission tax rate. At this equilibrium, an increase in the donor's perceived rate of cross-border pollution reduces emission levels.

Key Words: Cross-border Pollution, Pollution Abatement, Foreign Aid.

J.E.L. Classification: Q28: Environmental Management: Government Policy F35: Foreign Aid H41: Public Goods

Correspondence: Sajal Lahiri, Department of Economics, University of Essex, Colchester C04 3SQ, United Kingdom; Tel. + 44 1206872733, FAX + 441206872724, Email: [email protected]

Page 3: CAN CROSS-BORDER POLLUTION REDUCE POLLUTION? Panos ... · DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS UNIVERSITY OF CYPRUS CAN CROSS-BORDER POLLUTION REDUCE POLLUTION? Panos Hatzipanayotou, Sajal Lahiri

Can Cross-border Pollution Reduce Pollution?

1. Introduction

In recent years, policy makers and environmental activists have been voicing

strong concerns against the widespread environmental degradation due to the

intensification of economic activity. More often than not, the externalities associated

with pollution are not confined to a particular country or region. For this reason, the issue

of cross-border (or, transboundary) pollution has been the subject of discussion in many

international fora, and it is widely acknowledged that concerted international actions are

necessary to deal with the problem. It is also accepted that the developing countries need

help from the developed ones in order for the former to pursue environmental-friendly

policies.

The purpose of this paper is to demonstrate a positive aspect of the international

dimension of pollution. In particular, we consider a scenario in which pollution knows no

international boundary and the developed countries provide aid to the developing

countries to help the latter with pollution abatement. In this scenario, we show that an

increase in the perception in the developed world of the effect of cross-border pollution

will in fact reduce the total amount of pollution emission in the developing world.

In the literature on environment and the international economy, international trade

and trade policies play key roles (see, for example, Copeland (1994) and Beghin et al

(1997)).1 In our analysis, international linkages come via cross-border pollution and

transfers. We assume both countries to be small open economies so that the commodity

prices are exogenous and we do not consider trade polices. Instead, we allow the donor

country to determine endogenously the amount of aid, and the recipient country is free to

choose the emission tax rate and how much of the aid it wants to allocate for public

abatement of pollution.2 In other words, we assume that the developed country apply

1 For an extensive survey of the literature on environmental policies, see Cropper and Oats (1992). 2 Implicitly, we assume that the donor cannot tie aid to pollution abatement, i.e. aid is perfectly fungible. This assumption is consistent with the findings of many empirical studies that aid is, for all intents and purposes, highly fungible (see, for example, Pack and Pack (1993) and Zampelli (994)).

1

Page 4: CAN CROSS-BORDER POLLUTION REDUCE POLLUTION? Panos ... · DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS UNIVERSITY OF CYPRUS CAN CROSS-BORDER POLLUTION REDUCE POLLUTION? Panos Hatzipanayotou, Sajal Lahiri

"carrots" in the form of foreign aid rather than "sticks" such as trade sanctions, in order to

persuade the developing countries to follow sensible environmental polices.

There is a substantial literature on the economics of cross-border pollution. For

example, Merrifield (1988) in a two-country general equilibrium model with

internationally mobile goods, capital and pollution flows, examines the welfare effects of

selected abatement strategies (e.g., production taxes, abatement equipment standards).

Ludema and Wooton (1994) develop a two-country model with production generated

pollution in the exporting country and cross-border pollution externalities. Within this

framework, they examine the welfare effects of environmental policies (e.g., adoption of

pollution abating technology) vis-a-vis trade policies (e.g., reduction of import tariffs)

when the two countries either can non-cooperatively restrict trade, or when they are

bound by a free trade agreement. Ludema and Wooton (1997) extend their previous

theoretical framework by incorporating administrative costs and asymmetric information

in pollution abatement (known only to the exporting country), in order to examine the

welfare implications of cooperative and non-cooperative trade and environmental

policies. Copeland and Taylor (1995) consider a model of a world economy consisting of

two regions --North and South-- each composed of many countries. Governments set

national pollution quotas treating the rest of the world’s pollution as given. They

demonstrate, inter alia, that reduction in pollution by a coalition of countries may be

Pareto improving and that income transfers tied to pollution reduction can be welfare

enhancing. On the other hand, untied income transfers may not have an impact on global

pollution, terms of trade and levels of national welfare. Copeland (1996), in a two

country model of cross-border pollution, examines the effectiveness of a “pollution

content tariff”, i.e. an import tariff whose magnitude varies with the amount of pollution

generated by the production of the imported good.

In the bulk of the relevant literature, it is assumed that all abatement activities are

carried out by private agencies. Khan (1995) considers the other extreme where pollution

abatement is entirely provided by a central agency (e.g., government). Chao and Yu

(1999) examine the welfare implications of foreign aid tied to pollution abatement, in the

context of a two-country general equilibrium trade model where pollution is generated in

and inflicted upon the aid-receiving country only. In their model, private sectors

2

Page 5: CAN CROSS-BORDER POLLUTION REDUCE POLLUTION? Panos ... · DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS UNIVERSITY OF CYPRUS CAN CROSS-BORDER POLLUTION REDUCE POLLUTION? Panos Hatzipanayotou, Sajal Lahiri

undertake abatement in response to emission taxes, and, on the top of it, the public sector

carries out further abatement with the help of foreign aid.3 They examine the welfare

effects of an exogenous increase in foreign aid. We follow Chao and Yu (1999) in

considering the co-existence of private and public abatement of pollution. However, the

relationship between the two papers ends with that, both in terms of the model

formulation and the analysis.

The model is spelt out in the following section. Section 3 carries out welfare

analysis. The Nash equilibrium is characterised in section 4 which also carries out the

main exercise of the paper, i.e. the effect of a change in the donor’s perceived rate of

cross-border pollution. Finally, some concluding remarks are made in section 5.

2. The Model

In our model there are two small open economies --a developed donor and a

developing recipient country. Pollution takes place in the recipient country, as a by-

product of production. For simplicity, we assume that no pollution is generated in the

donor country. However, pollution created in the recipient country finds its way to the

developed country, and the latter suffers disutility from this cross-border pollution.

In both countries, a number of goods, which are freely traded in the international

market, are produced. The endowments of the internationally immobile factors of

production are inelastically supplied and the factor markets are perfectly competitive. In

the recipient country, both the private producers and the public sector take part in

pollution abatement. The private producers do so in response to an emission tax, t, and

the public sector abates some of the remaining pollution with the help of emission tax

revenue and foreign aid. The private and the public sectors compete in the factor market

on equal terms. The total factor endowment vector, V, in the recipient country can be

decomposed into the part that is used in the private sector, Vp, and the part that used in the

public abatement activities, Vg, i.e. V=Vp+Vg. The gross domestic product, or the

restricted revenue function, R(P, t, Vp), which is the country’s maximum value of

domestic production of private goods, is defined as

3 Hatzipanayotou et al (2000) derives conditions under which private and public abatement would co-exist.

3

Page 6: CAN CROSS-BORDER POLLUTION REDUCE POLLUTION? Panos ... · DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS UNIVERSITY OF CYPRUS CAN CROSS-BORDER POLLUTION REDUCE POLLUTION? Panos Hatzipanayotou, Sajal Lahiri

),(),(:'max),,( ,p

zxp VTzxtzxPVtPR ∈−=

where P is the vector of world commodity prices, T(Vp) is the country's aggregate

technology set and x and z are respectively the vector of net outputs and the amount of

pollution emission. The technology set includes pollution abatement technologies in the

various sectors. For a given level of abatement carried out by the public sector g, the

vector of factor uses in the public sector Vg and therefore Vp are uniquely determined.

Moreover, since P does not vary in our analysis, the revenue function can be written as

R(t,g).

The function is strictly convex in the effluent tax rate (i.e., ),

implying that an increase in the emissions tax rate lowers the amount of pollution

emissions by the private sector, and for the rest of the analysis we assume that .

R t g( , ) Rtt > 0

Rgg = 0

)]w

4

It is well known (see, for example, Abe (1992)) that is the

unit cost of public pollution abatement, where (w) is the vector of factor returns. It is also

well known (see, for example, Copeland (1994)) that is the amount of

pollution emissions by the private sectors. Therefore, taking both public and private

abatement of pollution, the net emission of pollution, r, is defined as

()/([ CgRR gg =∂∂−=−

ztgRt =− ),(

r z g R g tt= − = − −( , ) g

. (1)

We also assume that . That is, an increase in the government

provided pollution abatement reduces emission by the private sector. The justification for

this assumption is an induced Rybczynski effect on private goods production due to an

increase in . Heuristically speaking, if g increases, the supply of factor endowments

available for the production of the private goods becomes lower. This means that, on the

0)/( >∂−∂= gzRtg

g

4 This assumption implies that changes in (g), which change factor supplies available to produce private goods, do not affect its unit cost of production. For example, in a conventional H-O model, factor prices are determined by commodity prices and are independent of changes in factor endowments. Thus, when (g) changes then C . Abe (1992), Hatzipanayotou and Michael (1995) use this assumption in an alternative framework. Chao and Yu (1999) use the same assumption in a context similar to the one presented here.

0)( =−= gggg Rw

4

Page 7: CAN CROSS-BORDER POLLUTION REDUCE POLLUTION? Panos ... · DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS UNIVERSITY OF CYPRUS CAN CROSS-BORDER POLLUTION REDUCE POLLUTION? Panos Hatzipanayotou, Sajal Lahiri

whole, private production is reduced, which in turn implies that total pollution (i.e., )

falls, i.e., or .

tR−

t)

,( tg

0/)( <−=∂−∂ tgt RgR

=++ ),( tggRtzT g Tβ

0>tgR

0 < β

),( +tgtRt

Turning to the demand side in the recipient economy, the expenditure function

denotes the minimum expenditure required to achieve a level of utility u at the

prevailing commodity prices,

E r u( , )5 when the level of net pollution is r. The partial derivative

of the expenditure function with respect to u ( ) denotes the reciprocal of marginal

utility of income. Since pollution adversely affects household utility, the partial

derivative of the expenditure function with respect to r ( ) is positive and denotes the

households' marginal willingness to pay for the reduction in pollution (e.g., see Chao and

Yu (1999)). That is, a higher level of pollution requires a higher level of spending on

private goods to mitigate its detrimental effects in order to maintain a constant level of

utility. The expenditure function is assumed to be strictly convex in r, . That is, a

higher level of net pollution raises the households’ marginal willingness to pay for its

reduction.

Eu

rE

0>rrE

As for the recipient country government’s budget constraint, we assume that the

government finances the cost of publicly provided abatement (i.e., ) by

using a fraction or the entire amount of foreign aid provided by the donor

country,

gC tR ggg= − ( ,

tRtz t−=

1≤ 6 and the entire revenue raised from emission tax revenue (i.e., .

Thus, the government’s budget constraint can be written as:

)

(2) β .0),( =− tggRg

It may be useful to make to make two important observations on the above equation.

First, in defining the government budget constraint, we implicitly assume that emission

tax revenue is earmarked for public abatement. This assumption is not crucial for our

analysis as all our results would go through qualitatively if instead we assumed that that

this tax revenue is distributed in a lump-sum fashion to the consumers. We proceed with

5 For reasons mentioned before, prices are omitted from the arguments of the expenditure function. 6 Our assumption that implies that the recipient government is not required to provide matching funds for pollution abatement.

1≤β

5

Page 8: CAN CROSS-BORDER POLLUTION REDUCE POLLUTION? Panos ... · DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS UNIVERSITY OF CYPRUS CAN CROSS-BORDER POLLUTION REDUCE POLLUTION? Panos Hatzipanayotou, Sajal Lahiri

the present formulation of the budget constraint, as there is some evidence that emission

taxes are often earmarked for pollution abatement activities. For example, Brett and Keen

(2000) note that, in the US, it is quite customary for environmental taxes to be earmarked

for specific expenditure programs. In particular such tax proceeds are commonly paid

into trust funds that finance various clean-up activities, or are spend on road and public

transport networks. Second, as far as foreign aid is concerned, it could also be distributed

to domestic households in a lump-sum fashion and lump sum taxes, along with emission

tax revenue, could be used for financing the public abatement good. In such a case, it can

be easily shown that the donor country will have no incentive to provide foreign aid.

Therefore, from the viewpoint of the recipient country, by committing itself to the

proportional instrument , considered in the analysis, it can extract aid from the donor

country.

)(β

The description of the aid-receiving pollution-emitting country is completed by

writing its income-expenditure identity. The country’s budget constraint requires that

private spending ( ) must equal income from the production of private goods

( ) and from publicly provided pollution abatement ( ) plus the fraction

of aid distributed to domestic households in a lump-sum manner ( ( ). Using

equation (2), the recipient country’s budget constraint can be written as:

E r u( , )

R g t( , ) − gR g tg ( , )

)1− β T

. (3) E r u R g t tR g t Tt( , ) ( , ) ( , )= − +

Turning to the donor country, as noted before we assume that it does not generate

any pollution. The utility of this country, however, is affected adversely by cross-border

pollution originated in the recipient country (i.e. r). Denoting by θ the perceived degree

of cross-border pollution, the welfare of the donor country is affected adversely by the

perceived amount of cross-border pollution θ .r 7 In this context, θ is best interpreted as

the degree of consciousness in the donor country about cross-border pollution. That is, an

increase in θ means that, residents in the donor country are more aware of cross-border

7 See Ishikawa and Kiyono (2000) for the concept of perceived degree of cross-border pollution.

6

Page 9: CAN CROSS-BORDER POLLUTION REDUCE POLLUTION? Panos ... · DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS UNIVERSITY OF CYPRUS CAN CROSS-BORDER POLLUTION REDUCE POLLUTION? Panos Hatzipanayotou, Sajal Lahiri

pollution, but the actual level of cross-border pollution is not related to θ , but simply to

. r

Therefore, the country’s income-expenditure identity requires that private

spending, denoted by the expenditure function must equal revenue from

production of the private goods, , minus the amount of foreign aid transferred to the

recipient country. That is,

),,( ** urE θ

*R

. (4) TRurE −= *** ),(θ

Eu* denotes the reciprocal of the marginal utility of income in the donor country.

As before we assume that . Since the commodity prices are exogenous, the

factors of production are inelasticaly supplied, and there is no pollution or pollution

abatement --- private or public --- in the donor country, R

Err* > 0

* is exogenous to our analysis.

Equations (1)-(4) constitute a system of four equations in terms of the four

primary unknowns, namely u u and . The model contains one policy parameter for

the donor country, namely the amount of foreign aid ( , and two for the recipient

country: the fraction of foreign aid allocated to pollution abatement ( ) and the

emissions tax rate ( .

g, ,* z

)T

β

)t

3. Welfare Effects in the Recipient and Donor Countries

In this section we characterize the Nash optimal levels of the policy parameters

under a number of scenarios, depending on the scope of the instruments. First of all

differentiating equations (1)-(4), we obtain changes in the level of welfare in the donor

and the recipient countries as follows:8

dtAdAdTAduE tTu111 −−− ++= ∆β∆∆ β

∆β∆∆ β dtCdCdTCduE tTu111** −−− ++=

, (5)

, (6) θ∆ θ dC1−+

8 The system of basic equations for deriving these is stated in the matrix form in the appendix.

7

Page 10: CAN CROSS-BORDER POLLUTION REDUCE POLLUTION? Panos ... · DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS UNIVERSITY OF CYPRUS CAN CROSS-BORDER POLLUTION REDUCE POLLUTION? Panos Hatzipanayotou, Sajal Lahiri

where >0, , ))(1()1( gtgrtgT RtRERA −−++= ββ ])1[( tggrtg tRRERTA −++=β

)(])1)[(( tRREtRRERgRzA gttrtggrtggtt +−−+++= , ∆ >0, gtg RtR −=

)()1( *g

RtRERC tgrtgT −−+= βθ , C >0, )1(*tgr RET += θβ

)]())(1[(* tRRgRzREC gttgttgrt +−++=θ , and C <0.)(*gtgr RtRrE −−=θ

9

Before explaining the above equations, it may be helpful to explain how the policy

parameters affect the level of net emission. These are found to be:

dtgRzRtRRdRTdTRdr gttggtttgtg )])(1()([)1()1( ++−+++−+−=∆ ββ . (7)

It is clear from equation (7) that an increase in T or , as one would expect,

unambiguously reduces net pollution. However, an increase in t has an ambiguous effect

on net emission. An increase in t increases public abatement and reduces private

production, reducing demand for factors of production in the private sector and

increasing them in the public sector. The overall effect on the demand for, and therefore

the prices of, the factors are ambiguous. If the factors prices go up, the unit cost of

abating pollution would go up increasing net emission. An increase in t, ceteris paribus,

also reduces pollution emission by the private sector and therefore the tax base for public

sector abatement. The net effect of an increase in t on net emission is therefore

ambiguous.

β

Turning to the effects on welfare levels, since Rtg>0 and Rg<0, the term AT is

positive and therefore aid unambiguously improves welfare in the recipient country.

There is a direct positive effect due to the transfer per se, and an indirect positive effect

( ). The expression C in equation (6) indicates that for the donor country,

foreign aid has an ambiguous effect. That is, aid induces the direct negative effect due to

the income transfer, but so long as a fraction is spent on pollution abatement (i.e. ),

there is a positive indirect impact ( ) on the donor’s welfare. The expression

and A

rtg ER )1( +β

βA

T

0>β

rtg ER )1( +β

t are ambiguous in sign. An increase in either t or on one hand reduces β

9 Note that a change in θ has no effect on u.

8

Page 11: CAN CROSS-BORDER POLLUTION REDUCE POLLUTION? Panos ... · DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS UNIVERSITY OF CYPRUS CAN CROSS-BORDER POLLUTION REDUCE POLLUTION? Panos Hatzipanayotou, Sajal Lahiri

pollution, but on the other hand takes resources away from the private sector to the public

sector, reducing private income. An increase in reduces net pollution and thus, as

indicated by the term , unambiguously improves welfare of the donor country. The

term indicates that an increase in t has an ambiguous effect on the welfare of the

donor country. This is because, as noted before, an increase in t has an ambiguous effect

on the level of net emission.

β

βC

) = C

= βA

tA

dt =

=dt

0=

tC

E

E

E

dT +

+dT

+

Finally, as shown by the term , an increase in the perceived rate of cross-

border pollution in the donor country exerts a detrimental effect on the donor

country’s welfare level, while it has no direct effect on the welfare level in the recipient

country.

θC

( )θ

Turning now to the optimal choice of the instruments, we assume that the donor

decides on the amount of aid (T), while the recipient selects the proportion of aid

allocated to pollution abatement and the rate of emission tax (t). We assume that the two

countries behave non-cooperatively (Nash), so that the first order conditions are given by:

( )β

,0/( ** =∆ Tu dTdu (8)

(9) ,0)/( =∆ βdduu

(10) .0)/( ==∆u dtdu

Equations (8), (9) and (10) simultaneously determine the optimal values of T,

and t. Having obtained the optimality conditions, we examine the effect of an increase in

the perception parameter θ on the level of net emission r. To this end we differentiate

(8)-(10) and using (5)-(7), we obtain

β

θβ θβ dCCdCC TTtTTT −+ (11)

0+ AdAA tT ββββ β , (12)

+ dtAdAdTA ttttT ββ . (13)

9

Page 12: CAN CROSS-BORDER POLLUTION REDUCE POLLUTION? Panos ... · DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS UNIVERSITY OF CYPRUS CAN CROSS-BORDER POLLUTION REDUCE POLLUTION? Panos Hatzipanayotou, Sajal Lahiri

where10 *221 )1( rrtgTT ERC +∆−= − θβ , , )])(1()(1[)1( **1*

rrrutgrtgT RrTERC ηθηβθβ −+∆++= −

)()1()( **1rrruttgTt CRrC ηθηβ −+∆= − , C , )1()1( **

rurtgT ER θηβθ −+=

])1()[1( 11rrtguruTtgT EREEARTAA +−+∆+= −− βββ , , rrtg ERTA 221 )1( +∆−= −

ββ

rrgttgttgtgt EtRRgRzRRTA )]())(1)[(1(1 +−+++∆−= −β ,

)]()1()()1)][(())(1[( 1rrrurtgrugttgttgtT ERrEtRRgRzRA ηηββ −+∆+−+−++= − ,

ttrtgrrgttgttgtttt REREtRRgRzRARTA )1()]())(1[( 211 +−+−++∆−−= −−β ,

η η , η η . ),/( ururu EEr= ) ),/( ***ururu EEr=/( rrrrr EEr= )

/( ***rrrrr EEr=

Having obtained the general expression for changes in the policy variables, we shall

now examine the effect of a change in θ on the level of net emission r, under a number

of special cases.

3.1 A Benchmark Case: Passive Recipient

First, we consider a case where the donor government optimally chooses the amount

of foreign aid , but the recipient government treats as exogenous. In this case,

the effect of a change in the perceived rate of cross-border pollution on net pollution

is given by:

)(T ),( tβ

)(θ

=)/( θddr =∂∂+∂∂ )]/)(/()/[( θθ ddTTrr )/)(1(1 θβ ddTRtg+∆− − , (14)

where and is given by equations (7). Equation (14) indicates that

a higher value of θ reduces net emission if and only if it increases the amount of the

transfer. In order to find the effect on transfer, letting d in equation (11), we

get:

0)/( =∂∂ θr )/( Tr ∂∂

0== dtβ

10 Note that CTT<0 and <0, and therefore the respective welfare functions are concave in T and . A

sufficient condition for Att to be negative is that . Note also that third derivatives are assumed zero. ββA β

0≥βA

10

Page 13: CAN CROSS-BORDER POLLUTION REDUCE POLLUTION? Panos ... · DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS UNIVERSITY OF CYPRUS CAN CROSS-BORDER POLLUTION REDUCE POLLUTION? Panos Hatzipanayotou, Sajal Lahiri

1***1 ])1([)1()/( −− +−∆= rrtgrru EREddT θηθ , (15)

where is the donor country’s marginal propensity to pay for pollution

abatement. Since it is natural to assume that the consumers will not be willing, at the

margin, to pay more than their additional income for pollution abatement, we assume that

It then immediately follows from (14) and (15) that an increase in θ

unambiguously reduces net emission.

)/( ***ururu ErE=η

.1* <ruη

Proposition 1: Consider two countries, a donor that optimally chooses the amount of

aid, and a recipient pollution-emitting that uses a fixed fraction of aid and pollution tax

revenue, at a constant tax rate, to finance pollution abatement. Then, an increase in the

perceived rate of cross-border pollution, unambiguously raises the amount of foreign aid,

and reduces the level of net emission.

The intuition of this result can be as follows. An increase in θ increases the marginal

benefit of aid as the recipient country spends a positive fraction of it on pollution

abatement. This induces the donor to increase the amount of aid, and thus reducing

emission level.

3.2 The Case of Nash Equilibrium

Next we consider the case in which the donor, as before, decides on the level of

aid, and the recipient chooses the instruments at its disposal. We consider three sub cases

depending on the instruments the recipients decide to use.

Case 1: The donor country optimally chooses the amount of foreign aid (T), and the

recipient sets optimally the fraction ( of foreign aid allocated to pollution abatement.

The emission tax rate (t) is assumed to be exogenous.

In this case, the effect of a change in θ on net emission is given as:

11

Page 14: CAN CROSS-BORDER POLLUTION REDUCE POLLUTION? Panos ... · DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS UNIVERSITY OF CYPRUS CAN CROSS-BORDER POLLUTION REDUCE POLLUTION? Panos Hatzipanayotou, Sajal Lahiri

=∂∂+∂∂= )/)(/()/)(/()/( θββθθ ddrddTTrddr

)]/()/([)1( 1 θβθβ ddTddTRtg +∆+− − , (16)

where the expressions for ( and are given in (7). Equation (16) indicates

that if θ raises foreign aid and its fraction allocated to pollution abatement in the

recipient country (i.e. if and ), then it will reduce emission,

i.e. .

)/ Tr ∂∂

)/( θddT

)/( β∂∂r

/( βd0> 0) >θd

0)( <θdr / d

The Nash equilibrium in this case is derived by setting and .

Totally differentiating these two equations, we can solve for the effects on T and as:

0=TC 0=βA

β

, and (17) ββθθ ACddT T−=Ω )/(

, (18) θβθβ TT CAdd =Ω )/(

where Ω > 0 for stability of the system.)( ββββ TTTT CACA −= 11

From (17) it is clear that an increase in the perception parameter θ

unambiguously increases aid, as in the previous case. But, the effect on is

unambiguous. In particular, if the marginal propensity to pay for the pollution abatement

is very small in the recipient country, we have , and therefore an increase in θ

will reduce . The intuition is simple. If the marginal propensity to pay for pollution

abatement is small, the recipient government would allocate a smaller proportion of aid to

public abatement and thus increasing the activities of the private sector.

β

0<TAβ

β

Next, substituting equation (17) and (18) into (16), and after some manipulations,

we get

=)/( θddr ruTtg ECRT θ132 )()1( −∆Ω+− , (19)

11 See, for example, Takayama (1985), pp. 313-319.

12

Page 15: CAN CROSS-BORDER POLLUTION REDUCE POLLUTION? Panos ... · DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS UNIVERSITY OF CYPRUS CAN CROSS-BORDER POLLUTION REDUCE POLLUTION? Panos Hatzipanayotou, Sajal Lahiri

Equation (19) shows that an increase in θ unambiguously reduces net emission,

regardless of its ambiguous effect on . β

Case 2: The donor country optimally chooses the amount of foreign aid (T), and the

recipient sets optimally the emission tax rate ( . The fraction of foreign aid allocated to

pollution abatement is set exogenously.

)t

)(β 12

The Nash equilibrium in this case is derived by setting C and . Differentiating

these equilibrium conditions, we obtain:

0=T 0=tA

ttT ACddT θθ −=Ω )/(1 , and (20)

, (21) θθ TtT CAddt =Ω )/(1

where Ω >0 for the stability of the system. )(1 TttTTTtt CACA −=

Since Att <0 and , it follows from (20) that an increase in θ increases the

optimal level of aid. However, A

0>θTC

tT, and therefore dt , cannot be signed

unambiguously. Using the Nash equilibrium conditions, the expression for A

θd/

tT can be

simplified as:

])()1([)( 111 −−− ∆+++−+= ururrtgrgttT EEATEREgRzA βββ .

From the above expression it is clear that AtT, and therefore , are negative

if the marginal propensity to pay for pollution abatement in the recipient country is very

small. The intuition is similar to that given for in the previous case. The

effect on net emission in this case is given by:

θddt /

θβ dd /

=∂∂+∂∂= )/)(/()/)(/()/( θθθ ddttrddTTrddr

12 This case can also be viewed as one of tied aid, where the fraction of aid allocated to public abatement in the recipient country, , is set by the donor. β

13

Page 16: CAN CROSS-BORDER POLLUTION REDUCE POLLUTION? Panos ... · DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS UNIVERSITY OF CYPRUS CAN CROSS-BORDER POLLUTION REDUCE POLLUTION? Panos Hatzipanayotou, Sajal Lahiri

)/()()/()1( 11 θθβ ddtEgRzddTR rgttg−− +−∆+− , (22)

where the expressions for and are given in equation (7).)/( Tr ∂∂ )/( tr ∂∂ 13 Substituting

(20) and (21) into (22), we get:

=+−+∆Ω= −− ])()1([)/( 111 tTrgttttgT AEgRzARCddr βθ θ

rurgtururgttttgT EEgRzEEEgRzRRATC 2121212111 )()(])()()1([ −−−−− +∆−+++∆−Ω βθ β

− . (23) )1( 21ttrtg RER+∆− β

Unlike in the previous two cases, the effect on net emission is no longer

unambiguous. However, a sufficient condition for the effect to be negative is that is

non-negative. However, if the marginal propensity to pay for pollution abatement is small

and negative, an increase in θ may increase net emission. Note that is negative,

when the exogenously given value of is higher than the optimal one. It is also to be

noted that a higher means more resources are spent in the public sector at the expense

of the private one. In this case, therefore, the recipient government redresses this

imbalance by reducing emission tax rate and thus increasing net emission.

βA

βA βA

β

β

Case 3: The donor country optimally chooses the amount of , and the recipient

country optimally sets both the fraction of aid allocated to pollution abatement , and

the emission tax rate

)(T

)(β

)(t .

In this case, the Nash equilibrium is obtained by setting .

Differentiating these equations, we get:

0=== Tt CAAβ

)()/( ttttT AAAACddTD ββββθθ −−= , (24)

) , (25) ()/( tTtTT AAAACddtD ββββθθ −−=

14

Page 17: CAN CROSS-BORDER POLLUTION REDUCE POLLUTION? Panos ... · DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS UNIVERSITY OF CYPRUS CAN CROSS-BORDER POLLUTION REDUCE POLLUTION? Panos Hatzipanayotou, Sajal Lahiri

)()/( tTtTttT AAAACddD ββθθβ −= , (26)

where is the determinant of the matrix of coefficients for dT and in equations

(11)-(13). Stability requires that is negative. Note that the optimality conditions in this

case, i.e. , imply that , and thus the expressions of the

individual coefficients on the right hand sides are simplified as:

D βd, dt

D

0=== Tt CAAβ tRE gr =−=

, =TAβ ])1()[1( 11rrtgurutg EREERT +∆−+ −− β

== ββ tt AA rrtgtg EgRzRT )()1( 21 ++− −∆ ,

, =tTA ])1()[)(1( 11rrtgurutgtg EREEgRzR +∆−++ −− β

. =ttA )1()()1( 221tgttrrrtgtg RREEgRzR +−++∆− −

Substituting the above expressions in (24)-(26), we get:

ttrrrtgT REERTCddTD 312 )1()/( +∆−= −θθ , (27)

, (28) 0

)/( =θddtD

=)/( θβ ddD ])1([)1( 1122 −− −++ ururrtgrtttgT EEERERRTC β∆θ . (29)

From (27) and (28) it is clear that an increase in the perception parameter θ

unambiguously raises the amount of aid ( ), and has no effect on the emission

tax rate ( ). Finally, the impact on the fraction of aid allocated to pollution, ,

abatement is ambiguous. The reason for ambiguity in the effect on is the same as

before. Our assumption that a change in g does not affect R

0/ >θddT

0/ =θddt β

β

g (Rgg=0) and the fact the

optimality requires t=-Rg together means that a change in θ has no effect on the optimal

level of t.

The effect on net emission in this case is:

0=tA .0)()]())(1 1 >∆+=+−++ −rgtgttgttg EgRztRRgRzR13 Using , it can be shown that [(

15

Page 18: CAN CROSS-BORDER POLLUTION REDUCE POLLUTION? Panos ... · DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS UNIVERSITY OF CYPRUS CAN CROSS-BORDER POLLUTION REDUCE POLLUTION? Panos Hatzipanayotou, Sajal Lahiri

)]/()/()[1()/( 1 θβθβθ ddTddTRddr tg ++∆−= −

= . (30) ttururtgT REEERCTD 1321 )1()( −− +∆ θ

Since , it is evident from the above equation that an increase in θ unambiguously

reduces net emission. Summarizing our results for the two Nash equilibrium regimes, we

state:

0<D

Proposition 2: Consider a Nash equilibrium where a donor country optimally chooses

the amount of transfer to a pollution emitting country, which sets optimally either the

fraction of aid allocated to pollution abatement and/or the emission tax rate. In all cases

an increase in the perceived rate of cross-border pollution in the donor country

unambiguously raises the amount of foreign aid. In all the cases, except when the

recipient chooses only the emission tax rate, it also reduces net pollution, regardless of

its effect on either the fraction of aid allocated to pollution abatement or the effluent tax

rate. When the recipient country chooses only the emission tax rate, an increase in the

perception factor reduces net emission if the exogenous level of the fraction of aid

allocated to pollution abatement is lower than or equal to the optimal level.

4. Concluding Remarks

A dominant issue in current economic policy debates is the interaction between

international trade and negative cross-border environmental externalities due to increased

production of pollution-intensive goods, and due to the use of environmentally unfriendly

production technologies. This negative link allegedly has been exacerbated because of the

recent surge in the volume of international trade, and because of the conscious and

systematic efforts by international institution, organizations, and many countries to

liberalize the international mobility of commodities and factors of production. To limit

the damaging impact of cross-border pollution, the affected countries often use threat of

trade sanction to persuade the pollution-generating countries to get their acts together.

However, following a number of very high profile international summits --- the latest one

being the 1997 summit in Kyoto --- the developed countries have been advised to take a

16

Page 19: CAN CROSS-BORDER POLLUTION REDUCE POLLUTION? Panos ... · DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS UNIVERSITY OF CYPRUS CAN CROSS-BORDER POLLUTION REDUCE POLLUTION? Panos Hatzipanayotou, Sajal Lahiri

less combative approach and follow a "carrots" rather than "sticks" approach to cross-

border pollution.

Motivated by such aspects of the recent environmental agreements, we develop a

two-country model with income transfers, transboundary pollution, and co-existence of

private and public abatement. The government of the aid-receiving, pollution-emitting

country uses a fraction of this international transfer, along with emission taxes to finance

the provision of the public abatement good. We find that, even in the absence of

international cooperation, cross-border pollution can reduce the total amount of pollution

emission by inducing more international transfer that in turn brings about more sensible

pollution policies in the polluting country. In this respect the fact that the externalities

associated with pollution often knows no international border, is a blessing in disguise.

We conclude with a final remark. We know from Coase´s theorem that if the two

countries can contract costlessly with each other, the country affected by cross-border

pollution would agree to pay a transfer to the pollution emitting country to reduce, and

thus internalize, its pollution. Then, an increase in the degree of consciousness in the

donor country about cross-border pollution increases foreign aid and reduces net

pollution. Thus, the answer to the question “Can cross-border pollution reduce

pollution?” is obviously affirmative. In the present paper, however, this question is

addressed within a non-cooperative framework, i.e. it is implicitly assumed that

contracting is costly.

17

Page 20: CAN CROSS-BORDER POLLUTION REDUCE POLLUTION? Panos ... · DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS UNIVERSITY OF CYPRUS CAN CROSS-BORDER POLLUTION REDUCE POLLUTION? Panos Hatzipanayotou, Sajal Lahiri

Appendix A: The Matrix System of Changes in the Variable

Total differentiation of equations (1)-(4) yields:

+−−

tg

g

rru

grru

RRt

EEEREtEE

10000

0)()(0

*** θθ

dududzdg

*

= +

11

0

−−

βdT

0

00

rEdr

*

θ

+ + .

00

0−

T dβ

00

− +−

( )z gRR

dtgt

tt

18

Page 21: CAN CROSS-BORDER POLLUTION REDUCE POLLUTION? Panos ... · DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS UNIVERSITY OF CYPRUS CAN CROSS-BORDER POLLUTION REDUCE POLLUTION? Panos Hatzipanayotou, Sajal Lahiri

References

Abe, K., 1992, Tariff reform in a small open economy with public production,

International Economic Review 33, 209-222.

Baumol, W. and W. Oates, 1988, The theory of environmental policy, Cambridge:

Cambridge University Press.

Brett, C. and M. Keen, 2000, Political uncertainty and the earmarking of environmental

taxes, Journal of Public Economics 75, 315-340.

Beghin, J., D. Roland-Holst and D. van der Mensbrugghe, 1997, Trade and pollution

linkages: piecemeal policy reform and optimal intervention, Canadian Journal of

Economics 30, 442-455.

Chao, C.C. and E. Yu, 1999, Foreign aid, the environment, and welfare, Journal of

Development Economics 59, 553-564.

Copeland, B., 1994, International trade and the environment: policy reform in a polluted

small open economy, Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 26,

44-65.

Copeland, B.R., 1996, Pollution content tariffs, environmental rent shifting, and the

control of cross-border pollution, Journal of International

Economics 40, 459-476.

Copeland, B.R., and M.S. Taylor, 1995, Trade and transboundary pollution, American

Economic Review 85, 716-737.

Cropper, M.L. and W.E. Oates, 1992, Environmental economics: a survey,

Journal of Economic Literature 30, 675-740.

Hatzipanayotou, P. and M.S. Michael, 1995, Foreign aid and public goods, Journal of

Development Economics 47, 455-467.

Hatzipanayotou, P., S.Lahiri and M.S. Michael, 2000, On the coexistence of private and

public abatement of pollution, mimeo, University of Essex.

Ishikawa, J. and K. Kiyono, 2000, International trade and global warming, mimeo,

Hitotsubashi University, Japan.

Khan, A., 1995, Free trade and the environment, Journal of International Trade and

Economic Development 5, 113-136.

19

Page 22: CAN CROSS-BORDER POLLUTION REDUCE POLLUTION? Panos ... · DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS UNIVERSITY OF CYPRUS CAN CROSS-BORDER POLLUTION REDUCE POLLUTION? Panos Hatzipanayotou, Sajal Lahiri

Khilji, N.M. and E.M.Zampelli, 1994, The fungibility of U.S. military and non-military

assistance and the impacts on major aid recipients, Journal of Development

Economics 43, 345-362.

Ludema, R. and I. Wooton, 1994, Cross-border externalities and trade liberalization: the

strategic control of pollution, Canadian Journal of Economics 27, 950-966.

Ludema, R. and I. Wooton, 1997, International trade rules and environmental cooperation

under asymmetric information, International Economic Review 38, 605-625.

Merrifield, J., 1988, The impact of selected abatement strategies on transnational

pollution, the terms of trade, and factor rewards: A general equilibrium approach,

Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 15, 259-284.

Pack, H. and J. R. Pack, 1994, Foreign aid the question of fungibility, Review of

Economic and Statistics 75, 258-265.

Takayama, A., 1986, Mathematical economics 2nd edition, Cambridge: Cambridge

University Press.

20

Page 23: CAN CROSS-BORDER POLLUTION REDUCE POLLUTION? Panos ... · DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS UNIVERSITY OF CYPRUS CAN CROSS-BORDER POLLUTION REDUCE POLLUTION? Panos Hatzipanayotou, Sajal Lahiri

SELECTED RECENT PUBLICATIONS

Bera A. K. and Yannis Bilias, Rao´s Score, Neyman´s C ($\alpha$) and Silvey´s LM Tests:An Essay on Historical Developments and Some New Results, Journal of StatisticalPlanning and Inference, forthcoming.

Bertaut C. and M. Haliassos, Precautionary Portfolio Behavior from a Life - CyclePerspective, Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 21, 1511-1542, 1997.

Bilias Y., Minggao Gu and Zhiliang Ying, Towards a General Asymptotic Theory for theCox model with Staggered Entry, The Annals of Statistics, 25, 662-682, 1997.

Blundell R., P. Pashardes and G. Weber, What Do We Learn About Consumer DemandPatterns From Micro-Data?, American Economic Review, 83, 570-597, 1993.

Bougheas S., P. Demetriades and T. P. Mamouneas, Infrastructure, Specialization andEconomic Growth, Canadian Journal of Economics, forthcoming.

Caporale W., C. Hassapis and N. Pittis, Unit Roots and Long Run Causality: Investigating theRelationship between Output, Money and Interest Rates, Economic Modeling, 15(1), 91-112,January 1998.

Caporale G. and N. Pittis, Efficient estimation of cointegrated vectors and testing forcausality in vector autoregressions: A survey of the theoretical literature, Journal ofEconomic Surveys, forthcoming.

Caporale G. and N. Pittis, Unit root testing using covariates: Some theory and evidence,Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, forthcoming.

Caporale G. and N. Pittis, Causality and Forecasting in Incomplete Systems, Journal ofForecasting, 16, 6, 425-437, 1997.

Clerides K. S., Lach S. and J.R. Tybout, Is Learning-by-Exporting Important? Micro-Dynamic Evidence from Colombia, Morocco, and Mexico, Quarterly Journal of Economics113(3), 903- 947, August 1998.

Cukierman A., P. Kalaitzidakis, L. Summers and S. Webb, Central Bank Independence,Growth, Investment, and Real Rates", Reprinted in Sylvester Eijffinger (ed), IndependentCentral Banks and Economic Performance, Edward Elgar, 416-461, 1997.

Dickens R., V. Fry and P. Pashardes, Non-Linearities and Equivalence Scales, The EconomicJournal, 103, 359-368, 1993.

Demetriades P. and T. P. Mamuneas, Intertemporal Output and Employment Effects ofPublic Infrastructure Capital: Evidence from 12 OECD Economies, Economic Journal, July2000.

Eicher Th. and P. Kalaitzidakis, The Human Capital Dimension to Foreign DirectInvestment: Training, Adverse Selection and Firm Location”. In Bjarne Jensen and Kar-yiu

Page 24: CAN CROSS-BORDER POLLUTION REDUCE POLLUTION? Panos ... · DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS UNIVERSITY OF CYPRUS CAN CROSS-BORDER POLLUTION REDUCE POLLUTION? Panos Hatzipanayotou, Sajal Lahiri

Wong (eds), Dynamics,Economic Growth, and International Trade, The University ofMichigan Press, 337-364, 1997.

Fry V. and P. Pashardes, Abstention and Aggregation in Consumer Demand, OxfordEconomic Papers, 46, 502-518, 1994.

Gatsios K., P. Hatzipanayotou and M. S. Michael, International Migration, the Provision ofPublic Good and Welfare, Journal of Development Economics, 60/2, 561-577, 1999.

Haliassos M. and C. Hassapis, Non-expected Utility, saving, and Portfolios, The EconomicJournal, 110, 1-35, January 2001.

Haliassos M. and J. Tobin, The Macroeconomics of Government Finance, reprinted inJ.Tobin, Essays in Economics, vol. 4, Cambridge: MIT Press, 1996.

Haliassos M. and C. Bertaut, Why Do So Few Hold Stocks?, The Economic Journal, 105,1110- 1129, 1995.

Haliassos M., On Perfect Foresight Models of a Stochastic World, Economic Journal, 104,477-491, 1994.

Hassapis C., N. Pittis and K. Prodromidis, Unit Roots and Granger Causality in the EMSInterest Rates: The German Dominance Hypothesis Revisited, Journal of InternationalMoney and Finance, 18(1), 47-73, 1999.

Hassapis C., S. Kalyvitis and N. Pittis, Cointegration and Joint Efficiency of InternationalCommodity Markets”, The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance, 39, 213-231, 1999.

Hassapis C., N. Pittis and K. Prodromides, EMS Interest Rates: The German DominanceHypothesis or Else?” in European Union at the Crossroads: A Critical Analysis of MonetaryUnion and Enlargement, Aldershot, UK., Chapter 3, 32-54, 1998. Edward Elgar PublishingLimited.

Hatzipanayotou P., and M. S. Michael, General Equilibrium Effects of Import ConstraintsUnder Variable Labor Supply, Public Goods and Income Taxes, Economica, 66, 389-401,1999.

Hatzipanayotou, P. and M.S. Michael, Public Good Production, Nontraded Goods and TradeRestriction, Southern Economic Journal, 63, 4, 1100-1107, 1997.

Hatzipanayotou, P. and M. S. Michael, Real Exchange Rate Effects of Fiscal ExpansionUnder Trade Restrictions, Canadian Journal of Economics, 30-1, 42-56, 1997.

Kalaitzidakis P., T. P. Mamuneas and Th. Stengos, A Nonlinear Sensitivity Analysis ofCross-Country Growth Regressions, Canadian Journal of Economics, forthcoming.

Kalaitzidakis P., T. P. Mamuneas and Th. Stengos, European Economics: An Analysis Basedon Publications in Core Journals, European Economic Review, 43, 1150-1168, 1999.

Page 25: CAN CROSS-BORDER POLLUTION REDUCE POLLUTION? Panos ... · DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS UNIVERSITY OF CYPRUS CAN CROSS-BORDER POLLUTION REDUCE POLLUTION? Panos Hatzipanayotou, Sajal Lahiri

Kalaitzidakis P., On-the-job Training Under Firm-Specific Innovations and WorkerHeterogeneity, Industrial Relations, 36, 371-390, July 1997.

Ludvigson S. and A. Michaelides, Does Buffer Stock Saving Explain the Smoothness andExcess Sensitivity of Consumption?, American Economic Review, forthcoming

Lyssiotou Panayiota, Dynamic Analysis of British Demand for Tourism Abroad, EmpiricalEconomics, forthcoming, 2000.

Lyssiotou P., P. Pashardes and Th. Stengos, Testing the Rank of Engel Curves withEndogenous Expenditure, Economics Letters, 64, 61-65, 1999.

Lyssiotou P., P. Pashardes and Th. Stengos, Preference Heterogeneity and the Rank ofDemand Systems, Journal of Business and Economic Statistics, 17 (2), 248-252, April 1999.

Lyssiotou Panayiota, Comparison of Alternative Tax and Transfer Treatment of Childrenusing Adult Equivalence Scales, Review of Income and Wealth, 43 (1), 105-117, March 1997.

Mamuneas, Theofanis P., Spillovers from Publicly – Financed R&D Capital in High-TechIndustries, International Journal of Industrial Organization, 17(2), 215-239, 1999.

Mamuneas, T. P. and Nadiri M. I., R&D Tax Incentives and Manufacturing-Sector R&DExpenditures, in Borderline Case: International Tax Policy, Corporate Research andDevelopment, and Investment, James Poterba (ed.), National Academy Press, WashingtonD.C., 1997. Reprinted in Chemtech, 28(9), 1998.

Mamuneas, T. P. and Nadiri M. I., Public R&D Policies and Cost Behavior of the USManufacturing Industries, Journal of Public Economics, 63, 57-81, 1996.

Michaelides A. and Ng, S., Estimating the Rational Expectations Model of SpeculativeStorage: A Monte Carlo Comparison of three Simulation Estimators, Journal ofEconometrics, 96(2), 231-266, 2000.

Pashardes Panos, Equivalence Scales in a Rank-3 Demand System, Journal of PublicEconomics, 58, 143-158, 1995.

Pashardes Panos, Bias in Estimating Equivalence Scales from Grouped Data, Journal ofIncome Distribution, Special Issue: Symposium on Equivalence Scales, 4, 253-264,1995.

Pashardes Panos., Bias in Estimation of the Almost Ideal Demand System with the StoneIndex Approximation, Economic Journal, 103, 908-916, 1993.

Spanos Aris, Revisiting Date Mining: ´Hunting´ With or Without a License, Journal ofMethodology, July 2000.

Spanos Aris, On Normality and the Linear Regression Model, Econometric Reviews, 14,195-203, 1995.

Spanos Aris, On Theory Testing in Econometrics: Modeling with nonexperimental Data,Journal of Econometrics, 67, 189-226, 1995.

Page 26: CAN CROSS-BORDER POLLUTION REDUCE POLLUTION? Panos ... · DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS UNIVERSITY OF CYPRUS CAN CROSS-BORDER POLLUTION REDUCE POLLUTION? Panos Hatzipanayotou, Sajal Lahiri

Spanos Aris, On Modeling Heteroscedasticity: The Student's t and Elliptical LinearRegression Models, Econometric Theory, 10, 286-315, 1994.