bargaining, third-party information and the division...

37
Bargaining, Third-Party Information and the Division of Profit in the Distribution Channel Greg Shaffer University of Rochester Florian Zettelmeyer University of California at Berkeley August, 1999 We are indebted to Meghan Busse for detailed comments and helpful suggestions. We also thank Miguel Villas-Boas, Anne Coughlan, Wujin Chu, and seminar participants at UC Berkeley, the University of Chicago, Yale University, and the Marketing Science Conference in Syracuse (1999). Addresses for cor- respondence: William E. Simon Graduate School of Business, University of Rochester, Rochester NY 14627, and Haas School of Business, UC Berkeley, Berkeley CA 94720-1900. E-mail: shaff[email protected], [email protected]

Upload: vumien

Post on 15-Mar-2018

217 views

Category:

Documents


2 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Bargaining, Third-Party Information and the Division …haas.berkeley.edu/Courses/Spring2000/BA269D/bargainm.pdfBargaining, Third-Party Information and the Division of Profit in the

Bargaining, Third-Party Information and

the Division of Profit in the Distribution Channel∗

Greg Shaffer

University of Rochester

Florian Zettelmeyer

University of California at Berkeley

August, 1999

∗We are indebted to Meghan Busse for detailed comments and helpful suggestions. We also thankMiguel Villas-Boas, Anne Coughlan, Wujin Chu, and seminar participants at UC Berkeley, the Universityof Chicago, Yale University, and the Marketing Science Conference in Syracuse (1999). Addresses for cor-respondence: William E. Simon Graduate School of Business, University of Rochester, Rochester NY 14627,and Haas School of Business, UC Berkeley, Berkeley CA 94720-1900. E-mail: [email protected],[email protected]

Page 2: Bargaining, Third-Party Information and the Division …haas.berkeley.edu/Courses/Spring2000/BA269D/bargainm.pdfBargaining, Third-Party Information and the Division of Profit in the

Bargaining, Third-Party Information and

the Division of Profit in the Distribution Channel

Abstract

The consolidation of power among retailers in recent years has forced many manufacturersto compete in a channel structure in which managing relations with retailers has becomejust as important as competing with one’s rivals. One consequence of this is that supplyterms are now often negotiated individually with each retailer (e.g., wholesale prices,quantity discounts, cooperative advertising, slotting allowances). In this paper we use abargaining framework to address the question: how do profits get allocated in a distributionchannel in which a retailer carries the products of competing manufacturers, and howdo these profits change in response to changing market conditions. We find that eachmanufacturer’s profit depends on its product’s incremental contribution to overall channelprofit. In addition, we find that when demand conditions change over time, the typeof information/advertising that induces the change (i.e., whether it is product-specific orrelates to the whole category, and whether it is of equal relevance to all consumers oraffects some consumer groups more than others) is critical in understanding which firmsgain and which firms lose.

Page 3: Bargaining, Third-Party Information and the Division …haas.berkeley.edu/Courses/Spring2000/BA269D/bargainm.pdfBargaining, Third-Party Information and the Division of Profit in the

1 Introduction

The consolidation of power among retailers in recent years has forced many manufacturers to

compete in a channel structure in which managing relations with retailers has become just as

important as competing with one’s rivals. Retail giants such as Walmart,Toys- R-Us, Krogers,

Barnes and Noble, and CompUSA have used their power to pressure manufacturers into grant-

ing price concessions (Stern, El-Ansary, Coughlan, 1996). In many instances, these concessions

have taken place over non-marginal payments (e.g, slotting allowances, cooperative advertising).

In other instances, the concessions have taken place over marginal payments (e.g., wholesale

prices). But whatever their form, one thing is certain: negotiating over supply terms has

become commonplace. Manufacturers can no longer simply dictate their terms of sale.1

In this paper we analyze some of the factors that determine the outcome of these nego-

tiations. In particular we address the question: what determines how profits get allocated

within the channel, and how do these profits change over time in response to changing market

conditions? Our first main finding is that a manufacturer’s profit depends on its product’s

incremental contribution to overall channel profit, and thus, it depends critically on the pre-

vailing market demand conditions for all products. Thus, we argue that negotiations between

a retailer and one manufacturer cannot be analyzed in isolation from what is happening in

the marketplace between that retailer and competing manufacturers. For example, our model

suggests that the bargaining outcome between Walmart and Procter and Gamble critically

depends not only on how well Procter and Gamble’s products are selling, but also on how well

Colgate-Palmolive’s products are selling, and how well they would sell if Walmart were to drop

some of Procter and Gamble’s products.

Since demand conditions are inherently dynamic and can be affected by advertising and

product information to be found on the Internet and other media, we focus in addition on how

profits are likely to be affected as demand conditions change over time. In particular, we focus

on changes in external demand conditions that are induced by third party information that

affects consumers’ product valuations. This leads to our second main finding: when demand

conditions change over time, the type of information that induces the change (whether it is

product-specific or relates to the whole category, and whether it is of equal relevance to all

consumers or affects some consumer groups more than others) is critical in understanding who

gains and who loses at contract time—often, the results are counterintuitive.

1Although many observers believe that the balance of power has shifted in the favor of retailers as a result,and cite as evidence the growing use of slotting allowances, there is some evidence to the contrary. For example,Messinger and Narasimhan (1995) find that relative profits within the channel do not appear to have changedover time. We do not enter into this debate here, as we will take each side’s bargaining power as given. Thus,we focus on short run changes in firms’ profits around whatever long run trend there may or may not be.

1

Page 4: Bargaining, Third-Party Information and the Division …haas.berkeley.edu/Courses/Spring2000/BA269D/bargainm.pdfBargaining, Third-Party Information and the Division of Profit in the

Intuitions that may apply in a bilateral monopoly setting do not necessarily carry over to

contract negotiations among multiple contracting parties. For instance, we find that the profit

implications for Apple, Microsoft, and a retailer such as CompUSA, of reports that “the newest

upgrade of the MacOS fixes all known bugs in the operating system” qualitatively differ from

the profit implications of reports that “more software is available for the MacOS than previously

thought.” Since the information in both examples is positive about the MacOS, we find, not

surprisingly, that both types of information are beneficial to Apple (maker of the MacOS).

However, one might also expect that in both examples the retailer will share in Apple’s gains—

since consumers’ overall valuations for the MacOS have increased—and that Microsoft (Apple’s

competitor) will lose—since the increase in consumers’ valuations for the MacOS might cause

some consumers to shift from Microsoft to Apple. It turns out that this conjecture is incorrect.

We show that the information in the first example is harmful for the retailer and beneficial

for Microsoft, while the information in the second example has the opposite effect in that it is

beneficial for the retailer and harmful for Microsoft.

The key distinction in these two examples has to do with whether the information is of

more relevance to Apple’s core consumers (consumers who are more interested in an operating

system’s ease of use) or non-core consumers (consumers who are more interested in the avail-

ability of compatible application software). Rival manufacturers always benefit from positive

information that is more relevant to its rivals’ core consumers while retailers always benefit

from positive information that is more relevant to a manufacturer’s non-core consumers.

In our taxonomy of information types, we also consider the profit implications for channel

members of information that is of equal relevance to all consumers (e.g., students who have

Apple computers tend to have higher SAT scores), and information that pertains to the product

category as a whole (e.g., SAT scores are positively correlated with home use of computers).

Our analysis is relevant to managers in that it helps to clarify key factors that determine

the contract terms for which each member of the channel can negotiate, and it suggests when

managers will be able to renegotiate for better contract terms in response to changed demand

conditions. In particular, our results can help identify when advertising, third-party informa-

tion, or product innovations shift demand conditions in favor of a specific channel member. In

addition, although we focus on the profit implications of different types of information, and

treat the information as exogenously supplied by third-parties, our analysis can be easily ex-

tended to consider information provision by channel members. If we assume that firms will

want to provide information from which they gain, and withhold information (if possible) from

which they lose, then our analysis has additional managerial relevance. For example, our analy-

sis suggests that Apple but not Microsoft should be interested in informing consumers that “the

2

Page 5: Bargaining, Third-Party Information and the Division …haas.berkeley.edu/Courses/Spring2000/BA269D/bargainm.pdfBargaining, Third-Party Information and the Division of Profit in the

widespread adoption of the Java programming language is accelerating software development

and leading to more software across all operating system platforms,” and that Microsoft but

not Apple should inform consumers that “the main supplier of color LCD displays for note-

book consumers has dramatically improved its screens’ contrast, thus improving the legibility

and usability of both MacOS and Windows 95 based notebooks.” In both cases, it is in the

interests of computer retailers such as CompUSA to assist in the information dissemination

(the information pertains to the category, for which –as we will show– the retailers are primary

beneficiaries).

We contribute to the marketing literature in three areas. First, we introduce a bargaining

framework between two manufacturers and a retailer and show how channel profits depend on

consumer preferences at a point in time. The framework also allows us to analyze how these

profits are likely to change over time in response to changes in external demand conditions.

Iyer and Villas-Boas (1998) consider bargaining between a single manufacturer and retailer in

a bilateral monopoly setting, but this abstracts from the externalities which are present when

manufacturers compete in a common channel. These externalities are the focus of our paper.

O’Brien and Shaffer (1994) consider bargaining in a game between a single manufacturer and

multiple retailers. Their focus is on the implications of the Robinson-Patman Act for the

observability of contracts among retailers. In our paper, observability is not an issue, since

the contracts are negotiated by the same retailer. Marx and Shaffer (1999) consider the use of

below-cost pricing as a means of rent-shifting in a bargaining game in which a common retailer

negotiates in sequence with each of two manufacturers. This type of rent-shifting is not possible

(and arguably, illegal) if, as in our setting, contracts are negotiated simultaneously.

Second, we derive the effect of different types of information/advertising on the division of

channel profits, thereby contributing to the literature on channel management (Jeuland and

Shugan, 1983; Mathewson and Winter, 1984; Moorthy, 1987; Shaffer, 1991a; Ingene and Perry,

1995; Chu and Messinger, 1997; Iyer, 1998; Ingene and Perry, 1999). There is a small marketing

literature which looks at the two manufacturer-one retailer model, in which a single retailer

carries carries the products of competing manufacturers (Choi, 1991; Lal, 1990; Agrawal, 1996;

Lal, Little, and Villas-Boas, 1996). All of this literature restricts attention to supply contracts

in which manufacturers specify wholesale prices only. There are also a number of papers that

extend the two manufacturer-one retailer model to allow manufacturers to specify two-part

tariffs (Lin, 1990; O’Brien and Shaffer, 1993, 1997; Gabrielsen, 1997; Gabrielsen and Sorgard,

1999). However, none of this literature allows for bargaining among the members of the channel.

Third, our results contribute to the literature on the effect of information on firms’ com-

petitive behavior, which considers whether firms should provide information to consumers

3

Page 6: Bargaining, Third-Party Information and the Division …haas.berkeley.edu/Courses/Spring2000/BA269D/bargainm.pdfBargaining, Third-Party Information and the Division of Profit in the

(Zettelmeyer 1997, Lynch and Ariely 1998). It extends this literature by examining the ef-

fect of information in the context of distribution channels and by considering different types of

information.

This paper proceeds as follows. Section 2 presents the model and derives the equilibrium di-

vision of profits. Section 3 looks at how different types of product information affect each firm’s

profit. It shows that which firms gain and which firms lose depends on whether the informa-

tion is more relevant to a firm’s core or non-core consumers. Section 4 extends the analysis to

category information. Section 5 discusses extensions of the model to downstream competition,

information provision, and non-information based changes in consumers’ valuations. Section 6

concludes. The proofs of all propositions can be found in the appendix.

2 Bargaining and the division of channel profits

2.1 Consumers and demand

Consider a spatial model of demand in which consumers are distributed uniformly with unit

mass along the line segment between 0 and 1 and purchase at most one unit of a product.

Following in the tradition of Hotelling (1929), the line segment can be thought of as representing

a single attribute of differentiation or, alternatively, a ratio of two attributes. In many of our

examples below, we will make use of the second interpretation.

There are two products, X and Y, which are located at the endpoints respectively. Con-

sumers located at 0 derive a gross utility Vx from consuming product X and Vy − δy from

consuming product Y. Consumers located at 1 derive a gross utility Vx − δx from consuming

product X and Vy from consuming product Y. In general, a consumer that is located at z ∈ [0, 1]

derives a gross utility Vx − zδx from the consumption of product X and Vy − (1− z)δy from the

consumption of product Y , where δx > 0 and δy > 0 are the rates at which utility decreases as

a consumer’s ideal point moves away from the locations of products X and Y. See Figure 1.

As is standard in the Hotelling model, in the absence of product Y, the downward sloping

line (left to right) represents the maximum price that can be charged for product X if a quantity

x of product X is to be sold and product Y is not sold. Thus, it is the inverse demand for

product X in the absence of product Y. We denote this as px(x) ≡ Vx−xδx, x ∈ [0, 1]. Similarly,

the downward sloping line (right to left) is the inverse demand for product Y in the absence of

product X. We denote this as py(y) ≡ Vy − yδy, y ∈ [0, 1].

We assume production costs are zero and consider both the case in which a monopolist would

want to cover the market (serve all consumers) even if it sold only one product (Vi ≥ 2δi), and

the case in which a monopolist would not want to cover the market if it sold only one product

4

Page 7: Bargaining, Third-Party Information and the Division …haas.berkeley.edu/Courses/Spring2000/BA269D/bargainm.pdfBargaining, Third-Party Information and the Division of Profit in the

0 1z

V≈ V¥

V≈-zδ≈V¥-(1-z)δ¥

Figure 1: Consumers’ valuations for products X and Y

(Vi < 2δi).2 We assume the market is always covered when both products are sold.

To solve our model it is useful first to derive the maximum profit a monopolist can earn by

selling only one product. If it sells only product X, the monopolist’s profit is px(x)x. Let pmx

and xm denote the price and quantity that maximize this profit and let Πx denote its maximized

value. Then pmx = Vx/2 and xm = Vx/2δx if the market is not covered (i.e., δx > Vx/2), and

pmx = Vx − δx and xm = 1 if the market is covered (i.e., δx ≤ Vx/2), yielding profit Πx ≡ pm

x xm.

In what follows, we refer to Πx as the monopoly profit of the retailer and firm X. That is,

if firm X produced product X, and the retailer distributed the product to consumers, and if

there were no double marginalization in the channel, then Πx would represent the amount of

profit to be allocated between the retailer and firm X (in the absence of product Y).

Similarly, a monopolist’s maximized profit if it sells only product Y is Πy ≡ pmy ym, where

pmy and ym are defined analogously to their counterparts when only product X is sold. In what

follows, we refer to Πy as the monopoly profit of the retailer and firm Y . Its interpretation is

analogous to that of Πx.

These profits are illustrated in Figure 2 for the case in which the two firms are symmetrically

differentiated, so that pmx = pm

y , and in which the market is covered (δi ≤ Vi/2).

In contrast, if a monopolist were to sell both products X and Y, then its profit is maximized

by choosing a quantity x of product X and a quantity y of product Y to solve

maxx,y

px(x)x + py(y)y such that x + y = 1, (1)

where we have assumed that products X and Y are substitutes in demand at the monopoly

2These conditions can be found by solving for when the marginal revenue of product X (Y ) is weakly positiveat x = 1 (y = 1)in the case of full coverage, and when it is negative in the case of incomplete coverage.

5

Page 8: Bargaining, Third-Party Information and the Division …haas.berkeley.edu/Courses/Spring2000/BA269D/bargainm.pdfBargaining, Third-Party Information and the Division of Profit in the

0 1

V≈

0 1

p≈Â

p¥Â

X Y X Y

Π≈: Monopoly profit ofX and the retailer

Π¥: Monopoly profit ofY and the retailer

Figure 2: Monopoly profits

prices, i.e., the monopolist serves all consumers located in [0, 1]. Solving yields

pmmx = Vx − xmmδx, pmm

y = Vy − (1− xmm)δy, and xmm = (2δy + Vx − Vy)/(2(δx + δy)). (2)

At the quantities that maximize the monopolist’s profit, prices are (pmmx , pmm

y ), consumers

located in [0, xmm) purchase product X, and consumers located in [xmm, 1] purchase product

Y. Let Πxy ≡ pmmx xmm + pmm

y (1 − xmm) denote the monopoly profit when both products X

and Y are sold. This profit is illustrated in Figure 3 for the symmetric case (pmmx = pmm

y ).

V≈ V¥

0 1

pì¥pì≈

X Y

Π≈¥: Total channel profit

Figure 3: Total channel profit

We will refer to Πxy as the total channel profit. That is, if firm X produced product X, firm

Y produced product Y, and the retailer distributed both products to consumers, and if there

were no double marginalization anywhere in the channel, then Πxy would represent the amount

of profit to be allocated among the retailer, firm X, and firm Y . The following proposition

gives the relationship between this profit and the monopoly profit of the retailer with each firm.

Proposition 1 Πxy is less than the sum of the two monopoly profits when only one product is

6

Page 9: Bargaining, Third-Party Information and the Division …haas.berkeley.edu/Courses/Spring2000/BA269D/bargainm.pdfBargaining, Third-Party Information and the Division of Profit in the

sold, but greater than the individual monopoly profit when only one product is sold:

Πx + Πy > Πxy ≥ max{Πx,Πy}.

Proof: The first inequality holds since some substitution between products is assumed (if,

on the other hand, products are independent, then Πxy = Πx + Πy). The second inequality

holds by the definition of Πxy (a monopolist that can sell both products can always mimic the

price and quantity decisions of a monopolist constrained to sell only one product). The second

inequality holds with equality if the products are perfect substitutes, i.e., if one of the products

has no value added. This would be the case, for instance, if Vx = Vy and δi = 0, i ∈ [x, y].

Q.E.D.

Proposition 1 establishes that each product can potentially contribute to total channel

profit. In what follows, we refer to Πxy − Πy as the incremental contribution of product X

to total channel profit, and to Πxy − Πx as the incremental contribution of product Y to

total channel profit. In the next subsection, we will show that, under general conditions, each

manufacturer’s profit in a game between two manufacturers and a common retailer will depend

on its bargaining power and on its product’s incremental contribution to total channel profit.

2.2 Firms and bargaining

We now ‘break up’ the monopolist and consider a game between two manufacturers and a

common retailer. We assume that the retailer is a monopolist.3 The game consists of two

stages. In the first stage, the retailer negotiates contract terms with each manufacturer. In the

second stage, the retailer chooses how much to buy of products X and Y , and then resells these

quantities to consumers. We assume the firms are profit-maximizers, and that each consumer

maximizes his/her consumer surplus.

In the first stage we assume the retailer negotiates with each manufacturer on both the

marginal price of its product and on how the surplus is to be divided. In particular, we assume

they bargain over a wholesale price wi and fixed fee Fi, i = x, y. Thus, if Tx and Ty denote the

contracts negotiated by the retailer with firms X and Y respectively, then

Tx(x | wx, Fx) =

wxx + Fx, x > 0

0, x = 0and Ty(y | wy, Fy) =

wyy + Fy, y > 0

0, y = 0.

Since production costs are assumed to be zero, if the retailer buys quantity x of product X,

3We do not believe that our results depend on this assumption. See page 23 for a discussion.

7

Page 10: Bargaining, Third-Party Information and the Division …haas.berkeley.edu/Courses/Spring2000/BA269D/bargainm.pdfBargaining, Third-Party Information and the Division of Profit in the

firm X’s profit is Tx(x | wx, Fx). If the retailer buys quantity y of product Y, firm Y ’s profit is

Ty(y | wy, Fy). The retailer’s profit is px(x)x + py(y)y − Tx(x | wx, Fx) − Ty(y | wy, Fy), where

x + y ≤ 1 to reflect the assumption that consumers are distributed with unit mass.

Regarding how the bargaining outcomes are determined, we make minimal assumptions,

assuming only that bargaining between the retailer and firm i results in maximization of the

two players’ joint profit, taking as given the retailer’s contract with firm j, j = i, and that each

firm earns its disagreement payoff (what it would earn if negotiations fail) plus a share of the

incremental gains from trade (the joint profit of the retailer and firm i when they trade minus

their joint profit when they do not trade), with proportion λi ∈ [0, 1] going to firm i.

These assumptions on the bargaining outcomes are consistent with the commonly used bar-

gaining solutions (e.g., Nash bargaining, Rubinstein-alternating-offers-bargaining, egalitarian

bargaining, and Kalai-Smorodinsky bargaining) which require that players maximize bilateral

joint profits and divide the incremental gains from trade.4 The assumptions are also consistent

with the contract equilibrium concept of Cremer and Riordan (1987) and O’Brien and Shaffer

(1992), and the pairwise-proof equilibrium in McAfee and Schwartz (1994). Intuitively, our

assumptions require that the bargaining outcomes be immune to bilateral recontracting.5

Our assumption of a fixed division of the incremental gains from trade admits several

interpretations. For example, if the manufacturers make take-it or leave-it offers to the retailer,

then λi = 1. If the retailer makes take-it or leave-it offers to the manufacturers, then λi = 0.

In the bargaining game, the maximum payoffs for the players above their disagreement points

are the same, so the Nash bargaining solution and Kalai-Smorodinsky bargaining solution both

divide the gains from trade equally, and, by definition, the egalitarian bargaining solution

divides the gains from trade equally. Thus, the Nash bargaining solution, the egalitarian

bargaining solution, and the Kalai-Smorodinsky bargaining solution all imply λi = 1/2.

2.2.1 Equilibrium

We solve for the equilibrium strategies of the retailer and firms X and Y by working backwards,

taking our assumptions about the outcome of negotiations as given.6 Thus, the retailer’s profit-

maximizing choices in the second stage depend on the wholesale prices and fixed fees that were

negotiated in the first stage. If the retailer is indifferent between selling a positive amount of

a product and selling zero, we assume the retailer will sell the positive amount.

4See the seminal works of Nash (1950), Kalai and Smorodinsky (1975), and Rubinstein (1982).5This implicitly assumes that if a profitable bilateral deviation were to exist, the two players would want to

recontract. See McAfee and Schwartz (1994).6Our solution concept corresponds to subgame perfection in that equilibrium behavior in the first stage is

not supported by non-credible threats in the second stage.

8

Page 11: Bargaining, Third-Party Information and the Division …haas.berkeley.edu/Courses/Spring2000/BA269D/bargainm.pdfBargaining, Third-Party Information and the Division of Profit in the

Stage two: Conditional on the bargaining outcomes, the retailer takes the contracts with the

two manufacturers, Tx and Ty, as given and chooses x and y to solve

maxx,y≥0

px(x)x + py(y)y − Tx(x | wx, Fx) − Ty(y | wy, Fy) such that x + y ≤ 1. (3)

Since the retailer’s revenue, px(x)x + py(y)y, is strictly concave and bounded, the maximizers

in (3) exist (assuming wi ≥ 0) and are uniquely defined when they are both positive. Let

x∗∗(Tx, Ty) and y∗∗(Tx, Ty) denote these quantities. Two stars denote the equilibrium quantities

when contracts are in place with both manufacturers.

We must also consider the possibility (which doesn’t happen in equilibrium) that negotia-

tions with one of the manufacturers may have failed in the first stage. In this case, if bargaining

with firm Y breaks down, the retailer chooses x to solve

maxx

px(x)x − Tx(x | wx, Fx) such that x ∈ [0, 1], (4)

and if bargaining with firm X breaks down, the retailer chooses y to solve

maxy

py(y)y − Ty(y | wy, Fy) such that y ∈ [0, 1]. (5)

Define x∗(Tx) and y∗(Ty) to be the maximizers of (4) and (5) respectively. Since px(x)x and

py(y)y are strictly concave and bounded, if wi ≥ 0, these maximizers exist and are unique. One

star denotes the equilibrium quantities when contracts are in place with one manufacturer.

Stage one: In stage one, the retailer bargains with each firm simultaneously. In bargaining

with firm X over contract Tx, the retailer and firm X take Ty and the retailer’s equilibrium

behavior in stage two as given and choose wx to maximize their joint profit,

maxwx

px(x∗∗)x∗∗ + py(y∗∗)y∗∗ − Ty(y∗∗ | wy, Fy), (6)

and Fx to divide the incremental gains from trade so that each earns as profit its disagreement

payoff (what it could earn if negotiations failed) plus a share of the gains from trade, with

proportion λx going to firm X. Thus, Fx is chosen so that firm X’s profit is

λx (px(x∗∗)x∗∗ + py(y∗∗)y∗∗ − Ty(y∗∗ | wy, Fy) − (py(y∗)y∗ − Ty(y∗ | wy, Fy))) , (7)

where the first set of terms on the right side of (7) is the retailer’s joint profit with firm X and

9

Page 12: Bargaining, Third-Party Information and the Division …haas.berkeley.edu/Courses/Spring2000/BA269D/bargainm.pdfBargaining, Third-Party Information and the Division of Profit in the

the second set of terms, py(y∗)y∗ − Ty(y∗ | wy, Fy), is the retailer’s disagreement payoff.

In bargaining with firm Y over contract Ty, the retailer and firm Y take Tx and the retailer’s

equilibrium behavior in stage two as given and choose wy to maximize their joint profit,

maxwy

px(x∗∗)x∗∗ + py(y∗∗)y∗∗ − Tx(x∗∗ | wx, Fx), (8)

and Fy to divide the incremental gains from trade with proportion λy going to firm Y . Thus,

Fy is chosen so that firm Y ’s profit is

λy (px(x∗∗)x∗∗ + py(y∗∗)y∗∗ − Tx(x∗∗ | wx, Fx) − (px(x∗)x∗ − Tx(x∗ | wx, Fx))) , (9)

where the first set of terms on the right side of (9) is the retailer’s joint profit with firm Y and

the second set of terms, px(x∗)x∗ − Tx(x∗ | wx, Fx), is the retailer’s disagreement payoff.

2.3 Solution and Discussion

Given our assumptions, the maximizers of (6) and (8) exist and are uniquely defined. Substi-

tuting the equilibrium wx, wy into (7) and (9) and solving yields the following proposition.

Proposition 2 There exists a unique equilibrium to the bargaining game. In this equilibrium,

the negotiated contracts, T ex and T e

y , induce x∗∗(T ex , T e

y ) = xmm and y∗∗(T ex , T e

y ) = ymm. If πx,

πy, and πr denote firm X, firm Y, and the retailer’s equilibrium profit, then,

πx = λx (Πxy − Πy)

πy = λy (Πxy − Πx)

πr = Πxy − πx − πy.

The first thing to notice about the bargaining equilibrium is that the retailer’s quantity

choices in equilibrium are the same quantities that a fully integrated monopolist would choose

to maximize total channel profit. This implies that the bargaining in stage one proceeds in

a manner that eliminates any double marginalization. The reason is that the contracts are

sufficiently general to allow efficiency considerations in the sense of joint profit maximization

to be separated from how the surplus is divided. Thus, Proposition 2 extends the results in

Moorthy (1987). Moorthy showed that with take-it or leave-it offers, a two-part tariff contract

was sufficient to eliminate double marginalization in a bilateral monopoly setting. Proposition

2 generalizes this to the case of two manufacturers that sell through a common retailer, and to

a bargaining framework that subsumes as a special case take-it or leave-it contract offers.

10

Page 13: Bargaining, Third-Party Information and the Division …haas.berkeley.edu/Courses/Spring2000/BA269D/bargainm.pdfBargaining, Third-Party Information and the Division of Profit in the

The second thing to notice is that the total profit to be divided among channel members

is Πxy (this is a consequence of the retailer’s quantity choices being efficient). Of this profit,

firm i earns λi times the difference between total channel profit and the monopoly profit of the

retailer and its rival. Using Proposition 1, this means that firm i’s profit is strictly positive

in equilibrium, unless it has zero bargaining power (λi = 0) or unless products X and Y are

perfect substitutes. Intuitively, conditional on its bargaining power, each firm captures what is

unique about its product. If products X and Y are undifferentiated, the retailer earns Πxy and

each manufacturer earns zero. As the products become more differentiated (less substitutable),

each manufacturer’s profit increases and the retailer’s profit decreases.

The third thing to notice, however, is that the two manufacturers cannot extract everything

from the retailer no matter how differentiated their products become, as long as they are not

independent. With any amount of substitution, Propositions 1 and 2 imply that the retailer

earns positive profit—even if λx = λy = 1 (i.e., even if it has no bargaining power). See Figures

2 and 3 for a graphical depiction of the components of each firm’s profit in the case of full

market coverage and symmetry.

The bargaining parameter λi admits several interpretations. For example, if the manu-

facturers make take-it or leave-it offers to the retailer, then λx = λy = 1. In this case, each

manufacturer earns exactly its product’s incremental contribution to total channel profit:

πx = Πxy − Πy, πy = Πxy − Πx, πr = Πx + Πy − Πxy.

Interestingly, the retailer’s profit in this case, for a given Πx, Πy, is decreasing in total channel

profit. If the retailer makes take-it-or-leave-it offers to the manufacturers, then λx = λy = 0.

In this case, the retailer captures the entire channel profit and each manufacturer earns zero:

πx = 0, πy = 0, πr = Πxy.

Lastly, if the retailer and firm i share equally in the gains from trade, then λx = λy = 1/2.

This is the case, for instance, in a simultaneous Nash bargaining game. In this case, we have:

πx =12

(Πxy − Πy) , πy =12

(Πxy − Πx) , πr =12

(Πx + Πy) .

The interesting thing about this case is that, for a given Πx, Πy, the retailer is indifferent to

changes in total channel profit, since these changes accrue solely to the manufacturers.

Proposition 2 thus encompasses a wide variety of bargaining outcomes. It holds for any

distribution of bargaining power, symmetric or asymmetric. It also holds for any degree of

substitution between products X and Y and any amount of demand asymmetry subject to a

11

Page 14: Bargaining, Third-Party Information and the Division …haas.berkeley.edu/Courses/Spring2000/BA269D/bargainm.pdfBargaining, Third-Party Information and the Division of Profit in the

monopolist selling both products in equilibrium. But despite these different scenarios, there is

one important commonality; the negotiations between a retailer and one manufacturer cannot

be determined in isolation from the negotiations between that retailer and competing manu-

facturers. To see this, suppose firm X and the retailer were to negotiate their contract as if

product Y were not around, and suppose further that they were to split their joint profit with

proportion λx going to firm X. Then, firm X would earn profit λxΠx. In contrast, we know

from Proposition 2 that firm X earns λx (Πxy − Πy). Comparing the difference, we have

λxΠx − λx (Πxy − Πy) = λx (Πx + Πy − Πxy) ,

which, if λx > 0, is strictly positive from Proposition 1. This implies that while firm X is better

off bargaining in isolation, the retailer is not, and in fact the retailer would strictly lose if it did

so. This suggests that important externalities are present whenever a retailer sells the products

of competing manufacturers. In equilibrium, the bargaining outcome between a manufacturer

and retailer such as Procter and Gamble and Walmart cannot be separated from the bargaining

outcome between Walmart and a competing manufacturer such as Colgate-Palmolive. Each

manufacturer’s profits depend not just on how well its own product is selling, but also on how

well its competitor’s product is selling and on how well it would sell if the retailer were to drop

its product. Thus, our results imply that a thorough understanding of these relationships is

critical for understanding how profit is allocated in the channel.

3 Product Information and the division of channel profits

In the next two sections, we consider how the bargaining outcome in Proposition 2 is affected

as market conditions change over time. In particular, we focus on changes in external demand

conditions that are induced by third-party sources of information of the kind typically found

on the Internet and other media. In section 5, we consider how the model can be extended to

include informative and persuasive advertising by the channel members themselves.

Our main finding is that when demand conditions change over time, the type of information

that induces the change (whether it is product-specific or relates to the whole category, and

whether it is of equal relevance to all consumers or affects some consumer groups more than

others) is critical in understanding who gains and who loses at the time of recontracting. Thus,

we distinguish between information that is equally relevant to all consumers and information

that affects consumers unequally. In the latter case, we distinguish between information that

is more relevant to firm X’s core consumers and information that is more relevant to firm X’s

non-core consumers. Formally, under our assumption that firm X is located at 0, we define

12

Page 15: Bargaining, Third-Party Information and the Division …haas.berkeley.edu/Courses/Spring2000/BA269D/bargainm.pdfBargaining, Third-Party Information and the Division of Profit in the

firm X’s core consumers as those consumers who are located between 0 and 1/2, and we define

firm X’s non-core consumers as those consumers who are located between 1/2 and 1.7

3.1 Information Types

We conceptualize information as having three components to its content, namely (1) the prod-

ucts to which the information pertains, (2) the consumers to whom the information is relevant,

and (3) the effect that the information has on these consumers’ valuations. The first com-

ponent captures whether the information affects consumers’ valuations for all products in the

category, or just one product. We call the former type category information and the latter

type product information. The second component captures whether the information affects all

consumers’ valuations equally or whether there are some groups of consumers whose valuations

are more affected than others, i.e., whether the information is more relevant to firm X’s core

consumers or non-core consumers. The third component captures whether consumers’ gross

utilities for the product(s) to which the information pertains increases or decreases. We say

that the information is positive if valuations increase and negative if valuations decrease.

Our spatial model of demand captures each of these information components. Suppose

that information pertains to product X. If the information primarily affects consumers who

are located close to X (product X’s core consumers), we rotate the curve denoting consumers’

valuations of product X around its intersection with the vertical line at 1, thereby inducing a

larger change in utility for those consumers located closer to 0 (mathematically this corresponds

to an equal change in Vx and δx). If the information primarily affects consumers located far

from X (product X’s non-core consumers), we rotate the curve denoting consumers’ valuations

of product X around its intersection with the vertical line at 0, thereby inducing a larger

change in utility for those consumers located far from 0 (this corresponds to a change ∆δx). If

the information affects all consumers equally, we combine the two rotations; this is equivalent

to a parallel shift of all consumers’ valuations of product X. For positive information, we

shift/rotate consumers’ valuations for the respective product upward. For negative information,

we shift/rotate consumers’ valuations for the respective product downward.

3.2 Illustrative example

An example illustrates how we decompose and model different types of information. Suppose

that consumers’ preferences with respect to operating systems are horizontally differentiated.

7We define things relative to firm X’s perspective to avoid confusion. Note that whether a consumer is firmX’s core consumer or firm X’s non-core consumer does not imply anything about which product that consumerwill actually purchase. The core vs. non-core distinction is a function only of a consumer’s location in productspace, whereas the same consumer’s actual purchase decision is a function, in addition, of the prices of each firm.

13

Page 16: Bargaining, Third-Party Information and the Division …haas.berkeley.edu/Courses/Spring2000/BA269D/bargainm.pdfBargaining, Third-Party Information and the Division of Profit in the

Consumers located at 0 care primarily about the usability of the operating system, consumers

located at 1 care primarily about the availability of application software. A consumer located

at 1/2 cares equally about usability and the availability of application software. Assume that

Apple computer’s MacOS is located at 0 and Microsoft’s Windows 95 is located at 1.

Now suppose consumers learn that more software is available for the MacOS than they had

previously thought. We would describe this type of information as positive product information

(the information pertains only to the MacOS and consumers’ utilities increase in the availability

of software) that is of more relevance to Apple’s non-core consumers (the consumers who

care the most about the availability of application software). Figure 4 depicts the change in

consumers’ valuations of product X. The dashed line Vx − zδx represents consumers’ valuations

for the MacOS before learning the information. After learning the information, their new,

higher valuations are given by the solid line Vx − z(δx + ∆δx), where ∆δx < 0.

0 1X YMacOS

core consumersWindows 95

core consumers

Apple Microsoft

Vx

∆δx

Figure 4: Example of positive information of relevance to X’s non-core consumers

Suppose consumers learn instead that the newest upgrade of the MacOS fixes all known

bugs in the operating system, thus increasing stability and usability. We would describe this

type of information as positive product information that affects primarily the MacOS’s core

consumers (consumers who are more concerned about the availability of application software

will be less affected than those consumers who find the usability and hence stability of the

operating system relatively more important). See Figure 5. The dashed line Vx − zδx is now

replaced by the solid line Vx + ∆Vx − z(δx + ∆δx), where ∆δx = ∆Vx > 0.

Finally, suppose consumers learn that the SAT scores of children whose families own a

Macintosh are on average higher than the SAT scores of children without a Macintosh. We

would describe this type of information as positive product information about the MacOS that

affects all consumers equally (the study pertains both to the MacOS and the associated utility

increase is uncorrelated with usability or the availability of application software). See Figure 6.

The dashed line Vx − zδx is now replaced by the solid line Vx + ∆Vx − zδx, where ∆Vx > 0.

14

Page 17: Bargaining, Third-Party Information and the Division …haas.berkeley.edu/Courses/Spring2000/BA269D/bargainm.pdfBargaining, Third-Party Information and the Division of Profit in the

MacOScore consumers

Windows 95core consumers

Apple Microsoft

∆Vx

0 1X Y

Figure 5: Example of positive information of relevance to X’s core consumers

∆Vx

0 1X YMacOS

core consumersWindows 95

core consumers

Apple Microsoft

Figure 6: Example of positive information of equal relevance to all consumers

3.3 Core vs. non-core information

The three information examples appear to be very similar. Whether consumers learn that

more software is available for the MacOS than they had previously thought, whether they

learn that the newest upgrade of the MacOS fixes all known bugs in the operating system, or

whether they learn of the positive correlation between SAT scores and Macintosh ownership,

the information in each example is positive about the MacOS. Not surprisingly, we will show

that the information in all three examples increases Apple’s profits. It is less obvious, however,

what happens to the other channel members’ profits. Intuitively, one might expect that the

retailer would gain in all three examples (since consumers’ overall valuations have increased)

and that Microsoft would lose (since the increase in consumers’ valuations for the MacOS may

shift some customers from Microsoft to Apple). However, this intuition is incorrect.

The three examples are distinguished by the fact that the information in the first example

is more important to Microsoft’s customers, the information in the second example is more

important to Apple’s customers, and the information in the third example is equally relevant

15

Page 18: Bargaining, Third-Party Information and the Division …haas.berkeley.edu/Courses/Spring2000/BA269D/bargainm.pdfBargaining, Third-Party Information and the Division of Profit in the

to all consumers. This distinction has a dramatic effect on the division of channel profits. In

particular, we will show that the information in the first and third examples is beneficial for

the retailer and harmful for Microsoft while the information in the second example has the

opposite effect, it is beneficial for Microsoft and may be harmful for the retailer. This suggests

that, conditional on there being good news for Apple, Microsoft would prefer that the news

have more of an effect on Apple’s core consumers than on Apple’s non-core consumers.

To derive these results, we need to know how the information affects total channel profit

(∆Πxy) and how the information affects the monopoly profits of the retailer and each firm (∆Πx

and ∆Πy). Knowing these changes in profits, we can then use Proposition 2 to determine who

gains and who loses. For example, to analyze the impact on firm i’s profit it suffices to compute

∆Πxy − ∆Πj , i.e., the change in total channel profit minus the change in the monopoly profit

of the retailer and rival firm. We illustrate our results using a symmetric benchmark.

3.3.1 Product information of primary relevance to non-core consumers

We begin with information about product X that is of primary relevance to firm X’s non-

core consumers (see Figure 4 on page 14). To analyze the effect of this type of information,

note first that the retailer will increase its price on products X and Y (decrease its prices if

the information is negative) to reflect the increase in consumers’ valuations. This causes total

channel profit to increase and implies that ∆Πxy > 0. As for the effect of the information on Πx

and Πy, we can see from Figure 4 that the retailer’s monopoly profit with firm Y is unchanged

(Πy = 0), but its monopoly profit with firm X increases. In particular, ∆Πx = |∆δx| > 0.8

Since the retailer cannot raise equilibrium prices by |∆δx| without causing some consumers to

drop out of the market, ∆Πx > ∆Πxy. Thus, for positive information about product X that is

of primary relevance to firm X’s non-core consumers, we have ∆Πx > ∆Πxy > ∆Πy.

Proposition 3 Suppose consumers learn positive (negative) information about product X that

is of primary relevance to firm X’s non-core consumers. Then, firm X and the retailer’s profit

increases (decreases), and firm Y’s profit decreases (increases).

Firm X gains because it is the beneficiary of positive product information and because the

monopoly profit of the retailer and firm Y is unchanged. Thus, ∆πx = λx∆Πxy > 0. Firm

Y is not as fortunate. Although total channel profit increases, the increase in the retailer’s

monopoly profit with firm X is larger, implying that ∆πy = λy (∆Πxy − ∆Πx) < 0. As for the

retailer’s profit, there are two sources of change. Writing the change in the retailer’s profit as

∆πr = (1 − λx)∆Πxy − ∆πy, we see that the retailer stands to capture some of the increase

8We present the case in which δx ≤ Vx/2. For δx > Vx/2 the argument proceeds with ∆Πxy < ∆Πx < |∆δx|.

16

Page 19: Bargaining, Third-Party Information and the Division …haas.berkeley.edu/Courses/Spring2000/BA269D/bargainm.pdfBargaining, Third-Party Information and the Division of Profit in the

in total channel profit (unless λx = 1) and, in addition, there is a redistribution of profit

away from firm Y reflecting the retailer’s enhanced bargaining power. As a result, the retailer

may experience a larger profit increase than firm X. This would be the case, for example, if

λx = 1/2, so that firm X and the retailer divide equally the increase in channel profit.

Compare this to the case of positive information about product X that is of equal relevance

to all consumers (see Figure 6 on page 15). In this case, a similar result and intuition applies.

Proposition 4 Suppose consumers learn positive (negative) information about product X that

is of equal relevance to all consumers. Then, firm X and the retailer’s profit increases (de-

creases), and firm Y’s profit decreases (increases).

This information leads to an increase in total channel profit (∆Πxy > 0) since the utility of

the marginal consumer has increased. However, the retailer cannot raise prices by ∆Vx without

causing some consumers to drop out of the market; consequently total channel profit increases

by less than ∆Vx. If the retailer were selling only product X, profit would rise by ∆Vx.9 If

the retailer were selling only product Y , profit would be unchanged. Thus, as in the previous

example, we have ∆Πx > ∆Πxy > ∆Πy, implying that the qualitative results are the same.

3.3.2 Product information of primary relevance to core consumers

The previous two examples accord with most people’s intuition, which suggests that firm X

gains because the information is positive about its own product, the retailer gains because

it stands to gain from increases in consumers’ valuations (it can adjust its pricing to reflect

the higher valuations), and firm Y loses since the information will cause some consumers to

switch to product X. However, our bargaining equilibrium suggests that in a world of multi-

party contracting, a critical component of the change in each firm’s profit is the change in the

retailer’s disagreement payoff. If this increases by less than the increase in total channel profit,

then a firm can be better off even if the information is about its rival’s product.

This is the case for positive information about product X that is of primary relevance to

firm X’s core consumers (see Figure 5 on page 15). Here the retailer’s monopoly profit with

each manufacturer is unchanged, ∆Πx = ∆Πy = 0, but ∆Πxy > 0.10

Proposition 5 Suppose consumers learn positive (negative) information about product X that

is of primary relevance to firm X’s core consumers. Then, firm X and Y’s profit increases

(decreases), and the change in the retailer’s profit is ∆π∗r = (1 − λx − λy)∆Πxy.

9We present the case in which δx ≤ Vx/2. For δx > Vx/2 the argument proceeds with ∆Πxy < ∆Πx < ∆δx.10We present the case in which δx ≤ Vx/2. For δx > Vx/2, ∆Πx > 0, ∆Πy = 0, and the retailer’s profit is

∆π∗r = (1 − λx − λy)∆Πxy + λy∆Πx. The proposition holds generally for firm X and firm Y ’s profit.

17

Page 20: Bargaining, Third-Party Information and the Division …haas.berkeley.edu/Courses/Spring2000/BA269D/bargainm.pdfBargaining, Third-Party Information and the Division of Profit in the

With this type of information, the retailer’s profit increases only if it captures some of the

increase in total channel profit. If the retailer can make take-it or leave-it offers ( λx = λy = 0),

then ∆πr = ∆Πxy and the retailer clearly gains. If the retailer splits the gains from trade

with each firm (λx = λy = 1/2), then ∆πr = 0 and the retailer’s profit is unchanged, while

if the manufacturers can make take-it or leave-it offers (λx = λy = 1), then ∆πr = −∆Πxy

and the retailer loses. At first, it may seem surprising that both manufacturers can gain at the

expense of the retailer. To understand it, notice that since the marginal consumers’ valuation

for product X increases when the retailer sells both products, the retailer can profitably raise

prices, thus increasing total channel profit. However, the retailer cannot raise prices if it only

sells one product, since the marginal consumer’s valuation is then unchanged. This means

that total channel profit increases only if the retailer sells both products and, as a result, both

manufacturers are in a position to bargain for better contract terms.

Another way of thinking about why both manufacturers can benefit from information that

is or primary relevance to firm X’s core consumers is that the information tends to make the

products less substitutable, which is generally good for the manufacturers and bad for the

retailer. However, depending on its bargaining power, the retailer may be able to capture some

of the resulting increase in channel profit, and thus it is possible that all three firms may gain.

3.4 Discussion

We have shown that positive information about a rival’s product need not be harmful to a firm

if the information is of primary relevance to the rival’s core consumers.11 For example, Apple

may benefit if consumers learn of more software titles for Windows 95 because CompUSA can

only take advantage of the increase in consumers’ valuations for Microsoft if it also sells Apple

computers. In contrast, Apple would be harmed by information about increased stability in the

release of Windows 98. Such information would decrease the retailer’s dependence on Apple to

serve consumers who care primarily about the ease of use of an operating system.

We have also shown that a retailer with little bargaining power can lose from information

that increases consumers’ valuations for one of its products, even if it increases total channel

profit. CompUSA, for example, need not benefit if consumers learn of more software titles for

Windows 95. In contrast, CompUSA would benefit if consumers learn of more software for the

MacOS since this information is of primary relevance to Apple’s non-core consumers. Intu-

itively, the channel members’ incentives are intertwined in a multi-product price discrimination

that better segments consumers and allows all three firms to enjoy positive profits. How this

11The analogue to this is that negative information about a rival’s product need not be beneficial to a manu-facturer if the information is of primary relevance to the rival’s core consumers.

18

Page 21: Bargaining, Third-Party Information and the Division …haas.berkeley.edu/Courses/Spring2000/BA269D/bargainm.pdfBargaining, Third-Party Information and the Division of Profit in the

profit is allocated among the channel members depends in part on the role each party plays

in segmenting the market. In the example of positive information about product X that is

of relevance to firm X’s core consumers, the retailer is unable to use the information to fur-

ther increase channel profit unless it sells both manufacturers’ products. This is what enables

manufacturer Y to have the upper hand in negotiations with the retailer.

The distinction between core and non-core information thus has a dramatic effect on the

division of profit among the members of a channel. Positive non-core information about product

X hurts manufacturer Y and helps the retailer while positive core information about product

X has the opposite effect in that it benefits manufacturer Y and can hurt the retailer.

4 Category information and the division of channel profits

The distinction between core and non-core information is also important in understanding

how category information (i.e, information that is relevant to all products in the category)

affects channel profits. Suppose consumers learn that the widespread adoption of the Java

programming language is accelerating software development and leading to more software across

all operating system platforms. Who gains and who loses? Compare this with a second example

in which consumers learn that the main supplier of color LCD displays for notebook computers

has dramatically improved its screens’ contrast, thus improving the legibility and usability of

both MacOS and Windows 95 based notebooks. Do the same firm/s gain? Do the same firm/s

lose? In both examples, the information is positive about all products in the category. Notice,

however, that the information in the first example is more important to Microsoft’s customers,

while the information in the second example is more important to Apple’s customers.

Since each manufacturer always gains from positive product information about its own

product, one might think that both manufacturers would stand to gain from these examples

and that, if anyone loses, it would be the retailer. Alternatively, one might think that Microsoft

would be better off in the example with more software and that Apple would be better off in

the example with improved LCD displays. Instead, the opposite is true. In many cases,

Apple’s profit decreases and Microsoft’s profit increases when the information is more important

to Apples’ customers and vice versa when the information is more important to Microsoft’s

customers. The retailer is the only sure winner. It’s profit always increases in these examples.

4.1 Category information: The core vs. non-core distinction

We model the effect of category information that is more relevant to firm X’s core consumers

as a rotation of both products’ consumers’ valuation curves around their intersections with the

vertical line at 1 (this corresponds to shifting consumers’ valuations of product X and product

19

Page 22: Bargaining, Third-Party Information and the Division …haas.berkeley.edu/Courses/Spring2000/BA269D/bargainm.pdfBargaining, Third-Party Information and the Division of Profit in the

Y such that the new curves become Vx + ∆Vx − z(δx + ∆δx) and Vy − z(δy + ∆δy), where

∆δy < 0 and ∆Vx = ∆δx = −∆δy. See Figure 7 for the case in which δi ≤ Vi/2.12

0 1X Y

∆Π¥>0∆Π≈=0

Figure 7: Category Information of Primary Relevance to Firm X’s Core Consumers

Proposition 6 Suppose consumers learn positive (negative) category information that is of

primary relevance to firm X’s core consumers. Then firm Y and the retailer’s profit increases

(decreases) and firm X’s profit decreases (increases).

The price the retailer will charge when selling only product Y is determined by the marginal

consumer located at 0, i.e., the consumer who cares most about usability. This consumer is

the one whose valuation will rise most as a result of the new information, raising the value

to the retailer of selling only product Y by ∆Vx. Thus, ∆Πy = ∆Vx > 0. The prices the

retailer charges when it sells both products, however, must rise by less than ∆Vx, for otherwise

some consumers would drop out of the market. This implies that ∆πx = λx (∆Πxy − ∆Πy) < 0.

Firm Y gains from the increase in total channel profit and, since the information does not affect

the marginal consumer located at 1, ∆Πx = 0. This implies that ∆πy = λy (∆Πxy − ∆Πx) > 0.

The retailer’s profit can be written as ∆πr = (1 − λx − λy) ∆Πxy+λx∆Πy, which is positive

regardless of the distribution of bargaining power. If λx = λy = 1, then the retailer gains

solely from the redistribution of profit with firm X. Otherwise, the retailer both gains from a

redistribution of profit with firm X and captures some of the increase in total channel profit.

Since category information affects all products, the analysis of the core case is identical to

the analysis of the non-core case with only the names of firms X and Y interchanged.

12If Vi/2 < δi ≤ Vi/√

2 then the qualitative results remain unchanged. However, if δi > Vi/√

2, then whetherfirm X gains or loses depends on the size of the valuation changes (see the appendix). For large valuationchanges, the change in firm X’s profit is the same as in Proposition 6, but for small valuation changes, firm X’sprofit increases with positive information. The proposition holds generally for firm Y and the retailer’s profit.

20

Page 23: Bargaining, Third-Party Information and the Division …haas.berkeley.edu/Courses/Spring2000/BA269D/bargainm.pdfBargaining, Third-Party Information and the Division of Profit in the

Proposition 7 Suppose consumers learn positive (negative) category information that is of

primary relevance to firm X’s non-core consumers. Then firm X and the retailer’s profit

increases (decreases) and firm Y ’s profit decreases (increases).13

Propositions 6 and 7 imply that a manufacturer can lose from positive information about

its product if this information increases consumers’ valuations for the rival’s product as well.

Manufacturers gain if the category information is more relevant to their non-core consumers

and lose if the information is more relevant to their core consumers. This begs the question of

which firms would gain if the information is of equal relevance to all consumers.

4.2 Category information of equal relevance to all consumers

We model the effect of category information that is of equal relevance to all consumers as

an equal upward shift in consumers’ valuations for products X and Y (this corresponds to

shifting consumers’ valuations of product X and product Y such that the new curves become

Vx + ∆Vx − zδx and Vy + ∆Vy − (1− z)δy, where ∆Vx = ∆Vy > 0). See Figure 8. For example,

suppose consumers learn that the SAT scores of children who have a personal computer at

home are on average higher than the SAT scores of children without a personal computer. This

type of information affects all consumers equally; the study pertains both to the MacOS and to

Windows 95 and the associated utility increase is uncorrelated with usability or the availability

of application software. How does this affect the profit of each firm?

Proposition 8 Suppose consumers learn positive (negative) category information of equal rel-

evance to all consumers. In the case of full market coverage (δi ≤ Vi/2), firm X and Y’s profits

are unchanged and the retailer captures the entire increase (decrease) in channel profits. In the

case of incomplete coverage ( δi > Vi/2), all channel members’ profits increase (decrease).

0 1X Y

∆V

∆Π¥=∆V ∆Π≈=∆V

Figure 8: Change in consumers’ valuations for products X and Y

13The proposition reports the results for δi ≤ Vi/2. For the case of δi > Vi/2, see the previous footnote.

21

Page 24: Bargaining, Third-Party Information and the Division …haas.berkeley.edu/Courses/Spring2000/BA269D/bargainm.pdfBargaining, Third-Party Information and the Division of Profit in the

The increase in Vx and Vy shifts all consumers’ gross utilities from consuming products X

and Y upward by ∆V = ∆Vx = ∆Vy. Since the retailer will set prices in equilibrium to make

the marginal consumer just indifferent between purchasing and not, we know that both prices

will rise by ∆V , resulting in an increase in total channel profit of ∆Πxy = ∆V > 0.

If the retailer were to sell only one firm’s product, we distinguish between two cases, depend-

ing on whether a retailer would serve all consumers (δi ≤ Vi/2) or would leave some consumers

unserved (δi > Vi/2). If δi ≤ Vi/2, the retailer would raise prices by ∆V , leading to an identical

increase in its monopoly profit with manufacturer i, ∆Πx = ∆Πy = ∆V . Hence, neither man-

ufacturer can appropriate any of the added channel profit since ∆πi = λi(∆Πxy − ∆Πj) = 0,

i = j, and thus the retailer is the sole beneficiary of the shift in consumers’ valuations. On the

other hand, if δi > Vi/2, a price increase would only lead to increased revenues from a subset of

consumers. Thus, each firm would be able to appropriate some of the added channel profit.14

4.3 Discussion

The case in which information affects consumers unequally accentuates a key distinction be-

tween product and category information. In the case of product information about firm X, the

core vs. non-core distinction determines whether firm Y or the retailer gains, while in the case

of category information, the distinction determines which of the two manufacturers gain.

We have found that a manufacturer always benefits from positive category information

if such information primarily affects its rival’s core consumers. Apple, for example, benefits

from news about the release of new software development tools that cut development times and

increase the number of software titles on both operating systems. While such news also increases

consumers’ valuations for Windows 95, the information increases CompUSA’s dependence on

Apple to serve consumers whose primary concern is the ease of use of an operating system.

In both examples, the retailer gains irrespective of the consumer group for whom the infor-

mation is most important. The parallel to this in the case of product information is that the

manufacturer about whom the information is positive always benefits. However, for category

information, these examples show that positive information about a manufacturer’s product

does not imply that the manufacturer is better off. In fact, if the information is of equal

relevance to all consumers, for instance, it may be that the retailer is the sole beneficiary.

14Proposition 8 holds when the shift in consumers’ valuations is symmetric. However, if the new informationleads to an asymmetric increase in one of the products’ valuations, then it can be shown that one firm will gainand the other firm will lose despite the fact that the information is positive for all consumers.

22

Page 25: Bargaining, Third-Party Information and the Division …haas.berkeley.edu/Courses/Spring2000/BA269D/bargainm.pdfBargaining, Third-Party Information and the Division of Profit in the

5 Extensions and limitations

In this section, we consider extensions of the model to downstream competition, advertising and

consumer learning, information provision, and non-information based changes in consumers’

valuations.

5.1 Retail competition

We have analyzed a model in which two manufacturers sell through a common retailer, and

assumed that the retailer was a downstream monopolist. This allowed us to illustrate our

results using simple diagrams. It also captures a common feature in retailing; many retailers

carry a broad product line, often selling the products of competing manufacturers. Nonetheless

it is useful to consider how the model extends to the case of downstream competition.

In most of the literature in which two manufacturers compete, manufacturers are assumed to

sell through exclusive retailers (see McGuire and Staelin, 1983; Coughlan, 1985; Vickers, 1985;

Fershtman and Judd, 1987; Bonanno and Vickers, 1988; Lin, 1988; Moorthy, 1988; Coughlan

and Wernerfelt, 1989; Gal-Or, 1990, 1991; Shaffer, 1991b; Katz, 1991; and Gupta and Loulou,

1998). Recently this literature has been extended by Gabrielsen and Sorgard (1999).

Gabrielsen and Sorgard show that the division of profit that we identify, in which each

manufacturer earns its product’s incremental contribution to overall channel profit, is robust

to downstream competition. In their model, two manufacturers simultaneously choose their

retail distribution system. The manufacturers can choose to sell through a common retailer, or

the manufacturers can each choose to sell through an independent retailer. In the latter case,

each retailer can choose from which manufacturer to buy. In both subgames (the subgame

with the common retailer and the subgame with exclusive retailers) Gabrielsen and Sorgard

show that, with take-it or leave-it offers, each manufacturer earns its product’s incremental

contribution to overall channel profit. In particular in the subgame with exclusive retailers,

each manufacturer’s profit is equal to the difference between the overall channel profit and the

monopoly profit of the retailers with its rival if its product is not sold.

This is analogous to our findings in Proposition 2 for the case in which the manufacturers

have all the bargaining power, with one difference. In our model, overall channel profit is

maximized by the common retailer who internalizes all pricing decisions. In their model,

downstream competition prevents overall channel profit from being maximized. Thus, the

baseline of overall channel profit is different in the two models. Nonetheless, this difference is

not crucial for our comparative static results, since these results rely only on the changes in

each firm’s incremental contribution to channel profit, and not on the absolute level of total

channel profit. This suggests that our model can extended in an important way to allow for

23

Page 26: Bargaining, Third-Party Information and the Division …haas.berkeley.edu/Courses/Spring2000/BA269D/bargainm.pdfBargaining, Third-Party Information and the Division of Profit in the

downstream competition.

Ideally, however, we would want to have a model with multiple upstream and downstream

firms in which each retailer could sell the products of competing manufacturers. This turns

out to be a difficult problem to solve in theory, and thus is a limitation of the model.15

5.2 Provision of Information

We have assumed that information is supplied by third-parties. Our analysis can be extended,

however, to consider the provision of this information by the channel members themselves. If

one assumes that firms will provide information from which they gain, and withhold information

(if possible) from which they lose, then our analysis has additional managerial relevance.

Table 1 summarizes the profit implications of each of the information types we consider.

This leads to some generalizations about which channel members benefit from which type of

information and hence which members would have an incentive to provide the information.

Positive product information about product X affects ∆πx ∆πy ∆πr

primarily X’s core consumers + + − or +all consumers equally + − +primarily Y’s core consumers + − +

Positive category information affects (cases of less than full market coverage in parentheses)

primarily X’s core consumers − (+) + +all consumers equally 0 (+) 0 (+) +primarily Y’s core consumers + − (+) +

Table 1: Profit implications of information

• Manufacturers always benefit from positive product information about their own product.

Retailers always benefit from positive category information.

• A manufacturer benefits from positive product information about its rival’s product, and

from positive category information, if such information pertains to its rival’s core consumers.

• Retailers benefit from positive product information if such information pertains to all con-

sumers equally or to the product’s non-core consumers.

Thus, our analysis suggests that Apple but not Microsoft should be interested in informing

consumers that “the widespread adoption of the Java programming language is accelerating

15Chang (1992), Dobson and Waterson (1996), Lal and Villas-Boas (1996) and Lee and Staelin (1997) considera two manufacturer-two retailer model in which each retailer can sell both manufacturers’ products. However,these papers restrict attention to supply contracts in which manufacturers specify wholesale prices only.

24

Page 27: Bargaining, Third-Party Information and the Division …haas.berkeley.edu/Courses/Spring2000/BA269D/bargainm.pdfBargaining, Third-Party Information and the Division of Profit in the

software development and leading to more software across all operating system platforms,”

and that Microsoft but not Apple should inform consumers that “the main supplier of color

LCD displays for notebook consumers has dramatically improved its screens’ contrast, thus

improving the legibility and usability of both MacOS and Windows 95 based notebooks.” In

both cases, it is in the interest CompUSA to assist in the information dissemination (the

information pertains to the category, from which the retailers are primary beneficiaries).

There are some limitations, however, of extending the analysis to consider the incentives of

each firm to provide information. In particular, it is based on three implicit assumptions. First,

it implicitly assumes that there is an information asymmetry between consumers and firms with

regard to the information in question. This may be violated in practice since firms sometimes

have no control over whether information becomes known to consumers or not. Second, it

implicitly assumes that the information provided by firms is verifiable, so that it is credible

to consumers. In reality, however, not all information that is provided by firms is believed by

all consumers. This is more problematic if the information comes from an interested party,

such as a manufacturer or retailer, but less problematic if consumers receive the information

from a credible third-party. To the extent that information provided to consumers is not

credible, this would obviously mitigate the effects of the information. Third, it implicitly

assume that consumers do not draw conclusions about possible negative information from the

fact that a firm withholds information from them. If this assumption is relaxed, firms would

be pressured to release more information than they would ideally want to give (to avoid any

negative connotations). Hence, our results should be interpreted with these cautions in mind.

5.3 Advertising, information, and consumer learning

We have categorized information by its effect on consumers’ valuations. Since the model does

not rely on a specific process by which information influences consumers’ valuations, our re-

sults apply to any advertising message (e.g., persuasive or image) that may affect consumers’

valuations. For example, Apple computer’s “Think Different” advertising campaign is clearly

targeted towards consumers who derive some utility from being non-conformist in their choice

of computer platform. Although the “Think Different” advertising message has little or no in-

formational value for consumers, its intended purpose is nonetheless to increase the valuations

of consumers that like to “be different,” presumably Apple’s core consumers. If it does so, then

the effect of such an advertising message corresponds to that of positive product information

of primary relevance to Apple’s core consumers, which our analysis suggests may be good for

Microsoft and may be good or bad for retailers depending on their bargaining power.

While modelling information this way allows for many processes by which advertising can

25

Page 28: Bargaining, Third-Party Information and the Division …haas.berkeley.edu/Courses/Spring2000/BA269D/bargainm.pdfBargaining, Third-Party Information and the Division of Profit in the

affect consumers’ valuations, it raises the question of whether one can derive the shifts in

consumers’ valuations from first principles in a model in which information leads to consumer

learning. It turns out that this is straightforward to do using a model of Bayesian updating in

which consumers are uncertain about the true “quality” (maximum valuation) Vx, Vy and true

“fit” (rate at which utility decreases) δx, δy for products X and Y, respectively.16

5.4 Non-information based changes in consumers’ valuations

Evaluating the effect of information shocks on the division of profit in the distribution channel

is a two-step process. First, we modelled the effect of new information on consumers’ valuations

for all products in the market. Second, we performed comparative statics on each firm’s profit.

The separation of these two steps enhances the applicability of the model. Since the division of

channel profits depends on consumers’ valuations, we can analyze the effect on channel profits

of other variables that influence consumers’ valuations for products in the market. For example,

our framework can be used to analyze the profit implications of a new product introduction by

a firm. Or we can use the framework to assess any value added that a retailer might offer.

Consider the latter possibility. In our model, the retailer did not add any value of its

own. Suppose, instead, that retailers perform services that add to consumers’ valuations of

each manufacturer’s product an amount equal to ∆V .17 To analyze who gains and who loses,

one can think of the retailer’s value added as corresponding to the case of positive category

information that is equally relevant to all consumers. In this case, the retailer is the sole

beneficiary of the change in consumers’ valuations. This has some interesting implications.

It suggests that any value added by the retailer that is not biased between manufacturers’

products can be fully captured by the retailer. On the other hand, if the value added of the

retailer is product specific, say it benefits Apple’s products but not Microsoft’s products, then

we know from the analogous case of positive product information of equal relevance to all

consumers that the retailer and Apple will share in the gains but that Microsoft will lose. In

order to induce the appropriate level of retail service (from Apple’s perspective), therefore, it

may be necessary for Apple to engage in cooperative subsidies with the retailer. We leave these

topics for future research, but stress that a variety of such extensions can be handled within

our framework.

16We are happy to provide this analysis on request.17We thank Anne Coughlan for raising this issue.

26

Page 29: Bargaining, Third-Party Information and the Division …haas.berkeley.edu/Courses/Spring2000/BA269D/bargainm.pdfBargaining, Third-Party Information and the Division of Profit in the

6 Concluding remarks

This paper analyzes the factors that determine the outcome of manufacturer–retailer supply

contract negotiations. We show that each manufacturer’s profit is a function of its product’s

incremental contribution to total channel profit and its bargaining power vis-a-vis the retailer.

Since a product’s incremental contribution is defined as the difference between overall joint

profit and the monopoly profit of the retailer and rival firm, the bargaining outcome between

a retailer and a manufacturer depends critically on the prevailing demand conditions of all

products. This implies that the outcome of negotiations between a retailer and one manu-

facturer cannot be analyzed in isolation from the negotiations of that retailer with competing

manufacturers.

In addition, we analyze the effect on each firm’s profit of changes in demand conditions

that are induced by third-party information and advertising. We conceptualize information

as having three components to its content, namely (1) the products to which the information

pertains, (2) the consumers to whom the information is relevant, and (3) the effect that the

information has on these consumers’ valuations. Which firms gain and which lose as a result

of the information depends on the groups of consumers to whom the information is of primary

relevance. We find that while a manufacturer always benefits from positive information about

its own product, the core–non-core distinction determines whether the manufacturer’s rival or

the retailer gain. In the case of positive category information, this distinction determines which

of the two manufacturers gain, leaving the retailer always to benefit. Manufacturers benefit

from information that increases consumers’ valuations for their respective core product and

retailers benefit from information that increases non-core consumers’ valuations.

In addition to its managerial relevance, this paper makes two main theoretical contributions.

First, we introduce to the literature the equilibrium division of profits between competing

manufacturers selling through a common retailer using a bargaining framework. This framework

allows us to analyze the interaction between firms’ bargaining power and changes to external

demand. Second, we are the first to derive the effect of information provision on the division

of channel profits, thereby contributing to the literature on channel management. To this

purpose, we introduce a simple way of decomposing information and highlight the importance

of distinguishing which firms’ core consumers are the primary targets of information. These

results help understand the effect of advertising messages on different members of the channel

and thus predicts which firms have incentives to choose specific types of advertising content.

27

Page 30: Bargaining, Third-Party Information and the Division …haas.berkeley.edu/Courses/Spring2000/BA269D/bargainm.pdfBargaining, Third-Party Information and the Division of Profit in the

APPENDIX

Proof of Proposition 2

Let gy(Tx, Ty) denote the retailer’s incremental gains from trade with firm Y :

px(x∗∗)x∗∗ + py(y∗∗)y∗∗ − Tx(x∗∗ | wx, Fx) − (px(x∗)x∗ − Tx(x∗ | wx, Fx)) . (A-1)

Then, Fy is chosen so that firm Y ’s profit is equal to λygy(Tx, Ty).

Let gx(Tx, Ty) denote the retailer’s incremental gains from trade with firm X:

px(x∗∗)x∗∗ + py(y∗∗)y∗∗ − Ty(y∗∗ | wy, Fy) − (py(y∗)y∗ − Ty(y∗ | wy, Fy)) . (A-2)

Then, Fx is chosen so that firm X’s profit is equal to λxgx(Tx, Ty).

Lemma 1 The unique equilibrium T ey has wy = 0 and Fy(wx) ≡ λygy(Tx, (0, 0)) > 0.

Proof. Since Fy(wx) is less than or equal to the incremental gains from trade between the

retailer and firm Y, an increase in the fixed fee from zero to Fy(wx) does not cause the retailer to

stop purchasing product Y, i.e., gy(Tx, (0, Fy(wx))) > 0. Define x(ω) ≡ x∗∗(wx, ω, Fx, Fy(wx))

and y(ω) ≡ y∗∗(wx, ω, Fx, Fy(wx)). We show that wy = 0 maximizes the joint profit of the

retailer and firm Y, given in (8). Suppose not. Then there exists wy = 0 such that

px(x(wy))x(wy) + py(y(wy))y(wy) − Tx(x(wy) | wx, Fx) > (A-3)

px(x(0))x(0) + py(y(0)), y(0) − Tx(x(0) | wx, Fx).

However, the definition of x∗∗ and y∗∗ implies that the first line in (A-3) is less than or equal to

the second line. This establishes a contradiction. Since gy(Tx, (0, Fy(wx))) > 0, then y(0) > 0,

which implies that 0 is the unique maximizer in (8). Thus, wy = 0. Since supplier Y ’s disagree-

ment payoff is zero, it is clear that, when wy = 0, Fy(wx) gives supplier Y its disagreement

payoff plus proportion λy of the gains from trade. Q.E.D.

Lemma 2 The unique equilibrium T ex has wx = 0 and Fx(wy) ≡ λxgx((0, 0), Tx) > 0.

Proof. The proof of this lemma is analogous to the proof of the preceding lemma. Q.E.D.

28

Page 31: Bargaining, Third-Party Information and the Division …haas.berkeley.edu/Courses/Spring2000/BA269D/bargainm.pdfBargaining, Third-Party Information and the Division of Profit in the

We now use the results from the preceding lemmas to derive each firm’s equilibrium profit.

Since each firm’s wholesale is zero, its equilibrium is equal to the fixed fee it negotiates with

the retailer. Using lemmas 1 and 2, firm X’s profit is Fx(0) = λxgx((0, 0), (0, Fy(0))) and firm

Y ’s profit is Fy(0) = λygy((0, Fy(0)), (0, 0)). Note that since the unique equilibrium wholesale

prices in stage one are zero, the retailer’s problem in (3) simplifies to

maxx,y≥0

px(x)x + py(y)y − Fx(0) − Fy(0) (A-4)

such that x + y ≤ 1.

The unique solution yields x∗∗ = xmm and y∗∗ = ymm, i.e., the same quantities that maximize

total channel profit. In addition, the retailer’s choice of x if it were constrained not to sell

product Y would be x∗ = xm, and its choice of y if it were constrained not to sell product X

would be y∗ = ym, i.e., the same quantities that maximize the monopoly profit of the retailer

with each firm. Substituting these quantities into Fx(0) and Fy(0) yields πx = λx (Πxy − Πy),

πy = λy (Πxy − Πx), and πr = Πxy − πx − πy, as was to be proved. Q.E.D.

Proof of Propositions 3 through 8

Recall from equation 2 on page 6 that in equilibrium the retailer prices at pmmx = Vx −

xmmδx, pmmy = Vy − (1− xmm)δy, where xmm = (2δy + Vx − Vy)/(2(δx + δy)). The maximum

revenue of the retailer or total channel profit is given by Πxy = pmmx xmm + pmm

y (1 − xmm).

Substituting equilibrium prices and market shares and after some simplifications we obtain:

Πxy(Vx, Vy, δx, δy) = (Vx−Vy)2+4 Vx δy−4 δx (−Vy+δy)4 (δx+δy)

Πx(Vx, Vy, δx, δy) = V 2x

4δxfor δx > Vx/2

= Vx − δx otherwise

Πy(Vx, Vy, δx, δy) = V 2y

4δyfor δy > Vy/2

= Vy − δy otherwise

(A-5)

Let ∆Πxy = Πxy(Vx, Vy, δx, δy)−Πxy(Vx + ∆Vx, Vy + ∆Vy, δx + ∆δx, δy + ∆δy) and define ∆Πx

and ∆Πy analogously. Using proposition 2 we can then write the profit changes of each firm

29

Page 32: Bargaining, Third-Party Information and the Division …haas.berkeley.edu/Courses/Spring2000/BA269D/bargainm.pdfBargaining, Third-Party Information and the Division of Profit in the

as a function of information induced changes in Vx, Vy and δx, δy.

∆πx(∆Vx,∆Vy,∆δx,∆δy) = λx(∆Πxy − ∆Πy)

∆πy(∆Vx,∆Vy,∆δx,∆δy) = λx(∆Πxy − ∆Πx)

∆πr(∆Vx,∆Vy,∆δx,∆δy) = λx∆Πx + λy∆Πy + (1 − λx − λy)∆Πxy

(A-6)

By the assumption that a multiproduct monopolist serves all consumers located in [0,1],Vx2δx

> 1 − Vy

2δy, which is equivalent to V > δ in the benchmark case. It can be easily shown

that this condition also implies that the multiproduct monopolist serves all consumers after

the valuation shifts considered in the propositions.

Propositions 3 to 8 specify the effect of information on consumers’ valuations as a change

in Vx, Vy, δx, and δy. Evaluating (A-6) with the arguments corresponding to each proposition

yields after some simplifications the following profit changes.

Proposition 3 Let {∆Vx,∆Vy,∆δx,∆δy} = {0, 0,−µ, 0}, µ > 0. We assume non-negative

demand for product i if the retailer sells product i only, which is equivalent to a restriction on

information shocks applied to the benchmark case, µ < δ.

Assume V < 2δ, µ < δ−V/2. Then {∆πx,∆πy,∆πr} = { δ µ4 δ−2 µ , δ µ

4 δ−2 µ+ V 2 µ−4 δ2+4 δ µ

, δ µ−4 δ+2 µ+

V 2 µ4 δ2−4 δ µ

}. By µ < δ, ∆πx > 0. Also, ∂∆πy

∂µ < 0 by V > δ and µ < δ. Hence, ∆πy < 0. Since

Πy = 0, ∆πr = −∆πy > 0.

Assume V < 2δ, µ ≥ δ−V/2. Then {∆πx,∆πy,∆πr} = { δ µ4 δ−2 µ ,−V +V 2

4 δ +δ−µ+ δ µ4 δ−2 µ , V −

V 2

4 δ + µ + δ(−1 + µ

−4 δ+2 µ

)}. By µ < δ, ∆πx > 0. Also, ∂∆πy

∂µ < 0 by µ < δ. Evaluate ∆πy

at the smallest admissible µ = δ − V/2. The resulting function has a unique minimum at V ∗

where δ < V ∗ < 2δ. Hence, the function is maximized at one of the endpoints V = δ, V = 2δ.

Evaluating ∆πy at V = δ, V = 2δ shows ∆πy < 0. Since Πy = 0, ∆πr = −∆πy > 0.

Assume V ≥ 2δ. Then {∆πx,∆πy,∆πr} = { δ µ4 δ−2 µ ,

(−1 + δ

4 δ−2 µ

)µ, µ + δ µ

−4 δ+2 µ}. By

µ < δ, ∆πx = ∆Πxy, ∆πy < 0, and ∆πr = −∆πy > 0. Hence the proposition holds.

Proposition 4 Let {∆Vx,∆Vy,∆δx,∆δy} = {µ, 0, 0, 0}, µ > 0.

Assume V < 2δ, µ < 2δ−V . Then {∆πx,∆πy,∆πr} = {µ (4 δ+µ)8 δ , −(µ (4 V −4 δ+µ))

8 δ , µ (4 V −4 δ+µ)8 δ }.

∆πx > 0 by inspection. By V > δ, ∆πy < 0 and ∆πr > 0.

Assume V < 2δ, µ ≥ 2δ−V . Then {∆πx,∆πy,∆πr} = {µ (4 δ+µ)8 δ , 2 V 2+8 δ2+µ2−4 δ (2 V +µ)

8 δ , V −δ + µ

2 − 2 V 2+µ2

8 δ }. ∆πx > 0 by inspection. Under the assumptions, ∂∆πy

∂µ < 0. Evaluate ∆πy

at the smallest admissible µ = 2δ − V . The resulting function has a unique minimum at

V = 4/(3δ). Hence, the function is maximized at one of the endpoints V = δ, V = 2δ.

Evaluating ∆πy at V = δ, V = 2δ shows ∆πy < 0. Since Πy = 0, ∆πr = −∆πy > 0.

30

Page 33: Bargaining, Third-Party Information and the Division …haas.berkeley.edu/Courses/Spring2000/BA269D/bargainm.pdfBargaining, Third-Party Information and the Division of Profit in the

Assume V ≥ 2δ. Then {∆πx,∆πy,∆πr} = {µ (4 δ+µ)8 δ , µ (−4 δ+µ)

8 δ , −(µ (−4 δ+µ))8 δ }. To avoid

degenerate solutions assume |∆xmm| < 1/2. Since xmm = µ/(4δ), µ < 2δ. Thus, ∆πx = ∆Πxy,

∆πy < 0, and ∆πr = −∆πy > 0. Hence the proposition holds.

Proposition 5 Let {∆Vx,∆Vy,∆δx,∆δy} = {µ, 0, µ, 0}, µ > 0.

Assume V < 2δ. Then {∆πx,∆πy,∆πr} = {µ4 , (−V +δ)2 µ

4 δ (δ+µ) ,−((−V +δ)2 µ)

4 δ (δ+µ) }. ∆πx,∆πy > 0,

and ∆πr < 0 by inspection.

Assume V ≥ 2δ, µ ≥ V −2δ. Then {∆πx,∆πy,∆πr} = {µ4 , µ

4 − (−V +2 δ+µ)2

4(δ+µ) ,−µ4 + (−V +2 δ+µ)2

4(δ+µ) }.∆πx > 0 by inspection. Also, ∂∆πy

∂µ > 0. Evaluated at the smallest admissible µ = V − 2δ,

∆πy ≥ 0 by V ≥ 2δ. Since Πy = 0, ∆πr = −∆πy ≥ 0.

Assume V ≥ 2δ, µ < V − 2δ. Then {∆πx,∆πy,∆πr} = {µ4 , µ

4 , −µ4 }. Clearly, ∆πx = ∆πy =

∆Πxy and ∆πr = −∆πx = −∆πy < 0. Hence the proposition holds.

Proposition 6 Let {∆Vx,∆Vy,∆δx,∆δy} = {µ, 0, µ,−µ}, µ > 0. We assume non-negative

demand for product i if the retailer sells product i only, which is equivalent to a restriction on

information shocks applied to the benchmark case, µ < δ.

Assume V < 2δ, µ < δ − V/2. Then {∆πx,∆πy,∆πr} = {12 + µ

8 δ

(µ + 2 V 2

−δ+µ

),

µ (2 V 2−4 V δ+4 δ2+3 δ µ+µ2)8 δ (δ+µ) ,

µ (−4 δ3+4 V 2 µ+µ3+2 δ µ (−2 V +µ)+δ2 (4 V +µ))8 δ (δ−µ) (δ+µ) }. ∆πx < 0 at the largest

admissible µ. Let δ < V <√

2δ . One can easily show that there exists exactly one µ∗ > 0

such that ∆πx = 0 at µ∗. Also, ∂∆πx∂µ > 0 at µ = 0. Let

√2δ ≤ V < 2δ. Then there is no

µ∗ > 0 such that ∆πx = 0 at µ∗. Also, ∂∆πx∂µ ≤ 0 at µ = 0. The claims regarding ∆πx hold by

continuity of ∆πx. ∆πy is minimized at V = δ. Evaluating ∆πy at V = δ shows ∆πy > 0. The

numerator of ∆πr is minimized in the admissible parameter range at V = δ and is positive. By

µ < δ, ∆πr > 0.

Assume V < 2δ, µ ≥ δ − V/2. Then {∆πx,∆πy,∆πr} = {2 V 2+8 δ2+µ2−4 δ (2 V +µ)8 δ ,

µ (2 V 2−4 V δ+4 δ2+3 δ µ+µ2)8 δ (δ+µ) ,−δ − 4 V 2+µ2

8 δ + V 2+6 V µ+3 µ2+2 δ (2 V +µ)4 (δ+µ) }. ∆πx < 0 at the largest

admissible µ. Let δ < V < 10δ/9 . One can easily show that there exists exactly one µ∗ ≥δ − V/2 such that ∆πx = 0 at µ∗. Also, ∆πx > 0 at µ = δ − V/2. Let 10δ/9 ≤ V < 2δ. Then

there is no µ∗ > δ − V/2 such that ∆πx = 0 at µ∗. Also, ∂∆πx∂µ < 0 at µ = δ − V/2. The claims

regarding ∆πx hold by continuity of ∆πx. ∆πy is minimized at V = δ. Evaluating ∆πy at

V = δ shows ∆πy > 0. Approximating ∂∆πr∂µ from below using δ − V/2 ≤ µ < δ and V < 2δ

shows ∂∆πr∂µ > 0. Evaluate ∆πr at the smallest admissible µ = δ−V/2. The denominator of the

resulting function is negative by V < 2δ. The numerator is negative for δ < V < 2δ. Hence,

∆πr > 0.

Assume V ≥ 2δ, µ ≥ V −2δ. Then {∆πx,∆πy,∆πr} = {µ (−4 δ+µ)8 δ , −2 (−V +2 δ+µ)2

8(δ+µ) + µ (4 δ+µ)8δ ,

µ + (−V +2 δ+µ)2

4 (δ+µ) − µ (4 δ+µ)8 δ }. ∆πx < 0 by µ < δ. ∂∆πy

∂V ≥ 0 by µ ≥ V − 2δ. Evaluate ∆πy at

31

Page 34: Bargaining, Third-Party Information and the Division …haas.berkeley.edu/Courses/Spring2000/BA269D/bargainm.pdfBargaining, Third-Party Information and the Division of Profit in the

the smallest admissible V = 2δ shows ∆πy > 0. ∂∆πr∂V ≤ 0 by µ ≥ V − 2δ. Notice that by

δ > µ ≥ V − 2δ and V ≥ 2δ, 2δ ≤ V < 3δ. Evaluate ∆πr at the largest admissible V = 3δ.

This shows ∆πr > 0.

Assume V ≥ 2δ, µ < V − 2δ. Then {∆πx,∆πy,∆πr} = {µ (−4 δ+µ)8 δ , µ (4 δ+µ)

8 δ , −(µ (−4 δ+µ))8 δ }.

Since µ < δ, ∆πy = ∆Πxy, ∆πx < 0, and ∆πr = −∆πx > 0. Hence the proposition holds.

Proposition 7 The analysis is identical to that in Proposition 6 with only the names of firms

X and Y interchanged.

Proposition 8 Let {∆Vx,∆Vy,∆δx,∆δy} = {µ, µ, 0, 0}, µ > 0.

Assume V < 2δ, µ < 2δ−V . Then {∆πx,∆πy,∆πr} = {µ−µ (2 V +µ)4 δ , µ−µ (2 V +µ)

4 δ , µ (2 V −2 δ+µ)2 δ }.

∂∆πi∂µ > 0, i = x, y, r.

Assume V < 2δ, µ ≥ 2δ−V . Then {∆πx,∆πy,∆πr} = { (V −2 δ)2

4 δ , (V −2 δ)2

4 δ , 2 V − V 2

2 δ −2 δ+µ}.∆πx,∆πy > 0 by inspection. Also ∂∆πr

∂µ = 1. Evaluated at the smallest admissible µ = 2δ − V ,

∆πr > 0 by δ < V < 2δ.

Assume V ≥ 2δ. Then {∆πx,∆πy,∆πr} = {0, 0, µ}. Clearly, ∆πx = ∆πy = 0 and

∆πr = ∆Πxy > 0. Hence the proposition holds.

Q.E.D.

32

Page 35: Bargaining, Third-Party Information and the Division …haas.berkeley.edu/Courses/Spring2000/BA269D/bargainm.pdfBargaining, Third-Party Information and the Division of Profit in the

REFERENCES

Agrawal, Deepak (1996), “Effect of Brand Loyalty on Advertising and Trade Promotions:A Game Theoretic Analysis with Empirical Evidence,” Marketing Science, 15, 86-108.

Bonnano, Giacomo and John Vickers (1988), “Vertical Separation,” Journal of Indus-trial Economics, 36, 257-265.

Chang, M.H. (1992), “Exclusive Dealing Contracts in a Successive Duopoly with Side Pay-ments,” Southern Economic Journal, 59, 180-193.

Choi, S. Chan (1991), “Price Competition in a Channel Structure with a Common Re-tailer,” Marketing Science, 10 , 271-296.

Chu, Wujin and Paul R. Messinger (1997), “Information and channel profits,” Journalof Retailing, 73(4), 487-499.

Coughlan, Anne (1985), “Competition and Cooperation in Marketing Channel Choice:Theory and Application,” Marketing Science, 2, 110-129.

Coughlan, Anne and Birger Wernerfelt (1989), “On Credible Delegation By Oligopolists:A Discussion of Distribution Channel Management,” Management Science, 35, 226-239.

Cremer, Jacques and Michael Riordan (1987), “On Governing Multilateral Transac-tions with Bilateral Contracts,” Rand Journal of Economics, 18, 436-451.

Dobson, Paul and Mike Waterson (1996), “Product Range and Interfirm Competition,”Journal of Economics and Management Strategy, 5, 317-341.

Fershtman, Chaim and Kenneth Judd (1987), “Equilibrium Incentives in Oligopoly,”American Economic Review, 77, 927-940.

Gabrielsen, Tommy Stahl (1997), “Equilibrium Retail Distribution Systems,” Interna-tional Journal of Industrial Organization, 16, 105-120.

Gabrielsen, Tommy Stahl and Lars Sorgard (1999), “Exclusive Versus Common Deal-ership,” Southern Economic Journal, forthcoming.

Gal-Or, Esther (1990), “Excessive Retailing at the Bertrand Equilibria,” Canadian Jour-nal of Economics, 23, 294-304.

Gal-Or, Esther (1991), “Duopolistic Vertical Restraints,” European Economic Review,35, 1237-1253.

Gupta, Sudheer and Richard Loulou (1998), “Process Innovation, Product Differenti-ation, and Channel Structure: Strategic Incentives in a Duopoly,” Marketing Science, 17,301-316.

Hotelling, Harold (1929), “Stability in Competition,” Economic Journal, 39, 41-57.

Ingene, Chuck and Mark Parry (1995), “Channel Coordination When Retailers Com-pete,” Marketing Science, 14, 360-377.

33

Page 36: Bargaining, Third-Party Information and the Division …haas.berkeley.edu/Courses/Spring2000/BA269D/bargainm.pdfBargaining, Third-Party Information and the Division of Profit in the

Ingene, Chuck and Mark Parry (1999), “Is Channel Coordination All it is Cracked Upto Be,” working paper, University of Washington.

Iyer, Ganesh (1998), “Coordinating Channels Under Price and Nonprice Competition,”Marketing Science, 17, 338-355.

Iyer, Ganesh and Miguel Villas-Boas (1998), “A Bargaining Theory of DistributionChannels,” working paper, University of California at Berkeley.

Jeuland, Abel and Steven Shugan (1983), “Managing Channel Profits,” MarketingScience, 2, 239-272.

Kalai, Ehud and M. Smorodinsky (1975), “Other Solutions to Nash’s Bargaining Prob-lem,” Econometrica, 43, 513-518.

Katz, Michael (1991), “Game Playing Agents: Unobservable Contracts as Precommit-ments,” Rand Journal of Economics, 22, 307-328.

Lal, Rajiv (1990), “Manufacturer Trade Deals and Retail Price Promotions,” Journal ofMarketing Research, 27, 428-444.

Lal, Rajiv and Miguel Villas-Boas (1996), “Exclusive Dealing and Price Promotions,”Journal of Business, 69, 159-172.

Lal, Rajiv, John D.C. Little and Miguel Villas-Boas (1997), “A Theory of ForwardBuying, Merchandising, and Trade Deals,” Marketing Science, 15, 21-37.

Lin, Y. Joseph (1988), “Oligopoly and Vertical Integration: A Note,” American EconomicReview, 78, 251-254.

Lin, Y. Joseph (1990), “The Dampening of Competition Effect of Exclusive Dealing,” Jour-nal of Industrial Economics, 39, 209-223.

Lee, Eunkyu and Richard Staelin (1997), “Vertical Strategic Interaction: Implicationsfor Channel Pricing Strategy,” Marketing Science, 16, 185-207.

Lynch, John and Daniel Ariely (1998), “Interactive Home Shopping: Effects of Cost ofAcquiring Price and Quality Information on Consumer Price Sensitivity, Satisfaction withMerchandise Selected, and Retention,” working paper, Duke University.

Marx, Leslie and Greg Shaffer (1999), “Predatory Accommodation: Below-Cost Pric-ing Without Exclusion in Intermediate Goods Markets,” Rand Journal of Economics, 30,22-43.

Mathewson, G. Frank and Ralph Winter (1984), “An Economic Theory of VerticalRestraints,” Rand Journal of Economics, 15, 27-38.

McAfee, R. Preston and Marius Schwartz (1994), “Opportunism in Multilateral Ver-tical Contracting: Nondiscrimination, Exclusivity, and Uniformity,” American EconomicReview, 84, 210-230.

Mcguire, T. and Richard Staelin (1983), “An Industry Equilibrium Analysis of Down-stream Vertical Integration,” Marketing Science, 2, 161-191.

34

Page 37: Bargaining, Third-Party Information and the Division …haas.berkeley.edu/Courses/Spring2000/BA269D/bargainm.pdfBargaining, Third-Party Information and the Division of Profit in the

Messinger, Paul and Chuck Narasimhan (1995), “Has Power Shifted in the GroceryChannel?,” Marketing Science, 2, 189-223.

Moorthy, K. Sridhar (1987), “Managing Channel Profits: Comment,” Marketing Sci-ence, 6, 375-79.

Moorthy, K. Sridhar (1988), “Strategic Decentralization in Channels,” Marketing Sci-ence, 7, 335-55.

Nash, John (1950), “The Bargaining Problem,” Econometrica, 28, 155-162.

O’Brien, Daniel P. and Shaffer, Greg (1992), “Vertical Control with Bilateral Con-tracts,” Rand Journal of Economics, 23, 299-308.

O’Brien, Daniel P. and Greg Shaffer (1993), “On the Dampening-of-Competition Ef-fect of Exclusive Dealing,” Journal of Industrial Economics, 41, 215-221.

O’Brien, Daniel P. and Greg Shaffer (1994), “The Welfare Effects of Forbidding Dis-criminatory Discounts: A Secondary Line Analysis of Robinson-Patman,” Journal of Law,Economics, and Organization, 10, 296-318.

O’Brien, Daniel P. and Greg Shaffer (1997), “Nonlinear Supply Contracts, ExclusiveDealing, and Equilibrium Market Foreclosure,” Journal of Economics and ManagementStrategy, 6, 755-785.

Rubinstein, Ariel (1982), “Perfect Equilibrium in a Bargaining Model,” Econometrica,50, 97-110.

Shaffer, Greg (1991a), “Capturing Strategic Rent: Full Line Forcing, Brand Discounts,Aggregate Rebates, and Maximum Resale Price Maintenance,” Journal of Industrial Eco-nomics, 39, 557-575.

Shaffer, Greg (1991b), “Slotting Allowances and Resale Price Maintenance: A Compari-son of Facilitating Practices,” Rand Journal of Economics, 22, 120-135.

Stern, Louis, Adel El-Ansary, and Anne Coughlan (1996), Marketing Channels 5thed., Prentice Hall, Englewood Cliffs, New Jersey.

Vickers John (1985), “Delegation and the Theory of the Firm,” Economic Journal, 95,138-147.

Zettelmeyer, Florian (1997), “The Strategic Use of Consumer Search Cost,” mimeo,University of California at Berkeley.

35