assessing marginal impacts of investments on the performance of organisational units

13
production economics Int. J. Production Economics 39 (1995) 149-164 ELSEVIER Assessing marginal impacts of investments on the performance of organisational units Antreas D. Athanassopoulos*, Emmanuel Thanassoulis University of Warwick, Warwick Business School, Cove&y, CV4 7AL. UK Received March 1993; accepted for publication March 1994 Abstract This paper develops a data envelopment analysis (DEA) based method for targeting investment decisions in commercial organisations. The organisations considered are those comprising multiple outlets operating in geographi- cally different and changing markets. The method developed disentangles the effects of investments from those of market size changes on the ability of an outlet to attract an increasing share of its potential market. This information is useful not only in identifying practices and investments conducive to improved profitability but also outlets most likely to secure the best return on investment made on them. The method developed is illustrated using data from a set of pubs of a UK brewery. Key words: Data envelopment analysis; Capital investment; Market efficiency; Profitability; Retailing 1. Introduction This paper addresses the issue of disentangling investment and environmental impacts on the com- parative “market efficiency” of organisational deci- sion making units (DMUs). The market efficiency of a DMU is the factor by which its current sales level(s) can be multiplied to render it relatively efficient given the sales potential in the market in which the DMU oper- ates. This definition of market efficiency is essentially that of “technical efficiency” in DEA (e.g. see Cl]), the only difference being that it relates to a specific * Corresponding author. transformation process, namely the transformation of sales potential to actual sales. The variables used to reflect sales potential and actual sales will de- pend on the specific context. DMUs operating this transformation process will be referred to as “market” DMUs. The methodology developed in this paper is use- ful for identifying market DMUs most likely to secure a good return on invested funds and it is illustrated using data from the public houses of a private sector organisation. Parent organisations controlling a number of market DMUs typically invest funds to upgrade their outlets so that they will be more effective in the sale of their goods and services. This will ulti- mately lead to higher corporate profitability. The parent organisation needs to identify those DMUs 0925-5273/95/$09.50 0 1995 Elsevier Science B.V. All rights reserved SSDI 0925-5273(94)00066-2

Upload: antreas-d-athanassopoulos

Post on 26-Jun-2016

216 views

Category:

Documents


3 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Assessing marginal impacts of investments on the performance of organisational units

production economics

Int. J. Production Economics 39 (1995) 149-164 ELSEVIER

Assessing marginal impacts of investments on the performance of organisational units

Antreas D. Athanassopoulos*, Emmanuel Thanassoulis

University of Warwick, Warwick Business School, Cove&y, CV4 7AL. UK

Received March 1993; accepted for publication March 1994

Abstract

This paper develops a data envelopment analysis (DEA) based method for targeting investment decisions in commercial organisations. The organisations considered are those comprising multiple outlets operating in geographi- cally different and changing markets. The method developed disentangles the effects of investments from those of market size changes on the ability of an outlet to attract an increasing share of its potential market. This information is useful not only in identifying practices and investments conducive to improved profitability but also outlets most likely to secure the best return on investment made on them. The method developed is illustrated using data from a set of pubs of a UK brewery.

Key words: Data envelopment analysis; Capital investment; Market efficiency; Profitability; Retailing

1. Introduction

This paper addresses the issue of disentangling investment and environmental impacts on the com- parative “market efficiency” of organisational deci- sion making units (DMUs).

The market efficiency of a DMU is the factor by which its current sales level(s) can be multiplied to render it relatively efficient given the sales potential in the market in which the DMU oper- ates.

This definition of market efficiency is essentially that of “technical efficiency” in DEA (e.g. see Cl]), the only difference being that it relates to a specific

* Corresponding author.

transformation process, namely the transformation of sales potential to actual sales. The variables used to reflect sales potential and actual sales will de- pend on the specific context. DMUs operating this transformation process will be referred to as “market” DMUs.

The methodology developed in this paper is use- ful for identifying market DMUs most likely to secure a good return on invested funds and it is illustrated using data from the public houses of a private sector organisation.

Parent organisations controlling a number of market DMUs typically invest funds to upgrade their outlets so that they will be more effective in the sale of their goods and services. This will ulti- mately lead to higher corporate profitability. The parent organisation needs to identify those DMUs

0925-5273/95/$09.50 0 1995 Elsevier Science B.V. All rights reserved SSDI 0925-5273(94)00066-2

Page 2: Assessing marginal impacts of investments on the performance of organisational units

150 A.D. Athanassopoulos, E. Thanassoulisllnt. J. Production Economics 39 (1995) 149-164

which will secure the best return on funds invested. In many instances the identification of DMUs to receive investment funds rests on little more than their profitability in the previous financial year. This, however, it was argued in Athanassopoulos and Thanassoulis [2], is not a valid method of selection because it ignores the market efficiency of the DMU. A DMU showing a high profit could be benefiting from a very favourable environment and in fact securing only a fraction of its potential custom. In such a case further investment of funds would only be justified if they would lead to an improvement of the market efficiency of the DMU. In contrast a DMU enjoying a high market effi- ciency should only receive further investment funds if they are essential for the maintenance of its market efficiency.

Thus the likely impact of an investment of funds on the market efficiency of a DMU is of vital importance in the decision to invest or not funds in the DMU. It is not, however, straightforward to ascertain this impact. One possibility is to appraise changes in a DMU’s market efficiency resulting from past investments made in it and extrapolate them to the future. However, this is not very simple. Most private sector organisations and many in the public sector operate in environments which con- stantly change. The number of drinks and meals sold over a period of time by a restaurant are affected by the general state of the economy and the same goes for the sales secured by other commercial outlets such as car showrooms and holiday outlets. Indeed, the same is true for public sector organisa- tions selling goods and/or services. These changes in market conditions from one time period to the next compound the difficulty of prising out the effect of investments on the market efficiency of DMUs.

A variety of non-parametric models have been developed for assessing changes in efficiency over time. Chief among these are those by Charnes et al. [3], Clarke [4], Fare et al. [S] and Tulkens and Vanden Eeckaut [6]. These models, however, can- not be used to assess the impact of investments on market efficiency because they do not allow for estimates of the impact of changes in market size over time to be incorporated within the model. These estimates are necessary if investment and market size effects are to be disentangled.

This paper develops an approach for assessing the impacts of investments in a DMU on its market efficiency. The investments considered relate to funds invested in the infrastructure of the DMU as distinct from investments in new products and/or services. Investments in infrastructure (e.g. in new furniture and fittings) impact indirectly on sales and the revenue they generate cannot be estimated by conventional accounting methods. The method rests on estimating the market efficiency of the DMU as it would have been without the invest- ments and then contrasting that efficiency rating with its actual efficiency rating with the invest- ments. Any difference in these two efficiency ratings reflects in part the effect of the investments on the market efficiency of the DMU.

Our attempt to disentangle market and invest- ment impact on market efficiency has similarities in aim with Charnes [7] where an attempt was made to disentangle managerial and programme effects on efficiency. The approach adopted in our case is, however, different. In principle DMUs with invest- ment can be classified in one programme and those without in a separate programme. However, this will still not make it possible to disentangle market and investment effects. For this estimates of the effects on market efficiency emanating from cha- nges in market size alone are needed. Such esti- mates are used in the approach adopted here.

The structure of the paper is as follows. Section 2 develops the method for decomposing changes in market efficiency between two time periods into those attributable to investment and those attribu- table to changes in market size and other effects. Section 3 constructs the specific input-output set and associated DEA models for disentangling the impacts on market efficiency attributable to invest- ments made in a set of pubs. Section 4 discusses the results obtained.

2. Isolating the effects of investment on market efficiency A key feature of market DMUs is that the vol-

ume of goods or services they sell is strongly in- fluenced by the size of the market in which they operate. The size of markets generally changes over time. Consequently if we wish to assess the impact

Page 3: Assessing marginal impacts of investments on the performance of organisational units

A.D. Athanassopoulos, E. Thanassoulisllnt. J. Production Economics 39 (1995) 149-164 151

of an investment on the volume of goods or services sold by a DMU over time we need to segregate the impact of the change in the size of the market in which the DMU operates from the impact of in- vestments made in its infrastructure. This section develops a method for this purpose.

2. I. A method for isolating investment impacts on market efficiency

Consider a set of j = 1, . . . , n DMUs over a time period t = 1, . . . , T. For each time period t a “pro- duction possibility set” @’ can be defined as follows:

@’ = (Xl, Y ‘) i ;IjXf Q X'; i I i JLjYf 2 y’;

j=l j=l

~ ;ij=l,~j~O ,t=l,...,T (2.1) j= 1

@’ consists of all input levels X’ and corresponding output levels Y’ feasible in principle. The vectors (Xj, Yj) consist of the vector Xj E %1”, of input levels and the vector Yj E ‘SC of output levels observed at DMU j. This definition of @’ assumes variable returns to scale hold in the production process operated by the DMUs. (see [S]). Alternative mod- els for measuring efficiency can be found in Fare et al. [9], Thanassoulis and Dyson [lo] (models Ml and M2, and Fried et al. [ 111. In the case of market DMUs inputs relate typically to market size and capacity of the DMUs while outputs relate to rev- enue generated. The market efficiency of DMU j in period t is measured by E: where

E: = max{z’(X’ d Xjt, Yf 2 z’Yf,(X’, Y’)E@}.

(2.2)

Let (Xtj,X;j, Yf) be the input-output levels of DMU j at time period t so that Xii are the levels of inputs which stay constant from t to t + 1 when no investment in the DMU is made in year t, Xij are the levels of inputs that generally alter from year t to t + 1 irrespective of investments made in year t (for example the market size in which a DMU operates) and Yf are the levels of outputs in year t. Finally let E; be the market efficiency of DMU j computed using (2.2).

Let us assume now that an investment was made in DMU j, at the end of time period t. We can now measure the following:

(i) The market efficiency of DMU j,, ,J$~’ in period r + 1. E:zl is measured using (2.2) with reference to @’ + ’ defined as in (2.1) using in- put-output levels observed in period t + 1.

(ii) The estimated market efficiency of DMU j,, p,+1 .

,. , m period t + 1 had there been no investment in it at the end of period t. gfc ’ is measured using (2.2) with reference to a new production possibility set 6:“. 6;’ ’ is constructed as @I+ ’ in (i) above except that it contains the additional “DMU” which is being assessed and has the estimated in- put-output levels (Xt,, X[L’, #,‘+ ’ Yj,,) DMU j,, would have had in t + 1 without investment. How these estimates might be obtained is discussed later.

The following measures can now be defined to reflect the effects on the market efficiency of DMU j attributable to investment and changes in the size of the market in which it operates:

The overall change in the market efficiency of DMU j between periods t and t + 1 is reflected in

or,. I + 1 J

= E;+ l/E;. (2.3)

The change in the market efficiency of DMU j between periods t and t + 1 attributable to the change in the size of the market in which it operates and to other factors not related to investment is reflected in

M;,‘+ l = pjfi’ l/E;. (2.4)

The change in the market efficiency of DMU j between periods t and t + 1 which is attributable to investments made in it in period t is reflected in

I:,‘+ l = E;+‘/c.+‘. (2.5)

We shall refer to 1>‘+’ as the inoestment efsec- tiveness of DMU j from period t to period t + 1.

Note that O:r’ ’ = M>‘+‘xZ)‘+’ so that the measure reflecting overall change in market efficiency is multiplicatively decomposed into a measure reflecting change in market efficiency mainly due to market size changes and the invest- ment effectiveness measure. The estimation and use of the investment effectiveness component I>‘+ ’ is one of the main objectives of this paper.

Page 4: Assessing marginal impacts of investments on the performance of organisational units

152 A.D. Athannssopoulos, E. Thanassoulisllnt. J. Production Economics 39 (1995) 149-164

2.2. Practical aspects of the method developed

Both Ef+ ’ and ~j:.’ ’ are defined on production possibility sets which depend on observed input- output levels of DMUs in period t + 1. These levels in turn depend on investments made in DMUs other than j during time periods t, t - 1, etc. Thus the measures O>‘+l,iV;,f+l,Z:(‘+l are relative to investments made in all DMUs in periods up to and including t.

This observation has important consequences for the use of the measure of investment effec- tiveness If’* + 1 developed. The measure is seen as our best estimate of the effect on the market effi- ciency of DMU j due to the investments made in it, given the investments made in other DMUs to date. It is entirely possible that this estimate would be different had investments in DMUs other than DMU j been different to those actually made so far. It is, however, more sensible to use actual rather than hypothetical investments to estimate the im- pact on the market efficiency of DMU j from the investment made in it.

The key to measuring the investment effec- tiveness of a DMU is the estimate of the impact of market size change on its output levels. It is gener- ally safe to assume that without investment a DMU would continue to use the same operating practices in the short term. So the major difference in its ability to generate outputs (notably revenue) be- tween successive time periods when no investment is made will be due to changes in the size of the market in which it operates. There will, of course, be other random impacts on its outputs not related to market size changes but these are likely to prove minor in relation to those induced by changes in market size. Hence to estimate outputs as they would be without investment we need to focus on an estimate of the impact of market size changes on the DMU’s outputs.

The simplest estimate of an output level at DMU j when no investment is made in the DMU is obtained by assuming that the output level would have altered between periods t and t + 1 by the same factor as the size of the market alters between t and t + 1 in the output concerned. For example in the application of the method to public houses outlined later, it was assumed that a public house

(“pub”) that had no investment between years t and t + 1 would have experienced the same change in its sales of beer as was experienced in its catchment area overall. This is an acceptable basis for estima- ting the effects of market size changes when such changes are not affected significantly by any invest- ments in the individual DMU concerned. (Invest- ments in individual pubs, as pointed out later, generally affected only marginally the size of the market in their catchment area.).

The estimation of the investment effectiveness (defined in (2.5)) of a DMU with investments makes use of unobserved input-output levels. These are the input and output levels that would have been expected at the DMU without investment.

This has similarities with the so-called “counter- factual” studies often found in economics. Counter- factual studies use econometric models to link input-output factors of economic systems where the levels of some of the factors have not actually been observed. The models are then used to esti- mate the effects of unobserved factor levels on the economic system. For example, using counterfac- tual studies Dimsdale and Horewood [ 121 examine the effects of hypothetical public spending pro- grammes on unemployment levels in the UK dur- ing the interwar period. In assuming the absence of investment when estimating input or output levels of a DMU with investment, the estimates are being derived in a counterfactual manner.

The use of unobserved output levels for esti- mating the investment effectiveness has also simil- arities with the concept of latent variables in econometric theory. Latent variables can be used to account for measurement errors in independent variables but more importantly for estimating the effects of unobservable factors on social and economic phenomena. For instance, Lanen and Larcker [13] use latent variables to examine how adoption of contracts for executives affect perfor- mance of electric utilities in the USA. In estimating investment effectiveness in the case of pubs the latent efect is the overall change in drink and food sales from time period t to t + 1 in the market in which pubs operate.

In the general multi input/output case the vector

$j = (4~~~,&~), where 4,j~‘%, 4,,eW+, can be used to estimate (Xf”, Yf”) = (d,,X:,&,j Yf),

Page 5: Assessing marginal impacts of investments on the performance of organisational units

A.D. Athanassopoulos, E. Thanassoulisllnt. J. Production Economics 39 (1995) 149-164 153

the input-output levels of DMU j in period t + 1, without investment in period t. The vector 4j can be estimated in several ways. Use can be made of general economic growth indices such as consump- tion and trade indices reflecting market size changes over time. Indices reflecting local market effects on specific inputs/outputs will also be needed. Such approaches, reflecting overall market change at DMU level, will generally be appropri- ate, except in cases where the overall market change is in large measure induced by investment in the DMU concerned. Alternatively, an attempt can be made to estimate the elements of 4j by using causal regression or other more advanced stochas- tic methodologies along the lines of latent analysis (see [ 141).

The method developed in this paper makes it possible to compute the investment effectiveness of outlets for each year. This can be used to identify outlets and managements that offer the best scope of returns to investments.

The method is intended to be an aid rather than a sole instrument by which investments are deci- ded. In particular, the method cannot direct invest- ments to outlets that have had no investment in the past. However, for ongoing organisations the pro- portion of outlets which never had an investment should be very small and therefore this should not present serious difficulties. The next section illus- trates the use of the method in the case of a brewery controlling a number of pubs.

Corporate management identifies the outlets to receive investment funds and the nature of the investment to be made in each case. Managers of individual pubs have no discretion on how invest- ment funds are used.

Table 1 summarises the amounts invested in the four-year period 1988-1991 in pubs within the set of 155 pubs being studied. The table also shows the numbers of pubs that received investment funds each year. Amounts shown are in real (1988) prices.

The amount invested each year has on average remained relatively stable after a rise from 1988 to 1989. Total funds invested, however, have risen steadily as more and more pubs received invest- ment funds. It is noteworthy that maximum amounts invested rose too over time representing more substantial investments in the cases of certain pubs.

Estimates of 1>‘+l and I@‘+’ (see (2.4) nd (2.5)) were obtainable only for investments made during the period 1988-1990 as their estimation requires observations of at least one year after the invest- ments have taken place. There were 51 pubs that had investments in these three years but data for all four years was available for only 42 of them. The effects of investment on the market efficiency of these 42 pubs were studied.

3.1. An input-output set for assessing market eficiency of pubs using DEA

3. Disentangling market and investment effects on market efficiencies: An application

The method developed above was used to esti- mate the investment effectiveness of a set of public houses (pubs) owned by a brewery. The results were to be used to aid the selection of pubs to receive investments.

The input-output variables selected for assessing the market efficiency of the pubs are given in Table 2. The catchment area of a pub is taken as the area within a 2.5 miles radius from the pub.

Table 1

Capital investment in public houses (E’OOO per pub that received

investment that year)

The brewery owns several hundred pubs but the study focused on a subset of 155 pubs for which all the data required existed. Some 78 of these pubs had had capital invested in the period 1988-1991 and this was the period covered by the study. No pub had more than one investment of capital in the period under consideration.

Year

1988 1989 1990

1991

Pubs with Average Maximum Minimum

investment per pub in any pub in any pub

7 137763 191748 61652

18 146384 253 342 63 868

26 147 252 339 303 49712

27 147 675 554 534 34644

Page 6: Assessing marginal impacts of investments on the performance of organisational units

154 A.D. Athanassopoulos, E. Thanassoulisllnt. J. Production Economics 39 (1995) 149-164

The variables in Table 2 were arrived at after much deliberation and discussions with corporate management. Pricing, target clientele and invest- ments at a pub are the preserve of the controlling brewery. The assessment therefore seeks to reflect the efficiency of pub management in attracting cus- tom given the decisions made centrally by the brewery about the pub’s operations.

The turnover, our output, is the sum of revenues from the sale of drinks and meals.

Our input variables are intended to reflect the potential for revenue generation by a pub. Pub management’s effectiveness in converting this po- tential to actual revenue is reflected in the measure of market efficiency.

The input variables can be classified into internal and external. Internal variables reflect factors deci- ded upon by the brewery. External variables reflect environmental factors outside the brewery’s con- trol. None of the input variables is controllable by pub management. This approach ties in with our aim that market efficiency should be with reference to actual sales potential in a pub’s catchment area and not as that potential might be influenced by managerial action. For example a pub manager employing lower levels of labour than his/her mar- ket size requires should not be permitted to claim high market efficiency simply because sales are high relative to labour levels when in fact those sales are low for the market size in which the pub operates.

3. I. I. Internal inputs These are:

l bar area (ft’), l state of repair, . no. of car park spaces.

The bar area of a pub reflects its capacity to accommodate customers. Clearly the larger this area the more customers can be accommodated and the larger should be the revenue generated. This can disadvantage pubs which are given by the brewery a large area requiring them to attract a much larger share of their local market to fill up than is the case for most other pubs. However, in the absence of further information it is implicitly assumed that bar area at each pub is not such that it would require a significant proportion of the local market to fill up.

Table 2 Variables for assessing the market efficiency

Inputs

Bar area (ft’)

State of repair No. of car park spaces

No. of competitors

output

Total turnover (MOO)

Consumption of alcohol (‘000 barrels) in the catchment area

No. of potential customers in the

catchment area

Average income per household (E’OOO)

in the catchment area

The number of car park spaces is an important variable as customers almost exclusively use the car as a means of transport to and from the pub.

The state ofrepair of a pub relates to its general decor, furnishings and fittings. This is thought to influence significantly a pub’s ability to attract custom.

There is little difficulty in measuring bar area and car park spaces, However, reflecting the state of repair of a pub is difficult. In the case of this study the state of repair of each pub was assessed on a scale from 1 to 15 by the marketing department. The investments whose efects on market ejiciency are the concern of this study are usually towards improving the state of repair of the pub.

Strictly speaking the state of repair is measured on an ordinal scale and so the variable should be treated within the DEA model used as a categorical one [16]. This was not done in our case for two reasons. The range of the variable, stretching from 1 to 15, is large enough to make it behave as if it was a continuous one. That is the 15 levels of repair used mean the change in the attractiveness of the pub from one level of repair to the next is not so drastic and so rounding repair levels obtained by using the variable as a continuous one does not represent very wild approximations to physical state. The second reason for not using state of repair as a categorical variable was to avoid loss of discrimination in assessing pubs with low state of repair as they would only have been comparable with few other pubs having the same or worse state of repair.

Page 7: Assessing marginal impacts of investments on the performance of organisational units

A.D. Athanassopoulos, E. Thanassoulis/Int. J. Production Economics 39 (1995) 149-164 155

3.1.2. External inputs The external variables chosen were as follows:

l no. of competitors, l consumption of alcohol (‘000 barrels) in the

catchment area, l no. of potential customers in the catchment

area, l average income per household (E’OOO) in the

catchment area. Competition needs to be overcome by pub manage- ment to attract custom. So it too must be allowed for in assessing market efficiency. The inverse of the number of competitors is used in the model so that the turnover of an efficient pub is expected to be lower, the larger the number of competitors in its catchment area, all else being equal. Inverting the number of competitors could have been avoided by using instead their difference from some large (sub- jectively decided) number. The two approaches give generally different efficiency estimates. For example for our 155 pubs (in 1991) the median market effi- ciency was 90% when the number of competitors

Clearly the approach adopted is important for

was inverted but only 88% when it was subtracted

the results obtained but there is to our knowledge little guidance in the literature on the best ap-

from 162 (160 being the maximum number of com-

proach. Discussions are offered by Charnes [3] and Golany and Roll [ 173 favouring using the “inverse”

petitors any pub faced in that year).

approach. This was the approach adopted in our case. It must be noted that in our case the invest- ment effectiveness being measured is a ratio of market efficiencies (see (2.5)). Hence the different efficiencies obtained with the two approaches to treating competition will not matter in themselves so long as the two efficiencies in (2.5) are affected in a similar way (overestimated or underestimated). Hopefully this limits to an extent the impact of the particular treatment chosen for competition on our investment effectiveness results. (Further discussion of the use of the number of competitors as an input variable in the assessment of market efficiency can also be found [22].)

It should be noted that the brewery owning the pubs of our study does not position them close enough to one another so that they compete. Con- sequently none of the competing pubs within the

catchment areas referred to above are owned by the brewery.

The potential number of customers of a pub and

The higher the consumption of alcohol in the catchment area of a pub, all else being equal, the

their average income are used to reflect the size of its

larger should be its turnover if it is effective in

market for the sale of meals. (They are in effect

attracting custom. Thus to judge the effectiveness of a pub in attracting custom we must allow for the consumption of alcohol in its catchment area and

surrogate measures for the value of pub meals con-

this explains the use of this variable as an input.

sumed in the catchment area of the pub which was not available.) Market surveys had found that the typical customer of the pubs assessed was a person aged 15-24 or 35-54 belonging to one of the socio- economic groups B, Cl and C2. (For a definition of socio-economic groups in the UK see [lS].) Based on this information and data from the Office of Population Censuses and Surveys an estimate was made of the number of potential customers in the catchment area of each pub. The average income per household in the catchment area of each pub was derived from commercial databases.

There is clearly a correlation between the popu- lation, its income per capita and the consumption of alcohol in the catchment area of a pub. However, the correlation is not perfect and so all three vari- ables are used in the model.

It is argued sometimes (see for example [19, p. 533) that variables such as our external ones, over which pubs have no control, should not be used as input or output variables in the way sugges- ted above. Instead, efficiencies should be estimated in the first instance using controllable input-output variables only. In a second stage, the uncontrol- lable variables can be used in the context of a re- gression analysis to explain the efficiency scores obtained. The key difference between this two-stage approach and the one-stage approach we have ad- opted for assessing market efficiency is that in the former inefficiencies are attributed to the external (uncontrollable) variables while in our approach efficiency is measured while controlling for external variables. On balance the one-stage approach was selected because it makes it possible to assess how effectively pubs on an individual basis exploit their

Page 8: Assessing marginal impacts of investments on the performance of organisational units

156 A.D. Athanassopoulos, E. Thanassoulisllnt. J. Production Economics 39 (1995) 149-164

uncontrollable factors to generate revenue. The two-stage approach would in the second stage esti- mate the impact on pub efficiency due to each uncontrollable factor but this would be an average impact estimated with reference to all pubs irre- spective of how effective they were in exploiting the factor. An additional difficulty with the two-stage approach is that it requires the specification of a parametric (regression) model with the inherent dangers of misspecification.

3.2. The DEA models used

Using (2.2) the market efficiency in year t + 1, E:z I, of pub j, which had an investment in year t can be estimated in Ml below.

(Ml) E!+ 1 JO = maxz

AjsZ

n

S.t. 1 /ijXfJ’ ’ < X:j’,’ Vi, j=l

i /zj= 1, j= 1

z free and lj 2 0 Yj = 1, . . . ,n,

The formulation in (Ml) is based on the DEA models developed by Banker and Morey [15] for treating uncontrollable inputs. (The Banker and Morey [15] model (19) p. 516 reduces to (Ml) when, as in our case, all inputs are uncontrollable and an output orientation is used.) x:j’ ’ and yi+ ’ represent the ith input and output level of pub j in year t + 1. It is recalled that Efi+‘, the market efficiency of pub j,, is the factor by which the pub can in principle multiply its revenue in year t + 1 if it was relatively efficient in attracting custom given the levels of its internal and external variables.

Variable returns to scale have been assumed in (Ml) because it is not reasonable to expect that if the input levels of an efficient pub are multiplied by some factor then its revenue would be multiplied by the same factor. The assumption of variable returns to scale prevents pubs from being penalised in the

assessment for operating at the wrong scale size. Scale of operation, as measured by the levels of the input variables, is decided by central rather than local pub management.

The variable returns to scale model (Ml) still uses scaling to construct input-output levels feas- ible in principle. It merely requires that the sum of scaled inputs and outputs should be convex combi- nations of observed input-output vectors. The use of scaling even within the convexity constraint does at first sight appear problematic, particularly so far as the state of repair variable is concerned which is an ordinal variable. Scaling of the inverse of the number of competitors used as an input is also problematic as the inverse lacks a physical mean- ing. However, the resulting convex combinations in both cases are in fact meaningful. It was noted earlier that the large number of levels of state of repair makes the variable all but continuous. Com- peting pubs ranged from 2 to 160 and so this variable too can be treated as continuous.

The estimated market efficiency go” of pub j, during year t + 1, had it had no investment at the end of year t, was assessed by modifying (Ml) above to model (M2) below. “Pub j,” without in- vestment is labelled as j^.

(M2) &+’ = maxq Ir,. 4

j=l

qfreeandpjaO ‘dj=l,..., j, ,..., n,j^,,

where X:j and J$ are as defined for (Ml), &” ’ & is the estimated turnover of pub j, during year t + 1 had it had no investment during year t. The next subsection outlines the method followed for com- puting these estimates. s, and sr are the subsets of inputs whose levels change and do not change,

Page 9: Assessing marginal impacts of investments on the performance of organisational units

A.D. Athanassopoulos, E. Thanassoulis/Int. J. Production Economics 39 (1995) 149-164 157

respectively, due to the investment in period t. These subsets generally vary with investments.

The inclusion of pub r0 in the set of “observed” input-output levels may at first appear odd. How- ever, if we assume that our estimated input-output levels of pub j, during period t + 1 reflect what would have held true had pub j, had no investment during period t then there is no reason to exclude these estimates from the input-output levels used to define the production possibility set for period t + 1. (The interested reader is referred to further discussions at this point in [20,21].)

3.3. Estimating the input-output levels of a pub

As noted above, it was necessary to estimate for the purposes of model (M2) the levels of the inputs and the output of pub j, during period t + 1 as they

The internal variables were not affected by the

would have been had there been no investment in

investments during the period considered except for the state of repair. This was only available for

the pub during period t.

1991, that is as it was after the investments had been made. This changed the interpretation of the efficiency &‘+ ’ obtained from (M2). @“’ is now an estimate o the market efficiency of pub j in year t + 1 as it would have been with investment in year t had its turnover in t + 1 merely rejected overall market size changes. Thus, Z>L+ ’ as defined in (2.5) still reflects the extent to which investment has enabled pub j to perform better than if it was merely following market size changes.

The output level (turnover) ~$>‘+‘y; for year t + 1 net of the effects of investment in year t was estimated as follows.

Let y; be the turnover of pub j during year t, y;, its revenue from the sale of drinks and yBj its revenue from the sale of meals during the same year. Then we have y; = &j + yhj. The sales of drinks yD: ’ and meals jGj:j’ as they would have been without investment in pub j in year t were estimated as follows:

(3.1)

and

(3.2)

where TD: and TMf represent the total sales of drinks (barrels) and number of meals served in the surrounding area of pub j in year t. yi, and y’&, were adjusted for inflation using the drink and food retail prices indices so that all monetary values used in (3.1) and (3.2) were constant at 1988 values. This ensures year on year comparisons reflect revenue changes net of inflation.

The estimated output level c#$” iyi for pub j dur- ing period t + 1 without investment in year t was

(3.3)

The estimated turover in pub j using (3.3) assumes that without investment in year t the pub would have registered in its drinks and meals sales the

It is recalled that each catchment area contained only one pub of the brewery. Therefore the invest-

same change as did the size of its market in these

ments of the brewery themselves generally (although not always) had a negligible effect on the

two areas.

overall market size in each catchment area. (No pub of those in which the brewery invested ac- counted for more than 20% of the market in its catchment area and in all but four cases such pubs accented for less than 8% of the market.)

All investments were completed within the finan- cial year in which the funds were allocated so that their effects on market efficiency should be appar- ent in a subsequent year. Disruption in the year of investment t could, however, lead to @‘+ 1 Y ’ being an underestmate of potential sales in year t + 1. This in turn can lead to an overestimate of I>‘+‘.

4. Results

Before looking at the investment effectiveness of pubs, their average market efficiency during each one of the four years 1988-1991 was computed using model (Ml). The aim was to obtain an over- view of how average market efficiency has changed in the light of continuing investments in the pubs.

Page 10: Assessing marginal impacts of investments on the performance of organisational units

158 A.D. Athanassopoulos. E. Thanassoulisllnt. J. Production Economics 39 (1995) 149-164

1988 1989 1990 1991

Year of Assessment

Fig. 1. Average market efficiency of pubs.

The results appear in Fig. 1, where efficiencies de- fined in (Ml) have been inverted to give 100/E:. This means the efficiency ratings in Fig. 1 represent the percentage of its potential revenue a pub realises.

Average efficiency is relatively stable during the four-year period, if somewhat down. This means that either investments have not narrowed in any way the average gap between the proportions of their potential revenue the pubs actually realise or investments have revealed an increasing potential for revenue generation. If potential revenue has risen then stable mean market efficiency means rising mean gross revenue. In the case of the pubs, however, mean gross revenue declined through re- cession. This still, however, cannot be taken to mean that investments have been ineffective. The revenue realised might have been lower still with- out investments.

The investment effectiveness indices I:(‘+’ of the pubs are summarised in Table 3. Qrl and Qr3 are, respectively, the first and third quartile. Note that pub numbers are cumulative.

The following observations can be made: _ The market eficiency of pubs that have invest-

ments is generally 3-5 percentage points higher than would be expected if their turnover had merely reflec- ted overall market changes. This can be deduced from the median value of

I:,‘+’ . m Table 3. The rise in market efficiency appears managerially if not statistically significant. The improved market efficiency of pubs with in- vestments can naturally not be taken at face value. The estimated turnover at a pub is subject to

Table 3 Investment effectiveness indices

Years of Number of pubs with 1’; t + L , assessment

(t to t + 1) 17”’ > 1 ,;‘+I < 1 Qrl Median Qr3

1988-1989 4

1989-1990 11

1990-1991 28

Total 43

2 1 .oo 1.03 1.04

8 0.93 1.02 1.07 14 0.94 1.05 1.08

24 0.94 1.03 1.07

uncertainty. Also there could be factors unrelated to investments that have generally influenced posit- ively the market efficiency of pubs with invest- ments. The approach does, however, at least indi- cate where investment of capital might have led to better sales than would otherwise have been the case. _ Consistency of investment eflectiveness is variable. Eighteen of the 42 pubs showed consistently invest- ment effectiveness above 1. Five had consistently investment effectiveness below 1. The remaining pubs had inconsistent results, with investment effec- tiveness some of the years above and the rest below 1. _ Investment effectiveness was associated with loca- tion of pubs. Pub locations were characterised suburban, main road or industrial estate. The null hypothesis of no association between pub location and invest- ment effectiveness was rejected at the 5% level of significance. Pubs located in suburbs appeared more likely to register better than expected

Page 11: Assessing marginal impacts of investments on the performance of organisational units

A.D. Athanassopoulos, E. Thanassoulis/lnt. J. Production Economics 39 (1995) 149-164 159

market efficiency. Thus, more generally the analysis can lead not only to the identification of individual DMUs but also to environments where invest- ments might be more effective in securing better than expected market efficiency. - There are signijicant d@erences in the investment eflectiveness of individual pubs. The interquartile range of the investment effec- tiveness in Table 3 is quite large, covering generally some 14 percentage points. Pub 19 registered the largest investment effectiveness at 1.45. It was from the year 1990 to 1991. Investment in it in 1990 was above average but substantially below the max- imum size of investment in that year. At the other extreme Pub 5 registered the lowest investment effectiveness at 0.66 from 1989 to 1990. It had an investment of average size. Clearly in both cases the size of the investment does not seem likely to ex- plain the investment effectiveness observed. There may, of course, be factors not reflected in the in- put-output variables used which can explain the apparent good performance of Pub 19 and the weak performance of Pub 5. The usefulness of the analysis lies in identifying pubs such as Pubs 5 and 19 which exhibit performance substantially at vari- ance with expectations. Their operations can be further analysed outside the DEA context to ident- ify the factors responsible and use the information to improve performance of pubs generally. - There are indications that investment effectiveness is highest immediately after an investment is made. This can be seen more clearly in Table 4, where the investment effectiveness ratio computed one, two and three years after the investment is shown. Note that I>‘+’ . 1s always computed for consecutive years but the investment itself could have occurred before t.

Table 4

Investment effectiveness I?‘+ ’ J

Years between the year of investment

and t + 1

Qrl Median Qr3 Sample size

1 0.94 1.046 1.08 42 2 0.86 1.02 1.065 19 3 0.95 0.96 1.03 6

The sample where there has been a third year of operation after investment is too small to be re- liable. However, the sample sizes for one and two full years of operation after the investment are fair and it does appear that market efficiency is higher than expected in the year following immediately the one in which an investment was made. This could be simply because disruption in the year of invest- ment has led to an underestimate of market effi- ciency as it would be the following year without investment. It could, however, also be indicating that the life of investment in general infrastructure (refurbishment, etc.) is relatively short and continu- ing investments are necessary if pubs are to progressively improve on market efficiency. Better estimates of sales due to market size changes alone could help resolve this uncertainty. - Pubs that show high pro&ability and market ejti- ciency prior to investment are likely to show high investment ejiectiveness. This can be deduced by looking at the results in Table 5. It shows the median market efficiency and profitabihty of pubs of each category before and after investment and of their investment effec- tiveness. Profitability was defined as the ratio of profit before tax to turnover.

The “stars” are pubs with high market efficiency and profitability. Pubs in the “?” category have low profitability and market efficiency. “Sleepers” have high profitability but low market efficiency. Finally, “dogs” have high market efficiency but low profit- ability.

Pubs in the “?” category (low efficiency and profit- ability) appear to show low investment effectiveness. However, their median profitability rises substantially after investment from 18% to 24%. Although the sample is small, one likely explanation is that these pubs, faced with decreasing revenues, showed better cost control which resulted in higher profitability. The indications are, however, that despite investment they are not exploiting their market potential in full.

Pubs in the “sleeper” and “dogs” categories ap- pear to offer no better market efficiency than might be expected without investment. Their investment effectiveness is about 1 but their profitability de- clines. Possibly no action was taken to contain costs in a decreasing gross revenue situation during the period covered by the study.

Page 12: Assessing marginal impacts of investments on the performance of organisational units

160

Table 5

A.D. Athanassopoulos, E. Thanassoulis/Int. J. Production Economics 39 (1995) 149-164

Investment effects for pubs of each category

Groups of pubs

Category No. of pubs

Prior to investments (median) After the investments (median)

Market Profitability Investment Profitability

efficiency effectiveness

“y 6 60.5 0.18 0.95 0.24

“Sleepers” 9 56.2 0.30 0.99 0.25 “Stars” 11 100 0.34 1.06 0.335

“Dogs” 16 100 0.24 1.005 0.19

“Stars” (high market efficiency and profitability prior to investment) appear to offer the highest investment effectiveness. Their profitability is vir- tually unchanged before and after investment but the improved market efficiency should result in higher gross profits than would be the case without investment. This tends to justify selecting “star” pubs for further investment. Clearly there is a case of studying operating practices at “star” pubs and transferring them to the rest of the pubs.

5. Conclusions

Investment in the infrastructure of trading out- lets is an important part of their short-term man- agement. This paper has developed a method to aid corporate management to select recipients of in- frastructure investments.

It was argued that it is not sufficient to merely contrast the market efficiency of a DMU before and after investment in order to determine how effective investment in its infrastructure has been. An allowance needs to be made for the fact that market DMUs operate in changing market sizes and the effects of these changes need to be disentan- gled from those of investments. The method de- veloped relies on contrasting the market efficiency at a DMU after investment with its market efficien- cy as it would have been without investment. In this way an estimate was made of the improvement of the market efficiency of a DMU which may be attributed to the funds invested in it.

An organisation controlling a set of market out- lets would normally have data on investments made on outlets in the past. The method developed

in this paper makes it possible to compute the in- vestment effectiveness of such outlets for each year. The information can be used in a number of ways: l to identify outlets and managements that offer

the best scope of returns to investment l to estimate how rapidly investment effectiveness

wears off after an investment is made. l environmental features conducive to good invest-

ment effectiveness. The method is intended to be an aid rather than

a sole instrument by which investments are di- rected. In particular, the method cannot direct in- vestments to outlets that have had no investment in the past. However, for ongoing organisations the proportion of outlets which never had an invest- ment should be very small and therefore should not present serious difficulties for the use of the method developed.

‘The method developed was illustrated using data from a set of 155 pubs. Data were available on investments made in 42 of these pubs in the four- year period 1988-1991. It was found that generally investment increased market efficiency. This, how- ever, appears to depend on location of the pub, as well as on their market efficiency and profitability prior to investment. Pubs with high efficiency and profitability before investment were more likely to improve their market efficiency while pubs with low efficiency and profitability appear to suffer lower market efficiency after investment.

The estimates of the effects on market efficiency that the method provides are subject to uncer- tainty. However, the method is useful at least for indicating those DMUs that are likely to secure a good return on market efficiency if further funds are invested in their infrastructure.

Page 13: Assessing marginal impacts of investments on the performance of organisational units

A.D. Athanassopoulos. E. Thanassoulisllnt. J. Production Economics 39 (1995) 149-164 161

References

[l] Boussofiane, A., Thanassoulis, E. and Dyson, R., 1991. Applied data envelopment analysis. Eur. J. Oper. Res., 52: l-15.

[2] Athanassopoulos, A. and Thanassoulis, E., 1991 Separat-

ing market efficiency from profitability and its implications for planning. Warwick Business School Research Papers

No. 35 (forthcoming in J. Oper. Res. Sot.)

[3] Charnes, A., Clark, C., Cooper, W. and Golany, B., 1985.

A development study of data envelopment analysis in

measuring the efficiency of maintenance units in the US air

forces. Ann. Opcr. Res., 2: 95-112.

[4] Clarke, R., 1992. Evaluating USAF vehicle maintenance

productivity over time: An application of data envelop-

ment analysis. Dec. Sci., 23: 376384.

[S] Fare, R., Grosskopf, S., Lindgren, B. and Roos, P., 1992.

Productivity changes in Swedish pharmacies 1980-1989:

A non-parametric malmquist approach. J. Productivity Anal., 3: 85-101.

[6] Tulkens, H. and Vanden Eeckaut, P., 1991. Non-frontier measures of efficiency, progress and regress, CORE

Discussion Paper 9155, Centre of Operational Research

and Econometrics, Universite Catholique de Louvain,

Belgium.

[7] Charnes, A., Cooper, W. and Rhodes, E., 1981. Evaluating

program and managerial efficiency: An application of data

envelopment analysis to program follow through. Mgmt.

Sci., 27: 668-697.

[S] Banker, R., Charnes, A. and Cooper, W., 1984. Some

models for estimating technical and scale inefficiencies in data envelopment analysis., Mgmt. Sci., 30: 1078-1092.

[9] Fare, R., Grosskopf, S. and Lovell, K., 1985. The Measure- ment of Efficiency of Production. Kluwer-Nijhoff, Dor-

drecht.

[lo] Thanassoulis, E. and Dyson, R., 1992. Estimating preferred targets input-output levels using data envelopment analy-

sis. Eur. J. Oper. Res., 56: 8&97.

[l l] Fried, H., Lovell, K. and Schmidt, S., 1993. The Measure-

ment of Productive Efficiency: Techniques and Applica- tions. Oxford University Press, New York.

[12] Dimsdale, N. and Horsewood, N., 1992. A model of the

UK economy in the interwar period. Eur. Econom. Rev.,

36: 702-709.

[13] Lanen, W. and Larcker, D., 1992. Executive compensation contract adoption in the electric utility industry. J. Ac-

counting Res., 30: 7(r93.

[14] Bollen, K., 1989. Structural Equations with Latent Vari- ables. Wiley, New York.

[15] Banker, R. and Morey, R., 1986. Efficiency analysis for

exogenously fixed inputs and outputs. Oper. Res., 34:

513-521.

[16] Banker, R. and Morey, R., 1986. The use of categorical variables in data envelopment analysis Mgmt. Sci., 32:

1613-1628.

[17] Golany, B. and Roll, Y., 1989. An application procedure

for DEA. OMEGA. Int. J. Mgmt. Sci., 17: 237-250

[18] Monk, D., 1986. Social grading and the national reader-

ship survey. Joint Industrial Committee for National

Readership Survey (JICNARS). [19] Lovell, K., 1993. Production frontiers and productive effi-

ciency, in: H. Fried, K. Love11 and S. Schmidt (Eds.), The

Measurement of Productive Efficiency: Techniques and

Applications. Oxford University Press, New York.

[20] Berg, S., Forsund, F. and Jansen, E., 1992. Malmquist

indices of productivity growth during the deregulation of Norwegian banking, 198G-1992. Stand. J. Econom., 94:

211-228. [21] Elyasiani, E. and Mehidian, S. 1990. A nonparametric

approach to measurement of efficiency and technological

change: The case of large US commercial banks. J. Finan- cial Services Res., 4: 157-168.

[22] Athanassopoulos A., (1994 under progress), Developing

decision support systems for target settign and resource

allocation in Multi-unit organisations using data enevelop ment analysis, PhD thesis, University of Warwick.