armed politics and the study of intrastate conflict · pdf filearmed politics and the study of...

21
Armed Politics and the Study of Intrastate Conflict Paul Staniland* East Asian Peace Program Department of Peace and Conflict Research Uppsala University and Assistant Professor of Political Science University of Chicago [email protected] Word Count: 6,467 Abstract: States and armed groups can have diverse political relationships, from tight cooperation to intense warfare. As a result, violence is not identical to conflict, but conflict research often conflates the two. These conceptual insights have not been turned into a systematic empirical research agenda. This paper makes the case for studying state-group interactions across space and time as part of an “armed politics” approach to conflict. It conceptualizes and measures state-group armed orders of alliance, limited cooperation, and military hostilities, and the termination of these orders in collapse or incorporation. The paper applies this framework to several cases in South Asia. It measures armed orders across five groups and six decades in Nagaland, and then offers a briefer overview of state-group armed orders in Karachi, Mizoram, and northern Burma/Myanmar. These cases suggest that examining armed orders helps us better understand ceasefires and peace deals, rebel governance, and group emergence and collapse, among other substantively important topics. The armed politics approach valuably complements existing data on civil conflict, particularly in contexts where groups do not reliably align with or against the state, and/or in which datasets disagree about the existence of a conflict. The paper concludes by identifying new empirical and theoretical horizons for research on violence, order, and conflict. *Acknowledgments: Thanks to Christian Davenport, Sana Jaffrey, Joakim Kreutz, Janet Lewis, Ben Lessing, Katy Lindquist, Mashail Malik, Aila Matanock, Nicholas Miller, Monika Nalepa, Vipin Narang, Sarah Parkinson, Paul Poast, Lee Seymour, Caitlin Talmadge, Steven Wilkinson, three anonymous reviewers, and JPR Associate Editor Desiree Nilsson for comments on this paper. Katy Lindquist, Morgane Martinet, and Jonathan Weatherwax provided valuable research assistance.

Upload: doandat

Post on 08-Mar-2018

216 views

Category:

Documents


1 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Armed Politics and the Study of Intrastate Conflict · PDF fileArmed Politics and the Study of Intrastate Conflict ... I show how conventional approaches miss ... I scope the armed

Armed Politics and the Study of Intrastate Conflict

Paul Staniland*

East Asian Peace Program Department of Peace and Conflict Research

Uppsala University and

Assistant Professor of Political Science University of Chicago [email protected]

Word Count: 6,467

Abstract: States and armed groups can have diverse political relationships, from tight cooperation to intense warfare. As a result, violence is not identical to conflict, but conflict research often conflates the two. These conceptual insights have not been turned into a systematic empirical research agenda. This paper makes the case for studying state-group interactions across space and time as part of an “armed politics” approach to conflict. It conceptualizes and measures state-group armed orders of alliance, limited cooperation, and military hostilities, and the termination of these orders in collapse or incorporation. The paper applies this framework to several cases in South Asia. It measures armed orders across five groups and six decades in Nagaland, and then offers a briefer overview of state-group armed orders in Karachi, Mizoram, and northern Burma/Myanmar. These cases suggest that examining armed orders helps us better understand ceasefires and peace deals, rebel governance, and group emergence and collapse, among other substantively important topics. The armed politics approach valuably complements existing data on civil conflict, particularly in contexts where groups do not reliably align with or against the state, and/or in which datasets disagree about the existence of a conflict. The paper concludes by identifying new empirical and theoretical horizons for research on violence, order, and conflict. *Acknowledgments: Thanks to Christian Davenport, Sana Jaffrey, Joakim Kreutz, Janet Lewis, Ben Lessing, Katy Lindquist, Mashail Malik, Aila Matanock, Nicholas Miller, Monika Nalepa, Vipin Narang, Sarah Parkinson, Paul Poast, Lee Seymour, Caitlin Talmadge, Steven Wilkinson, three anonymous reviewers, and JPR Associate Editor Desiree Nilsson for comments on this paper. Katy Lindquist, Morgane Martinet, and Jonathan Weatherwax provided valuable research assistance.

Page 2: Armed Politics and the Study of Intrastate Conflict · PDF fileArmed Politics and the Study of Intrastate Conflict ... I show how conventional approaches miss ... I scope the armed

2

The Kachin Independence Organization (KIO) is one of Asia’s most resilient armed

groups groups. Founded in 1961, it was a determined foe of the Burmese military for decades.1

Yet from 1993 to 2010, it drops out of the most detailed dataset on armed conflict because it

signed a ceasefire in 1992 and did not resume hostilities until 2011.2 During this period, the KIO

continued to govern civilians, mobilize military forces, and bargain with the state, even though it

was not actively fighting. This is an example of the broader phenomenon of “armed politics”:

whether Kurdish pesh merga, Shiite militias, and Sunni armed groups in Iraq, private armies in

the Philippines, or the armed wings of political parties in Pakistan, many armed actors oscillate

between conflict and cooperation with governments. Some eventually merge into the state, others

fight protracted wars, and yet others maintain steady spheres of influence with the government.

These cases suggest that conflict should not always be conflated with violence.

Ceasefires, peace deals, rebel governance, and armed group emergence and collapse can occur in

periods marked by little violence, while distinctions between insurgents, militias, and electoral

violence are often variable, not fixed. Recent research has pointed out many of these nuances and

puzzles, but conceptual and case-based insights have not been turned into a broader empirical

research agenda.3 This article offers a way to build on previous work by systematically

measuring armed orders in South Asian cases and using this research to identify the costs and

benefits of studying state-group interactions across levels of violence.

Exploring armed politics has two advantages. First, it allows systematic comparisons

between armed orders of alliance, limited cooperation, and military hostilities, as well as their

termination in either collapse or group incorporation. Violence is undoubtedly important, but

1 Smith 1999. 2 Gleditsch et al. 2002. The most updated version of these data is Themner and Wallensteen 2014. 3 Reno 2011, Staniland 2012, Mukhopadhyay 2014, Day and Reno 2014, Keen 1998, Tull 2005.

Page 3: Armed Politics and the Study of Intrastate Conflict · PDF fileArmed Politics and the Study of Intrastate Conflict ... I show how conventional approaches miss ... I scope the armed

3

these armed orders (and their termination) can all exist in its absence.4 Studying armed politics

helps us understand shifts between orders across dyads and over time within them, and it can

improve how we study other important outcomes like variation in rebel governance and the

signing of peace agreements. Second, the armed politics approach integrates diverse types of

armed groups under a shared framework. Militias, insurgents, and armed electoral groups can all

be part of similar armed orders. This lets us compare across otherwise disparate types of groups.

Research on armed orders, however, is very resource-intensive and cannot be easily

pursued across a large number of countries. Rather than replacing existing cross-national data,

therefore, the armed politics approach can instead complement them. It will be most useful in

complex political environment in which armed actors do not align consistently with or against

the state and governments and groups continue to interact across different levels of violence.

Armed politics lets scholars study these contexts at a fine-grained level while still using a shared

approach that can travel across cases.

This paper first unifies existing intuitions under the analytical framework of armed orders

and their termination. It then provides a detailed examination of a context, Nagaland in India,

that existing datasets struggle to represent. I show how conventional approaches miss important

variation that can inform theories of conflict dynamics and outcomes. Briefer discussion of other

cases from South Asia illustrates the value-added of the armed politics approach. The paper

concludes with a discussion of when and where studying armed orders will be most and least

helpful, the empirical challenges and opportunities associated with this agenda, and new

theoretical directions for studying the origins and evolution of armed orders.

4 Fearon and Laitin 2003, Sambanis 2004, Gleditsch et al. 2002, Carey et al. 2013, and Sundberg et al. 2012 focus on violence as central to civil war/armed conflict.

Page 4: Armed Politics and the Study of Intrastate Conflict · PDF fileArmed Politics and the Study of Intrastate Conflict ... I show how conventional approaches miss ... I scope the armed

4

Armed Politics

The core of armed politics is the existence of multiple armed political actors within the

territory of a state.5 Recent research has begun to probe these complex dynamics of cooperation

and conflict. Yet these critiques and conceptual arguments do not provide a simple way to

measure and compare state-group interactions. Here I offer one way to build on these valuable

insights and embed them in an empirical research agenda.6

I identify three armed orders between a state and an armed group – hostilities, limited

cooperation, and alliance – and two forms of termination – collapse and incorporation.7 These

can be measured over time within state-groups dyads. For instance, Sunni groups in Iraq’s Anbar

province shifted from hostilities to limited cooperation to alliance and, in some cases, back to

military hostilities between 2003 and 2015. Armed orders can be compared across dyads: the

limited cooperation between the Pakistani military and the Mullah Nazir group in South

Waziristan is different than hostilities between the military and Maulana Fazlullah’s Tehrik-i-

Taliban Pakistan (TTP).8 This approach builds most clearly on Staniland’s “wartime political

orders,”9 but simplifies that framework, applies it much more broadly to non-wartime contexts,

and identifies pathways through which orders come to an end.

Scope

Armed politics begins when an armed group emerges as a coherent actor and begins to

interact with and/or make claims on the government. We need clear evidence of cadres being

training and equipped with lethal weaponry under the control of a leadership group within a

5 Kalyvas 2003, Staniland 2012b. 6 This work draws inspiration from the dyadic approaches found in Gleditsch et al. 2002 and Cunningham et al. 2009, but with a broader conceptual, and thus empirical, focus. 7 Though I focus in this paper on state-group dynamics, the basic framework is applicable to relationships among different armed groups as well. Christia 2012, Cunningham et al 2012, Krause 2013/14. 8 Bergen 2013. 9 Staniland 2012.

Page 5: Armed Politics and the Study of Intrastate Conflict · PDF fileArmed Politics and the Study of Intrastate Conflict ... I show how conventional approaches miss ... I scope the armed

5

formal organization. I scope the armed politics approach to organizations that make public

political demands of some sort and that exist with a formal command structure for at least one

year. This means that “pure” criminal organizations and highly transient actors are not included,

substantially limiting the range of relevant groups.10 After armed politics begins, state-group

political relationships can be traced over time, identifying in each year (or a more fine-grained

period of time) the armed order between the group and state, and whether or not the dyad

terminates.

Armed Orders

Hostilities orders involve the deployment of military forces by both a group and a

government that are intended to inflict harm on one another: military offensives, regular

insurgent operations, and a belief on both sides that they are engaged in a contest of military

power. Hostilities orders sometimes involve little violence, especially in low-intensity

“containment” conflicts, but they can also involve huge amounts of violence accompanying total

internal warfare. Evidence of hostilities is found in the operational activities of state and armed

group armed forces, with mutual targeting, consistent force deployments, and clear strategies for

imposing costs on the other actor.

A limited cooperation order is constituted by formal ceasefires or informal live-and-let-

live bargains between a state and armed group. Some form of arrangement limits mutual

violence without formal demobilization, a full peace settlement, or military victory. Both

continue to exist as distinct actors engaged in bargaining. Unlike in hostilities, we do not see

sustained military offensives by either side, and force deployments are limited geographically

and/or functionally (leadership decapitation tends to be avoided, for instance). Unlike in alliance

orders, there is not tight policy coordination toward shared purposes, but instead a delimitation of 10 On logics of criminal conflict, see Lessing 2015.

Page 6: Armed Politics and the Study of Intrastate Conflict · PDF fileArmed Politics and the Study of Intrastate Conflict ... I show how conventional approaches miss ... I scope the armed

6

territorial and functional authority and the maintenance of “rules” of interaction.11 This can

involve formal agreements, such as ceasefires or peace deals, that minimize conflict without

either side disarming. Limited cooperation can also involve informal understandings between

governments and armed actors.

Alliance orders are characterized by tight, institutionalized cooperation between a state

and armed group, generally with targeting of a shared enemy, observable coordination of

policies, and sharing of organizational resources.12 These are not tacit arrangements or live-and-

let-live deals, as in limited cooperation. Instead the security apparatus closely and consistently

operates alongside and in dialogue with armed groups. Coding an alliance order requires

evidence of government support for armed actors and regular coordination between them.

How Armed Orders End

These orders end in two ways: collapse or incorporation. Since groups often continue to

operate even when not engaged in conflict with the state, lack of violence cannot be equated with

the lack of an armed group. We need to assess whether it continues to interact with the state.

Collapse occurs when the group cannot consistently mobilize followers or engage in

basic organizational activities. The group no longer exists, or cannot sustain activities related to

revenue extraction, military mobilization, recruitment, or political claim making. This may be the

result of military destruction or of internal dissension that undermine organizational

organization. In rare cases, collapse can go in the other direction, with military victory by

revolutionary or secessionist armed groups. Incorporation, by contrast, occurs when a group

demobilizes its armed capacity as part of a formal or informal deal with the government that

eliminates it an autonomous armed actors.

11 This resembles what Staniland 2012 refers to as “passive cooperation.” See also Reno 2011 and Richards 2004. 12 Christia 2012.

Page 7: Armed Politics and the Study of Intrastate Conflict · PDF fileArmed Politics and the Study of Intrastate Conflict ... I show how conventional approaches miss ... I scope the armed

7

Understanding Other Outcomes

Studying these orders helps us understand other conflict dynamics. First, studying armed

orders can provide valuable new evidence on the creation, organization, and end of groups.

Many groups emerge and organize themselves prior to any violence occurring, others collapse

after years of low activity, and yet others are incorporated into the state after long periods of

negotiating and bargaining. The Tamil Tigers, for instance, were born well before the standard

start date of the civil war, while the People’s Liberation Organisation of Tamil Eelam continued

to exist even after it stopped fighting the state. The “organizational turn”13 in studies of armed

groups seeks to explain the trajectories of groups. By more comprehensively measuring their

origins, structures, and pathways of termination we can better test theories about these groups,

while still examining their interactions with states.

Second, the signing and implementation of ceasefires and peace deals frequently occur in

situations that do not meet necessary death thresholds to be included as a civil war. Kreutz shows

that many conflict episodes end in an “other” form of termination, and armed politics provides

one reason why: deals are culminated only after negotiations during in which both sides reduce

violence.14 In complex political environments, existing data on ceasefires and peace deals can be

valuably supplemented with armed orders research. This will help us understand when and how

incorporation deals are signed/implemented, and when instead active fighting comes to an end

through alliance, collapse, or limited cooperation. The dynamics of the eastern Democratic

Republic of Congo are an excellent example: there are multiple pathways through which

13 Weinstein 2007, Cohen 2013, Wood and Gutierrez-Sanin 2014. 14 Kreutz 2010.

Page 8: Armed Politics and the Study of Intrastate Conflict · PDF fileArmed Politics and the Study of Intrastate Conflict ... I show how conventional approaches miss ... I scope the armed

8

violence has fallen, ranging from group collapse to enduring limited cooperation or alliance to

incorporation.15

Third, armed group governance, whether by rebels, militias, or other actors, occurs across

armed orders. Governance is certainly useful during high-intensity civil wars, but is also

extensively deployed to pursue political and economic influence in low violence contexts as

well.16 The KIO in Burma did not stop governing when it stopped fighting the state, and

Hezbollah has governed throughout periods of both active fighting and cold “peace.” Exploring

these kinds of cases contributes comparative data to our understanding of armed group

governance and how it may be related to different armed orders.

Armed Politics in South Asia

This section uses on new empirical research on South Asia to better identify the benefits

and limits of armed politics as a research agenda. It focuses on state-group interactions that

existing datasets either disagree with or do not include. First, I measure armed orders in one of

the world’s most complex and protracted conflict environments, Nagaland in India. Existing

datasets disagree with one another over the existence, timing, and relevant actors in this context.

This makes it a valuable opportunity to show whether and how the armed orders framework can

complement and move beyond conventional approaches. Second, I briefly code armed orders in

state-group dyads in Mizoram, Karachi, and northern Burma/Myanmar to illustrate that armed

politics can provide a unifying framework for measurement and comparison across cases. In all

of these cases, I use qualitative research to build new, quantifiable, data.17

15 Stearns et al. 2013. 16 Arjona et al. ed 2016 (2015?) 17 Though there are no missing data in this specific set of codings, missing data is another possible coding in a dyad/year.

Page 9: Armed Politics and the Study of Intrastate Conflict · PDF fileArmed Politics and the Study of Intrastate Conflict ... I show how conventional approaches miss ... I scope the armed

9

Nagaland

Background and Existing Representations

Since 1955, state-group interactions in Naga areas of India have involved multiple armed

groups, a major peace deal, and several rounds of negotiations and ceasefires, alongside

continual Indian military operations.18 UCDP/PRIO codes an active conflict between the Indian

government and the Naga National Council (NNC) from 1956-1968, when Kreutz identifies an

“Other/Low Activity” episode termination.19 It then recurs as an armed conflict from 1992-1997

and 2000 on the part of the National Socialist Council of Nagaland-Isaac/Muivah (NSCN-IM).20

Toft codes Nagaland as a war that ended in 1997, while Fearon and Laitin and Sambanis both

appear to include it as part of a single war in the Northeast beginning in 1952 and 1990,

respectively.21 Neither Fortna nor Harbom et al. code ceasefires or peace deals related to the

conflict, and Walter’s coding of state responses to Naga demands involves no accommodation.22

Research on armed orders provides a different picture. There have been five substantial

armed groups: the NNC and NSCN-IM are joined by the NSCN-Khaplang (NSCN-K),

Revolutionary Government of Nagaland (RGN) and the original NSCN. They have operated for

approximately 79 group-years between 1956 and 2013, compared to the three groups and 24

group-years identified in previous work.23 The NSCN-IM and NSCN-K have changed their

relationships with the state over time, shifting from hostilities to limited cooperation, and then 18 Bhaumik 2009; Chasie 1999. 19 Kreutz 2010. 20 Gleditsch et al. 2002. Cunningham et al. 2013 draws on this coding, though the most recent version of the UCDP/PRIO Armed Conflict Dataset, in Themner and Wallensteen 2014, does not include any conflict between the NSCN-K and India (instead, the NSCN-K only appears in clashes with the Burma/Myanmar government between 2000 and 2007). 21 Fearon and Laitin 2003, Sambanis 2004. Toft 2010 is unclear – the case notes suggest termination in 1975, but the apparent actual coding of termination is 1997. Compare p. 2 and p. 24 of Data Appendix for Toft 2010, at <http://www.bsg.ox.ac.uk/sites/blavatnik/files/documents/MTcodebook2010_0.pdf>. 22 Fortna 2008, Harbom et al. 2006, Hogbladh 2011, Walter 2006. 23 22 for the NNC; 5 for RGN; 8 for NSCN; 22 for NSCN-IM; 22 for NSCN-K. By contrast, Cunningham et al. 2013 code 13 years for NNC; 8 for NSCN-IM; 3 for NSCN-K. See <http://privatewww.essex.ac.uk/~ksg/eacd.html>.

Page 10: Armed Politics and the Study of Intrastate Conflict · PDF fileArmed Politics and the Study of Intrastate Conflict ... I show how conventional approaches miss ... I scope the armed

10

more recently back to hostilities for the NSCN-K. The RGN was an ally of the Indian

government for five years before being incorporated into the state in 1973. The NSCN collapsed

into a pair of fratricidal splinters, the NSCN-K and NSCN-IM, in 1988. We see ceasefires from

1964-1972 (with the NNC), 1997-present (with the NSCN-IM), and 2001-2015 (NSCN-K), as

well as the Shillong Accord peace deal in 1975. In 2015, the NSCN-IM also signed a peace deal,

though it has not yet been implemented.

Armed Orders in Nagaland

Table 1. Measuring Armed Politics in Nagaland

NNC NSCN NSCN-IM NSCN-K RGN Hostilities, 1955-1964; Limited Cooperation 1964-1972; Hostilities 1972-1975; Incorporation, 1975

Hostilities, 1978-1988; Collapse, 1988

Hostilities, 1988-1997; Limited Cooperation, 1997-present; Peace deal signed but not yet implemented, 2015

Hostilities, 1988-2001; Limited Cooperation, 2001-2015; Hostilities, 2015-present

Alliance, 1968-1973; Incorporated, 1973

The NNC was in military hostilities with the Indian state from 1955 until the ceasefire of

1964, brokered by the Naga Peace Mission.24 From 1964-1967, it was engaged in direct talks

with the Indian government. From 1968 until 1972 the ceasefire continued, but clashes occurred

as the two sides probed one another and the NNC tried to infiltrate weapons from China.25 1964-

1972 is therefore a period of limited cooperation, even as there were deaths in combat and

attacks during some years. In 1968, the RGN split from the NNC and allied with the Indian

24 Guha 2007, 391. 25 Verghese 1996, 89-94.

Page 11: Armed Politics and the Study of Intrastate Conflict · PDF fileArmed Politics and the Study of Intrastate Conflict ... I show how conventional approaches miss ... I scope the armed

11

government against the NNC, acting as a de facto pro-state paramilitary force.26 It was

incorporated into the state government in 1973.27

In 1972, the Indian government ended the ceasefire and banned the NNC, launching a

major offensive against the group that badly degraded it.28 After three years of hostilities, NNC

elements then signed the 1975 Shillong Accord peace deal, leading to the incorporation of the

NNC.29 This deal led to the rise of a disgruntled splinter group, the National Socialist Council of

Nagaland (NSCN), which formed in the 1978-80 period and went back to war with the Indian

state.30 A new armed order was born, characterized by military hostilities. The actual levels of

violence in the 1980s were relatively low, as the NSCN adopted a strategy of protracted guerrilla

warfare, but India’s Ministry of Home Affairs continued to treat Nagaland as a disturbed area

even in years with few fatalities.31 Participants unambiguously understood this as a context of

conflict.

The NSCN split into two factions, the –IM and –K, in 1988.32 They each operated in

Manipur, Nagaland, Burma/Myanmar, and other states in the Northeast, with violence increasing

in the 1990s. However, the NSCN-IM signed a ceasefire with the government in 1997 and the

NSCN-K followed in 2001.33 Both ceasefires lasted until 2015, creating two long stretches of

limited cooperation. The NSCN factions during this time were deeply involved in extorting

money from businesses, influencing government bureaucrats, bargaining with government

26 Horam 1988, 146-151; Dev 1988, 82. 27 Bhaumik 2009, 97; Verghese 1996, 94; Das 2005, 206-7; Horam 1988, 143-151. 28 Nehru 1997, 520. 29 Dev 1988, 98-114. 30 Verghese 1996, 95. 31 For instance, MHA 1982-3, 2; MHA 1987-88, 8. 32 Bhaumik 2009, 99; Goswami 2007, 138. 33 Rajagopalan 2007, 16.

Page 12: Armed Politics and the Study of Intrastate Conflict · PDF fileArmed Politics and the Study of Intrastate Conflict ... I show how conventional approaches miss ... I scope the armed

12

negotiators, clashing with one another, and trying to control social and political life, even though

they not fighting state forces.34

In 2015, the NSCN-K ended its limited cooperation and is now engaged again in military

hostilities, while the NSCN-IM signed a peace deal, though it is still technically on ceasefire.

Rather than hard distinctions between war and peace, armed politics in this context has taken a

number of distinct trajectories, from the collapse of the NNC to the incorporation of the RGN to

limited cooperation between the state and NSCN factions. These orders are essential to

understanding the broader politics of India’s volatile Northeast because of Naga groups’ links to

other insurgents and their impact on neighboring states.

Rethinking Data on Peace Deals and Group “Types”

This empirical analysis reveals two important ways armed politics can complement

existing approaches. First, extant data on concessions, peace deals, and ceasefires have not

accurately measured Naga history. Walter codes this conflict as involving no accommodation or

concessions, but in 1957 (Delhi Agreement), 1963 (creation of state of Nagaland), and 1963-4

(Naga Peace Mission) we see exactly this.35 This matters for theory testing: the case is in tension

with Walter’s claim that states will aggressively crack down on early separatists to prevent

demonstration effects. Indian governments have instead cut numerous deals with ethno-linguistic

and tribal armed groups, though not religious separatists.36 The ceasefires from 1963-1972,

1997-present, and 2001-2015 endured for substantial periods without the international

peacekeeping that Fortna argues is crucial to the duration of ceasefires.37 Finally, my study

identifies the 1975 Shillong Accord, which is missed in the UCDP dataset on peace agreements

34 Interviews in Dimapur and Kohima in October 2013. 35 Walter 2006. 36 Staniland 2015b; Saez et al. 2012, Brass 1974. 37 Fortna 2008. Although it falls within the temporal range of her study, the 1997 NSCN-IM ceasefire is not included in Fortna’s data.

Page 13: Armed Politics and the Study of Intrastate Conflict · PDF fileArmed Politics and the Study of Intrastate Conflict ... I show how conventional approaches miss ... I scope the armed

13

because it occurred in a year with relatively little violence.38 Actors may sign agreements after

already reducing military operations during negotiation; only looking at periods of violence

misses this set of cases.

Second, Nagaland shows the limits of trying to fit groups into clear insurgent vs. militia

categories. The NSCN-IM, for instance, has both fought the state and engaged in limited

cooperation with it. The same group, with the same structures and leadership, has acted in ways

similar to a militia, an insurgent, and a criminal group. Similar shifts in political roles occurred in

both the RGN and the NSCN-K. Hard distinctions between “types” can obscure more than they

reveal when it comes to group organization, governance, and strategy.

Other Cases in South Asia

Nagaland is a particularly useful context because of its complexity and variation, but the

armed orders approach can be applied more broadly. Here I identify armed orders in three other

South Asian cases, showing that we can use the armed politics framework to compare across

contexts.

Karachi is Pakistan’s dominant source of urban political violence. There is no consensus

about its status in the civil war literature, specifically the interactions between the Muttahida

Qaumi Movement Party (MQM) and the government. Kalyvas and Balcells argue that violence

in the city was actually communal rioting and do not include it as a civil war, a non-coding Toft

agrees with.39 Fearon and Laitin code it as a civil war from 1994-1999.40 Gleditsch et al. code

four years of armed conflict (1990, 1994-96)41, while the UCDP Non-State Conflict Dataset

38 Harbom et al. 2006. 39 Kalyvas and Balcells 2010, Toft 2010. 40 Fearon and Laitin 2003. 41 Gleditsch et al. 2002, Themner and Wallensteen 2014. Cunningham et al. 2013 code the MQM as operating in 1990, 1995, and 1996.

Page 14: Armed Politics and the Study of Intrastate Conflict · PDF fileArmed Politics and the Study of Intrastate Conflict ... I show how conventional approaches miss ... I scope the armed

14

codes it as involving non-state conflict between the MQM and MQM-Haqiqi in 1991-1995 and

1997-1998.42

Studying armed orders helps make Karachi’s politics more “legible” to researchers. I find

that the MQM was part of limited cooperation orders in 1985-1989, 1997-8, 1999-2002, and

2008-present; it was part of an alliance order during 1990-1991 with Nawaz Sharif and 2002-

2008 with Pervez Musharraf. It was targeted in hostilities from 1992-1996 and more briefly

during 2011 and 2015. Rather than having to choose which years count as armed conflict, non-

state conflict, or peace, we can study all of them through the same framework.

Karachi also presents an opportunity to compare violence levels with armed orders.43 In

1992, when the Army launched a major operation against the MQM, there were comparatively

few deaths in Karachi: the MQM strategically withdrew rather than standing and fighting.44 In

1996, another year of military crackdowns, violence was actually lower than in 1997, when the

Sharif government welcomed the MQM back into the fold. Yet in 1995, an explosion of violence

accompanied an offensive against the MQM.45 The same number of deaths can have radically

different political meanings. In turn, similar armed orders may involve very different death

counts: the alliance order in 1991 was much bloodier than the alliance order in 2003. This does

not mean that violence data is unimportant, but instead that it is not always a good guide to state-

group interactions.

Studying armed orders in Karachi also shows that, as in Nagaland, the exact same group

can move between diverse political roles. The MQM has acted at various points like an

insurgent, pro-state militia, and armed electoral group, yet it has had the same leader and

42 Sundberg et al. 2012. 43 Violence data from 1994-2012 are drawn from Gayer 2014, 10; earlier and later dates rely on press accounts. 44 Bakhtiar 1992, 38. 45 Herald 1996.

Page 15: Armed Politics and the Study of Intrastate Conflict · PDF fileArmed Politics and the Study of Intrastate Conflict ... I show how conventional approaches miss ... I scope the armed

15

structure throughout. It has governed, coerced, and contested elections throughout its lifecycle.

The armed politics approach helps us better understand such groups that “fuse militancy and

governance, disruption and political convention.”46

In Mizo areas of Northeast India, we see a conflict between 1966 and 1986, culminating

in the 1986 Mizo Accord, the most successful peace deal in Indian history. Existing datasets

generally have little to say about Mizoram, folding it into the larger “Northeast” conflict. The

exception is PRIO/UCDP’s Armed Conflict dataset, which codes a conflict between 1966-1968.

Examining armed politics identifies more complex variation. There were hostilities during 1966-

1976, 1977-1979, and 1981-1983 (at different levels of intensity). In 1976, 1980, and 1984 there

were periods of limited cooperation during ceasefires and negotiations.47 This dyad ended in the

incorporation of the Mizo National Front (MNF) via the Mizo Accord in 1986. Systematically

explaining the origins and success/failure of peace agreements requires examining both violent

and non-violent interactions between states and armed groups.

Finally, the United Wa State Army in Burma/Myanmar’s Shan State is not a traditional

insurgent group. It emerged from the wreckage of the Communist Party of Burma (CPB) in

1989,48 and Kreutz shows it involved in only one year of armed conflict, in 1997. Yet it is also

not a standard pro-state militia, due to its often-tense relations with the military.49 This force has

20,000 men under arms and controls large swathes of territory along the Chinese border, so it is

neither transient nor tiny, but there is no obvious place for it in existing literature. Studying it

through the armed orders lens allows us to compare it to other groups: the UWSA has been part

of a sustained limited cooperation order almost continuously since 1989, with a brief slide into

46 Gayer 2014, 120. 47 Bhaumik 2009, 103-105; Verghese 1996, 147-149. 48 Lintner 1990. 49 Kramer 2007, 3. Kreutz 2010.

Page 16: Armed Politics and the Study of Intrastate Conflict · PDF fileArmed Politics and the Study of Intrastate Conflict ... I show how conventional approaches miss ... I scope the armed

16

hostilities in 1997, divvying up power and authority with the government while running its own

independent governance and illicit economic networks.50

Armed Politics and the Study of Conflict

There are advantages and disadvantages to using armed orders as an empirical unit of

analysis. Carefully tracking state-group relationships is data-intensive, requiring substantial

investments in fieldwork and specialized literature. There is a possibility of opening a “Pandora’s

box” in which the relevant number of actors and events expands beyond tractability. The scope

conditions I offered above do reduce this challenge, but tracking individual groups across levels

of violence remains an undoubtedly major empirical task. Interdependence between dyads and

the complexities of multi-actor conflicts pose other important problems.51 These costs mean that

straightforward civil wars will often not require research on armed politics. Existing datasets do

an excellent job in identifying clear cases of large-scale hostilities between states and insurgents.

If there is little evidence of more complex dynamics in a context, then researchers can rely on

traditional approaches to understand it.

The armed orders framework is instead most valuable in contexts 1) about which datasets

disagree, 2) in which there are ambiguous groups and years of armed conflict, and 3) actors that

do not fall straightforwardly into the insurgent/militia dichotomy. The best cross-national data

collection efforts have carefully identified unclear and borderline cases that create a preexisting

set of candidates for deeper study.52 Kreutz specifically identifies this potential complementary:

“By including unclear case observations, researchers would have more observations in the form

of longer time series and more countries/organizations, with potentially improved analytical

50 Ibid., 37-45. 51  Poast  2010.  52 Kreutz 2015; Salehyan 2015.

Page 17: Armed Politics and the Study of Intrastate Conflict · PDF fileArmed Politics and the Study of Intrastate Conflict ... I show how conventional approaches miss ... I scope the armed

17

leverage.”53 Armed orders establish a shared framework for comparing across and within these

contexts, instead of one-off case studies that do not cumulate.

Given extensive within-country variation in armed orders over space and time, country-

and region-level studies can generate substantial numbers of observations that facilitate broader

generalizations. In a distinct research project, Otto et al. (2015) shows that it is possible to

measure armed group interactions with the state across a substantial number of cases between

1989 and 2007, suggesting that the perspective advanced in this article is plausible. By linking

groups and orders to UCDP Actor and Dyadic identifiers and UCDP/PRIO Conflict identifier

and location information when possible, such contextual studies can still be embedded within

broader data. The benefits of going deep into conflicts can balance the limitations of only

studying a subset of cases. This approach is not a substitute for cross-national data on civil war,

but armed politics brings new and useful insights and data to our understanding of conflict.

The armed politics framework can be adapted in a variety of ways. Careful sub-national

research may identify local armed orders that are distinct from national orders. Studying armed

politics may help to bridge “macro” and “meso” levels of conflict analysis by allowing scholars

to study armed groups and state-group interactions simultaneously, rather than separating the two

into distinct research programs. It can potentially be applied to shorter periods of time than a

dyad/year, tracking much more fluid shifts in alignment over the course of weeks or months.

The armed politics approach has implications for theory. First, it suggests that in some

cases the distinction between war and peace, or between conflict and its absence, is neither

obvious or natural. Low numbers of dead bodies do not equate to political harmony, centralized

control over violence, or a lack of conflict, while high levels of violence may not reflect intense

or foundational political conflict between a state and armed group. This analytical move should 53 Kreutz 2015, 123.

Page 18: Armed Politics and the Study of Intrastate Conflict · PDF fileArmed Politics and the Study of Intrastate Conflict ... I show how conventional approaches miss ... I scope the armed

18

encourage theories of bargaining, armed group behavior, state strategy, and conflict outcomes

that take violence as a one potential outcome of interest, rather than a starting point or scope

condition, and that explicitly seek to explore movement between violence and non-violence.54

Second, the core question raised by the armed politics approach is why governments and

armed actors pursue, or are willing to accept, particular armed orders. Regime ideologies, desires

for reputation building, group fragmentation, electoral incentives and the group-state balance of

power may all shape the orders that emerge.55 On the side of armed groups, internal rivalries and

factionalism, dependence on or autonomy from different material resources, and the political

preferences of civilians may all shape the orders that groups pursue.56 These provide starting

hypotheses for explaining the sources of armed orders.

Exploring new theory and evidence about armed politics can help us make sense of a

contemporary world in which the formal trappings of de jure sovereignty co-exist, sometimes

uneasily, with the persistence of non-state armed groups and their diverse interactions with state

power.57 This research agenda builds on the strengths of existing work while allowing rigorous

comparative study of the full diversity of armed orders.

References

Ahram, Ariel. 2011. Proxy Warriors: The Rise and Fall of State-Sponsored Militias. Stanford, Calif: Stanford Security Studies.

Bakhtiar, Idrees. 1992. “Hello, this is the MQM. . . .” Herald, August 1992. Bergen, Peter L. 2013. Talibanistan: Negotiating the Borders between Terror, Politics, and

Religion. New York: Oxford University Press. Bhaumik, Subir. 2009. Troubled Periphery: Crisis of India’s North East. Los Angeles: SAGE. Chasie, Charles. 1999. The Naga Imbroglio  : A Personal Perspective. Standard Printers &

Publishers.

54 Fearon 1995; Chenoweth and Lawrence 2010; Chenoweth and Stephan 2011. 55 Walter 2006, Wilkinson 2004, Cunningham 2014, Staniland 2015, Straus 2015. 56 Shapiro 2013, Krause 2013/14, Pearlman 2011. 57 Reno 2011, Mukhopadhyay 2014, , Ahram 2011.

Page 19: Armed Politics and the Study of Intrastate Conflict · PDF fileArmed Politics and the Study of Intrastate Conflict ... I show how conventional approaches miss ... I scope the armed

19

Carey, Sabine C., Neil J. Mitchell, and Will Lowe. 2013. “States, the Security Sector, and the Monopoly of Violence A New Database on pro-Government Militias.” Journal of Peace Research 50(2): 249–58.

Cederman, Lars-Erik, Andreas Wimmer, and Brian Min. 2010. “Why Do Ethnic Groups Rebel?: New Data and Analysis.” World Politics 62(1): 87–119.

Chenoweth, Erica, and Adria Lawrence, eds. 2010. Rethinking Violence: States and Non-State Actors in Conflict. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

Chenoweth, Erica, and Maria J. Stephan. 2011. Why Civil Resistance Works: The Strategic Logic of Nonviolent Conflict. Columbia University Press.

Christia, Fotini. 2012. Alliance Formation in Civil Wars. Cambridge  ; New York: Cambridge University Press.

Cohen, Dara Kay. 2013. “Explaining Rape during Civil War: Cross-National Evidence (1980–2009).” American Political Science Review 107(03): 461–77.

Cunningham, David E., Kristian Skrede Gleditsch, and Idean Salehyan. 2009. “It Takes Two: A Dyadic Analysis of Civil War Duration and Outcome.” Journal of Conflict Resolution 53(4): 570–97.

Cunningham, David E., Kristian Skrede Gleditsch, and Idean Salehyan. 2013. “Non-State Actors in Civil Wars: A New Dataset.” Conflict Management and Peace Science 30(5): 516–31.

Cunningham, Kathleen Gallagher. 2014. Inside the Politics of Self-Determination. Oxford  ; New York: Oxford University Press.

Das, Samir Kumar. 2005. “Nobody’s Communique: Ethnic Accords in Northeast India.” In Samir Kumar Das, Peace Processes and Peace Accords, Vol. v. 2, New Delhi: SAGE Publications.

Day, Christopher R., and William S. Reno. 2014. “In Harm’s Way: African Counter-Insurgency and Patronage Politics.” Civil Wars 16(2): 105–26.

Davenport, Christian, and Patrick Ball. 2002. “Views to a Kill Exploring the Implications of Source Selection in the Case of Guatemalan State Terror, 1977-1995.” Journal of Conflict Resolution 46(3): 427–50.

Dev, S. C. 1988. Nagaland, the Untold Story. Calcutta: Gouri Dev. Eaton, Kent. 2006. “The Downside of Decentralization: Armed Clientelism in Colombia.”

Security Studies 15(4): 533–62. Fearon, James D. 1995. “Rationalist Explanations for War.” International Organization 49(3):

379–414. Fearon, James D., and David D. Laitin. 2003. “Ethnicity, Insurgency, and Civil War.” The

American Political Science Review 97(1): 75–90. Gayer, Laurent. 2014. Karachi: Ordered Disorder and the Struggle for the City. Oxford: Oxford

University Press. Gleditsch, Nils Petter et al. 2002. “Armed Conflict 1946-2001: A New Dataset.” Journal of

Peace Research 39(5): 615–37. Guha, Ramachandra. 2007. India after Gandhi: The History of the World’s Largest Democracy

New York: Ecco. Goswami, Namrata. 2007. “Retracing the Naga Peace Process.” In Jaideep Saikia, Frontier in

Flames: North-East India in Turmoil. New Delhi: Viking. Harbom, Lotta, Stina Högbladh, and Peter Wallensteen. 2006. “Armed Conflict and Peace

Agreements.” Journal of Peace Research 43, no. 5: 617–31. Herald. 1996. “City of Death.” Karachi. 1995 Annual Issue.

Page 20: Armed Politics and the Study of Intrastate Conflict · PDF fileArmed Politics and the Study of Intrastate Conflict ... I show how conventional approaches miss ... I scope the armed

20

Högbladh, Stina, 2011. ”Peace agreements 1975-2011 - Updating the UCDP Peace Agreement dataset”, in Pettersson Therése & Lotta Themnér (eds.), 2012, States in Armed Conflict 2011, Uppsala University: Department of Peace and Conflict Research Report 99.

Horam, M. Naga Insurgency: The Last Thirty Years. New Delhi, India: Cosmo Publications, 1988.

Kalyvas, Stathis N. 2006. The Logic of Violence in Civil War. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Kalyvas, Stathis N. 2003. “The Ontology of ‘Political Violence’: Action and Identity in Civil Wars.” Perspectives on Politics 1(3): 475–94.

Kramer, Tom. 2007. The United Wa State Party: Narco-Army or Ethnic Nationalist Party? Washington, D.C: East-West Center Washington.

Krause, Peter. 2013. “The Structure of Success: How the Internal Distribution of Power Drives Armed Group Behavior and National Movement Effectiveness.” International Security 38(3): 72–116.

Kreutz, Joakim. 2010. “How and When Armed Conflicts End: Introducing the UCDP Conflict Termination Dataset.” Journal of Peace Research 47(2): 243 –250.

———. 2015. “The War That Wasn’t There: Managing Unclear Cases in Conflict Data.” Journal of Peace Research 52(1): 120–24.

Lessing, Benjamin. 2015. “Logics of Violence in Criminal War.” Journal of Conflict Resolution 59(8): 1486–1516.

Lewis, Janet. 2015. “Do Ethnic Groups Rebel? Evidence from Nascent Insurgencies in Uganda.” Working paper, US Naval Academy.

Lintner, Bertil. The Rise and Fall of the Communist Party of Burma (CPB). SEAP Publications, 1990.

Ministry of Home Affairs (MHA). 1982-3. Annual Report. New Delhi: Government of India Press.

Ministry of Home Affairs (MHA). 1987-8. Annual Report. New Delhi: Government of India Press.

Mukhopadhyay, Dipali. 2014. Warlords, Strongman Governors, and the State in Afghanistan. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Nehru, B. K. 1997. Nice Guys Finish Second. New Delhi: Viking. Otto Sabine, Adam Scharpf, and Anita Gohdes. 2015. The History of Armed Actors/Groups

Dataset. Working paper. Pearlman, Wendy. 2011. Violence, Nonviolence, and the Palestinian National Movement. 1st ed.

Cambridge University Press. Poast, Paul. 2010. “(Mis)Using Dyadic Data to Analyze Multilateral Events.” Political Analysis

18(4): 403–25. Reno, William. 2011. Warfare in Independent Africa. New York: Cambridge University Press. Richards, Paul. 2004. No Peace No War: Anthropology Of Contemporary Armed Conflicts.

Oxford: Ohio University Press. Salehyan, Idean. 2015. “Best Practices in the Collection of Conflict Data.” Journal of Peace

Research 52(1): 105–9. Sambanis, Nicholas. 2004. “What Is Civil War? Conceptual and Empirical Complexities of an

Operational Definition.” The Journal of Conflict Resolution 48(6): 814–58. Sanín, Francisco Gutiérrez, and Elisabeth Jean Wood. 2014. “Ideology in Civil War Instrumental

Adoption and beyond.” Journal of Peace Research 51(2): 213–26.

Page 21: Armed Politics and the Study of Intrastate Conflict · PDF fileArmed Politics and the Study of Intrastate Conflict ... I show how conventional approaches miss ... I scope the armed

21

Seymour, Lee J.M. 2014. “Why Factions Switch Sides in Civil Wars: Rivalry, Patronage, and Realignment in Sudan.” International Security 39(2): 92–131.

Shapiro, Jacob N. 2013. The Terrorist’s Dilemma: Managing Violent Covert Organizations. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

Themnér, Lotta & Peter Wallensteen. 2014. Armed Conflict, 1946-2013. Journal of Peace Research 51(4).

Smith, Martin J. 1999. Burma: Insurgency and the Politics of Ethnicity. 2nd. ed. London: Zed Books.

Staniland, Paul. 2015. “Militias, Ideology, and the State.” Journal of Conflict Resolution. ———. 2012. “States, Insurgents, and Wartime Political Orders.” Perspectives on Politics 10,

no. 02. Stearns, Jason, Judith Verweijen, and Maria Erikson Baaz. 2013. The national army and armed

groups in the eastern Congo: Untangling the Gordian knot of insecurity. Nairobi: Rift Valley Institute.

Straus, Scott. 2015. Making and Unmaking Nations: War, Leadership, and Genocide in Modern Africa. 1 edition. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.

Sundberg, Ralph, Kristine Eck, and Joakim Kreutz. 2012. “Introducing the UCDP Non-State Conflict Dataset.” Journal of Peace Research 49(2): 351–62.

Toft, Monica Duffy. 2010. Securing the Peace: The Durable Settlement of Civil Wars. Princeton, N.J: Princeton University Press.

Tull, Denis M. The Reconfiguration of Political Order in Africa: A Case Study of North Kivu (DR Congo). GIGA-Hamburg, 2005.

Verghese, B. G. 1996. India’s Northeast Resurgent: Ethnicity, Insurgency, Governance, Development. New Delhi Konark Publishers.

Walter, Barbara F. 2006. “Building Reputation: Why Governments Fight Some Separatists but Not Others.” American Journal of Political Science 50(2): 313–30.

Weinstein, Jeremy. 2007. Inside Rebellion  : The Politics of Insurgent Violence. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Wilkinson, Steven. 2004. Votes and Violence: Electoral Competition and Ethnic Riots in India. Cambridge, U.K: Cambridge University Press.