arid land management in syiria

40
CAPRi WORKING PAPER NO. 15 CGIAR Systemwide Program on Collective Action and Property Rights Secretariat: International Food Policy Research Institute 2033 K Street, N.W. Washington, D.C. 20006 U.S.A. JUNE 2001 CAPRi Working Papers contain preliminary material and research results, and are circulated prior to a full peer review in order to stimulate discussion and critical comment. It is expected that most Working Papers will eventually be published in some other form, and that their content may also be revised. TRIBES, STATE, AND TECHNOLOGY ADOPTION IN ARID LAND MANAGEMENT, SYRIA Rae, J., Arab, G., Nordblom, T., Jani, K., and Gintzburger, G.

Upload: ronyza

Post on 03-Oct-2015

222 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

DESCRIPTION

Ini terkait dengan manajemen lahan gurun untuk pertanian

TRANSCRIPT

  • CAPRi WORKING PAPER NO. 15

    CGIACollective

    Secretariat: International Food Policy Research Institute2033 K Street, N.W. Washington, D.C. 20006 U.S.A.

    JUNE 2001

    CAPRi Working Papers contain preliminary material andprior to a full peer review in order to stimulate discussion and criWorking Papers will eventually be published in some other form, revised.

    TRIBES, STATE, AND TECHNOLOGY ADOPTION IN

    ARID LAND MANAGEMENT, SYRIA

    Rae, J., Arab, G., Nordblom, T., Jani, K.

    R Systemwide Program on Action and Property Rights

    research results, and are circulated tical comment. It is expected that most and that their content may also be

    , and Gintzburger, G.

  • i

    ABSTRACT

    Arid shrub-lands in Syria and elsewhere in West Asia and North Africa are widely thought degraded. Characteristic of these areas is a preponderance of unpalatable shrubs or a lack of overall ground cover with a rise in the associated risks of soil erosion. Migrating pastoralists have been the scapegoats for this condition of the range. State steppe interventions of the last forty years have reflected this with programs to supplant customary systems with structures and institutions promoting western grazing systems and technologies. Principal amongst the latter has been shrub technology, particularly Atriplex species, for use in land rehabilitation and as a fodder reserve. This paper deconstructs state steppe policy in Syria by examining the overlap and interface of government and customary legal systems as a factor in the history of shrub technology transfer in the Syrian steppe. It is argued that the link made between signs of degradation and perceived moribund customary systems is not at all causal. Indeed, customary systems are found to be adaptive and resilient, and a strong influence on steppe management and the fate of technology transfer initiatives. Furthermore, developments in rangeland ecology raise questions about claims for grazing-induced degradation and call for a reinterpretation of recent shifts in vegetation on the Syrian steppe. Given the ineffectiveness of past state interventions, and in view of renewed understanding of customary systems and rangeland ecology, decentralization and some devolution of formal management responsibility is likely to be a viable and an attractive option for policymakers.

  • ii

    TABLE OF CONTENTS

    1. Introduction.................................................................................................................... 1 2. Rangeland Degradation: Models and Empirical Evidence ............................................ 2 3. Performance of Technologies aimed at Improving Rangeland Conditions ................... 8 4. Property Rights in Syria: An Historical Overview ...................................................... 14 5. Conclusions and Policy Implications........................................................................... 26 REFERENCES ................................................................................................................. 29

  • TRIBES, STATE, AND TECHNOLOGY ADOPTION IN ARID LAND MANAGEMENT, SYRIA

    Rae, J1, Arab, G.2, Nordblom, T.3, Jani, K.4, and Gintzburger, G.5

    1. INTRODUCTION

    Arid rangelands dominate the countries of West Asia and North Africa (WANA).

    Syria, at the eastern end of the Mediterranean is better endowed with arable lands than

    most countries in the region but still just over half its area, or 10.2 million hectares, falls

    below the 200mm isohyet and is designated as badiah or 'steppe' where cultivation is

    outlawed. In the steppe the majority of people are tribally organized and dependent on a

    migratory pastoral or agro-pastoral economy where mobility and natural resource

    management are facilitated by extensive customary systems. However, for much of this

    century, migratory pastoralists have been blamed for being the key instigators of land

    degradation. Most WANA states won their independence after World War II and pursued

    policies of nation building and economic growth, neither of which carved out a role for tribes

    or migratory pastoralism. Not only did the state generally perceive that the tribe and their

    mobility were divisive and unstable elements in a fledgling nation, they saw customary

    grazing practices as archaic, inefficient and environmentally exploitative. The tribe was seen

    as a political and environmental threat that if not eliminated would undermine the new

    state and stifle economic growth.

    1 University of Oxford. 2 International Centre for Agricultural Research in Dry Areas. 3 CRC for Weed Management Systems, Charles Sturt University. 4 Steppe Directorate, Syrian Ministry for Agriculture and Agrarian Reform. 5 International Centre for Agricultural Research in Dry Areas.

  • 2

    With the assistance of the Food and Agriculture Organization (FAO) of the

    United Nations and other aid agencies, many WANA states sidestepped and sought to

    suffocate customary practices, and "green the desert" with the introduction of national

    rangeland management. Coming in the early years of independence for many of the

    WANA countries, the dominance of this paradigm had considerable influence on the

    direction and evolution of state institutions responsible for steppe management. This

    paper looks specifically at Syria and examines the impact of national policy over the past

    forty years on the institutions governing range management, as well as how the overlap

    and interface of the Syrian government and customary legal systems have shaped the

    history of shrub technology transfer in the Syrian steppe.

    2. RANGELAND DEGRADATION: MODELS AND EMPIRICAL EVIDENCE

    THEORETICAL MODELS APPLYING TO RANGELANDS

    The characterization of moving tribes as creators of desert conditions has a long

    history among people of the settled areas in the region and further afield (Ibn Khaldun

    translated in Issawi 1987; Bietenholz 1963). Hardin (1968) described a rationale for this

    position in his influential "Tragedy of the Commons" paper. He considered the

    perspective of a rational herder with private ownership of livestock in a pastoral society

    that is reliant on pastures "open to all". Herders would follow the incentive to increase

    the number of their herd because they would receive direct benefit but bear only a share

    of the costs resulting from the delayed impact of their action. Each herder is "locked into

    a system that compels him to increase his herd without limitin a world that is limited

    (Hardin 1968). According to tragedy theorists, effective property rights and rational

  • 3

    rangeland management is not possible without strong state involvement. This theory has

    formed the rationale for state governance over rangelands and other natural resources in

    many developing countries.

    State programs to assess, manage or increase productivity of steppe areas are also

    based on a model of how the steppe ecosystem functions. Predominant in rangeland

    management science for much of this century has been the range succession model,

    which derives from plant ecology (Westoby et al.1989). It assumes that the livestock

    sector operates in environments that are largely stable, where weather variability is

    limited to a narrow range and therefore inconsequential for long-term outcomes. The

    model supposes that a given rangeland continually returns to a single persistent state (the

    climax) of vegetation in the absence of grazing. By producing changes in the opposite

    direction, grazing pressure arising from a set stocking rate can slow or halt the

    successional tendency, producing an equilibrium in vegetation levels. This theory has

    guided the principles of the western ranching system, which were subsequently

    introduced in many parts of Sub-Saharan Africa and WANA to supplant customary

    practices. These included private rights to graze, rotational or paddock grazing systems,

    the establishment of water points to spread grazing pressure, the setting of a universal

    stocking rate, and the reseeding or re-planting of the range with grasses and shrubs.

    EMPIRICAL EVIDENCE

    Whereas there are widespread claims for degradation in Syria, only limited

    inventories and no long-term studies of the steppe flora have been carried out. Despite

    this, numerous references in the literature attest to the 'degraded' nature of the vegetation.

    A synthesis of range reports through to the mid-1950s concluded that "without exception,

  • 4

    range management specialists and ecologists have stressed that the range grazing of the

    steppe and semi desert regions of Syriais progressively deteriorating as a result of

    overgrazing" (FAO 1956). A 1985 study of the Syrian rangelands by the Arab Center for

    the Studies of Arid Zones and Dry lands (ACSAD 1992) suggested that unpalatable shrub

    species have become "dominant in large areas of the steppe". It went on to estimate that

    25% of the steppe is affected by wind erosion to one degree or another, while water

    erosion affects around 6% of the area. Furthermore, almost all relevant publications

    issued from the International Center for Agricultural Research in the Dry Areas

    (ICARDA), which is based in Aleppo, are premised on the assumption of widespread

    degradation in the Syrian steppe (Rae 1999). Yet, evidence exists to the contrary.

    An unpalatable shrub associated with a degraded steppe in Syria and neighboring

    regions is the spiny Noaea mucronata. An ecological study carried out by Deiri (1990)

    under the auspices of ICARDA, found Noaea ubiquitous in the Aleppo steppe, masking

    the heterogeneity of climate and soil. Apparently, dominance of Noaea in some areas is a

    relatively new phenomenon here (Sankary 1982) and elsewhere (Zakirov 1989; Noy-Mier

    1990). Deiri and others have assumed that this shift in floral composition is the result of

    overgrazing for lack of good management, and that with a reduction in grazing pressure a

    climax community dominated by the palatable shrub Salsola vermiculata would return

    (Deiri 1990; Sankary 1982). However, the link between cause and effect is not

    adequately demonstrated.

    Indeed, the basis of an alternative interpretation comes from grazing trials carried

    out by the FAO and the Steppe Directorate in the 1960s at Wadi al-`Azib research station

    in the Aleppo steppe. Over a three-year period, three sites were fenced off with a

  • 5

    different stocking rate in each (trial A: 9ha per sheep, B: 6ha, and C: 4.5ha). No sizeable

    differences in average meat production per animal were reported between the three

    treatments. As for the vegetation, it was noted that plant density "fluctuated more

    between years than between stocking rate treatments" (FAO 1966), suggesting climate

    more than grazing determines productivity. The reported vegetation change was,

    however, unexpected. Spininess in plants is usually interpreted as an anti-grazing

    adaptation, and it has often been recorded that spiny plants increase under heavy grazing

    but give way once protected (Noy-Mier 1990). In treatment C, with the highest stocking

    rate there was a "reduction" in the spiny variety Noaea while in treatment A, with the

    lowest stocking rate, Noaea "increased greatly in density" (FAO 1966, 1967). The cause

    of this vegetation change is not alluded to by either of the reports at hand; Noaea is just

    described as "a spiny, undesirable shrub".

    An explanation for the expansion of Noaea under reduced grazing pressure is

    given by another study in the Negev and Jerusalem deserts (Noy-Mier 1990). During

    certain periods on the open range, Noaea are exposed to heavy pressure from herbivores

    selecting for the rare green material. Even though spines and other types of protection

    save the plants from local extinction, Noy-Mier asserted they are insufficient to outweigh

    grazing pressure and are therefore among the first plants to benefit when an area is

    protected.

    The crucial difference between Noaea mucronata and other shrubs is its extended

    growing period. Heavy grazing either end of the green season disadvantages Noaea, but

    when such grazing pressure is relieved the extended growing period becomes an

    advantage. When camels are removed from the near steppe, the pressure in late spring

  • 6

    and summer is largely removed. Also, whereas as recently as thirty years ago almost all

    herders wintering (November-February) on the near steppe sustained their flocks entirely

    from grazing6, today almost none do. Instead they feed their sheep on hand-feed

    generally imported from the settled areas7. Thus, rather than being due to overgrazing,

    the shift to Noaea mucronata is a result of changes in the composition of livestock

    grazing the steppe coupled with the adoption and widespread use of hand feed for

    wintersomething encouraged by the state following the 1958-61 drought (Lewis 1987).

    Conclusions like this bring into question the validity of the range succession

    model in arid environments. Whereas the model predicts that rainfall cycles combined

    with sustained grazing pressure will keep range vegetation in equilibrium, it is now

    thought that where droughts or other episodic events are a feature, population fluctuations

    hinder plants and herbivores from establishing closely linked interactions, and succession

    is abbreviated or non-existent (Behnke et al. 1993; Scoones 1994). This realization that

    equilibrium conditions are not met in many instances has led to the development of an

    alternative paradigm centered around two models: the non-equilibrium model, which

    deals with population dynamics in uncertain environments; and the state-and-transition

    model (Westoby, Walker and Noy-Mier 1989). In contrast to the linear succession

    model, it is argued that rangeland dynamics can be more accurately described by a set of

    discrete states of vegetation with discrete transitions between them, triggered by natural

    events, like floods, drought or fire, either alone or in combination with herbivore activity.

    6 Van de Veen estimates that 58% of the Syrian sheep population, or 3.8 million head, resided in the steppe for winter grazing only shrubs, amongst them Noaea mucronata and Haloxylon articulatum (FAO 1967). 7 In an in-depth two-year study on animal diets of 129 herds frequenting the Aleppo steppe 98% of feed needs came from hand-feeding, the remainder from crop residues. No steppe grazing was reported during the winter months (Wachholtz 1996). Perversely, pressure is relieved on the steppe to the advantage of Noaea.

  • 7

    Objectively apportioning responsibility for perceived or actual changes in steppe

    vegetation composition is therefore difficult. Grazing inevitably has an impact on shrub

    communities, but the nature of this impact is unclear, particularly when causes arise from

    a conjunction of other factors in addition to grazing. Indeed, some speculate that the

    landscape may in some sense be 'adapted' to grazing pressure. That is, either less

    resistant shrub species have been eliminated long ago or the species in these communities

    have adapted to grazing pressure. There is even some evidence to suggest that a certain

    amount of grazing pressure on arid rangelands maintains or even enhances floral species

    diversity (Olsvig-Whittaker et al. 1993; Perevolotsky 1995). In the case of the transition

    to Noaea mucronata, it seems likely that this was actually brought about by a reduction in

    grazing during critical times of the year.

    Despite the lack of a clear consensus on the best model for predicting the extent

    and causes of rangeland degradation, the Syrian government, aided by international

    research and development institutions, has undertaken several measures to bring about a

    change in rangeland management for the stated purpose of improving environmental

    outcomes. Actions have reflected a persistent adherence to 'tragedy of the commons' and

    rangeland succession models. They span from centralizing the governance and

    enforcement of rangeland management to introducing new technologies designed to

    enhance the quantity and quality of rangeland vegetation. The following section will

    discuss shrub and plantation technologies that have been developed, extended, and often

    imposed on herders occupying the Syrian steppe. Despite more than 50 years of

    technological efforts, however, technology uptake has lagged far behind expectations.

    Subsequent sections elaborate on the institutional changes preceding and accompanying

  • 8

    technical solutions that demonstrate the important role played by customary institutions

    in steppe management and shed light on the underlying reasons for the lack of adoption

    success.

    3. PERFORMANCE OF TECHNOLOGIES AIMED AT IMPROVING

    RANGELAND CONDITIONS

    ATRIPLEX SHRUB TECHNOLOGY

    From its creation in 1961, the Steppe Directorate (SD) of the Syrian government

    was given responsibility for range management, range and pasture research, management

    and expansion of government wells, and organization of emergency feed during times of

    drought. With the assistance of the FAO, the SD embarked on a highly centralized range

    management initiative, setting the tenor for all future interventions. Part of this initiative

    included trials to identify rain-use efficient, edible plants to re-vegetate the steppe and act

    as a drought feed store. This was deemed necessary, for though the successional model

    predicted natural regeneration towards a climax community, climatic variability and the

    unpredictable recurrence of devastating droughts meant that natural regeneration could be

    a long time coming. Shrub planting would fill this temporal gap, check soil erosion and

    provide a source of animal feed during drought. The trials concluded in the late 1960s

    recommending Atriplex, a shrub species already favored by range managers elsewhere

    around the world, most notably Australia, South Africa and the United States (Houerou

    1995).

    Le Houerou, one of the most influential people involved in rangeland

    management and rehabilitation in the WANA region over the last thirty years, describes

    the planting of Atriplex species as "one of the most efficient ways to reclaim [arid lands],

  • 9

    if not the only one" (Le Houerou 1992). The shrubs can prevent wind and water erosion

    and are efficient users of water (McKell 1975). They could also serve as a feed reserve in

    years of drought. There are around 400 species of Atriplex in the world, most in mid-

    latitude temperate, sub-tropical and Mediterranean zones. Though many Atriplex species

    exist in the Mediterranean region, their use in arid land stabilization and rehabilitation

    began with the introduction of the Australian variety Atriplex nummularia into Tunisia in

    the last years of the 19th century (McKell 1975). The introduction of this and other

    varieties from Australia continued after World War I in Tunisia and Morocco. By the

    1950s, Atriplex was being recommended for steppe rehabilitation in FAO circles, and

    from the 1960s introductions took place throughout the WANA region and further afield.

    Although many trials of non-indigenous species showed limited promise, Omar Draz,

    FAO's chief advisor to the Syrian government on rangeland issues, conducted trials in

    1968-69 with Atriplex nummularia that produced successful outcomes in an agricultural

    district of Aleppo (FAO 1974).

    With the support of Draz and a wider scientific consensus for the technology, the

    Syrian authorities initiated programs to transfer Atriplex on the steppe. History of this

    intervention in Syria can conveniently be divided into two phases: 1) encouraging and

    later obliging agro-pastoralists to plant a part of their area with Atriplex; and then 2) the

    establishment of government-run fodder shrub plantations from 1987. The first phase

    envisaged that agro-pastoralists would forego barley cultivation over a portion of their

    licensed steppe area and plant Atriplex in its place. In hindsight poor adoption rates for

    Atriplex were a foregone conclusion. Barley is nutritious and palatable, while post-

    harvest stubble can be used for grazing. During drought, it can be grazed in-situ. By

  • 10

    contrast, it can take between three and five months for sheep grazing Atriplex to get used

    to consuming and digesting it. Oxalates in the plant are potentially toxic to some

    ruminant microorganisms and can form stones in the urinary tract (Goodchild & Osman

    1993). Furthermore, to compensate for the high salt content of the plant, the animal must

    drink between 6 and 12 liters of water day (depending on the heat of the day), twice the

    normal levels (Le Houerou 1992; Nordblom et al. 1995). Nor does Atriplex fit

    comfortably in the bedouin farming system. The "proper" time to harvest most Atriplex

    used in Syria is late summer and early autumn, a period when most sheep are grazing

    nutritious cotton residues in the settled areas (Wachholtz 1996). Not surprisingly, only a

    fraction of those cultivating in the steppe actually planted Atriplex, and of those all but a

    handful ensured their private plantation survived, the otherswith the shrubs gone

    again cultivated barley (Leybourne et al. 1993).

    THE PLANTATION APPROACH

    The poor success of government initiatives to encourage or require private

    adoption of range technology led directly to the 'plantation concept'. Here, the

    government effectively privatizes an area of steppe with a trench, plants the enclosure

    with shrubs, and after a period of establishment permits range users restricted access

    under contract and on payment of a grazing fee. The idea is not unique to Syria. In the

    last two decades, 470,000 ha have been taken for plantations in Tunisia, 133,000 ha in

    Iran, 33,000 ha in Algeria, and there are many others (World Bank 1995). In Syria, the

    plantations have been at the heart of state intervention in the steppe since the late 1980s

    and by 2000 occupied 220,000 ha.

  • 11

    The plantation concept came after a generation of frustrated state intervention in

    rangeland management and technology transfer. It represented a significant step against

    the tide of devolution in natural resource management elsewhere, and instead advocated

    centralization as a solution for sustainable development in arid regions. The actual

    presence on the steppe of the plantations, coupled with the fact the state had tilled and

    planted the land (i.e. invested), brought the formal legal system and state authorities into

    direct conflict with the customary land tenure system like never before.

    Plantations are supposedly located where Steppe Directorate (SD) officials judge

    the steppe to be degraded. Only private steppe land (approximately 2%) cannot be

    included within a plantation; otherwise all other land (including cultivated fields and co-

    operative pastures) is technically state land, and can therefore be appropriated, despite the

    fact that customary institutions have governed land tenure for centuries. Once the site

    and size are determined, a committee is appointed within the Ministry of Agricultural and

    Agrarian Reform (MAAR), to produce a technical and economic feasibility study for the

    proposed plantation8. Socio-economic or environmental impact assessments are not

    regularly carried out. If the committee gives the go ahead, MAAR provides financial

    support for plantation establishment.

    After a period of shrub establishment, averaging five years, the plantations are

    opened under contract for use during restricted periods, generally a couple months each

    in the winter and spring. Enforcement of plantation rules is the prime responsibility of

    the Steppe Directorate but the rules themselves are decided on at the provincial level by

    8 The committee is composed of an agricultural economist, a geologist, and representatives from the provincial departments of the MAAR and the Steppe Directorate.

  • 12

    the Agricultural Council9 and hence vary. However, the following rules are broadly

    applicable. The carrying capacity of all the plantations was set at three head-of-sheep per

    hectare in 1995, and has not changed since. In line with the succession model of plant

    ecology, if the SD officials feel that grazing is insufficient in a particular season, access

    to the plantations is delayed, truncated, or denied completely. Firewood collection

    camping, milking and watering are prohibited in the plantations during leasing. A

    deposit on the contract is also required in some provinces, including Aleppo, and where

    this is the case each contract is clearly designated an allotted area. The cost to a herder

    for a spring contract is harmonized across the country, at 125 Syrian Lira (SL) ($2.25)

    per hectare per month.

    On the frontline of plantation rule enforcement are year-round resident guards.

    Those caught trespassing in Aleppo province are fined 5,000 SL, the equivalent of around

    $100 or the price of a two-year old ewe. The official number of trespassers prosecuted in

    the country since the plantations were first opened in 1995 is estimated around a

    thousand, the vast majority of them reportedly at two plantations in the Aleppo steppe10.

    9 The Agricultural Council is chaired by the provincial governor and includes provincial heads for Agriculture, Finance, the Ba`th Party, and the Peasants' Union. 10 Conversation with staff at Steppe Directorate Head Quarters, Palmyra: 4th July 1999

  • 13

    TECHNOLOGICAL OUTCOMES, RANGELAND MANAGEMENT AND INSTITUTIONS

    Syrian authorities have sought to transfer shrub technology to the steppe through a

    variety of institutional arrangements, all of which have discounted customary land tenure

    and property rights. The underlying premise for the state approach is rooted in the

    'tragedy of the commons' model of pastoral society, which hinges on the assumption of

    non co-operating herders and eventual degradation.

    While many researchers and rangeland scientists implicate government policy

    itself for the decline of customary systems, a pervasive perception is that the system is

    unable to adapt to changing socio-economic conditions (FAO 1967; World Bank 1995;

    Ngaido 1997).

    Customary systems in Syria, as elsewhere, have been perceived as being unable to

    regulate pasture use in the face of pressures from increasing human and animal

    populations, and a diminishing range area. Some have felt that the organizational and

    institutional basis on which the customary system relies is in a process of irreversible

    decline as an inevitable consequence of modernization (UN 1955; Abu Jaber 1966). That

    is, tribes weaken as they become superfluous in the presence of a maturing and

    ubiquitous judiciary and civil administration system.

    Research on customary control and access systems in Syria is noticeable for its

    absence. The tribes have been identified as the cause of degradation by a process of

    deductive reasoning from ecology and political science theories, and re-enforced by

    ambivalent attitudes held by policymakers towards migratory groups. Herders' resistance to

    adoption of technologies and institutions imposed by government authorities is not well

    understood, and often attributed to irrational behavior. However, a more accurate

  • 14

    understanding of the institutions governing rangeland management and the incentives

    underlying adoption behavior necessitates a detailed appreciation of the customary system,

    state centralization, capitalist penetration and the evolution of these institutions in Syria

    during the 20th century.

    4. PROPERTY RIGHTS IN SYRIA: AN HISTORICAL OVERVIEW

    Modern-day Syria is a relatively new phenomenon. It was originally carved out of

    two Ottoman Provinces after World War I and placed under French Mandatory rule

    before the country won its independence in 1944. A judicial-political division, called the

    'steppe line', was inherited by the French and subsequently by the nationalists. It was first

    defined in state law in 1870 by a centralizing Ottoman government wanting to

    encapsulate and subject the moving camel and sheep rearing tribes of the desert interior.

    Within the steppe line, the state recognized the authority of customary law and courts in

    regulating the activities of tribal society, including land tenure issues. What amounted to

    a "state within a state" remained ostensibly unchanged following independence, but it

    was an obvious anathema to a fledgling nation, and within fourteen years customary law

    and tribes were formally abolished, and the steppe areas nationalized. This was of

    historic importance for it was the last legislation to deal specifically with the tribes and

    marked the final act in the long struggle by central governments to eliminate the tribes

    and shaykhs as rivals to their own power and jurisdiction.

    Key to understanding property rights in Syria is the concept of legal pluralism.

    For a long time the formal legal system of the state, the qanun, co-existed with tribal

    customary law, `urf. Whereas the qanun is by definition written, the `urf is largely

    unwritten. Often the qanun has confirmed existing local custom, as custom is recognized

  • 15

    as one of the sources of Islamic law, shari`a, itself a pillar of the qanun (Heyd 1973).

    The moving tribes were rarely subject to qanun prior to 1958. Amongst them customary

    law prevailed in all matters including marriage, divorce, homicide and property rights.

    These tribal legal institutions have been described as "remarkable for their sophistication,

    and a central feature of the culture" (Stewart 1995).

    The question of property rights in the steppe area was not of much concern to the

    authorities prior to the 1940s. Historically, the government's principal interest in rural

    property rights has been in regulating and taxing cultivation. The authority of the state

    has broadly correlated with the extent of cultivation, and both have waxed and waned at

    various times in history. Cultivation's most recent expansion began in the 1840s with

    impetus from world trade and later a growing domestic human population. For a century

    this expansion was mostly accommodated within the steppe line, particularly south of

    Aleppo City and the Euphrates River. Rising international and local demands were also

    encouraging expansion of sheep numbers in the steppe. These two forces of expanding

    cultivation and growing sheep numbers converged along the margins of the steppe in the

    early 1940s, raising land scarcity and precipitating dramatic developments in both the

    statutory and customary land tenure systems.

    THE STATUTORY TENURE SYSTEM

    In Islamic law and prevalent in Syria until the 1950s, the uncultivated steppe was

    categorized mawat, or dead land. On mawat land no taxes were claimed by the state and

    all persons could "cut for fuel and for buildingor collect herbagewithout anyone

    being able to prevent him" (Ottoman Land Code 1858). As for cultivation, Sunni jurists

    considered vivification of mawat land as desirable and an activity that should be

  • 16

    encouraged (Maktari 1971), although the state retained the right to demand consent prior

    to cultivation in lieu of a fee. This said, such consent was largely academic in the steppe

    prior to state expansion in the late 19th century and was never fully enforced thereafter.

    Prescriptive rights and the ancient category of mawat were eventually abolished in the

    first years of independence (1952), and all such land was re-classed as state land (amlak

    dawlah). Mawat was seen as a legitimization of open access and the destructive habits

    that this in principal engenders amongst resource users.

    Nationalization not only underscored the authority of the state to regulate land use

    but also provided the state a tool with which to further reduce tribal power. The law,

    however, failed to make a material impact until 1958 when the sway of customary law

    among the tribes was officially abolished and a government more bent on state-led steppe

    development, the Socialist Ba`th Party, came to power in 1963. They originally espoused

    "pragmatism and evolutionism within the national framework" (Abu Jaber 1966) and

    advocated the dispersal and sedentarization of moving tribes in order that individual

    loyalty could be redirected toward national goals. The Ba'thist constitution states:

    Nomadism is a primitive social state. It decreases the national output and makes an important part of the nation a paralyzed member and an obstacle to its development and progress. The party struggles for the sedentarization of nomads by the grants of land to them [and] for the abolition of tribal custom (Art.43)

    The abolition of tribal rights coincided with the start of a severe drought (1958-

    1961) that destroyed herds on an unprecedented scale. According to official estimates,

    80% of the camel population was killed while the sheep population dropped from 6

    million in 1957 to 3.5 million in 1961 (FAO 1967). The single most important

    government response to the drought was the establishment of the Steppe Directorate

  • 17

    within the MAAR to take on range management and alleviate the impact of future

    droughts. With virgin cultivable land in the country now thought to be exhausted,

    considerable state resources were redirected to steppe management and animal husbandry

    in the hopes of stabilizing and expanding meat production. FAO had charged that over-

    grazing, absence of grazing control mechanisms, expansion of cultivation, and the

    uprooting of shrubs had together "resulted in the grazing capacity of the steppe being

    seriously depleted" (FAO 1973). These factors, along with the current breeding system

    and the region's susceptibility to drought, were implicated in adversely affecting the

    nation's terms of trade and balance of payments, since livestock meat and grains tended to

    be exported at low prices and imported at high prices.

    With the guiding principles of import substitution and food security through self-

    sufficiency, the authorities devised a four-point plan for steppe development with

    assistance from the FAO, the impact of which continues to be felt today. It proposed to

    regenerate the steppe through controlled grazing, increase local production of forage,

    create feed supplies to meet emergencies caused by drought, and improve sheep

    fattening. Their target was 11 million sheep by 1985, which would contribute to a

    desired increase in per capita meat consumption and at the same time continue the

    valuable export trade for which there was a large demand in neighboring countries (FAO

    1967). To fulfill these ambitious objectives, the Steppe Directorate initiated research in

    shrub technology for range rehabilitation and initiated in 1968 a rotational grazing

    scheme within a co-operative model termed Hema to supplant the tribal system. Showing

    little resemblance to a perceived indigenous mechanism of controlled grazing that

    inspired it, the stringency of Hema cooperative rules, the corruption of cooperative

  • 18

    structures for political ends, and the government's inability to supply credible grazing

    management institutions and structures undermined the cooperative approach.

    THE CUSTOMARY TENURE SYSTEM

    The prevailing assumption of the inadequacy of the tribal system to manage

    steppe resources supposedly stems from the failure of the tribes to either evolve their

    institutions to adapt to changing socio-economic conditions or to resist suppression by a

    nationalist state. Evidence uncovered from examining the case of tribes and land tenure

    in the northern region of the Syrian steppe reveals an alternative history for the customary

    system. Indeed, there is clear indication of an evolving, resilient customary system here,

    one that has not only endured repression by the state but has obliged government

    authorities to resume a positive and active role in its institutions.

    All Arab tribal individuals belong to a particular tribe, which imparts an

    authenticity of descent and a quality of honor that sets them apart from non-tribal society

    (Dresch 1993; Hourani 1991). Individual families form larger groups, called `quam

    (sing. qom), the fundamental organizing units within a tribe. A collection of `quam forms

    a maximal lineage or clan, called fakhdh. Families within a clan rely on group collective

    action and commonly hold water and pastures together (Wilkinson 1983). Generally, a

    council of elders guides the clan, and in many instances there is a well-respected

    individual amongst them, a mukhtar or wajih, who can speak for the group as a whole. A

    tribe is much larger, often comprising several villages or herding groups. Common to

    many tribes and clans is the ethno-political ideology of patrilineal descent or shared

    ancestry. The language of common descent does not necessarily reflect fact but is better

  • 19

    understood as a metaphor for signifying notions of closeness (LaBianca 1990). In the

    wider region, most tribes also have had long histories of a specific territorial identity11.

    Tribal society has a wealth of social capital: the social relations and norms

    embedded in the structures of their society that regulate interactions. Things do change

    over time, but given that individuals involved in any of these social structures will engage

    in repeated interactions, each relationship is guided by expectations of predictable

    behavior, leading to trust and reciprocity. Such trust underpins the customary land tenure

    system and its flexibility. The fact that the state has had to take overt actions to break up

    customary systems and as yet remains unable to do away with them attests to the strength

    and utility of these social capital networks.

    A group associated with a territory holds the exclusive right to invest in land, such

    as digging a well, building a house, or cultivating a field. They also hold the right to

    graze and exclude others, but given the nature of an arid environment and the size of any

    one territory, herders inevitably need to maintain flexible, reciprocal arrangements with

    other groups to maintain mobility. Hence, social capital is a critical ingredient upholding

    such arrangements and assuring mutual compliance. Events that transpired at the turn of

    the 20th century in the Aleppo steppe illustrate the important role played by such

    adaptive customary institutions in the face of resource competition.

    Before the arrival of trucks, the broad region in which a tribe migrated throughout

    the year was (and sometimes still is) known as the dirah. It represented a functional area

    of habitual use composed of water holes and associated pastures to which the group held

    rights. In drought years when parts or all of a dirah were affected, families, groups or

    11 In Sinai, Stewart (1986); In Yemen, Dresch (1993); Hourani (1991).

  • 20

    larger parts of a tribe sought water and pastures through social networks in the dirah of

    other tribes.

    At the turn of the 20th century the Aleppo steppe was dominated by two

    neighboring sheep herding tribes, the Hadidiyin and the Mawali, and a powerful camel-

    herding tribe called the Sba`ah. The size of the dirah depended on the herding animal,

    with camels-herders having substantially larger dirah and venturing deeper into the desert

    then their brethren, the sheep and goat herders. These latter herders were restricted by

    the water dependency of their animals to the desert fringes where water sources were

    more frequent and plentiful. The Sba`ah spent their winter and early spring around wells

    of Wadi Hauran and its environs in modern-day western Iraq, 500 km southeast of the

    Aleppo steppe line. In spring the Sba`ah migrated to the Aleppo steppe were they stayed

    the summer occupying water points and pastures just vacated by the sheep herding tribes,

    the Hadidiyin and the Mawali. There, they traded with the settled areas, and grazed their

    animals on steppe shrubs largely unpalatable to sheep. This complementary and non-

    exclusive use of water and pastures between the sheep and camel rearing tribes has an

    ancient history in the region, with rights to waters and pastures in the near steppe and the

    time windows on seasonal movement acknowledged in a written tribal treaty signed in

    the last years of the Ottoman Empire (1907-1918) (Zakrya 1947).

    This agreement lasted until the 1940s. In the meantime, cultivation in Syria

    trebled to 2.1 million ha, sheep numbers also trebled to 3.4 million head, while camels

    started to give way to tractors and trucks (Issawi 1951; Widmer 1936). Sba`ah

    households were adapting to the changing demands in the market place. Whereas they

    owned no sheep in 1920 they reportedly held some 80,000 ten years later (H.C.R.F.

  • 21

    1930). As all three tribes now had sheep in large numbers but still broadly lacked the

    ability to truck water, conflict arose between Sba`ah and the old sheep herding tribes over

    water and pastures in the near steppe during winter and spring months.

    Together with an expansion of agriculture, the rising sheep numbers demanded

    changes in the customary land tenure system, at least in the near steppe. Of immediate

    concern to the Hadidiyin, the Mawali and the Sba`ah, was an untangling of their

    overlapping dirah in the near steppe and the establishment of discrete tribal territories as

    a basis for access rights to natural resources. Once this was achieved, investment either

    in water or agriculture could be undertaken without risk of inter-tribal disputes. To

    facilitate this shift, the disputing tribes sought an agreement through customary channels

    and under the auspices of the state. By far the most important of such agreements was

    the Damascus tribal treaty of 1956, which divided over 500,000 ha of the Aleppo steppe

    among the three tribes, although pre-existing claims to water and pasture were kept

    intact. The political process used in this treaty, and other similar ones before and after it,

    was based on tribal custom.

    In 1958, when the role of customary law and structures was formerly abolished in

    Syria, the Damascus treaty and others like it were automatically annulled. The authorities

    assumed full responsibility for rangeland management, placing it with the Steppe

    Directorate from 1961. Nevertheless, customary institutions continued to exert authority

    over rangeland management and tribal control. Documented evidence, such as that

    described below, shows that substantial cooperation to regulate control and access to

    steppe resources persisted among herders from different tribes, despite the hostile

  • 22

    political environment, including a significant level of tribal corporate activity in

    protecting rights.

    In 1958, large numbers of the Sba`ah left Syria for Saudi Arabia following the

    abolition of tribal rights. With most of Sba`ah gone, Ghanatsah (a faction of the

    Hadidiyin) took the opportunity to reoccupy and claim for themselves a portion of the

    treaty lands called Abu al Naytel and Dayl`. They went unchallenged for more than a

    decade, but in 1974 Muharrab al-Rakan, a son of the supreme shaykh of Sba`ah, "and the

    members of Sba`ah represented by him," (SAR 1975) returned to Syria and immediately

    laid a claim on the Abu al-Naytel well and the lands of Dayl`.

    Ghanatsah took the matter to the state authorities. The head (mudir) of the

    Palmyra administrative district carried out preliminary consultations with the disputing

    tribes and visited the questioned site. The "final meeting" (SAR 1975) to resolve the

    problem was convened on the 10th of February 1975. The decision went in favor of

    Ghanatsah and the old mutual border from the 1956 treaty was adjusted to the new

    agreement. The legal precedent for the decision was adverse possession, i.e. undisputed

    occupation of property for a given period of time becomes the property of the occupant.

    Six years later, the situation flared up again when Muharrab attempted again to

    extend his area of control by cultivating his shared border with Ghanatsah in an area

    referred to as the "airport". This was land Ghanatsah believed was theirs. Another round

    of resolution talks was held. The settlement reached went again in favor of Ghanatsah.

    Muharrab was allowed to reap his crop "as he had ploughed and planted it" but

    afterwards the land would revert to Ghanatsah.

  • 23

    This agreement, like many others12, was extraordinary considering the Ba`thist

    constitution and ideology. The decision had been reached with the full participation of

    the state authorities. As far as the written law was concerned the disputed land was state

    land and, since it was not part of a cooperative, was technically open to all Syrian citizens

    and their livestock. The shaykhs' intermediary roles were formally terminated in 1958,

    but two decades later little had changed in practice. Indeed, customary institutions

    remain the principal mechanism regulating access to steppe resources on a day-to-day

    basis, while the state continues to implicitly recognize and endorse tribal customary

    rights and practices, with high officials and Party cadres guaranteeing agreements and

    signing documents in the name of the state. It is important to note, however, that the

    Steppe Directorate of the Ministry of Agriculture, with statuary responsibility for steppe

    resource management, was not involved in this particular agreement. It was seen instead

    as a political not a land management problem per se.

    CONFLICTS BETWEEN STATUTORY AND CUSTOMARY TENURE ON THE PLANTATIONS

    That violations of plantation rules of access are a particular problem in Aleppo is

    at least partially explained by the overlap of tribal territories. Both plantations discussed

    below form a group of four located on lands held by the Abraz clan of the Hadidiyin.

    12 Additional post-1958 documented territorial treaties have come to light. The dates of these agreements include 1962, 1983, 1989, and 1992.

  • 24

    A guard at one of these plantation suggested he had turned over for prosecution

    no less than 200 Abraz herders in five years in addition to the "many others caught but

    not charged" (Conversation with the guard: Maraghah, Syria, 21st June 1999). Faysal,

    the shaykh of Abraz, puts the number of Abraz prosecuted as a whole at 370. Evidence

    from official communications on a proposed fifth plantation in the Abraz area strongly

    suggests that appropriation of land for the plantations was causing serious pasture

    shortages for the clan. Upon hearing of the proposed plantation in early 1995, Faysal

    wrote to the Aleppo Governor:

    Once these lands are annexed and the said plantation is established ... we would no longer have lands for our sheep to graze. We were moved from `Ein al-Zarqah and Maraghah where two plantations were established. To the north of us is the al-Haib tribewith whom we have a bloody dispute[and consequently] we are not welcome on their pasture. Moreover, the establishment of the plantation would cause hundreds of herders to move away, many of whom have houses in the area.13 As a result, the proposed plantation was abandoned, although the reason given

    was that the site was in fact "one of the good sites in our steppe in terms of plant cover."

    This episode demonstrates that past decisions for plantation location failed to assess the

    implications of customary land tenure and the inevitable impact this would have on the

    household economy of local range uses.

    It is an unwritten rule within the Steppe Directorate that first refusal on plantation

    leases goes to local herders and clans, despite formal claims that the steppe and the

    plantations are open to all. Problems of who can have access to a plantation do not

    generally arise when the site is located entirely within a particular clan territory.

    13 Letter to H.E. The Governor of Aleppo from Faysal al-Nuri and companions on behalf of the Abraz tribe: 13.2.1995.

  • 25

    However, when the plantation border cuts across tribal territories, or unwelcome groups

    from far afield attempt to purchase a lease on a local plantation, then the incongruence of

    tenure systems can result in some very serious problems. Of the four plantations under

    study by ICARDA in 1996, two plantations fell wholly within clan territories but the

    other two did not. In the latter, disputes over access between neighboring groups resulted

    in considerable difficulties for the authorities.

    Such was the case when two clans, Bu Hasan and Jimlan (both of the Hadidiyin),

    attempted to gain access to the plantation and establish de facto possession of land

    originally held by three tribal territories: the Bu Salah of Abraz, the Twimat of

    Ghanatsah, and the Ma`atah, all three of which are also part of the Hadidiyin. In the

    previous two leasing seasons, the plantation had been leased predominately by the Bu

    Salah, Abraz, which had also secured the vast majority of leases for that season. The

    only other group to have grazed the plantation in previous seasons, and who were there

    again in 1996, was that led by members of Bu Kurdy (Ghanatsah) who neighbored the

    reserve to the north. When Bu Hasan and Jimlan also lodged requests for licenses, all

    applications were approved. Both Bu Kurdy and Bu Salah, however, felt that Jimlan and

    Bu Hasan had no right to any leases on the plantation, as their tribal grazing grounds at

    Hrabjah were unaffected by the plantation. They took their grievance to the plantation

    guard who cancelled Jimlan's and Bu Hasan's leases on the spot.

    Aggrieved, Jimlan and Bu Hasan took their protest to the authorities, reiterating

    the formal position that any Syrian could legally take out a lease. The Hama Governor

  • 26

    went with the heads of the provincial Steppe Directorate and Peasants Union14 office to

    Abu al-Fayad to settle the dispute. The resolution went in Jimlan's and Bu Hasan's favor.

    The authorities hired a local tractor and ploughed a boundary line within the plantation to

    separate the disputing parties. As compensation, Bu Salah and Bu Kurdy were released

    from all plantation rules: firewood could henceforth be collected, sheep numbers would

    be unregulated, and camping, watering and milking could take place in the plantation.

    The Head of the Steppe Directorate protested strongly against the decision but was

    ultimately unsuccessful in changing it. Within a few days, instead of the 22,000 sheep

    paid for by the Bu Salah and the Bu Kurdy groups there were now 40,000 in the

    plantation. The plantation was shut down after three weeks.

    5. CONCLUSIONS AND POLICY IMPLICATIONS

    The above discussion demonstrates the value of customary institutions supportive

    of herder mobility, reciprocal arrangements with respect to resource use, and inter-tribal

    conflict resolution mechanisms when it comes to rangeland management. Contrary to

    popular belief that they have broken down and disappeared, many customary institutions

    in Syria remain strong and continue to be influential in the property rights domain. Their

    inherent flexibility means they are usually better suited to the prevailing non-equilibrium

    environment of the Syrian rangelands when compared to the rigid statutory laws and

    inappropriate technologies imposed by the state. Imposition of technologies will not

    succeed unless tribal land tenure and institutions are taken into account. Customary

    institutions represent a superior foundation for an integrated and inclusionary resource

    14 The Peasants Union is an arm of the ruling Bath Party and took control of co-operatives from the MAAR in 1974.

  • 27

    management system. The continuing existence of these institutions contradicts Hardins

    assumption of the inability of resource users to coordinate their actions to avert over-

    exploitation. It is not possible to prove that these customary methods are

    environmentally sustainable since ecological studies based on the new paradigms in the

    field have yet to be conducted. But what these institutions do represent are the

    foundations of a sustainable system by reducing transaction costs and affording local

    legitimacy.

    Past policies centralizing rangeland management were founded on misplaced

    assumptions about the physical dynamics of the steppe environment as well as the

    capacity of herders to cooperate together and regulate their use of pastoral resources.

    Shrub technologies like Atriplex have proven ill-suited to livestock as well as

    incompatible with herders' socioeconomic realities. Plantations likewise conflict with

    mobility objectives and customary land tenure, fueling the incidence of tribal conflict. In

    contrast to this failed top-down approaches are the enduring customary institutions whose

    sensitivity to the physical and social environment and inherent legitimacy have enabled

    them to overcome statutory abolition, even to the extent of obliging the authorities to

    recognize customary agreements.

    With a fresh understanding of arid environments and the customary system, there

    are new opportunities for rangeland management in Syria. Tribes no longer represent a

    political threat as they once did, but they do represent irreplaceable social capital. With

    doubts raised about imported shrub technologies, plantations, and steppe policy more

    broadly, existing tribal systems offer a solid foundation on which to build an effective

    and efficient administration of steppe management and conservation. The task that now

  • 28

    faces the authorities in Syria and elsewhere in the region is to respond to this latent

    opportunity and enter into a genuine partnership with the steppe users for the

    management and conservation of steppe resources.

  • 29

    REFERENCES

    Abu Jaber, K. 1966. The Arab Ba`th Socialist party: History, ideology, and organization. Syracuse: Syracuse University Press.

    ACSAD. 1992. Desertification in Syria. In World atlas of desertification, eds. N. Middleton and D. Thomas. London: Edward Arnold.

    Behnke, R., I. Scoones, and C. Kerven. 1993. Range ecology at disequalibrium: New methods of natural variability and pastoral adaptation in African Savannas. London: Overseas Development Institute.

    Bietenholz, P. 1963. Desert and Bedouin in the European mind: Changing conceptions from Middle Ages to the present day. Extramural Studies Board. Khartoum: University of Khartoum.

    Deiri, W. 1990. Contribution a l'etude phyto-ecologique et de la potentialite pastorale en Syrie aride, MSc, Thesis, Institut de botanique, Universite de Montpellier.

    Dresch, P. 1993. Tribes, government and history in Yemen. Oxford: Clarendon Paperbacks.

    FAO. 1956. Report to the government of Syria on a program for improvement in sheep breeding and management. No 571. Rome.

    ________. 1966. Report to the Steppe Directorate: Grazing trial, Wadi al-`Azib Range and Sheep Experiment Station 1963-1966. Rome.

    ________. 1967. Report to the government of Syria on range management and fodder development. No.TA2351 PL:TA/43. Rome: UNDP/FAO.

    ________. 1973. Terminal Report: Syria 002. Intergovernmental Committee 24th Session 3-9 October 1973, p. 14. Rome.

    ________. 1974. Report to the Government of the SAR on range management and fodder development. SYR/58/011. Rome.

    Goodchild, A. and A. Osman. 1993. Value of Atriplex halimus and Salsola vermiculata foliage as supplements for barley straw. Annual report 1992 of Pasture, Forage and Livestock Program. Aleppo: ICARDA.

    Hardin, G. 1968. The tragedy of the commons. Science 162: 12431248.

    Haut-commisariat de la Republique Francaise and Direction du Service des Renseignements du Levant. 1930. Les tribus nomades et semi-nomads des etats du Levant places sous Mandat Francais. Beyrouth: Imp Jeanne D'arc.

    Heyd, U. 1973. Studies in old Ottoman law. Oxford: Clarendon Press.

  • 30

    Hourani, A. 1991. Tribes and states in Islamic history. In Tribes and state formation in the Middle East, eds. P. Khoury and J. Kostiner, pp. 303312. London: IB Tauris.

    Issawi, C. 1987. An Arab philosophy of history: Selections from the Prolegomena of Ibn Khaldun of Tunis (1332-1406). Cairo: The American University in Cairo Press.

    Issawi, C. and C. Dabezies. 1951. Population movements and population pressure in Jordan, Lebanon, and Syria. Midland Memorial Fund Quarterly 29(4).

    LaBianca, O. 1990. Sedentarization and nomadization: Food system cycles at Hesban and vicinity in Transjordan. Berrien Springs.

    Le Houerou, N. 1992. The role of saltbush (Atriplex spp.) in arid land rehabilitation in the Mediterranean Basin: A review. Agroforestry Systems 18: 107148.

    ________. 1995. Drought-tolerant and water-efficient trees and shrubs ('trubs') for rehabilitation of tropical and subtropical arid lands. Journal of Land Husbandry 1: 26.

    Lewis, N. 1987. Nomads and settlers in Syria and Jordan, 1800-1980. Cambridge: Cambridge Middle East Library.

    Leybourne, M., F. Ghassali, A. Osman, T. Nordblom, and G. Gintzburger. 1993. The utilization of fodder shrubs (Atriplex spp., Salsola vermiculata) by agro-pastoralists in the north Syrian steppe. ICARDA Annual Report for the Pasture, Forage and Livestock Program, pp. 142160. Aleppo: ICARDA.

    Maktari, A. 1971. Water rights and irrigation practices in Lahj: A study of the application of customary and Shari'ah law in southwest Arabia. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    McKell, C. 1975. Shrubs: A neglected resource of arid lands. Science 187: 803809.

    Ngaido, T. 1997. Land tenure issues and the development of rangelands in Syria: Appraisal mission for the Badia rangeland development project in Syria. Rome: International Fund for Agricultural Development.

    Nordblom, T., G. Arab, A. Osman, A., and G. Gintzburger. 1995. Survey of Bedouin groups with contracts to graze the government rangeland plantations at Maraghah, Aleppo Province, Syria. Regional symposium on integrated crop-livestock systems I the dry areas of West Asia and North Africa. Aleppo: ICARDA.

    Noy-Mier, I. 1990. Responses of two semiarid rangeland communities to protection from grazing. Israel Journal of Botany 39: 431442.

    Ostrom, E. 1990. Governing the commons: The evolution of institutions for collective action. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

  • 31

    Olsvig-Whittaker, L., P. Hosten, M. Shochat, and E. Shochat. 1993. Influence of grazing on sand field vegetation in the Negev desert. Journal of Arid Environments 24: 8193.

    Perevolotsky, A. 1995. Conservation, reclamation and grazing in the northern Negev: Contradictory or complementary concepts. ODI Pastoral Network Paper 38a. London: ODI.

    Rae, J. 1999. Tribe and State: Rangeland Management in the Syrian Steppe. Unpublished thesis. Faculty of Geography and Anthropology, University of Oxford.

    Rae, J., G. Arab, K. Jani, N. Murad, T. Ngaido, and T. Nordblom. 1996. Socio-economics of shrub plantations in Syria. Report to the Syrian Government. Aleppo: ICARDA.

    Sankary, A. 1982. Flora of the Syrian Steppe. Aleppo: University of Aleppo.

    Scoones, I. 1994. Living with uncertainty: New directions in pastoral development in Africa. London: Intermediate Technology Publications.

    Syrian Arab Republic (SAR). 1975. The minutes of meeting to resolve dispute over al-del`a al-gharbieh between Muhurrab Rakan al-Murshed, the representative of Sba`ah tribe, and the members of Ghanatsah tribe [Hadidiyin], represented by Faysal al-Sfuk. Office of Chief, Secret Police. Homs: Homs Provincial Administration.

    Stewart, F. 1995. Texts in Bedouin law. Unpublished copy of cases recorded in southern Sinai, the Social Studies Center. Sede Boqer:Blaustein Center for Desert Research.

    ________. 1986. Bedouin boundaries in central Sinai and the southern Negev. Wiesbaden: Otto Harrassowitz.

    UN. 1955. Progress in land reform. New York: UN Economic and Social Council.

    Wachholtz, R. 1996. Socio-economics of Bedouin farming systems in dry areas of Northern Syria. Stuttgart-Hohenhiem: Wissenschaftsverlag Vauk KG.

    Westoby, M., B. Walker, and I. Noy-Mier. 1989. Opportunistic management for rangelands not at equilibrium. Journal of Range Management 42(4): 266274.

    Widmer, R. 1936. Population. In Economic organization of Syria, ed. S. Himadeh, pp. 338. New York: AMS Press.

    Wilkinson, J. 1983. Traditional concepts of territory in southeast Arabia. The Geographical Journal 149: 301315.

  • 32

    World Bank. 1995. North Africa and Iran: Rangelands development in arid and semi-arid areas, strategies and policies. Washington D.C.: World Bank.

    Zakirov, 1989. Grazing problems in Iraq, Problems of desert development. c/c of problemy osvoeniia pustyn`, 4: 5863.

    Zakrya, A. 1947. Tribes of al-sham. Damascus: Dar al-Fekr.

  • CAPRi WORKING PAPERS

    LIST OF CAPRi WORKING PAPERS

    01 Property Rights, Collective Action and Technologies for Natural Resource Management: A Conceptual Framework, by Anna Knox, Ruth Meinzen-Dick, and Peter Hazell, October 1998.

    02 Assessing the Relationships Between Property Rights and Technology Adoption in Smallholder Agriculture: A Review of Issues and Empirical Methods, by Frank Place and Brent Swallow, April 2000.

    03 Impact of Land Tenure and Socioeconomic Factors on Mountain Terrace Maintenance in Yemen, by A. Aw-Hassan, M. Alsanabani and A. Bamatraf, July 2000.

    04 Land Tenurial Systems and the Adoption of a Mucuna Planted Fallow in the Derived Savannas of West Africa, by Victor M. Manyong and Victorin A. Houndkon, July 2000.

    05 Collective Action in Space:Assessing How Collective Action Varies Across an African Landscape, by Brent M. Swallow, Justine Wangila, Woudyalew Mulatu, Onyango Okello, and Nancy McCarthy, July 2000.

    06 Land Tenure and the Adoption of Agricultural Technology in Haiti, by Glenn R. Smucker, T. Anderson White, and Michael Bannister, October 2000.

    07 Collective Action in Ant Control, by Helle Munk Ravnborg, Ana Milena de la Cruz, Mara Del Pilar Guerrero, and Olaf Westermann, October 2000.

    08 CAPRi Technical Workshop on Watershed Management Institutions: A Summary Paper, by Anna Knox and Subodh Gupta, October 2000.

    09 The Role of Tenure in the Management of Trees at the Community Level: Theoretical and Empirical Analyses from Uganda and Malawi, by Frank Place and Keijiro Otsuka November 2000.

    10 Collective Action and the Intensification of Cattle-Feeding Techniques a Village Case Study in Kenyas Coast Province, by Kimberly Swallow, November 2000.

    11 Collective Action, Property Rights, and Devolution of Natural Resource Management: Exchange of Knowledge and Implications for Policy, by Anna Knox and Ruth Meinzen-Dick, January 2001.

  • CAPRi WORKING PAPERS

    12 Land Dispute Resolution in Mozambique: Evidence and Institutions of Agroforestry Technology Adoption, by John Unruh, January 2001.

    13 Between Market Failure, Policy Failure, and Community Failure: Property Rights, Crop-Livestock Conflicts and the Adoption of Sustainable Land Use Practices in the Dry Area of Sri Lanka, by Regina Birner and Hasantha Gunaweera, March 2001.

    14 Land Inheritance and Schooling in Matrilineal Societies: Evidence from Sumatra, by Agnes Quisumbing and Keijuro Otsuka, May 2001.