an example of creative accounting in public

Upload: sophia-ririn-kali

Post on 04-Apr-2018

218 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 7/29/2019 An Example of Creative Accounting in Public

    1/24

    Critical Perspectives on Accounting 19 (2008) 963986

    An example of creative accounting in publicsector: The private financing of

    infrastructures in Spain

    Bernardino Benito a,, Vicente Montesinos b,1, Francisco Bastida c,2

    a Department of Accounting, Faculty of Economics and Business, University of Murcia-Campus

    of Espinardo, 30100 Espinardo (Murcia), Spainb Department of Accounting, Faculty of Economics, University of Valencia, Avga. Tarongers s/n,

    46022 Valencia, Spainc Department of Accounting, Faculty of Economics and Business, Technical University of Cartagena,

    Alfonso XIII, 50, 30203 Cartagena, Spain

    Received 11 January 2007; received in revised form 25 July 2007; accepted 30 August 2007

    Abstract

    This paper analyses some proposals forprivatefinancing of public workshaving emerged in Spain inrecent years. We show that all the new financing methods assessed are incorrectly named as private,

    for the payments are finally made by the Government by means of its budgetary resources. A deferral

    of accounting and budgetary recognition of these transactions, together with a false disclosure in

    financial statements of the debt connected with the projects, are the main reporting consequences of

    the new funding methods. In short, it is a clear example of creative accounting with the aim of

    meeting the convergence criteria imposed by the European Union.

    2007 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.

    Keywords: Public sector; Creative accounting; Infrastructures; PFI

    The analysis and conclusions of this paper are part of a broader study, funded by the Spanish Fiscal Studies

    Institute. Corresponding author. Tel.: +34 968 363812; fax: +34 968 363818.

    E-mail addresses: [email protected] (B. Benito), [email protected] (V. Montesinos),

    [email protected] (F. Bastida).1 Tel.: +34 963 828294; fax: +34 963 828287.2 Tel.: +34 968 325740; fax: +34 968 325782.

    1045-2354/$ see front matter 2007 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.

    doi:10.1016/j.cpa.2007.08.002

    mailto:[email protected]:[email protected]:[email protected]://localhost/var/www/apps/conversion/tmp/scratch_2/dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.cpa.2007.08.002http://localhost/var/www/apps/conversion/tmp/scratch_2/dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.cpa.2007.08.002mailto:[email protected]:[email protected]:[email protected]
  • 7/29/2019 An Example of Creative Accounting in Public

    2/24

    964 B. Benito et al. / Critical Perspectives on Accounting 19 (2008) 963986

    1. Introduction

    Most of infrastructures have been financed in Spain through the public budget untilthe middle of the nineties. Concessions and private financing have been scarcely used.

    However, private financing of new infrastructures (private finance initiative, PFI, or more

    recently named also as publicprivate partnership, PPP) is growing in recent years. These

    are the main reasons for reducing the use of budgetary resources:

    European Monetary Union (EMU) requirements concerning government deficit and debt

    limit the amounts that public entities can borrow to finance capital assets. According to

    the 1996 Stability and Growth Agreement, European Governments must reach a balanced

    budget in 2001, namely, a zero deficit. This target must be achieved in spite of the social

    pressure for more and best public services and benefits, making almost impossible for

    the public sector to reduce current expenses and thus generate savings.

    Important investment funds are searching in the financial markets for safe and steady

    investments.

    Rigidity of traditional Public Administration brings about high management inefficien-

    cies. Financial earnings are normally improved by companies flexibility and management

    skills. Investment priorities, as well as verification of public works profitability and

    feasibility can be enhanced through the private business requirements if enough financial

    rate of return is achieved.

    Furthermore, the infrastructures still remain in Spain quite below the most advanced

    countries equipments in the European Union (EU). It is generally known that endowment

    for infrastructures is one of the most important conditions for economic growth in anycountry. For example, the 20052020 Infrastructures and Transports Strategic Plan of the

    Spanish Ministry of Developmenthighlights that,according to recent studies, the cumulative

    marginal productivity of the public capital is almost of 1.5, i.e., an increase ofD1 in public

    capital investment leads, in the long term, to a GDP increase of almost D1.5.

    All the arguments set out here lead to the conclusion that lots of imagination are required

    when searching for new methods to fund public investments. On the one hand, a high quality

    in public services must be accomplished, and on the other hand, a rigid budgetary discipline

    has to be achieved. Accordingly, new funding methods have appeared in which private

    partners are involved in the development of public investment projects (PFI).

    Our main hypothesis is that many countries have used PFIs to defer payment and this way

    control their deficits and debt without cutting investments in infrastructures and public ser-vices. Lack of a clear accounting standards on how to report PFIs has allowed governments

    to do it.

    The following pages analyse some proposals for private financing of public works having

    emerged in Spain in recent years. After assessing all the new financing methods, we find that

    they areincorrectly named as private, for thepayments arefinally made by theGovernment

    by means of its budgetary resources. A deferral of accounting and budgetary recognition of

    these transactions and a wrong disclosure in financial statements of the debt connected with

    the projects are the main reporting consequences of the new funding methods. In short, it is

  • 7/29/2019 An Example of Creative Accounting in Public

    3/24

    B. Benito et al. / Critical Perspectives on Accounting 19 (2008) 963986 965

    a clear example of creative accounting with the aim of meeting the convergence criteria

    imposed by the EU.

    The remaining of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 presents the theoreticalbackground. Section 3 describes the main PPP contracts characteristics. Section 4 shows

    the opportunities for using new financing methods of public works in Spain. In Section 5

    we analyse different forms of private financing of infrastructures and their implications for

    government deficit and debt. Section 6 summarizes and presents conclusions.

    2. Theoretical framework

    The choice between budget and PFI when financing infrastructures has to do with the

    theory of propertyrights, whichstates thatownership matters whencontractsare incomplete,

    thus preventing parties from stipulating all the potential eventualities in the contract (see

    Hart, 1996 for an insight on this theory). Therefore, a key aspect in PFI is the appropriate

    risk sharing between private and public sectors established in the contract. If adequate

    risk is not shifted to the private sector, then projects become quasi public, but with the

    funding removed from the governments balance sheet. A critical issue in the risk transfer

    arrangements is to achieve pricing that correctly reflects the risks assumed by each party to

    the transaction (Brown, 2005).

    Hart (2003) developed a theoretical model of PPPs within the framework of the property

    rights theory. He concluded that conventional provision is good if the quality of the building

    can be well specified, whereas the quality of the service cannot be. In contrast, PPP is good

    if the quality of the service can be well specified in the initial contract (or, more generally,

    there are good performance measures which can be used to reward or penalise the service

    provider), whereas the quality of the building cannot be.The principal rationale for the adoption of PPP is that it addresses the deficit of phys-

    ical infrastructures of the countries. Since Public investment is constrained by the limits

    on public spending imposed by membership of the single EU currency, PPP becomes an

    attractive way of funding investments. PPPs involve contracting between government and

    the private sector under conditions of imperfect information. Theoretical developments

    such as principalagent theory provide an insight on PPPs. This theory focuses on the

    design of optimal contracts in the face of asymmetries in the information and objectives

    of contracting parties. Emphasis is placed on the optimal allocation of risk as a means of

    incentivising agents to achieve principals (government) objectives. PPP contracts spec-

    ify which risks are borne by the government (principal) or contractor (agent). Moreover, as

    PPP contracts can connect different elements of infrastructure projects (for example, link thedesign and construction with one or all of the finance, operation and maintenance elements)

    there is better scope for transferring risk compared to traditional procurement methods.

    For example, payment may be withheld until assets are in operation thereby encourag-

    ing contractors to complete construction on time and within budget (Hurst and Reeves,

    2004).

    PPPs can provide higher value for money compared with other approaches, if there is an

    effective implementation structure and if the objectives of all parties can be met within the

    contract. We must bear in mind that such contracts are complex to design, implement and

  • 7/29/2019 An Example of Creative Accounting in Public

    4/24

    966 B. Benito et al. / Critical Perspectives on Accounting 19 (2008) 963986

    manage. Sometimes they are not the best option: indeed in some cases it has been reported

    that they lead to an increase in the costs of services to citizens.

    From a theoretical viewpoint, the main justification for PPP is the possibility to exploitthe management expertise and the efficiency of the private sector without giving up quality

    standards of outputs, thanks to appropriate control mechanisms from the public party. This

    result is achieved by setting up complex contractual arrangements with the private sector

    operator (agent) where the public sector acts as the principal. In principalagent rela-

    tionships, the most complex issues are the precise definition of the tasks assigned to the

    agent, the measurement of the agents performance, and the extent to which the principal

    can control the agents performance for the whole duration of the contractual relationship. In

    PPPs, the cornerstone is the allocation of risk between the two parties: well-designed PPPs

    redistribute the risk to the party that is the superior insurer or the least cost avoider, i.e.,

    the party best suited to control and/or bear the risk (European Parliament, 2006).

    The Public Choice theory argues that taxpayers perceive debt-funded projects less costly

    than tax-financed ones, since they fail to perceive the actual cost of debt (Buchanan, 1967).

    Taxpayers do not properly evaluate inter-temporal government budget restrictions. When

    government offers deficit-financed outlay program, taxpayers overestimate benefits of cur-

    rent expenditures and underestimate future tax burden. PFI contracts allow incumbents to

    invest in new infrastructures, which have a positive impact on voters opinion about them,

    while deferring the payments of the infrastructure.

    3. Public works funding through publicprivate partnership

    In order to fill the growing gap between needed infrastructures and available resources,

    a key question arises: Which is the best way to make the investment in terms of valuefor money? In this context, since the nineties, PPPs have spread in Europe in general,

    and in Spain in particular. However, compared to PPPs, traditional contracts still are

    more widely used, and they may be more appropriate in many projects. Even in the

    UK, where PPP is frequently used, traditional contracts finance 85% of public invest-

    ment (PriceWaterhouseCoopers-PWC, 2005). Thus, it is important to analyse the traditional

    model of public contracting as opposed to PPP. The main characteristics of the former would

    be

    The public sector buys assets, not services, to the private sector.

    Assets are ex ante perfectly specified: the public sector designs the asset before the

    contracting process starts.

    The private sector only takes responsibility for the asset construction. The private sectortakes no responsibility for the assets long-run yield after the guarantee period.

    The public sector is directly involved in the management of the project contract. If

    there are several companies singing the contract, the public sector usually takes the

    responsibility of coordinating them.

    In spite of its common use, there is neither a generally accepted definition nor a unique

    model of PPP. It encompasses several relationship structures in which the private sector

    provides an asset or a service to the public sector. Utilities and transport projects based in

  • 7/29/2019 An Example of Creative Accounting in Public

    5/24

    B. Benito et al. / Critical Perspectives on Accounting 19 (2008) 963986 967

    administrative concessions have been used since years ago in the EU, especially in France,

    Italy and Spain. In this type of contracts, the company receives the payments made by

    service users, as it is the case, for example, in highway tolls. PFIs, in the UK, broadenedthis concept to a wider scope of public infrastructures, and combined it with the introduction

    of services not paid by final users, but by the public sector.

    PFIs include several types of contract, such as

    Short run management contracts with zero or small capital expenditure. Administrative concession contracts. These may involve the funding, design and con-

    struction of assets, with an important investment, together with the providing of related

    services.

    Joint ventures and partial privatizations, with a shared ownership between the public and

    the private sector (see in this respect Bult-Spiering and Dewulf, 2006; PWC, 2005).

    The main difference between a PPP and a traditional contract is that in a PPP, private

    holder earnings are connected to service outcomes and to asset yield during the contractual

    period. The private holder is responsible not only for delivering the asset, but also for the

    project management and for the appropriate provision of the service during the contractual

    period. The timing of payments received by the company is completely different from

    traditional contracts.

    The European Commission (2004) highlights the following PPP characteristics:

    The relatively long duration of the relationship, involving cooperation between the public

    and the private partner on the project. The method of funding the project, partly from the private sector, sometimes by means

    of complex arrangements between the various players. However, public funds in some

    cases rather substantial may complement the private funds. The key role of the economic operator, who is involved in different stages in the project

    (design, completion, implementation, funding). The public partner focuses primarily on

    defining the objectives to be attained in terms of public interest, quality of services and

    pricing, and it takes responsibility for ensuring compliance with these objectives.

    The distribution of risks between the public partner and the private partner, to whom

    the risks generally borne by the public sector are transferred. However, a PPP does not

    necessarily mean that the private partner assumes all the risks, or even the major share

    of the risks linked to the project. The precise distribution of risk is determined case by

    case.

    Besides, the European Investment Bank (2005) identifies these aspects in PPP:

    It is initiated by the public sector. Involves a clearly defined project and the sharing of risks with the private sector.

    Is based on a contractual relationship which is limited in time.

    Has a clear separation between the public sector and the borrower: there must be a private

    partner providing financial resources to fund the project (PWC, 2005).

    PPPs introduce new elements in the relationships between public and private sector. The

    financial reports must disclose the assets/rights and liabilities/commitments that arise in

    the provision of services and infrastructures under PPP. PPPs, as opposed to traditional

  • 7/29/2019 An Example of Creative Accounting in Public

    6/24

    968 B. Benito et al. / Critical Perspectives on Accounting 19 (2008) 963986

    contracts or privatization, imply a risk sharing between public and private partners, in order

    to achieve a more efficient use of resources. Risk sharing and public resources involved

    determine the responsibility of the parties concerned in the project.An accounting discussion has started stemming from what we have just said. The issue

    at stake is the way PPPs should be reported in the public sector financial statements. The

    concrete PPP where the problem arises is the one in which the private holder is responsible

    for designing, building or reforming and financing an infrastructure. The contract enables

    the public partner to have the infrastructure at the citizens disposal, whereas the private

    partner commits to provide the infrastructure and is entitled to be paid by the public partner.

    When these new financing methods emerged, there was no clear accounting standard

    providingguidance on how to reportthem. Thus, many countriesused them to defer payment

    and this way control their deficits and debt without cutting investments in infrastructures

    and public services. In this sense, Milesi-Ferretti (2004, p. 378) says that the imposition of

    numerical rules may encourage the use of dubious accounting practices, thereby reducing

    the degree of transparency in the government budget. These concerns have gained strength

    with the use of creative public finance by a number of European countries in order to

    facilitate meeting the budget deficit ceiling established in the Maastricht Treaty. In the same

    way, Koen and van den Noord (2005, p. 7) state that creative accounting operations may

    have merits of their own. PPPs for instance have proliferated in several EU countries since

    the late 1990s, either at the national or sub-national level (e.g., in the form of PFI contracts in

    the UK and concessions in Spain). Instead of the government buying an asset and operating

    it, a private entity invests and owns the asset (at least partly and at least during the period of

    exploitation), selling the corresponding services to the government. PPPs may be justified

    on efficiency grounds, but from the perspective adopted here their main feature is that they

    initially reduce the general government deficit and debt for a given level of investment

    in publicly used infrastructure. In 1999, the Irish Government launched a programme ofPPPs, in order to address the countrys acute deficit of physical infrastructure. The first PPP

    to reach the stage of operation was the contract for five secondary schools. The evidence

    indicated that this PPP has not resulted in significant innovations, and the public sector has

    failed to provide any evidence of value for money (Hurst and Reeves, 2004).

    Within the EU, Spain has been one of the countries taking advantage of the lack of clear

    accounting standard for new financing methods for infrastructures. However, as we will see

    later, the last Eurostat guidance has banished all doubts, and accordingly, almost all these

    new methods must be included in order to compute the public deficit and debt.

    4. Opportunities for using new financing methods of public works

    Soon after the Spanish Conservative Government took over in March 1996, the Minister

    of Public Works considered the possibility of financing infrastructures based upon the use

    of funds coming from privatizations and other methods. The aim was to avoid an increase

    of government deficit and debt rates.

    Besides, several circumstances did exist for resorting to private financing:

    Plenty of available private savings.

  • 7/29/2019 An Example of Creative Accounting in Public

    7/24

    B. Benito et al. / Critical Perspectives on Accounting 19 (2008) 963986 969

    Private business licensees had at that time remarkable earnings and capitalization rates.

    Therefore, they had financial resources available for reinvesting.

    Considering the reduction of government investment gross fixed capital formation building firms looked to be inclined to share direct infrastructure investments, in order

    to enhance certain bidding amounts in public works.

    A policy of monetary stability led to reductions of interest rates and thus private invest-

    ment funds started to be interested in long-term investments with satisfactory profit

    margins.

    All these advantageous circumstances made the Government issue several rules to boost

    government investment. Thus, in December 1996 two acts were passed with the following

    decisions regarding private financing of public works:

    Amendment of some provisions of Governments Contracts Act, setting up the so-called

    German or key on hand method (also called turnkey) for contracting investments,according to which, government investments are not paid for until they are completely

    finished. The regulation of this contracting method was later developed by a Royal Decree

    in May 1997. The next section will analyse in detail this type of contract. Amendment of some provisions of the General Budgetary Act, in order to allow longer

    terms for payments and to ease the use of revenues from public enterprises.

    Changes in the 1972 rules for building, maintenance and operation of granted highways:

    Extension of concession term limit from 50 to 75 years.

    Enlargement of the scope of the concession for licencees. Road maintenance and

    operation are no longer the only allowed activities for these enterprises, but also other

    could be carried out, such as service areas at the highways. Securities could be issued as toll rights supporting documents. Further provisions for

    constitution and operations of the funds corresponding to these securities have beendeveloped by a 1998 Royal Decree.

    State-controlled firms entitled to borrow money can be established with budgetary

    resources. This variety has been known as Spanish method. We will be dealing with

    this in more detail later on.

    A public entity named Railway Infrastructures Management Entity (Gestor de

    Infraestructuras Ferroviarias, GIF)3 was created with the main objective of building

    and managing new railway infrastructures. This entity is a commercial corporation, not

    considered as Public Administration, since its revenues come from a fee the operators4

    pay for using the infrastructures. These entities will not be taken into account when

    calculating the public sector deficit and net lending/borrowing, according to European

    System of Accounts 1995 (ESA 95). This will be explained below.

    3 Established in 1997,has disappeared and joined the Railway Infrastructures Managing Administration (Admin-

    istrador de Infraestructura Ferroviaria, ADIF), which started working on 1 January 2005.4 A 1998 Royal Decree regulated the railway infrastructures operation for international transport services,

    railways corporations licences and rates for the use of railways infrastructures. All theses rules were adopted

    according art. no. 104 of the 1997 Spanish Act and the European Directives 95/18/CE, regulating the railways

    corporations licences and 95/19/CE, regulating the concession of railways infrastructure capacities and the fees

    to be paid by its use.

  • 7/29/2019 An Example of Creative Accounting in Public

    8/24

    970 B. Benito et al. / Critical Perspectives on Accounting 19 (2008) 963986

    The next section analyses these proposals, particularly: the full price payment con-

    tract (also known as German method or Turnkey); the establishment of enterprises or

    public entities building works on behalf of either the Administration or themselves (sys-tem known as Spanish method) and the shadow toll (financing method used by some

    Spanish Regions). In spite of these methods being considered PPP or PFI, as we said in

    the introduction, all of them are incorrectly categorized as private, for the payments are

    finally made by the Government through its budgetary resources. A deferral of accounting

    and budgetary recognition of these transactions and a wrong disclosure in financial state-

    ments of the debt connected with the projects are the main reporting consequences of these

    new funding methods. In short, it is a clear example of creative accounting with the aim

    of meeting the convergence criteria imposed by the EU.

    5. Different forms of private financing of infrastructures and their implications

    for government deficit and debt

    First, we must make clear that no standards have been developed in Spain for PFI

    accounting treatment. Accordingly, we will focus on the EU regulatory framework, more

    specifically, on the ESA 95 Manual on government deficit and debtissued by Eurostat. We

    believe the analysis of these EU rules is of great interest, because they are legally binding in

    all member countries of the Eurozone, and almost all of them have considered the financing

    formulas explained in this manuscript in a larger or smaller extent (see at this respect PWC,

    2005), with the purpose of fulfilling the Maastricht Treaty requirements for public deficit

    and debt limits.

    Fig. 1 and Table 1 show how PFI use and high government deficit have been closely

    related in many EU countries. Thus, the higher the government deficit, the larger the useof PFI. This relationship makes clear, as stated above, that in most cases the aim of using

    PPP or PFI has been the deferral of the payment and debt. In summary, we could label it as

    creative accounting.

    Fig. 1. Average 20002005 PFI activity as a percentage of mean GDP. Source: PricewaterhouseCoopers (2005).

  • 7/29/2019 An Example of Creative Accounting in Public

    9/24

    B. Benito et al. / Critical Perspectives on Accounting 19 (2008) 963986 971

    Table 1

    General government deficit ()/surplus (+) as a percentage of GDP

    Source: Eurostat.

    Shaded countries are those with the highest PFI activity (see Fig. 1).

    The ESA 95 Manual is the result of European Commissions concern about the need

    to ensure the correct application of ESA 95 criteria to elaborate statistics and government

    finance accounts. PFI are among the operations with unclear treatment. This document

    supersedes other Eurostat regulations, and it is the result of some countries consultations

    to Eurostat regarding the accounting treatment of some PFI operations, which were being

    reported according to ESA 79. Usually, the answers to the consultations were published asNews Releases, which we will refer to in the following pages (Table 2 summarizes them).

    5.1. Full price payment when public works are accepted (German method)

    In this case, the Government signs a contract with the successful bidder for building and

    financing the project. Building costs and interests are paid when the work is finished and

    accepted by the Government. Therefore, the Government does not pay any money until the

    project is finished (there are no partial payments). The contractor must finance the building,

    i.e., paying costs in advance while the building project is in progress, until the work is finally

  • 7/29/2019 An Example of Creative Accounting in Public

    10/24

    972 B. Benito et al. / Critical Perspectives on Accounting 19 (2008) 963986

    Table 2

    Main news releases of the Eurostat in relation with the treatment of PFI/PPP

    News Release no. 16/97 of 21 February 1997, Treatment of Public Finance Initiatives

    News Release no. 33/97 of 30 April 1997, Treatment of public finance initiatives

    News Release no. 15/2002 of 31 January 2002, Treatment of the transfer of Government real estate to a

    publicly owned corporation in Austria

    News Release no. 80/2002 of 3 July 2002, Securitisation operations undertaken by general government

    News Release no. 18/2004 of 11 February 2004, Treatment of publicprivate partnerships

    News Release no. 88/2007 of 25 June 2007, Securitisation operations undertaken by general government

    accepted. This method has been widely used for road building in Germany (that is why it

    is known as German method) (Izquierdo and Vasssallo, p. 200).

    When the public work is finished, the Government will pay either in cash or througha maximum period of 10 years. It is possible for the contractor to convert these future

    payments into tolls to be paid by the infrastructure users. The following conditions have to

    be met to use this financing method:

    Eligible projects are: road infrastructures, water and railway equipment and environmen-

    tal and coastal installations.

    Total contracting price, financial costs when deferring payments not included, must be

    over the following amounts: Roads, 24 million euros. Railway and water infrastructures, 18 million euros. Environmental and coastal installations, 6 million euros.

    This kind of contracts is not applicable to infrastructures improvements, repairs, conser-vation and demolition works.

    A specific contract will be signed for any individual work, within the abovementioned

    limits. Therefore, accumulation of works in a single contract is not permitted.

    Total annual amount committed using this contracting method cannot go beyond 30% of

    initial budgetary appropriations for investments in capital assets during the year.

    This German method has been used by the Spanish Central Administration. Although

    a specific regulation of this method for Municipal Governments was supposed to be issued

    more than 1 year ago, it hasnot been publishedso far. In thesame way, some Spanish Regions

    planned to use this kind of contract, but no concrete regulation has yet been adopted.5

    The main reason argued for using this financing method is the possibility to defer

    accounting and budgetary recognition of investment expenses until the date the work is

    fully executed. In the same way, the recognition of the debt connected with these trans-

    actions is also deferred. Therefore, during the building period, neither budgetary expenses

    nor net borrowing increase, thus making easier for the Spanish Government to meet the

    5 Public sector in Spain is organized in three levels: State or Central Administration, Regions (Autonomous

    Communities) and Local Entities. Out of the total government expenses in Spain, these three administrations

    spend approximately 50%, 35% and 15%, respectively.

  • 7/29/2019 An Example of Creative Accounting in Public

    11/24

    B. Benito et al. / Critical Perspectives on Accounting 19 (2008) 963986 973

    convergence criteria (this is a patent example of creative accounting). That is to say,

    the Government argues that the infrastructure is not reported until it is finished and deliv-

    ered. However, the bottom line is only the deferral of recognition of expenses and debtin the accounting books. This contract makes possible to do important public works, but

    at the expense of relevant commitments on future budgets and an increase of government

    indebtedness.

    According to the current EU accounting standard (ESA 95), in force since 1999, invest-

    ment expenses must be reported along the years of construction (accrual accounting). The

    previous approach under ESA79 (cash accounting). reported the expenses according to the

    payments made (Luder, 2000, pp. 118122). A consequence of the taking in consideration

    of these circumstances has been the suspension of the use this financing method during

    several years, according to additional dispositions of the laws passing the State General

    Budgets.

    5.2. Constitution of public corporations and/or public entities

    As previously stated, the possibility to create public firms for road and water works build-

    ing and operation was created by Law in 1996. This is the case of Railway Infrastructures

    Management Entity. This entity has its own legal status as a subsidiary of the Ministry

    of Public Works, it is able to hire and fire its own staff and it holds its own assets and

    liabilities. The entitys main activities are building the high-speed railway infrastructures

    connecting MadridBarcelonaFrance, as well as the safety and control systems manage-

    ment. Revenues come from rates paid by users of operated lines and by the users of its own

    telecommunication networks. The entity can borrow funds by itself and the State is allowed

    to give it a financial support. Similar corporations has been also established by the Ministry

    of Environment, for example, Ebro Basin Waters (Aguas de la Cuenca del Ebro, ACESA).Considering the Spanish Regions, the Catalan Government was the first creating this

    kind of corporations, as in 1990 it established the firm Infrastructures Management Inc.

    (Gestion de Infraestructuras S.A., GISA). An agreement defines the management and

    financial links between Catalan Government and GISA, which obtains revenues by the

    management responsibilities for building infrastructures. Under the guarantee of these rev-

    enues, the firm obtains funding in the financial markets, without any specific governmental

    guarantee. When infrastructure construction is finished, it becomes a capital asset of the

    Catalan Government. Similar processes are going on in other Regions: Andalusia, Castilla-

    Leon, Galicia, Castilla-La Mancha or Madrid. This kind of corporations is also usual in the

    local public sector, but only in the largest municipalities.

    In addition to efficacy and efficiency criteria, the main advantage of these entities hasbeen that their borrowing is not consolidated when setting up public sector debt. However,

    in the new ESA 95 the borders for different sectors of economy are established according

    to a market criterion. Thus, if an entitys purpose is to produce goods or services for the

    market and it sells its production in the market, it must be included in the corporations

    sector, irrespective whether the owner is public or private (Jones, 2000). According to ESA

    95 criteria, if sales are 50% or more out of the total operating expenses of an economic

    unit, the production of this unit is considered as market-oriented (paragraphs 3.33 and

    3.37). In order to meet this criterion, amounts paid by the Government that contracted the

  • 7/29/2019 An Example of Creative Accounting in Public

    12/24

    974 B. Benito et al. / Critical Perspectives on Accounting 19 (2008) 963986

    building of the infrastructure are not considered as sales. On the one hand, a consequence of

    ESA 95 criteria is the non-inclusion in the consolidated accounts of Public Administrations

    of market-oriented units, not necessarily with legal status. On the other hand, ESA 95simultaneously leads to the inclusion of corporations, agencies or entities mainly operating

    on the base of official financial aids. This is the case, for instance, of the agent corporations

    we are analysing in this section.

    In the above-mentioned circumstances, newfunding and management methods arise with

    the aim of establishing entities whose debt is not consolidated in public sector accounts.

    Special attention must be paid to the constitution of securities funds. A securitisation oper-

    ation occurs when a government transfers ownership rights over financial or non-financial

    assets, or the right to receive specific future revenues, to another unit, named the securi-

    tisation unit, who in exchange pays the originator. In order to finance the purchase, the

    securitisation unit borrows on its own account by, typically, issuing bonds called asset

    backed securities (ABS). The securitisation unit uses income generated by the transferred

    asset or by the specific future flows, or by sales of the transferred assets, to service its debt.

    Usually the lenders will have a direct and legal claim on those assets or on those flows, in

    the event of the securitisation unit not paying the interest and principal due.

    When the proceeds obtained from the sale of the assets are higher than the initial price

    paid to government, and the securitisation contract includes, in addition to the initial pay-

    ment by the securitisation unit, a clause on additional future payments to government, a

    deferred purchase price (DPP) is said to exist and all or part of the proceeds are allocated

    to government.

    Fig. 2 shows the basic features of the operating mechanism of this funding method.

    The key issue to be determined is whether a securitisation operation gives rise to revenue

    for the government, thereby reducing the public deficit if there is one, or whether the

    proceedsshould be considered as government borrowing. Eurostat has decided the following(News Release no. 88/2007 of 25 June 2007) (this decision complements and amends the

    decision taken on the same issue in News Release 80/2002 of 3 July 2002):

    1. All securitisation of fiscal claims by government should be treated as government bor-

    rowing.

    2. The existence of a DPP clause or of similar arrangements should lead to the classification

    of the securitisation operation as government borrowing.

    3. A clause in the contract referring to the possibility of substitution of assets (except for

    marginal cases limited in scope and deriving purely from technical and material errors)

    should lead to the classification of the securitisation operation as government borrowing.

    4. A clause of the securitisation contract stipulating ex ante government compensation tothe unit (in case of government actions which are specifically related to the unit and

    not to different economic units more generally) should lead to the classification of the

    securitisation operation as government borrowing.

    5. When government compensates (for instance in the form of cash, of debt assumption,

    or of direct or indirect guarantee) the unit ex post for specific events, although compen-

    sation was not originally foreseen in the contract, a reclassification of the operation as

    government borrowing must occur, with an impact on the surplus/deficit of government

    in the year in which the compensation is decided.

  • 7/29/2019 An Example of Creative Accounting in Public

    13/24

    B. Benito et al. / Critical Perspectives on Accounting 19 (2008) 963986 975

    Fig. 2. Operating mechanismof securities funds.(1) Public Administration asks the public entity for infrastructure

    building. This request gives rise to rights in favour of this public entity. (2) Public entitys rights are handed over

    to a securities fund, which pays to the entity the present value of these rights. With this money, the public entity

    can afford to pay builders or financial institutions for refunding previous borrowings. (3) Public Administration

    pays to the securities fund.

    To sum up, when Spain has used this funding method, the aim was to hide public debt(as Koen and van den Noord, 2005 point out). Eurostat decision, however, concluded that it

    was creative accounting, and therefore the balance sheet should disclose the related debt.

    Something similar happened in other EU countries, such as Austria, Greece or Italy (see in

    this respect Milesi-Ferretti and Moriyama, 2006, p. 3288).

    5.3. The shadow toll method

    Known also as DBFO (design, build, finance and operate), the infrastructure is built

    and operated by the concessionaire, who usually is a private firm. Government just

    pays the corresponding rates in order to get services provided using the assets con-

    structed. This model is being applied for motorways, medical care in hospitals, elderlyshomes, day nurseries, sport facilities, pools, waste treatment, water desalination, etc.

    The payment is made by means of periodic amounts of money that depend upon the

    use of the infrastructures by citizens. In order to avoid a low-use risk for the licensee

    firm, the Government guarantees the concessionaire enough revenues to achieve financial

    balance.

    This kind of contracts is, in short, nearly pure concessions, with the only difference that

    it is not the user but the Government who pays the rates. The accounting treatment of this

    funding method for infrastructures resembles the operating lease. Sometimes, infrastruc-

  • 7/29/2019 An Example of Creative Accounting in Public

    14/24

    976 B. Benito et al. / Critical Perspectives on Accounting 19 (2008) 963986

    tures ownership transfers to the Administration at the end of the operating period, and then

    the essence of the method is closer to a finance lease.

    Spanish Regions legislation also labels this funding method as demand levy, and thesystem is built upon a private sector involvement in the construction projects, on the base

    of foreseeable cash flows generation. Users do not pay any toll, but it is the Government

    who guarantees payments to private corporations according to previously fixed rates.

    The main argument Spanish Regions make for the adoption of this funding method is

    to foster private involvement specially small and medium size firms in public works

    projects development.

    It is not hard to realize that the funding method based on the shadow toll is very similar

    to the finance lease. As in the cases of Germany and France,6 when the Government uses

    the finance lease, it cedes public property to a leasing corporation for some time. This

    corporation constructs and finances the work and when the building process is concluded,

    the construction is made over to the Government, which operates the installations as lessee,

    until the date of reversion.

    We think the Belgian experience on the shadow toll is worth commenting. In 1960 the

    Belgian Government decided to use this way to finance its road construction. The reason

    for using this method was to cope with the existing budgetary limitations and thus being

    able to avoid an increase in taxes or debt. As time went by, it was clear that the only real

    outcome of this policy was an increase of public financial burden. Accordingly, in 1982,

    after more than 600 km of roads had been constructed (50% of total network), the Belgian

    State took up again the direct management of the highways program (Izquierdo, 1992, pp.

    119120).

    In the United Kingdom, the 1991 Roads Act set up a new system for construction of

    toll roads by the private sector. This system operates through a contractual link with the

    State. On the one hand, each project must be self-financed by means of the tolls paid by theusers. On the other hand, no public guarantees or aids are allowed (this is purely the method

    known as project finance). The promoter or contractor takes on the building and operation

    risks; as it is not usual in UK to pay tolls by the users, it is the State which pays during

    the first years the road runs (from this fact follows the famous name of shadow toll for this

    method). However, the possibility exists for a financial support of the British State to these

    infrastructures, using operating grants, earmarked taxes, exchange guarantees, refunding

    advances, subsidized loans, fiscal benefits, etc.

    Austria has also experienced this financing method. In this way, different highways

    construction, operation and maintaining projects have been developed since 1982. Other

    experiences using this method for financing roads or highwayswereimplemented in Finland,

    Portugal and the Netherlands (Yates, 1992).Out of the PPP/PFI methods for infrastructure and public services provision, the shadow

    toll technique has been the most controversial, mainly in the British accounting practice,

    due to its implications in the Government financial reports (see in this respect Allen, 2001;

    Broadbent and Laughlin, 1999; English and Guthrie, 2003; Froud and Shaoul, 2001; Heald,

    6 In this latter country this kind of contractsis named public work management contracts (marche dentreprise

    de travaux publics); see Aguila (1995) and Besancon and Van Ruymbeke (1990).

  • 7/29/2019 An Example of Creative Accounting in Public

    15/24

    B. Benito et al. / Critical Perspectives on Accounting 19 (2008) 963986 977

    2003; Heald and Geaughan, 1997; Hodges and Mellett, 2002; Mayston, 1999; Rutherford,

    2003). This is a summary of the accounting problems at stake:

    (a) whether properties used in PFI contracts are assets and the amounts to be paid to

    operators are governments liabilities or if, by contrast, the Government only receives

    a service and pays for it;

    (b) whether the operator owns an asset to deliver a service or if, by contrast, the operator

    has a financial asset representing the amount of payment obligations owed by the

    Government.

    The solution finally adopted in the UK is that the Government must report the asset if

    the Government directly assumes the assets risks and benefits. Therefore, risk is the key

    element when defining the nature of a DBFO contract (Accounting Standards Board, 1994;

    Treasury Private Finance Taskforce, 1997).

    The first time Eurostat issued guidance for estimating PFI incidence on Government

    deficit and debt was in its 21 February 1997 News Release no. 16/97, through the analysis

    of two cases:

    Case no. 1. A Government asks a corporation to build and finance a capital asset. Cor-

    porations become the owners of these assets as the building is going on. In this case, the

    gross capital formation must be included in the Public Administration sector. Investment

    in this case increases government deficit but it has no impact on government borrowing,

    as Council Regulation 3065/93 determines. According to this regulation, Public Admin-

    istrations long and medium-term commercial commitments with corporations are not

    included in debt when calculating convergence criteria accomplishment. Case no. 2. A Government asks a corporation to build a capital asset which will be

    operated by this corporation right through its useful life. The corporation becomes toothe owner of the asset. In this case, gross capital formation must be included in the

    corporations sector, and there is no incidence either on government deficit or debt.

    Eurostat shows also concrete examples where both possibilities are simultaneously in

    use: case no. 1 is the method used in Germany for building and pre-financing of roads by

    public sector agents. The bridge of Oresund, joining Denmark and Sweden, is an example

    of case no. 2. The construction began in 1996 by means of a Governmental Danish and

    Swedish Consortium of public corporations. The consortium funded the project by issuing

    government-secured debentures. The works ended in 2000 and the consortium has a license

    for operating the bridge and collecting tolls. Total debt is estimated to be refunded in 2026,

    while the consortium will operate the bridge indefinitely. Gross capital formation is included

    in the corporations sector, with no incidence on government deficit.Other PFI contracts in UK are examples of case no. 2. Instead of buying and operating a

    capital asset, the State hires the services of an operator in the private sector ( Heald, 1997;

    Mumford, 1998). These operators manage to get the assets in order to provide the requested

    services. Gross capital formation is included in the corporations sector, with no incidence

    on government deficit. A purchase of services provided by business corporations is recorded

    in Public Administrations accounts, thus increasing government deficit every year.

    The Eurostat 30 April 1997 News Release no. 33/97added a new case to the previously

    considered (case no. 3): a corporation builds an infrastructure and subsequently the corpora-

  • 7/29/2019 An Example of Creative Accounting in Public

    16/24

    978 B. Benito et al. / Critical Perspectives on Accounting 19 (2008) 963986

    tion operates it during a given time period, collecting periodically certain amounts of money

    paid by Government. These payments concern the acquisition of infrastructure services. At

    the end of the operation time, the infrastructure comes back to the Public Administrationwith no additional payment. In this case, these rules must be taken into account:

    Initial investment (gross fixed capital formation) must be recorded in the corporations

    accounting books, with no incidence on government deficit. Government annual payments are services acquisitions that increase government deficit

    every year.

    At the end of the operating time, the reversion of infrastructures to Public Administration

    does not generate a reduction in government deficit.

    Considering the three above-mentioned PFI cases, we can conclude that Eurostat News

    Releases presents the German method (case no. 1) and shadow toll (cases no. 2 and no.

    3) treatment.

    Focusing on cases no. 2 and no. 3, investment must be reported as a fixed asset by the

    building corporation, with no increase of government expenses and debt. Only the amounts

    paid by Government when using fixed assets are recorded as government expenses (current

    expenses to be more precise).

    However, as previously discussed, shadow toll method has been used in Spain, as a

    licence system where private sector is engaged to build and maintain the infrastructure, and

    Government pays a toll or rate for its use, until the settlement of financial commitments.

    When the concession term is over, infrastructure becomes a public ownership, with no

    additional cost for Public Administration. As can be observed, the Spanish implementation

    of shadow toll differs a little bit of British PFI. According to British practices, any new

    investment the government tries to do using budgetary resources, must be supported by a

    specific study; this study must disclose that investment costs are lower than those incurredwhen using a new DBFO concession. As a result of this assessment, if PFI is preferred, a

    pure-toll concession or a service management or payment for services rendered contract

    will be implemented. Nevertheless, it is indeed a question of a deferred disclosure and by

    instalments paymentof investment, along with maintenance costs, all throughthe concession

    time.

    In short, we can considered this PFI as a hire purchase, or at most a quite similar method

    to a finance lease, with the only difference that no option will be paid by the lessee (Gov-

    ernment) to the lessor (private corporation) when receiving the definitive ownership of the

    asset. Another difference that can also be argued is that in the case of a finance lease, a fixed

    amount must be paid all through the term of the contract, whereas the fees to be paid when

    using the shadow toll method depend upon the use citizens make of the infrastructure(e.g., for roads fees are paid according to annual traffic). No exact previous calculation

    can thus be done of the amounts to be paid every year by Public Administration with its

    budgetary resources. However, Government will guarantee enough revenues for financial

    balance of the concessionaire. If no guarantee existed, probably nobody would bid for build-

    ing the infrastructure. Besides, the Government will also fix a ceiling amount to be paid

    (for example if traffic exceeds the ceiling volume of vehicles, no more fees will be paid).

    To sum up, we can say that Public Administration runs into debts that must be reported

    in the financial statements by its maximum amount, as required by a conservative account-

  • 7/29/2019 An Example of Creative Accounting in Public

    17/24

    B. Benito et al. / Critical Perspectives on Accounting 19 (2008) 963986 979

    ing philosophy. Spanish Regions PFI regulations require budgetary appropriations by the

    maximum amount the Government is bound to pay to the concessionaires (according to

    the foreseeable use of infrastructures), in order to guarantee both the effective operationof privately constructed works and the profitability of the investment. This fact endorses

    our opinion about the accounting treatment of the commitments stemming from this PFI,

    as no risks are indeed assumed by licensees. We must bear in mind that, as the theory of

    property rights shows, a key aspect in PFI is the accurate risk sharing between private and

    public sectors. If adequate risk is not shifted to the private sector, then projects become quasi

    public, but with the funding removed from the governments balance sheet. The amount of

    debt will be included in a fixed asset (a tangible asset or use duties). If the maximum amount

    taken for debt evaluation remains over the effective payments done when the concession

    term is over, asset and debt must be cut down by the difference. This reduction must be

    done every year by the difference between the maximum estimated payments and the real

    amount of commitments.

    In January 2000 there was a relevant shift in Eurostat initial opinion towards a position

    close to our arguments. Thus, the document ESA95 Manual on government deficit and

    debt shows a clarification about accounting treatments of these PFIs by means of two

    examples (which are identical to the shadow toll):

    Casea. Government requiresa corporation to build a prison accordingto the governments

    specifications. Government agrees to pay the corporation a certain amount for 25 years

    for making the prison available for its use, provided it is adequately maintained. At the

    end of the 25-year period, legal ownership of the prison is transferred from de contractor

    to government.

    Case b. Government signs a contract with a corporation for the design and construction of

    a road. The corporation is also responsible for maintaining the road for 25 years accordingto an agreed standard. Government pays the contractor an annual fee linked to the number

    of vehicles using the road.

    According to Eurostat standards, the treatment for each case should be

    Case a. When the corporation is exposed to most of the risk/rewards of ownership dur-

    ing the period of exploitation, the infrastructure is recorded in the corporation balance

    sheet. The contract between government and the corporation has the characteristics of

    an operating lease. Only regular payments by government have an impact on govern-

    ment net lending/borrowing. If the infrastructure is given to government at the end of

    the operation period it will be presented in the government balance sheet through a gross

    fixed capital formation, balanced by a capital transfer, with no impact on government netlending/borrowing.

    Case b. When the government is exposed to most of the risk/rewards of ownership

    during the period of exploitation, the infrastructure is reported in the government balance

    sheet. The contract between government and the corporation has the characteristics of

    a financial lease. The infrastructure built by the corporation is allocated to government

    balance sheets through GFCF, balanced by an imputed loan of equal value. Accordingly,

    there is an impact on government net lending/borrowing for the value of GFCF, and

    government debt is increased by the amount of the loan imputed. During the operation

  • 7/29/2019 An Example of Creative Accounting in Public

    18/24

    980 B. Benito et al. / Critical Perspectives on Accounting 19 (2008) 963986

    Table 3

    Factors influencing the distinction between operating and finance lease

    1. Who is responsible for the maintenance and insurance of the asset?Assume government organizes and pays directly for the insurance and maintenance of the asset

    This suggests a finance lease since government is bearing the risk of variations in such costs

    2. Who repays finance on early termination of a contract?

    Assume the government is responsible for repayment of the corporation debt in the event of early

    termination of the contract

    This suggests a finance lease since government is bearing that risk

    3. Who determines the nature of the asset?

    Assume the corporation has significant and ongoing discretion on how to fulfil the contract; it makes the key

    decisions on design and construction of the asset; it decides how it is operated and maintained in order to

    provide the service required by the purchaser

    This suggests and operating lease

    4. Who bears the demand risk?Demand for services provided by the asset might be greater or less than expected. Assume the corporation

    income is affected by the demand for the asset, such that government or other customers only pay for the

    amount of service consumed

    This suggests an operating lease

    5. Are there any third part revenues?

    Assume the corporation uses the asset to provide services to customers other than just government, and the

    government is not exposed to the variability of third party demand, and these revenues are significant part

    of the total income from the asset

    This suggests an operating lease

    6. Does government pay less if the quality of service is not good enough?

    Assume government payments are reduced when the service provided by the corporation is not up the

    required standard, even if this is because of problems with asset rather than how it is operated

    This suggests an operating lease

    7. Does government pay more if the corporation costs increase?

    Assume government does pay more if there is an increase in the corporation costs related to the asset. For

    example the corporation might have to undertake more maintenance than expected

    This suggests a finance lease

    8. Who bears the residual value risk?

    Assume government has the option, at the end of the contract, to buy the asset at the current market price,

    and that it is not bound to buy the asset at a pre-agreed price if it does not need it nor if the asset is not in

    good condition

    This suggests an operating lease

    period, annual payments should be subdivided into repayments of principal and interestpayments related to the imputed loan. Interest payments have an impact on government

    net lending/borrowing.

    Risks/rewards of ownership should be assessed according to the factors presented in

    Table 3.

    In a contract, not all the characteristics have to point to the same assessment of the con-

    tract, but some may lead to classify it as financial lease and some others may lead to consider

    it as an operating lease. In this situation, the relative importance of each characteristic of the

  • 7/29/2019 An Example of Creative Accounting in Public

    19/24

    B. Benito et al. / Critical Perspectives on Accounting 19 (2008) 963986 981

    project must be balanced. In order to avoid confusion regarding risks evaluation, Eurostat

    issued 11 February 2004 News Release no. 18/2004 (which has been added to the ESA

    95 Manual), making clear the treatment of PFI impact on government deficit (net borrow-ing)/surplus (net lending) and debt. This news release states that Eurostat decision applies

    to contracts in which government is the main buyer of services provided by a private entity

    and the demand comes directly from the government or from other users (as for example,

    in medical and education services or some transport infrastructures). An important feature

    of these contracts is that they usually require the production of several assets. These assets,

    on the one hand, are specifically designed for the provision of the service, and on the other

    hand, they need an initial capital outlay. The key issue is the beforehand classification of the

    assets involved in the PFI contract: either as government assets or recorded in the private

    partner balance sheet.

    Eurostat considers the assets involved in a PFI as non-government assets only if there

    is strong evidence that the partner is bearing most of the risk attached to the specific PFI.

    Therefore, the analysis of the risks borne by the contractual parties is the core element

    for the assessment of a PFI project, as far as the classification of the assets involved in

    the contract is concerned. This analysis, therefore, is essential to ensure the appropriate

    accounting treatment of PFI impact on the government deficit. However, this assessment

    does not consider risks not closely related to the asset and that can be fully separated from

    the main contract. This the case when part of the contract might be periodically renegotiated,

    and subject to performance and penalty payments that do not significantly depend on the

    condition of the main assets. Many risks may be observed in practice in such arrangements.

    Eurostat has selected three main categories of generic risks. Therefore, bearing a risk

    for one party means that this party bears the majority of the risk.

    A first category is construction risk, covering notably events like late delivery, failure to

    keep specified standards, additional costs, technical deficiency and external negative effects.Governments obligation to start making regular payments to a partner without taking into

    account the effective condition of the assets would be evidence that government bears the

    majority of the construction risks.

    A second category is availability risk, where the responsibility of the partner is quite

    clear. It may not be in a position to deliver the volume that was contractually agreed or to

    meet safety or public certification standards relating to the provision of services to final

    users, as specified in the contract. It also applies where the partner does not meet the

    required quality standards relating to the delivery of the service, as stated in the contract,

    and resulting from an evident lack of performance of the partner. Government will be

    assumed not to bear such risk if it is entitled to reduce significantly (as a kind of penalty)

    its periodic payments, like any normal customer would require in a commercial contract.Government payments must depend on the effective degree of availability supplied by the

    partner during a given period of time. Application of the penalties where the partner is

    defaulting on its service obligations should be automatic, should also have a significant

    effect on the partners revenue/profit and must not be purely cosmetic or symbolic.

    A third category is demand risk, covering variability of demand (higher/lower than

    expected when the contract was signed) irrespective of the performance of the private

    partner. This risk should only cover a shift of demand not resulting from inadequate or low

    quality of the services provided by the partner or any action changing the quantity/quality

  • 7/29/2019 An Example of Creative Accounting in Public

    20/24

    982 B. Benito et al. / Critical Perspectives on Accounting 19 (2008) 963986

    of services provided. To the contrary, it should result from other factors, such as business

    cycle, new market trends, direct competition or technological obsolescence. Government

    will be assumed to bear the risk where it is obliged to ensure a given level of payment to thepartner regardless of the effective level of demand by the final user. This makes irrelevant the

    impact of fluctuations in demand level on the partners profitability. However, this statement

    does not apply where the shift in demand results from an obvious government action, such

    as decisions of units of general government (and thus not just the unit(s) directly involved

    in the contract) that represent a significant policy change, or the development of directly

    competing infrastructure built under government mandate.

    Eurostat recommends that assets involved in PFI should be classified as non-government

    assets, and therefore recorded off-balance sheet for government, if both of the following

    conditions are met:

    1. The private partner bears the construction risk.

    2. The private partner bears at least one of either availability or demand risk.

    If the construction risk is borne by government or if the private partner bears only the

    construction risk and no other risks, the assets are classified as government assets. This has

    important consequences for government finances, bothfor deficit and debt. The initial capital

    expenditure related to the assets will be recorded as government fixed capital formation,

    with a negative impact on government deficit/surplus. As a counterpart of this government

    expenditure, government debt will increase in the form of an imputed loan from the

    partner, which is part of the Maastricht debt concept. The regular payments made by

    government to the partner will have an impact on government deficit/surplus only for the

    part relating to purchases of services and imputed interest.

    Finally, we must bear in mind that the concept of private entity must be interpretedas opposed to the limits of the government. Therefore, it includes public, publicprivate or

    private companies providing services to the government on a market basis (Jones, 2000).

    All mentioned above supports the idea of real transfer of demand and availability risks

    for the not-consolidation of this kind of operations in the Public Administration sector,

    discarding models of fixed and unconditional payments as those of some projects developed

    by the government.

    Furthermore, special attention is paid to the construction risk. This makes clear the strong

    need for two elements as a previous stage before the definition of the contract or before

    its bidding. On the one hand, the definition of investment costs before establishing the

    conditions of the provision of services. On the other hand, a thorough financial planning of

    flows the operation will generate.Provided that in the Spanish case the Government has assumed the majority of the

    contractual risks, we can conclude that, once again, the aim was to defer the reporting of

    deficit and debt. This deferral is no longer possible in the light of the last Eurostat guidance,

    and was a clear example of creative accounting.

    Renda and Schrefler (2006, p. 1) state that in the case of Spain the legislation spells out

    that the State always maintains responsibility in contracts involving the public party. As a

    result, when a PPP turned out to be more expensive than what had been calculated ex ante,

    the government was expected to fund the project and ensure its viability.

  • 7/29/2019 An Example of Creative Accounting in Public

    21/24

    B. Benito et al. / Critical Perspectives on Accounting 19 (2008) 963986 983

    Something similar has happened in Ireland, where Eurostat indicated that early PPP

    projects involved insufficient risk transfer to the private partner, and that investment in

    these projects would be classified as public investment. Until 2005, all PPP investment inIreland had been treated in this way (International Monetary Fund, 2004).

    6. Concluding remarks

    When PFIs described in this paper areused,it is theGovernment andtherefore taxpayers

    but not users, who finally pay the public works. A common characteristic of PFI is

    that private corporations construct and they (where appropriate) also operate the public

    work. Business revenues come either from official aids or from periodical payments for

    construction, maintenance and operation of infrastructures, the amount of which are linked

    to its actual use.

    Deferral of payments and instalment plans, as well as borrowing decentralization, have

    made possible for Spanish Public Administrations, as well as other European governments,

    to bid and contract new public works while fitting EMU requirements without a dramatic

    reduction in public investment. However, PFI implementation has just been, at bottom, a

    financial make-up. In other words, it has been a clear example of public sector creative

    accounting. As Hart (2003) points out, policy makers argue that PPPs are good because

    the private sector is a cheaper source of financing than the public sector. This reasoning is

    strange since it is hard to imagine an agent that is more able to borrow than the Government

    through its taxation powers.

    It is important to say, according to PWC (2005), that all these PFIs are, in gen-

    eral, more expensive than traditional debt operations. As Hurst and Reeves (2004) show,

    PPPs implemented in Ireland have not resulted in significant innovations, failing to pro-vide value for money. PFIs are more complex operations and difficult to analyse, and

    sometimes they are extremely sophisticated from a legal perspective. However, we must

    bear in mind that governments must keep on investing on social centres, road infras-

    tructures, water-treatment plants, etc., and therefore the first point must be whether the

    investment is feasible from a traditional budgetary point of view. In case it is not viable,

    other alternatives will be considered (price subsidies, refundable advances, syndicated

    loans, subsidiary loans, exceptional financial aids, among others). These alternatives

    should have the appropriate budgetary surveillance, so as to accurately control the vol-

    ume of operations the government is able to finance. In the same way that limits upon

    future expenses prevent current politicians from imposing excessive financial burdens to

    future politicians, PFI use should be justified from a budgetary and economic point ofview.

    The theoretical underpinnings of our assessment of PFI is twofold. On the one hand,

    according to the property rights theory, a key aspect in PFI is the appropriate risk sharing

    between private and public sector in the contract. If adequate risk is not shifted to the

    private sector, then projects become quasi public, but with the funding removed from the

    governments balance sheet. If this is the case, projects become more expensive in the

    long run, while politicians have been able to present a good financial situation in the

    short run. On the other hand, if we take into account the Public Choice theory, as we said

  • 7/29/2019 An Example of Creative Accounting in Public

    22/24

    984 B. Benito et al. / Critical Perspectives on Accounting 19 (2008) 963986

    before, taxpayers overestimate benefits of current expenditures and underestimate future

    tax burden. Thus, PFIs allow incumbents to create infrastructures, with an eye on winning

    the next elections. However, the sad part of the story is that these PFIs are more expensivein the long run than them being financed through the traditional contracts.

    In thesearch forimaginative solutions, we wouldlike to comment on a recentand interest-

    ing practice used by the Austrian Government, that could be used by other European public

    entities. The government establishes a new real estate company (Bundesimmobilienge-

    sellschaft, BIG), which is 100% owned by the federal State. Most of the public buildings

    (schools, universities, offices, etc.) have been transferred to this company for its manage-

    ment and maintenance. BIG has financed this transfer by issuing securities and contracting

    loans. Most of the buildings transferred to BIG are subsequently rented back to the gov-

    ernment units which previously occupied these buildings, by individual contracts based

    on market estimates. The BIG continues to employ all State civil servants who previously

    managed the maintenance of these buildings. Their civil servant status has been maintained.

    As far as government accounts are concerned, this transfer has raised three questions:

    (i) whether BIG is an institutional unit in its own right or an ancillary unit of general

    government, (ii) whether BIG had to be classified in the sector general government or

    in the sector non-financial corporations, and (iii) whether the property transfer from the

    government to BIG should be considered as a sale of property (improving the deficit) or

    as other volume changes in financial assets/changes in classification and structure (neutral

    for the measurement of deficit).

    Eurostat decision is as follows in this respect (see Eurostat 31 January 2002 News

    Release no. 15/2002): BIG is an institutional unit in its own right, should be classified

    in the non-financial corporations sector, and BIG debt is not to be considered as part of

    government debt. Besides, the purpose of the transfer is to improve public management

    of real estate by rationalisation of buildings use, as well as management costs reduction.Moreover, because of the size of the transaction, it was not possible to organise a normal

    market sale of the property on the Austrian market. In addition, Austrian State wanted to

    maintain indirectly the ownership of the transferred property via the State owned company.

    For these reasons, the transfer of property was arranged bilaterally between the Austrian

    State and BIG. Considering these aspects, this transfer should not be treated as a market

    sale of real estate property in the sense of ESA 95. In consequence, the assets transfer to

    BIG has no impact on government deficit/surplus.

    To sum up, PPPs are not a miracle solution and need long time to produce visible results.

    Governments should allocate the risk to the party that is the least cost avoider, i.e., the

    party best suited to control and/or bear the risk. Without this approach, the public sector

    runs the risk of using PPPs for the wrong reasons, for example to make up public accountsin the short-term while worsening the long-term financial sustainability.

    References

    Accounting Standards Board. Reporting the substance of transactions, financial reporting standard 5. London:

    Accounting Standards Board; 1994.

    Aguila Y. Le guide du marche dentreprise de travaux publics. Pars: Ed. EFE; 1995.

  • 7/29/2019 An Example of Creative Accounting in Public

    23/24

    B. Benito et al. / Critical Perspectives on Accounting 19 (2008) 963986 985

    Allen G. Risk and the private finance initiative (PFI): library standard note. London: House of Commons Library,

    Economic Policy and Statistics; 2001.

    Besancon X, Van Ruymbeke O. Le marche dentreprise de travaux publics: une forme particuliere de concession.

    Pars: Ed. AJDA; 1990.

    Broadbent J, Laughlin R. The PFI: clarification of a future research agenda. Financial Accountability and Man-

    agement 1999;15(2):95114.

    Brown C. Financing transport infrastructure: for whom the road tolls. The Australian Economic Review

    2005;38(4):4318.

    Buchanan JM. Public finance in democratic process, fiscal institutions and individual choice. The University of

    North Carolina Press; 1967.

    Bult-Spiering M, Dewulf G. Strategic issues in public private partnerships. An international perspective. Oxford:

    Blackwell Publishing; 2006.

    English LM, Guthrie J. Driving privately financed projects in Australia: what makes them tick? Auditing &

    Accountability Journal 2003;16(3):493511.

    European Commission. Green paper on publicprivate partnerships and community law on public

    contracts and concessions. COM(2004) 327 final; 2004. Available online at http://europa.eu.int/eur-

    lex/en/com/gpr/2004/com2004 0327en01.pdf.European Investment Bank. Evaluation of PPP projects financed by the EIB. Synthesis Report; 2005.

    European Parliament. Publicprivate partnerships. Models and trends in the European Union. DG Internal Policies

    of the Union (IP/A/IMCO/SC/2005-161); 2006.

    Froud J, Shaoul J. Appraising and evaluating PFI for NHS hospitals. Financial Accountability and Management

    2001;17(3):24770.

    Hart O. Firms, contracts and financial structure. Oxford: Clarendon Press; 1996.

    Hart O. Incomplete contracts and public ownership: remarks, and an application to public private partnerships.

    The Economic Journal 2003;113:C6976.

    Heald D. Privately financed capital in public services. Manchester School 1997;LXV(4):56899.

    Heald D. Value for money tests and accounting treatment in PFI schemes. Accounting, Auditing & Accountability

    Journal 2003;16(3):34271.

    Heald D, Geaughan N. Accounting for the private finance initiative. Public Money and Management

    1997;17(3):116.

    HodgesR, MellettH. Investigating standard setting.Accounting for the United Kingdoms privatefinance initiative.Accounting Forum 2002;26(2):12651.

    Hurst C, Reeves E. An economic analysis of Irelands first public private partnership. The International Journal

    of Public Sector Management 2004;17(5):37988.

    International Monetary Fund. Publicprivate partnerships. Manuscript prepared by the Fiscal Affairs Department;

    2004.

    Izquierdo R. La financiacion de las infraestructuras del transporte. Madrid: Ed. Camara de Comercio e Industria

    de Madrid; 1992.

    Izquierdo R, Vassallo JM. Nuevos sistemas de gestion y financiacion de infraestructuras de transporte. Madrid:

    Colegio de Ingenieros de Caminos, Canales y Puertos; 2004.

    Jones R. Public versus private: the empty definitions of national accounting. Financial Accountability & Manage-

    ment 2000;16(2):16778.

    Koen V, van den Noord P. Fiscal Gimmickry in Europe. One-off measures and creative accounting. OECD

    Economics Department Working Papers, no. 417, OECD Publishing; 2005.Luder K. National accounting, governmental accounting and cross-country comparisons of government financial

    condition. Financial Accountability & Management 2000;16(2):11728.

    Milesi-Ferretti GM. Good, bad or ugly? On the effects of fiscal rules with creative accounting. Journal of Public

    Economics 2004;88(12):37794.

    Milesi-FerrettiGM, Moriyama K. Fiscal adjustment in EU countries: a balance sheet approach.Journal of Banking

    and Finance 2006;30:328198.

    Mayston D. The private finance initiative in the NHS: an unhealthy development in new public management?

    Financial Accountability and Management 1999;15(3/4):24974.

    Mumford M. Public-worksprivate finance: the principles of the private finance initiative. London: Ed. Richard

    Griffin; 1998.

    http://europa.eu.int/eur-lex/en/com/gpr/2004/com2004_0327en01.pdfhttp://europa.eu.int/eur-lex/en/com/gpr/2004/com2004_0327en01.pdf
  • 7/29/2019 An Example of Creative Accounting in Public

    24/24

    986 B. Benito et al. / Critical Perspectives on Accounting 19 (2008) 963986

    PricewaterhouseCoopers. Delivering the PPP promise. A review of PPP issues and activity. London; 2005.

    Renda A, Schrefler L. Publicprivate partnerships models and trends in the European Union. Brussels: European

    Parliament; 2006.

    RutherfordB. The social construction of financial statementelements underprivate finance private finance initiative

    schemes. Accounting, Auditing & Accountability Journal 2003;16(3):37296.

    Treasury Private Finance Taskforce. PFI technical note no. 1, How to account for PFI transactions. London: HM

    Stationery Office; 1997.

    Yates ChM. Private sector finance for roads in Europe. In: Proceedings of a seminar held at the PTRC transport,

    highways and planning summer annual meeting. England: University of Manchester, Institute of Science and

    Technology; 1992. p. 1530.