a game-theoretic approach to non-life insurance

51
Lorna Pamba & Karol Rakowski A Game-theoretic approach to non-life insurance.

Upload: enoch

Post on 24-Feb-2016

63 views

Category:

Documents


1 download

DESCRIPTION

A Game-theoretic approach to non-life insurance. Lorna Pamba & Karol Rakowski. Introduction: . Goal of research as mathematics majors with minors in economics - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: A Game-theoretic approach to non-life insurance

Lorna Pamba & Karol Rakowski

A Game-theoretic approach to non-life insurance.

Page 2: A Game-theoretic approach to non-life insurance

Introduction:

• Goal of research as mathematics majors with minors in economics

• Nash Equilibrium: a stable state of a system involving the interaction of different participants, in which no participant can gain by a unilateral change of strategy if the strategies of the others remain unchanged

Page 3: A Game-theoretic approach to non-life insurance

Some background Information; • Hawk and Dove Game

• Player choice either Hawk(H) or Dove (D)

• Four pure strategy combinations ; HH,HD,DH,HH

is the reproductive value of territory is the cost of being injured in a fight

Page 4: A Game-theoretic approach to non-life insurance

In bird's 1 point of view, lets consider the cases:

• DH( Bird1 plays dove and Bird 2 plays Hawk)

Payoff = 0• HD( Bird 1 plays Hawk and Bird 2 plays Dove)

Payoff = ρ• DDExpected payoff=0*Prob(F=I)+ρ*Prob(F=II)=ρ/2

• HH

Exp=ρ*Prob(S=I)+(-C)*Prob(S=II)=(( ρ-C))/2

Page 5: A Game-theoretic approach to non-life insurance

  H D

D

  H D

D

Payoff Matrices;Bird 1 Bird 2

Page 6: A Game-theoretic approach to non-life insurance

Probabilities of mixed strategies;Bird I, play H with probability u and play D with probability

Bird II, play H with probability v and play D with probability If I and II choices don’t affect each other;

= =

  HH HD DH DDPossible values

 

 

0  

 

Probabilities

Page 7: A Game-theoretic approach to non-life insurance

Then f1(u,v)= E(F1) = =

Then f2 (u,v)= E(F2 ) = =

Similarly, f2 (u,v) = E(F2 )

For a fixed v

For a fixed u

Page 8: A Game-theoretic approach to non-life insurance

Therefore bird I’s reaction set is; R1 =

And bird II’s reaction set is; R2 = {

R1= blue lineR2= Green lineIntersection: Nash equilibrium

Page 9: A Game-theoretic approach to non-life insurance

2 companiesFixed number of customers in marketPossible strategies (increase or decrease in premiums) Represented by i and d.Disclaimer of quantatative “real world” application of following work

Insurance Market

Page 10: A Game-theoretic approach to non-life insurance

Variable Defined As:

I Insurance Company 1

II Insurance Company 2

rI Premium for I

rII Premium for II

xI Increase in Premium for I

xII Increase in Premium for II

yI Decrease in Premium for I

yII Decrease in Premium for II

T Total Number of Customers in Market

PI Number of Customers for I

PII Number of Customers for II

RI Revenue for I

RII Revenue for II

Definitions

Page 11: A Game-theoretic approach to non-life insurance

Change in Revenue = (Change in Number of Customers) * (Change in Premium) - (Previous Revenue).

Change in Revenue = ((∆rI,II - ∆rII,I) * (.01 * T) + PI,II) * (rI,II + ∆rI,II) – ((PI,II) * (RI,II))

Payoff – Change in Revenue

Page 12: A Game-theoretic approach to non-life insurance

  I’s Payoff

  I II

d

 

i

 

(((-xI + xII)*(.01T) + PI)*(rI + xI)) - RI

 

(((-xI - yII)*(.01T) + PI)*(rI + xI)) - RI

 

I  

(((yI + xII)*(.01T) + PI)*(rI - yI)) - RI

 

(((yI - yII)*(.01T) + PI)*(rI - yI)) - RI 

d

Payoff Matrices

Page 13: A Game-theoretic approach to non-life insurance

  II’s Payoff

  I II

d

 

i

 

(((-xII - xI)*(.01T) + PII)*(rII + xII)) - RII

 

(((yII + xI)*(.01T) + PII)*(rII - yII)) - RII

 

I  

(((-xI - yI)*(.01T) + PII)*(rII + xII)) - RII

 

(((yII - yI)*(.01T) + PII)*(rII - yII)) - RII 

d

Payoff Matrices

Page 14: A Game-theoretic approach to non-life insurance

4 possible outcomes for both companies

Want to create a payoff function so we can examine which strategy is best choice

dominant strategy (a strategy is dominant if it is always better than any other strategy)

Payoff Matrices

Page 15: A Game-theoretic approach to non-life insurance

we need to establish the probabilities, for both companies, of determining their decision to increase or decrease their premiums. Let: u = ( Prob{I}=i ) and v = ( Prob{II}=i ) where 0 ≤ u ≤ 1 and 0 ≤ v ≤ 1 1 – u = ( Prob{I}=d ) and 1 – v = ( Prob{II}=d )

Constructing Payoff Functions

Page 16: A Game-theoretic approach to non-life insurance

Constructing Payoff Functions

Company 1 ( I )

Probabilities

Strategies

Possible Outcomes (Payoffs)

uv

ii

(((-xI + xII)*(.01T) + PI)*(rI + xI)) - RI

u(1-v)

id

(((-xI - yII)*(.01T) + PI)*(rI + xI)) - RI

(1-u)v

di

(((yI + xII)*(.01T) + PI)*(rI - yI)) - RI

(1-u)(1-v)

dd

(((yI - yII)*(.01T) + PI)*(rI - yI)) - RI

Page 17: A Game-theoretic approach to non-life insurance

Constructing Payoff Functions

Company 2 ( II )

Probabilities

Strategies

Possible Outcomes (Payoffs)

uv

ii

(((-xII - xI)*(.01T) + PII)*(rII + xII)) - RII

u(1-v)

id

(((yII + xI)*(.01T) + PII)*(rII - yII)) - RII

(1-u)v

di

(((-xI - yI)*(.01T) + PII)*(rII + xII)) - RII

(1-u)(1-v)

dd

(((yII - yI)*(.01T) + PII)*(rII - yII)) - RII

Page 18: A Game-theoretic approach to non-life insurance

ƒI(u,v) = ((((-xI + xII)*(.01T) + PI)*(rI + xI)) - RI)(uv) + ((((-xI - yII)*(.01T) + PI)*(rI + xI)) - RI)(1-v)u + ( (((yI + xII)*(.01T) + PI)*(rI - yI)) - RI)(u-1)v + ((((yI - yII)*(.01T) + PI)*(rI - yI)) - RI)(1-u)(1-v)

ƒI(u,v) = u(v((xI+rI)(-.01xIT + .01xIIT + PI) – RI) + (1-v)((xI+rI)(-.01xIT - .01yIIT + PI) – RI) + (v((rI-yI)(.01T(xII + yI) + PI) – RI) – ((1-v)((rI – yI)(.01yIT - .01yIIT + PI) – RI))) – v((rI-yI)(.01T(xII + yI) + PI) – RI) + ((1-v)((rI – yI)(.01yIT - .01yIIT + PI) – RI)))

Evaluation of Payoff Function (1)

Page 19: A Game-theoretic approach to non-life insurance

⍵ = (v((xI+rI)(-.01xIT + .01xIIT + PI) – RI) + (1-v)((xI+rI)(-.01xIT - .01yIIT + PI) – RI) + (v((rI-yI)(.01T(xII + yI) + PI) – RI) – ((1-v)((rI – yI)(.01yIT - .01yIIT + PI) – RI)))

ƒI(u,v) = u⍵– v((rI-yI)(.01T(xII + yI) + PI) – RI) + ((1-v)((rI – yI)(.01yIT - .01yIIT + PI) – RI)))

Evaluation of Payoff Function (1) cont.

Page 20: A Game-theoretic approach to non-life insurance

ƒII(u,v) = ((((-xII + xI)*(.01T) + PII)*(rII + xII)) - RII)(uv) + ((((-xII - yI)*(.01T) + PII)*(rII + xII)) - RII)(1-v)u + ( (((yII + xI)*(.01T) + PII)*(rII - yII)) - RII)(u-1)v + ((((yII - yI)*(.01T) + PII)*(rII - yII)) - RII)(1-u)(1-v)

ƒII(u,v) = v(u((xII+rII)(-.01xIIT + .01xIT + PII) – RII) - u((xII+rII)(-.01xIIT - .01yIT + PII) – RII) + (u-1)((rII-yII)(.01T(xI + yII) + PII) – RII) – ((1-u)((rII – yII)(.01yIIT - .01yIT + PII) – RII))) + u((rII-yII)(.01T(xI + yII) + PII) – RII) + ((1-u)((rII – yII)(.01yIIT - .01yIT + PII) – RII)))

Evaluation of Payoff Function (2)

Page 21: A Game-theoretic approach to non-life insurance

⍺ = (u((xII+rII)(-.01xIIT + .01xIT + PII) – RII) - u((xII+rII)(-.01xIIT - .01yIT + PII) – RII) + (u-1)((rII-yII)(.01T(xI + yII) + PII) – RII) – ((1-u)((rII – yII)(.01yIIT - .01yIT + PII) – RII)))

ƒII(u,v) = v⍺+ u((rII-yII)(.01T(xI + yII) + PII) – RII) + ((1-u)((rII – yII)(.01yIIT - .01yIT + PII) – RII)))

Evaluation of Payoff Function (2) cont.

Page 22: A Game-theoretic approach to non-life insurance

Company 1 has no control over the value of v and hence has no control over the value of the expression v((rI-yI)(.01T(xII + yI) + PI) – RI) + ((1-v)((rI – yI)(.01yIT - .01yIIT + PI) – RI)))

The goal is to maximize u⍵ (when we maximize u⍵, we maximize ƒI). Again, we also know 0 ≤ u ≤ 1. So, when ⍵ is positive, negative, or equal to 0, we will have three different optimal values for u

Evaluation of Payoff Functions

Page 23: A Game-theoretic approach to non-life insurance

If, ⍵ > 0 Then, u = 1If, ⍵ = 0 Then, All u ∈ [0,1]If, ⍵ < 0 Then, u = 0

Relation Between ⍵ and u

Page 24: A Game-theoretic approach to non-life insurance

If, ⍺ > 0 Then, v = 1If, ⍺ = 0 Then, All v ∈ [0,1]If, ⍺ < 0 Then, v = 0

Relation Between ⍺ and v

Page 25: A Game-theoretic approach to non-life insurance

A closer look at what determines the values of ⍵ and ⍺

The ⍵ and ⍺ equalities are crucial to examine as they have a direct impact on the u, v strategies that will be taken by Companies 1 and 2.

Further Evaluation

Page 26: A Game-theoretic approach to non-life insurance

⍵ = (v((xI+rI)(-.01xIT + .01xIIT + PI) – RI) + (1-v)((xI+rI)(-.01xIT - .01yIIT + PI) – RI) + (v((rI-yI)(.01T(xII + yI) + PI) – RI) – ((1-v)((rI – yI)(.01yIT - .01yIIT + PI) – RI)))

⍵ = v (-2 RI + (xI + rI) (PI - 0.01 xI T + 0.01 xII T) + (-yI + rI) (PI + 0.01 (xII + yI)T) - (xI + rI) (PI - 0.01 xI T - 0.01 yII T) + (-yI + rI) (PI + 0.01 yI T - 0.01 yII T))+ (xI + rI) (PI - 0.01 xI T - 0.01 yII T) - (-yI + rI) (PI + 0.01 yI T - 0.01 yII T)

Evaluation of ⍵

Page 27: A Game-theoretic approach to non-life insurance

δ = (-2 RI + (xI + rI) (PI - 0.01 xI T + 0.01 xII T) + (-yI + rI) (PI + 0.01 (xII + yI)T) - (xI + rI) (PI - 0.01 xI T - 0.01 yII T) + (-yI + rI) (PI + 0.01 yI T - 0.01 yII T))

a = (xI + rI) (PI - 0.01 xI T - 0.01 yII T) - (-yI + rI) (PI + 0.01 yI T - 0.01 yII T)

⍵ = v δ + a

Evaluation of ⍵ cont.

Page 28: A Game-theoretic approach to non-life insurance

⍺ = (u((xII+rII)(-.01xIIT + .01xIT + PII) – RII) - u((xII+rII)(-.01xIIT - .01yIT + PII) – RII) + (u-1)((rII-yII)(.01T(xI + yII) + PII) – RII) – ((1-u)((rII – yII)(.01yIIT - .01yIT + PII) – RII)))

⍺ = u(-2 RII + (xII + rII) (PII - 0.01 xII T + 0.01 xI T) + (-yII + rII) (PII + 0.01 (xI + yII)T) - (xII + rII) (PII - 0.01 xII T - 0.01 yI T) + (-yII + rII) (PII + 0.01 yII T - 0.01 yI T))+(xII + rII) (PII - 0.01 xII T - 0.01 yI T) - (-yII + rII) (PII + 0.01 yII T - 0.01 yI T)

Evaluation of ⍺

Page 29: A Game-theoretic approach to non-life insurance

λ = (-2 RII + (xII + rII) (PII - 0.01 xII T + 0.01 xI T) + (-yII + rII) (PII + 0.01 (xI + yII)T) - (xII + rII) (PII - 0.01 xII T - 0.01 yI T) + (-yII + rII) (PII + 0.01 yII T - 0.01 yI T))

b = (xII + rII) (PII - 0.01 xII T - 0.01 yI T) - (-yII + rII) (PII + 0.01 yII T - 0.01 yI T)

⍺ = u λ + b

Evaluation of ⍺ cont.

Page 30: A Game-theoretic approach to non-life insurance

v = 1 ⍵ = δ + av = 0 ⍵ = av = V0 ⍵ = 0

Relation between v and ⍵

Page 31: A Game-theoretic approach to non-life insurance

u = 1 ⍺ = λ + bu = 0 ⍺ = bu = U0 ⍺ = 0

Relation between u and ⍺

Page 32: A Game-theoretic approach to non-life insurance

for every v which Company 1 has no control over, there exists a corresponding u which is a strategy that will make Company 1’s payoff/benefit as large as possible given the situation. So a rational reaction set is a set of all of these possible combinations, given an opposing strategy that a player has no control over

Rational Reaction Set

Page 33: A Game-theoretic approach to non-life insurance

ZI = { (u,v) | 0 ≤ u, v ≤ 1 , ƒI(u,v) = max0 ≤ ū ≤ 1 ƒI(ū,v) }For each (u,v) in ZI, if Company 2 selects v then a best reply for Company 1 is to select u (a best reply rather than the best reply because there may be more than one). Note that ZI is obtained in practice by holding v constant and maximizing ƒI as a function of a single variable (whose maximum will depend on v). ZII = { (u,v) | 0 ≤ u, v ≤ 1 , ƒII(u,v) = max0 ≤ ῡ ≤ 1 ƒI(u,ῡ) } *Similar Explanation*

Rational Reaction Set

Page 34: A Game-theoretic approach to non-life insurance

ZII - Blue Line

V0 ZI - Red Line

1

Nash Equilibrium 3

U0

Nash Equilibrium 1

Nash Equilibrium 2

Rational Reaction Sets

u

v

1

0

0

First Example

Page 35: A Game-theoretic approach to non-life insurance

1

V0

U0

0.7

Rational Reaction Sets

u

v

1

0

0

ZII - Blue Line

0

0

Nash Equilibrium 2

Nash Equilibrium 1

Nash Equilibrium 3

ZI - Red Line

Example 2

Page 36: A Game-theoretic approach to non-life insurance

ZII - Blue Line

V0

ZI - Red Line

1

Nash Equilibrium

Rational Reaction Sets

u

v

1

0

0

U0

Third Example

Page 37: A Game-theoretic approach to non-life insurance

Rational Introspection: A NE (Nash Equilibrium) seems a reasonable way to play a game because my beliefs of what other players do are consistent with them being rational. This is a good explanation for explaining NE in games with a unique NE. However, it is less compelling for games with multiple NE. Markus Mobius, Lecture IV: Nash Equilibrium II - Multiple Equilibria. (lecture., Harvard, 2008), http://isites.harvard.edu/fs/docs/icb.topic449892.files/lecture42.pdf.Risk Aversion method in decision

Multiple Nash Equilibriums

Page 38: A Game-theoretic approach to non-life insurance

A continuous Non-coperative game.

• 2 Insurance Companies; Geico and Progressive

• Battleground for the two companies;

Based on;

Area under the curve should be 1 ;

Since we are trying to estimate some realistic situation , we’ll say; Therefore our probability distribution function;

Page 39: A Game-theoretic approach to non-life insurance

This is our pdf if the mean is chosen to be 13000.

10 00 0 20 00 0 30 00 0 40 00 0 50 00 0

0. 000 05

0. 000 10

0. 000 15

0. 000 20

4m̂ xe ^ 2xm

X axis represents the number of miles driven in a yearY axis represents the population in (100000000)

Page 40: A Game-theoretic approach to non-life insurance

Some assumptions made

• Homogenous product but different level of satisfaction;

• Best premium rate for the Geico depends upon Progressive premium rate and vice versa.

• Geico and Progressive do not communicate with one another

• Utility is measurable.

Page 41: A Game-theoretic approach to non-life insurance

• Let player 1 be Geico and player 2 be Progressive.

• Let be the premium rate set by Geico and be the premium set by Progressive

• Let u be the customers’ utilityAccordingly, we can say ans makes progressive the better choice.Similarly, we can say and makes Geico the better choice.

Page 42: A Game-theoretic approach to non-life insurance

𝒖=𝒌𝒎𝒑𝟏−𝒌𝟏𝒎<𝒑𝟐−𝒌𝟐𝒎

Then we have 3 cases,

𝒌𝟐<𝒌𝟏𝒐𝒓𝒎>𝒑𝟐−𝒑𝟏𝒌𝟐−𝒌𝟏 𝑻𝒉𝒆𝒏𝒄𝒖𝒔𝒕𝒐𝒎𝒆𝒓𝒔 𝒑𝒖𝒓𝒄𝒉𝒂𝒔𝒆𝒆𝒏𝒕𝒊𝒓𝒆𝒍𝒚 𝒇𝒓𝒐𝒎𝑷

𝒌𝟐=𝒌𝟏 𝒊𝒎𝒑𝒍𝒊𝒆𝒔 𝒕𝒉𝒂𝒕 𝒑𝟐>𝒑𝟏

Page 43: A Game-theoretic approach to non-life insurance

Without loss of generality, let’s assume all through that; ,

𝑮 (𝒔 )=𝒑𝒓𝒐𝒃 (𝒎≤ 𝒔 )= 𝟒𝐦𝛍𝟐 𝒙 ⅇ

−𝟐𝐱 /𝐦𝛍𝟎≤𝒎≤𝟏𝟑 ,𝟎𝟎𝟎

Let denote a cumulative distribution function

Let F1 denote Geico’ s payoff function;

Page 44: A Game-theoretic approach to non-life insurance

Similarly progressive’s payoff function;

Let be Geico’ s and Nan’s strategy simultaneously,

𝒇 𝟏 (𝒙 ,𝒚 )=𝑬 ( 𝑭𝟏 )=𝒑𝟏 .𝒑𝒓𝒐𝒃 (𝒎≤ 𝒔 )+𝟎 .𝑷𝒓𝒐𝒃 (𝒎> 𝒔 )

=

=

Page 45: A Game-theoretic approach to non-life insurance

And progressive’s reward function is

𝒇 𝟐 (𝒙 ,𝒚 )=𝒑𝟐(𝟏+−𝟔𝟓𝟎𝟎+ⅇ

−𝐌𝐚𝐱 [𝟎 ,𝟓𝟎𝟎 (−𝒑𝟏+𝒑 𝟐)]𝟔𝟓𝟎𝟎 (𝟔𝟓𝟎𝟎+𝐌𝐚𝐱 [𝟎 ,𝟓𝟎𝟎(−𝒑𝟏+𝒑𝟐)])

𝟔𝟓𝟎𝟎 )

Recall, that if Similarly;

Page 46: A Game-theoretic approach to non-life insurance

The set of all feasible strategy combinations

Or similarly; |

Restricted price

Page 47: A Game-theoretic approach to non-life insurance

with constant R2 = with constant

Recall,

¿𝝏𝒑𝟏 𝒇 𝟏[𝒑𝟏 ,𝒑𝟐]

𝑺𝒐𝒍𝒗𝒆 [𝟒𝟐𝟐𝟓𝟎𝟎𝟎𝟎 −𝟔𝟓𝟎𝟎ⅇ

𝒑𝟏−𝒑 𝟐𝟔𝟓𝟎𝟎(𝒌𝟏−𝒌𝟐) (𝟔𝟓𝟎𝟎+−𝒑𝟏+𝒑𝟐

𝒌𝟏−𝒌𝟐 )

𝟒𝟐𝟐𝟓𝟎𝟎𝟎𝟎 +𝒑𝟏(𝟔𝟓𝟎𝟎ⅇ

𝒑𝟏−𝒑 𝟐𝟔𝟓𝟎𝟎(𝒌𝟏−𝒌𝟐)

𝒌𝟏−𝒌𝟐 −ⅇ

𝒑𝟏−𝒑𝟐𝟔𝟓𝟎𝟎(𝒌𝟏−𝒌𝟐 ) (𝟔𝟓𝟎𝟎+−𝒑𝟏+𝒑𝟐

𝒌𝟏−𝒌𝟐 )

𝒌𝟏−𝒌𝟐 )

𝟒𝟐𝟐𝟓𝟎𝟎𝟎𝟎 =¿𝟎 ,𝒑𝟏]

This would help us find points in R1 if exact solutions were possible (would give potential p1 values to choose for a fixed p2).

Page 48: A Game-theoretic approach to non-life insurance

This would help us find points in if exact solutions were possible (would give potential values to choose for a fixed).For example

Page 49: A Game-theoretic approach to non-life insurance

20 0 40 0 60 0 80 0 10 00 12 00

20 0

40 0

60 0

80 0

10 00

12 00

This shows R1 in blue and R2 in red when k1=15/1000 and k2=17/1000.

Nash Equilibrium

Page 50: A Game-theoretic approach to non-life insurance

Weaknesses of research

Justifications

Conclusion

Page 51: A Game-theoretic approach to non-life insurance

 Questions?