5.1 auction theory slides

Upload: chrisroby

Post on 02-Jun-2018

269 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 8/10/2019 5.1 Auction Theory Slides

    1/35

    Today

    Auction Theory Basics

    1. Bidding and Equilibria in IPV model

    2. Revenue Equivalence

    3. General Model: Affiliated Values

    4. Linkage Principle: Revenue RankingAd Auctions: Sponsored Search

  • 8/10/2019 5.1 Auction Theory Slides

    2/35

    Auctions: The Independent Private Values Model

    Basic Auction Environment

    Bidders i= 1,...,n

    One object to be sold

    Bidder i observes a signal Si F(), with typical realizationsi[s, s]. Assume F is continuous.

    Bidders signals S1,...,Sn are independent.

    Bidder is value vi(si) =si.

    A set of auction rules will give rise to a game between the bidders.

  • 8/10/2019 5.1 Auction Theory Slides

    3/35

    The IPV Model

    Two important features of the model:

    Bidder is information (signal) is independent of bidder js infor-mation (signal).

    Bidder is value is independent of bidder js information (i.e. pri-vate values).

  • 8/10/2019 5.1 Auction Theory Slides

    4/35

    Vickrey (Second-Price) Auction

    Auction Rules:

    Bidders are asked to submit sealed bids b1,...,bn.

    Bidder who submits the highest bid wins the object.

    Winner pays the amount of the second highest bid.

    Proposition 1In a second price auction, it is a (weakly) domi-nant strategy to bid ones value, bi(si) =si.

    Proof. Biddingbimeansi will win if and only if the price is below bi.Bid bi > si sometimes win at price above value.Bid bi < si sometimes lose at price below value.

  • 8/10/2019 5.1 Auction Theory Slides

    5/35

    Expected Vickrey Auction Revenue

    Sellers revenue equals second highest value.

    Let Si:n denote theith highest ofn draws from distributionF.

    Sellers expected revenue is

    E

    S2:n

    .

  • 8/10/2019 5.1 Auction Theory Slides

    6/35

    Open Ascending Auction

    Auction Rules:

    Prices rise continuously from zero.

    Bidders have the option to drop out at any point.

    Auction ends when only one bidder remains.

    Winner pays the ending price.

    With private values, just like a Vickrey auction!

  • 8/10/2019 5.1 Auction Theory Slides

    7/35

    Sealed Bid (First-Price) Auction

    Auction Rules:

    Bidders submit sealed bids b1,...,bn.

    Bidders who submits the highest bid wins the object.

    Winner pays his own bid.

    Bidders will want to shade bids below their values.

    Well look at two approaches to solving for symmetric equilibrium bid-ding strategies.

  • 8/10/2019 5.1 Auction Theory Slides

    8/35

    FOC Approach to First Price Auction

    Suppose bidders j =i bid bj =b(sj), b() increasing.

    Bidderis expected payoff:

    U(bi, si) = (si bi) Pr [bj =b(Sj) bi, j =i]

    Bidderichooses bito solve:

    maxbi

    (si bi) Fn1

    b1(bi)

    .

    First order condition:

    0 = (si bi) (n1)Fn2

    b1(bi)

    f

    b1(bi) 1

    b(b1(bi))Fn1

    b1(bi)

  • 8/10/2019 5.1 Auction Theory Slides

    9/35

    FOC Approach to First Price Auction

    At symmetric equilibrium, bi=b(si), first order condition is:

    b(s) = (s b(s)) (n 1)f(s)

    F(s).

    Solve using the boundary condition b(s) =s:

    b(s) =s

    sis

    Fn1(s)ds

    Fn1(s) .

  • 8/10/2019 5.1 Auction Theory Slides

    10/35

    Envelope Approach to First Price Auction

    Suppose there is a symmetric increasing equilibrium: bi=b(si).

    Then is equilibrium payoff given signal si:

    U(si) = (si b(si)) Fn1(si). (1)

    As b(si) is optimal fori:

    U(si) = maxbi

    (si bi) Fn1(b1(bi)).

    By the envelope theorem:d

    dsU(s)

    s=si

    =Fn1(b1(b(si)) =Fn1(si)

  • 8/10/2019 5.1 Auction Theory Slides

    11/35

    Envelope Approach to First Price Auction

    Rewriting the envelope formula:

    U(si) =U(s) +

    sis

    Fn1(s)ds. (2)

    Asb(s) is increasing, bidder with signal snever winsU(s) = 0.

    Equating the two representations ofU(si):

    b(s) =s

    sis

    Fn1(s)ds

    Fn1

    (s)

    .

  • 8/10/2019 5.1 Auction Theory Slides

    12/35

    Equilibrium in the First Price Auction

    Weve found necessary conditions for symmetric equilibrium.

    Verifying that b(s)isan equilibrium isnt too hard.

    Also can show that equilibrium is unique.

  • 8/10/2019 5.1 Auction Theory Slides

    13/35

    Expected First Price Auction Revenue

    Revenue is high bid b(s1:n); expected revenue is E

    b(S1:n)

    .

    b(s) =s

    ss

    Fn1(s)ds

    Fn1

    (s)

    = 1

    Fn1

    (s)

    s

    s

    sdFn1(s) = E S1:n1|S1:n1 s .

    Expected revenue is:

    E

    b

    S1:n

    = E

    S1:n1|S1:n1 S1:n

    = E

    S2:n

    .

    First and second price auction yield same expected revenue.

  • 8/10/2019 5.1 Auction Theory Slides

    14/35

    Revenue Equivalence Theorem

    Theorem (Revenue Equivalence)Supposenbidders have valuess1,...,snidentically and independently distributed with cdfF(). Thenany equilibrium of any auction game in which(i) the bidder with thehighest value wins the object, and(ii) a bidder with value sgets zero

    profits, generates the same revenue in expectation.

  • 8/10/2019 5.1 Auction Theory Slides

    15/35

    Proof of the RET

    Consider any auction where bidders submit bids b1,...,bn, and wherethe auction rule specifies for all i,

    xi : B1 ... Bn[0, 1]

    ti : B1 ... Bn R,

    xi() gives probabilityiwill get the object.

    ti() gives is payment as a function of (b1,...,bn).

  • 8/10/2019 5.1 Auction Theory Slides

    16/35

    Proof of the RET

    Bidderis expected payoff is:

    Ui(si, bi) =siEbi[xi(bi, bi)] Ebi[ti(bi, bi)] .

    Letbi() , bi() denote an equilibrium of the auction game.

    Bidderisequilibriumpayoff is:

    Ui(si) =Ui(si, b(si)) =siFn1 (si) Esi[ti(bi(si), bi(si)] ,

    where because highest value wins:

    Esi[xi(b(si), b(si))] =Fn1(si).

  • 8/10/2019 5.1 Auction Theory Slides

    17/35

  • 8/10/2019 5.1 Auction Theory Slides

    18/35

    Proof of the RET, continued

    Combine the expressions for Ui(si) to get:

    Esi[ti(bi, bi)] =siFn1 (si)

    sis

    Fn1(s)ds=

    sis

    sdFn1(s),

    If auction satisfies(i) and(ii), is expected payment given si is:

    E

    S1:n1 |S1:n1 < si

    = E

    S2:n |S1:n =si

    .

    Thus expected revenue is constant:

    E [Revenue] =nEsi[is expected payment| si] = E

    S2:n

    .

  • 8/10/2019 5.1 Auction Theory Slides

    19/35

    Using the Revenue Equivalence Theorem

    Many applications of the revenue equivalence theorem.

    If the auction equilibrium satisfies(i) and(ii), we know:

    Expected Revenue

    Expected Bidder Profits (payoff equivalence)

    Expected Total Surplus

    We can use this to solve for auction equilibria.

  • 8/10/2019 5.1 Auction Theory Slides

    20/35

    The All-Pay Auction

    Bidders 1, . . ,n

    Values s1,...,sn, i.i.d. with cdfF

    Bidders submit bids b1,...,bn

    Bidder who submits the highest bid gets the object.Every bidder must pay his or her bid.

  • 8/10/2019 5.1 Auction Theory Slides

    21/35

    Solving the All-Pay Auction

    Suppose all pay auction has a symmetric equilibrium with an in-creasing strategy bA(s). In this equilibrium, is expected payoff givenvaluesi will be:

    U(si) =siFn1

    (si) bA

    (si) = si

    s Fn1

    (s)ds

    So

    bA(s) =sFn1(s)

    ss

    Fn1(s)ds

  • 8/10/2019 5.1 Auction Theory Slides

    22/35

    Other Revenue Equivalent Auctions

    1. The English (oral ascending) auction. All bidders start in the auc-tion with a price of zero. Price rises continuously; bidders may dropout at any point in time. Once they drop out, they cannot re-enter.Auction ends when only one bidder is left; this bidder pays the price

    at which the second-to-last bidder dropped out.2. The Dutch (descending price) auction. The price starts at a very

    high level and drops continuously. At any point in time, a biddercan stop the auction, and pay the current price. Then the auctionends.

  • 8/10/2019 5.1 Auction Theory Slides

    23/35

    Common Value Auctions

    Generalize the model to allow for the possibility that:

    1. Learning bidder js information could cause bidder i to re-assesshis estimate of how much he values the object,

    2. The information of i and jis not independent (when js estimateis high, is is also likely to be high).

    Examples:

    Selling natural resources such as oil or timber.

    Selling financial assets such as treasury bills.

    Selling a company.

  • 8/10/2019 5.1 Auction Theory Slides

    24/35

    A General Model

    Bidders i= 1,...,n

    Signals S1,...,Snwith joint density f()

    Value to bidder iis v(si, si).

  • 8/10/2019 5.1 Auction Theory Slides

    25/35

    Affiliated Signals

    Signals are(i) exchangeable, and(ii) affiliated.

    Signals areexchangeable: s is permutation ofsf(s) =f(s).

    Signals areaffiliated: For any s1 > s1, s

    2 > s

    2, we have

    f(s1|s2)

    f(s1|s2)

    f(s1|s2)

    f(s1|s2)

    .

    i.e. sj|si has monotone likelihood ratio property.

    This implies, but is not equivalent to

    F(s1|s2) F(s1|s

    2)

    for all s1. (FOSD)

  • 8/10/2019 5.1 Auction Theory Slides

    26/35

    Examples of the General Model

    1. The IPV model.

    2. Pure common value with conditionally independent signals.

    Example: Si = V +i, where 1, . . ,n are independent, andv(si, si) = E[V|s1,...,sn].

    3. Interdependent values, independent signals model.

    Example: vi(si, si) =si+

    j=i sj, with 1, with S1,...,Snindependent.

    Note: With interdependent values, i must realize that js bid is in-formative aboutis own value. This leads to the winners curse.

  • 8/10/2019 5.1 Auction Theory Slides

    27/35

    Second Price Auction

    Look for a symmetric increasing equilibrium bid strategy b(s).

    Let si denote the highest signal of bidders j =i.

    Ifbib(si), iwins and pays b(si).

    Bidder is problem:

    maxbi

    ss

    ESi

    v(si, Si)| si, S

    i =si b(si)

    1{b(si)bi}f(s

    i|si)dsi

    or

    maxbi

    b1(bi)s

    ESi

    v(si, Si)| si, S

    i =si b(si)

    dF(si|si)

  • 8/10/2019 5.1 Auction Theory Slides

    28/35

    Second Price Auction

    The first order condition for this problem is:

    0 = 1

    b(b1(bi)) ESi

    v(si, Si)| si, S

    i =b1(bi)

    b(b1(bi))

    f(b1(bi)|si)

    or simplifying:

    bi=b(si) = ESi

    v(si, Si)| si, max

    j=isj =si

  • 8/10/2019 5.1 Auction Theory Slides

    29/35

    Failure of Revenue Equivalence Theorem

    The RET does not hold in this more general environment.

    Basic idea: bidders profits are due to information rents. Whensignals are correlated, information rents can be reduced if moreinformation is used in setting the price.

    Example: english auction generates more revenue than a secondprice auction.

  • 8/10/2019 5.1 Auction Theory Slides

    30/35

    Linkage Principle Intuition

    Bidder profits (rents) are derived from their private information

    Statistical linkages align the price more closely to the buyers will-ingness to pay.

    Rents associated with private information fall

    Revenue rises

  • 8/10/2019 5.1 Auction Theory Slides

    31/35

    Linkage Principle

    Standard auctionsA, Bwith symmetric, increasing eqabA( ), bB( )

    LetWA(s, s) denote the expected price paid by bidder 1 if he is thewinning bidder when he receives a signal s but bids as if his signalwere s.

    Let WA2 (s, s) denote the partial w.r.t. the second argument. Thatis, W2 measures how much the expected price increases with in-creases in the bidders valuation, holding bidding strategy constant.

    Theorem 1 Suppose that for alls,

    W

    A

    2 (s, s) W

    B

    2 (s, s).Then the expected revenue inA is at least as large as the expected

    revenue inB.

  • 8/10/2019 5.1 Auction Theory Slides

    32/35

    Revenue Ranking: First vs Second Price Auction

    For the first price (I) auction WI(s, s) =b1(s), so

    WI2 (s, s) = 0.

    For the second price (II) auction,

    WII

    2 (s, s)> 0,

    because conditional on winning by bidding as if his signal is s...

    having a higher signal smeans that others also have a higher signal...

    so the expected price paid (the second highest bid) will be higher.

    From the theorem, it follows that the second price auction yieldsgreater revenue than the first price auction.

  • 8/10/2019 5.1 Auction Theory Slides

    33/35

    Linking Price to Seller Information

    If the seller has private informationS0about the object that is affil-iated with the signals of the buyers, the seller can increase revenue bycommitting to a policy to reveal this information.

    Theorem 2Verifiably revealing information variableS0raises theexpected price both in the first auction and second price auctions.Among all policies for full or partial revelation of information, thepolicy of full revelation maximizes the expected price.

  • 8/10/2019 5.1 Auction Theory Slides

    34/35

    Linking Price to Seller Information

    Interestingly, the policy of full information can be expected to emergeeven when the seller cannot commit to an information policy.

    Theorem 3 If a seller must decide, after observing S0, whether

    to report it, and if his report is verifiable, then in any equilibrium,he always reportsS0 regardless of the value.

    Why would a seller report ifs0is low? Because of affiliation, biddersignals will be low with or without this information. Revealing willnonetheless link this information to price.

    (If the seller observed s0 *and* bidder signals, then he may prefernot to reveal.)

  • 8/10/2019 5.1 Auction Theory Slides

    35/35

    Royalties

    When the value can be observed by all parties ex-post (even imper-fectly), expected revenue is higher when part of the price is a royaltybased on the observed value.

    Again, a linkage of available information to final price.