10 climate stavins

Upload: affnegcom

Post on 30-May-2018

217 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 8/14/2019 10 Climate Stavins

    1/68

    HAMILTONTHE

    PROJECT

    Advancing Opportunity,

    Prosperity and Growth

    The Brookings Institution

    A U.S. Cap-and-TradeSystem to AddressGlobal Climate Change

    D I S C U S S I O N P A P E R 2 0 0 7 - 1 3 O C T O B E R 2 0 0 7

    Robert N. Stavins

  • 8/14/2019 10 Climate Stavins

    2/68

    The Haiton Project sees to advance Aericas proise o

    opportunit, prosperit, and groth. The Projects econoic

    strateg reects a judgent that ong-ter prosperit is best

    achieved b aing econoic groth broad-based, b

    enhancing individua econoic securit, and b ebracing a

    roe or eective governent in aing needed pubic

    investents. Our strategstriing dierent ro the

    theories driving econoic poic in recent earscas or fsca

    discipine and or increased pubic investent in e groth-

    enhancing areas. The Project i put orard innovative

    poic ideas ro eading econoic thiners throughout the

    United Statesideas based on experience and evidence, not

    ideoog and doctrineto introduce ne, soeties

    controversia, poic options into the nationa debate ith

    the goa o iproving our countrs econoic poic.

    The Project is naed ater Aexander Haiton, the

    nations frst treasur secretar, ho aid the oundation

    or the odern Aerican econo. Consistent ith the

    guiding principes o the Project, Haiton stood or sound

    fsca poic, beieved that broad-based opportunit or

    advanceent oud drive Aerican econoic groth, and

    recognied that prudent aids and encourageents on the

    part o governent are necessar to enhance and guide

    aret orces.

    HAMILTONTH E

    PROJECT

  • 8/14/2019 10 Climate Stavins

    3/68

    The Brookings Institution

    OCTOBER 2007

    HAMILTONTHE

    PROJECT

    A U.S. Cap-and-Trade System to

    Address Global Climate Change

    Robert N. StavinsHarvard University

    National Bureau o Economic Research

    This discussion paper is a proposal rom the author. As emphasized in The Hamilton Projects

    oriinal stratey paper, the Project is desined in part to provide a orum or leadin thiners

    rom across the nation to put orard innovative and potentially important economic policy ideas

    that share the Projects broad oals o promotin economic roth, broad-based participation in

    roth, and economic security. The authors are invited to express their on ideas in discussion

    papers, hether or not the Projects sta or advisory council aree ith the specic proposals.

    This discussion paper is oered in that spirit.

  • 8/14/2019 10 Climate Stavins

    4/68

    A U.S. CAp-And-TrAde SySTem To AddreSS GlobAl ClimATe ChAnGe

    2 THE HAMILTON PROJECT|

    THE BROOkINgS INSTITUTION

    Copyriht 2007 The Brooins Institution

    Astact

    The need or a domestic U.S. policy that seriously addresses climate change is increas-

    ingly apparent. A cap-and-trade system is the best approach in the short to medium term.

    Besides providing certainty about emissions levels, cap-and-trade oers an easy means o

    compensating or the inevitably unequal burdens imposed by climate policy; it is straight-orward to harmonize with other countries climate policies; it avoids the current political

    aversion in the United States to taxes; and it has a history o successul adoption in this

    country. The paper proposes a specic cap-and-trade system with several key eatures

    including: an upstream cap on CO2 emissions with gradual inclusion o other greenhouse

    gases; a gradual downward trajectory o emissions ceilings over time to minimize dis-

    ruption and allow rms and households time to adapt; and mechanisms to reduce cost

    uncertainty. Initially, hal o the programs allowances would be allocated through auc-

    tioning and hal through ree distribution, primarily to those entities most burdened by

    the policy. This should help limit potential inequities while bolstering political support.

    The share distributed or ree would phase out over twenty-ve years. The auctioned

    allowances would generate revenue that could be used or a variety o worthwhile publicpurposes. The system would provide or linkage with international emissions reduction

    credit arrangements, harmonization over time with eective cap-and-trade systems in

    other countries, and appropriate linkage with other actions taken abroad that maintains a

    level playing eld between imports and import-competing domestic products.

  • 8/14/2019 10 Climate Stavins

    5/68

    A U.S. CAp-And-TrAde SySTem To AddreSS GlobAl ClimATe ChAnGe

    www.HAMILTONPROJECT.ORg|

    OCTOBER 2007

    Ctts

    I. Introduction 5

    II. A Comprehensive Cap-and-Trade System or greenhouse gases 14

    III. Economic Assessment o the Proposal 1

    IV. Comparison o the Cap-and-Trade Proposal ith Alternative Proposals 48

    V. Responses to Common Objections 54

    VI. Summary and Conclusions 57

    Reerences 60

    http://www.hamiltonproject.org/http://www.hamiltonproject.org/
  • 8/14/2019 10 Climate Stavins

    6/68

  • 8/14/2019 10 Climate Stavins

    7/68

    A U.S. CAp-And-TrAde SySTem To AddreSS GlobAl ClimATe ChAnGe

    www.HAMILTONPROJECT.ORg|

    OCTOBER 2007 5

    The megadisaster lm The Day Ater Tomor-

    row, about the apocalyptic consequences othe greenhouse eect, had less scientic basis

    than The Wizard o Oz, but the reality is disturb-

    ing enough. There is now a near consensus that

    anthropogenic emissions o greenhouse gases are

    very likely to change the earths climate in ways

    than many people will regret.

    The basic story has been explained many times, but

    it merits repeating. Two trace constituents o the

    atmosphere, carbon dioxide (CO2) and water vapor,

    create a thermal blanket or the planet much as glasson a greenhouse traps the suns energy within. It

    is a good thing, too: without greenhouse warming,

    the earth would be ar too cold to be livable. But

    the balance between too much and too little green-

    house eect is remarkably delicate. Massive quanti-

    ties o CO2 are produced rom the combustion o

    ossil uelscoal, petroleum, and natural gasand

    deorestation. Meanwhile the direct warming e-

    ects o CO2 and other greenhouse gasesmeth-

    ane, nitrous oxide, and halocarbonsare indirectly

    amplied because the warming increases the evap-oration o water, raising atmospheric water vapor

    concentrations (Intergovernmental Panel on Cli-

    mate Change 2007a).

    Average global surace temperatures have risen by

    about 1.25 degrees Fahrenheit over the past 150

    years, with most o the increase occurring since

    1970. This ts the predictions o modern com-

    puter models o climate change that also take ac-

    count o increases in atmospheric dust (dust cools

    the earth by refecting sunlight) and variations inthe suns energy output. Changes in temperatures

    in the middle o continents and at high latitudes

    have been two to our times greater than the aver-

    age global changealso as predicted.

    Warmer days and nights (which would surely be

    welcome in some places) are only part o the story.

    The most important consequences o greenhouse

    gas concentrations are likely to be changes in pat-terns o precipitation and runo, the melting o gla-

    ciers and sea ice, increases in sea levels, and changes

    in storm requency and intensity (Intergovernmen-

    tal Panel on Climate Change 2007b). That is why it

    is important to view the problem as global climate

    change rather than global warming alone.

    But moving rom predictions o average global tem-

    perature change to predictions o regional climate

    impacts is dicult. The best computer models can-

    not yet produce reliable estimates o these impacts.What is obvious, however, is that emissions in one

    country aect the climate in every other. Hence the

    undamental logic o a global pact on emissions,

    such as the one hammered out in Kyoto, Japan, in

    December 1997.

    Four years ater Kyoto, the Bush administration an-

    nounced that it would not submit the Kyoto Pro-

    tocol, initialed by the Clinton White House, to the

    U.S. Senate or ratication. O course, the Clinton

    administration also chose not to submit the agree-ment to the Senate, and it is very unlikely that Al

    Gore or John Kerry, had either been elected presi-

    dent, would have done so. Even beore the Kyoto

    conerence, the Senate had resolved, by a vote o

    95-0 in the Byrd-Hagel resolution, that it would

    not approve a climate control pact along the lines

    o the Kyoto accord.

    Many analystsparticularly economistshave

    been highly critical o the Kyoto Protocol, noting

    that, because o specic deciencies, it will accom-plish little, and that at a relatively high cost (Aldy,

    Barrett, and Stavins 2003). Others have been more

    supportive, noting that Kyoto is essentially the only

    game in town. But both sides agree that wheth-

    er that rst step was good or bad, a second step is

    required. Indeed, as some nations prepare or the

    Kyoto Protocols rst commitment period (2008-

    i. ituct

    http://www.hamiltonproject.org/http://www.hamiltonproject.org/
  • 8/14/2019 10 Climate Stavins

    8/68

    A U.S. CAp-And-TrAde SySTem To AddreSS GlobAl ClimATe ChAnGe

    6 THE HAMILTON PROJECT|

    THE BROOkINgS INSTITUTION

    12), the international policy community as a whole

    has begun to search or a better global policy archi-

    tecture or the second (Aldy and Stavins 2007).

    In the meantime the impetus or a meaningul U.S.

    climate policy is growing. Scientic evidence hasincreased (Intergovernmental Panel on Climate

    Change 2007a, 2007b), public concern has been

    magnied, and many people perceive what they

    believe to be evidence o climate change in prog-

    ress. Such concern is reinorced by the aggressive

    positions o key advocacy groups, which are no lon-

    ger limited on this issue to the usual environmental

    interest groups; religious lobbies, or example, have

    also been vocal. All this has been refected in greatly

    heightened attention by the news media. The re-

    sult is that a large and growing share o the U.S.population now believe that government action is

    warranted (Bannon et al. 2007).1

    In the absence o a responsive ederal policy, re-

    gions, states, and even cities have moved orward

    with their own proposals to reduce emissions o

    CO2 and other greenhouse gases. Ten northeastern

    states, or example, have developed a cap-and-trade

    program under their Regional Greenhouse Gas

    Initiative (RGGI), and Caliornias Assembly Bill 32

    may do likewise or the nations largest state. Partlyin response to ears o a ractured set o regional

    policies, an increasing number o large corpora-

    tionssometimes acting individually, other times

    in coalition with environmental advocacy groups

    have announced their support or serious national

    action.2 Building on this initiative is the April 2007

    U.S. Supreme Court decision that the administra-tion has the legislative authority to regulate CO2

    emissions,3 as well as ongoing demands rom Euro-

    pean allies and other nations that the United States

    reestablish its international credibility in this realm

    by enacting a meaningul domestic climate policy.

    Indeed, in June 2005 the Senate balanced its dis-

    tinctly negative view o the Kyoto Protocol with an

    aggressive sense-o-the-Senate resolution, adopted

    by unanimous consent, regarding domestic climate

    policy.4

    Thus momentum is clearly building toward enact-

    ment o a domestic climate change policy. But there

    should be no mistake about it: meaningul action to

    address global climate change will be costly. This is

    a key inconvenient truth that must be recognized

    when policymakers construct and evaluate propos-

    als, because the details o such a policys design will

    greatly aect its ability to achieve its goals, its costs,

    and the distribution o those costs. Even a well-de-

    signed policy will ultimately impose annual costs on

    the order o tens and perhaps hundreds o billionso dollars.5 That certainly does not mean that action

    1. Not surprisingly, the public ocus in this domain is on the goals o public policy, not on the specic means. When asked, the general publicappears to be predisposed to conventional regulatory approaches; but when conronted with a possible trade-o between the promisedbenets and the perceived cost o conventional regulation, public enthusiasm or cost-eective, market-based policy instruments increases(Bannon et al.2007).

    2. The U.S. Climate Action Partnership issued a call or action in January 2007, recommending the prompt enactment o nationallegislation in the United States to slow, stop, and reverse the growth o greenhouse gas emissions over the shortest time reasonablyachievable (2007, p. 2). The partnership consists o some o the largest U.S. companies with a stake in climate policy, rom a diverse seto sectors: electricity (Duke Energy, Exelon, FPL Group, NRG Energy, PG&E, and PNM Resources); oil and gas (BP, ConocoPhillips,and Shell); motor vehicles (Caterpillar, Daimler-Chrysler, Ford, GM, and John Deere); aluminum (Alcan and Alcoa); chemicals (DuPontand Dow); insurance (AIG and Marsh); mining (Rio Tinto); and manuacturing (Boston Scientic, General Electric, Johnson & Johnson,Pepsico, Siemens, and Xerox). The coalition is rounded out by six environmental organizations: Environmental Deense, the National

    Wildlie Federation, the Natural Resources Deense Council, the Nature Conservancy, the Pew Center on Global Climate Change, andthe World Resources Institute.

    3. Massachusetts et al. v. Environmental Protection Agencyet al., no. 05-1120, argued November 29, 2006, decided April 2, 2007.4. The resolution states: Congress should enact a comprehensive and eective national program o mandatory, market-based limits and

    incentives on emissions o greenhouse gases that slow, stop, and reverse the growth o such emissions at a rate and in a manner that (1)will not signicantly harm the United States economy; and (2) will encourage comparable action by other nations that are major tradingpartners and key contributors to global emissions. The proposal set orth in this paper is consistent with that resolution.

    5. By comparison, the cost (in 2001 dollars) o all U.S. Environmental Protection Agency regulations enacted rom 1996 to 2006 is estimatedat $25 billion to $28 billion annually (U.S. Oce o Management and Budget 2007), and a number o historical studies have estimated theannual cost o all environmental regulation in the United States to be on the order o 1 to 2 percent o GDP (Jae et al. 1995; Morgen-stern, Pizer, and Shih 2001).

  • 8/14/2019 10 Climate Stavins

    9/68

    A U.S. CAp-And-TrAde SySTem To AddreSS GlobAl ClimATe ChAnGe

    www.HAMILTONPROJECT.ORg|

    OCTOBER 2007 7

    should not be taken, but it does mean that the costs

    should be recognized i eective and sensible poli-

    cies are to be designed and implemented.

    It is important to identiy an appropriate policy

    instrument at the outset, to avoid creating con-stituencies that will later resist change (Repetto

    2007). Once a policy architecture is put in place,

    it can be exceptionally dicult to change. For ex-

    ample, any policy o signicant scope, once imple-

    mented, leads to institutional investments in both

    the public and the private sectors. And as people

    learn how to operate within the policy, status quo

    bias sets in. Some sectors and interests will benet

    rom any policy, and these groups will resist sub-

    sequent reorm. Thus the stakes associated with

    policy design are signicant. A poorly designedpolicy could impose unnecessarily high costs or

    unintended distributional consequences while pro-

    viding little public benet, and could detract rom

    the development o and commitment to a more

    eective long-run policy. In the case o climate

    change, choosing an inerior approach could be

    exceptionally costly: the dierence between a cost-

    eective approach and an inerior one could be as

    great as $150 billion annually (1 percent o todays

    GDP), or $1.8 trillion over a decade (Repetto

    2007). And because o the unique characteristicso the climate change problem, simply relying on

    existing and amiliar policy models will not lead to

    the best solutions.

    Atatv pc istuts truc Gus Gas esss

    There is general consensus among economists and

    policy analysts that a market-based policy instru-

    ment targeting CO2 emissionsand potentially

    some non-CO2 greenhouse gas emissionsshouldbe a central element o any domestic climate pol-

    icy.6 Two alternative market-based instrumentsa

    cap-and-trade system and a carbon taxhave been

    advocated. Although there are trade-os between

    them, this paper will argue that the better approach

    and the one more likely to be adopted in the short

    to medium term in the United States is a cap-and-

    trade system.

    The environmental eectiveness o a domesticcap-and-trade system or climate change can be

    maximized and its costs and risks minimized by

    inclusion o several specic eatures. The system

    should target all ossil uel-related CO2 emissions

    through an economy-wide cap on those emissions.

    The cap should be imposed upstream, that is, on

    ossil uels at the point o extraction, processing, or

    distribution, not at the point o combustion. The

    system should set a trajectory o caps over time that

    begin modestly and gradually become more strin-

    gent, establishing a long-run price signal to encour-age investment in emission-reducing technology. It

    should adopt mechanisms to protect against cost

    uncertainty. And it should include linkages with the

    climate policy actions o other countries. Impor-

    tantly, by providing politicians with the option to

    mitigate economic impacts through the distribution

    o emissions allowances, this approach can estab-

    lish consensus or a policy that achieves meaningul

    reductions. It is or these reasons and others that

    cap-and-trade systems have been used increasingly

    in the United States to address an array o environ-mental problems, or example to phase out the use

    o lead in gasoline, limit emissions o sulur diox-

    ide (SO2) and nitrous oxides (NOX), and phase out

    chlorofuorocarbons (CFCs; Stavins 2003; see also

    the online appendix atwww.hamiltonproject.org).

    Cap-and-trade should not be conused with emis-

    sions reduction credits or other credit-based pro-

    grams, in which those reporting emissions reduc-

    tions receive credits that others either may or must

    buy to oset obligations under some other policy.Credit-based programs have oten been considered

    as a means o encouraging emissions reductions

    rom activities outside the scope o a cap-and-trade

    system, emissions tax, or standards-based policy. But

    6. This perspective is embodied in international assessments o national policy instruments as well (Intergovernmental Panel on ClimateChange 2007c).

    http://www.hamiltonproject.org/http://www.hamiltonproject.org/http://www.hamiltonproject.org/http://www.hamiltonproject.org/
  • 8/14/2019 10 Climate Stavins

    10/68

    A U.S. CAp-And-TrAde SySTem To AddreSS GlobAl ClimATe ChAnGe

    8 THE HAMILTON PROJECT|

    THE BROOkINgS INSTITUTION

    an important limitation o credit-based programs is

    that they typically require measurementor, more

    likely, estimationo emissions reductions, which,

    unlike emissions themselves, cannot be directly ob-

    served. Hence these programs generally ace di-

    culties in establishing that reported reductionswould not have occurred in the absence o the pro-

    gram. This is the so-called baseline or addition-

    ality problem: how to compare actual outcomes

    with an unobserved and undamentally unobserv-

    able hypothetical. Despite this obstacle, cost sav-

    ings still may be achieved through the selective use

    o credit-based programs targeting certain activi-

    ties. As discussed later, these include various types

    o carbon-saving land management that otherwise

    would be too costly or ineasible to integrate into a

    cap-and-trade (or a tax) system.

    The alternative to a cap-and-trade system most re-

    quently considered by policymakers is the use o

    command-and-control standards, such as energy

    eciency or emissions perormance standards,

    which require rms and consumers to take particu-

    lar actions that directly or indirectly reduce emis-

    sions. The costs o standards are oten largely invis-

    ible except to those directly aected by them. But

    in act, those costs would be signicantly greater

    than under sound market-based policies, becausestandards oer rms and consumers ar less fex-

    ibility in reducing emissions, and they cannot target

    many low-cost emissions reduction opportunities.

    Moreover, the eectiveness o standards in achiev-

    ing nationwide emissions targets is highly uncer-

    tain, in part because they could cover only a raction

    o those emissions, leaving many sources unregu-

    lated. In contrast, market-based policies can cover

    all sources o ossil uel-related CO2 emissions, and

    unlike other alternatives, a cap-and-trade system

    can essentially guarantee achievement o emissionstargets or sources covered by the cap.

    T Fcus Ca-a-Ta

    A cap-and-trade system places a cap, or ceiling, on

    the aggregate emissions o a group o regulated

    sources by creating a limited number o tradable

    emissions allowances or a given period and requir-ing rms to surrender a quantity o allowances equal

    to their emissions during that period.7 The system

    imposes no particular limits on emissions rom any

    given rm or source. A rm may emit as much as it

    chooses, as long as it obtains sucient allowances

    to do so. The government may initially distribute

    the allowances or ree or sell them at auction. In ei-

    ther case, the need to surrender valuable allowances

    to cover any emissions and the opportunity to trade

    those allowances establishes a price on emissions.

    In turn, this price provides rms with an incentiveto reduce their emissions that infuences all o their

    production and investment decisions.

    Because allowances are tradable, the ultimate dis-

    tribution o emissions reduction eorts necessary

    to keep emissions within the cap is determined by

    market orces. Those sources that nd it cheaper

    to reduce their emissions than to continue emit-

    ting and pay or allowances will do so, and those

    that nd it cheaper to purchase allowances will do

    so. Through the trading o allowances, the priceadjusts until emissions are brought down to the

    level o the cap. Firms ability to trade emissions

    allowances creates a market in which allowances

    migrate toward their highest-valued use, covering

    those emissions that are the most costly to reduce.

    A well-designed cap-and-trade system thus mini-

    mizes the costs o achieving any given emissions

    target. Overall, a cap-and-trade system provides

    certainty regarding emissions rom the regulated

    sources as a group, because aggregate emissions

    rom all regulated entities cannot exceed the totalnumber o allowances.8

    7. This description is o what is called a downstream cap-and-trade system or CO2, which regulates the sources that emit CO2 by burningossil uels. This paper proposes an upstream system, as dened above, because o its economy-wide coverage.

    8. The trade-o or such emissions certainty is uncertainty regarding the policys costs, as regulated sources will meet the cap regardless ocost. In contrast, a carbon tax provides greater certainty over program costs but does not guarantee achievement o a specic emissionstarget. Later in this paper, the trade-o between cost uncertainty and emissions uncertainty is examined, and specic means o reducing acap-and-trade systems cost uncertainty are identied.

  • 8/14/2019 10 Climate Stavins

    11/68

    A U.S. CAp-And-TrAde SySTem To AddreSS GlobAl ClimATe ChAnGe

    www.HAMILTONPROJECT.ORg|

    OCTOBER 2007

    The cost o achieving signicant greenhouse gas

    emissions reductions in uture years will depend

    critically on the availability and cost o low- or

    nonemitting technologies. A cap-and-trade system

    that establishes caps extending decades into the

    uture generates price signals that provide incen-tives or rms to invest in the development and

    deployment o such technologies, thereby low-

    ering the uture cost o reducing emissions. To

    create these incentives, a cap-and-trade system

    must provide credible commitments to meeting

    long-run emissions targets.9 I a lack o credibility

    makes the payo rom investments in the new

    technologies highly uncertain, these investments

    will lag (Montgomery and Smith 2007). On the

    other hand, policymakers also need to maintain

    fexibility to adjust long-term targets as new in-ormation is obtained regarding the benets and

    costs o mitigating climate change. Managing this

    trade-o between the credibility o long-run tar-

    gets and fexibility is important or the success o

    any climate policy.

    Even a credible long-run cap-and-trade system may

    provide insucient incentives or investment in

    technology development i it does not address cer-

    tain well-known market ailures, in particular those

    associated with investments that create knowledgewith a public good nature (Jae et al. 2005, Newell

    2007). A cap-and-trade system alone will not en-

    courage the socially desirable level o investment

    in research, development, and deployment o new

    technologies that could reduce uture emissions re-

    duction costs. Additional policies may be necessary

    to increase government unding or incentives or

    private unding o such research.10

    Acats Ca-a-Ta

    mcass

    Over the past two decades, tradable permit systems

    or pollution control have been adopted with in-

    creasing requency in the United States (Tieten-

    berg 1997) as well as other parts o the world. As

    explained above, tradable permit programs are o

    two basic types, credit programs and cap-and-trade

    systems. The ocus o this brie review is on appli-

    cations o the cap-and-trade approach.11 The pro-grams described below are examined in more detail

    in the online appendix to this paper.

    pvus Us Ca-a-Ta Ssts

    lca a rga A put

    The rst important example o an environmen-

    tal trading program in the United States was the

    phasedown o leaded gasoline in the 1980s. Al-

    though not strictly a cap-and-trade system, the

    phasedown included eatures, such as trading and

    banking o environmental credits, that brought itcloser than other credit programs to the cap-and-

    trade model and resulted in signicant cost savings.

    The program was successul in meeting its environ-

    mental targets, and the system was cost-eective,

    with estimated cost savings o about $250 million

    a year (Stavins 2003). Also, the program provided

    measurable incentives or the diusion o cost-sav-

    ing technology (Kerr and Newell 2000).

    A cap-and-trade system was also used in the United

    States to help comply with the Montreal Protocol,an international agreement aimed at slowing the

    rate o stratospheric ozone depletion. The proto-

    col called or reductions in the use o CFCs and

    halons, the primary chemical groups thought to

    lead to depletion. The timetable or the phaseout

    o CFCs was later accelerated, and the system ap-

    pears to have been relatively cost-eective.

    The most important application in the United

    States to date o a market-based instrument or

    environmental protection is arguably the cap-and-trade system that regulates SO2 emissions,

    the primary precursor o acid rain. The program,

    established under the U.S. Clean Air Act Amend-

    9. Although no legislation can guarantee that uture commitments will be met, legislated targets increase credibility by increasing the politi-cal costs to legislators o altering uture requirements.

    10. See, or example, National Commission on Energy Policy (2007b). Such complementary policies are examined later in this paper.11. This section draws, in part, on Stavins (2003).

    http://www.hamiltonproject.org/http://www.hamiltonproject.org/
  • 8/14/2019 10 Climate Stavins

    12/68

    A U.S. CAp-And-TrAde SySTem To AddreSS GlobAl ClimATe ChAnGe

    10 THE HAMILTON PROJECT|

    THE BROOkINgS INSTITUTION

    ments o 1990, is intended to reduce SO2 and NOX

    emissions by 10 million tons and 2 million tons,

    respectively, rom 1980 levels. A robust market in

    SO2 allowances emerged under the program, re-

    sulting in cost savings on the order o $1 billion an-

    nually compared with some command-and-controlalternatives (Carlson et al. 2000). The program has

    also had a signicant environmental impact: SO2

    emissions rom the electric power sector decreased

    rom 15.7 million tons in 1990 to 10.2 million tons

    in 2005 (U.S. Environmental Protection Agency

    2005).

    In 1994 Caliornias South Coast Air Quality Man-

    agement District launched a cap-and-trade pro-

    gram to reduce NOX and SO2 emissions in the Los

    Angeles area. This program, called the RegionalClean Air Incentives Market (RECLAIM), set an

    aggregate cap on NOX and SO2 emissions or all

    signicant sources, with an ambitious goal o re-

    ducing aggregate emissions 70 percent by 2003.

    Trading under the RECLAIM program was re-

    stricted in several ways, with positive and negative

    consequences. But despite problems, RECLAIM

    has generated environmental benets, with NOX

    emissions in the regulated area alling by 60 percent

    and SO2 emissions by 50 percent. The program has

    also reduced compliance costs or regulated acili-ties, with the best available analysis suggesting cost

    savings o 42 percent, amounting to $58 million an-

    nually (Anderson 1997).

    Finally, in 1999, under U.S. Environmental Pro-

    tection Agency guidance, twelve northeastern

    states and the District o Columbia implement-

    ed a regional NOX cap-and-trade system to re-

    duce compliance costs associated with the Ozone

    Transport Commissions (OTC) regulations under

    the 1990 amendments to the Clean Air Act. Emis-sions caps or two zones rom 1999-2003 were set

    at 35 percent and 45 percent o 1990 emissions.

    Compliance cost savings o 40 to 47 percent have

    been estimated or the period, compared with

    a base case o continued command-and-control

    regulation without trading or banking (Farrell et

    al. 1999).

    Gus Gas Ca-a-Ta Ssts

    Although cap-and-trade has proved to be a cost-e-

    ective means to control conventional air pollutants,

    it has a very limited history as a method o reducing

    CO2 emissions. Several ambitious programs are in

    the planning stages or have been launched.

    First, the Kyoto Protocol, the international agree-

    ment signed in Japan in 1997, includes a provision

    or an international cap-and-trade system among

    countries, as well as two systems o project-level

    osets. The protocols provisions have set the stage

    or the member states o the European Union to

    address their commitments using a regional cap-

    and-trade system. This system, the European

    Union Emissions Trading Scheme (EU ETS) or

    CO2 allowances, is by ar the largest active cap-and-trade program in the world. It has operated or

    two years with considerable success, despite some

    initialand predictableproblems. The 11,500

    emissions sources regulated by the downstream

    program include large sources such as oil rener-

    ies, combustion installations, coke ovens, cement

    actories, and errous metal, glass and ceramics, and

    pulp and paper producers, but the program does

    not cover sources in the transportation, commer-

    cial, or residential sectors. Although the rst phase,

    a pilot program rom 2005 to 2007, allows tradingonly in CO2, the second phase, 2008-12, potentially

    broadens the program to include other greenhouse

    gases. In its rst two years o operation, the EU

    ETS has produced a unctioning CO2 allowanc-

    es market, with weekly trading volumes ranging

    between 5 million and 15 million tons, and with

    spikes in trading activity accompanying major price

    changes. Apart rom identiying some problems

    with the programs design and early implementa-

    tion (discussed in the online appendix), it is much

    too soon to provide a denitive assessment o thesystems perormance.

    In the United States, RGGI, a program among

    ten northeastern states, will be implemented in

    2009 and begin to cut emissions in 2015. RGGI

    is a downstream cap-and-trade program intended

    to limit CO2 emissions rom electric power sec-

  • 8/14/2019 10 Climate Stavins

    13/68

    A U.S. CAp-And-TrAde SySTem To AddreSS GlobAl ClimATe ChAnGe

    www.HAMILTONPROJECT.ORg|

    OCTOBER 2007 11

    tor sources. Beginning in 2015 the emissions cap

    will decrease by 2.5 percent each year until 2019,

    when it will be 10 percent below current emissions,

    or about 35 percent below the business-as-usual

    (BAU) estimate, and 13 percent below 1990 emis-

    sions levels. Because RGGI limits emissions romthe power sector only, incremental monitoring

    costs are low, as U.S. power plants are already re-

    quired to report their hourly CO2 emissions to the

    ederal government, under provisions o the SO2

    allowance trading program. The program requires

    participating states to auction at least 25 percent o

    their allowances; the remainder may also be auc-

    tioned or distributed ree. It is obviously not yet

    possible to assess the systems perormance, but sev-

    eral problems with its design are examined in the

    online appendix.

    Finally, under Caliornias Global Warming So-

    lutions Act (Assembly Bill 32), signed into law in

    2006, the state will begin in 2012 to reduce emis-

    sions to 1990 levels by 2020, and may employ a cap-

    and-trade approach. Although the act does not re-

    quire the use o market-based instruments, it does

    allow or them, with restrictions: they must not

    result in increased emissions o criteria air pollut-

    ants or toxics, they must maximize environmental

    and economic benets in Caliornia, and they musttake localized economic and environmental justice

    concerns into account. This mixed set o objectives

    may interere with the development o a sound

    policy mechanism. The Governors Market Advi-

    sory Committee has recommended a cap-and-trade

    program, with a gradual phase-in o caps covering

    most sectors o the economy, and an allowance dis-

    tribution system that uses both ree distribution

    and auctions, with a shit toward more auctions in

    later years.

    Cta pc Asssst

    Three criteria stand out as particularly important

    or the assessment o a domestic climate change

    policy: environmental eectiveness, cost-eective-

    ness, and distributional equity.12

    evta ectvss

    The rst criterion any proposed climate policy

    must meet is environmental eectiveness: Can the

    proposed instrument achieve its intended targets?

    This will depend, in the case o a standards-based

    approach, on the technical ability o policymakers to

    design and the administrative ability o governments

    to implement standards that are suciently diverse

    to address all o the sources o CO2 emissions in a

    modern economy. In the case o a tax, it will dependon the ability o political systems to impose taxes that

    are suciently high to achieve meaningul emissions

    reductions (or limits on global greenhouse gas con-

    centrations, or limits on temperature changes).

    The evaluation must also consider how certain it is

    that the proposed policy will achieve its emissions

    or other targets. Dierent policy designs may be

    expected to achieve identical targets, but with di-

    erent degrees o certainty. A cap-and-trade system

    can achieve emissions targets with high certaintybecause guaranteed emissions levels are built into

    the policy. With a carbon tax or technology stan-

    dards, on the other hand, actual emissions are di-

    cult to predict because o current and uture un-

    certainty about uture energy prices or how quickly

    new technologies will be adopted. Such policies

    may aim to achieve particular emissions targets,

    but actual emissions may either exceed or all below

    those targets, depending on actors beyond policy-

    makers control.

    12. Eciency is ordinarily a key criterion or assessing public policies but is less useul when comparing alternative domestic policy instru-ments to address climate change. The eciency criterion requires a comparison o benets and costs, but given the global commonsnature o climate change, a strict accounting o the direct benets o any U.S. policy to the United States will produce benets that aresmall relative to costs. Clearly, the benets o a U.S. policy can only be considered in the context o a global system. Later in this paper themarginal cost (allowance price) o the proposed policy is compared with previous estimates o the marginal benets o globally ecientpolicies. In the short term, the cap-and-trade system, like any other meaningul domestic climate policy, may best be viewed as a step to-ward establishing U.S. credibility or negotiations on post-Kyoto international climate agreements. At the same time, another argument inavor o a cap-and-trade (or a carbon tax) policy is political: the likelihood o some national climate policy being enacted is increasing, andit is preerable that such a policy be implemented cost-eectively rather than through more costly conventional regulatory approaches.

    http://www.hamiltonproject.org/http://www.hamiltonproject.org/
  • 8/14/2019 10 Climate Stavins

    14/68

  • 8/14/2019 10 Climate Stavins

    15/68

    A U.S. CAp-And-TrAde SySTem To AddreSS GlobAl ClimATe ChAnGe

    www.HAMILTONPROJECT.ORg|

    OCTOBER 2007 1

    require rapid changes in capital stock, markets, and

    consumer choices. Finally, policies may also create

    negative costs(or co-benefts) by reducing the cost o

    complying with other environmental regulations,

    such as those targeting SO2 and NOX emissions, or

    by bringing about other non-climate-related ben-ets, including increased energy security.

    dstuta equt

    The economic impacts o any climate policy will be

    broadly elt but will vary across regions, industries,

    and households. The ultimate distribution will de-

    pend not only on the costs imposed by the policy,

    but also on resulting shits in the supply o and de-

    mand or aected goods and services, and associated

    changes in market prices. Firms directly regulated

    by a climate policy typically experience two impacts:direct regulatory costs that reduce their prot mar-

    gins, and changes in demand or their products. A

    policys initial burden on directly regulated rms

    may be partially oset as the introduction o direct

    regulatory costs leads to increases in those rms

    product prices, or reductions in prices o some in-

    puts, or both. As a result o these price changes,

    other rms not directly regulated by climate policy

    will also experience changes in prots and demand.

    The extent to which rms acing the direct or indi-

    rect costs o a climate policy pass those costs on totheir consumers (or back to their suppliers) depends

    on the characteristics o the markets in which they

    compete, including the industrys cost structure and

    consumers price responsiveness.

    Any comprehensive climate policy will adversely a-

    ect many rms, but some may experience windall

    prots. For example, rms making less carbon-in-

    tensive products may enjoy windall prots i a cli-

    mate policy increases market prices or their prod-

    ucts more than it increases their own costs. Thusevaluation o a climate policys distributional im-

    plications requires identiying its ultimate burdens,

    ater all adjustments in market prices, rather than

    just its initial impacts on costs.

    Although discussion oten ocuses on the impact

    o climate policies on rms, all economic impacts

    are ultimately borne by households in their roles

    as consumers, investors, and workers. As produc-

    ers pass through their increased costs, consumers

    experience increased prices o energy and nonen-

    ergy goods and may reduce their consumption. As

    a policy positively or negatively aects the prot-ability o rms, investors experience changes in

    the value o investments in those rms. Finally,

    workers may experience changes in employment

    and wages.

    The benets (that is, the avoided damages) o cli-

    mate policy are also unevenly distributed. Alterna-

    tive policy instruments are very unlikely to result

    in dierent geographic distributions o climate im-

    pacts, because greenhouse gases mix uniormly in

    the atmosphere. On the other hand, emissions onon-greenhouse gas pollutants that are correlated

    with emissions o CO2 may have local impacts and

    be sensitive to the choice o policy instrument.

    ogazat t pa

    Section II o this paper proposes a comprehensive

    U.S. CO2 cap-and-trade system and describes its

    key elements: a gradual trajectory o emissions re-

    ductions; tradable allowances; upstream regulation

    with economy-wide eects; mechanisms to reducecost uncertainty; allowance allocations that com-

    bine auctions with ree distribution, with auctions

    becoming more important over time; availability

    o osets or underground and biological carbon

    sequestration; supremacy over state and regional

    systems; and linkage with international emissions

    reduction credit and cap-and-trade systems and cli-

    mate policies in other countries.

    Section III provides an economic assessment o the

    proposal, including an analysis o aggregate costsand distributional impacts. Section IV compares

    the proposal with alternative approaches to the

    same policy goal, with particular attention to com-

    mand-and-control regulation and carbon taxes.

    Section V examines some common objections to

    the proposed policy and provides responses. Sec-

    tion VI concludes.

    http://www.hamiltonproject.org/http://www.hamiltonproject.org/
  • 8/14/2019 10 Climate Stavins

    16/68

    A U.S. CAp-And-TrAde SySTem To AddreSS GlobAl ClimATe ChAnGe

    14 THE HAMILTON PROJECT|

    THE BROOkINgS INSTITUTION

    The United States can launch a scientically

    sound, economically rational, and politicallyeasible approach to reducing its greenhouse

    gas emissions by adopting an upstream, economy-

    wide CO2 cap-and-trade system that implements

    a gradual trajectory o emissions reductions over

    time. The approach proposed here also includes

    mechanisms to reduce cost uncertainty, such as

    multiyear compliance periods, provisions or bank-

    ing and borrowing, and possibly a cost containment

    mechanism to protect against extreme price volatil-

    ity.15

    Allowances under the system would be allocated

    through a combination o ree distribution and

    open auction. This is intended to balance, on the

    one hand, the legitimate concerns o those who will

    be particularly burdened by this (or any) climate

    policy with, on the other hand, the opportunity to

    achieve important public purposes with unds gen-

    erated by the auctions. The share o ree allowances

    would decrease over time as the private sector ad-

    justs to the carbon constraints, with all allowances

    being auctioned ater twenty-ve years.

    Osets would be made available or both under-

    ground and biological carbon sequestration, to

    achieve short-term cost-eectiveness and create

    long-term incentives or appropriate technologi-

    cal change. The cap-and-trade system would be a

    ederal program, with supremacy over all U.S. re-

    gional, state, and local systems, to avoid duplication,

    double counting, and conficting requirements. It

    would also provide or harmonization over time

    with emissions reduction credit and cap-and-tradesystems in other nations, as well as related interna-

    tional systems.

    maj Tug nt excusv Fcus

    Co2

    This proposal ocuses on reductions o ossil uel-

    related CO2 emissions, which accounted or nearly

    85 percent o the 7.1 billion metric tons o U.S.

    greenhouse gas emissions in 2005.16 CO2 emissions

    arise rom a broad range o activities involving the

    use o dierent uels in many dierent economic

    sectors (Figure 1). In addition, biological seques-

    tration and reductions in non-CO2 greenhouse gas

    emissions can contribute substantially to minimiz-

    ing the cost o limiting total greenhouse gas con-centrations (Reilly, Jacoby, and Prinn 2003; Stavins

    and Richards 2005). Some non-CO2 emissions

    might be addressed under the same ramework as

    or CO2 in a multigas cap-and-trade system.17 But

    challenges associated with measuring and moni-

    toring other non-CO2 emissions and biological

    sequestration may require separate programs tai-

    lored to their specic characteristics, as described

    later.

    Gaua icasg Tajct esss ructs v T

    Because climate change is a long-term problem,

    policies can be somewhat fexible regarding when

    emissions reductions actually occur. Policies that

    take advantage o this when fexibility, or exam-

    ple by setting annual emissions targets that gradu-

    ally increase in stringency, can avoid many o the

    costs associated with taking stringent action too

    quickly, without sacricing environmental benets

    (Wigley, Richels, and Edmonds 1996). Prematureretirement o existing capital stock can be avoided,

    as can many production and siting bottlenecks.

    ii. A Csv Ca-a-Ta Sst Gus Gass

    15. For a review o alternative designs or a national cap-and-trade system, see Cambridge Energy Research Associates (2006).16. This gure measures greenhouse gases in CO2-equivalent terms; that is, quantities o greenhouse gases other than CO2 are converted to

    quantities o CO2 o the same radiative orcing potential over their average duration in the atmosphere.17. Because landll methane emissions are already monitored, and monitoring o industrial (as opposed to agricultural) non-CO 2 greenhouse

    gases would not be dicult, regulation o these sources might be integrated with CO 2 policies (Reilly, Jacoby, and Prinn 2003).

  • 8/14/2019 10 Climate Stavins

    17/68

    A U.S. CAp-And-TrAde SySTem To AddreSS GlobAl ClimATe ChAnGe

    www.HAMILTONPROJECT.ORg|

    OCTOBER 2007 15

    Gradually phased-in targets also provide time toincorporate advanced technologies into long-lived

    investments (Goulder 2004; Jae, Newell, and

    Stavins 1999).18 Thus, or any given cumulative

    emissions target or associated atmospheric con-

    centration objective, a climate policys cost can be

    reduced by gradually phasing in eorts to reduce

    emissions.

    The long-term nature o the climate problem and

    the need or technological change to bring about

    lower-cost emissions reductions also make it es-sential that the caps be instituted gradually over a

    long period. The development and eventual adop-

    tion o new low-carbon and other relevant tech-

    nologies will depend on the predictability o uture

    carbon prices, which themselves will be aected bythe caps constraints. Thereore the cap-and-trade

    policy should incorporate medium- to long-term

    targets, not just short-term targets.

    It would be a mistake, however, to think that when

    fexibility is a reason to allow delay in enacting a

    mandatory policy. On the contrary, the earlier a

    mandatory policy is established, the more fexibility

    there will be to set emissions targets that gradually

    depart rom BAU levels while still achieving a long-

    run objective or atmospheric concentration. Thelonger it takes to establish a mandatory policy, the

    more stringent the near-term emissions targets will

    need to be to achieve a given long-run concentra-

    tion objective.

    FiGUre 1

    U.S. Gus Gas esss, 2005

    18. In addition, given the time value o money (the opportunity cost o capital), environmentally neutral delays in the timing o emissionsreduction investments can be socially advantageous.

    PetroleumCO

    2 2,614CoalCO

    2 2,142

    NaturalGasCO2 1,178RenewablesCO

    2 12

    IndustrialP

    rocessesCO2

    105

    Methane

    612

    Nitrou

    sOxid

    e367

    Othe

    rgase

    s160

    (Million Metric Tons Carbon Dioxide Equivalent)

    U.S. Territories 59

    International Bunkers 101

    CO2Energy

    Subtotal5,945

    CO2Unadjusted

    Total6,051

    Direct Fuel Uses3,570

    Power SectorConversion

    to Electricity2,375

    Industrial Processes105

    Methane, Nitrous Oxide,Other Gases

    1,139

    Greenhouse

    Gases

    2005 Total

    7,147

    Coal 1,944Natural Gas 319Petroleum 100Renewables 12

    CO21,2

    66

    Non-CO2

    18

    Residenti

    al

    1,284

    CO2 1,061

    Non-CO2 240

    Commercial

    1,301

    CO2 1,804Non-CO2 757

    Industrial

    2,562

    CO2 1,877Non-CO

    2 123Transportation2,000

    Source: U.S. Energy Information Administration (2006).

    http://www.hamiltonproject.org/http://www.hamiltonproject.org/
  • 8/14/2019 10 Climate Stavins

    18/68

    A U.S. CAp-And-TrAde SySTem To AddreSS GlobAl ClimATe ChAnGe

    16 THE HAMILTON PROJECT|

    THE BROOkINgS INSTITUTION

    Gradually phasing in the stringency o emissions

    targets may also reduce the near-term burden o

    a climate policy, and with it both the costs and the

    challenges associated with gaining political consen-

    sus. On the other hand, a policy that shits reduc-

    tion eorts too ar into the uture may not be cred-ible, thus weakening incentives or investments in

    advanced technologies.

    Several alternative types o policy-target trajecto-

    ries are possible, including trajectories or emis-

    sions caps, emissions reduction targets, global con-

    centration targets, and allowance prices. Given the

    long-term nature o the problem, the best measure

    o policy stringency may be the sum o national

    emissions permitted over some extended period.

    As explained later, i banking and borrowing o al-lowances are allowed, then only the sum o capped

    national emissions over time matters, not the spe-

    cic trajectory, because trading o allowances will

    generate the cost-minimizing trajectory.O course,

    i there is too much delay in bringing down emis-

    sions, then the timing o emissions reductions can

    aect total damages, even i cumulative emissions

    are the same.

    How should the appropriate sum o capped nation-

    al emissions be identied? The classic economicapproach is to choose targets that maximize the

    dierence between expected benets and expected

    costs, but such an approach is simply not ea-

    sible in this context, or several reasons. Reliable

    inormation about anticipated damageseven in

    biophysical, let alone economic termsis lack-

    ing. In any case such a calculation could be made

    only at the global, not the national, level given

    that the problem aects the global commons. Fi-

    nally, it is increasingly clear that an analysis that

    merely compares expected benets with expected

    costs is inadequate, since it is the small risks o

    catastrophic damages that are at the heart o the

    problem (Weitzman 2007).

    The cost assessment presented later in this paper

    adopts and assesses a pair o trajectories or 2012-50

    to establish a reasonable range o possibilities or

    illustrative purposes. The less ambitious trajectory

    involves stabilizing CO2 emissions at their 2008

    level over 2012-50, as predicted by Paltsev and oth-

    ers (2007a, 2007b). This trajectory, in terms o its

    cumulative cap, lies within the range dened by the

    2004 and 2007 recommendations o the National

    Commission on Energy Policy (2004, 2007b). The

    more ambitious trajectory, also dened over 2012-50, would reduce CO2 emissions to 50 percent be-

    low their 1990 level. This trajectory, dened by its

    cumulative cap, is consistent with the lower end

    o the range proposed by the U.S. Climate Action

    Partnership (2007).

    This illustrative pair o cap trajectories has sever-

    al signicant attributes. First, both are consistent

    with the requently cited global goal o stabilizing

    atmospheric concentrations o CO2 at between 450

    and 550 parts per million (ppm), i all nations wereto take commensurate actions.19 Second, the caps

    gradually become more stringent over an extended

    period, thus reducing costs by avoiding the necessi-

    ty o premature retirement o existing capital stock,

    by reducing vulnerability to siting bottlenecks and

    other risks that arise with rapid capital stock transi-

    tions, and by ensuring that rms have the opportu-

    nity to incorporate appropriate advanced technol-

    ogy in their long-lived capital investments.20

    19. Commensurate action is dened in the analysis as other countries taking action that is globally cost-eective, or example by employingcap-and-trade systems with the same allowance price or equivalent carbon taxes (Paltsev et al. 2007a, including Table 12, page 57).

    20. An alternative to the type o caps recommended here, which are denominated in tons o CO 2 emissions, is the use o intensity-basedtargets, where emissions intensity is specied by the ratio o emissions to economic activity. Any aggregate output index could serve asthe denominator, but a target based on CO2 emissions per dollar o GDP has been requently proposed. Under such a GDP-indexed cap,allowable emissions in each year would be equal to the intensity cap multiplied by GDP. The Bush administrations climate policy includesemissions intensity targets o this type (Pizer 2005a). Intensity-based caps are not inherently more or less stringent than absolute caps:given a GDP orecast, an intensity-based cap can be designed to yield the same expected emissions level as any absolute cap. An intensity-based cap does introduce uncertainty regarding emissions levels, but at the same time it reduces cost uncertainty. However, intensity-basedtargets would create problems or linking with cap-and-trade systems in other nations. Total emissions under linked systems may eitherincrease or decrease i one or both systems employ an intensity-based rather than an absolute cap. It should be noted that the correlation

  • 8/14/2019 10 Climate Stavins

    19/68

    A U.S. CAp-And-TrAde SySTem To AddreSS GlobAl ClimATe ChAnGe

    www.HAMILTONPROJECT.ORg|

    OCTOBER 2007 17

    Usta pt rguat aec-W Sc Cvag

    Any cap-and-trade system or CO2 must dene theset o emissions sources that are capped (the scope

    o coverage) and the point in the ossil uel supply

    chain at which that cap is enorced (the point o reg-

    ulation). To achieve economy-wide coverage, the

    point o regulation should be upstream, collecting

    allowances according to the carbon content o uels

    at the point o their extraction, import, processing,

    or distribution.21 The rst sellers o extracted ossil

    uels would be required to hold allowances: or coal,

    at the mine shipping terminus; or petroleum, at the

    renery gate; or natural gas, at the rst distributionpoint; and or imports, at the point o importation.

    Such a cap would eectively cover all sources o CO2

    emissions throughout the economy (Table 1).22

    Any upstream program should include a credit

    mechanism, to address both the small portion o

    ossil uels that are not combusted and the use o

    between GDP and emissions varies substantially across countries, ranging rom 0.70 or the United States to only 0.10 or France (Newelland Pizer 2006). Where the relationship between GDP and emissions is weak, an intensity-based cap may exacerbate fuctuations in emis-sions reduction eorts by overadjusting emissions targets in response to economic fuctuations. More broadly, an intensity target need not

    take the orm o a simple ratio, and more sensible outcomes would be associated with slightly more complex ormulas (Aldy 2004).21. Regulation at the point o transportation or distribution is sometimes reerred to as midstream regulation. A downstream program im-

    poses allowance requirements at the point o emissions, or example at electric power plants or actories. An upstream point o regulationhas been used in the past where ultimate emissions are directly related to upstream production activity. For example, an upstream point oregulation was used to phase out automobile lead emissions by limiting the quantity o lead that reneries could use in gasoline. Similarly,emissions o ozone-depleting substances were phased out through limits on their production rather than on their use. It should be notedthat an upstream approach is not ully comprehensive unless provisions are made to address process emissions rom natural gas andcrude oil extraction.

    22. The electric power and transportation sectors account or over 70 percent o total CO 2 emissions; when the industrial sector is included,these three sectors account or nearly 90 percent o emissions. But electric power sector emissions result rom electricity use by all othersectors. The last column o Table 1 includes indirect emissions rom electricity use in reporting each o the other sectors emissions.

    TAble 1

    Co2 esss eg Csut Sct a Fu T, 2005Millions o metric tons except here stated otherisea

    Scts ct sss

    Sct Ca onatua

    gasA uts

    Scts ctsss assa tta a scts

    (ct)

    Sctsctsss

    ctct us

    Scts cta ctsss

    Scts ct

    a ctsss assa tta a scts

    (ct)

    Residential 1 105 262 68 6.2 886 1,254 21.1

    Commercial 8 55 166 20 . 821 1,051 17.7

    Transportation 0 1,22 2 1,5 2. 5 1,5 2.

    Industrial 185 41 400 1,020b 17.1 66 1,682 28.

    Electricity 1,44 100 1 2,75c . NA NA NA

    All sectors 2,18 2,614 1,178 5,45 5,45

    All sectors asshare o total(percent) 6.0 44.0 1.8 100.0 100.0

    Source: U.S. Enery Inormation Administration (2006).

    a. Emission totals dier rom those in ure 1 because ure 1 includes CO2 emissions rom industrial processes and because o minor dierences in measurement, such

    as treatment o emissions rom U.S. territories.

    b. Includes emissions rom net coe imports not accounted or in the rst three columns.

    c. Includes emissions rom eothermal and aste-to-enery eneration not accounted or in the rst three columns.

    http://www.hamiltonproject.org/http://www.hamiltonproject.org/
  • 8/14/2019 10 Climate Stavins

    20/68

    A U.S. CAp-And-TrAde SySTem To AddreSS GlobAl ClimATe ChAnGe

    18 THE HAMILTON PROJECT|

    THE BROOkINgS INSTITUTION

    postcombustion emissions reduction technologies,

    such as carbon capture and sequestration (CCS). It

    should also include a credit-based arrangement or

    ossil uel exports so that exporters are not placed

    at a competitive disadvantage relative to oreign

    suppliers that do not ace allowance requirements.Emissions reductions rom CCS technologies can

    be readily measured. Also, unlike some credit-

    based programs, a program or CCS runs no risk

    o granting credits or ctitious emissions reduc-

    tions: because emissions sources have no incen-

    tive to install CCS equipment in the absence o

    a climate policy, emissions reductions achieved by

    CCS are clearly additional. CCS technologies are

    expected to play a signicant role in achieving

    long-run emissions reduction goals; thereore such

    a credit mechanism is an essential component oan upstream cap.

    Although the point o regulation determines which

    entities are ultimately required to hold allowances,

    this decision can be made independently o the

    initial allowance allocation decision. The point

    o regulation does not dictate or in any way limit

    who may receive allowances i allowances are dis-

    tributed or ree. The point-o-regulation deci-

    sion also has no direct eect on either the costs o

    emissions reduction or the distribution o resultingeconomic burdens.23 A cap has the same impact on

    the eective cost o uel or downstream users re-

    gardless o the point o regulation. With upstream

    regulation, the allowance cost is included in the uel

    price. Since all suppliers ace the same additional

    allowance cost, all will include it in the prices they

    set or downstream customers. With downstream

    regulation, the downstream customer pays or the

    allowances and the uel separately. In either case

    the downstream customer ultimately aces the same

    additional cost associated with emissions rom itsuel use.

    This has two important implications. First, the

    distribution o costs between upstream and down-

    stream rms is unaected by the point-o-regula-

    tion decision. Second, rms and consumers will

    undertake the same emissions reduction eorts

    and thereby incur the same emissions reductioncostsin either case, because they ace the same

    carbon price signal.

    Some conusion has emerged regarding these

    points, with some observers suggesting that an up-

    stream program will dilute the carbon price signal,

    because only part o the allowance costs will be

    passed through to downstream emitters. In par-

    ticular, higher uel prices will reduce demand, lead-

    ing producers to moderate their price increases and

    absorb some o the allowance costs themselves.This argument is valid but not unique to upstream

    systems. With a downstream point o regulation,

    ossil uel would in eect become more expensive,

    because emissions sources would be required to sur-

    render valuable allowances. This would reduce their

    demand and lead to the same osetting eect on

    uel prices. Similarly, some critics nd an upstream

    point o regulation counterintuitive, since it does

    not control emissions per se. In act, an upstream

    approach gets at the problem more directly: it caps

    the amount o carbon coming into the system.

    evta ectvss

    An economy-wide cap provides the greatest cer-

    tainty o achieving a given national emissions tar-

    get. Limiting the scope o coverage to a subset o

    emissions sources leads to emissions uncertainty

    through two channels. First, exogenous changes

    in emissions rom unregulated sources can cause

    national emissions to deviate rom expected lev-

    els, even i emissions rom regulated sources meet

    the target.24 Second, a limited scope o coveragecan cause leakage, in which market adjustments

    23. This point was established decades ago in the context o tax policy (Musgrave and Musgrave 1980). However, there are a ew exceptions.For example, the point o regulation will aect the distribution o administrative costs between upstream and downstream entities, al-though, again, these costs would be small relative to the overall cost o a well-designed cap-and-trade system.

    24. For example, the EU ETS covers CO2 emissions rom acilities accounting or about 45 percent o EU greenhouse gas emissions. As aresult, the European Unions ability to meet its Kyoto Protocol target is threatened by signicant growth in transportation sector emis-sions, which are not covered by the ETS (European Environment Agency 2006; see also the online appendix).

  • 8/14/2019 10 Climate Stavins

    21/68

    A U.S. CAp-And-TrAde SySTem To AddreSS GlobAl ClimATe ChAnGe

    www.HAMILTONPROJECT.ORg|

    OCTOBER 2007 1

    resulting rom the regulation lead to increased

    emissions rom unregulated sources outside the

    cap that partially oset reductions under the cap.

    For example, a cap that includes emissions by the

    electric power sector (and thereby aects electric-

    ity prices) but excludes emissions rom natural gasor heating oil use in commercial and residential

    buildings may encourage substitution o unregu-

    lated natural gas or oil heating or electric heating

    in new buildings. As a result, increased emissions

    rom natural gas and oil heating will oset some

    o the reductions achieved in the electric power

    sector.

    Some stakeholders have argued or a downstream

    point o regulation or at least some emissions

    sources.25 I downstream regulation o some acili-ties is allowed, broad coverage o emissions will

    require a hybrid point-o-regulation approach, in

    which some sources are regulated upstream and

    others downstream. As commonly proposed, such

    a hybrid approach would involve upstream pro-

    ducers surrendering allowances or some but not

    all o the uel they sell, depending on whether or

    not the uel is sold to sources subject instead to

    downstream regulation. This approach has two

    signicant problems. First, a hybrid system may

    ail to provide complete coverage. Some emis-sions sources may all through the cracks, covered

    by neither downstream nor upstream regulation.

    Second, there would need to be two classes o

    uel in the market, one or which allowances have

    been surrendered, and one intended or use by

    acilities subject to downstream regulation. This

    would increase administrative complexity and the

    potential or noncompliance.26

    Cst ectvss

    The aggregate costs o emissions reductions un-

    dertaken to meet a cap are directly aected by the

    scope o coverage. Emissions reduction programs

    are subject to economies o scope: costs decline

    more than proportionately as the programs scopeincreases. An upstream point o regulation makes

    economy-wide coverage easible, thus exploiting

    these economies.

    Three actors contribute to these lower costs. First,

    a broader cap expands the pool o low-cost emis-

    sions reduction opportunities that can contribute to

    meeting a national target. Even i a sector may con-

    tribute only a small portion o reductions, includ-

    ing that sector under the cap can yield signicant

    cost savings by displacing the highest-cost reduc-tions that would otherwise be necessary in other

    sectors. For example, it has been estimated that the

    cost o achieving a 5 percent reduction in U.S. CO2

    emissions could be cut in hal under an economy-

    wide cap compared with a cap limited to the electric

    power sector (Pizer et al.2006).

    Second, an economy-wide cap provides important

    fexibility to achieve emissions targets given uncer-

    tainties in emissions reduction costs across sectors.

    By drawing rom a broader, more diverse set oemissions reduction opportunities, an economy-

    wide cap reduces the risk o unexpectedly high

    costs, much as investing in a mutual und reduces

    investment risk through diversication.

    Third, an economy-wide cap creates incentives or

    innovation in all sectors o the economy. Such in-

    novation increases each sectors potential to con-

    25. See, or example, the debates surrounding the development o a cap-and-trade program to implement Caliornias AB 32 (Market Advisory

    Committee 2007; Stavins 2007).26. An alternative approach that may address the objectives o downstream proponents while reducing administrative complexity would be to

    adopt a pure upstream cap-and-trade system as proposed here, but allow certain downstream sourcessuch as electric power generatorsusing CCSto choose downstream regulation. This would be an alternative to the credits or CCS proposed elsewhere in this paper.Under this optional downstream regulation, sources would be granted allowances refecting their uel consumption to oset the eect oupstream regulation on their uel costs, but would be required to surrender allowances or their emissions. Since any sources subject todownstream regulation need to be monitored in any event, this approach would be ar less administratively complex than requiring up-stream sources to determine their allowance requirements or uel supplied based on the identity o the end consumer. To the extent thatthere are real benets o downstream regulation, such an approach could capture some o these benets without sacricing the completecoverage achieved by pure upstream regulation, while minimizing the administrative complexity that usually comes with a hybrid point-o-regulation system.

    http://www.hamiltonproject.org/http://www.hamiltonproject.org/
  • 8/14/2019 10 Climate Stavins

    22/68

    A U.S. CAp-And-TrAde SySTem To AddreSS GlobAl ClimATe ChAnGe

    20 THE HAMILTON PROJECT|

    THE BROOkINgS INSTITUTION

    tribute cost-eective emissions reductions in uture

    years, and the resulting long-run cost savings rom

    starting with a broad scope o coverage may ar ex-

    ceed any short-term gains. In theory, a policy that

    proposes to eventually expand an initially narrow

    scope o coverage might create broad incentivesor innovation. But achieving that subsequent ex-

    pansion would be dicult in practice, given that

    the adjustments that sectors ace upon joining the

    cap will only become greater over time as the caps

    stringency increases. Thus political obstacles to

    expanding the cap may grow over time as the cap

    becomes more stringent.

    The point-o-regulation decision is a primary de-

    terminant o a cap-and-trade systems administra-

    tive costs through its eect on the number o sourc-es that must be regulated. As that number increases,

    the administrative costs to regulators and rms rise.

    The point o regulation should be chosen to acili-

    tate regulation and minimize the administrative

    costs o a desired scope o coverage.27

    An upstream point o regulation makes an econ-

    omy-wide cap-and-trade system administratively

    easible: nearly all U.S. CO2 emissions could be

    capped with regulation o just 2,000 upstream enti-

    ties (Bluestein 2005). It would be administrativelyineasible to implement an economy-wide cap-and-

    trade (or carbon tax) system through downstream

    regulation, as this would require regulation o hun-

    dreds o millions o commercial establishments,

    homes, and vehicles. An upstream program also

    eliminates the regulatory need or acility-level

    greenhouse gas emissions inventories, which would

    be essential or monitoring and enorcing a down-

    stream cap-and-trade system. The ossil uel sales

    o the 2,000 entities to be regulated under the up-

    stream cap-and-trade system are already monitoredand reported to the government or tax and other

    purposes (Table 2). Because monitoring is o little

    use without enorcement, meaningul and credible

    penalties are also important, such as ees set at up

    to ten times marginal abatement costs, plus the

    requirement or rms to make up the dierence.

    Such provisions have resulted in virtually 100 per-

    cent compliance in the case o the SO2 allowance

    trading program (Stavins 1998).

    dstuta Csqucs

    An economy-wide emissions cap spreads the cost

    burden o emissions reductions across all sectors.

    In contrast, limiting the scope o coverage both

    increases the overall cost (as discussed above) and

    concentrates the burden among certain sectors, re-

    gions, and income groups.

    Limiting the scope o coverage may also have unin-

    tended consequences. For example, limiting cover-age to the electric power sector would lead to greater

    electricity rate impacts and more regional variation

    in those impacts than would be anticipated under

    an economy-wide cap. In addition, excluding direct

    emissions rom residential and commercial build-

    ings would alter regional variation in household im-

    pacts because o regional dierences in household

    use o electricity, heating oil, and natural gas.

    ets t Ca-a-Ta Sst

    tat ruc Cst Uctat

    A cap-and-trade system minimizes the cost o

    meeting an emissions target, but emissions reduc-

    tion costs can be greater than anticipated. This risk

    arises because, without mechanisms (described be-

    low) that control costs, regulated sources will have

    to meet the emissions cap regardless o the cost.

    This cost uncertainty is one argument oered in

    avor o a carbon tax, which largely eliminates cost

    uncertainty (but introduces uncertainty about the

    quantity o emissions reduction) by setting thecarbon price at a predetermined level. But policy-

    makers can protect against cost uncertainty under

    a cap-and-trade system, while largely maintaining

    27. The size o the regulated sources also aects aggregate administrative costs. The EU ETS, a downstream scheme, covers approximately11,000 sources, 90 percent o which account or less than 10 percent o total emissions (Ellerman, Buchner, and Carraro 2007). Thequestionable x apparently being devised in that case is a set o less demanding monitoring and verication requirements or smallersources.

  • 8/14/2019 10 Climate Stavins

    23/68

    A U.S. CAp-And-TrAde SySTem To AddreSS GlobAl ClimATe ChAnGe

    www.HAMILTONPROJECT.ORg|

    OCTOBER 2007 21

    certainty over emissions, by adopting a ew key de-

    sign elements: provision or banking and borrow-

    ing o allowances, and possible inclusion o a cost

    containment mechanism.

    T natu Cst Uctat

    Cost uncertainties can arise in an emissions reduc-

    tion scheme rom numerous actors: many advanced

    technologies expected to contribute signicantly to

    achieving emissions reductions have highly uncer-

    tain costs, or their commercial easibility has not yetbeen demonstrated; peoples willingness to adopt

    less emissions-intensive and energy-intensive tech-

    nologies is not well understood; and unanticipated

    events, including uture exogenous changes in en-

    ergy prices or GDP growth, as well as uture politi-

    cal decisions, could signicantly aect the cost o

    meeting emissions reductions targets.

    Concern about cost uncertainty in the context o cap-

    and-trade systems derives rom the possibility o un-

    expected, signicant cost increases. The experiencewith the southern Caliornia RECLAIM cap-and-

    trade system or NOX emissions is a requently cited

    example. RECLAIM had no automatic mechanism

    or relaxing emissions caps in the ace o unexpect-

    edly high costs, and in 2000 allowance prices spiked

    to more than twenty times their historical levels

    (Pizer 2005b).28 Cost uncertainty may increase the

    long-run cost o emissions caps, because uncertainty

    about uture allowance prices may deter rms rom

    undertaking socially desirable but capital-intensive

    emissions reduction investments, orcing greater

    reliance on less capital-intensive but more costly

    measures. Firms acing investments in irreversible

    (sunk) costs require greater returns as uncertaintyabout costs or revenue increases (Dixit and Pin-

    dyck 1994). Furthermore, although the populations

    directly aected by allowance price spikes may be

    relatively small, the higher prices pass through to

    aect the prices o goods and services that are more

    broadly consumed, such as electricity prices in the

    case o RECLAIM or gasoline prices in the case o

    an economy-wide cap on CO2 emissions.

    pvs Awac bakg a

    bwg Allowance banking and borrowing can mitigate

    some o the undesirable consequences o cost un-

    certainty by giving rms the fexibility to shit the

    28. Because electric power generators were part o this cap-and-trade system, these price spikes worsened the developing West Coast electric-ity market crisis (Joskow 2001). Such unexpectedly high costs, even i only temporary, may jeopardize commitments to long-run policygoals. The RECLAIM program, or example, returned electric power generators to standards-based regulation in response to the eco-nomic disruptions that occurred (Harrison 2003; see also the online appendix).

    TAble 2

    Atatv pts rguat a U.S. Ca-a-Ta Sst

    Fss u catg

    pt guat Ca o natua gas

    Upstream Minin and imports

    (500 companies)

    Production ells and

    imports (750 companies)

    Production ells and imports

    (750 companies)

    Midstream Rail, bare, and trucin

    (not addressed)

    Renin (200 reneries) Pipelines and processin

    (200 pipelines, or 1,250 localdistribution companies and500 liquied natural as

    plants)

    Donstream Electric poer plants

    (500 plants)

    Mobile sources, industrial

    boilers, and electric poerplants (millions o sources)

    Industrial boilers, commercial

    and residential urnaces, andelectric poer plants (millionso sources)

    Source: Cambride Enery Research Associates (2006).

    http://www.hamiltonproject.org/http://www.hamiltonproject.org/
  • 8/14/2019 10 Climate Stavins

    24/68

    A U.S. CAp-And-TrAde SySTem To AddreSS GlobAl ClimATe ChAnGe

    22 THE HAMILTON PROJECT|

    THE BROOkINgS INSTITUTION

    timing o emissions reductions in the ace o unex-

    pectedly high or low costs.29 I the cost o achieving

    targets is unexpectedly and temporarily high, rms

    can use banked or borrowed allowances instead o

    undertaking costly reductions. Banking o allow-

    ancesundertaking extra emissions reductions ear-lier, so that more allowances are available or use

    laterhas added greatly to the cost-eectiveness o

    previous cap-and-trade systems (Stavins 2003), but

    banking provides little protection when costs remain

    high or so long that the banked allowances ace ex-

    haustion. This problem may be particularly acute in

    a caps early years, when relatively ew allowances

    have been banked. Borrowing o allowances rom

    uture years allocations can be a particularly useul

    orm o cost protection in these early years.

    Banking oers this cost protection while still guar-

    anteeing achievement o long-run cumulative emis-

    sions targets. Although banking may shit some

    emissions out in time, rom when allowances are

    banked to when they are used, cumulative emis-

    sions at any point can never exceed the number o

    allowances issued up to that point.

    Credible mechanisms need to be established to en-

    sure that borrowed allowances are repaid through

    uture emissions reductions. For example, rmscould be allowed to borrow rom their own uture

    supplies, while entering into a contractualpos-

    sibly bondedagreement with the government to

    repay the borrowed emissions at a subsequent date.

    Or the government could allocate allowances rom

    a uture year to be used this year, decreasing the

    rms uture allocation by the same amount.

    pvs a Ss Cst Ctat

    mcas

    Ultimately the most robust cost control eature o acap-and-trade program is a broad and fuid market

    in allowances. With such a market, osetsdis-

    cussed elsewherecan play a key role in keeping

    costs down. Another issue is cost uncertainty linked

    with short-term allowance price volatility. Banking

    and borrowing can be exceptionally important in

    reducing long-term cost uncertainty, but the pos-sibility o dramatic short-term allowance price

    volatility may call or inclusion o a sensible cost-

    containment mechanism. Such a mechanism could

    allow capped sources to purchase additional allow-

    ances at a predetermined price, set suciently high

    (say, rom twice to ten times the expected level o

    allowance prices, not 10 or 20 percent above) to

    make it unlikely to have any eect unless allowance

    prices exhibit truly drastic spikes. The resulting

    revenue would be dedicated exclusivelyto nanc-

    ing emissions reductions by uncapped sources, suchas o non-CO2 greenhouse gases, or to buy back

    allowances in uture years. This is very dierent

    rom standard proposals or a saety valve, both

    because the environmental integrity o the program

    (the cap) is maintained by using the revenue or the

    specic uses just mentioned, and because the high

    predetermined price has no eect unless there are

    drastic price spikes.

    The predetermined trigger price or the cost-

    containment mechanism would place a ceiling onallowance prices and hence on abatement costs,

    because rms will not undertake emissions reduc-

    tions more costly than the trigger price (Jacoby

    and Ellerman 2002).30 To be eective as an insur-

    ance mechanism, the trigger price should be set

    at the maximum incremental emissions reduction

    cost that society is willing to bear. At this level

    the mechanism would be triggered only when

    costs are unexpectedly and unacceptably high. O

    course, a cost-containment mechanism that is set

    too high would provide no insurance against ex-cessive costs.

    29. All existing cap-and-trade programs have implicit provision or banking and borrowing within the length o their compliance periods: oneyear in the case o the SO2 allowance trading program, and ve years in the case o the Kyoto Protocols commitment periods.

    30. An alternative that would maintain and possibly exceed long-run emissions targets is a complementary allowance price foor, acilitated bya government promise topurchase allowances at a specied price. A price foor ensures achievement o all emissions reduction opportuni-ties below a given cost, which may exceed the amount o reductions necessary to meet the cap. The need or a price foor may decrease,however, with banking.

  • 8/14/2019 10 Climate Stavins

    25/68

    A U.S. CAp-And-TrAde SySTem To AddreSS GlobAl ClimATe ChAnGe

    www.HAMILTONPROJECT.ORg|

    OCTOBER 2007 2

    Importantly, because revenue rom the trigger price

    mechanism would be used to nance emissions re-

    ductions by uncapped sources or to buy back allow-

    ances in uture years, the cost-containment mecha-

    nism would reduce cost uncertainty and increase

    cost-eectiveness, whilesimultaneously maintain-ing environmental eectiveness.

    Acat Awacs

    The cap-and-trade system would create a new com-

    modity, a CO2 allowance, which would have value

    because o its scarcity: only as many allowances

    would be issued as is consistent with the emissions

    target. The government could distribute allow-

    ances or ree or auction them. This proposal rec-

    ommends an allowance allocation mechanism thatcombines auctions with ree distribution, with auc-

    tions becoming more important over time.

    The aggregate value o allowances in a nationwide

    system would be substantial. Indeed, i all allow-

    ances are auctioned, annual auction receipts would

    amount to a signicant share o ederal revenue.31

    For rms needing to buy auctioned allowances, total

    allowance costs would signicantly exceed the cost

    o emissions reductions that would meet a modest

    cap. The reason is that under an economy-wideemissions cap that reduces nationwide emissions by

    5 percent, or example, regulated rms would incur

    costs associated with reducing those emissions but

    would have to purchase allowances or the remain-

    ing 95 percent o their emissions.

    The magnitude o these rm-level costs indicates

    that the choice o allocation method (auctioning

    versusree distribution) and the use o auction reve-

    nue can have important distributional implications.

    By contrast, the allocation choice does not aect

    the achievement o the emissions targets, andasemphasized abovethe allocation issue is inde-

    pendent o the point o regulation. Indeed, since

    alternative points o regulation lead to the same

    ultimate distribution o economic burdens, there is

    no economic rationale or tying allocation choices

    to the point o regulation. For example, under an

    upstream cap, it would be possible to distribute al-

    lowances or ree to downstream energy-intensive

    industries that are aected by the cap even though

    they are not directly regulated by it. This is one

    approach to compensating those industries or theimpact o a climate policy, since they could then

    sell the allowances to rms directly regulated under

    the cap.

    T Cc btw Auct a F

    dstut: ova Cst Ccs

    Beyond the distributional consequences o alloca-

    tion decisions, the choice o whether allowances

    will be auctioned or distributed or ree can aect

    the programs overall cost. Generally speaking, the

    choice between auctioning and allocating allowanc-es or ree does not infuence rms production and

    emissions reduction decisions.32 Firms ace the same

    emissions cost regardless o the allocation method.

    Even when it uses an allowance that it received or

    ree, a rm loses the opportunity to sell that allow-

    ance and thus incurs an opportunity cost.

    31. Under the economy-wide program proposed here, annual auction revenue (i all allowances were auctioned) would exceed $100 billion,compared with ederal net tax revenue in scal year 2006 o $351 billion rom the corporation income tax, $994 billion rom the individualincome tax, and $810 billion rom employment taxes (U.S. Energy Inormation Administration 2006b).

    32. Two exceptions are allocations to regulated utilities (discussed below) and updating allocations. I allowances are reely allocated, the

    allocation should be on the basis o some historical measure or measures, not on the basis o measures that rms can infuence. Updatingallocations, which involve periodically adjusting allocations over time to refect changes in rms operations, violate this principle. For ex-ample, an output-based updating allocation ties the quantity o allowances that a rm receives to its output. This distorts rms pricing andproduction decisions in ways that can introduce unintended consequences and can signicantly increase the cost o meeting an emissionstarget. Selective use o updating allocations has nevertheless been recommended by some to preserve industry competitiveness and reduceemissions leakage in sec