© 2009 jiaoju ge

142
1 BARGAINING BETWEEN COOPERATIVES AND PROCESSORS: A MODELING AND EMPIRICAL STUDY IN FLORIDA DAIRY INDUSTRY By JIAOJU GE A DISSERTATION PRESENTED TO THE GRADUATE SCHOOL OF THE UNIVERSITY OF FLORIDA IN PARTIAL FULFILLMENT OF THE REQUIREMENTS FOR THE DEGREE OF DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY UNIVERSITY OF FLORIDA 2009

Upload: others

Post on 24-Dec-2021

4 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

1

BARGAINING BETWEEN COOPERATIVES AND PROCESSORS: A MODELING AND EMPIRICAL STUDY IN FLORIDA DAIRY INDUSTRY

By

JIAOJU GE

A DISSERTATION PRESENTED TO THE GRADUATE SCHOOL OF THE UNIVERSITY OF FLORIDA IN PARTIAL FULFILLMENT

OF THE REQUIREMENTS FOR THE DEGREE OF DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY

UNIVERSITY OF FLORIDA

2009

2

© 2009 Jiaoju Ge

3

To the most important loved ones in my life: my husband, Qiyong; my son, Michael; and my daughter, Sarah.

4

ACKNOWLEDGMENTS

First, I express my deepest appreciation to all my committee, Dr. Richard L. Kilmer, Dr.

Alfonso Flores-Lagunes, Dr. Lisa House, Dr. Thomas Spreen and Dr. Lawrence Kenny.

Foremost, I would like to gratefully express my sincere gratitude to my committee chair,

Dr. Richard L. Kilmer, for his generous guidance and encouragement. I was very fortunate to

work with him and learned much invaluable knowledge from him. I would like to express my

deepest appreciation to him for his thorough review of the manuscript and patience to

successfully complete my study.

I am also very grateful to Dr. Alfonso Flores-Lagunes for guiding me through the

econometric knowledge of disequilibrium model and the method of Expectation Maximization

algorithm. I sincerely thank him for providing me with invaluable comments and suggestions for

me to complete this dissertation.

I am very appreciative of the support I received from Dr. Lisa House and thank her for

providing me the comments and suggestions.

Many thanks must also go to the other members of my supervisory committee, Dr. Thomas

Spreen and Dr. Lawrence Kenny. Thank them all for their support and guidance, ,comments and

suggestions.

I would also like to thank Dr. Charles Moss, Dr. Ronald Ward for their generous help and

suggestions, thank for my fellow graduate students in the Food and Resource Economics

Department, Ledia Guci and Xinxin Zhang, for their support and suggestions, and all other

fellow students for all the unforgettable memories.

I thank my families, especially my mom for her support for me to finishing my

dissertation. Finally, the greatest thank you goes to my husband, Qiyong Xu, for his

understanding, encouragement and love.

5

TABLE OF CONTENTS

page

ACKNOWLEDGMENTS.................................................................................................................... 4

LIST OF TABLES................................................................................................................................ 8

LIST OF FIGURES .............................................................................................................................. 9

ABSTRACT ........................................................................................................................................ 10

CHAPTER

1 INTRODUCTION, PROBLEM STATEMENT AND OBJECTIVES ................................... 11

1.1 Introduction ........................................................................................................................... 11 1.2 Problem Statement ................................................................................................................ 12 1.3 Objectives .............................................................................................................................. 12 1.4 Overview of the Study .......................................................................................................... 13

2 LITERATURE REVIEW ........................................................................................................... 14

2.1 Introduction ........................................................................................................................... 14 2.2 Bargaining Theory ................................................................................................................ 14

2.2.1 Introduction................................................................................................................. 14 2.2.2 Bilateral Bargaining ................................................................................................... 16

2.2.2.1 Axiomatic approach model ............................................................................. 16 2.2.2.2 Strategic approach model ................................................................................ 19 2.2.2.3 Summary of bilateral bargaining theory......................................................... 34

2.2.3 Multilateral Bargaining .............................................................................................. 35 2.2.3.1 Axiomatic approach ......................................................................................... 35 2.2.3.2 Strategic approach ........................................................................................... 36 2.2.3.3 Solution approximation of strategic approach to axiomatic approach ......... 37 2.2.3.4 Summary of multilateral bargaining theory ................................................... 39

2.2.4 Bargaining Theory Summary .................................................................................... 40 2.3 Distribution Channels Bargaining Theory........................................................................... 41

2.3.1 Introduction................................................................................................................. 41 2.3.2 Supply Chain Bargaining ........................................................................................... 41 2.3.3 Cooperative Bargaining ............................................................................................. 43 2.3.4 Distribution Channel Bargaining Theory Summary ................................................ 47

2.4 Bargaining Model Applications ........................................................................................... 47 2.4.1 Model Applications .................................................................................................... 47 2.4.2 Bargaining Model Applications Summary ............................................................... 52

6

2.5 Summary, Conclusions and Discussions ............................................................................. 53 2.5.1 Summary ..................................................................................................................... 53 2.5.2 Conclusions and Discussions..................................................................................... 54

2.6 Relevant Information For Model Developing Next Chapter ............................................. 56

3 THE THEORETICAL MODEL ................................................................................................ 59

3.1 Building Model ..................................................................................................................... 59 3.1.1 Bilateral Model with Risk of Breakdown ................................................................. 59 3.1.2 Bilateral Model with Risk of Breakdown and Outside Options .............................. 60 3.1.3 Bilateral Model with Risk of Breakdown and Outside Options between A

Cooperative and Processor .............................................................................................. 61 3.2 Model Solution ...................................................................................................................... 62

3.2.1 Case 1: Outside Option Prices are Variable ............................................................. 63 3.2.2 Case 2: Outside Option Prices are Fixed .................................................................. 72 3.2.3 Case 3: One Outside Option Price is fixed and The Other Outside Option

Price is Variable ............................................................................................................... 74 3.2.4 Summary of Model Solution ..................................................................................... 75

4 THE EMPIRICAL MODEL....................................................................................................... 77

4.1 Florida Milk Industry ............................................................................................................ 77 4.2 The Econometric Model ....................................................................................................... 79 4.3 Discussion of The Exogenous Variables ............................................................................. 82 4.4 Data Description ................................................................................................................... 85 4.5 Model Estimation .................................................................................................................. 86 4.6 Summary................................................................................................................................ 91

5 RESULTS .................................................................................................................................... 93

5.1 Summary Statistics................................................................................................................ 93 5.2 Parameter Estimates .............................................................................................................. 94 5.3 Bargaining Power Parameter ................................................................................................ 98 5.4 Variance Covariance ........................................................................................................... 101

6 SUMMARY, CONCLUSIONS AND IMPLICATIONS ....................................................... 103

6.1 Summary.............................................................................................................................. 103 6.2 Conclusions ......................................................................................................................... 105 6.3 Implications ......................................................................................................................... 107 6.4 Further Researches .............................................................................................................. 107

APPENDIX

A CALCULATION OF THE NEGOTIATED QUANTITY Q ................................................. 109

B DATA ........................................................................................................................................ 122

7

C GAUSS PROGRAM ................................................................................................................. 130

D TAO TESTING ......................................................................................................................... 134

LIST OF REFERENCES ................................................................................................................. 138

BIOGRAPHICAL SKETCH ........................................................................................................... 142

8

LIST OF TABLES

Table page 4-1 Florida Milk Processor Plants ............................................................................................... 78

4-2 Monthly SDC Non-Florida Cooperative members .............................................................. 79

5-1 Summary Statistics of Data ................................................................................................... 93

5-2 Correlation Matrix of Data .................................................................................................... 94

5-3 Coefficient Estimates ............................................................................................................. 96

5-4 Monthly Bargaining Power Coefficient Estimates for SDC and Processors ..................... 98

5-5 Yearly Bargaining Power Coefficient Estimates for SDC and Processors....................... 100

5-6 Test Result for Zero Covariance ......................................................................................... 102

B-1 Data(1) .................................................................................................................................. 122

B-2 Data(2) .................................................................................................................................. 126

B-1 Testing Results for Maximum Bargaining Power for SDC in Year 2008 ........................ 134

B-2 Testing Results for Minimum Bargaining Power for SDC in Year 2001......................... 135

B-3 Testing Results for Maximum Bargaining Power for SDC in April................................. 136

B-4 Testing Results for Minimum Bargaining Power for SDC in November ........................ 137

9

LIST OF FIGURES

Figure page 5-1 SDC’s Monthly Bargaining Power Coefficient and Over-order Premium....................... 101

10

Abstract of Dissertation Presented to the Graduate School of the University of Florida in Partial Fulfillment of the Requirements for the Degree of Doctor of Philosophy

BARGAINING BETWEEN COOPERATIVES AND PROCESSORS: A MODELING AND

EMPIRICAL STUDY IN FLORIDA DAIRY INDUSTRY

By

Jiaoju Ge

December 2009 Chair: Richard L. Kilmer Major: Food and Resources Economics

The Florida dairy market has a few fluid milk processors and many dairy farmers. The

dairy farmers are represented in negotiation with the processors by a cooperative. This

dissertation builds a theoretical model for bargaining between the processors and a cooperative

with outside options and risk of breakdown. The model is applied to the Florida dairy market to

examine price negotiations between Florida milk processors and a dairy cooperative. Time series

data was collected for the period of October 1998 to May 2009. An expectation maximization

(EM) algorithm along with Maximum Likelihood Estimation was used to analyze the

econometric disequilibrium model empirically in Gauss statistical software.

The results show that the class I price set by the Federal Milk Marketing Order is the major

factor influencing the processors’ demand reservation price. Negotiated quantity and production

seasonality affect the cooperative’s supply reservation price. The cooperative appears to be more

patient and has higher average bargaining power (0.7055) than the bargaining power for

processors (0.2945). The highest (lowest) bargaining power for the cooperative (processors)

occured in 2008 and the lowest (highest) bargaining power for the cooperative (processors)

occurred in both 2001 and 2004.

11

CHAPTER 1 INTRODUCTION, PROBLEM STATEMENT AND OBJECTIVES

1.1 Introduction

Food processors are generally large and few in number due to economies of size (Durham

and Sexton, 1992). However, large numbers of independent farmers are small which put

processors at an advantage over individual farmers when contracts are negotiated. Thus,

marketing cooperatives were established to give individual farmers a better bargaining position

with processors (Jesse, et al., 1982). Florida’s milk marketing cooperative was established to

represent Florida dairy farmers and negotiate the price of fluid milk with Florida dairy

processors.

The objective of the milk marketing cooperative is to maximize the profit of cooperative

members (farmers) (Iyer and Villas-boas, 2003, Nagarajan and Bassok, 2002, Oczkowski, 1999,

Oczkowski, 1991, Oczkowski, 2006). For a given quantity of milk supplied by farmers, the price

paid by processors decides the net revenue for farmers. Thus, a milk marketing cooperative

would prefer to negotiate with processors and receive a high price.

This negotiated fluid milk price includes (1) the class 1 (fluid milk) price and (2) the over-

order premium. The class 1 price is set monthly by the federal milk marketing order which

means it is exogenous to the bargaining process. This implies that the higher the over-order

premium, the higher the negotiated price. Therefore, dairy farmers and their cooperative would

prefer a high over-order premium and the processors would prefer a low over-order premium.

Thus, the interesting question becomes what factors affect the negotiated price (class 1 price plus

over-order premium). While the milk cooperative and milk processor bargain over the over-order

premium, some other milk cooperatives and processors outside of the state of Florida exist and

they might provide a better offer for either the Florida milk cooperative or Florida milk

12

processor. Thus, when outside offers are accepted, the negotiation process between the Florida

milk cooperative and the Florida milk processor breaks down.

In Florida, there exist several milk processors. However, when it comes to negotiating with

the milk cooperative for the fluid milk price, the biggest milk processor generally represents all

milk processors. Thus, the Florida milk cooperative and the Florida milk processor can be treated

as a monopoly and monopsony organization. Nash indicates that “The economic situation of

monopoly versus monopsony may be regarded as a bargaining problem.” (Nash 1950).

1.2 Problem Statement

The problem to be examined in this study is what factors affect the negotiated price

between milk cooperatives and milk processors when outside options are available for both sides.

1.3 Objectives

The general objective of this study is to understand the factors that influence the bargaining

process between the dairy cooperatives and the milk processors. Specific objectives are listed

below:

1. To do a comprehensive literature review on bargaining theory, its applications, and estimating disequilibrium models;

2. To develop a theoretic bargaining model with two-side outside options and risk of breakdown;

3. To develop a disequilibrium econometric model and collect the data needed;

4. To specify and estimate the model including the demand reservation price equation, the supply reservation price equation, the negotiated price equation, and the bargaining power parameter equation in order to examine how they are affected by different factors;

5. To examine and interpret the factors that affect the demand reservation price, the supply reservation price, the negotiated price and the bargaining power parameter;

6. To summarize the results and draw conclusions and implications from the results.

13

1.4 Overview of the Study

Chapter 2 is the literature review chapter on bargaining theory and applications which

provide all the information needed for developing a theoretical bargaining model. There are three

categories of literature including (1) bargaining theory, (2) distribution channel theory, and (3)

bargaining model applications.

A general bargaining model is developed in chapter 3 with outside options and risk of

breakdown. Three cases are discussed including (1) the case of variable outside option

bargaining price, (2) the case of fixed outside option price, and (3) the case where one player

accepts a fixed outside option price and the other player’s outside option price is variable.

An empirical disequilibrium econometric model is developed in chapter 4 for bargaining

between a milk cooperative and Florida milk processors. Associated econometric literature will

be reviewed. The Expectation Maximization method is used to estimate the empirical model. The

data needed will be identified.

The model will be estimated in chapter 5 and the results of the econometric model will be

presented. Chapter 6 provides a summary, conclusions and implications.

14

CHAPTER 2 LITERATURE REVIEW

2.1 Introduction

In Florida, the milk cooperative and the milk processors can be treated as a monopsony

and monopoly structure during bargaining. The price negotiation process between milk

cooperatives and milk processors is complicated. Nash indicates that “The economic situation of

monopoly versus monopsony may be regarded as bargaining problem.” (Nash, 1950). Thus this

price determination process is complicated and can be captured through the negotiation process

by using bargaining theory.

The purpose of this chapter is to review the literature associated with the bargaining

problem and its application to bargaining between a milk cooperative and the Florida milk

processors. Three major areas of past literature will be reviewed and discussed. The first area is

the development and the history of bargaining theory. The second area is the distribution channel

bargaining theory, which is concentrated on cooperative theory development in the bargaining

area. The third area is the application of bargaining theory including the empirical econometric

works of bargaining models.

2.2 Bargaining Theory

“Bargaining is any process through which the players on their own try to reach an

agreement” (Muthoo, 1999). In my research, bargaining refers to the price negotiation process

between milk cooperatives and milk processors.

2.2.1 Introduction

Bargaining theory has caught people’s eyes ever since 1950, when John Nash published

his famous work containing a bilateral bargaining solution by using the axiomatic approach

(Nash, 1950). The axiomatic approach can be defined as the approach of analyzing bargaining

15

behavior to have a unique solution based on a series of axiomatic assumptions. This bargaining

solution is called a symmetric Nash bargaining solution. Then, Roth (Roth, 1979) followed the

same axiomatic approach, but generalized the symmetric Nash bargaining solution to the

asymmetric Nash bargaining solution, which is called the generalized Nash bargaining solution.

However, this axiomatic approach has overlooked the complexity of the negotiation

process, which might have an unexpected effect on the bargaining solution. This motivated the

appearance of the other approach which is called the strategic approach. In 1982, Rubinstein first

proposed a two person alternating offer model (Rubinstein, 1982) by using the strategic

approach. The strategic approach can be thought of as an approach to find the bargaining

solution taking into consideration the strategies each player would use at each negotiation stage.

Roth (Roth, 1985) then added the risk component to Rubinstein’s strategic alternating model.

By 1986, people paid attention to the relationship between the above two approaches. One

article (Binmore, et al., 1986) examined this relationship and suggested that the solution of the

strategic approach approximates the Nash bargaining solution if the negotiation time goes to zero

in each bargaining period.

In the 1990s, more articles studied bargaining theory by adding new components into the

bilateral bargaining model, such as risk and outside options (Muthoo, 1999, Muthoo, 1995) to the

bilateral bargaining model. Furthermore, additional work has been done on a n-player bargaining

model (Chae and Yang, 1988, Jun, 1987, Nagarajan and Bassok, 2002, Schneider, 2005, Suh and

Wen, 2006). In this case, some authors tried to reduce the n-player game to a multi-stage game

with bilateral bargaining at each stage (Nagarajan and Bassok, 2002) where the first stage is to

form a coalition on the supply side and a coalition on the demand side and the second stage is the

bilateral bargaining between the supply side coalition and the demand side coalition. Other

16

authors reduced the game to a series of bilateral bargaining sessions (Chae and Yang, 1994, Chae

and Yang, 1988, Jun, 1987, Suh and Wen, 2006). The direct n-player game with risk and outside

option components is still developing.

2.2.2 Bilateral Bargaining

Napel (Napel, 2002)pointed out that economically, bilateral bargaining is a situation

where two agents have a common interest in cooperating to get joint payoffs, but conflicting

interests in the process of how to reach the cooperation and how to divide the payoffs. In my

research, bilateral bargaining refers to milk price bargaining between two monopolies (one milk

processor and one milk cooperative) for the purpose of cooperating to obtain a market solution

and dividing the joint profits. The development of bilateral bargaining has been the major field in

bargaining theory development history, probably because of the interesting monopoly power

between two parties. Both the axiomatic approach and the strategic approach have the theory

developed in bilateral bargaining.

2.2.2.1 Axiomatic approach model

The standard economic bargaining model uses the axiomatic Nash (Nash, 1950)

equilibrium concept. For any bargaining game, as Rubinstein et al.(Rubinstein, et al., 1992)

pointed out, this unique Nash bargaining solution can be represented by the following function

N, defined as

both for and ),())(max(arg),( 212211 iduSuudududSN ii ≥∈−−= (2-1)

where N is the Nash bargaining solution; S is the feasible bargaining solution set; d is the

disagreement point; arg max represents the maximization through logical discussion; u1 and d1

are utility representation for party 1 at the agreement point and the disagreement point,

respectively; u2 and d2 are the utility representation for party 2 at the agreement point and the

17

disagreement point, respectively. This Nash bargaining solution is a unique solution satisfying

the following four axioms:

1.(IAT) Invariance to positive affine transformations: The solution is invariant to all independent person-by-person, positive affine transformations of utilities.

2.(SYM) Symmetry: If the set S is symmetric with respect to the main diagonal and if d1 = d2, then the solution should assign equal utilities to both players.

3.(PAR) Pareto Optimality: There is no point in S which Pareto-dominates the solution outcome.

4.(IIA) Independence of irrelevant alternatives.(Muthoo, 1999)

The first axiom of IAT implies that the bargaining outcome does not rely on the calibration

of player’s utilities (Binmore, 1992), or in other words that the bargaining outcome is based on

the player’s preferences, not the utility representation of them (Muthoo, 1999). This axiom seems

reasonable from Muthoo’s view. For example, if the utility representations for both players are

multiplied by a scale, the new bargaining outcome should be the old bargaining outcome

multiplied by a scale .

The second axiom SYM concerns a symmetric bargaining problem and suggests that both

players should get the same bargaining outcome. This axiom is feasible as long as both parties

choose to cooperate. For example, under a strike, a labor bargaining agreement is not reached

implying that both parties are not cooperating, then the outcome for both parties is not

symmetric.

The third axiom PAR explains that there is no other bargaining outcome that is preferred

by both players to this unique Nash bargaining solution because both parties are playing the

game in a rational way. Finally, the last axiom IIA says that if both parties agree on the payoff

set S while another payoff set T is feasible, they should never agree on T (Binmore, 1992). This

axiom indicates that the disagreement point for both parties should be the same.

18

Similarly, Muthoo (Muthoo, 1999) used the following optimization model and showed us

the same conclusion such that the Nash bargaining solution is the unique solution to the

following maximization problem based on the above four axioms as

))(( max)( ,

BBAAuududuN

bA

−−=Θ∈

(2-2)

where , and ),( BBAABA duduSuu ≥≥∈≡Θ , N is the maximization problem; uA, uB, S, dA

and dB are defined the same as above. Now, we can solve the problem mathematically rather than

logically as discussed above in equation (2-1).

However, Nash (1950) suggests that the symmetry assumption needs to be reconsidered.

Since the symmetric axiom might not be feasible for all games, asymmetric Nash economic

bargaining models were developed. Binmore ((Binmore 1992), p.180-195) discussed the

asymmetric Nash bargaining solution by introducing the bargaining power parameter for both

players. The same result is shown by Muthoo. Muthoo (1999) explains that the bargaining

solution may be affected by many other factors, such as the tactics used by the bargainers, or the

negotiation procedure, which results in asymmetric power for the participating parties. Thus, for

a given value which is defined as bargaining power, a generalized or an asymmetric Nash

bargaining solution is a unique solution of the maximization problem

ττ −−−= 1

),()()( max BBAAUU

duduNBA

(2-3)

as long as all but the symmetric axiom is satisfied (Muthoo, 1999). When 5.0=τ , this

asymmetric Nash’s bargaining solution is equivalent to the symmetric Nash bargaining solution.

Regarding the economics of bargaining, the symmetric Nash bargaining solution, when

joint profits are maximized, results in a single transacted price which is half way between the

demand reservation price and the supply reservation price if both parties are assumed to seek

maximized profits ((Oczkowski 2004), p. 6). Roth (Roth 1979) shows that the difference

19

between the symmetric and the asymmetric Nash bargaining solution is that the negotiated price

for the asymmetric Nash equilibrium falls between the demand reservation price and the supply

reservation price instead of at the half way point. This is determined by the relative bargaining

power of the parties.

2.2.2.2 Strategic approach model

The axiomatic approach discussed above has certain disadvantages when exploring the

details of the bargaining process. Thus, another approach called the strategic approach appeared

in the early 1980s. It was introduced by Rubinstein (Rubinstein, 1982).

2.2.2.2.1 Basic strategic approach alternating offer model: In 1982, Rubinstein wrote

an article on the pure game theory of bargaining for a two player game. It allowed the Nash

equilibrium to be combined with the complexity of the negotiation process. The bilateral

bargaining model in Rubinstein’s article assumes that one player makes an offer, and then the

other player accepts the offer reaching the agreement or rejects the offer and makes another

offer. Negotiation continues until the agreement is reached. Rationality and complete

information of preferences are also assumed for both players.

Rubinstein’s model described two players who are bargaining on the partition of a pie

which is represented by s, a number in the unit interval. That is, the portion of the pie player 1

receives is 1s and the portion of the pie player 2 receives is 12 1 ss −= . Rubinstein defined t as the

bargaining period. The outcome function of this alternating bilateral bargaining model is defined

as

∞=∞∞<

=T(f,g)T(f,g)gfTgfD

gfP ),,0(

)),,(),,((),( (2-4)

20

where ),( gfP is the outcome function; f is the set of all strategies of the player who starts the

bargaining by making an offer; g is the set of all strategies of the player who in the first move has

to respond to the offer; ),( gfD is the partition induced by ),( gf ; and ),( gfT is the length of

the sequence of offers. Thus, the outcome ),( ts represents reaching the agreement s in

bargaining period t; and ),0( ∞ suggests a permanent disagreement. Then, the ordered pair

),(∧∧

gf is a Nash equilibrium if there is no f such that ),(),(∧∧∧

> gfPgfP or no g such

that ),(),(∧∧∧

> gfPgfP . In other words, there is no outcome that is preferred by either player 1 or

2 except the equilibrium offer.

Rubinstein’s model shows how the results of the existing perfect Nash equilibrium are

different from the axiomatic approach model by looking at two different cases. First, bargaining

costs are fixed for each player in each bargaining period and second, a case where the discount

factor is fixed for each player. For the case of the fixed bargaining cost models, each player i has

a number of fixed bargaining costs ic such that ),(),( 21 tsts ≥ if and only if

),()( 21 tcstcs iiii −≥⋅− where s and s are the portion of the pie received by player 1 and 2 and

1t and 2t represent the negotiation time period, then the perfect equilibrium (P.E.) is:

1.If 21 cc > , 2c is the only P.E..

2. If 21 cc = , every 11 ≤≤ xc is a P.E..

3.If 21 cc < , 1 is the only P.E.. (Rubinstein, 1982)

where x is an offer associated with each strategy that the player chooses to play; player 1 accepts

the offer 2c when 21 cc > ; player 1 accepts the offer between 1c and the entire negotiated pie

when 21 cc = ; and player 1 accepts the offer of the entire negotiated pie when 21 cc < .

21

For the case of the fixed discount factor models Rubinstein shows that, each player i has

a number of discount factors 10 ≤< iδ such that the outcome ),(),( 21 tsts ≥ if and only

if 21 tii

tii ss δδ ≥ , then if at least one of the discount factors is strictly less than 1 and at least one of

them is strictly positive, the only P.E. is )1/()1( 212 δδδ −− .

Later, Muthoo (Muthoo, 1999) explains this alternating Rubinstein strategic approach

model with more mathematical detail and shows the results at the limit. Two players, A and B,

bargain over a partition of a cake size of π (π >0). At time 0, A makes an offer. Then if B

accepts the offer, the agreement is reached; if B rejects the offer, B will make a counteroffer at

time period ∆ (∆>0), and A will make a decision on either to accept or reject. If A rejects the

offer, player A makes a counter offer to B at time period ∆2 . This process continues until an

agreement is reached. Muthoo defines ix as a share of the cake for player i when the agreement is

reached, where π≤≤ ix0 . Then, given the discount rate )0( >ii rr for player i, the payoff for

player i is )exp( ∆−⋅ trx ii where ,...2,1,0=t . For simplicity, the discount factor )exp( ∆−≡ triiδ is

defined. Notice that 10 << iδ . Thus, player i’s payoff at the agreement point is iix δ . Notice that

if perpetual disagreement occurs, and then each player’s payoff is zero.

Muthoo indicates that this subgame perfect equilibrium outcome, denoted by *ix , should

satisfy the following two properties:

1.(No Delay). Whenever a player has to make an offer, her equilibrium offer is accepted by the other offer.

2.(Stationarity).In equilibrium, a player makes the same offer whenever she has to make an offer. (Muthoo, 1999)

22

Given these two properties, the subgame perfect equilibrium of this alternating offer game is a

unique payoff set, ),( **BA xx , for player A and B, respectively. Muthoo shows that the equilibrium

can be solved from the following equations

**BBA xx δπ =− (2-5)

**AAB xx δπ =− (2-6)

where

πδδδ

BA

BAx

−−

=1

1* (2-7)

πδδδ

BA

ABx

−−

=1

1* . (2-8)

In the limit as 0→∆ ,

BA

B

BA

B

BA

B

BA

B

BA

BA

rrr

rrr

rrr

rrrx

+=

∆+∆

=∆+−−

∆−−→

∆+−−∆−−

=−−

=

)())(1(1)1(1

))(exp(1)exp(1

11*

δδδ

(2-9)

BA

A

BA

A

BA

A

BA

A

BA

AB

rrr

rrr

rrr

rrrx

+=

∆+∆

=∆+−−

∆−−→

∆+−−∆−−

=−−

=

)())(1(1)1(1

))(exp(1)exp(1

11*

δδδ

. (2-10)

Equations (2-9) and (2-10) show that the unique equilibrium outcome set ),( **BA xx depends on the

relative discount rate between two players. When, BA rr / gets bigger, the equilibrium outcome

for player A ( *Ax ) decreases and the equilibrium outcome for player B ( *

Bx ) increases. This

means that the equilibrium outcome for the player who faces a higher discount rate is smaller

than the equilibrium outcome for the player who faces a lower discount rate. Notice that as

0→∆ , the discount factor for both players goes to unity.

23

From the result of Rubinstein’s model (equation 2-4) and Muthoo’s result (equation (2-7)

and (2-8)), they reach the same conclusion such that the unique subgame perfect equilibrium

exists and the outcome for player 1 and 2 is )1/()1( 212 δδδ −− , or )1/()1( 211 δδδ −− multiplied

by the bargaining cake π , respectively.

Based on the above basic strategic approach alternating offer bargaining model, other

perspectives of the model are discussed. Some authors discuss the risk of breakdown of the

model, such as Roth (Roth, 1985), Binmore, etal. (Binmore, et al., 1986), and Muthoo (Muthoo,

1999). Others discuss the outside option of the model, such as Muthoo (Muthoo, 1995), Ponsati

and Sakovics (Ponsati and Sakovics, 1998), and Muthoo (Muthoo, 1999). Even later, this

bilateral alternating offer bargaining model has been extended to the multilateral bargaining

level, which will be reviewed in the multilateral bargaining section.

2.2.2.2.2 Strategic approach alternating offer model with risk of breakdown: For the

risk component of the bargaining model, Roth (Roth, 1985) had a note on risk aversion at perfect

equilibrium in the Rubinstein bilateral alternating offer bargaining model. Roth pointed out that

the more risk averse the party is, the smaller share at equilibrium the party has. Roth explains the

effect of risk by replacing one player i with a risk averse player *i in the original alternating

offer fixed discount factor model, but keeps the other player unchanged. Recall that it was

discussed above, *x is the equilibrium share (for the first move player) of the cake. Now, we

introduce )2 ,2 ;1 ,1, ( ),,( **=jijix representing the share but measured by commodities rather

than utility so that the share ),( jix can be compared directly. Thus, if player 1 is replaced by *1 ,

then the equilibrium share for the first move player 1 or *1 can be represented

by )2,1(x or )2,1( *x , respectively. Similarly, if player 2 is replaced by *2 , then the equilibrium

24

share for the second move player 2 or *2 can be represented by ( )2,1(1 x− ) or ( )2,1(1 *x− ),

respectively. Roth proved the theorem such that

)2,1()2,1()2,1( ** xxx ≤≤ . (2-11)

For the part of )2,1()2,1( * xx ≤ , it suggests that for the same bargaining game, if player 1 is

replaced with a risk averse player *1 , the equilibrium share is smaller for the risk averse player *1 .

For the part of )2,1()2,1( *xx ≤ , it implies that )2,1(1)2,1(1 *xx −≥− , which says that for the same

bargaining game, if player 2 is replaced with a risk averse player *2 (player 1 is no longer risk

averse), the equilibrium share is smaller for the risk averse player *2 . Thus, Roth concludes that

the more risk averse player gets the smaller share than the less risk averse player does. Roth

discussed the concept of risk such that for both the axiomatic approach models and the strategic

approach models, the risk is the bargainers’ subjective probability of failing to reach an

agreement. In other words, if a breakdown in the negotiation process occurs, then an agreement

is not reached.

Later, Binmore, Rubinstein and Wolinsky (Binmore, et al., 1986) present a strategic

model (Rubinstein’s alternating offer bilateral model discussed above) and add the risk of

breakdown(failing to reach an agreement). They use probability to represent the risk of

breakdown and showe the utility maximization problem mathematically. Binmore, Rubinstein

and Wolinsky assume that the time of the breakdown is exponentially distributed with a

parameter λ such that the risk of breakdown in each bargaining period can be presented by a

positive probability

)exp(1)( ∆−−=∆= λpp (2-12)

where for each bargaining period of length∆ , there is p probability that the bargaining process

will breakdown. Binmore, Rubinstein and Wolinsky assume that the outcome is b at the point of

25

breakdown. Recall that in Rubinstein’s basic model discussed above, x is the outcome when the

agreement is reached. Thus, Binmore, Rubinstein and Wolinsky suggest that the outcome for this

bargaining game is shown below as

bpxpO tt ))1(1()1( −−+−= (2-13)

where O represents expected offer; t is defined the same as the time period. Binmore, Rubinstein

and Wolinsky also point out that if ordered preference is assumed, then the utility outcome of

this bargaining model can be represented as

)())1(1()()1( bupxupEU it

it −−+−= (2-14)

where EU represents expected utility; )(xui and )(bui are defined as the utility pair at the

agreement point and the disagreement point, respectively. The above results imply that the

outcome for each player in the strategic model with risk of breakdown is the expected utility.

Then some years later, Muthoo (Muthoo, 1999) showed the same strategic bilateral

model with risk of breakdown by defining the probability a different way. Muthoo explained that

the potential cause of the risk of breakdown is that players might just walk away from the

negotiation table or the intervention by a third party occurs. The model discussed by Muthoo

shows that the equilibrium payoffs for both players are heavily affected by the degree of risk

aversion when negotiation breaks down.

The model is based on Rubinstein’ alternating offer bargaining model discussed above.

Player A and B bargain over the partition of a cake size π . At any time period ∆t , the probability

that the negotiation breaks down is p (where 0<p<1), and then 1-p represents the probability that

the bargaining proceeds to time period ∆+ )1( t . Muthoo assumes that as 0→∆ , 0→p (Recall

that )exp(1 ∆−−= tp so that p goes to zero when ∆goes to zero). Let ix be defined as the payoff

(share of the cake) for the first move player when the agreement is reached, then ix−1 is the

26

payoff for the second move player. Let ib be the payoff for both players at the breakdown point,

then Muthoo called this payoff pair ),( BA bb as the impasse point. Muthoo suggests that the

unique subgame perfect equilibrium with risk averse players is the solution to the following two-

equation system

)()1()( **BBBAB xUppbxU −+=−π (2-15)

)()1()( **AAABA xUppbxU −+=−π (2-16)

where BU and AU are the utility outcomes from this bargaining game; *Ax−π and *

Bx−π are the

outcome cake share; p is the overall probability that negotiation breaks down; 1-p is the overall

probability when the agreement is reached; Bb and Ab are the payoffs at the disagreement point;

*Bx and *

Ax are the payoff cake shares when the agreement is reached for player B and A,

respectively.

As we can see, all the articles mentioned above regarding the strategic approach

alternating offer model with a risk component, define risk as the probability of the negotiations

breaking down. Further more, when the agreement is reached, there exists a unique subgame

perfect equilibrium payoff set ),( **BA xx . When the disagreement occurs, the payoff set for both

players can be represented by ),( BA bb . Thus, the final outcome from this type of bargaining

game is the combination of the payoff at the agreement point and disagreement point considering

the risk.

2.2.2.2.3 Strategic approach alternating offer model with outside options: For any

bargaining game, players can have outside opportunities that are relevant for the negotiation

outcome. However, the strategic approach model with outside options was not developed until

the nineties. In 1984, Shaked and Sutton (Shaked and Sutton, 1984) clearly established the

27

conceptual difference between a “threat point” and an outside option where a threat point can

exist between two players. One question is can only one player have an outside option or can

both players have outside options? Shaked (Shaked, 1994) analyzed a bilateral model where only

one player can opt out and recognized that the assumption that only one side can opt out is not

without loss of generality, which implies that outside options are possible for both players for the

bilateral bargaining game.

In 1995, Muthoo (Muthoo, 1995) studied a bargaining strategic model with two-sided

outside options. The model assumes that player B can search for outside options while

temporally leaving the negotiation table. Thus, the bargaining results can be either player B

chooses the outside option or player B chooses to go back to the negotiation table and set an

agreement with player A. The conclusion suggests that this kind of outside option does not

affect the equilibrium outcome, and the unique equilibrium can still be found approximately by

applying the Nash bargaining solution.

In 1998, Ponsati and Sakovics (Ponsati and Sakovics, 1998) had a note on Rubinstein’s

alternating offer with both players having outside options. The model assumes that (1) players 1

and 2 bargain over a fixed surplus, which is normalized to one, (2) negotiation time is numbered

by the natural numbers and players make alternating offers in each period starting with player 2

making the offer first, (3) both players have outside options that yield payoff ix (where i=1,2;

ix≤0 and 1≤∑ ix ). When both players opt out, they will get outside payoffs, (4) if both players

decide to come back to the negotiation table, when the agreement is reached, the payoff set

)1,( yy − is being discounted for both players by a discount factor tiδ . That is the payoffs for

player 1 and 2 are yt1δ and )1(2 yt −δ , and (5) if the outside options are taken at the negotiation

time period r, then the payoffs for player 1 and 2 are 11 xrδ and 22 xrδ , respectively.

28

Assumptions 1 and 2 are the standard assumptions of the basic Rubinstein alternating

offer model. Assumption 3 suggests that when the payoff from the outside option is greater than

the bargaining surplus (recall that is normalized to 1), the bargaining does not even begin, which

makes the whole bargaining discussion nonsense. That’s the reason the assumption 1≤∑ ix is

made. Similarly, if the outside option is less than 0, no players will ever choose to opt out. Then

the model becomes the standard model again. That’s why ix≤0 is made. Assumptions 4 and 5

are the discount factor, which implies that continued bargaining over periods will result in the

reduction of payoffs due to the presence of the discount factor.

Ponsati and Sakovics do not prove the result mathematically, but more in a logical way.

The article suggests that for any 110 21 ≤−≤≤ xx , no matter when the proposers can opt out

(i.e., in the first round or each negotiation period), a subgame perfect equilibrium is the outcome

set ),1( 22 xx− . This implies that the payoff from the offer that the proposer makes is greater than

the payoff from the outside option for the responder, then the responder will take the offer and

the agreement is reached. And this is true for all periods. Since player 2 is assumed to make the

first offer, the equilibrium payoff for player 2 is 2x . Then, at the agreement point, the payoff for

player 1 will be 21 x− .

In 1999, Muthoo ((Muthoo, 1999), p.100-105) shows mathematically how the model with

outside options but no risk of breakdown works. He describes the model in the following way.

Two players, A and B, bargain over the partition of a cake sizeπ . When one player makes an

offer, the other player has three choices which include “(i) accept the offer, (ii) reject the offer

and make a counter offer ∆ time units later, and (iii) reject the offer and opt out ((Muthoo, 1999),

p.100-101).” It suggests that if the agreement is reached at the time period ∆t , the equilibrium

29

payoff set is ),( **BA xx where BAitrxx iii , ),exp(* =∆−= . Recall that ii tr δ≡∆− )exp( is the

discount factor. If the players choose to opt out to the outside options, then the players obtain the

payoff )exp( ∆− triiω . Notice that the set ),( BA ωω is the payoff pair at the outside option point,

where )(),( πωπω << BA and πωω <+ BA . This is almost the same assumption as the Ponsati

and Sakovics’ article made but allows the outside point payoff to go negative. Then, Muthoo

(Muthoo, 1999) shows that the unique subgame perfect equilibrium for this outside option model

is ),( **BA xx , where

)( and )( if

)( and )1

1( if )-(1

)1

1( and )( if

)1

1( and )

11

( if )1

1(

BBAA

BBAABAB

BBAA

BBAA

*

−>−>−

−≤−−

>+

−−

>−≤−

−−

≤−−

≤−−

=

ABB

ABA

B

BA

ABB

BA

A

BA

B

BA

B

Ax

ωπδωωπδωωπ

ωπδωπδδδ

δωπδωδ

πδδδ

δωωπδωωπ

πδδδ

δωπδδδ

δωπδδδ

(2-17)

and

)( and )( if

)( and )1

1( if

)1

1( and )( if )-(1

)1

1( and )

11

( if )1

1(

BBAA

BBAA

BBAAABB

BBAA

*

−>−>−

−≤−−

>−

−−

>−≤+

−−

≤−−

≤−−

=

ABA

ABA

BA

BA

AB

BA

A

BA

B

BA

A

Bx

ωπδωωπδωωπ

ωπδωπδδδ

δωωπ

πδδδ

δωωπδωπδωδ

πδδδ

δωπδδδ

δωπδδδ

(2-18)

This equilibrium payoff set implies that if the outside option payoffs for player A and B are less

(or greater) than the discounted payoffs from the bargaining agreement, respectively, then both

player A and B will choose to negotiate until the agreement is reached (or to opt out). The

30

payoffs for A and B are πδδδ

BA

B

−−

11 (or Bωπ − ) and π

δδδ

BA

A

−−

11 (or Aωπ − ), respectively. If

player B’s outside option payoff is greater than the payoff when the agreement is reached and

player A’s outside option payoff is less than the payoff when player A takes player B’s outside

offer, then player B will make an outside option payoff offer to player A and A will take that

offer to get the payoff Bωπ − and B’s payoff will be )-(1 ABB πδωδ + . Similarly, if the situation

is reversed for player A and B, the result will be similarly reversed.

In the limit, as 0→∆ , recall that

BA

B

BA

B

rrr+

→−−

δδδ

11 and

BA

A

BA

A

rrr+

→−−

δδδ

11 , then Muthoo (Muthoo, 1999) shows that the

unique subgame perfect equilibrium ),( **BA xx converges to ),( ****

BA xx , which is called “the

outside option principle”

)( and )( if

)( and )( if

)( and )( if )(

BAA

BA

BA

**

+≤

+>

+>

+≤−

+≤

+≤

+

=

πωπωω

πωπωωπ

πωπωπ

BA

A

BA

B

BA

A

BA

BB

BA

A

BA

B

BA

B

A

rrr

rrr

rrr

rrr

rrr

rrr

rrr

x (2-19)

****AB xx −= π (2-20)

Equation (2-19) and (2-20) suggest that when the negotiation time period goes to zero, the payoff

is only affected by the discount rate if both players choose to negotiate until the agreement is

reached.

In conclusion, all the strategic models paid more attention to what strategies are being

used which might affect the final bargaining results. The axiomatic approach model has a simple

31

equation to maximize, and then the bargaining problem can be solved when the utility

presentation is established. The axiomatic approach is very easy to apply in a real world

problem. However, the strategic approach models do not have any equations to solve for

bargaining directly, and the result of what could be depends on what strategies are being used.

This approach is difficult to apply. Thus, people are thinking that there might be a way to

combine the advantages of the two different approach models. The question is can the solution of

the strategic approach model converge to the solution (Nash equilibrium) of the axiomatic

approach model? If so, under what conditions?

2.2.2.2.4 Solution approximation of strategic approach to axiomatic approach: In

1986, Binmore et al. (Binmore, et al., 1986) examined the relationship between the axiomatic

approach and the strategic approach to bargaining theory. They explained that compared to the

axiomatic approach, the strategic approach of non-cooperative bargaining games deals with the

complexity of the negotiation process and might have two different incentives for parties to

bargain which include the parties’ impatience to settle an agreement and parties’ fear of

breakdown (i.e., the component of risk). Binmore, Rubinstein et al. conclude that Nash’s

bargaining solution can be seen as the approximation of the equilibria of the strategic approach

models.

Binmore et al. assume rationality and complete information of preferences for all parties,

the same as Rubinstein’s strategic approach alternating offer model. Following the strategic

model with the exogenous risk of breakdown discussed above, Binmore, Rubinstein et al.

showed that the approximate solution for this model is the Nash bargaining solution of

)]()()][()([max arg 2211xbUxUbUxU −− (2-21)

32

where 1U and 2U are the utilities for player 1 and 2 respectively at the agreement point; )(1 bU

and )(2 bU are the utilities for player 1 and 2 respectively at the breakdown point; x is the

solution payoff at the agreement point; and b the payoff when negotiation breaks down. It proves

that as 0→∆ , the solution *x of the equation (2-14) )())1(1()()1( bupxup it

it −−+− converges

to the Nash bargaining solution of the equation (2-21) )]()()][()([max arg 2211xbUxUbUxU −− .

Overall, Binmore, Rubinstein et al. show that the Nash bargaining solution can be applied

to some economic bargaining situations by using the strategic approach models involved with the

utility representations and the consideration of either parties’ impatience or parties’ fear of

breakdown during the negotiation process.

In 1999, Muthoo ((Muthoo, 1999), p.113-116) first showed a model with risk of

breakdown which could include negotiators walking away from the negotiation table, and

intervention by a third party. Then, Muthoo showed another model with both the risk of

breakdown and outside options. These models have already been discussed in this chapter.

Muthoo suggested that the results from both models can converge to the generalized Nash

bargaining solution as long as the time period between two negotiations goes to zero ( 0→∆ ).

Following Muthoo’s ((Muthoo 1999), p.78-118) strategic approach alternating bilateral

model with risk discussed above, the author shows that the solution of that model can converge

to the Nash bargaining solution under some conditions. Define the risk of breakdown in the same

way as the overall probability that negotiation breaks down, which is )exp(1 ∆−−= λp . Recall

that λ is the probability that negotiation breaks down in each period. The author suggests that in

the limit as 0→∆ , the payoff pair ))(),(( **BBAA xUxU (equations (2-15) and (2-16)) of the above

model with a risk component converges to the following Nash bargaining solution of

33

))((max, BBAAUU

bUbUBA

−− (2-22)

where the terms are defined the same as equations (2-15) and (2-16). Notice that p goes to zero

as 0→∆ (equation (2-12)) which means that when the risk of breakdown gets smaller, the

approximation of the solution of the strategic approach model to the Nash bargaining solution is

applicable.

Then, Muthoo extends this solution approximation to the generalized Nash bargaining

solution. To extend the strategic approach bilateral alternate offer model with risk of breakdown,

the author assumes that player A and B have different views on the risk of breakdown, which is

represented by Ap and Bp , respectively. Moreover, the timing of the agreement is considered so

that there exists discount factors Aδ and Bδ for player A and B respectively. Thus, by considering

an outside option as the constraints for player A and B’s decision, when BB b≥ω and AA b≥ω ,

the solution pair ),( **BA VV from the following equation system

))1(( *1*BBBBBA VpbpV δφ −+= − (2-23)

))1(( *1*AAAAAB VpbpV δφ −+= − (2-24)

converges to the generalized Nash bargaining solution of

AA

BABBAAUU

dUdU σσ −−− 1

,)()(max (2-25)

subject to AABA dUUU ≥Ω∈ ,),( and BB dU ≥ , where *AV , *

BV represent the utility for player A

and B at the agreement point, respectively. All other terms are defined the same as those of the

strategic approach bilateral alternate offer model with risk of breakdown discussed above. AU ,

Ad represent the utility for player A at the agreement point and the disagreement point,

respectively; BU , Bd represent the utility for player B at the agreement point and the

34

disagreement point, respectively; τσ =A is defined as the bargaining power for player A and

Aσ−1 is the bargaining power parameter for player B. The variables can be defined as

BBAAABABA UUUUUUU ωωππ ≥≥−=≤≤=Ω and ,,0:),( (2-26)

)2/()( BABA rrr +++= λλσ (2-27)

),(),(λ

λλ

λ++

=B

B

A

ABA r

br

bdd (2-28)

where λ (λ >0) is the negotiation breakdown rate calculated as the number of disagreements

divided by the total number of negotiations.

However, there are some components that we need to pay attention to which include (1) if

ib is zero, then id becomes zero, (2)λ is actually the calculated probability of breakdown, (3) the

total payoff from the outside options )( BA ωω + is less than the total bargaining cake π ,

otherwise bargaining will not begin in the first place, (4) the author does not assume that the

breakdown point is always the same as the opt out point (not always iib ω= ), outside option

payoff only enters as a constraint, and (5) at the limit as 0→∆ , the present value of expected

payoff only slightly differs from the actual payoff at time ∆ which implies that the discount

factor does not actually affect the payoff that much.

2.2.2.3 Summary of bilateral bargaining theory

As a summary of bilateral bargaining theory, two different approaches were discussed

which include the axiomatic approach and the strategic approach. The axiomatic approach model

is based on a series of assumptions and the result is called the Nash bargaining solution. For most

of the cases where symmetry is not satisfied, the solution is considered as a generalized Nash

bargaining solution. The strategic approach models are more complicated depending on what

strategy players choose during the negotiation process. The basic strategic approach model was

35

developed by Rubinstein in 1982. Then the model was extended to the basic model with risk of

breakdown or outside options. Furthermore, as it is discussed above, the solution of the strategic

approach models converge to the Nash bargaining solution at the limit as the negotiation time

period goes to zero. This allows the application of these models to be easier where pure

mathematics of the Nash bargaining solution can be used.

2.2.3 Multilateral Bargaining

Recently, some theoretical work was done in the field to extend the above bilateral

bargaining model. Compared to the above extended outside option models, some of them extend

the model to the outside option but do not allow the negotiator to come back to the negotiation

table once that player chooses to opt out, such as Sloof (Sloof, 2004), and Li (Li, et al., 2005).

But most of the literature has paid more attention to developing the multilateral bargaining

theory based on bilateral bargaining theory. These models can be divided into two categories

which include the axiomatic approach models and the strategic approach models. The strategic

approach multilateral bargaining models are presented in two ways which include (1) reduce the

multilateral bargaining to a series of bilateral bargaining models and (2) form coalitions among

the negotiators on the supply and the demand side, then bilateral bargaining theory is used

between these two sides.

2.2.3.1 Axiomatic approach

To extend the axiomatic approach bilateral bargaining model, Krishna and Serrano

(Krishna and Serrano, 1996) and Schneider (Schneider, 2005) all pointed out that the Nash

bargaining solution from the axiomatic approach is very easy to extend to the n-player case,

where the solution must maximize the product of all players’ utilities and also satisfy Nash’s four

axioms ( IAT,SYM,PAR,IIA) discussed above.

36

For the case of extending Nash’s bargaining solution to n players, Schneider (Schneider,

2005) showed us the bargaining power associated with the n player case model with application

to international relations . It defines power as “actors are powerful if they possess some capacity

to withstand pressure or, to put it another way around, to force other actors to give in”(Schneider,

2005). Schneider suggests that the bargaining power can shift Nash’s bargaining solution when

one player has a better outside option. The n-player situation model is

icii

n

iOQuOu ))()((max

1−Π

=Θ∈ (2-29)

where Θ represents all feasible offer sets for all players; ∑=

=n

ii Cc

1

; ic is capacity for each player

representing bargaining power; C is the overall bargaining power parameter; )(Oui represents the

outcome utility for player i; and )(Qui is the utility at a disagreement point for player i.

Schneider concludes that the larger the country’s capabilities, the more negotiation power the

country has over the international negotiations. It is obvious that to extend the bilateral model to

a multilateral model for the axiomatic approach is easy.

2.2.3.2 Strategic approach

To extend the Rubinstein alternating offer model to the n players’ case, several different

model forms have been analyzed based on different negotiation processes. Some early articles

tried to reconcile the Nash bargaining solution and the Rubinstein alternating offer model for the

n player negotiating situation. For example, Krishna and Serrano (Krishna and Serrano, 1996)

had an article about multilateral bargaining which attempted to extend Rubinstein ‘s alternating

offer model to a n player model and links the solution to Nash’s bargaining solution.

Unfortunately this n player game has many perfect equilibria, which can’t be represented by a

unique Nash bargaining solution. To extend Rubinstein’s alternating offer model directly to the

37

multilateral level is unfeasible. Thus, past literature is focused on either reducing multilateral to

bilateral or forming a coalition before bilateral negotiation, in order to have the result of the

model approximate the multilateral Nash bargaining solution.

2.2.3.3 Solution approximation of strategic approach to axiomatic approach

Some of the passed articles assume that there could be coalitions forming before the

negotiation process, and then the n player multilateral game can be reduced. However, Bennett

(Bennett, 1997) points out that some problems are associated with a coalition. For instance, the

distribution of the gain within each coalition and the opportunity cost of participating in a

particular coalition are problems that must be addressed.

Bloch and Gomes (Bloch and Gomes, 2006) studied a model by assuming multiple players

in the negotiation process with two step coalitional games. Step one is the contracting phase,

which is to form a coalition among some players. Step two is the action stage, which means that

each existing coalition is playing a simultaneous bargaining game together, and inside each

coalition, there exists a unique Nash bargaining solution. However, this article restricts the

strategies to the Markovian strategies which result in a markov perfect equilibrium. This

equilibrium could be efficient or inefficient depending on whether outside options are

independent or non-independent of the actions of other players.

Some other studies assume that this n player bargaining situation can be reduced to n-1

bilateral bargaining sessions where the bilateral strategic model is used to analyze the subgames.

For example, Suh and Wen (Suh and Wen, 2006) point out that as the discount factor goes to one

for all players, the subgame perfect equilibrium for every subgame within a n-1 bilateral

bargaining game converges to the Nash bargaining solution. Suh and Wen assume the model has

n players who negotiate how to split a fixed pie through n-1 bilateral subgames. Further more,

38

they assume that there are two types of procedures in each bilateral bargaining Rubinstein

alternating offer game which include the offer procedure and the demand procedure.

In the offer procedure, Suh and Wen assume that one player (the proposer) makes an offer

and if the other player (responder) accepts the offer, then the responder will receive their share

and exit the game. Then, the proposer will continue to bargain with the next player by continuing

the same process. The results show that there is a unique subgame pefect equilibrium that is

efficient and converges to the Nash equilibrium when the discount factor goes to one. The

solution for this procedure is

))(()( jjjjjij XYsuXu += δ (2-30)

))(()( ij

iiiji XYsuXu += δ (2-31)

where, for player j and i respectively, ju and iu represent the utility at the agreement point; iX

and jX are players i and j’s offer at the agreement point; jδ and iδ are the discount factors; Y is

the total share offered to n-2 players; )( jjj XYs + is the share for player j when j offers jX and

accepts iX ; )( jj

i XYs + is the share for player i when i offers iX and accepts jX .

The demand procedure is slightly different from the offer procedure at which the

proposer will exit the game instead of the responder when the offer from the proposer is not

accepted by the responder, and all other procedures are the same. Thus, similar results can be

drawn from the procedure where the utilities are

)())(( jjjijjj XuXYsu δ=+ (2-32)

)())(( iiijj

ii XuXYsu δ=+ (2-33)

where all terms are defined the same as equations (2-30) and (2-31)

39

Suh and Wen then prove that the solution of the above two subgame perfect equilibrium

outcomes converge to the symmetric Nash bargaining solution of the following problem, as the

players’ common discount factor goes to one.

)( max1

ii

n

ixuΠ

=

, subject to ∑=

≤n

iix

11 and nixi ,...,1,0 =∀≥ (2-34)

where ix represents the offer played by player i.

Suh and Wen conclude that the Nash bargaining solution can be used to solve this

complex n player multilateral bargaining situation when the common discount factor goes to one.

Moreover, if players have different discount factors, when the length of each bargaining period

goes to zero (i.e., )0→∆ , the subgame perfect equilibrium outcomes of the above multilateral

bargaining model, which when reduced to n-1 bilateral bargaining models, converges to the

asymmetric Nash bargaining solution.

2.2.3.4 Summary of multilateral bargaining theory

As a summary of multilateral bargaining theory, it’s still developing. Carraro et al.

(Carraro, et al., 2005) have a systematic discussion of bargaining theory development until 2005

in their World Bank policy research working paper. The paper includes all major developments

of bargaining theory and has almost the same conclusion on the multiple player non-cooperative

bargaining models such that the direct extension to an n player model from Rubinstein’s two

player alternating offer model is less successful due to the existence of multiple subgame perfect

equilibria, for instance, Shaked’s past work (Shaked, 1986). Shaked also concludes that various

solutions have been proposed to isolate a unique equilibrium and an appealing way is to modify

the structure of the game. Other authors, Jun (Jun, 1987), Chae and Yang (Chae and Yang, 1994,

Chae and Yang, 1988), and Krishna and Serrano (Krishna and Serrano, 1996) follow Shaked’s

40

suggestion to solve the multi-player game by reducing the game to a series of bilateral

negotiation games.

2.2.4 Bargaining Theory Summary

In summary, bargaining theory has been developing since 1950 when Nash’s axiomatic

bargaining solution was first introduced. Symmetric (Nash, 1950) and asymmetric (Binmore,

1992) axiomatic models have been developed. A more complex strategic model ( (Rubinstein,

1982) alternating offer model) was introduced in 1982. All these models were concentrated on

bilateral two player games. Later, Roth (Roth, 1985), Binmore et al. (Binmore, et al., 1986), and

Muthoo (Muthoo, 1999)) extended the strategic model with risk of breakdown. In the 1990’s and

2000’s, Shaked (Shaked, 1994), Muthoo (Muthoo, 1995), Ponsati and Sakovics (Ponsati and

Sakovics, 1998), Muthoo(Muthoo, 1999), Sloof (Sloof, 2004), and Li et al.(Li, et al., 2005)

extended Rubinstein’s basic alternating model to the model with outside options. Shaked

(Shaked, 1994) pointed out that the assumption of “one side opt out” lost generality. But

compared with the axiomatic approach by Nash, all strategic models are difficult to apply. Thus,

Binmore et al.(Binmore, et al., 1986), and Muthoo (Muthoo, 1999) showed that the strategic

model’s solution approximated the Nash bargaining solution at the limit when the negotiation

time period goes to zero ( 0→∆ ).

However, in reality, most issues are composed of multiple players instead of only two

players. More and more authors try to extend the two player alternating model to an n player

game. To extend the axiomatic approach models to solve for the n-player Nash bargaining

solution is straight forward (Krishna and Serrano, 1996), (Schneider, 2005); however, the direct

application of Rubinstein’s strategic model is less successful in the empirical world because of

the existence of multiple subgame perfect equilibria (Krishna and Serrano, 1996). To solve the

multiple equilibrium problems, most authors change the structure of the multi-player game. Jun

41

(Jun, 1987), Chae and Yang (Chae and Yang, 1988), Chae and Yang (Chae and Yang, 1994),

Krishna and Serrano (Krishna and Serrano, 1996), and Suh and Wen (Suh and Wen, 2006) tried

to reduce the multilateral bargaining to a series of bilateral bargaining sessions. Suh and Wen

(Suh and Wen, 2006) conclude that at the limit, when negotiation time goes to zero, the solution

of this series of bilateral models converge to the asymmetric Nash bargaining solution.

Other work by Bloch and Gomes (Bloch and Gomes, 2006) tried to reduce the game to

multi-stage games such that coalitions are formed at the first stage, and the second stage is to

negotiate as the bilateral alternating offer bargaining model, and the third stage is to discuss the

profit distribution inside the coalition. Bloch and Gomes conclude that inside the coalitions, the

convergence of the Nash bargaining solution can be proved, but the over all game has a Markov

equilibrium. The theory of multilateral bargaining is still developing. As we can see above,

people are still trying to figure out a way to solve the basic multiple player problem. No literature

on multiple-player models with risk of breakdown and outside options has been found.

2.3 Distribution Channels Bargaining Theory

2.3.1 Introduction

A cooperative is one distribution channel participant. Once finishing the review of

bargaining theory, the question becomes has bargaining theory developed in the area of

distribution channels? So I extend the literature of bargaining theory to the specific field of

distribution channels, which includes supply chain bargaining and cooperative bargaining.

2.3.2 Supply Chain Bargaining

Literature on the bargaining within distribution channels or supply chains can be very

complex. Some of the literature paid attention to distributional bargaining through bilateral

bargaining models (Iyer and Villas-boas, 2003). Iyer and Villas-Boas define a distribution

channel as a manufacturer producing a product and a retailer selling this product to end

42

consumers. They examine the channel relationship and the relative bargaining power between

manufacturers and retailers by using two different well-known bargaining processes which

include Nash’s bargaining solution and Rubinstein’s alternating offer bargaining model. The

same equilibrium solution for the demand from the above two models with different definitions

of the bargaining power parameter are analyzed. By the end, Iyer and Villas-Boas explained that

the two player case can be extended to allow more retail competition; however, the authors left

this for further research.

Other authors analyzed the supply chain bargaining through multistage game analysis.

Nagarajan and Bassok (Nagarajan and Bassok, 2002) examined a supply chain contracting

problem with one single buyer (assembler) and n suppliers. Two assumptions the authors made

were that all players were risk neutral and that the disagreement points were normalized to zero.

The two major issues solved were profit allocation among coalition members and at equilibrium

how the stable supplier coalitions were affected by their relative bargaining power. Three stages

of the negotiating game include stage 1 as the suppliers form coalitions, stage 2 as these

coalitions compete for a better position in the negotiation sequence, and stage 3 as the buyer

(assembler) negotiates with the coalitions in sequence. The game was solved backwards from

stage 3 to stage 1. In stage 3, the Nash bargaining solution was used for the multilateral (a

sequential bilateral) negotiation process as

βα )()(max, nAxx

xxnA

(2-35)

where Ax represents the share of the negotiated pie for the assembler; nx is the total share of the

negotiated pie for all n suppliers inside the coalition; α and β represent the bargaining power

for the assembler and the supplier coalition. The outcome solution of this stage for the assembler

43

and the thi supplier is CnA Π=απ and Ci

i Π= − βαπ 1 (where CΠ is the allocated pie),

respectively.

Then, in stage 2, a dynamic coalition formation was used to solve the problem of these

supplier coalitions competing for the negotiation sequence by using the Nash bargaining

solution. Nagarajan and Bassok show that at every Nash equilibrium, the profits for every

supplier and the assembler are Cn Π− βα 1 and )1( 1βα −−Π nC n , respectively, where all terms are

defined the same as above.

Finally, back to stage 1, the stability of supplier coalitions is discussed where unique

stablity occurs when the assembler’s bargaining power parameter α is less than 1/n (n is the

number of suppliers). Over all, this article provides a way to solve the multi player bargaining

problem by restructuring the game to a multi-stage game and still use the Nash bargaining

solution to solve the problem. However, Nagarajan and Bassok indicated that the risk averse

players could be very hard, if not impossible, to obtain closed form solutions for profit

allocations.

Over all, there is only a few articles applying bargaining theory on the supply chain. From

the two articles reviewed on supply chain bargaining, (1) profit maximization is assumed to be

the goal for all negotiators, (2) the Nash bargaining solution is used to solve the problem, and (3)

the multi player bargaining game has been reduced to a bilateral game so that the problem can be

solved.

2.3.3 Cooperative Bargaining

Cooperative bargaining in U.S. agricultural fruit and vegetable industry has a long history

dating from the 1960’s. In 1962, Helmberger and Hoos (Helmberger and Hoos, 1962) developed

a theory of cooperation by recognizing a cooperative enterprise as a decision-making entity, a

44

broader interpreted firm. Within an organizational framework, Helmberger and Hoos analyzed

the performance of cooperatives by assuming that the goal of the cooperative organization was to

maximize the price Pm for any amount of M which the member firms choose to supply, but

subject to the constraint that all costs including fixed costs, F, are met. The result showed that the

cooperative surplus was maximized by a maximum Pm.

In 1963, Helmberger and Hoos (Helmberger and Hoos, 1963) discussed the economic

theory of bargaining in agriculture. Regarding the theoretical approaches to bargaining,

Helmberger and Hoos indicate that bilateral monopoly theory was the simplest type of market

structure that implies a bargaining process to determine the outcome. They assumed that joint

profit of the monopolist and monopsonist was maximized at a given quantity with an

undetermined price. Helmberger and Hoos indicated that cooperative bargaining can be an

effective tool for certain markets and for certain farm products such as processing fruits and

vegetables, sugar beets, and fluid milk.

In 1967, Johnson (Johnson, 1967) appraised collective bargaining in the U.S. milk

industry. Johnson introduced the use of bargaining theory to analyze U.S. milk cooperatives and

concludes that to achieve income gains from bargaining, cooperative unity and strength was the

key.

In 1974, Ladd (Ladd, 1974) pointed out the lack of well-developed models to understand

cooperative behavior, then developed an operational method to analyze the behavior of a

cooperative selling raw material to processors and the bargaining price. Ladd assumed that the

cooperative's objectives could be either the maximization of the raw material price received by

members or the maximization of quantity marketed through the cooperative.

45

In 2006, Oczkowski (Oczkowski, 2006) developed the generalized Nash bargaining

solution for a bargaining cooperative selling its output to a single buyer. Oczkowski analyzed the

case of the bilateral monopoly where a cooperative bargains with a single trader over the price

and quantity for a good. The theory used in the article was the generalized Nash bargaining

model. The generalized framework was consistent with various strategic models and the standard

axiomatic foundation of the Nash program.

Oczkowski assumed that the cooperative acts only as a bargaining agent, and the

cooperative only exists for the members and hence makes no profit (ΠC=0). Also, all of the

cooperative surplus (CS) is returned to members (CS=PMY), where Y is output and PM is the per-

unit price returned to members. The cooperative faces fixed bargaining costs (B) which members

incur if negotiations reach agreement. Oczkowski also assumed that the Nash disagreement point

is a zero payoff for both the cooperative and processor. Based on all the above assumptions, the

cooperative’s profit function (ΠC), the cooperative’s surplus function (CS), and the members’

profit function ( Mπ ) are constructed. By using the static approach, when cooperatives and

processors bargained for price and quantity, three objectives can be made.

The first objective is to maximize members’ profits ( Mπ ). The Nash bargaining program

is used to find the optimal output Y and output price PY by

ττττ ππ −− −−== 11

),(P)()()()( max

YYYY

PARYATCPYPMF (2-36)

where F represents the objective function that needs to be maximized; Mπ , Y, and PY are defined

the same as above; τ )10( ≤≤ τ and τ−1 are the bargaining power for cooperative and processor,

respectively ( 5.0=τ implies equal bargaining power); Pπ is the profit for the processor; ATC is

the average total cost for cooperatives; and AR is the average revenue for processors. The

solution of this maximization problem can be obtained as

46

ATCARPY ⋅−+⋅= )1( ττ (2-37)

)/()(Y

ARY

ATCATCARY∂∂

−∂

∂−= (2-38)

where all terms are defined the same as above. The results show that the bargained price falls

between an upper limit determined by the processor’s average revenue and a lower limit

determined by the cooperative’s average total cost and transacted quantity occurs at the

intersection of the marginal cost and marginal revenue curves.

The second objective is to maximize the cooperative’s surplus (CS). The Nash bargaining

equation to find the optimal Y and PY is

ττττ π −− −−== 11

),(P)()()()( max

YYYY

PARYABPYPCSF (2-39)

where all terms are defined the same as above. The third objective is to maximize average

returns ( MP ) for cooperative members. The Nash bargaining equation is to find the optimal Y

and PY is

ττττ π −− −−== 11

),(P)()()()( max

YYYMY

PARYABPYPPF (2-40)

where AB is the average bargaining cost for cooperatives. However, Oczkowski shows that when

either maximizing the members’ surplus or maximizing the price, the Nash solution will result in

highest quantity with lowest price, or lowest quantity with highest price, respectively.

In summary of cooperative bargaining theory, we found that a cooperative acts as an

organization or as a firm, which has possibly three different goals which include maximize the

member’s surplus, maximize the member’s price of the commodity, or maximize the member’s

profit assuming the processor is a profit maximization firm. Furthermore, the above literature

suggests that cooperative bargaining is a bilateral bargaining problem where the Nash bargaining

47

solution can be used to solve a profit maximization problem for both players to find out the

negotiated price and quantity of the product.

2.3.4 Distribution Channel Bargaining Theory Summary

Whether it is a cooperative, representing the producers or a manufacturer acting as a firm,

taking profit maximization as their goal to negotiate with the processors or other buyers, a Nash

bargaining model with bilateral bargaining or a multi player bargaining (which can be reduced to

a series of bilateral bargaining) is used to solve the negotiation problem, no matter what

strategies are adapted.

2.4 Bargaining Model Applications

Theoretically, from the literature review on bargaining theory, the multi player

bargaining game can be reduced to a series of bilateral bargaining games. At the limit, the

generalized Nash bargaining solution can be used for each bilateral game. However, it’s also

important to know what the applications are.

2.4.1 Model Applications

The application of bargaining theory has existed for a long time. However, most of the past

work is related to labor issues, such as labor bargaining (Bloom, 1980), (Neumayer and Soysa,

2006), or related to insurance premium bargaining (Maude-Griffin, et al., 2004). Only a few

articles, showed in the following content, relate to cooperative bargaining.

In 1969, Babb et al.(Babb, et al., 1969) analyzed factors which affected the bargaining

process and outcome of negotiations for the tomato processing industry in Indiana and Ohio

during the 1966 growing season through ranking the survey results from tomato processors,

grower representatives, and growers. They concluded that processors and grower representatives

(cooperatives) underestimated supply response and consumers' response to higher prices.

Significant differences between grower and processor attitudes toward bargaining were

48

identified. Processors were primarily concerned about quality factors and growers with price.

This article is an early cooperative bargaining work; however, it does not use a Nash bargaining

framework.

In 1998, Folwell et al. (Folwell, et al., 1998) used the general economic theory of

bargaining to analyze the bargaining process and its role in price discovery within the Pacific

Northwest asparagus industry. The theory is based on the equilibrium of quantity and

disequilibrium of price for the inverse supply and demand equations as

),( dddd ZQPP = Buyer’s Inverse Demand (2-41)

),( ssss ZQPP = Seller’s Inverse Supply (2-42)

*QQQ sd == Quantity Equilibrium (2-43)

ds PPP αα +−= )1(* Price Equilibrium under Bargaining (2-44)

where dP and sP represent the demand and supply price for the buyer and the seller, respectively;

dQ and sQ are the quantity transacted by the buyer and the seller, respectively; dZ and sZ are

exogenous variables that affect the demand and the supply, respectively; *Q is the equilibrium

quantity; *P is the negotiated price; and α−1 and α represent the relative bargaining power

coefficients for the buyer and the seller, respectively.

The empirical model is based on two-rounds of bargaining to set up the price for asparagus

with processors and growers. At the beginning, a growers’ representative (a cooperative)

provides the first round price and processors either accept or reject the offer. Then the

cooperative will offer the second price. If processors accept, the bargaining game ends; however,

if processors reject the offer, the price will be determined by the arbitration board with members

from both growers and processors. Folwell, Mittelhammer et al. estimated their model

49

econometrically with ordinary least squares for the first round bargaining and Heckman’s two-

stage estimation procedure (probit model) for the second round of bargaining.

The results indicated that (1) basic supply and demand forces exerted substantial influences

on the bargaining process, (2) expected levels of supply played a large role in the level of prices

offered and also influenced whether the bargaining process required more than one round to

complete, and (3) past prices also influence current offers. This article estimated the bargaining

price econometrically by also considering the process of bargaining as all strategic approach

models do.

In 1991 and 1999, Oczkowski conducted some analysis on bilateral monopoly bargaining

by using the Nash bargaining solution and econometric techniques. In his 1991 article,

Oczkowski (Oczkowski, 1991) developed a disequilibrium econometric model for single markets

with fixed quantity transacted or contracted and varied negotiated price. The maximum

likelihood method was used to estimate the bargaining power of the Australian tobacco-leaf

market.

The 1999 article by Oczkowski (Oczkowski, 1999) is an extension of his 1991 article. It

allows fix quantity to be varied over different contracts, and allows the strictly bilateral

monopoly market to have outside traders. A disequilibrium econometric model was used and the

bargaining power was estimated by the maximum likelihood (ML) method in the coking coal

trade market between Japan and Australia. The advantage to use this model and ML is that only

the data on price and quantity transacted was needed plus some exogenous shifters for the

demand and supply equations.

Oczkowski follows the assumption that both seller and buyer will trade if their expected

profit is greater than 0. Then, the maximization of joint profit was assumed to have the

50

asymmetric Nash equilibrium solution. Under the above assumptions, joint profit is maximized

for this pure monopoly market as

ττ ππ −−− 1

PQ,]0),([]0),([ max PQPQ ds (2-45)

where Q and P represent the negotiated quantity and price; sπ and dπ are the profit for the

supplier (cooperative) and the buyer (processor), respectively; and τ and τ−1 represent the

bargaining power for the cooperative and the processor, respectively.

For the case with possible outside options, in addition to the above assumptions, the

breakdown point is assumed to be the outside option point instead of the zero profit point, and

then the objective function becomes

ττ −⋅Π−⋅Π⋅Π−⋅Π 1

PQ,)](([)()]([()( max QPQPQQPQPQ d

dds

ss (2-46)

where )([( QPQ ss

⋅Π and )(([ QPQ dd

⋅Π are the profits for the cooperative and the processor at the

outside option point, respectively; and all other terms are defined the same as above.

Oczkowski indicates that for the above cases (equation (2-45) and (2-46)), the same

solution can be obtained as

)()1()( QPQPP sd ⋅−+⋅= ττ (2-47)

/)(/)(/)()( QQPQQPQPQPQ dssd ∂∂−∂∂−= . (2-48)

Econometrically, the article shows that the solution can be written as the following

disequilibrium model

dtt

dt

dt uQXgP += ),,(α (2-49)

stt

st

st uQXhP += ),,(β (2-50)

Pt

stt

dttt uPPP +⋅−+⋅= )1( ττ (2-51)

51

),( θτ btt Xk= (2-52)

qt

st

dttt uPPQ +−= )(δ (2-53)

/),,(/),,(/1 ttdttt

stt QQXgQQXh ∂∂−∂∂= αβδ (2-54)

where for the processor and the cooperative, respectively, dtP and s

tP are the demand price and

the supply price; tP and tQ are the negotiated price and quantity; dtX , s

tX and btX are the

exogenous shifters for the demand, the supply and the bargaining power equation, respectively;

g, h, and k are functional forms; and α , β , θ and δ are parameters; all u are residuals; and τ

and τ−1 are bargaining power parameters for the cooperative and the processor, respectively.

This econometric model is estimated using the maximum likelihood method

dt

stP

P

tts

td

t dPPdQPPPfLt

t

∫ ∫∞

∞−∏= ),,,( (2-55)

where f is the joint density function assumed to be a bivariate normal distribution. Double log

functional form was assumed for both the supply and the demand equation. A general linear

function form was assumed for the negotiated price equation.

Overall, this article is a good application example of bargaining theory. It illustrated the

utility of employing limited dependent variable techniques to estimate the bargaining power in

bilateral monopoly markets. It suggests that the more patient bargainer generally has more

bargaining power.

In 2008, there is one article done in the milk bargaining area (Prasertsri and Kilmer, 2008).

Prasertsri and Kilmer use the generalized Nash bargaining solution (bilateral case) to develop an

econometric model and estimate the negotiated price and bargaining power between the milk

processor and the milk cooperative.

52

Instead of assuming profit maximization, both the cooperative’s utility and processor’s

utility are jointly maximized using the following generalized Nash bargaining model as

αα −−− 1)()(max bppbccp

UUUUN

(2-56)

with the econometric solution of

ijbcj

jbcjbpj

jbpNi eDppDppp

iiii+−−−−+−++= ∑∑

==

)]1(1[)1( 1

12

211

12

21 αααααα (2-57)

where cU and bcU are utilities for the cooperative at the agreement and breakdown point,

respectively; pU and bpU represent utilities for the processor at the agreement and breakdown

point, respectively; α and α−1 are bargaining power parameters for the cooperative and

processor, respectively; Np is the negotiated price; bpp and bcp are the cost and the minimum

price that the processor pays to the cooperative when agreement is reached or breaks down; and

D is a monthly dummy variable. The model is estimated by the maximum likelihood method and

concludes that the cooperatives’ bargaining strength exceeds that of the processor for all

negotiated periods.

2.4.2 Bargaining Model Applications Summary

In summary, all the past works have been shown such that the generalized Nash bargaining

solution can be used to analyze bilateral negotiation between any two traders over some

commodity, or used to analyze a multi player game by reducing it to a series of bilateral

bargaining games. Some empirical work has been done in the field related to both bargaining and

econometrics, such as Folwell, Mittelhammer et al.(Folwell, et al., 1998), Oczkowski

(Oczkowski, 1999), and Prasertsri and Kilmer (Prasertsri and Kilmer, 2008). However, all three

empirical econometric models are dealing with bilateral bargaining. None of them has risk of

breakdown associated.

53

2.5 Summary, Conclusions and Discussions

2.5.1 Summary

The bargaining theory has been developing ever since 1950 when John Nash (Nash, 1950)

presented an axiomatic approach to solve the bilateral bargaining problem. This approach is

called the symmetric Nash bargaining solution based on four axioms which include Invariance to

positive affine transformations (IAT), Symmetry (SYM), Pareto optimality (PAR) and

Independence of irrelevant alternatives (IIA). Then, Roth (Roth, 1979), and Muthoo(Muthoo,

1999), relaxed the symmetry assumption and developed the generalized (asymmetric) Nash

bargaining solution. Another approach called the strategic approach model, was introduced by

Rubinstein in 1982 (the basic alternating bilateral offer model) (Rubinstein, 1982). Further, Roth

(Roth, 1985), Binmore, Rubinstein et al.(Binmore, et al., 1986), and Muthoo (Muthoo, 1999)

extended this basic bilateral alternative offer model to a model with the component of risk of

breakdown. Muthoo (Muthoo, 1995), Ponsati and Sakovics (Ponsati and Sakovics, 1998) and

Muthoo (Muthoo, 1999) further extended the bilateral alternative offer basic model to a model

with possible outside options. Finally, Binmore et al.(Binmore, et al., 1986) and Muthoo

(Muthoo, 1999) showed that the solution to the strategic approach model approximated the Nash

bargaining solution at the limit when the negotiation time period goes to zero.

Later, bargaining theory development extended from the bilateral two player model to the

multi player model. The axiomatic Nash bargaining solution is easy to extend to an n player

bargaining model, (Krishna and Serrano, 1996) and (Schneider, 2005). However, authors tried to

extend the strategic bilateral model to an n player bargaining model in two ways. First, Jun (Jun,

1987), Chae and Yang (Chae and Yang, 1994, Chae and Yang, 1988), Krishna and

Serrano(Krishna and Serrano, 1996), Suh and Wen (Suh and Wen, 2006) reduce the multiple

54

player game to a series bilateral games. Second, Bloch and Gomes(Bloch and Gomes, 2006)

formed a coalition first, and then reduce the game to a bilateral game.

Since cooperatives are one of the participants in the distribution channel, the reviews on

distribution channel bargaining has been done too. Regarding distribution channel bargaining,

Iyer and Villas-boas (Iyer and Villas-boas, 2003) and Nagarajan and Bassok (Nagarajan and

Bassok, 2002) agree that profit maximization is the goal for all participants including

manufacturers, retailers and assemblers. Furthermore, the Nash bargaining solution was used for

both the bilateral bargaining models (Iyer and Villas-boas, 2003) and multi player bargaining

models (Nagarajan and Bassok, 2002). As a special participant in agricultural, the cooperative

and its bargaining game with processors has a long history being discussed back to the 1960s.

Maximizing the commodity price, maximizing the cooperative’s surplus and maximizing profit

are all discussed as the goal of cooperatives (Helmberger and Hoos, 1962), (Helmberger and

Hoos, 1963),(Oczkowski, 2006).

The empirical work of bargaining theory majorly focused on agricultural products

(Folwell, et al., 1998), (Prasertsri and Kilmer, 2008), and some international trade commodities

(Oczkowski, 1999). These three articles applied bargaining theory in the real world bilateral

negotiation problems and used the Nash bargaining solution to solve the problems. Then, the

econometric technique (Maximum Likelihood Estimator) was used to estimate the solution

models. The empirical work has analyzed the bargaining power through the negotiated price

estimation.

2.5.2 Conclusions and Discussions

Over all, the axiomatic approach model is based on a series of axioms and less on the

consideration of strategies adopted by all bargaining game participants. The results of the

strategic approach model heavily depend on what strategies and who plays the strategy first.

55

However, the results of axiomatic approach models ( i,e., Nash bargaining solution) are easier to

apply in the real world than the results of the strategic approach models. At the limit, when the

negotiation time period goes to zero, the solution of the strategic approach model converges to

the Nash bargaining solution. To solve any bilateral bargaining problem, it’s obvious that the

Nash bargaining solution can be applied at the limit. If the negotiation time period does not go to

zero ( 0→∆ is not satisfied), the solution of strategic approach model does not converge to the

Nash Bargaining solution.

When it comes to the multiple player game, the problem can be reduced to a series of

bilateral bargaining games, or to form a coalition first and then to adopt the bilateral bargaining.

Therefore, regardless of bilateral or multi player games, no matter what approach is used, the

generalized Nash bargaining solution of bilateral bargaining can be used to solve these

negotiation problems when negotiation time goes to zero.

When the negotiated game extends to the game with outside options or risk of breakdown,

the theory on bilateral bargaining is abundant; however, the bargaining theory on multi player

games with outside options and risk of breakdown is still developing.

For a cooperative, profit maximization should be considered as the goal when negotiating

with a processor over any commodity rather than maximize price or maximize a cooperative’s

surplus because the last two situations only occur when the cooperative or the processor has

absolute bargaining power. And if one side has absolute bargaining power, the bargaining game

will not begin in the first place. The major negotiated topic is the commodity price in this

bilateral game for a given quantity. Empirically, the generalized Nash bargaining solution can be

estimated econometrically, which suggests that the negotiated price is the price somewhere

between the maximum price that the buyer is willing to pay and the minimum price that the

56

seller is willing to sell. It depends on the bargaining power of each side. With a multiple player

game ( e.g., one cooperative and multiple processors), it appears that whether the risk of

breakdown or the outside option exists or not, the best way to solve the game is to reduce the

game to a series bilateral bargaining games and adopt the generalized Nash bargaining solution

of bilateral bargaining theory. For this case, outside options can be assumed as the only break

point of the negotiation. Thus, the utility pair for the generalized Nash bargaining solution would

be the profit at the agreement point and the profit when outside options are chosen for both

players.

The resulting model of the Nash bargaining solution can be estimated by some

econometric techniques. Thus, to compare the results of all different econometric techniques

could be one area of further research. Since the lack of abundance of work in the multiple player

bargaining game area, more research could be done in this related area such as outside options

and players risk attitude.

2.6 Relevant Information For Model Developing Next Chapter

The bargaining problem was first introduced by Nash (Nash, 1950), who analyzed the

bilateral bargaining game by the axiomatic approach based on four axioms (IAT, SYM, PAR and

IIA). It results in a famous Nash bargaining solution, a unique solution of the following

maximization problem (Muthoo, 1999)

))(( max BBAA dudu −− (2-58)

where Au and Bu are the utilities at the agreement point for player A and B, respectively; Ad and

Bd represent the utility pair at the disagreement point for player A and B, respectively.

Later, Binmore (Binmore, 1992) and Muthoo (Muthoo, 1999) discussed the generalized

(asymmetric) Nash bargaining solution by abandoning the non-generality axiom assumption of

57

symmetry (SYM). The asymmetric Nash bargaining solution is a unique solution of the

maximization problem

ττ −−− 1)()( max BBAA dudu (2-59)

where τ )10( << τ is the bargaining power parameter such that τ represents the bargaining

power for player A and ( τ−1 ) is the bargaining power for player B, and all other terms are

defined the same as the above.

Further, for the same bilateral game discussed above, a strategic approach was introduced

by Rubinstein (Rubinstein, 1982) called the alternating offer bilateral bargaining model. Then,

Binmore et al. (Binmore, et al., 1986) extended this basic bilateral model to the model with risk

of breakdown, where the utility outcome can be represented as

)())1(1()()1( bUpxUp it

it −−+− (2-60)

where )exp(1 ∆−−= λp represents the probability of the negotiation breakdown; ∆ is the length

of the negotiation time period (1,2,3,…t); )(xU i and )(bU i represent the utility for player i at the

agreement point and the breakdown point, respectively; x and b are the offers accepted by player

i at the agreement point and disagreement point, respectively. Binmore indicates that as the time

period of bargaining∆ goes to zero, the solution equation (2-60) (the outcome of strategic model

with risk of breakdown) converges to the unique Nash bargaining solution.

Further, the bilateral bargaining theory was extended to the multi player bargaining level.

When the axiomatic approach is applied in the multi player game, it is very easy to extend the

Nash bargaining solution (Krishna and Serrano, 1996),(Schneider, 2005) to

icii

n

iOQuOu ))()((max

1−Π

=Θ∈ where ∑

=

=n

ii Cc

1

(2-61)

58

where all terms are defined the same as the main body literature. However, as Krishna and

Serrano, and Schneider point out that to extend the strategic approach bilateral bargaining game

to a multi player game is less successful due to the existence of multiple sub-game perfect

equilibria. Thus, to solve the multiple player bargaining game, one way to solve it is to reduce

the game to a series bilateral bargaining games as shown by Jun (Jun, 1987), Chae and Yang

(Chae and Yang, 1988), Krishna and Serrano (Krishna and Serrano, 1996) and Suh and Wen

(Suh and Wen, 2006). Each bilateral game is solved by the Nash bargaining solution.

More over, when it comes to cooperative bargaining, the theory has been developed ever

since the 1960s, such as Helmberger and Hoos (Helmberger and Hoos, 1962), Helmberger and

Hoos (Helmberger and Hoos, 1963) and Ladd (Ladd, 1974). The goal of the cooperatives and the

factors affecting bargaining were discussed. At that early time, maximize price or quantity is

assumed to be cooperative’s objective. However, as more and more articles in distribution

channel bargaining was published by Folwell, Mittelhammer et al.(Folwell, et al., 1998),

Oczkowski (Oczkowski, 1991), (Oczkowski, 1999), Nagarajan and Bassok (Nagarajan and

Bassok, 2002), and Iyer and Villas-boas (Iyer and Villas-boas, 2003) profit maximization

became a more appealing objective for cooperative bargaining.

59

CHAPTER 3 THE THEORETICAL MODEL

3.1 Building Model

Following the literature review of chapter two from the studies of Binmore and Rubinstein

et al.(Binmore, et al., 1986) and Muthoo (Muthoo, 1999), a standard bilateral bargaining game is

used where two players, A and B, bargain over a fixed pie for a commodity. Assume that player

A makes an offer first, and then player B makes a decision either to accept the offer or reject the

offer and make a counter offer. For each bargaining period ∆ , assume that the probability of

negotiation breakdown is represented by the exponentially distributed Variable

)exp(1 ∆−−= γrP where γ is a distributional parameter. This process continues until the

agreement is reached or perpetual disagreement happens, which will be explained later.

3.1.1 Bilateral Model with Risk of Breakdown

Thus, according to Binmore et al. (Binmore, et al., 1986), the outcome solution of this

bilateral bargaining model with risk of breakdown converges to the following generalized Nash

bargaining solution of

ττ −1RA )()(U max R

BU (3-1)

where

ArArRA dpUpU +−= )1( (3-2)

BrBrRB dpUpU +−= )1( (3-3)

where RAU and R

BU are the utility outcome for player A and B, respectively; τ and 1-τ represent

the bargaining power for player A and B, respectively; rp is the probability that negotiation

breaks down; AU , Ad and BU , Bd are the utilities at the agreement and the disagreement points

for players A and B, respectively where Ad and Bd could be any value less or equal to zero.

60

Further, let’s discuss the possible disagreement point in detail. Muthoo (Muthoo, 1999)

and Oczkowski (Oczkowski, 1999) point out that an outside option point can be considered as

the disagreement point when negotiation breakdown happens. Now let’s assume that when

player B makes a decision, they have one more option such that player B can reject the offer and

opt out for an outside option. Similarly, if player B makes a counter offer, player A can choose to

make a counter offer or choose to opt out. This process continues until the agreement is reached

or the negotiation breaks down. If both players have a choice to opt out, they opt out because

they reject the offer and still have the demand or the supply needs. If they do nothing, the

expected utility from this bargaining disagreement would be zero. If they choose to opt out and

do something, then they can get the expected utility from an outside trade which must be greater

than zero but less than the expected utility from the success of the negotiation; otherwise, they

will not opt out. Thus, let’s assume that the breakdown point for this model is the outside option

point.

3.1.2 Bilateral Model with Risk of Breakdown and Outside Options

Following Binmore et al. (Binmore, et al., 1986), assuming that the breakdown points are

the outside option points, let AW , and BW be the utilities that player A and B receive when the

player opts out, respectively. Further, assume that 0,0 >> BA WW . Then, the disagreement point

utility pair of two players become AW and BW . Thus, the solution of the bilateral bargaining

model with both risk of breakdown and two-side outside options becomes

τROB

τROA )(U)(U −1 max (3-4)

where

ArArROA WpUpU +−= )1( (3-5)

BrBrROB WpUpU +−= )1( (3-6)

61

and all terms are defined the same as the above.

The next question becomes how to define the utilities for the bargaining game between a

milk cooperative and milk processor. As discussed in the literature review in chapter two, the

Nash bargaining solution can be used to solve cooperative bargaining (Iyer and Villas-boas,

2003), (Nagarajan and Bassok, 2002). Regarding the utility pair at the agreement point and the

breakdown point, Helmberger and Hoos (Helmberger and Hoos, 1962), (Helmberger and Hoos,

1963) used the price of the commodity or the quantity of the commodity. Oczkowski

(Oczkowski, 2006) suggests that besides price and quantity, profit can be used to replace utility.

In addition, Iyer and Villas-boas (Iyer and Villas-boas, 2003), and Nagarajan and Bassok

(Nagarajan and Bassok, 2002) use profit instead of utilities for all players entering into the Nash

bargaining solution.

3.1.3 Bilateral Model with Risk of Breakdown and Outside Options between A Cooperative and Processor

Thus, for the bilateral bargaining game between the Florida milk cooperative and the

Florida milk processor, profit is used to replace the utilities in the Nash bargaining solution of

equation (3-4) (Iyer and Villas-boas, 2003, Nagarajan and Bassok, 2002, Oczkowski, 1999,

Oczkowski, 1991, Oczkowski, 2006). Let’s assume that both the cooperative and the processor

maximize their profits and define A as the cooperative and B as the processor. Following the

above authors, using profit instead of utility for both players, the Nash bargaining solution for

this bilateral bargaining model with risk of breakdown and outside options becomes

ττ ππ −1ROA )()( max RO

B (3-7)

where

WArArROA pp πππ +−= )1( (3-8)

WBrBrROB pp πππ +−= )1( (3-9)

62

and, ROAπ , RO

Bπ are expected profits for the milk cooperative and milk processor, respectively;

Aπ , Bπ are profits for the milk cooperative and milk processor at the agreement point,

respectively; WAπ , WBπ are the profits for the milk cooperative and milk processor when both

choose to opt out; and all other terms are defined the same as above.

The outside option prices can be fixed or variable. First, the outside option prices for the

milk cooperative and milk processor can be fixed when they decide to opt out. They will choose

to accept the outsider’s offer without negotiations which makes the outside offer price fixed.

Second, the outside option prices are variable if the milk cooperative and milk processor choose

to opt out and they have to search for the possible outside option and negotiate the price with

outsiders which implies that the outside option price varies due to the presence of another

bargaining process. Third, the outside option price can be fixed for the milk marketing

cooperative (milk processor) and variable for the milk processor (milk marketing cooperative)

when the milk marketing cooperative (milk processor) accepts the outsider’s offer and the milk

processor (milk marketing cooperative) has to search for outside options and bargains over the

commodity price and quantity. Thus, the model can be solved for all above three cases.

3.2 Model Solution

Following Oczkowski (Oczkowski, 2006) to solve the bilateral bargaining model with risk

of breakdown and outside options, the profit functions for the cooperative and the processor are

defined as

)(QCCPQM PBC −−=π (3-10)

PQQRP −= )(π (3-11)

where CMπ is the cooperative members’ profit; P is the negotiated price of the commodity; Q is

the output of the commodity; BC is the bargaining cost; )(QCP is the production cost of the

63

commodity; Pπ represents the profit of the processor; and )(QR is the commodity associated net

revenue for the processor.

The latest cooperative bargaining theory is only found in the following works. Oczkowski

(Oczkowski, 1999) defined the outside option price as variable along the supply and the demand

curve but fixed for any quantity of the bargaining product. Later, Oczkowski (Oczkowski, 2006)

had a theoretical bilateral bargaining model on cooperative and processor bargaining but without

the consideration of outside options and risk of breakdown. Besides to what Oczkowski has

done, I assume that the outside option prices could be fixed or variable for any quantity of the

bargaining product and there exists three possible cases including (1) both outside option prices

are variable, (2) both outside option prices are fixed, and (3) one outside option price is fixed and

the other outside option price is variable.

3.2.1 Case 1: Outside Option Prices are Variable

Differing from what Oczkowski (Oczkowski, 1999) defined as the outside option price

being variable along the supply and the demand curve but fixed for any quantity of the

bargaining product, I assume the outside option prices are bargaining prices which are variable

for any quantity of the bargaining product. In this case, when the negotiation breaks down and

both players need to go and search for outside options, they need to start the bargaining process

again but with outsiders. This means that the outside prices are endogenous variables. Then, the

following objective function needs to be maximized with respect to four endogenous variables

( P

O

C

O ,PP,Q,P ) as

τWBrBr

τWArAr

,PP,Q,Pπpπ-pπpπ-p F

PO

CO

−++= 1

)(])1[(])1[( max (3-12)

where

)(QCPQ CPA −=π (3-13)

64

)(QCQP COC

OWA −=π (3-14)

PCPCB BPQQR −−= )(π (3-15)

POP

OPOWB BQPQR −−= )(π (3-16)

where P is the negotiated price between the cooperative and the processor; Q is the negotiated

quantity; CPC is the total cost (bargaining cost and production cost) for the cooperative when the

cooperative contracts with the processor; COP is defined as the negotiated price between the

cooperative and its outside option; COC is the total cost (bargaining cost and production cost) for

the cooperative when the cooperative contracts with an outside option; PCR is processor’s

commodity associated net revenue when contracting with the cooperative; PCB is bargaining cost

for the processor when contracting with cooperatives; POR is processor’s commodity associated

revenue when contracting with an outside option; POP is the negotiated price between the

processor and its outside option; POB is bargaining cost for the processor when contracting with

an outside option; and all other terms are defined the same as above.

Thus, the negotiated price between the Florida milk cooperative and Florida milk processor

can be found by solving this profit maximization problem with respect to ,, COPP Q and P

OP . The

first order condition (FOC) of equation (3-12) with respect to P is

0])1([][])[[1(]][)1[(][ 11 =−−−+−=∂∂ −−− QpQp

PF

rROB

ROA

ROBr

ROA

ττττ ππτππτ . (3-17)

Multiplying both sides by τπ −1][ ROA (see equation 3-7), then

0])1([]][)[1(]][)1[( 1 =−−−+− −− QpQp rROB

ROA

ROBr

ττ ππτπτ (3-18)

and

65

0]][)[1(][ 1 =−− −− ττ ππτπτ ROB

ROA

ROB . (3-19)

Multiplying both sides by τπ ][ ROB (see equation 3-7), then

0])[1(][ =−− ROA

ROB πτπτ . (3-20)

Then, substitute ROAπ and RO

Bπ (see equation (3-8), (3-9), (3-13) through (3-16)) into the

above equation (3-20) and solve for P as

0))](())()(1)[(1(

)])(())()(1[(

=−+−−−−

−−+−−−

QCQPpQCPQpBQPQRpBPQQRp

COC

OrCPr

POP

OPOrPCPCr

τ

τ (3-21)

0))](())()(1)[(1(

)])(())()(1[(

])1)[(1(])1[(

=−+−−−−

−−+−−+

−−−−−

QCQPpQCpQPBQRpBQRp

PQpPQp

COC

OrCPr

POPOPOrPCPCr

rr

τ

τ

ττ

(3-22)

))](())()(1)[(1(

)])(())()(1[(])1)[((

QCQPpQCpQPBQRpBQRpPQp

COC

OrCPr

POPOPOrPCPCrr

−+−−−+

−−+−−−=−−

τ

τ (3-23)

)])((1

)()[1(

)])((1

))(([

QQCP

pp

QQC

PQ

BQRp

pQ

BQRP

COCO

r

rCP

PO

POPO

r

rPCPC

−−

−−+

−−

−+

−=

τ

τ. (3-24)

Simplifying the negotiated price P (equation 3-24) as

)](1

)[1(

)](1

)[(

COC

Or

rCP

POPOPO

r

rPCPC

ATCPp

pATC

PABARp

pABARP

−−

−−+

−−−

+−=

τ

τ (3-25)

where PCAR = Q

RPC is the processor’s commodity associated net revenue when contracting with

cooperatives; PCAB = Q

BPC is the processor’s bargaining cost when contracting with

66

cooperatives; POAR = Q

RPO is the processor’s commodity net associated revenue when

contracting with an outside option; POAB = Q

BPO is the processor’s bargaining cost when

contracting with an outside option; CPATC = Q

CCP is the average total cost (bargaining cost and

production cost) for the cooperative when the cooperative contracts with the processor; COATC =

QCCO is the average total cost (bargaining cost and production cost) for the cooperative when the

cooperative contracts with an outside option.

The solution found in equation (3-25) is different from what Oczkowski (Oczkowski,

1999, Oczkowski, 2006) found in both his articles such that the probability of breakdown and

outside option prices are inside the solution (equation (3-25)). The reason is that Oczkowski’s

1999 article assumed outside option price varies along the supply curve and the demand curve

but is fixed for any quantity. This dissertation assumes that outside option prices vary along the

average net revenue and average cost curve and is variable for any quantity.

However, notice that if the probability of breakdown goes to zero, which means that my

model simplifies to Oczkowski’s model in 2006 (Oczkowski, 2006), the above solution

(equation 3-25) of negotiated price becomes

CPPCPCY ATCABARP )1()( ττ −+−= (3-26)

which is identical to the Oczkowski’s solution (Oczkowski, 2006) which is the result that should

be the same because the model is the same when 0=rp (i.e., no risk of breakdown and no

outside options).

The first order condition of equation (3-12) with respect to COP is

67

0]][[][ 11 ==∂∂ −− ττ ππτ RO

BrROAC

O

QpPF . (3-27)

And the solution is

0=τ (3-28)

or

0=rp . (3-29)

0=τ means that when the cooperative has no bargaining power at all, they will not choose to

trade with the processor and the cooperative will opt out. This is the same result that Oczkowski

(Oczkowski, 2006) found; however, compared to the mathematical derivations shown here, only

a word explanation was presented by Oczkowski. 0=rp implies that there is no chance that

both players would opt out.

The first order condition of equation (3-12) with respect to POP is

0]][)[1(][ =−−=∂∂ −ττ πτπ RO

BrROAP

O

QpPF . (3-30)

And the solution is

1=τ (3-31)

or

0=rp . (3-32)

1=τ means that when the cooperative has absolute power, then the processor will not choose to

trade with the cooperative and they will opt out. This is identical to what Oczkowski

(Oczkowski, 2006) found but without the mathematical derivations along with the explanations

shown here.

68

Let’s discuss the solutions with respect to COP and P

OP (equations (3-28), (3-29), (3-31),

and (3-32)) before solving the first order condition with respect to Q. There are four possible

solutions:

(1). 0=τ (equation (3-28)) for maximizing with respect to COP and 1=τ (equation (3-31)) for

maximizing with respect to POP ,

(2). 0=τ (equation (3-28)) for maximizing with respect to COP and 0=rp (equation (3-32))

for maximizing with respect to POP ,

(3). 0=rp (equation (3-29)) for maximizing with respect to COP and 1=τ (equation (3-31))

for maximizing with respect to POP ,

(4). 0=rp (equation (3-29), equation (3-32)) for maximizing with respect to COP and P

OP .

Possible solution (1) 0=τ and 1=τ conflict, thus, this is not a solution. Possible solution

(2) 0=τ implies that the processor has absolute bargaining power over the cooperative, thus the

bargaining process would not begin in the first place. In the mean time, 0=rp suggests that

there is no chance that both players will go to an outside option. However, since the bargaining

process does not actually begin, 0=τ and 0=rp is not a bargaining solution. Similarly,

possible solution (3) 0=rp and 1=τ is not a bargaining solution. Possible solution (4) 0=rp

is the only solution for maximizing the expected profits with respect to COP and P

OP . This is a

solution because both players have to go outside and search for a possible option when

negotiation breakdown occurs. Furthermore, they need to bargain with the outside options over

the price and quantity again. 0=rp suggests that the costs of searching outside options,

bargaining, and timing exceed the benefit of breakdown so that the best decision for both players

is to continue negotiation until agreement is reached.

69

Then, when 0=rp , let’s solve the first order condition of equation (3-12) with respect to

Q,

0][])[[1(][][ 11 =∂∂

−+∂∂

=∂∂ −−−

QQQF RO

BROB

ROA

ROB

ROARO

Aπππτπππτ ττττ . (3-33)

Multiplying both sides by τπ −1][ ROA , then

0]][)[1(][ 1 =∂∂

−+∂∂ −−

QQ

ROBRO

BROA

ROB

ROA πππτππτ ττ . (3-34)

Multiplying both sides by τπ ][ ROB , then

0][)1(][ =∂∂

−+∂∂ RO

A

ROBRO

B

ROA

QQππτππτ . (3-35)

Then, solve for Q

ROA

∂∂π and

Q

ROB

∂∂π

QATCQATCP

QCP

CP

ROA

∂∂

−−=∂∂π (3-36)

)(Q

ABQ

ARQPABARQ

PCPCPCPC

ROB

∂∂

−∂

∂+−−=

∂∂π . (3-37)

Then, substitute ROAπ , RO

Bπ , equations (3-36) and (3-37) into equation (3-35) to get

0][)]()[1(

][)(

=−∂

∂−

∂∂

+−−−+

−−∂

∂−−

CPPCPC

PCPC

PCPCCP

CP

ATCPQQ

ABQ

ARQPABAR

PABARQQ

ATCQATCP

τ

τ. (3-38)

Simplify equation (3-38) to get

70

0)()()()(

)()()()(

)()()(

=−∂

∂−

∂∂

−−−−−

−∂

∂−

∂∂

+−−−+

−−∂

∂−−−−

CPPCPC

CPPCPC

CPPCPC

CPPCPC

PCPCCP

PCPCCP

ATCPQQ

ABQ

ARQATCPQPABAR

ATCPQQ

ABQ

ARQATCPQPABAR

PABARQQ

ATCQPABARQATCP

ττ

ττ

. (3-39)

Then, divide both sides of equation (3-39) by Q

0)()()()(

))(()(

=−∂

∂−

∂∂

−−∂

∂−

∂∂

+

−−−+−−∂

∂−

CPPCPC

CPPCPC

CPPCPCPCPCCP

ATCPQQ

ABQ

ARATCPQQ

ABQ

AR

ATCPPABARPABARQQ

ATC

τ

τ. (3-40)

When 0=rp , the negotiated price (P) equation (3-25) can be simplified as

))(1()( CPPCPC ATCABARP ττ −+−= . (3-41)

Then, substitute equation (3-42) into equation (3-41) to get

0]))(1()([)(

]))(1()([)(

]))(1()([ ))])(1()(([

))])(1()(([

=−−+−∂

∂−

∂∂

−−+−∂

∂−

∂∂

+

−−+−•−+−−−+

−+−−−∂

∂−

CPCPPCPCPCPC

CPCPPCPCPCPC

CPCPPCPC

CPPCPCPCPC

CPPCPCPCPCCP

ATCATCABARQQ

ABQ

AR

ATCATCABARQQ

ABQ

ARATCATCABAR

ATCABARABAR

ATCABARABARQQ

ATC

τττ

ττ

ττττ

τττ

. (3-42)

Then, simplify it to get

0)()(

)()(

)())(1(

))(1(

=−−∂

∂−

∂∂

−−∂

∂−

∂∂

+

−−−−−+

−−−∂

∂−

CPPCPCPCPC

CPPCPCPCPC

CPPCPCCPPCPC

CPPCPCCP

ATCABARQQ

ABQ

AR

ATCABARQQ

ABQ

ARATCABARATCABAR

ATCABARQQ

ATC

ττ

τ

ττ

ττ

. (3-43)

Divide both sides of equation (3-43) by )( CPPCPC ATCABAR −−τ to get

71

0)()(

))(1()1(

=∂

∂−

∂∂

−∂

∂−

∂∂

+

−−−+−∂

∂−

QQ

ABQ

ARQQ

ABQ

AR

ATCABARQQ

ATC

PCPCPCPC

CPPCPCCP

τ

ττ. (3-44)

Then simplify to get

0))(1(

))(1()1(

=∂

∂−

∂∂

−+

−−−+−∂

∂−

QQ

ABQ

AR

ATCABARQQ

ATC

PCPC

CPPCPCCP

τ

ττ. (3-45)

Divide both sides of equation (3-45) by )1( τ− to get

0)()( =∂

∂−

∂∂

+−−+∂

∂− Q

QAB

QARATCABARQ

QATC PCPC

CPPCPCCP . (3-46)

Then solving for Q

CPPCPCPCPCCP ATCABAR

QAB

QAR

QATC

Q −−=∂

∂+

∂∂

−∂

∂)( . (3-47)

Thus, the negotiated quantity equation can be presented as

QATC

QAB

QAR

ABARATCQ

CPPCPC

PCPCCP

∂∂

−∂

∂−

∂∂

−−=

)(

)(. (3-48)

where terms are defined the same as equation (3-25). This result (equation 3-48) is equivalent to

what Ozkcowski (Oczkowski, 2006) found but we assume that bargaining cost exists for the

processor ( 0≠PCAB ).

In summary, the solutions for the bilateral bargaining model with outside options and risk

of breakdown with variable outside option prices (equation 3-12) are equations (3-29, 3-32, 3-41

and 3-48) which are listed below

(3-29, 3-32) PO

CO PP ∀∀ , with 0=rp

72

(3-41) ))(1()( CPPCPC ATCABARP ττ −+−= .

(3-48)

QATC

QAB

QAR

ABARATCQ

CPPCPC

PCPCCP

∂∂

−∂

∂−

∂∂

−−=

)(

)(.

The above results imply that the probability of opting out or in other words, the risk of

breakdown is zero which suggests that outside options are not binding and do not affect the

negotiated price and the negotiated quantity. A possible reason might be the existing high cost

(outside option search cost and bargaining cost). The negotiated price is between the processor’s

average revenue and the cooperative’s average total cost, and the final negotiated price depends

on the bargaining power of each side. The negotiated quantity is also affected by the processor’s

average revenue and the cooperative’s average total cost.

3.2.2 Case 2: Outside Option Prices are Fixed

In this case, when the negotiation breaks down, both players go outside options and accept

the prices that outsiders offer. Thus, the objective function of the model needs to be maximized

only with respect to the negotiated price P and the negotiated quantity Q shown as

τWBrBr

τWArAr(P,Q)

πpπ-pπpπ-p F −++= 1])1[(])1[( max (3-49)

where

)]([)( QATCPQQCPQ CPCPA −=−=π (3-50)

)]([)( QATCPQQCQP COC

OCOC

OWA −=−=π (3-51)

])()([)( PQABQARQBPQQR PCPCPCPCB −−=−−=π (3-52)

])()([)( POPOPOPO

POPOWB PQABQARQBQPQR −−=−−=π (3-53)

Solve for the negotiated price P by using the first order condition of equation (3-49) with

respect to P (same as case I, equation 3-25) shown below as

73

)](1

)[1(

)](1

)[(

COC

Or

rCP

POPOPO

r

rPCPC

ATCPp

pATC

PABARp

pABARP

−−

−−+

−−−

+−=

τ

τ. (3-54)

Solve for the negotiated quantity Q by using the first order condition of equation (3-49)

with respect to Q (Appendix A)

]

1[

])11

1

]1

)(

))()(1(2

))((2

)()1(

)(

))()(1(2

22

2

22

2

22

22

)ATC(Pp)PAB(ARp

)ATCAB)(ARp(p)Q

ABQ

AR(

)ATC(Pp(p)PAB)(ARp(p

)ATCAB(AR)p)[(Q

ABQ

AR(

)ATC(P p)ATCAB)(ARp(

)P(Q)AB(Q)(AR p)[Q

ATC(

ATCPpATCABARATCPpp

PABARATCPpATCABARp

PABARpPABARATCABARpp

Q

COC

OrP

OPOPOr

CPPCPCrrPOPO

COC

OrrP

OPOPOrr

CPPCPCrPCPC

COC

OrCPPCPCr

POPOPOr

CP

COC

Or

CPPCPCCOC

Orr

POPOPOCO

COr

CPPCPCr

POPOPOr

POPOPOCPPCPCrr

−+−−+

−−−∂

∂−

∂∂

+

−−+−−−+

−−−∂

∂−

∂∂

+

−−−−−−

−−−∂

∂−−

−−−−−

−−−−

−−−−

−−−

−−−−−−

=

. (3-55)

In summary, the solution for the bilateral bargaining model with outside options and risk

of breakdown with fixed outside option prices (equation (3-49)) are equations (3-54) and (3-55)

for the negotiated price and quantity, which suggests that the negotiated price and quantity is not

only affected by the bargaining power parameter τ , but also affected by the risk of breakdown

when outside options are chosen. No other authors have found this result before. In other words,

outside options do affect the negotiated price and the negotiated quantity through the risk of

breakdown.

74

Notice that when 0=rp , the negotiated price and negotiated quantity become

CPPCPC ATCABARP )1()( ττ −+−= (3-56)

QATC

)Q

ABQ

AR(

ABARATC Q

CPPCPC

PCPCCP

∂∂

−∂

∂−

∂∂

−−=

)( (3-57)

which is same as the solution of case I when outside option prices vary.

3.2.3 Case 3: One Outside Option Price is fixed and The Other Outside Option Price is Variable

The third possible case is that negotiation breakdown occurs because one player decides

to accept the offer provided by an outsider, and then the other player has to search for an outside

option to start the negotiation process all over again. Thus, the outside option price for the player

who accepts the outsider’s offer is fixed, but the outside option price for the player who has to

search and negotiate with the outsider is variable.

For simplicity, let’s assume that the processor has a fixed outside option price POP and the

cooperative has a variable outside option price COP . Then, the following objective function needs

to be maximized with respect to three endogenous variables ( P

OP,Q,P ) as

τWBrBr

τWArAr

P,Q,Pπpπ-pπpπ-p F

PO

−++= 1

)(])1[(])1[( max (3-58)

where terms are defined the same as in case 1.

To solve the problem, let’s follow the same procedure in case 1 to find the first order

conditions with respect to P, Q and COP . The solution is the same as shown in equation (3-41),

equation (3-48) and equations (3-28), (3-29) for P, Q and COP , respectively.

When 0=τ (equation 3-28), it means that the processor has absolute bargaining power.

The cooperative will not choose to bargaining because they lose at the beginning. Therefore, no

75

bargaining problem exists which indicates that this is not a real solution. Then, 0=rp (equation

3-29) is the solution. It means that both players will choose to continue negotiating until the

agreement is reached. So the solution for case 3 is the same as that for case 1 which is shown in

equation (3-41) for P and equation (3-48) for Q as

COP∀ with 0=rp (3-59)

CPPCPC ATCABARP )1()( ττ −+−= (3-60)

QATC

)Q

ABQ

AR(

ABARATC Q

CPPCPC

PCPCCP

∂∂

−∂

∂−

∂∂

−−=

)( (3-61)

3.2.4 Summary of Model Solution

The model presented in this chapter differs from the model presented by Oczkowski in

1999 (Oczkowski, 1999). Instead of assuming that the outside option price is variable along the

supply and the demand curve but fixed for any quantity of the bargaining product, I assume that

the outside options can be fixed or variable for any existing quantity so that the model was

developed and solved in three different cases (never seen before in other literatures). Further, the

model developed in this chapter differs from the model presented by Oczkowski in 2006

(Oczkowski, 2006) in the way that outside options and risk of breakdown are included in the

bilateral model. Notice that, when 0=rp , the bilateral bargaining model with risk of breakdown

and outside options simplifies to the same solution of what Oczkowski (Oczkowski, 2006) has.

In summary, case 1 (both prices are variable) and case 3 (one price fixed and one price

variable) have same solutions for negotiated price and negotiated quantity such that no players

would choose to opt out where 0=rp . They will continue to negotiate until the agreement is

reached where the negotiated price (equation 3-(60)) and the negotiated quantity (equation (3-

76

61)) are the same for these two cases. This suggests that an outside option does not affect the

negotiated price and the negotiated quantity directly, but might instead affect the negotiated price

and the negotiated quantity through the bargaining power parameter.

Furthermore, the result of case 2 is completely new and different from the result of case 1

and case 3. The solution has a risk of breakdown variable ( rp ) and both outside option prices

inside the solution of the negotiated price (equation (3-41)) and the negotiated quantity (equation

(3-48)). This solution implies that option prices do affect the negotiated price and the negotiated

quantity directly. When outside option prices are fixed for both players, if the profit from the

outside option is higher than that from the insider, players will opt out where negotiation

breakdown occurs ( 0≠rp ), and if the profit from outside option is less than what both players

get from each other, both players will choose to continue the negotiation process until an

agreement is reached ( 0=rp ).

77

CHAPTER 4 THE EMPIRICAL MODEL

4.1 Florida Milk Industry

In the Florida dairy industry, two milk cooperatives, Florida Dairy Farmers' Association

(FDFA) and Tampa Independent Dairy Farmers' Association, Inc. (TIDFA) were established in

1956 and in 1967, respectively (http://www.southeastmilk.org/v2/about/). In 1998 with the

merger of FDFA and TIDFA, Southeast Milk, Inc. (SMI) was created as a new cooperative with

members from FDFA and TIDFA. SMI is a cooperative with approximately 280 members and

markets approximately 3 billion pounds of milk annually

(http://www.southeastmilk.org/v2/about/). SMI represents most Florida dairy farmers plus

approximately one half of the Georgia dairy farmers and some members in Alabama and

Tennessee. SMI is a member of the Southeast Dairy Cooperative, Inc. (SDC). SDC negotiates

with Florida milk processers. There were fourteen milk processors in Florida from the year 1998

to the year 2009 (Table 4-1).

The fluid milk price and quantity are determined through the negotiation process between

SDC and the leading processor. The negotiated price is adopted by all Florida processors. The

actual milk supply contract between SDC and the Florida processors is a yearly contract which is

annually renewable and can be cancelled given a 60 day notice. However, under the contract, the

quantity and price is negotiated once a month. The quantity is variable throughout the month as

processors increase or decrease their demand.

This market environment is a monopoly on the supply side (SDC) and oligopsony on the

demand side. Iskow and Sexton (Iskow and Sexton 1992) indentified this type of the market

structure first in the fruit and vegetable markets. Then Sexton (Sexton 1993) indicated that the

78

market approximated a bilateral monopoly during negotiations. Thus, the bargaining between

SDC and milk processors in the Florida dairy market approximates bilateral bargaining.

Table 4-1 Florida Milk Processor Plants Number Plant Name City Name ZipCode 1 Gustafsons L.L.C. Green Cove Springs 32043 2 Hato Patrero Farms, Inc. Clewiston 33440 3 M&B Dairy Products, Inc. Tampa 33637 4 McArthur Dairy, Inc. Miami 33325

5 Publix Supermarkets, Inc. Deerfield Beach 33442 Lakeland 33802

6 Sunbelt Dairy and Food Company Tampa 33686 7 Sunshine State Dairy Farms, LLC Plant City 33567

8 T. G. Lee Foods, Inc. Orange City 32763 Orlando 32802

9 Velda Farms, LLC Miami. 33164 Winter Haven 33881

10 Ryan Foods Company Jacksonville 32209

11 Superbrand Dairy Products, Inc Miami 33167 Plant City 33567

12 Morningstar Foods, Inc. Jacksonville 32209 13 WhiteWave Foods Jacksonville 32209 14 Winn-Dixie Stores, Inc. Plant City 33567 source: http://future.aae.wisc.edu/tab/production.html#43, date visited, July 3rd, 2009

Every month, SDC is the only supplier of milk to those processors whether it’s a deficit

month or surplus month. During the deficit months, SDC will have more cooperative members

from outside the state of Florida to provide milk to processors (table 4-2). The numbers inside

the table represent months. When SDC has surplus months, the number of cooperative members

decrease (table 4-2) and SDC sells surplus milk to manufacturing plants who make non fluid

milk products.

The negotiation process has broken down only once over the past twenty five years which

suggests that the probability of negotiations breaking down and SDC and the processors opting-

out can be assumed to be zero ( 0=rp ).

79

Table 4-2. Monthly SDC Non-Florida Cooperative members

Year

Cobblestone Milk Cooperative, Maryland/Virginia Milk Cooperative, Virginia

Lone Star Milk Producer, Inc, Texas

Select Milk Producers, New Mexico

White Eagle Cooperative Association, Indiana

Land-O-Lakes, Pennsylvania

Michigan Milk Producers, Michigan

2000 8 2001 8 2002 2003 4-12 1, 7-11 8-9 2004 1-6,9-12 9 1, 3, 8-12

2005 1-12 7-12 3-4, 6, 8-12 8 8-9

2006 1-12 1-12 1, 7-12 2007 1-12 1-12 1, 6, 8-11 9-11 8 2008 1-12 1-12 1 source: http://www.fmmatlanta.com/Annual%20Statistics.htm, date visited, October 20th, 2009

4.2 The Econometric Model

Assuming 0=rp , the bilateral solution of the negotiated price (P) and the negotiated

quantity (Q) for all three cases (fixed outside option prices, variable outside option prices, and

one fixed/one variable outside option prices) mentioned in chapter 3 can be presented as

CPPCPC ATCABARP )1()( ττ −+−= (4-1)

QATC

)Q

ABQ

AR(

ABARATC Q

CPPCPC

PCPCCP

∂∂

−∂

∂−

∂∂

−−=

)( (4-2)

where PCPC ABAR − is the processors’ average net revenue (AR) associated with fluid milk

( PCAR ) (Blair, et al., 1989) which does not include the bargaining cost for the processor ( PCAB ),

and CPATC is the associated average total cost (ATC) for SDC members. Recall that τ is the

bargaining power for SDC and τ−1 is the bargaining power for processors. Following

Oczkowski (Oczkowski, 1999), AR is processor’s demand reservation price which is

QQRARP D )(

== and ATC is the supply reservation price which is defined as

80

QQCATCP S )(

== , where R(Q) and C(Q) represent the net revenue function for the processor

and the cost function for SDC. Thus, equation (4-1) and (4-2) can be expressed as

SD PPP )1( ττ −+= (4-3)

QP

QP

PP Q SD

DS

∂∂

−∂∂

−= (4-4)

The four endogenous variables are the negotiated unit price (P), the demand reservation price

( DP ), the supply reservation price ( SP ), and the negotiated quantity (Q). τ and τ−1 are the

bargaining power parameters for SDC and the milk processor.

Following Oczkowski (Oczkowski, 1999), the bilateral generalized Nash bargaining

econometric model (equations (4-3) and (4-4)) with risk of breakdown and outside options for

the Florida dairy market can be presented as

Dt

Dt

Dt XfP εα += ),( (4-5)

St

St

St XgP εβ += ),( (4-6)

Pt

Stt

Dtt PPP εττ +−+= )1( (4-7)

),( θτ τtt Xh= (4-8)

Qt

Dt

Sttt PP Q εγ +−= )( (4-9)

)]),(),(/[(1Q

XgQXf S

tDt

t ∂∂

−∂

∂=

βαγ (4-10)

where DtP , S

tP , tP and tQ are endogenous variables representing the demand reservation price for

the processor, the supply reservation price for SDC, the negotiated price and the negotiated

quantity; f, g and h represent functional forms; α , β , τ , θ and γ are estimated parameters; τ

81

and τ−1 are the bargaining parameters for SDC and milk processors; DtX , S

tX , and τtX are

exogenous variables which affect the demand reservation price ( DtP ), the supply reservation

price ( StP ) and the bargaining power parameter (τ ), respectively; D

tε , Stε , P

tε and Qtε are error

terms with constant variance 2Dσ , 2

Sσ , 2Pσ , and 2

Qσ , respectively.

Following the argument of Oczkowski (Oczkowski, 1999), theoretically, log-linear,

double-log and interaction permit all directional changes so that they are potentially fitted for

empirical analysis. The double log function is assumed in our research for the processor’s

demand reservation price (equation (4-11)) and SDC’s supply reservation price (equation (4-

12)). A logistic function is used to ensure that the bargaining power parameter τ is between zero

and one for equation (4-8) (equation (4-14)). Thus, the econometric model can be rewritten as

Dt

K

i

Ditit

Dt XQP εααα +++= ∑

=

1

210 )ln()ln()ln( (4-11)

St

K

i

Sitit

St XQP εβββ +++= ∑

=

2

210 )ln()ln()ln( (4-12)

Pt

Stt

Dttt PPP εττ +−+= )1( (4-13)

∑=

++=

3

10 )exp(1

1K

iiti

t

X τθθτ (4-14)

Qt

Dt

Sttt PP Q εγ +−= )( (4-15)

)/(1 11

QQtβα

γ −= (4-16)

where 1K , 2K and 3K represent the number of exogenous variables in equations (4-11), (4-12)

and (4-14), respectively, and all other terms are defined in equations (4-5) to (4-10).

82

4.3 Discussion of The Exogenous Variables

By rewriting the processor’s demand reservation price equation to include the exogenous

variables and the expected signs of the parameters, equation (4-11) becomes

Dttttt

Dt WPLCQP εααααα ++−+−= )ln()ln()1ln()ln()ln( 43210 (4-17)

where DtP is the demand reservation price for the processor; α are the parameters associated

with the exogenous variables; tQ is the negotiated quantity; tC1 is the Florida Federal Milk

Marketing Order (FMMO) #6 Class 1 price; tL is the labor cost index; and tWP is the wholesale

price index for dairy products; and all other terms are defined the same as in equations (4-5) to

(4-10).

Regarding the possible variables affecting the processor’s demand reservation price ( DtP ),

the more fluid milk the processors buy from SDC, the lower the price processors are willing to

pay. This indicates a negative relationship between negotiated quantity ( tQ ) and the processor’s

demand reservation price ( DtP ). For the dairy industry, there exists Federal Milk Marketing

Orders (FMMO) who set the Class 1 (fluid milk) price every month for each individual Federal

Milk Marketing Order area. Responding to FMMO policy, the class I price ( tC1 ) is the minimum

price that the fluid milk processors have to pay. The higher the class I price, the higher the

demand reservation is for processors1.

Both the cost of processing fluid milk and the price of selling the containerized fluid milk

to wholesalers needs to be considered. Among all the variable costs, labor accounts for 31.4% of

the cost of processing fluid milk (Dalton, Griner and Halloran, 2002). Thus, following Prato 1 Oczkowski Oczkowski, E. "An Econometric Analysis of the Bilateral Monopoly Model." Economic Modelling 16, no. 1(1999): 11. suggested that besides the factors affecting cost for SDC and net revenue for processors, other price variables may be considered.

83

(Prato, 1973), the total labor compensation index ( tL ) is used to examine the relationship

between labor cost and the processor’s demand reservation price ( DtP ). The higher the labor

input cost, the lower the processors demand reservation price which suggests a negative

relationship between them. Similarly, if the processors can sell their processed fluid milk to

wholesalers at a higher price ( tWP ), the higher the demand reservation price ( DtP ) will be.

To include the exogenous variables and the expected signs of the parameters in the

SDC’s supply reservation price, equation (4-12) becomes

Stttttt

St TCSFCCQP εββββββ ++−+++= )ln()ln()ln()1ln()ln()ln( 543210

(4-18)

where StP is the supply reservation price for SDC; β are the parameters associated with the

exogenous variables; tQ is the negotiated quantity; tC1 is the Florida FMMO #6 Class 1 price;

tFC is the feed cost index; tS represents seasonality; tTC is the transportation cost index; and

all other terms are defined the same in equations (4-5) to (4-10).

Considering the supply reservation price ( StP ) for SDC who represents dairy farmers, it is

partly associated with milk production ( tQ ).When the cost of milk production ( tQ ) increases,

StP goes up which implies a positive relationship between S

tP and tQ . Since the class 1 price is

the minimum price that processors must pay SDC for buying fluid milk. The Class 1 price ( tC1 )

will be used as a policy related exogenous variable. When the Florida Class 1 price is high, it

means that the minimum price is high. This suggests a positive relationship between StP and

tC1 .

The exogenous variables that go into the supply reservation price equation (equation (4-

14)) should include some major cost variables. Feed cost should be included ( tFC ). When tFC

84

is high, StP has to go up. Milk production per cow is chosen to represent seasonality ( tS ). SMI

states that the Florida’s summer heat reduces milk production

(http://www.southeastmilk.org/v2/about/). This increases production cost per cow which results

in a higher StP . This suggests a negative relationship between S

tP and tS . SMI states that

transportation cost is the major cost of selling fluid milk

(http://www.southeastmilk.org/v2/about/) to Florida processors ( tTC ).When cost increases, StP

goes up which implies a positive between tTC and StP .

The exogenous variables and the expected signs of the parameters in the bargaining power

equation (4-14) can be rewritten as

)*exp(11

10 tt OOPθθ

τ−+

= (4-19)

where tOOP is the over order premium for cooperatives (SDC).

For the bargaining power parameter, Oczkowski (Oczkowski, 1999) and Binmore, Rubinstein et

al. (Binmore, et al., 1986) suggest that the impatience of either buyer or seller has an impact on

the bargaining power parameter. The more patience the player is, the stronger bargaining power

that player has. The over order premium ( tOOP ) is calculated as the difference between the

negotiated price and class 1 price. When SDC expects to have a higher tOOP , SDC should be

more patient when negotiate with the processor. Therefore, the expected sign for the parameter

associated with the over order premium ( tOOP ) inside the logistic function should be negative

which implies that when the over order premium ( tOOP ) increases, SDC’s bargaining power

( tτ ) increases due to the functional form in equation (4-19).

85

4.4 Data Description

The data used for the above model are monthly time series data based on the monthly

negotiation process between SDC and processor(s). It ranges from October 1998 to May 2009

(APPENDIX B). All data are available at the websites of the Agricultural Marketing Service

(AMS), the Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS), and the National Agricultural Statistics Services

(NASS). The data set includes:

(1) Negotiated price ( tP in dollars per hundred weight) is the monthly cooperative announced fluid milk price in Miami, Florida (http://www.ams.usda.gov/AMSv1.0/ams.fetchTemplateData.do?template=TemplateF&navID=IndustryMarketingandPromotion&leftNav=IndustryMarketingandPromotion&page=AnnouncedCooperativeClassIPrices&description=Announced+Cooperative+Class+I+Prices&acct=dmktord);

(2) Negotiated quantity ( tQ in million pounds) is the monthly in area fluid milk sales for FMMO #6 in Florida (http://www.ams.usda.gov/AMSv1.0/ams.fetchTemplateData.do?startIndex=1&template=TemplateV&navID=IndustryMarketingandPromotion&leftNav=IndustryMarketingandPromotion&page=MilkMarketingandUtilizationIndividualOrdersYeartoDate&acct=dmktord);

(3) Class I price ( tC1 in dollars per hundred weight) is the monthly FMMO #6 minimum fluid milk price paid to farmers (http://www.ams.usda.gov/AMSv1.0/ams.fetchTemplateData.do?template=TemplateF&navID=IndustryMarketingandPromotion&leftNav=IndustryMarketingandPromotion&page=AnnouncedCooperativeClassIPrices&description=Announced+Cooperative+Class+I+Prices&acct=dmktord);

(4) Index of feed price paid by farmers ( tFC ) is the seasonally unadjusted index calculated from the survey of 48 contiguous states of the USA with the base period of 1990 to 1992 (http://usda.mannlib.cornell.edu/MannUsda/viewDocumentInfo.do?documentID=1002);

(5) Seasonality ( tS in pounds per cow) is the monthly milk production per cow in Florida (http://future.aae.wisc.edu/data/monthly_values/by_area/98?tab=production&grid=true&area=Florida);

(6) Transportation cost index ( tTC ) is the seasonally unadjusted Producer Price Index (PPI) for freight/truck transportation published by BLS every month based on June 1993 (http://www.bls.gov/schedule/archives/ppi_nr.htm);

86

(7) Labor cost index ( tL ) is the seasonally unadjusted total employment cost index of total compensation in the manufacturing industry based on 1989 which is used to represent the labor cost of processing fluid milk (http://www.bls.gov/schedule/archives/eci_nr.htm#2009);

(8) Fluid milk wholesale level price index ( tWP ) is the seasonally unadjusted PPI index for dairy products with the base year of 1982 (http://www.bls.gov/schedule/archives/ppi_nr.htm);

(9) The over-order-premium ( tOOP in dollars per hundred weight) is calculated by using the negotiated price ( tP ) minus the FMMO #6 Class I price ( tC1 ).

The data set that has been collected includes all exogenous variables and two endogenous

variables ( tP and tQ ). However, the other two endogenous variables ( DtP and S

tP ) are

uncollectable because they are the reservation prices for all the past negotiation period, and just

as the willingness to pay or sell prices for the past. Therefore, the collected data set is

incomplete. How to estimate the model with incomplete data set is a difficulty. This problem will

be addressed and solved in the next section.

4.5 Model Estimation

Quandt (Quandt, 1988) argues that disequilibrium models have two classes which are (1)

models where the observed demand is less or greater than the observed supply of a particular

good (the demand price is not equal to the supply price) and (2) models where the demand and

supply information is not available. The bargaining econometric model presented above showed

that the negotiated price lies between the demand reservation price (demand information) and the

supply reservation price (supply information) depending on the value of the bargaining power

parameter τ (equation (4-13)). The data for DtP and S

tP is not available which suggests that the

econometric bilateral bargaining model between Florida milk processors and SDC is a

disequilibrium model.

87

Quandt ((Quandt, 1988) suggested to estimate the disequilibrium model using maximum

likelihood estimation (MLE). The MLE method was pioneered by Fisher between 1912 and

1922 (Aldrich, 1997). Then, Oczkowski (Oczkowski, 1999) followed Quandt’s suggestion and

applied MLE in the disequilibrium model presented in his article and showed that the likelihood

function can be written as

Dt

StP

P

ttS

tD

t dPPdQPPPfLt

t

∫ ∫∞

∞−Π= ),,,( (4-20)

where ),,,( ttS

tD

t QPPPf is the joint density function of DtP , S

tP , tP , and tQ which are the

endogenous variables assuming a multivariate normal distribution. The likelihood function

presented here has double integrals inside as it was shown by Dempster et al (Dempster, et al.,

1977). This because the data set is incomplete where no data available for DtP and S

tP , the

probability density function (pdf) is then calculated by integrated the variables DtP and S

tP out.

Let’s define

4] [ ×= nQt

Pt

St

Dt εεεεε (4-21)

where Pt

St

Dt εεε ,, and Q

tε can be defined from equation (4-11) to equation (4-16), respectively, as

∑=

−−−=1

210 )ln()ln()ln(

K

i

Ditit

Dt

Dt XQP αααε (4-22)

∑=

−−−=2

210 )ln()ln()ln(

K

i

Sitit

St

St XQP βββε (4-23)

Stt

Dttt

Pt PPP )1( ττε −−−= (4-24)

)( Dt

Sttt

Qt PPQ −−= γε (4-25)

Then, by assumption, ε is distributed normally with zero mean and a variance-covariance

matrix Σ as

88

),0(~ ΣNε (4-26)

where the variance-covariance matrix ( Σ ) among equations can be defined as

442

PQSQ

PQ2

SP

SQSP2

DS

DQDPDS2

×

QDQ

PDP

S

D

σσσσ

σσσσ

σσσσ

σσσσ

(4-27)

where 2Dσ , 2

Sσ , 2Pσ , and 2

Qσ are the constant variances of the error terms Dtε , S

tε , Ptε and Q

tε ,

respectively; PQSQSPDP σσσσσσ and , , , , , DQDS are covariance between errors Dtε and S

tε , Dtε

and Ptε , D

tε and Qtε , S

tε and Ptε , S

tε and Qtε , P

tε and Qtε , respectively. Notice that all the variance

and covariance terms defined here are parameters to be estimated.

Thus, the joint normal density function can be written as

)21exp()2(),,,( 12/12/ εεπ −−− Σ−Σ= Tk

tttt QPATCARf (4-28)

where 4=k represents the number of error terms; ε and Σ are defined above in equations (4-21)

to (4-25) and equation (4-27), respectively. By substituting the joint normal density function

(equation (4-28)) into the likelihood function (equation (4-20)), the likelihood function of the

econometric model presented here can be then written as

Dt

StP

P Tk dPPdLt

t

∫ ∫∞

∞−

−−− Σ−ΣΠ= )]21exp()2[( 12/12/ εεπ . (4-29)

Recall that the data for DtP and S

tP is not available. So to maximize this likelihood

function (equation (4-29)) is difficult. This issue is solved by using the Expectation

Maximization (EM) algorithm (Dempster, et al., 1977). This method was used by Oczkowski

(Oczkowski, 1999) with the assumption that the covariance among all equations was zero. The

covariance assumption is not made in this dissertation. As suggested by Dempster , Laird and

89

Rubin (Dempster, et al., 1977), the EM algorithm includes two major steps which are expectation

and maximization. The first step is expectation which will find the expectation of the unobserved

variables ( DtP and S

tP ) based on the specified model (equation (4-11) through (4-12)). The

second step is the maximization step which says that once the unobserved data is calculated by

using the expectation, the data set will be considered complete and then the regular log-

likelihood function will be maximized to get the optimum level parameter estimates which then

are used to calculate the expectation step again for the unobserved variables followed by another

maximization step. This process continues until the optimum level parameter estimates for two

consecutive EM algorithm runs converge.

To explain the EM algorithm mathematically, for the empirical model, the supply

reservation price for SDC ( DtP ) and the demand reservation price for processors ( S

tP ) are

unobservable. Following the assumption that all errors have zero means, the mean of DtP and

StP can be calculated from equation (4-11) and (4-12) to get

])ln()ln(exp[_1

210 ∑

=

++=K

i

Ditit

Dt XQPMean ααα (4-30)

])ln()ln(exp[_2

210 ∑

=

++=K

i

Sitit

St XQPMean βββ (4-31)

where α and β are estimated parameters associated with the exogenous variables which are

defined in equation (4-11) to equation (4-16). Once the means for DtP and S

tP are computed, for

a given variance covariance matrix between DtP and S

tP , the data for DtP and S

tP are simulated

from the bilateral distribution which is assumed.

Once the expectation step is done as shown by Dempster, et al. (Dempster, et al., 1977),

the second step is to maximize the likelihood function using a complete data set including

90

DtP and S

tP simulated in the expectation step. Following Greene (Greene, 2008) but in matrix

form, the likelihood function that will be maximized for the normal distribution in the

maximization step is

)]21exp()2[( 12/12/ εεπ −−− Σ−ΣΠ= TkL

. (4-32)

Then, the log-likelihood function to be maximized becomes

∑=

−Σ−Σ−−=n

itt

nknL1

1' )(21ln

2)2ln(

2ln εεπ (4-33)

where k is the number of normally distributed variables; n is the number of observations; Σ is

the variance covariance matrix defined in equation (4-27); and ε is a matrix of all errors for all

observations and all equations defined in equations (4-21) to (4-25). To maximize equation (4-

33), the necessary condition is that all parameters should be solved by setting the first order

derivatives with respect to all parameters equal to zero and the sufficient condition is that the

Hessian matrix (second order derivatives) has to be negative definite. The first order conditions

(FOC) are

0'2

ln 1 =Σ=∂∂ −εµ

xnL (4-34)

0)'(21

2ln 11 =ΣΣ+

Σ−=

Σ∂∂ −− εεnL (4-35)

where x is the exogenous variables arranged horizontally for all equations with errors. The FOC

are solved to get the maximum likelihood estimator (MLE) for the variance covariance matrix as

εε '1n

MLE =Σ∧

. (4-36)

91

Following Greene ((Greene, 2008), p533), substitute the solution (equation (4-36)) of the

variance-covariance matrix Σ into the log-likelihood function (equation (4-33)). Then the log-

likelihood function becomes the concentrated log-likelihood function

εεπ '1ln2

)2ln(22

lnn

nnknkL −−−= . (4-37)

Notice that the first and second terms are constant. Thus, the MLE of all coefficients for all

variables can be found through minimizing εε 'ln . Based on the law of large numbers, MLE has

the following asymptotic properties (Greene, 2008): asymptotic normal, consistent and

asymptotic efficient because the variance-covariance has achieved the Cramer-Rao Lower

bound. So the second step of the EM algorithm for maximization finishes here. If the last two

parameter estimates from the EM algorithm do not converge, the process starts over from the

expectation step to maximization step and continues until the last two parameter estimates

converge.

By using the EM algorithm on the expectation step (equation (4-30) and (4-31)) and the

maximization step (maximizing equation (4-37) by MLE), the parameter estimates are consistent

parameter estimates for the likelihood function presented in equation (4-29). In summary, by

assuming error terms that are distributed normal, the EM algorithm and the MLE are used to

estimate the empirical model for Florida dairy market. The statistical software GAUSS is used

for programming (APPENDIX C).

4.6 Summary

Since milk price bargaining in the Florida dairy market actually occurs between one

cooperative and one processor, the theoretical bilateral bargaining model can be applied to this

market. Moreover, during the past twenty five plus years which implies more than three hundred

negotiation periods, negotiations broke down only once. This suggests a very low probability for

92

both players to opt out and contract with out of state cooperatives or processors. Thus, by

assuming the probability of breakdown equals to zero, the common solution of Chapter 3 (

equations (4-1) and (4-2)) can be analyzed econometrically for the Florida dairy market to

examine the bargaining power of both players (equation (4-1) and (4-2)). The data was collected

as time series data from October 1998 to May 2009. However, the data set is incomplete due to

the unobservable supply reservation price for SDC and the demand reservation price for

processors. The incomplete data set problem is solved by using the EM algorithm and MLE to

estimate the model by programming inside GAUSS software (APPENDIX C).

93

CHAPTER 5 RESULTS

5.1 Summary Statistics

Following all the variables defined in chapter 4, the summary statistics of the data are

shown in Table 5-1. Negotiated price ( tP ) has the mean of $21.35 per hundredweight with a

minimum of $17.16 and a maximum of $31.37. The negotiated quantity ( tQ ) has the average of

209.82 million pounds with the minimum at 169 million pounds and the maximum at 242.10

million pounds.

Table 5-1. Summary Statistics of Data Variables Mean Standard Deviation Minimum Maximum

tP 21.35a 3.46 17.16a 31.37a

tQ 209.82b 15.48 169.00b 242.10b

tC1 18.33a 3.23 13.94a 26.78a

tFC 125.95c 29.66 96.00c 217.00c

tS 1346.47d 181.11 1020.00d 1760.00d

tTC 133.69c 14.07 112.40c 164.74c

tL 168.44c 17.38 138.90c 193.45c

tWP 151.24c 16.66 130.10c 189.50c

tOOP 3.02a 0.68 1.94a 4.85a

a Dollars per hundredweight. b Million pounds per month. c Index with various base yearS. d Pounds per cow per month.

The data correlations in Table 5-2 shows that a majority of the exogenous variables are less

than 0.5, and only two are 0.9 and above. The negotiated price ( tP ) and negotiated quantity ( tQ )

are endogenous variables. However, the correlation between the wholesale dairy price index

( tWP ) and the Class 1 price ( tC1 ) is 0.9 and between the labor index ( tL ) and transportation cost

index ( tTC ) is 0.97.

94

Table 5-2. Correlation Matrix of Data tP tQ tC1 tFC tS tTC tL tWP tOOP

tP 1.00

tQ 0.11 1.00

tC1 0.98 0.07 1.00

tFC 0.68 0.27 0.57 1.00

tS 0.09 0.74 0.05 0.36 1.00

tTC 0.61 0.30 0.50 0.86 0.32 1.00

tL 0.52 0.29 0.42 0.78 0.35 0.97 1.00

tWP 0.94 0.15 0.90 0.78 0.17 0.78 0.72 1.00

tOOP 0.43 0.26 0.25 0.74 0.23 0.73 0.62 0.53 1.00 The data collected is time series data with data for two endogenous variables are

simulated. As Cecchetti et al. (Cecchetti, et al., 2006) pointed out that the stationary residuals are

necessary for the reliability of the estimated parameters. First of all, all variables (Table 5-1) are

tested stationary individually by using Phillips and Perron (Phillips and Perron, 1988) test where

the null hypothesis is with unit root and the alternative hypothesis is stationary data. The results

suggest that among all 9 variables, only four of them are stationary at 5% significant level.

Therefore, the residuals are further tested. The test results reject the null hypothesis at 1%

significant level for all residuals which suggest that statistically, all residuals are stationary and

implies that the parameter estimated shown in the next section are reliable.

5.2 Parameter Estimates

The econometric model is

Dttttt

Dt WPLCQP εααααα ˆ)ln(ˆ)ln(ˆ)1ln(ˆ)ln(ˆˆ)ln( 43210 ++−+−= (5-1)

Stttttt

St TCSFCCQP εββββββ ˆ)ln(ˆ)ln(ˆ)ln(ˆ)1ln(ˆ)ln(ˆˆ)ln( 543210 ++−+++= (5-2)

Pt

Stt

Dttt PPP εττ ˆ)ˆ1(ˆ +−+= (5-3)

95

)*ˆˆexp(11ˆ

10 tt OOPθθ

τ−+

= (5-4)

Qt

Dt

Sttt PP Q εγ ˆ)(ˆ +−= (5-5)

)ˆˆ

/(1ˆ 11

QQtβα

γ −−

= (5-6)

where DtP , S

tP , tP and tQ are endogenous variables representing the processor’s demand

reservation price, the SDC’s supply reservation price, the negotiated price and the negotiated

quantity; α , β , τ , θ and γ are estimated coefficients; tC1 is the Florida Class 1 price; tL is the

labor cost index; tWP is the wholesale price index for dairy products; tFC is the feed cost index;

tS is the monthly average Florida production per cow which represents seasonality; tTC is the

transportation cost index; τ and τ1− are the bargaining power coefficients for SDC and the milk

processor; tOOP is the over order premium for SDC; Dtε , S

tε , Ptε and Q

tε are estimated standard

errors with constant variance 2Dσ , 2

Sσ , 2Pσ , and 2

Qσ , respectively.

Serial correlation and heteroscedasticity are potential problems that need to be dealt with

to ensure consistent estimators. Generally, time series data might have serial correlation but no

heteroscedasticity. The Durbin-Watson d test was used to test for serial correlation. Positive

serial correlation was found for equations 5-1, 5-2, 5-3 and 5-5. However, the MLE coefficient

estimates are asymptotically consistent (Levine, 1983). In addition, by using MLE to estimate the

model, the correction for serial correlation is intractable (Oczkowski, 1999). So, no corrections

were done.

The results show that all signs of the coefficients are the same as theoretically expected

except the sign of the parameter for transportation cost ( tTC ) (Table 5-3). However, the

96

coefficient estimate for tTC is insignificant which indicates that the estimated coefficient (-

2.5099) is not different from zero, statistically.

Table 5-3. Coefficient Estimates equations Variables Coefficient Estimates standard error

DtP Constant 1.3316 1.2011

tQ -0.0072 0.1612 tC1 0.6974*** 0.2548 tL -0.0308 0.1732 tWP 0.0165 0.3895

StP Constant -30.0392*** 0.9317

tQ 14.1532*** 1.5892 tC1 1.9391 4.6594 tFC 1.1535 3.1874 tS -5.8438* 3.4020 tTC -2.5099 3.0431 τ Constant 0.4814 0.6499 tOOP -0.4547* 0.2473

tP DtP 0.7055***(1) 0.0603

StP 0.2945***(1) 0.0603

tQ Dt

St PP − -14.8174***(1) 1.0931

*** 0.01 significance ** 0.05 significance * 0.1 significance (1) The coefficients for tP and tQ equations are the average coefficients

In the demand reservation price equation ( D

tP ), the estimated coefficients (Table 5-3) are

insignificant (statistically not different from zero) except the coefficient (0.6974) for the class I

price ( tC1 ). This suggests that when tC1 increases by one percent, the processors demand

reservation price goes up by 0.6974%. This result is reasonable because for fluid milk

processors, the class I price is the minimum price that they have to pay. This result implies that

government policy has a huge impact on the demand reservation price.

97

In the supply reservation price equation ( StP ), the estimated coefficients for the Constant,

negotiated quantity ( tQ ) and seasonality ( tS ) are significant. All other coefficients are

insignificant which implies that they are statistically not different from zero. The coefficient of

negotiated quantity ( tQ ) is 14.1532 which suggests that when the negotiated quantity increases

by one percent, the supply reservation price for SDC goes up by 14.1532%. The coefficient of

seasonality ( tS ) is -5.8438, which indicates that when the production per cow deceases by one

percent, the supply reservation price will increase by 5.8438%. The results suggest that quantity

is very important for SDC. When SDC has a surplus quantity, they have to sell them to the

manufacture plants. If the quantity is in deficit, SDC has to have more members from outside of

Florida to be able to meet the demand of the processors. The similar results also founded by

Folwell (Folwell, et al., 1998) for the analysis in tomato processing industry.

In the τ equation, the coefficient (-0.4547) for the over order premium ( tOOP ) is

negative and statistically significant. Recall that the bargaining power parameter (τ ) for SDC is

a logistic function of tOOP . This indicates that if tOOP between the Class I price (C1) and the

announced fluid milk price goes up, SDC is more patient during the negotiation, thus the

bargaining power for SDC goes up. This means that the bargaining power for processors goes

down by the same magnitude.

In the negotiated price equation ( tP ), both average coefficients for the demand

reservation price ( DtP ) and supply reservation price ( S

tP ) are statistically significant. If DtP

increases by one unit, tP will increase by 0.7055 units. One unit increase in StP will increase tP

by 0.2945 units.

98

In the negotiated quantity equation ( tQ ), the coefficient of the difference between the

supply reservation price and the demand reservation price ( Dt

St PP − ) is statistically significant

which shows that if Dt

St PP − gets larger by one unit, in other words, if the rang of the supply

reservation price and the demand reservation price gets larger, tQ will decrease by 14.8174

unites.

5.3 Bargaining Power Parameter

Table 5-4. Monthly Bargaining Power Coefficient Estimates for SDC and Processors

Months SDC Bargaining Power Estimates

Processors Bargaining Power Estimates

Differences Standard Errors(1)

January 0.6990*** 0.3010*** 0.3980 0.0511 Febuary 0.7158*** 0.2842*** 0.4316 0.0541 March 0.7099*** 0.2901*** 0.4198 0.0600 April 0.7210*** 0.2790*** 0.4420 0.0583 May 0.7094*** 0.2906*** 0.4188 0.0662 June 0.7032*** 0.2968*** 0.4064 0.0743 July 0.7065*** 0.2935*** 0.4130 0.0698 August 0.7100*** 0.2900*** 0.4200 0.0690 September 0.7101*** 0.2899*** 0.4202 0.0652 October 0.6903*** 0.3097*** 0.3806 0.0675 November 0.6889*** 0.3111*** 0.3778 0.0654 December 0.7031*** 0.2969*** 0.4062 0.0540 mean 0.7055*** 0.2945*** 0.4110 0.0603 *** 0.01 significance different from 0 (1) Standard errors are the same for both SDC’s bargaining power and processors’ bargaining power.

All monthly bargaining power coefficient estimates for both SDC and processors are

statistically significant and different from 0 (Table 5-4). Further, all monthly estimates are

statistically different from 0.5 which suggests that SDC and the processors have unequal

bargaining power during negotiations. The average bargaining power for SDC is 0.7055 where

the monthly average varies from 0.6889 in November to 0.7210 in April (Table 5-4). The

average bargaining power for processors is 0.2945 where the monthly average varies from

99

0.2790 in April to the highest 0.3111 in November. The overall average bargaining power

difference between SDC and the processors is 0.4110 which suggests that the overall bargaining

power for SDC is higher than the bargaining power for processors. The biggest bargaining power

difference between SDC and processors occurred in April (0.4420) and the lowest appeared in

November (0.3778).

Although we did not expect any seasonality among months, a statistical one tail t test was

used to examine whether SDC (processors) has the highest (lowest) bargaining power in April,

and whether SDC (processors) has the lowest (highest) bargaining power in November. The

results (Appendix B) show that statistically, there is no evidence to reject the null hypothesis

such that there is no difference between the bargaining power parameter for SDC (processors) in

April (November) and the bargaining power in the remaining 11 months. This indicates that

statistically, there is no difference among all monthly bargaining power coefficients for SDC.

The same result for processors. This implies that there is no seasonality among the months.

All yearly bargaining power coefficient estimates for both SDC and the processors are

statistically significant and different from 0 (Tables 5-5). In addition, all yearly estimates are

statistically different from 0.5 which suggests that SDC and processors have unequal bargaining

power over years. Compared to the monthly estimates, the yearly bargaining power for SDC

varies more from 0.6316 in 2001 to 0.8146 in 2008, while that for processors varies from 0.1854

in 2008 to 0.3684 in 2001. The difference among the yearly bargaining power estimates between

SDC and the processors ranges from 0.6292 in 2008 to 0.2631 in 2001.

In addition, a statistical one tail t test was used to analyze whether the SDC (processors)

has the highest (lowest) bargaining power in 2008, and whether SDC (processors) has the lowest

(highest) bargaining power in 2001. The results (Appendix D) show that statistically, there is

100

evidence to reject the null hypothesis such that the yearly average bargaining power in 2008 is

different from that in other years and in favor of the alternative hypothesis such that SDC

(processors) has the highest (lowest) yearly average bargaining power in 2008. Furthermore, the

null hypothesis of the yearly bargaining power in 2001 is not different from that in 2004;

however, the null hypotheses is rejected for all other years and indicates that SDC (processors)

has the lowest (highest) yearly average bargaining power in 2001. This implies that for the year

of 2001 and 2004, SDC (processors) has the lowest (highest) bargaining power.

Table 5-5. Yearly Bargaining Power Coefficient Estimates for SDC and Processors

Year SDC Bargaining Power Estimates

Processors Bargaining Power Estimates

Differences Standard Errors(1)

1998 0.6783*** 0.3217*** 0.3566 0.0124 1999 0.6630*** 0.3370*** 0.3260 0.0395 2000 0.6847*** 0.3153*** 0.3694 0.0265 2001 0.6316*** 0.3684*** 0.2631 0.0227 2002 0.7111*** 0.2889*** 0.4222 0.0271 2003 0.6960*** 0.3040*** 0.3920 0.0420 2004 0.6462*** 0.3538*** 0.2924 0.0327 2005 0.6855*** 0.3145*** 0.3710 0.0255 2006 0.7489*** 0.2511*** 0.4978 0.0250 2007 0.7665*** 0.2335*** 0.5331 0.0170 2008 0.8146*** 0.1854*** 0.6292 0.0351 2009 0.7394*** 0.2606*** 0.4788 0.0249 mean 0.7055*** 0.2945*** 0.4110 0.0603 *** 0.01 significant level different from 0 (1) Standard errors are the same for both SDC’s bargaining power and processors’ bargaining power

Graphically, the bargaining power for SDC has the same trend as the over-order premium

for SDC in the entire negotiation period from October 1998 to May 2009. Recall that for

cooperatives, the negotiated price is the sum of the Class I price and the over-order premium.

The class I price is a fixed minimum price that processors have to pay. So a higher bargaining

power for SDC implies more over-order premium for SDC. Figure 5-1 shows this positive

relationship for the bargaining power coefficient τ and over-order premium for cooperatives.

101

They are highly correlated with lowest point in 2001 and highest point in 2008 and an upward

trend started in 2004 through 2008 and started down in 2009.

Year

99 01 03 05 07 09 98 00 02 04 06 08 10

τ

0.5

0.6

0.7

0.8

0.9

1.0

Ove

r Ord

er P

rem

ium

($

per

hun

dred

wei

ght)

0

1

2

3

4

5

6τOver Order Premium

Figure 5-1. SDC’s Monthly Bargaining Power Coefficient and Over-order Premium

5.4 Variance Covariance

Let’s look at the estimated variance covariance matrix from the MLE even though they are

inconsistent due to the presence of serial correlation. The estimated variance covariance matrix

( Σ ) among equations is

4*42

PQSQ

PQ2

SP

SQSP2

DS

DQDPDS2

ˆ ˆ ˆ ˆ

ˆ ˆ ˆ ˆ

ˆ ˆ ˆ ˆ

ˆ ˆ ˆ ˆ

ˆ

QDQ

PDP

S

D

σσσσ

σσσσ

σσσσ

σσσσ

(5-7)

102

where 2ˆ Dσ , 2ˆ Sσ , 2ˆ Pσ , and 2ˆQσ are the constant variance of the error terms Dtε , S

tε , Ptε and Q

tε ,

respectively; PQSQSPDP σσσσσσ ˆ and ,ˆ ,ˆ ,ˆ ,ˆ ,ˆ DQDS are covariance between errors Dtε and S

tε , Dtε

and Ptε , D

tε and Qtε , S

tε and Ptε , S

tε and Qtε , P

tε and Qtε , respectively. Following the definition in

equation 5-7, testing the null hypothesis that all covariances are zero by using the likelihood ratio

test

)()ln(ln2 2 kxLL UR →−− (5-8)

where RL is the likelihood value for the restricted model by restricting the covariance terms to

equal zero; UL is the likelihood value for the unrestricted model (covariance are not restricted to

zero) which is the model that has been presented and estimated in chapter 4; the statistic

)ln(ln2 UR LL −− follows a chi-square distribution with k (the number of restrictions) degrees of

freedom (Greene, 2008). Thus, the null hypothesis that all covariances equal zero can be written

as

Ho: 0ˆ ˆ ˆ ˆ ˆ ˆ DQDS ====== PQSQSPDP σσσσσσ

Ha: not all co-variances are zero

Table 5-6. Test Result for Zero Covariance ln RL ln UL )ln(ln2 UR LL −− 01.0 )6(2 atx

-1018 -717 601 16.8119

The result (Table 5-6) indicates that the test statistic (601) is larger then the associated

chi-square value (16.8119). The null hypothesis is rejected which implies that there is only a 1%

probability that the null hypothesis of all zero covariances is true. This result indicates that one

or more non-zero covariances among equation DtP , S

tP ,P and Q do exist.

103

CHAPTER 6 SUMMARY, CONCLUSIONS AND IMPLICATIONS

6.1 Summary

In chapter 2, a comprehensive literature review was done on three major categories. The

first category is bargaining theory including bilateral bargaining and multilateral bargaining

theory review. The second category is distributional channels bargaining including supply chain

and especially the cooperatives bargaining theory review. The third category is the empirical

applications associated with bargaining theory.

In summary, bargaining theory was developed by two different approaches: the axiomatic

approach and the strategic approach. The axiomatic approach is based on four axioms which

include Invariance to positive affine transformations (IAT), Symmetry (SYM), Pareto optimality

(PAR) and Independence of irrelevant alternatives (IIA). This approach develops the bargaining

model for two monopoly/monoposony players, and then easily extends to a multilateral model.

The solution for the axiomatic approach model is the generalized Nash bargaining solution for

both the bilateral and multilateral models.

The strategic approach had difficulties extending the model from bilateral to multilateral

with outside options and risk of breakdown. Two different methods were used to solve the

difficulties. One is to reduce the multilateral strategic game to a multistage game by forming

coalitions in the first stage and bilateral bargaining as the second stage. The other method is to

reduce the game to a series of bilateral games. The solution to the strategic approach model

approximated the generalized Nash bargaining solution for both the bilateral and multilateral

models at the limit when the negotiation time period goes to zero.

In chapter 3, a theoretical strategic bargaining model was developed for bilateral

bargaining with outside options for both sides under the assumption that when negotiation

104

breakdown occurs, both players will go to outside options. Three cases were discussed when the

outside option price was fixed or variable for any existing quantity. When the probability of

negotiation breakdown goes to zero, the model was solved by using the generalized Nash

bargaining solution and the common solution of all three cases indicates that the negotiated price

is between the processor’s average net revenue and SDC’s average total cost depending on the

bargaining power for each side. The negotiated quantity is also a function of the processor’s

average net revenue and SDC’s average total cost. The interesting result is that under the

assumption that both SDC and processor can opt out when breakdown occurs, outside options

only affects the solution of the case where one outside option price is variable and the other one

is fixed.

An empirical econometric model was developed for the Florida dairy market.

Econometrically, the common solution to the Nash model was developed into a six equation

disequilibrium econometric model. The time series data for the econometric model, from

October 1998 to May 2009, is incomplete due to the unavailable supply reservation price

(average total cost) for SDC and the unavailable demand reservation price (average net revenue)

for processor(s). The estimation difficulty of incomplete data was solved by using the

expectation maximization (EM) algorithm along with maximum likelihood estimation (MLE)

inside the EM algorithm where the concentrated log-likelihood function was estimated.

The results were then presented in chapter 5. The data was tested for serial correlation and

heteroscedasticity. The results show that serial correlation does exist for all four error terms, but

no evidence of heteroscedasticity was found. This implies that the coefficient estimates are

consistent. The coefficient estimates for all exogenous variables and the bargaining power

coefficient τ were presented and discussed.

105

6.2 Conclusions

Regardless of bilateral or multi player games, no matter what approach is used, the

generalized Nash bargaining solution of bilateral bargaining can be used to solve these

negotiation problems when negotiation time goes to zero. Therefore, the strategic approach was

adopted to develop the theoretical bilateral bargaining model with outside options and risk of

breakdown under the assumption that both sides are maximizing their profits. The common

solution of the Nash model was chosen for empirical use to examine the bargaining power for

dairy cooperatives and Florida fluid milk processors.

The negotiated price is influenced the most by the class I price (C1) set by the FMMO #6.

The market intervention by the FMMO significantly influences the demand reservation price set

by the processors. The coefficient of C1 is much larger than the coefficients of any other

variables even through their signs are correct. Further, the coefficient estimate for the negotiated

quantity turns out to be statistically insignificant which implies that negotiated quantity is

actually not a major issue for processors. Processors need the milk and they know that there is a

minimum price they must pay. This suggests a certain a mount of impatience by the processors.

On the supply side, the negotiated quantity and seasonality are the most significant factors

for SDC. The negotiated quantity is important because SDC must find milk in deficit months and

must sell milk to manufacturing plants during surplus months. This influences their supply

reservation price. Furthermore, seasonality in milk production influences the cost to produce.

Hot weather decreases milk production per cow and expenses per hundredweight of milk are

increased. This causes the average total cost per cow to increase which increases SDC’s supply

reservation price.

The results for the bargaining power coefficient τ show that statistically the monthly and

yearly average bargaining power coefficient estimates are different from 0.5, and the average

106

bargaining power for SDC (0.7055) is higher than the average bargaining power for processors

(0.2945). The reasons for this were explained by Prasertsri and Kilmer (Prasertsri and Kilmer,

2008). First, Florida milk “processors are more impatient than SDC because they have buyers

who need a continuous supply of dairy products.” Second, if negotiation breaks down, Florida

milk processors must go outside of the state to find milk suppliers whose milk will not be as

fresh as the milk provided by SDC considering the time for transportation. Third, the cost of

delivering milk to Florida processors from non-Florida milk suppliers is high which will result in

a higher price to processors.

All monthly and yearly bargaining power coefficients are statistically different from zero.

This suggests that the model captures well the bilateral bargaining between SDC and Florida

milk processors. The bargaining is bilateral bargaining which means that both sides have some

bargaining power but neither side has absolute power (bargaining power coefficient estimates are

different from zero). If one side had absolute power, then the bargaining process would not begin

in the first place.

Furthermore, the monthly bargaining power coefficient estimates are statistically the same

for each month for both SDC and processors. However, the yearly average bargaining power

coefficient estimates vary. SDC (processors) has the lowest (highest) yearly bargaining power in

2001 and year 2004, and the highest (lowest) yearly bargaining power in 2008. This occurred

because the over order premium trended upward from 2004 to 2008.

Theoretically, when the bargaining power for SDC is high, the over-order premium above

the class I price should be high which gives more revenue to dairy farmers. The estimated results

from the empirical model capture and present this theoretical explanation well such that the

bargaining power coefficient for SDC and the over-order premium trends in the same direction

107

with the lowest value for both of them occurring in 2001 and highest values for both of them

appearing in 2008.

Over all, the model indicates that on average, SDC has higher bargaining power than

Florida milk processors which suggests that SDC is competitive with processors during the

negotiation process. Class I price is the most important factor for processors when buying milk

from SDC. Negotiated quantity is more important for SDC when it comes to bargaining.

6.3 Implications

Increasing Class 1 price increases the demand reservation price for processors which raises

the negotiated price. Thus, dairy policy, a price floor policy (class 1 price) set by the Federal

Milk Marketing Order (FMMO), has a strong impact on negotiated prices. Government

intervention matters for processors.

Higher bargaining power for SDC but statistically, non-variable monthly bargaining power

parameters for both SDC and processors indicate that both SDC and processors are effective

negotiators. However, compared to monthly bargaining power, the variable yearly bargaining

power suggests a dynamic bargaining environment.

On the supply side, the supply reservation price is more volatile than the demand

reservation price. This suggests that SDC must put more time into determining its reservation

price than the processors. The quantity turns out to be a very important factor for SDC. Further,

SDC has the ability to deal with the surplus (selling the product to the manufacturing plants) or

deficit (needing more milk) situation in quantity. This suggests that they are more patient during

negotiation which results in higher bargaining power.

6.4 Further Research

Thus, future research can be done in the following areas: (1) extend the bargaining power

equation to include risk preferences; (2) the method can be used in other commodity markets; (3)

108

building more complex dynamic strategic approaches for bilateral markets and how to

econometrically estimate the dynamic bargaining power coefficients over time; (4) develop multi

player games for oligopoly market structure; (5) research related to examining whether the

negotiated price would be different if there were no price floor policy or other similar price

policies.

109

APPENDIX A CALCULATION OF THE NEGOTIATED QUANTITY Q

τWBrBr

τWArAr ]πp)π-p[(]πp)π-p[( F −++= 1

)Q(P,11 max (A-1)

where

)]([)( QATCPQQCPQ CPCPA −=−=π (A-2)

)]([)( QATCPQQCQP COC

OCOC

OWA −=−=π (A-3)

])()([)( PQABQARQBPQQR PCPCPCPCB −−=−−=π (A-4)

])()([)( POPOPOPO

POPOWB PQABQARQBQPQR −−=−−=π (A-5)

Solve for the negotiated quantity Q by using the first order condition of equation (A-1)

with respect to Q

0][])[[1(][][ 11 =∂∂

−+∂∂

=∂∂ −−−

QQQF RO

BROB

ROA

ROB

ROARO

ππτππ

πτ ττττ . (A-6)

Multiplying both sides by τπ −1][ ROA , then

0]][)[1(][ 1 =∂∂

−+∂∂ −−

QQ

ROBRO

BROA

ROB

ROA π

ππτππ

τ ττ (A-7)

Multiplying both sides by τπ ][ ROB , then

0][)1(][. =∂∂

−+∂∂ RO

A

ROBRO

B

ROA

QQπ

πτπ

πτ . (A-8)

Then, solve for Q

ROA

∂∂π and

Q

ROB

∂∂π

])(

)1())(1[(

QATC

QpATCPp

QATC

QpATCPpQ

COrCO

COr

CPrCPr

ROA

∂∂

−−+

∂∂

−−−−=∂∂π

(A-9)

110

)]()([

)]()1())(1[(

QAB

QARQpPABARp

QAB

QARQpPABARp

Q

POPOr

POPOPOr

PCPCrPCPCr

ROB

∂∂

−∂

∂+−−+

∂∂

−∂

∂−+−−−=

∂∂π

(A-10)

Then, substitute ROBπ

and equation (A-9) into the first part of equation (A-8) to get

)])()((

))()(()1[(

])(

)1())(1[(][

POPOPOr

PCPCr

COrCO

COr

CPrCPr

ROB

ROA

PQABQARQpPQABQARQp

QATCQpATCPp

QATCQpATCPp

Q

−−+

−−−•∂

∂−−+

∂∂

−−−−=∂∂ τππτ

(A-11)

Extend all terms of equation (A-11) to get

))()((

))()()(1(

))()(()(

))()(()1)((

))()(()1(

))()(()1(

))()(())(1(

))()(()()1(][

22

2

2

2

22

2

POPOPO

COr

PCPCrCO

r

POPOPOCO

COr

PCPCrCOC

Or

POPOPOr

CPr

PCPCCP

r

POPOPOrCPr

PCPCCPrROB

ROA

PQABQARQ

ATCQpτ

PQABQARpQ

ATCQp

PQABQARQATCPpPQABQARQpATCPp

PQABQARpQ

ATCQp

PQABQARQ

ATCQp

PQABQARQpATCPp

PQABQARQATCPpQ

−−∂

∂−

−−−∂

∂−

−−−+

−−−−+

−−∂

∂−−

−−∂

∂−−

−−−−+

−−−−=∂∂

τ

τ

τ

τ

τ

τ

τππτ

(A-12)

Then, substitute ROAπ and equation (A-10) into the second part of equation (A-8) to get

111

))]((.))(()1[(

)]()(

)()1())(1)[(1(

][)1(

QATCPQpQATCPQpQ

ABQ

ARQpPABARp

QAB

QARQpPABARp

Q

COC

OrCPr

POPOr

POPOPOr

PCPCrPCPCr

ROA

ROB

−+−−•

∂∂

−∂

∂+−−+

∂∂

−∂

∂−+−−−−=

∂∂

τ

ππτ

(A-13)

Extend all terms of equation (A-13) to get

))()((

))()(1)((

))(()(

))(()1)((

))(()()1(

))()(()1(

))(())(1(

))(()()1(

))()((

))()(1)((

))(()(

))(()1)((

))(()()1(

))()(()1(

))(())(1(

))(()()1(

][)1(

22

2

2

2

22

2

22

2

2

2

22

2

QATCPQ

ABQ

ARQp

QATCPpQ

ABQ

ARQp

QATCPQPABARpQATCPQpPABARp

QATCPpQ

ABQ

ARQp

QATCPQ

ABQ

ARQp

QATCPQpPABARpQATCPQPABARp

QATCPQ

ABQ

ARQp

QATCPpQ

ABQ

ARQp

QATCPQPABARpQATCPQpPABARp

QATCPpQ

ABQ

ARQp

QATCPQ

ABQ

ARQp

QATCPQpPABARpQATCPQPABARp

Q

COC

OPOPO

r

CPrPOPO

r

COC

OP

OPOPOr

CPrP

OPOPOr

COC

OrPCPC

r

CPPCPC

r

COC

OrPCPCr

CPPCPCr

COC

OPOPO

r

CPrPOPO

r

COC

OP

OPOPOr

CPrP

OPOPOr

COC

OrPCPC

r

CPPCPC

r

COC

OrPCPCr

CPPCPCr

ROA

ROB

−∂

∂−

∂∂

−−∂

∂−

∂∂

−−−−

−−−−−

−∂

∂−

∂∂

−−

−∂

∂−

∂∂

−−

−−−−−

−−−−−

−∂

∂−

∂∂

+

−−∂

∂−

∂∂

+

−−−+

−−−−+

−∂

∂−

∂∂

−+

−∂

∂−

∂∂

−+

−−−−+

−−−−=

∂∂

τ

τ

τ

τ

τ

τ

τ

τ

ππτ

(A-14)

112

Substitute equation (A-12) and (A-14) into equation (A-8) to get

0))()((

))()(1)((

))(()(

))(()1)((

))(()()1(

))()(()1(

))(())(1(

))()((

))()(1)((

))(()(

))(()1)((

))(()()1(

))()(()1(

))(())(1(

))(()()1(

))()((

))()()(1(

))()(()(

))()(()1)((

))()((.)1(

))()(()1(

))()(())(1(

22

2

2

2

22

22

2

2

2

22

2

22

2

2

2

22

=−∂

∂−

∂∂

−−∂

∂−

∂∂

−−−−

−−−−−

−∂

∂−

∂∂

−−

−∂

∂−

∂∂

−−

−−−−−

−∂

∂−

∂∂

+

−−∂

∂−

∂∂

+

−−−+

−−−−+

−∂

∂−

∂∂

−+

−∂

∂−

∂∂

−+

−−−−+

−−−−+

−−∂

∂−

−−−∂

∂−

−−−+

−−−−+

−−∂

∂−−

−−∂

∂−−

−−−−+

QATCPQ

ABQ

ARQp

QATCPpQ

ABQ

ARQp

QATCPQPABARpQATCPQpPABARp

QATCPpQ

ABQ

ARQp

QATCPQ

ABQ

ARQp

QATCPQpPABARp

QATCPQ

ABQ

ARQp

QATCPpQ

ABQ

ARQp

QATCPQPABARpQATCPQpPABARp

QATCPpQ

ABQ

ARQp

QATCPQ

ABQ

ARQp

QATCPQpPABARpQATCPQPABARp

PQABQARQ

ATCQpτ

PQABQARpQ

ATCQp

PQABQARQATCPpPQABQARQpATCPp

PQABQARpQ

ATCQp

PQABQARQ

ATCQp

PQABQARQpATCPp

COC

OPOPO

r

CPrPOPO

r

COC

OP

OPOPOr

CPrP

OPOPOr

COC

OrPCPC

r

CPPCPC

r

COC

OrPCPCr

COC

OPOPO

r

CPrPOPO

r

COC

OP

OPOPOr

CPrP

OPOPOr

COC

OrPCPC

r

CPPCPC

r

COC

OrPCPCr

CPPCPCr

POPOPO

COr

PCPCrCO

r

POPOPOCO

COr

PCPCrCOC

Or

POPOPOr

CPr

PCPCCP

r

POPOPOrCPr

τ

τ

τ

τ

τ

τ

τ

τ

τ

τ

τ

τ

τ

(A-15)

113

Divide both sides of equation (16) by Q to get

0))()((

))()(1)((

))()((

))()(1)((

))(()()1(

))()(()1(

))(())(1(

))()((

))()(1)((

))()((

))()(1)((

))(()()1(

))()(()1(

))(())(1(

))()(()1(

))()((

))()()(1(.

))()()((

))()()(1)((

))()(()1(

))()(()1(

))()(())(1(

2

2

2

2

2

2

2

2

2

2

=−∂

∂−

∂∂

−−∂

∂−

∂∂

−−−−

−−−−−

−∂

∂−

∂∂

−−

−∂

∂−

∂∂

−−

−−−−−

−∂

∂−

∂∂

+

−−∂

∂−

∂∂

+

−−−+

−−−−+

−∂

∂−

∂∂

−+

−∂

∂−

∂∂

−+

−−−−+

−−−−+

−−∂

∂−

−−−∂

∂−

−−−+

−−−−+

−−∂

∂−−

−−∂

∂−−

−−−−+

QATCPQ

ABQ

ARQp

QATCPpQ

ABQ

ARQp

QATCPPABARpQATCPpPABARp

QATCPpQ

ABQ

ARQp

QATCPQ

ABQ

ARQp

QATCPpPABARp

QATCPQ

ABQ

ARQp

QATCPpQ

ABQ

ARQp

QATCPPABARpQATCPpPABARp

QATCPpQ

ABQ

ARQp

QATCPQ

ABQ

ARQp

QATCPpPABARpQATCPPABARp

PQABQARQ

ATCQpτ

PQABQARpQ

ATCQp

PQABQARATCPpPQABQARpATCPp

PQABQARpQ

ATCQp

PQABQARQ

ATCQp

PQABQARpATCPp

COC

OPOPO

r

CPrPOPO

r

COC

OP

OPOPOr

CPrP

OPOPOr

COC

OrPCPC

r

CPPCPC

r

COC

OrPCPCr

COC

OPOPO

r

CPrPOPO

r

COC

OP

OPOPOr

CPrP

OPOPOr

COC

OrPCPC

r

CPPCPC

r

COC

OrPCPCr

CPPCPCr

POPOPO

COr

PCPCrCO

r

POPOPOCO

COr

PCPCrCOC

Or

POPOPOr

CPr

PCPCCP

r

POPOPOrCPr

τ

τ

τ

τ

τ

τ

τ

τ

τ

τ

τ

τ

τ

(A-16)

114

Collect all the terms with “Q”, all the terms without Q and move the one without “Q” to the right

hand side of equation (A-16) to get

2

2

2

(1 ) ( ( ) ( ) )

(1 ) ( ( ) ( ) )

(1 )( ( ) ( ) )

( ( ) ( ) )

(1 ) ( )( ( ))

(1 ) (

CPr PC PC

PCPr r PO PO O

COr r PC PC

PCOr PO PO O

PC PCr CP

r

ATCp Q AR Q AB Q PQ

ATCp Q p AR Q AB Q PQ

ATCp Q p AR Q AB Q PQ

ATCτ p Q AR Q AB Q PQ

AR ABp Q P ATC QQ Q

p Q

τ

τ

τ

∂− − − −

∂∂

− − − −∂

∂− − − −

∂∂

− − −∂∂ ∂

+ − − −∂ ∂

∂+ −

2

2

) ( ( ))

( )(1 )( ( ))

( )( ( ))

(1 ) ( )( ( ))

(1 ) ( ) ( ( ))

(

CPC PCr O CO

PO POr r CP

CPO POr O CO

PC PCr CP

CPC PCr r O CO

POr

AR AB p P ATC QQ Q

AR ABp Q p P ATC QQ Q

AR ABp Q P ATC QQ Q

AR ABp Q P ATC QQ Q

AR ABp Q p P ATC QQ Q

ARp Q

τ

τ

τ

∂− −

∂ ∂∂ ∂

+ − − −∂ ∂

∂ ∂+ − −

∂ ∂∂ ∂

− − − −∂ ∂

∂ ∂− − − −

∂ ∂∂

−∂

2

)(1 )( ( ))

( )( ( ))

POr CP

CPO POr O CO

AB p P ATC QQ Q

AR ABp Q P ATC QQ Q

τ

∂− − −

∂∂ ∂

− − −∂ ∂

(A-17)

115

2

2

(1 )( ) ( ( ) ( ) )

( )(1 )( ( ) ( ) )

( )( ( ) ( ) )

(1 ) ( )( ( ))

(1 )( ) ( ( ))

(

Pr CP r PO PO O

Cr O CO r PC PC

C Pr O CO PO PO O

r PC PC CP

Cr PC PC r O CO

r PO

p P ATC p AR Q AB Q P

p P ATC p AR Q AB Q P

p P ATC AR Q AB Q P

p AR AB P P ATC Q

p AR AB P p P ATC Q

p AR AB

τ

τ

τ

=

− − − − −

− − − − −

− − − −

− − − − −

− − − − −

− −2

2

)(1 )( ( ))

( )( ( ))

(1 )( ) ( ( ))

( )(1 )( ( ))

( )( ( ))

PPO O r CP

P Cr PO PO O O CO

Cr PC PC r O CO

Pr PO PO O r CP

P Cr PO PO O O CO

P p P ATC Q

p AR AB P P ATC Q

p AR AB P p P ATC Q

p AR AB P p P ATC Q

p AR AB P P ATC Q

τ

τ

τ

− − −

− − − −

+ − − − −

+ − − − −

+ − − −

(A-17 continued)

Let’s collect the terms of the left hand side of equation (A-17) and define it as “Left”, and

))]((

))()(1( ))((

))()(1()[(

))](()1(

))(()1(

))(()1(

))(()1)[((

)])()((

))()()(1( ))()(()1(

))()(()1()[(

2

2

2

2

2

2

QATCPpQATCPpp

QATCPp

QATCPppQ

ABQ

ARQATCPpp

QATCPpQATCPpp

QATCPpQ

ABQ

ARPQABQARpτ

PQABQARppPQABQARpp

PQABQARpQ

ATCQleft

COC

Or

CPrr

COC

Or

CPrrPOPO

COC

Orr

CPr

COC

Orr

CPrPCPC

POPOPOr

PCPCrr

POPOPOrr

PCPCrCP

−−

−−−−+

−−+∂

∂−

∂∂

+

−−−

−−−

−−+

−−∂

∂−

∂∂

+

−−−

−−−−−−−−

−−−−∂

∂•=

τ

τ

τ

τ

ττ

τ

(A-18)

116

))](( )1(

))()(1()1)[((

))](()1)(1(

))(()1)(1)[((

)])()((

))()()(1()[(

2

2

QATCPp

QATCPppQ

ABQ

ARQATCPpp

QATCPpQ

ABQ

ARPQABQARpτ

PQABQARpQ

ATCQleft

COC

Or

CPrrPOPO

COC

Orr

CPrPCPC

POPOPOr

PCPCrCP

−−+

−−−∂

∂−

∂∂

+

−−−+

−−−∂

∂−

∂∂

+

−−−

−−−−∂

∂•=

τ

τ

τ

τ

τ

(A-19)

Let’s collect the terms of the right hand side of equation (A-17) and define it as “right”, and

])[))(((

])1()[))(((

])1()[)()()((

)))(()(1(

2

2

rP

OPOPOCOC

O

rPCPCCP

rrPCPCCOC

O

POPOPOCPrr

pPABARQATCPpPABARQATCP

ppPQABQARATCPPABARQATCPppright

−−−−+

−−−−−+

−−−−−+

−−−−−=

(A-20)

Solving for )(QATCP CP− by substituting the negotiated price equation (3-25) to get

)(1

)1(

)()](1

)[(

)](1

[

)(1

)](1

)[(

)()](1

)[1(

)](1

)[(

)(

COC

Or

r

CPP

OPOPOr

rPCPC

COC

Or

rCP

COC

Or

rPOPOPO

r

rPCPC

CPCOC

Or

rCP

POPOPO

r

rPCPC

CP

ATCPp

p

ATCPABARp

pABAR

ATCPp

pATC

ATCPp

pPABARp

pABAR

QATCATCPp

pATC

PABARp

pABAR

QATCP

−−

−−

−−−−

+−=

−−

−−

−−

−−−−

+−=

−−−

−−+

−−−

+−=

τ

ττ

τ

τ

τ

τ

(A-21)

Solving for PABAR PCPC −− by substituting the negotiated price equation (3-25) to get

117

)](1

)[1(

)(1

))(1(

)](1

)[1(

)](1

)[(

COC

Or

rCP

POPOPO

r

rPCPC

COC

Or

rCP

POPOPO

r

rPCPCPCPC

PCPC

ATCPp

pATC

PABARp

pABAR

ATCPp

pATC

PABARp

pABARABAR

PABAR

−−

−−−

−−−

−−−=

−−

−−−

−−−

+−−−=

−−

τ

ττ

τ

τ

(A-22)

Then, substitute equation (A-21) and (A-22) into equation (A-19) to get

))](( )1(

)](1

)1(

)())(1

)(()[1()1)((

))(()1)(1(

)](1

)1(

)())(1

)(([)1)(1)((

))()((

))](1

)(1(

)(1

))(1)[(1()(

2

2

QATCPp

ATCPp

p

ATCPABARp

p

ABARppQ

ABQ

ARQATCPpp

ATCPp

p

ATCPABARp

p

ABARpQ

ABQ

ARPQABQARpτ

ATCPp

pATC

PABARp

p

ABARpQ

ATCQleft

COC

Or

COC

Or

r

CPP

OPOPOr

r

PCPCrrPOPO

COC

Orr

COC

Or

r

CPP

OPOPOr

r

PCPCrPCPC

POPOPOr

COC

Or

rCP

POPOPO

r

r

PCPCrCP

−−+

−−

−−

−−−−

+

−−−∂

∂−

∂∂

+

−−−+

−−

−−

−−−−

+

−−−∂

∂−

∂∂

+

−−−

−−

−−−

−−−

−−−−∂

∂•=

τ

τ

τ

ττ

τ

τ

τ

ττ

τ

τ

ττ

(A-23)

Simplifying equation (A-23) to get

118

]11

11[

])1111

11

]111

1

22

2

)ATC(Pτ)p()PAB(ARτ)p(

)ATCAB)(ARp(τ)p()Q

ABQ

AR(

)ATC(Pp(τ)p()PAB)(ARp(τ)p(

)ATCAB(AR)pτ)(()[Q

ABQ

AR(

)ATC(Pτ) pτ()ATCAB)(ARpτ)(τ(

)P(Q)AB(Q)(ARτ)τ p()[Q

ATC(Q

left

COC

OrP

OPOPOr

CPPCPCrrPOPO

COC

OrrP

OPOPOrr

CPPCPCrPCPC

COC

OrCPPCPCr

POPOPOr

CP

−−+−−−+

−−−−∂

∂−

∂∂

+

−−−+−−−−+

−−−−∂

∂−

∂∂

+

−−−−−−−−

−−−−∂

∂•=

ττ

τ

ττ

τ (A-24)

]

1[

])11

1

]1

1

22

2

)ATC(Pp)PAB(ARp

)ATCAB)(ARp(p)Q

ABQ

AR(

)ATC(Pp(p)PAB)(ARp(p

)ATCAB(AR)p)[(Q

ABQ

AR(

)ATC(P p)ATCAB)(ARp(

)P(Q)AB(Q)(AR p)[Q

ATC(τ)τ(Q

left

COC

OrP

OPOPOr

CPPCPCrrPOPO

COC

OrrP

OPOPOrr

CPPCPCrPCPC

COC

OrCPPCPCr

POPOPOr

CP

−+−−+

−−−∂

∂−

∂∂

+

−−+−−−+

−−−∂

∂−

∂∂

+

−−−−−−

−−−∂

∂•−•=

(A-25)

Then, substitute equation (22) and (23) into equation (21) to get

119

])[))(((

])1()][(1

)[1(

)(1

))(1)((1

)1(

)()](1

)[(

)]1()[)()()((1

)1(

)()](1

)[(

])1()][(1

)[1(

)(1

))(1)((

2

2

rP

OPOPOCOC

O

rCOC

Or

rCP

POPOPO

r

r

PCPCCOC

Or

r

CPP

OPOPOr

rPCPC

rrP

OPOPOCOC

Or

r

CPP

OPOPOr

rPCPC

rrCOC

Or

rCP

POPOPO

r

rPCPCCO

CO

pPABARQATCP

pATCPp

pATC

PABARp

p

ABARATCPp

p

ATCPABARp

pABAR

ppPQABQARATCPp

p

ATCPABARp

pABAR

ppATCPp

pATC

PABARp

pABARATCP

right

−−−−

+−−−−

−−−

−−−

−−−−

−−

−−−−

+−

+−−−−−−

−−

−−−−

+−

+−−−−

−−−

−−−

−−−−

=

τ

τ

ττ

ττ

τ

ττ

τ

ττ

(A-26)

Simplifying equation (A-26) to get

120

))((

)()1(

)( )()1(

))()(1()1(

))(()1(

)(

))()(1()1(

))()(1()1(

))()(1(

)()1)(1(

))()()()()(1(

)()(

)]1()[)()()((

))(1(

))((

))()(1()1(

2

222

2

2

2

222

2

22

2

22

22

2

POPOPOCO

COr

COC

Or

POPOPOCO

COr

CPPCPCCOC

Orr

COC

OP

OPOPOr

POPOPOr

CPPCPCP

OPOPOrr

COC

OCPPCPCrr

POPOPOCPPCPCrr

CPPCPCr

rP

OPOPOCOC

O

rP

OPOPO

rrP

OPOPOCPPCPC

COC

Or

POPOPOCO

COr

CPPCPCCOC

Orr

PABARATCPpATCPp

PABARATCPpATCABARATCPpp

ATCPPABARpPABARp

ATCABARPABARppATCPATCABARpp

PABARATCABARppATCABARp

pPQABQARATCPpPABAR

ppPQABQARATCABARATCPp

PABARATCPpATCABARATCPpp

right

−−−−

−−+

−−−−−

−−−−−+

−−−−−

−−+

−−−−−−−

−−−−−−

−−−−−+

−−−−−

−−−−+

−−−

−−−−−−

−−−

−−−+

−−−−−−

=

τ

ττ

τ

ττ

τ

ττ

ττ

τ

ττ

τ

τ

τ

τ

τ

τ

(A-27)

Simplifying equation (A-27) to get

22

2

22

22

)()1(

))()(1()1(2

))(()1(2

)()1)(1(

)()1(

))()(1()1(2

COC

Or

CPPCPCCOC

Orr

POPOPOCO

COr

CPPCPCr

POPOPOr

POPOPOCPPCPCrr

ATCPpATCABARATCPpp

PABARATCPpATCABARp

PABARpPABARATCABARpp

right

−−−

−−−−−−

−−−−−

−−−−−

−−−−

−−−−−−−

=

ττ

ττ

ττ

ττ

ττ

ττ

(A-28)

121

)(

))()(1(2

))((2

)()1(

)(

))()(1(2)1(

22

2

22

22

COC

Or

CPPCPCCOC

Orr

POPOPOCO

COr

CPPCPCr

POPOPOr

POPOPOCPPCPCrr

ATCPpATCABARATCPpp

PABARATCPpATCABARp

PABARpPABARATCABARpp

right

−−

−−−−−

−−−−

−−−−

−−−

−−−−−−

•−= ττ

(A-29)

Solving the negotiated price of Q by using “right” (equation A-29, the right hand side of

the equation (A-17)) divided by “left” (equation A-25, the left hand side of the equation (A-17))

leftrightQ = (A-30)

where “right” and “left” are calculated in equation (A-29) and (A-25). Then, the terms

)1( ττ − can be cancelled out, and Q becomes

]

1[

])11

1

]1

)(

))()(1(2

))((2

)()1(

)(

))()(1(2

22

2

22

2

22

22

)ATC(Pp)PAB(ARp

)ATCAB)(ARp(p)Q

ABQ

AR(

)ATC(Pp(p)PAB)(ARp(p

)ATCAB(AR)p)[(Q

ABQ

AR(

)ATC(P p)ATCAB)(ARp(

)P(Q)AB(Q)(AR p)[Q

ATC(

ATCPpATCABARATCPpp

PABARATCPpATCABARp

PABARpPABARATCABARpp

Q

COC

OrP

OPOPOr

CPPCPCrrPOPO

COC

OrrP

OPOPOrr

CPPCPCrPCPC

COC

OrCPPCPCr

POPOPOr

CP

COC

Or

CPPCPCCOC

Orr

POPOPOCO

COr

CPPCPCr

POPOPOr

POPOPOCPPCPCrr

−+−−+

−−−∂

∂−

∂∂

+

−−+−−−+

−−−∂

∂−

∂∂

+

−−−−−−

−−−∂

∂−−

−−−−−

−−−−

−−−−

−−−

−−−−−−

=

(A-31)

122

APPENDIX B DATA

Table B-1. Data(1)a

Year Month

Negotiated Price ( tP ) ($ per hundredweight)

Negotiated Quantity ( tQ ) (million pounds)

FMMO #6 Class I price ( tC1 ) ($ per hundredweight))

Index of Feed Cost Paid by Farmers ( tFC ) (US)

1998 10 21.99 189.7 19.17 100 11 21.99 191.7 19.28 103 12 22.79 217.3 20.22 104 1999 1 23.39 224.3 21.02 104 2 23.89 208.4 21.52 103 3 22.82 230.5 20.45 101 4 17.32 219.4 14.45 102 5 18.17 207.4 15.80 101 6 18.36 198.3 15.99 100 7 18.36 205.6 15.44 97 8 18.87 182.0 15.60 97 9 20.54 180.6 17.77 98 10 21.99 186.8 19.97 97 11 22.46 205.4 20.44 97 12 18.64 221.2 15.67 98 2000 1 18.32 225.0 15.20 98 2 18.06 221.0 15.01 101 3 18.2 236.0 15.14 102 4 18.37 212.0 15.23 102 5 18.67 215.0 15.78 105 6 18.64 203.0 16.00 104 7 19.15 199.0 16.76 100 8 18.89 202.0 16.25 96 9 18.78 187.0 16.14 99 10 18.83 199.0 16.19 101 11 18.76 209.0 16.12 103 12 18.82 219.0 16.43 108 2001 1 20.68 233.0 18.29 112 2 18.88 209.0 16.24 108 3 19.26 240.0 16.95 107 4 20.13 211.0 17.74 106 5 20.79 213.0 18.51 106 6 21.23 203.0 19.29 107 7 21.73 197.0 19.64 108 8 21.79 199.0 19.70 111

123

Table B-1. Continueda

Year Month

Negotiated Price ( tP ) ($ per hundredweight)

Negotiated Quantity ( tQ ) (million pounds)

FMMO #6 Class I price ( tC1 ) ($ per hundredweight))

Index of Feed Cost Paid by Farmers ( tFC ) (US)

2002 9 21.95 179.0 19.86 110 10 22.32 201.0 20.23 109 11 22.15 203.0 20.06 109 12 18.84 204.0 16.28 109 2002 1 18.76 220.0 16.26 108 2 18.76 202.0 16.25 107 3 18.76 218.0 15.92 109 4 18.76 211.0 15.77 109 5 18.80 207.0 15.56 108 6 18.57 186.0 15.33 110 7 18.16 194.0 14.92 114 8 18.02 200.0 14.78 116 9 18.00 173.0 14.76 118 10 17.69 185.0 14.45 116 11 18.04 191.0 14.90 114 12 17.96 207.0 14.82 114 2003 1 18.00 228.0 14.86 114 2 17.67 202.0 14.53 114 3 17.33 219.0 14.11 114 4 17.16 209.0 13.94 114 5 17.23 207.0 14.01 115 6 17.26 186.0 14.04 114 7 17.29 196.0 14.07 111 8 18.27 186.0 15.27 107 9 20.51 177.0 18.01 112 10 20.80 193.0 18.57 112 11 20.80 190.0 18.67 118 12 20.64 218.0 18.14 117 2004 1 18.90 227.0 16.15 117 2 18.90 204.0 15.89 121 3 18.90 225.0 16.24 124 4 20.54 217.0 17.94 131 5 26.05 197.0 23.95 135 6 27.53 189.0 25.43 129 7 24.35 203.0 22.25 128 8 21.02 190.0 18.92 119 9 20.84 169.0 18.24 116 10 21.18 190.0 19.08 111

124

Table B-1. Continueda

Year Month

Negotiated Price ( tP ) ($ per hundredweight)

Negotiated Quantity ( tQ ) (million pounds)

FMMO #6 Class I price ( tC1 ) ($ per hundredweight))

Index of Feed Cost Paid by Farmers ( tFC ) (US)

2004 11 20.90 200.0 18.59 109 12 20.98 222.0 18.73 108 2005 1 23.29 229.0 21.04 112 2 20.86 209.0 18.18 110 3 22.41 231.0 19.73 115 4 21.11 224.0 18.43 116 5 21.78 208.0 19.10 118 6 20.60 199.0 17.92 121 7 20.87 203.0 18.19 122 8 21.42 218.0 18.74 122 9 21.08 201.0 18.00 119 10 21.57 200.0 18.57 117 11 21.86 218.0 18.86 115 12 21.11 231.0 17.87 118 2006 1 20.66 238.0 17.68 121 2 20.66 216.0 17.68 121 3 19.85 242.0 16.79 123 4 19.08 221.0 15.52 123 5 18.83 218.0 15.27 123 6 18.69 208.0 15.05 122 7 19.28 207.0 15.64 123 8 18.91 215.0 15.27 120 9 18.87 205.0 15.15 120 10 20.36 211.0 16.72 125 11 20.26 221.0 16.70 133 12 20.39 225.0 16.73 138 2007 1 21.51 239.1 17.89 140 2 21.32 218.2 17.69 148 3 22.10 242.1 18.55 150 4 22.93 219.9 19.30 148 5 23.85 214.7 20.22 145 6 25.85 204.7 22.14 147 7 28.77 198.7 25.21 147 8 29.47 213.6 26.06 145 9 29.62 199.2 26.21 147 10 29.80 216.6 25.89 151 11 29.74 217.0 25.75 156 12 28.42 219.7 24.34 160

125

Table B-1. Continueda

Year Month

Negotiated Price ( tP ) ($ per hundredweight)

Negotiated Quantity ( tQ ) (million pounds)

FMMO #6 Class I price ( tC1 ) ($ per hundredweight))

Index of Feed Cost Paid by Farmers ( tFC ) (US)

2008 1 29.12 234.0 25.27 168 2 28.50 220.6 23.98 176 3 25.77 233.0 21.00 183 4 27.76 218.7 22.91 186 5 27.13 227.2 22.62 199 6 28.77 196.6 24.18 203 7 31.37 204.2 26.78 217 8 29.22 211.1 24.47 215 9 28.4 205.2 23.65 209 10 25.32 220.7 21.53 196 11 27.04 210.1 23.33 191 12 24.90 223.6 21.43 185 2009 1 25.05 234.0 21.74 189 2 20.60 218.0 16.72 187 3 18.66 234.0 15.43 185 4 19.51 222.0 16.36 184 5 20.20 212.0 16.97 192 a) Data Source found in the 4.4 Data Description section of Chapter 4

126

Table B-2. Data(2)a

Year Month

Seasonality ( tS ) (Milk production per cow in Florida, lbs/cow)

Transportation Cost ( tTC ) (PPI Freight transportation)

Labor Index ( tL )

Whole Sale level Price ( tWP ) ( finished dairy products PPI)

Over Order Premium ( tOOP )

1998 10 1030 112.5 138.9 148.0 2.8 11 1120 112.4 138.9 148.6 2.7 12 1325 112.6 138.9 148.5 2.6 1999 1 1415 113.2 139.9 149.0 2.4 2 1365 113.4 139.9 145.1 2.4 3 1540 113.9 139.9 142.6 2.4 4 1435 114.4 140.9 132.1 2.9 5 1400 114.4 140.9 132.9 2.4 6 1290 114.8 140.9 135.5 2.4 7 1190 114.8 142.1 136.4 2.9 8 1045 115.4 142.1 139.9 3.3 9 1020 115.7 142.1 143.9 2.8 10 1025 115.4 143.6 144.1 2.0 11 1115 115.3 143.6 142.5 2.0 12 1320 115.8 143.6 132.7 3.0 2000 1 1455 116.5 146.0 130.9 3.1 2 1410 116.8 146.0 130.1 3.1 3 1565 118.1 146.0 130.5 3.1 4 1470 118.2 147.5 131.7 3.1 5 1465 118.8 147.5 133.1 2.9 6 1325 119.4 147.5 134.4 2.6 7 1215 118.8 148.7 136.3 2.4 8 1120 120.1 148.7 134.9 2.6 9 1030 120.6 148.7 135.6 2.6 10 1120 121.4 149.3 134.6 2.6 11 1170 121.6 149.3 135.6 2.6 12 1360 121.5 149.3 136.8 2.4 2001 1 1440 121.9 151.3 136.8 2.4 2 1380 122.5 151.3 136.1 2.6 3 1580 122.6 151.3 138.6 2.3 4 1475 122.7 152.6 141.3 2.4 5 1515 123.0 152.6 146.4 2.3 6 1330 123.2 152.6 150.1 1.9 7 1235 123.3 153.3 150.9 2.1 8 1115 123.4 153.3 152.0 2.1 9 1030 123.6 153.3 153.5 2.1 10 1120 123.8 154.6 150.6 2.1 11 1170 124.0 154.6 145.4 2.1 12 1320 123.2 154.6 140.3 2.6

127

Table B-2. Continueda

Year Month

Seasonality ( tS ) (Milk production per cow in Florida, lbs/cow)

Transportation Cost ( tTC ) (PPI Freight transportation)

Labor Index ( tL )

Whole Sale level Price ( tWP ) ( finished dairy products PPI)

Over Order Premium ( tOOP )

2002 1 1410 123.4 156.6 140.9 2.5 2 1335 123.3 156.6 139.8 2.5 3 1515 123.2 156.6 138.1 2.8 4 1455 123.8 158.1 137.7 3.0 5 1450 123.8 158.1 136.2 3.2 6 1345 124.3 158.1 135.2 3.2 7 1250 124.2 159.1 134.0 3.2 8 1190 124.6 159.1 134.5 3.2 9 1045 125.0 159.1 133.9 3.2 10 1055 125.4 160.5 136.6 3.2 11 1100 125.9 160.5 134.3 3.1 12 1265 125.9 160.5 135.3 3.1 2003 1 1360 126.5 164.0 134.8 3.1 2 1290 126.8 164.0 133.6 3.1 3 1435 127.3 164.0 132.5 3.2 4 1415 127.4 165.4 133.7 3.2 5 1385 127.3 165.4 134.1 3.2 6 1290 127.5 165.4 134.1 3.2 7 1215 127.8 166.5 139.3 3.2 8 1120 128.3 166.5 143.6 3.0 9 1020 128.7 166.5 147.5 2.5 10 1105 128.6 167.1 147.6 2.2 11 1180 128.8 167.1 145.7 2.1 12 1355 128.8 167.1 143.5 2.5 2004 1 1435 129.1 171.7 141.5 2.8 2 1415 130.3 171.7 142.2 3.0 3 1550 130.5 171.7 147.4 2.7 4 1515 130.7 173.2 162.7 2.6 5 1525 131.6 173.2 173.4 2.1 6 1395 132.3 173.2 169.8 2.1 7 1340 132.9 174.9 159.7 2.1 8 1225 133.4 174.9 155.1 2.1 9 1025 133.9 174.9 154.6 2.6 10 1165 134.9 175.4 154.3 2.1 11 1250 135.8 175.4 154.5 2.3 12 1450 135.6 175.4 157.4 2.3 2005 1 1520 136.7 178.2 157.7 2.3 2 1475 136.8 178.2 154.8 2.7 3 1640 137.7 178.2 155.1 2.7

128

Table B-2. Continueda

Year Month

Seasonality ( tS ) (Milk production per cow in Florida, lbs/cow)

Transportation Cost ( tTC ) (PPI Freight transportation)

Labor Index ( tL )

Whole Sale level Price ( tWP ) ( finished dairy products PPI)

Over Order Premium ( tOOP )

2005 4 1570 138.7 179.6 155.8 2.7 5 1585 139.2 179.6 153.8 2.7 6 1440 139.9 179.6 152.7 2.7 7 1315 140.6 180.7 155.2 2.7 8 1235 140.6 180.7 153.7 2.7 9 1105 142.9 180.7 155.3 3.1 10 1135 144.5 181.3 155.7 3.0 11 1220 144.3 181.3 153.5 3.0 12 1360 143.1 181.3 153.7 3.2 2006 1 1485 143.4 181.5 152.6 3.0 2 1425 143.1 181.5 149.2 3.0 3 1640 143.7 181.5 145.9 3.1 4 1540 144.8 183.1 144.4 3.6 5 1520 146.8 183.1 143.3 3.6 6 1415 147.1 183.1 144.1 3.6 7 1350 146.9 183.8 143.8 3.6 8 1180 147.9 183.8 145.3 3.6 9 1110 148.1 183.8 148.2 3.7 10 1185 146.4 184.6 149.1 3.6 11 1245 146.3 184.6 151.4 3.6 12 1390 145.9 184.6 152.4 3.7 2007 1 1470 146.8 184.9 154.7 3.6 2 1415 146.1 184.9 156.8 3.6 3 1620 146.8 184.9 159.8 3.6 4 1590 148.1 186.6 162.3 3.6 5 1585 148.8 186.6 169.6 3.6 6 1470 148.8 186.6 180.3 3.7 7 1400 148.9 187.1 186.8 3.6 8 1230 149.0 187.1 186.5 3.4 9 1170 149.1 187.1 189.5 3.4 10 1160 149.5 188.2 187.8 3.9 11 1240 151.1 188.2 188.4 4.0 12 1410 151.6 188.2 188.7 4.1 2008 1 1550 151.9 189.8 187.5 3.9 2 1530 153.0 189.8 184.6 4.5 3 1655 154.3 189.8 181.2 4.8 4 1568 157.3 190.5 181.9 4.9 5 1625 160.2 190.5 180.8 4.5 6 1440 163.8 190.5 187.1 4.6

129

Table B-2. Continueda

Year Month

Seasonality ( tS ) (Milk production per cow in Florida, lbs/cow)

Transportation Cost ( tTC ) (PPI Freight transportation)

Labor Index ( tL )

Whole Sale level Price ( tWP ) ( finished dairy products PPI)

Over Order Premium ( tOOP )

2008 7 1375 164.7 191.5 189.3 4.6 8 1240 163.7 191.5 187.0 4.8 9 1160 160.7 191.5 183.2 4.8 10 1225 159.7 192.0 181.6 3.8 11 1320 155.5 192.0 178.3 3.7 12 1520 151.7 192.0 174.3 3.5 2009 1 1660 151.7 193.1 162.1 3.3 2 1540 151.9 193.1 155.1 3.9 3 1760 149.8 193.1 153.1 3.2 4 1710 150.8 193.4 153.8 3.2 5 1700 150.6 193.4 153.1 3.2 a) Data Source found in the 4.4 Data Description section of Chapter 4

130

APPENDIX C GAUSS PROGRAM

new; clear all; rndseed 3434567; /* read data and variable names in from the disc*/; data = xlsreadm("SepData.xls", "d2:p129",1, 0); datanames=xlsreadSA("SepData.xls", "d1:p1", 1, ""); names=datanames'; print data[.,1]; print "Variable Names=" names; /* caculate the means */; means=meanc(data); print "Means=" means; /* calculate the standard deviation */ stds = stdc(data); print "Standard Deviations=" stds; /* caculate variance-covariance matrix */; VarCovs = vcx(data[.,2:12]); print " Variance Covariance Matrix=" VarCovs; /* calculate the correlation matrix */; Cor=corrvc(VarCovs); print "Correlation Matrix=" Cor; detcor=det(cor); vif=inv(cor); print "Vif (variance inflation factors)=" diag(vif); /* define model terms */; n=128; P=data[.,1]; Q=data[.,2]; XD=data[.,3]~data[.,10]~data[.,11]; XS=data[.,3]~data[.,4]~data[.,8:9]; XT=data[.,12]; NP=12; /* 4 demand + 7 supply +1 bargaining */; print " Demand price EQ exogenous variables=" Q~XD; print " Supply price EQ exogenous variables=" Q~XS; print " Tao EQ exogenous variables=" XT;

131

//************* EM algorithm loop Starts here***************// diff=1; count=1; /******************Initial Values**********/; x0=-0.004, 0.82, -0.002, 0.057, 0.9, 3.548, -16.03, -5.761, 1.68, 4.63, 23, 0.01, 0.51; print "initial values=" x0; do until diff<=0.1; /***********simulation by using expectation of PD, PS****** */; /* calculate the mean of PD and PS2 */; lnPD_means = ln(Q)*x0[1,1]+ln(XD)*x0[2:4,1]+ones(128,1)*x0[5,1]; lnPS_means = ln(Q)*x0[6,1]+((ln(XS[.,1:2]))~(ln(XS[.,3:4])))*x0[7:10,1]+ones(128,1)*x0[11,1]; mu = meanc(lnPD_means~lnPS_means); /* print "Demand and Supply equation means=" mu; */ /* define the variance covariance matrix of PD and PS */; vc = (120~0)|(0~130); /* print "Variance Covariance Matrix of Demand and Supply Equations=" vc; */ /* simulating all needed PD and PS */ trial=128^2; PDPS=zeros(256, trial); j=1; for j(1, trial, 1); library rndmn; mvnvars=rndmn(mu,vc, 128); @ calling the biviraite normal generator procedure @ /* print "Psuedo biviraite normal PD and PS=" mvnvars; */ PDPS[1:128,j] = mvnvars[.,1]; PDPS[129:256,j] = mvnvars[.,2]; endfor; PDall=PDPS[1:128,.]; PSall=PDPS[129:256,.]; /* taking the average of all trials */ PDsum=sumr(PDall); 1 Originally, some difficulties occurred for finding initial values. Then, by making the assumption for PD and PS, a simple OLS provide some possible initial values. With the knowledge that PD is above P and PS is below P, some magnitude changes in the OLS initial values were made.

2 Besides double log functional form for PD and PS, other functional forms (linear log, linear) have been tried. The results are non sensible.

132

PSsum=sumr(PSall); lnPD=PDsum./trial; lnPS=PSsum./trial; PD=exp(lnPD); PS=exp(lnPS); // print "PD and PS=" PD~PS; /*****************maximization*************/; /***** define log-likelihood function *****/; proc ll(x0); local BD, BS, BDQ, BSQ, BT, BDC, BSC, BTC, e, tao, gama, test; /* define parameters as the element of b */ BDQ = x0[1,1]; BD = x0[2:4,1]; BDC= x0[5,1]; BSQ = x0[6,1]; BS = x0[7:10,1]; BSC= x0[11,1]; BT = x0[12,1]; BTC= x0[13,1]; /* define variance covariance matrix */ e=zeros(128,4); e[.,1] = lnPD- ln(Q)*BDQ-ln(XD)*BD-ones(128,1)*BDC; e[.,2] = lnPS- ln(Q)*BSQ-((ln(XS[.,1:2]))~(ln(XS[.,3:4])))*BS-ones(128,1)*BSC; tao=1/(1+exp(XT*BT+ones(128,1)*BTC)); // print "Tao=" tao; e[.,3]= P-tao.*PD-(1.-tao).*PS; gama = Q./(BDQ-BSQ); e[.,4]= Q-gama.*(PS-PD); /* testing sigularity */ test=det(e'e); if test==0; print "sigular"; endif; retp(ln(det(e'e))); endp; /* calling the library and setting globals */; library optmum; optset; _opgtol=0.0001; x,fmin,g,retcode = optprt(optmum(&ll,x0)); bn=x; diff=maxc(abs(bn-x0)); count=count+1; print "count=" count;

133

x0=bn; endo; print "count=" count; print "final estimates=" bn; /* standard errors of parameters */ print "standard erroes of parameters =" sqrt(diag(inv(_opfhess))); /* variance covariance matrix of equation errors */ er=zeros(128,4); er[.,1] = lnPD- ln(Q)*x[1]-ln(XD)*x[2:4]-ones(128,1)*x[5]; er[.,2] = lnPS- ln(Q)*x[6]-((ln(XS[.,1:2]))~(ln(XS[.,3:4])))*x[7:10]-ones(128,1)*x[11]; taoc=1/(1+exp(XT*x[12]+ones(128,1)*x[13])); er[.,3]= P-taoc.*PD-(1.-taoc).*PS; gamac = Q./(x[1]-x[6]); er[.,4]= Q-gamac.*(PS-PD); varc=((er'er)/128); print "variance covariance matrix of all equation errors=" varc; print "bargaining power parameter tao=" taoc; print "Gama =" gamac; print "mean Gama =" meanc(gamac);

134

APPENDIX D TAO TESTING

The one tail t test is used to test whether the average bargaining power coefficient in year

2008 is the highest for SDC and the lowest for processors (Table B-1). The hypothesis is:

Ho: 02008 =− yearµµ

Ha: 02008 >− yearµµ

Table B-1. Testing Results for Maximum Bargaining Power for SDC in Year 20081 Year P-value Conclusion 2009 0.0003 reject Ho at 5% significant level 2007 0.0003 reject Ho at 5% significant level 2006 0.0000 reject Ho at 5% significant level 2005 0.0000 reject Ho at 5% significant level 2004 0.0000 reject Ho at 5% significant level 2003 0.0000 reject Ho at 5% significant level 2002 0.0000 reject Ho at 5% significant level 2001 0.0000 reject Ho at 5% significant level 2000 0.0000 reject Ho at 5% significant level 1999 0.0000 reject Ho at 5% significant level 1998 0.0000 reject Ho at 5% significant level

1 Before the one tail t test, an equal variance test has been done for all t tests. The results show that the variances are statistically equal at 5% significant level except the test for year 2007.

135

The one tail t test is used to test whether the average bargaining power coefficient in year

2001 is the lowest for SDC and the highest for processors (Table B-2). The hypothesis is:

Ho: 02001 =− yearµµ

Ha: 02001 <− yearµµ

Table B-2. Testing Results for Minimum Bargaining Power for SDC in Year 20011 Year P-value Conclusion 2009 0.0000 reject Ho at 5% significant level 2008 0.0000 reject Ho at 5% significant level 2007 0.0000 reject Ho at 5% significant level 2006 0.0000 reject Ho at 5% significant level 2005 0.0000 reject Ho at 5% significant level 2004 0.1082 fail to reject Ho at 5% significant level 2003 0.0001 reject Ho at 5% significant level 2002 0.0000 reject Ho at 5% significant level 2000 0.0000 reject Ho at 5% significant level 1999 0.013 reject Ho at 5% significant level 1998 0.0025 reject Ho at 5% significant level

1 Before the one tail t test, an equal variance test has been done for all t tests. The results show that the variances are statistically equal at 5% significant level except the test for year 2003.

136

The one tail t test is used to test whether the average bargaining power coefficient in April

is the highest for SDC and the lowest for processors (Table B-3). The hypothesis is:

Ho: 0=− MonthApril µµ

Ha: 0≠− MonthApril µµ

Table B-3. Testing Results for Maximum Bargaining Power for SDC in April1 Month P-value Conclusion 1 0.1695 fail to reject Ho at 5% significant level 2 0.4133 fail to reject Ho at 5% significant level 3 0.3236 fail to reject Ho at 5% significant level 5 0.3251 fail to reject Ho at 5% significant level 6 0.2686 fail to reject Ho at 5% significant level 7 0.3009 fail to reject Ho at 5% significant level 8 0.3446 fail to reject Ho at 5% significant level 9 0.3413 fail to reject Ho at 5% significant level 10 0.1282 fail to reject Ho at 5% significant level 11 0.1141 fail to reject Ho at 5% significant level 12 0.2255 fail to reject Ho at 5% significant level

1 Before the two tail t test, an equal variance test has been done for all t tests. The results show that the variances are statistically equal at 5% significant level.

137

The one tail t test is used to test whether the average bargaining power coefficient in

November is the lowest for SDC and the highest for processors (Table B-4). The hypothesis is:

Ho: 0=− MonthNovember µµ

Ha: 0≠− MonthNovember µµ

Table B-4. Testing Results for Minimum Bargaining Power for SDC in November1 Month P-value Conclusion 1 0.3445 fail to reject Ho at 5% significant level 2 0.1567 fail to reject Ho 3 0.2169 fail to reject Ho 4 0.1141 fail to reject Ho 5 0.2321 fail to reject Ho 6 0.3227 fail to reject Ho 7 0.2789 fail to reject Ho 8 0.2408 fail to reject Ho 9 0.2336 fail to reject Ho 10 0.4809 fail to reject Ho 12 0.2927 fail to reject Ho

1 Before the two tail t test, an equal variance test has been done for all t tests. The results show that the variances are statistically equal at 5% significant level.

138

LIST OF REFERENCES

Aldrich, J. "R.A. Fisher and the making of maximum likelihood 1912-1922." Statistical Science 12, no. 3(1997): 15.

Babb, E. M., S. A. Belden, and C. R. Saathoff. "An Analysis of Cooperative Bargaining in the

Processing Tomato Industry." American Journal of Agricultural Economics 51, no. 1(1969): 13-25.

Bennett, E. "Multilateral Bargaining Problems." Games and Economic Behavior 19, no. 2(1997):

151-179. Binmore, K. "Fun and Games: a Text on Game Theory." D.C. Heath and Company Lexington,

MA(1992). Binmore, K., A. Rubinstein, and A. Wolinsky. "The Nash Bargaining Solution in Economic

Modelling." The RAND Journal of Economics 17, no. 2(1986): 176-188. Blair, R. D., D. L. Kaserman, and R. E. Romano. "A Pedagogical Treatment of Bilateral

Monopoly." Southern Economic Journal 55, no. 4(1989): 831-841. Bloch, F., and A. Gomes. "Contracting with Externalities and Outside Options " Journal of

Economic Theory 127(2006): 30. Bloom, J. R. "United Dairy Farmers Cooperative Association - Nlrb Bargaining Orders in the

Absence of a Clear Showing of a Pro-Union Majority." Columbia Law Review 80, no. 4(1980): 840-856.

Carraro, C., C. Marchiori, and A. Sgobbi. "Advances in Negotiation Theory: Bargaining,

Coalition, and Fairness." World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 3642(2005): 53. Cecchetti, S. G., A. Flores-Lagunes, and S. Krause. "Has Monetary Policy Become More

Efficient? A Cross-Country Analysis." The Economic Journal 116, no. 115(2006): 26. Chae, S., and J.-A. Yang. "An N-Person Pure Bargaining Game." Journal of Economic Theory

62, no. 1(1994): 86-102. Chae, S., and J.-A. Yang. "The unique perfect equilibrium of an n-person bargaining game."

Economics Letters 28, no. 3(1988): 221-223. Dempster, A. P., N. M. Laird, and D. B. Rubin. "Maximum Likelihood from Incomplete Data via

the EM Algorithm." Journal of the Royal Statistical Society. Series B (Methodological) 39, no. 1(1977): 1-38.

Durham, C. A., and R. J. Sexton. "Oligopsony Potential in Agriculture: Residual Supply

Estimation in California's Processing Tomato Market." American Journal of Agricultural Economics 74, no. 4(1992): 962-972.

139

Folwell, R. J., R. C. Mittelhammer, and Q. Wang. "An Empirical Bargaining Model of Price Discovery: An Application to the Washington/Oregon Asparagus Industry." International Food and Agribusiness Management Review 1, no. 4(1998): 525-537.

Greene, W. H. "Econometric Analysis." Pearson Prentice Hall Six Edition(2008). Helmberger, P., and S. Hoos. "Cooperative Enterprise and Organization Theory." Journal of

Farm Economics 44, no. 2(1962): 275-290. Helmberger, P. G., and S. Hoos. "Economic Theory of Bargaining in Agriculture." Journal of

Farm Economics 45, no. 5(1963): 1272-1280. Iyer, G., and J. M. Villas-boas. "A Bargaining Theory of Distribution Channels." Journal of

Marketing Research 40, no. 1(2003): 21. Jesse, E. V., et al. "Interpreting and Enforcing Section 2 of the Capper-Volstead Act." American

Journal of Agricultural Economics 64, no. 3(1982): 431-443. Johnson, S. "Collective Bargaining in Milk Marketing." Journal of Farm Economics 49, no.

5(1967): 1376-&. Jun, B. H. "A structural Consideration on 3-person Bargaining." Chapter III in Essays on Topics

in Economic Theory, Ph.D Thesis, Department of Economics, University of Pennsylvania (1987).

Krishna, V., and R. Serrano. "Multilateral Bargaining." The Review of Economic Studies 63, no.

1(1996): 61-80. Ladd, G. W. "A Model of a Bargaining Cooperative." American Journal of Agricultural

Economics 56, no. 3(1974): 509-519. Levine, D. "A remark on serial correlation in maximum likelihood." Journal of Econometrics 23,

no. 3(1983): 337-342. Li, C., K. Sycara, and J. Ciampapa. "Dynamic Outside Options in Alternating-Offers

Negotiations." IEEE, Proceedings of the 38th Hawaii International Conference on System Sciences (2005).

Maude-Griffin, R., R. Feldman, and D. Wholey. "Nash bargaining model of HMO premiums."

Applied Economics 36, no. 12(2004): 1329-1336. Muthoo, A. "Bargaining Theory with Applications." Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

(1999). Muthoo, A. (1995) On the Strategic Role of outside Options in Bilateral Bargaining, vol. 43,

INFORMS, pp. 292-297.

140

Nagarajan, M., and Y. Bassok. "A Bargaining Framework in Supply Chains (The Assembly Problem) " Social Science Research Network http://ssrn.com/abstract=1021602(2002).

Napel, S. "Bilateral bargaining:Theory and Applications." Springer (2002): 188. Nash, J. F., Jr. "The Bargaining Problem." Econometrica 18, no. 2(1950): 155-162. Neumayer, E., and I. d. Soysa. "Globalization and the Right to Free Association and Collective

Bargaining: An Empirical Analysis." World Development 34, no. 1(2006): 31-49. Oczkowski, E. "An Econometric Analysis of the Bilateral Monopoly Model." Economic

Modelling 16, no. 1(1999): 11. Oczkowski, E. "The Econometrics of Markets with Quantity Controls." Applied Economics 23,

no. 3(1991): 8. Oczkowski, E. "Nash Bargaining and Co-operatives." Australian Economic Papers 45, no.

2(2006): 89-98. Phillips, P. C. B., and P. Perron. "Testing For A Unit Root In Time Series Regression."

Biometrika 75, no. 2(1988): 12. Ponsati, C., and J. Sakovics. "Rubinstein Bargaining with Two-sided outside Options."

Economic theory 11, no. 3(1998): 6. Prasertsri, P., and R. L. Kilmer. "The bargaining Strength of a Milk Marketing Cooperative."

Agricultural and Resource Economics Review 37, no. 2(2008): 7. Quandt, R. E. "The Econometrics of Disequilibrium." Blackwell, New York(1988). Roth, A. E. "Axiomatic Models of Bargaining." New York : Springer-Verlag (1979). Roth, A. E. "A Note on Risk Aversion in a Perfect Equilibrium Model of Bargaining."

Econometrica 53, no. 1(1985): 207-212. Rubinstein, A. "Perfect Equilibrium in a Bargaining Model." Econometrica 50, no. 1(1982): 97-

109. Rubinstein, A., Z. Safra, and W. Thomson. "On the Interpretation of the Nash Bargaining

Solution and Its Extension to Non-Expected Utility Preferences." Econometrica 60, no. 5(1992): 1171-1186.

Schneider, G. "Capacity and concessions: Bargaining power in multilateral negotiations."

Millennium-Journal of International Studies 33, no. 3(2005): 665-689.

141

Shaked, A. "Opting out: Bazaars versus " hi tech" Markets." Investigaciones Económicas 18, no. 3(1994): 12.

Shaked, A. "A Three-Person Unanimity Game." mimeo (1986). Shaked, A., and J. Sutton. "Involuntary Unemployment as a Perfect Equilibrium in a Bargaining

Model." Econometrica 52, no. 6(1984): 1351-1364. Sloof, R. "Finite Horizon Bargaining With Outside Options And Threat Points." Theory and

Decision 57, no. 2(2004): 34. Suh, S.-C., and Q. Wen. "Multi-agent bilateral bargaining and the Nash bargaining solution."

Journal of Mathematical Economics 42, no. 1(2006): 61-73.

142

BIOGRAPHICAL SKETCH

Jiaoju Ge was born in Hubei province, P.R. China. After she obtained her Bachelor of

Science degree in investment economics from Sichuan University in 1999, she worked for LG

Electronics for 3 years as a marketing product manager.

In August 2006, Jiaoju Ge was awarded the Master of Science degree from the Food and

Resource Economics in University of Florida under the direction of Dr. Allen Wysocki. Then she

was admitted to the PhD program in the Food and Resource Economics Department specialized

in marketing, econometrics and international trade and expected to graduate on December 2009.

She was married to Qiyong Xu on May 21st, 2002 and they have two kids, Michael and Sarah.