ttr final report - 8 feb 2013

Upload: juha-saarinen

Post on 04-Apr-2018

220 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 7/29/2019 TTR Final Report - 8 Feb 2013

    1/63

    Trans-Tasman roaming

    Final Report

    February 2013

  • 7/29/2019 TTR Final Report - 8 Feb 2013

    2/63

    1

    ContentsNo reliance .............................................................................................................................................. 3

    Background to the final report ............................................................................................................... 4

    Executive Summary ................................................................................................................................. 6

    Approach ............................................................................................................................................. 6

    Market definition ................................................................................................................................ 6

    Recent market outcomes .................................................................................................................... 6

    Future market outcomes .................................................................................................................... 7

    Options for intervention ..................................................................................................................... 8

    Recommendation ................................................................................................................................ 8

    Reasons for recommendation ............................................................................................................ 9

    Section 1: Market definition ................................................................................................................. 10

    1.1 Wholesale market ................................................................................................................. 10

    1.1.1 Product dimension ........................................................................................................ 10

    1.1.2 Geographic dimension .................................................................................................. 11

    1.1.3 Customer dimension ..................................................................................................... 11

    1.2 Downstream market ............................................................................................................. 111.2.1 Product dimension ........................................................................................................ 11

    1.1.2 Geographic dimension .................................................................................................. 20

    1.1.3 Customer dimension ..................................................................................................... 20

    1.3 Conclusion ............................................................................................................................. 20

    Section 2: Competition assessment: current state of the markets ...................................................... 21

    2.1 Introduction .......................................................................................................................... 21

    2.2 The wholesale market relevant to New Zealand roamers .................................................... 27

    2.3 The retail market relevant to New Zealand roamers ............................................................ 27

    2.4 The wholesale market relevant to Australian roamers ........................................................ 28

    2.5 The retail market relevant to Australian roamers ................................................................ 29

    Section 3: Competition assessment: future state of the markets ........................................................ 30

    3.1 What constraints have caused the wholesale margins to trend downwards? ..................... 30

    3.1.1 Credible service alternatives ......................................................................................... 30

    3.1.2 Market forces ................................................................................................................ 31

    3.1.3 Existing ex ante regimes................................................................................................ 36

  • 7/29/2019 TTR Final Report - 8 Feb 2013

    3/63

    2

    3.1.4 The current investigation .............................................................................................. 36

    3.2 Will the relevant constraints on wholesale remain in place? ............................................... 37

    3.3 Will new constraints on wholesale emerge? ........................................................................ 37

    3.4 Will retail margins continue to trend downwards? .............................................................. 38

    3.4.1 The impact of high IOTs on retail prices ....................................................................... 38

    3.4.2 The extent to which retail margin change will mitigate high IOTs ............................... 39

    3.5 Conclusion on future state of the markets ........................................................................... 40

    Section 4: Analysis of options for action ............................................................................................... 41

    4.1 Maintaining a watching brief ................................................................................................ 41

    4. 1.1 Submissions ................................................................................................................... 41

    4.1.2 Our view ........................................................................................................................ 42

    4.1.3 Conclusion on maintaining a watching brief ................................................................. 44

    4.2 Direct intervention in the market ......................................................................................... 44

    4.2.1 Measures directly aimed at pricing levels ..................................................................... 44

    4.2.2 Measures to alter the market structure ....................................................................... 48

    4.2.3 Conclusion on direct intervention in the market .......................................................... 52

    4. 3 Measures to promote pricing transparency ......................................................................... 52

    4.3.1 Submissions ................................................................................................................... 53

    4.3.2 Our view ........................................................................................................................ 54

    4.3.3 Conclusion on promoting pricing transparency ............................................................ 54

    4.4 Enhancing the abilities of the regulators .............................................................................. 55

    4.4.1 Submissions ................................................................................................................... 55

    4.4.2 Our view ........................................................................................................................ 56

    4.4.3 Conclusion on enhancing the abilities of the regulators .............................................. 58

    4.5 Conclusions on options for action ........................................................................................ 59

    Glossary and acronyms ......................................................................................................................... 60

  • 7/29/2019 TTR Final Report - 8 Feb 2013

    4/63

    3

    No reliance

    The opinions and proposals contained in this document are those of MBIE and DBCDE and do not

    necessarily reflect government policy.

    Readers are advised to seek specific legal advice from a qualified professional person before

    undertaking any action in reliance on the contents of this publication. The contents of this final

    report must not be construed as legal advice. MBIE and DBCDE do not accept any responsibility or

    liability whatsoever whether in contract, tort (including negligence), equity or otherwise for any

    action taken as a result of reading, or reliance placed on MBIE and DBCDE because of having read,

    any part, or all, of the information in this draft report or for any error, inadequacy, deficiency, flaw in

    or omission from it.

  • 7/29/2019 TTR Final Report - 8 Feb 2013

    5/63

    4

    Background to the final report

    In 2005, the Australian Competition and Consumer Commission (ACCC) examined international

    mobile roaming (IMR) services and concluded that the prices paid by Australian consumers appeared

    high1. Subsequently, in 2009, the Australian House of Representatives Standing Committee onCommunications released the report Phoning Home: Inquiry into international mobile roaming.

    One of its recommendations was that the Australian Government engage other countries in bilateral

    and multilateral negotiations to address high roaming costs, ensuring that countries with the largest

    number of Australian visitors be given priority.

    In this context, in May 2010, the then New Zealand Minister for Communications and Information

    Technology, Steven Joyce, and the Australian Minister for Broadband, Communications and the

    Digital Economy, Stephen Conroy, released a discussion document prepared by officials from the

    then Ministry of Economic Development (MED) and Australias Department of Broadband,

    Communications and the Digital Economy (DBCDE).

    The purpose of the discussion document was to test whether the state of the trans-Tasman roaming

    market was such as to warrant a full market investigation. The discussion document and the

    responses to it are available at:

    www.med.govt.nz/sectors-industries/technology-communication/communications/mobile-

    phones/trans-tasman-roaming/submissions

    www.dbcde.gov.au/mobile_services/mobile_roaming/trans-

    tasman_mobile_roaming_discussion_paper

    In April 2011, having considered submissions on the discussion document as well as traffic and

    revenue data collected from operators, Minister Joyce and Senator Conroy announced that theywere launching a full market investigation. The reasons for their decision are at:

    www.med.govt.nz/sectors-industries/technology-communication/communications/mobile-

    phones/trans-tasman-roaming

    www.dbcde.gov.au/ttmr

    The purpose of the full investigation has been to determine whether the market is competitive and,

    if not, what (if any) form of intervention by the New Zealand and Australian governments should be

    considered.

    To this end, the Ministry of Business, Innovation and Employment (MBIE) and DBCDE prepared a

    draft report, published in August 2012. The draft report comprised a market definition, anassessment of competition within the market so defined and an analysis of potential interventions.

    As an input to the draft report, MBIE and DBCDE (together referred to in this final report as we)

    also funded the preparation of a separate study by a consulting firm, WIK-Consult (WIK). WIKs study

    estimated the underlying costs that mobile operators face in providing trans-Tasman roaming

    services.

    The draft report, the WIK study and submissions on them are available at:

    1 ACCC, 2005, Mobile Services Review: International inter-carrier roaming, p. 53,www.accc.gov.au/content/index.phtml/itemId/333898

    http://www.med.govt.nz/sectors-industries/technology-communication/communications/mobile-phones/trans-tasman-roaming/submissionshttp://www.med.govt.nz/sectors-industries/technology-communication/communications/mobile-phones/trans-tasman-roaming/submissionshttp://www.med.govt.nz/sectors-industries/technology-communication/communications/mobile-phones/trans-tasman-roaming/submissionshttp://www.dbcde.gov.au/mobile_services/mobile_roaming/trans-tasman_mobile_roaming_discussion_paperhttp://www.dbcde.gov.au/mobile_services/mobile_roaming/trans-tasman_mobile_roaming_discussion_paperhttp://www.med.govt.nz/sectors-industries/technology-communication/communications/mobile-phones/trans-tasman-roaminghttp://www.med.govt.nz/sectors-industries/technology-communication/communications/mobile-phones/trans-tasman-roaminghttp://www.med.govt.nz/sectors-industries/technology-communication/communications/mobile-phones/trans-tasman-roaminghttp://www.dbcde.gov.au/ttmrhttp://www.dbcde.gov.au/ttmrhttp://www.accc.gov.au/content/index.phtml/itemId/333898http://www.accc.gov.au/content/index.phtml/itemId/333898http://www.accc.gov.au/content/index.phtml/itemId/333898http://www.accc.gov.au/content/index.phtml/itemId/333898http://www.dbcde.gov.au/ttmrhttp://www.med.govt.nz/sectors-industries/technology-communication/communications/mobile-phones/trans-tasman-roaminghttp://www.med.govt.nz/sectors-industries/technology-communication/communications/mobile-phones/trans-tasman-roaminghttp://www.dbcde.gov.au/mobile_services/mobile_roaming/trans-tasman_mobile_roaming_discussion_paperhttp://www.dbcde.gov.au/mobile_services/mobile_roaming/trans-tasman_mobile_roaming_discussion_paperhttp://www.med.govt.nz/sectors-industries/technology-communication/communications/mobile-phones/trans-tasman-roaming/submissionshttp://www.med.govt.nz/sectors-industries/technology-communication/communications/mobile-phones/trans-tasman-roaming/submissions
  • 7/29/2019 TTR Final Report - 8 Feb 2013

    6/63

    5

    www.med.govt.nz/sectors-industries/technology-communication/communications/mobile-

    phones/trans-tasman-roaming

    www.dbcde.gov.au/ttmr

    Following consultation and analysis of submissions, MBIE and DBCDE have prepared this Final

    Report.

    http://www.med.govt.nz/sectors-industries/technology-communication/communications/mobile-phones/trans-tasman-roaminghttp://www.med.govt.nz/sectors-industries/technology-communication/communications/mobile-phones/trans-tasman-roaminghttp://www.med.govt.nz/sectors-industries/technology-communication/communications/mobile-phones/trans-tasman-roaminghttp://www.dbcde.gov.au/ttmrhttp://www.dbcde.gov.au/ttmrhttp://www.dbcde.gov.au/ttmrhttp://www.med.govt.nz/sectors-industries/technology-communication/communications/mobile-phones/trans-tasman-roaminghttp://www.med.govt.nz/sectors-industries/technology-communication/communications/mobile-phones/trans-tasman-roaming
  • 7/29/2019 TTR Final Report - 8 Feb 2013

    7/63

    6

    Executive Summary

    Approach

    In this Final Report, MBIE and DBCDE set out a market definition, an assessment of competitionwithin the market so defined, and an analysis of different interventions.

    This approach accords with that taken by the two countries telecommunications regulators, the

    Commerce Commission and the Australian Competition and Consumer Commission, when they

    investigate domestic telecommunications issues.

    Market definition

    MBIE and DBCDE maintain the conclusion in the Draft Report that there are four relevant markets.

    Two of these markets are relevant to New Zealand customers roaming in Australia and two are

    relevant to Australian customers roaming in New Zealand.

    The markets relevant to New Zealand roamers are:

    the wholesale market in which Australian visited networks sell services to New Zealandhome networks; and

    the retail market in which New Zealand home networks and MVNOs, and potentially

    Australian visited networks, sell services to New Zealand customers roaming in Australia.

    The markets relevant to Australian roamers are:

    the wholesale market in which New Zealand visited networks sell services to Australian

    home networks; and the retail market in which Australian home networks and MVNOs, and potentially New

    Zealand visited networks, sell services to Australian customers roaming in New Zealand.

    The services in question, which cover voice, SMS and data communications, comprise traditional

    international roaming services but also mobile local access services, which enable a home

    networks roamer to use a mobile device like a local user, without having to swap the SIM card,

    while remaining contactable on the original number.

    Recent market outcomes

    In the Draft Report, we assessed market outcomes in the calendar years 2009, 2010 and 2011,examining the pricing of, and margins on, services in the wholesale and retail markets, as well as

    other features such as the range and quality of services offered. Voice, SMS and data were examined

    separately in the pricing analysis, due to the different units used (minutes, texts, and MBs).

    However, voice, SMS and data were aggregated in the margin analysis to reflect the market

    definition.

    We maintain our conclusion that, within the wholesale and retail markets examined, prices and

    margins have, broadly speaking, been trending down since 2009 (particularly for data roaming), and

    the quality of service is high. While margins are still significant, and no New Zealand or Australian

    operator has introduced mobile local-access services, very recent developments, such as Telecom

    New Zealands flat-rate for post-paid data roaming, nevertheless suggest positive progress.

  • 7/29/2019 TTR Final Report - 8 Feb 2013

    8/63

    7

    Future market outcomes

    We maintain the conclusion of the Draft Report that the joint investigation by the New Zealand and

    Australian governments has been a key factor in the emergence of reduced prices and margins in

    each countrys wholesale market. Reductions have coincided with the joint investigation, and other

    factors, though they may have contributed to the reductions, are unlikely to have been sufficient, forthe following reasons.

    Service alternativesthere are no credible service alternatives at wholesale level that constrainvisited networks terms of supply.

    Emergence of three solid operators in each marketthis is unlikely to have stimulated

    significant competition in trans-Tasman mobile roaming since:

    o there does not appear to be a clear correlation between the number of visited networks in

    a given destination and the level of wholesale pricing;

    o visited networks in New Zealand and Australia cannot compete on an even playing field for

    trans-Tasman roaming traffic, due to such factors as frequency incompatibilities, grouployalties and vastly different levels of return traffic.

    The existing ex ante regulatory frameworksthese create an effective threat only where there

    are access seekers with an ability and willingness to seek regulated terms of supply. In

    international roaming, the access seekers are the home networks. However, a home network

    that is net inbound2 actually prefers high wholesale prices, since they contribute to its

    wholesale profit without (given price inelasticity) significantly reducing its retail profit. A home

    network that is net outbound3, meanwhile, has its incentive to seek a low wholesale price

    undermined by the desire to secure the most return traffic it can, as this will minimise the loss

    it makes at wholesale level.

    We further consider that other potential constraints on visited networks behaviour are unlikely to

    emerge in the next few years.

    Mobile local-access servicesno operator has indicated it has plans to introduce 2G or 3G-compatible mobile local-access services, and the LTE-based local break-out solution will not be

    available to the vast majority of trans-Tasman roamers for many years to come (if at all).

    Structural change in the market2degrees is likely to increase its footprint and (potentially) its

    volume of return traffic, and VHAs 850MHz overlay network will equip it to compete better

    for Telecom NZ traffic. However, the majority of structural challenges in the market will remain,

    including frequency incompatibility, group loyalties, and Telecom NZs lack of a 2G network

    (although as Australian 2G traffic declines, this last factor will become less of a handicap for

    Telecom NZ).

    Strengthening of countervailing buyer powerthe growing importance of data may lead home

    networks to place more emphasis on the quality of service a visited network can offer,

    potentially shifting their focus away from return traffic. However, this is still an embryonic

    change and the extent to which it overrides a (net outbound) home networks desire to

    minimise wholesale losses is yet to be seen.

    2 A home network is net inbound, vis--vis a given foreign operator, if the wholesale revenue it receives from that foreign operator (for hosting that operators

    customers), exceeds the wholesale payments it makes to that f oreign operator (for hosting the home networks customers).

    3 A home network is net outbound, vis--vis a given foreign operator, if the wholesale revenue it receives from that foreign operator (for hosting that operators

    customers), are less than the wholesale payments it makes to that foreign operator (for hosting the home networks customers).

  • 7/29/2019 TTR Final Report - 8 Feb 2013

    9/63

    8

    Threat of entrymarket entry appears unlikely in either New Zealand or Australia, with the

    global trend towards consolidation. In any event, we have not seen a clear correlation between

    the number of visited networks in a market and the wholesale prices charged to home

    networks.

    Regulatory developmentsfor incoming voice calls, the charges that operators can levy for

    mobile termination access services (MTAS) are trending down, by virtue of regulation, and for

    practical reasons these drops will also apply to the termination charges levied by visited

    networks. However, the impact will not be significant on the wider trans-Tasman roaming

    market.

    In this context, we consider that, upon the conclusion of the joint investigation, wholesale prices and

    margins are likely to cease to fall. We also consider that retail margins are likely to cease to fall,

    meaning that they will not mitigate the impact of the wholesale price issue. This provides

    justification for considering joint action by both governments.

    Options for intervention

    In the Draft Report, we set out seven options for coordinated action by the New Zealand and

    Australian governments. Some alternative options were also suggested in submissions.

    In this Final Report, the original seven options and the alternatives have been grouped into four

    categories:

    Option 1: maintaining a watching brief;

    Option 2: directly intervening in the market;

    Option 3: requiring reporting on pricing trends; and

    Option 4: enhancing the ability of the regulators to intervene effectively.

    Option One is for the two governments to maintain a watching brief, and to launch a furtherinvestigation in future, if necessary.

    Option Two is for the two governments to introduce, through legislation, measures directly aimed at

    pricing levels (imposing wholesale regulated terms of access, or wholesale and/or retail price caps)

    or measures designed to alter the market structure (unbundling trans-Tasman roaming from

    domestic mobile services, or requiring operators to offer mobile local-access services).

    Option Three is for the two governments, through legislation, to require mobile operators to

    provide the New Zealand and Australian regulators with wholesale and retail traffic and revenue

    information on trans-Tasman roaming, and for the regulators to report publicly on this.

    Option Four is for the two governments, through legislation, to empower the New Zealand and

    Australian regulators, when investigating trans-Tasman roaming services, to choose from a wider

    range of regulatory measures, should the regulators determine that intervention is warranted.

    Recommendation

    We favour Options Three and Four in parallel. We therefore recommend that the New Zealand and

    Australian governments:

    require the New Zealand and Australian regulators to collect and report regularly on wholesale

    and retail price trends for trans-Tasman roaming, with appropriate protections against

    disclosure of commercially sensitive information; and

  • 7/29/2019 TTR Final Report - 8 Feb 2013

    10/63

    9

    expand the remedies available to the New Zealand and Australian regulators for investigations

    into trans-Tasman roaming services, to include:

    o wholesale regulated terms of access;

    o wholesale price caps;o retail price caps, whether opt-in, opt-out or compulsory for roamers (with a

    presumption in favour of opt-in, in order to minimise market distortions);o mobile local-access obligations:

    a wholesale obligation on visited networks to offer home networks a mobile

    local-access service, and a corresponding retail obligation on home networks

    to offer that mobile local-access service to their end-users; or

    a retail obligation on visited networks to offer directly to inbound roamers a

    mobile local-access service.

    We also recommend that, in implementing these recommendations, the two governments ensure

    that:

    regulators aim to cooperate on remedies rather than imposing them unilaterally, whilerecognising that different market conditions in different countries could justify a departure

    from this principle;

    regulators be free to apply remedies asymmetrically amongst operators, and to impose

    combinations of remedies, if that is appropriate in the circumstances at the relevant time.

    Reasons for recommendation

    The benefits of expanding the regulators palette of remedies mimic those of directly intervening,

    with far fewer upfront costs. Because operators, particularly those in New Zealand, have responded

    to the threat of effective regulation posed by the current investigation, it is likely that, once

    enhanced remedies are implemented, prices for trans-Tasman roaming will continue their decline

    and operators will continue to expand the array of features they offer their trans-Tasman roamers

    perhaps even introducing mobile local-access services. In the event that this does not occur, and

    regulators are obliged to intervene in the market, then prices will at that time be forced down to

    competitive levels.

    Requiring the regulators to collect and report on pricing trends could name and shame operators

    (as a group) into more competitive offerings. It would also provide the regulators, and potentially

    the Governments during a review of the effectiveness of the regime proposed, with information

    they could use to decide whether consideration of further (or less) intervention is necessary. It is

    therefore a useful and proportionate complement to the expansion of regulatory remedies.

  • 7/29/2019 TTR Final Report - 8 Feb 2013

    11/63

    10

    Section 1: Market definition

    We begin this section with a brief comment on the approach we have taken.

    In the Draft Report, we approached the definition of relevant (wholesale) markets by:- starting with the provision by VNs to HNs of trans-Tasman voice, SMS and data roamingservices;

    - considering whether other services should be included in the same market as those services

    either because:

    o the other service is substitutable for those services; or

    o the other service forms part of a cluster with those services.

    In our assessment of substitutability, we used the hypothetical monopolist test, to determine

    whether a small but significant, non-transitory price (SSNIP) increase would be sustainable. Some

    respondents criticised this approach.

    Telecom NZ submitted that the use of the SSNIP test to the markets for services in network

    industries should in our view be the exception rather than the rule.4 Vodafone NZ echoed this by

    stating that SSNIP tests are commonly used in an anti-trust context for mergers and acquisitions.5

    These submissions are misplaced. It is true that there are occasions when the SSNIP test should be

    avoided in network industries, but that is where industry rates are regulated. This is because, if the

    regulated rate is lower than the hypothetically competitive rate, there is more scope for a SSNIP

    on the regulated rate to be sustainable. As a result, the market can be defined too narrowly (the

    reverse Cellophane fallacy). In the present case, however, there is no regulation of trans-Tasman

    roaming rates.

    1.1 Wholesale market

    1.1.1 Product dimension

    In the Draft Report, we concluded that the product dimension for wholesale trans-Tasman roaming

    services included access, origination and termination, and that it encompassed these services

    whether they were supplied in the context of traditional roaming (where communications primarily

    hub through the home network) or in the context of a mobile local-access (MLA) service (where

    communications are effected by the visited network alone).

    Telecom NZ made an oblique criticism of this approach in stating that the market definition should

    have taken a broader approach to economic substitutes and not been as technologically focussed.6

    When asked for clarification, the company stated in correspondence with us that wifi (a

    technologically different service) might be a wholesale substitute for HNs. In fact, the Draft Report

    4Telecom NZ, para 8

    5Vodafone NZ, para 26

    6Telecom NZ, para 8

  • 7/29/2019 TTR Final Report - 8 Feb 2013

    12/63

    11

    considered wifi as a wholesale substitute. We stated that this service faces obstacles to being

    considered a substitute for wholesale IMR services: not only is it a data-centric service, but it also

    fails to offer the comprehensive geographic coverage of a mobile network.7 We have seen no

    evidence in submissions to suggest that this conclusion was flawed. We note further that HNs do not

    provide the ability to redirect incoming calls to their roamers Wi-Fi VoIP service.

    1.1.2 Geographic dimension

    The Draft Report concluded that the wholesale market for the provision of trans-Tasman roaming

    services is a single national one. In other words, VNs compete in one territory, being the whole of

    the country in which they are established. Respondents did not comment on this conclusion, and we

    maintain it.

    1.1.3 Customer dimension

    The Draft Report defined the wholesale market as the market for the provision of IMR-like services

    to HNs across the Tasman, rather than to HNs from all foreign destinations. Respondents did not

    comment on this conclusion, and we maintain it.

    1.2 Downstream market

    1.2.1 Product dimension

    In the Draft Report, we concluded that the product dimension for retail trans-Tasman roaming

    services included access, origination and termination, and that it encompassed these serviceswhether they were supplied in the context of traditional roaming or in the context of an MLA

    service.

    The two major issues that emerged during the consultation period were:

    - whether domestic services should be included in the retail market; and- whether alternative means of communication should be included in the retail market.

    1.2.1.1 Domestic services

    The Draft Report concluded that domestic retail mobile services should not be considered to form acluster market with trans-Tasman roaming services, given the evidence of the MED survey that a

    large number of customers would unpick the two services if they were able.

    In its submission, Optus however stressed that operators compete by selling a multi-product bundle

    of services to consumers These services are not typically offered on a stand-alone basis rather they

    are offered in combination as product bundles. As such any proper analysis of the market must

    consider how operators compete across the combined bundle.8 (para 1.3). The GSM Association

    7Draft Report,section 1.1.1.1, at p.15

    8

    Optus, para 1.3

  • 7/29/2019 TTR Final Report - 8 Feb 2013

    13/63

    12

    echoed these comments, stating that looking at roaming prices in isolation may be misleading, as

    the price of roaming is one element within an overall tariff bundle for the total mobile service that a

    consumer purchases. This bundle can include the price of a mobile handset, the monthly rental,

    domestic call charges, SMS charges, volume discounts, contract term, and interconnection charges

    for terminating calls that originate off-net.9

    What these respondents are effectively claiming is that operators determine the market definition

    by their practices: if they include a service in a bundle, then it is part of the same retail market as the

    other services in the bundle.

    However, as the European Commission has made clear, if, in the presence of a small but significant

    non-transitory increase in price there is evidence that a sufficient number of customers would

    unpick the bundle and obtain the service elements of the bundle separately, then it can be

    concluded that the service elements constitute the relevant markets in their own right and not the

    bundle.10

    The MED survey results seemed to provide the evidence mentioned by the European Commissionbut, given recent price drops for retail roaming services, they may now be vulnerable to the

    cellophane fallacy. Still, respondents have not provided any evidence contradicting the initial

    assumption we made in the May 2010 Discussion Document that sufficient customers would choose

    to unpick domestic services and international roaming if they had the choice. Nor, as we noted in

    the Draft Report, has any New Zealand or Australian operator ever argued that the OECD/Teligen

    domestic pricing benchmarks (often relied upon by the New Zealand regulator, the NZCC/M, and the

    Australian regulator, the ACCC, for the regulation of domestic services) should be extended to

    include IMR pricing in order to reflect a wider retail market definition. Finally, we also wonder to

    what extent operators can credibly argue that trans-Tasman roaming services are part of the

    domestic services market when the bulk of their submissions argue that trans-Tasman roaming

    services are in the same market as local alternative services.

    As such, we maintain our view that, despite the bundling of domestic services with trans-Tasman

    roaming services, there are insufficient grounds on which to include the two services within a cluster

    market.

    1.2.1.2 Roaming in other destinations

    The Draft Report concluded that it was not appropriate to include roaming services for third-country

    destinations in the retail market, notably due to the lack of demand-side substitutability.

    Respondents did not comment on this conclusion, and we maintain it.

    9GSM Association, p.8

    10See Explanatory Memorandum to Commission recommendation dated 11 December 2011 on Relevant

    Product and Service Markets within the electronic communications sector susceptible to ex ante regulation, at

    section 3.2

  • 7/29/2019 TTR Final Report - 8 Feb 2013

    14/63

    13

    1.2.1.3 Alternative means of communication

    The Draft Report concluded that it was inappropriate to include any alternative means of

    communication in the same retail market as trans-Tasman roaming. It did so on the basis of limited

    supply-side and demand-side substitutability.

    Arguments on this point centred on the interpretation of survey results and on the conclusions

    reached.

    Interpretation of survey results

    In the Draft Report, we made two key assumptions when interpreting the results of the MED survey:

    first, that using a roaming service less in response to a SSNIP (own price elasticity) is not sufficient

    to demonstrate demand-side substitutability; and that when assessing diversion ratios to alternative

    services (cross price elasticity), it was appropriate to test individual alternatives rather than

    alternatives collectively.

    In our opinion, such an approach sits well with Queensland Wire, where it was stated that in the

    determination of a 'market' for particular purposes, regard shall be had to substitute products, being

    products which have a reasonable interchangeability of use and which have high cross-elasticity of

    demand, i.e. where a small decrease in the price of a particular product would cause a significant

    quantum of demand for a similar product to switch to the product in question.11

    Nevertheless, Optus objected to both our assumptions. It considered that significant own price

    elasticity was sufficient to demonstrate demand-side substitutability.12 It also submitted that the

    SSNIP test must be applied to all alternative means of communication as a group.13

    On the first point, we can understand Optus perspective. However, it fails to take into account therisk of false negatives that the SSNIP test can generate; the fact that many people might simply use

    a product less, rather than switch to any alternatives, may mean that a price rise is unsustainable,

    but not because of any demand-side substitutability (which is what we are trying to assess).

    On the second point, Optus appears to be echoing sentiments expressed in the academic literature.

    Werden, for example, has written that it is folly to focus on the competitive significance of

    individual substitutes rather than on the collective competitive significance of all substitutes. He

    states:

    If there are many brands, as with breakfast cereals, the cross elasticities of demand between

    any pair of products may be quite small [A] small increase in [a brands] price would induce

    substitution to many other brands, each of which gains only a small fraction of the customers. Ifcross elasticities were the basis for market delineation, each brand would probably have to be

    considered a market unto itself.14

    11Mason CJ and Wilson J, in Queensland Wire Industries Pty. Ltd. v Broken Hill Proprietary Co. Ltd (1989)

    Australia, 167 CLR 177

    12Optus, para 2.28

    13Optus, para 2.21

    14Gregory Werden, Demand Elasticities in Antitrust Analysis, Antitrust Law Journal, Vol 66, No.2, 1998, p.363

    at p.402

  • 7/29/2019 TTR Final Report - 8 Feb 2013

    15/63

    14

    We accept that the Draft Report may have erred in this respect. We think, as a matter of common

    sense, there is a case for using the own-price elasticity as a guide for whether or not another

    individual product should be added to the market definition. Individual cross-elasticities can then be

    used to select the next best alternative to add to a market definition before repeating the SSNIP

    test.

    In this regard, the own-price elasticity indicated in the survey ranged from 40-71% of respondents in

    the MED survey, depending on whether they were individuals, SMEs or large corporates, and

    whether the test concerned voice or data.

    On the face of it, this suggests that a 10% price increase would be unsustainable and that the next

    best alternative product should be added to the market, before repeating the survey. However,

    switchers would continue to generate a certain amount of roaming traffic because:

    - the survey indicates respondents would try to use roaming less, not stop using it altogether;and

    - there are barriers to switching that may make it hard for respondents to act on their desireto move to an alternative service (for example, wifi cannot be used outside accessible wifizones, company premises may not be accessible 24 hours a day).15

    The issue becomes whether this residual use of roaming by switchers, when combined with the

    increased revenue from the SSNIP applied to non-switchers, would be enough to compensate for the

    loss in revenue caused by the partial switching to alternative services.

    We suspect that the answer is no, and that therefore we would need to add the strongest

    substitute and then rerun the SSNIP test with a new survey. However, we do not consider it

    necessary to resolve this issue definitively.

    That is because, as the Draft Report noted, the prices used for the MED survey were the prevailing

    prices at the time. Subsequent price movements have demonstrated that these were startlingly far

    from the competitive level. 2degrees, for example, now offers incoming voice calls at NZ$0.44 per

    minute and data at as little as NZ$0.50 per MB. This compares with the figures of NZ$1.00 per

    minute and NZ$10.00 per MB used in the survey. Telecom NZ itself highlights this cellophane

    fallacy: The reality is that the starting point of the SSNIP test applied was at a price that is

    substantially higher than it is today.16

    As a result, the responses to the SSNIP portion of the MED survey are likely to lead to an overly wide

    market definition, and should not be relied on.

    15In this regard, ACCANs submission on the optimism bias seems relevant when interpreting the MED

    survey results. In section 1.2 of its submission, ACCAN notes that consumers have an unrealistic optimism

    about future events and believe that they are more skilled and less likely to experience a negative event than

    others.

    16Telecom NZ, para 8

  • 7/29/2019 TTR Final Report - 8 Feb 2013

    16/63

    15

    Conclusions reached

    In this context, we consider that it is appropriate to focus on other elements that may provide clues

    as to the limits of the relevant retail market. As pointed out by Optus, the ACCC has set out a

    number of types of information that can inform an assessment of substitutability.17 These include:

    - the function of the product;- physical and technical characteristics of the product;

    - costs of switching purchases;

    - views and past behaviour of buyers;- evidence of buyers switching to other products in response to price increases in the recent

    past;

    - evidence of producers redeploying their production capacity in response to price increases

    in the recent past;

    - views, business records and past behaviour of suppliers;

    - relative price levels and price movements.

    As evidenced by the submissions, the two main contenders for inclusion in the same market astrans-Tasman roaming services are wifi services and SIM cards.

    Using the ACCC points as a guide, we consider that wifi hotspots should be excluded from the

    market, on multiple grounds. For example, the function of trans-Tasman roaming is to allow

    communications across the breadth of a territory; the function of wifi is to enable communications

    within discrete geographic zones. The main technical characteristic of roaming is support for voice,

    SMS and data services; the main technical characteristic of wifi is support for data services. The costs

    of switching to wifi are high in the sense that the customer loses the ability to use his or her original

    number, can no longer use traditional telephony or SMS service, and may face difficulties in

    registering complaints. Wifi also generally involves significant security compromises compared to

    use of a cellular network. Furthermore, there seems little possibility for wifi providers to switch toproviding mobile cellular services in response to a SSNIP. And operators, while they have expressed

    the view that they compete with wifi, have produced no evidence in support, be it evidence that

    they have actively monitored wifi prices abroad or evidence that roaming price trends correlate with

    foreign wifi prices. For example, neither VHA (3 brand) or Telstra has provided any evidence of

    customers switching to wifi, in response to their increases in outgoing voice and SMS prices for

    trans-Tasman roaming between 2010 and 2011.

    We are less certain about excluding SIM cards, be they local (e.g. for a New Zealander, a Telstra

    SIM card) or global (e.g. TravelSIM).

    In this regard, while TUANZ points out that swapping out a SIM card for a local providers card is

    rarely as simple as it sounds18 (for example, with iOS handsets, the consumer must type in a local

    APN before gaining access to data services), local and global SIMs do share with trans-Tasman

    roaming the same function and the same technical characteristics (except to the extent that some

    global SIMs are limited to voice and text).

    Further, as Vodafone NZ states, mobile operators on both sides of the Tasman including Vodafone

    have spent considerable amounts on advertising at international airports. International airport

    17ACCC, Merger Guidelines, para 4.27

    18TUANZ, p.4

  • 7/29/2019 TTR Final Report - 8 Feb 2013

    17/63

    16

    advertising for local SIMs, similar to airport car-parking, is considerably more expensive than most

    other forms of similar advertising. Vodafone New Zealand continues to spend significant on

    advertising at international airports. However, the benefit of engaging in such activity is clearly

    correlated and only justified by local SIM substitution for mobile roaming.19

    One issue that concerns us, however, is the need to change SIM cards and the associated loss of thecustomers usual mobile number. Optus claims that the fact that alternative local services do not

    allow a roamer to be contacted on his or her usual number is not sufficient to warrant a separate

    economic market.20 However, as TUANZ states in its submission, loss of ones usual mobile number

    is not a painless experience for most customers.21 Optus has itself previously underlined the

    barrier that loss of ones mobile number poses domestically, stating that with the introduction of

    mobile number portability in the Australian domestic market the last barrier to competition in the

    mobile market is about to finally come down.22 In New Zealand, the Telecommunications Forum

    (TCF) states on its website that local and mobile number portability has empowered consumers and

    businesses to choose the service provider that best meets their needs.23

    Another issue with including local and global SIM cards in the same market as trans-Tasman roamingservices, at least for the downstream market relevant to Australian roamers,24 is SIM-locking. All

    Australian operators SIM-lock some of their mobile devices. While most SIM-locking concerns

    prepaid roamers (who are, we understand, less likely to roam):

    - this is of little comfort to prepaid roamers; and

    - post-paid customers using Apple and Blackberry devices are also SIM-locked. While this is at

    the direction of the device manufacturer and can be reversed by a call to the operator

    concerned, it remains an extra obstacle to those who, upon arrival in New Zealand, find

    themselves unable to make a local SIM function.

    Still, we note that despite similar barriers to switching faced by domestic end-users (for example, the

    absence of mobile number portability in New Zealand until 2007; SIM-locking in Australia; theexistence of incompatible CDMA and GSM networks in both countries for a time), the NZCC/M and

    ACCC have both included all mobile connections in the same retail mobile services market

    19VFNZ, para 25. We would point out, however, that while operators domestic teams are aware of pricing for,

    and compete with, roaming services (e.g. advertising at airports), operators have produced no evidence that

    their roaming teams are aware of pricing for, and compete with/feel constrained by, domestic services. New

    Zealand operators produced no charts from their roaming teams showing they track (or are even aware of)

    Australian prepaid pricing, and Australian operators produced no charts from their roaming teams showing

    they track (or are even aware of) New Zealand prepaid pricing.20

    Optus, para 2.57

    21TUANZ, p.4.

    22See media release dated 27 August 2001 at

    www.optus.com.au/aboutoptus/About+Optus/Media+Centre/Media+Releases/2001/Optus+unveils+MNP+pla

    ns

    23See www.tcf.org.nz/content/26d0a04d-68a3-4cbd-bafb-ebee1d688992.html

    24Telecom NZs Skinny brand also SIM-locks its handsets, although it is a very minor player in the market.

    http://www.optus.com.au/aboutoptus/About+Optus/Media+Centre/Media+Releases/2001/Optus+unveils+MNP+planshttp://www.optus.com.au/aboutoptus/About+Optus/Media+Centre/Media+Releases/2001/Optus+unveils+MNP+planshttp://www.tcf.org.nz/content/26d0a04d-68a3-4cbd-bafb-ebee1d688992.htmlhttp://www.tcf.org.nz/content/26d0a04d-68a3-4cbd-bafb-ebee1d688992.htmlhttp://www.optus.com.au/aboutoptus/About+Optus/Media+Centre/Media+Releases/2001/Optus+unveils+MNP+planshttp://www.optus.com.au/aboutoptus/About+Optus/Media+Centre/Media+Releases/2001/Optus+unveils+MNP+plans
  • 7/29/2019 TTR Final Report - 8 Feb 2013

    18/63

    17

    downstream from wholesale mobile termination services.2526 They do not appear to have

    considered that these barriers to switching warranted defining separate retail markets for different

    operators (although we can find no active consideration of this point by the regulators). Is there

    something that distinguishes trans-Tasman roaming services from domestic services, such that the

    regulators approach to domestic market definition should not apply?

    We believe there may be. This is because the costs associated with switching SIM cards, and losing

    ones original number, seem higher when roaming than when at home, both in absolute terms and

    relative to the benefits gained.

    In absolute terms, the switching process domestically is seamless: customers are in a familiar

    environment (their home market) and can use their original number without penalty until the very

    moment they insert the rival companys SIM card. Whats more, after switching mobile numbers,

    many can still be reached on a fixed line connection (be it at the home or at the office) by those

    unaware of their change of number.

    By contrast, roaming customers are in an unfamiliar environment and, unless they hold a (still active)SIM card from a previous trip, they will also have to either go without communication, or navigate a

    period of roaming charges, before they locate and insert a local SIM (and for New Zealand travellers

    in Australia, produce appropriate registration details).27 After switching numbers, they are unlikely

    to be as easily reachable on a fixed line connection, since their fixed contact number will have

    changed also (and indeed may change from day to day if they are travelling around their visited

    destination). They will also lose in terms of mobile coverage: roamers enjoy the combined coverage

    of all the visited networks with which their home network has a roaming agreement, but on

    switching to a local SIM they are limited to the coverage offered by the local operator they have

    chosen. Roaming customers who use local SIM or global cards also have to switch numbers twice:

    once upon arrival in the destination; and again on their return to their home market.

    In relative terms, domestic customers stand to gain for a long period of time by switching to a more

    competitive provider. By contrast, trans-Tasman roamers travel to their destination for a limited

    period of time. In this context, the cost of changing SIMs becomes greater, relative to the likely

    benefits: a morning spent finding a local SIM card,28 then making calls to ones home network to

    unlock ones device, is a valuable portion of ones trip not spent visiting local attractions or securing

    a business deal.

    In this context, we tend to the view that local and global SIM cards are not part of the same retail

    market as trans-Tasman roaming services.

    25By contrast, neither the ACCC nor the NZCC/M has ever included wifi in the downstream (domestic) mobile

    market for any wholesale mobile service

    26See also the ACCC Final Report on mobile number portability (MNP) dated September 1999, at

    www.accc.gov.au/content/item.phtml?itemId=688494&nodeId=bcc11f2ed2bdfe18764f9eaf364f6932&fn=Mo

    bile+number+portability+final+report+(Sep+99).pdf

    27Local SIM cards are available at some international airports.

    28Anecdotal evidence suggests that most visitors arriving after a three-hour trans-Tasman flight do not line up

    to acquire a local SIM card at the airport.

    http://www.accc.gov.au/content/item.phtml?itemId=688494&nodeId=bcc11f2ed2bdfe18764f9eaf364f6932&fn=Mobile+number+portability+final+report+(Sep+99).pdfhttp://www.accc.gov.au/content/item.phtml?itemId=688494&nodeId=bcc11f2ed2bdfe18764f9eaf364f6932&fn=Mobile+number+portability+final+report+(Sep+99).pdfhttp://www.accc.gov.au/content/item.phtml?itemId=688494&nodeId=bcc11f2ed2bdfe18764f9eaf364f6932&fn=Mobile+number+portability+final+report+(Sep+99).pdfhttp://www.accc.gov.au/content/item.phtml?itemId=688494&nodeId=bcc11f2ed2bdfe18764f9eaf364f6932&fn=Mobile+number+portability+final+report+(Sep+99).pdf
  • 7/29/2019 TTR Final Report - 8 Feb 2013

    19/63

    18

    However, we think it important to consider a further indicator useful for market delineation

    purposes: price correlation. If two products/regions are in the same market, one would expect that

    prices move together over time due to active demand and supply substitution.

    Given that New Zealand operators do not generally SIM-lock their mobile devices, and that roaming

    to Australia constitutes a large proportion of all outbound roaming for New Zealand operators, onemight expect any price correlation between trans-Tasman roaming prices and local/global SIM prices

    to be more apparent in the New Zealand (as opposed to Australian) Retail Market.

    However, trends in New Zealand operators roaming prices for Australia do not appear to have

    correlated significantly to trends in pricing for Australian local users or to trends in pricing for global

    SIM users.

    For example, the graph below shows New Zealand operators pricing for data roaming in Australia as

    against recent trends in Australian wireless Internet pricing.2930 The graph shows little apparent

    price correlation.

    The graph below shows New Zealand operators pricing for voice roaming31 in Australia as against

    recent trends in Australian prepaid GSM pricing (GSM pricing being a proxy for voice pricing,

    although SMS are also included in the basket32).33 This appears to show some degree of correlation,

    although only after the 2009/2010 period when the joint investigation was launched.

    29 Australian pricing has been sourced from the ACCC report entitled Changes in prices paid for

    telecommunications services in Australia, 201112, scheduled to be tabled in the Australian Parliament in the

    first sitting week of 2013. That report states that wireless internet services are those services that provide internet

    connectivity via a USB modem key or wireless card. In other words, they reflect dongle data pricing.30

    The Australian data prices reflect both prepaid and postpaid pricing (the ACCC has not isolated prepaid

    pricing for this service).

    31We have calculated New Zealand operators pricing using the typical roamer profile approach used in the

    Discussion Document of May 2010 (using outgoing and incoming calls of 2 and 2.5 minutes).

    32Section 8.1.2 of Report 2 of the ACCC Report for 2010/11 (available at

    www.accc.gov.au/content/item.phtml?itemId=1060713&nodeId=5efa3bfbeea69f8cf1cf30c7690edbcb&fn=AC

    CC%20Telecommunications%20reports.pdf) sets out the manner in which baskets were constructed.

    -

    20

    40

    60

    80

    100

    120

    2007/8 2008/9 2009/10 2010/11 2011/12

    Index

    NZ data roaming prices versus

    Australian data pricing

    Australian local pricing NZ roaming pricing

    http://www.accc.gov.au/content/item.phtml?itemId=1060713&nodeId=5efa3bfbeea69f8cf1cf30c7690edbcb&fn=ACCC%20Telecommunications%20reports.pdfhttp://www.accc.gov.au/content/item.phtml?itemId=1060713&nodeId=5efa3bfbeea69f8cf1cf30c7690edbcb&fn=ACCC%20Telecommunications%20reports.pdfhttp://www.accc.gov.au/content/item.phtml?itemId=1060713&nodeId=5efa3bfbeea69f8cf1cf30c7690edbcb&fn=ACCC%20Telecommunications%20reports.pdfhttp://www.accc.gov.au/content/item.phtml?itemId=1060713&nodeId=5efa3bfbeea69f8cf1cf30c7690edbcb&fn=ACCC%20Telecommunications%20reports.pdf
  • 7/29/2019 TTR Final Report - 8 Feb 2013

    20/63

    19

    Overall, we acknowledge that local and global SIM cards can and possibly do exert constraint on

    trans-Tasman roaming services, at least in the absence of SIM-locking. However, given our residual

    concerns, we consider it more appropriate to consider the impact of this constraint in the

    assessment of competition.

    In this conclusion, we see a parallel with the decisions of the NZCC34

    and the ACCC35

    to consider that

    butcheries, bakeries, dairies and convenience stores were not part of the same retail market as

    supermarkets, on the basis that only supermarkets provided a one-stop shopping experience.

    Only trans-Tasman roaming services from HNs offer a one-stop communication experience: the

    customers home number; the use of the home SIM; full mobile coverage; etc.

    There may be merit in VHAs suggestion36 to consider dividing the retail market for trans-Tasman

    roaming into two, with mobile telephony services on the one hand (for which local and global SIMs

    would not be substitutable) and mobile broadband services on the other hand (for which local and

    global SIMs would be substitutable). However, we do not consider it justified at this time.37

    33The figure for 2011/12 includes both prepaid GSM and prepaid 3G mobile services, due to changes in

    the data reported by the ACCC.

    34 See NZCC Decisions nos.606 and 607, Foodstuffs and the Warehouse, 8 June 2007 at paras 120 et seq,available at www.comcom.govt.nz/assets/Imported-from-old-

    site/PublicRegisters/ContentFiles/Documents/PUBLIC-VERSION-Decision-606-and-607.pdf35

    See Australian Competition and Consumer Commission: Public Competition Assessment on Woolworths

    Limited Proposed Acquisition of 22 Action Stores and Development Sites , 19 October 2005, at p.636

    VHA, p.7

    37The ACCC considered whether retail mobile services should be split into two markets, mobile telephony and

    mobile broadband, in its consideration of the Vodafone-Hutchison merger in 2009. It rejected this idea on the

    basis of supply-side substitutability, and limited but increasing demand-side substitutability. See the ACCC

    Public Competition Assessment dated 24 June 2009 at para 51, available at

    www.accc.gov.au/content/index.phtml/itemId/874445/fromItemId/751043

    40

    50

    60

    70

    80

    90

    100110

    2007/8 2008/9 2009/10 2010/11 2011/12

    Index

    NZ voice roaming pricing versus

    Australian prepaid GSM pricing

    Australian local pricing NZ roaming pricing

    http://www.comcom.govt.nz/assets/Imported-from-old-site/PublicRegisters/ContentFiles/Documents/PUBLIC-VERSION-Decision-606-and-607.pdfhttp://www.comcom.govt.nz/assets/Imported-from-old-site/PublicRegisters/ContentFiles/Documents/PUBLIC-VERSION-Decision-606-and-607.pdfhttp://www.comcom.govt.nz/assets/Imported-from-old-site/PublicRegisters/ContentFiles/Documents/PUBLIC-VERSION-Decision-606-and-607.pdfhttp://www.comcom.govt.nz/assets/Imported-from-old-site/PublicRegisters/ContentFiles/Documents/PUBLIC-VERSION-Decision-606-and-607.pdf
  • 7/29/2019 TTR Final Report - 8 Feb 2013

    21/63

    20

    1.1.2 Geographic dimension

    The Draft Report concluded that the retail market for the provision of trans-Tasman roaming

    services is a single national one. In other words, HNs compete in one territory, being the whole of

    the country in which they are established. Respondents did not comment on this conclusion, and we

    maintain it.

    1.1.3 Customer dimension

    The Draft Report defined the retail market as the market for the provision of IMR-like services to

    customers who travel across the Tasman. Respondents did not comment on this conclusion, and we

    maintain it.

    1.3 Conclusion

    We confirm our conclusion in the Draft Report that, in each of New Zealand and Australia, there is a

    wholesale market for the provision:

    - by VNs;- to HNs based across the Tasman;

    - of IMR-like services (including traditional IMR services and MLA services);

    - for voice, SMS and data communications.

    We also confirm our conclusion in the Draft Report that, in each of New Zealand and Australia, there

    is a retail market for the provision:

    - by HNs

    38

    , their MVNOs, and potentially VNs;- to customers who travel across the Tasman;- of IMR-like services (including traditional IMR services and MLA services);

    - for voice, SMS and data communications.

    38 New Zealand HNs are downstream from Australian VNs; Australian HNs are downstream from New Zealand VNs.

    38 However, the emerging use of send or pay arrangements could be construed as a form of access charge.

    38 VNs charge the MSRN termination fee not to the HN but to the telecommunications operator that ultch enables services with high price elasticity to be offered at lower

    prices.

    38 These activities will be supplemented by others: for example, in the case of outgoing SMS and data, the HN will need to arrange and pay for the termination of the SMS

    on the destination network / the c onnection of the data to the internet.

    38 Some Australian HNs also charge a flag fall.

    38 Mobile operators in the same country typically charge one another an SMS termination charge. By contrast, mobile operators in different countries typically use bill

    and keep.

    38 We have calculated HN profit by subtracting, from HNs revenues, wholesale charges paid to VNs and the additional costs identified by WIK.

    38 See the MED survey results, available a t www.med.govt.nz/sectors-industries/technology-communication/communications/mobile-phones/trans-tasman-roaming

    38 They may, by contrast, have regulatory incentives to do so, such as in the face of the current joint investigation.

    38XT does, however, refer to the fact that Vodafone NZ and VHA have joint ownership: We do understand

    that Vodafone New Zealand and Vodafone Australia roam on each

    http://www.med.govt.nz/sectors-industries/technology-communication/communications/mobile-phones/trans-tasman-roaminghttp://www.med.govt.nz/sectors-industries/technology-communication/communications/mobile-phones/trans-tasman-roaming
  • 7/29/2019 TTR Final Report - 8 Feb 2013

    22/63

    21

    Section 2: Competition assessment: current state of the

    markets

    2.1 Introduction

    For the Draft Report, we commissioned WIK to produce estimates of the costs underlying the

    provision of wholesale trans-Tasman roaming (TTR) services by a VN to a HN. WIKs estimates, and

    our aggregation of them, appear in the tables below:

    2011 costs to New Zealand VNs (NZ cents, to one decimal point)

    Scenario

    WIK cost

    estimate

    (NZ cents)

    Assumed

    proportionSub-total

    Assumed

    aggregate

    cost

    (NZ cents)

    Voice outgoing

    per min

    Local 6.3 0.15 0.945

    11.7Home 12.6 0.80 10.08

    3rd

    country 12.6 0.05 0.63

    Voice incoming

    per min

    From local 9.1 0.15 1.365

    5.8From home 5.2 0.80 4.16

    From 3rd

    country5.2 0.05 0.26

    SMS outgoing

    per text

    Local 0.9 0.15 0.135

    0.9Home 0.9 0.80 0.72

    3rd

    country 0.9 0.05 0.045

    SMS incoming

    per text

    From local 0.9 0.15 0.135

    0.9From home 0.9 0.80 0.72

    From 3rd

    country0.9 0.05 0.045

    Data

    per MBn/a 27.5 1 27.5 27.5

    2011 costs to Australia VNs (AU cents, to one decimal point)

    Scenario

    WIK cost

    estimate(AU cents)

    Assumed

    proportion Sub-total

    Assumed

    aggregate

    cost

    (AU cents)

    Voice outgoing

    per min

    Local 6.0 0.15 0.9

    9.3Home 9.8 0.80 7.84

    3rd

    country 10.9 0.05 0.545

    Voice incoming

    per min

    From local 8.4 0.15 1.26

    5.6From home 5.1 0.80 4.08

    From 3rd

    country 5.1 0.05 0.255

    SMS outgoing

    per text

    Local 0.8 0.15 0.12

    0.8Home 0.8 0.80 0.64

    3rd

    country 0.8 0.05 0.04

  • 7/29/2019 TTR Final Report - 8 Feb 2013

    23/63

    22

    Scenario

    WIK cost

    estimate

    (AU cents)

    Assumed

    proportionSub-total

    Assumed

    aggregate

    cost

    (AU cents)

    SMS incoming

    per text

    From local 0.8 0.15 0.12

    0.8From home 0.8 0.80 0.64From 3

    rdcountry 0.8 0.05 0.04

    Data

    per MBn/a 24.7 1 24.7 24.7

    For the Draft Report, we assumed that these costs would have been 5 per cent higher in 2010 and 5

    per cent higher again in 2009. We further assumed, for outgoing voice calls and SMS, that 80 per

    cent are calls/texts back to the home country, 15 per cent are calls/texts to a network within the

    visited country, and 5 per cent are calls/texts to networks in a third country. We used the cost

    estimates to help calculate the margins that VNs enjoy (profit divided by costs).

    We also commissioned WIK to produce estimates of the costs that a HN incurs in providing TTR

    services to its retail customers (beyond the wholesale charge it must pay to the VN). This produced

    the following.

    2011 costs to New Zealand HNs (NZ cents, to one decimal point)

    Scenario

    WIK cost

    estimate

    (NZ cents)

    Assumed

    proportionSub-total

    Assumed

    aggregate cost

    (NZ cents)

    Voice outgoing

    per min

    Local 32.9 0.15 4.935

    32.9Home 32.9 0.80 26.32

    3rd

    country 32.9 0.05 1.645

    Voice incoming

    per min

    From local 36.9 0.15 5.535

    36.9From home 36.9 0.80 29.52

    From 3rd

    country 36.9 0.05 1.845

    SMS outgoing

    per text

    Local 21.0 0.15 3.15

    21.0Home 21.0 0.80 16.8

    3rd

    country 21.0 0.05 1.05

    SMS incoming

    per text

    From local 21.0 0.15 3.15

    21.0From home 21.0 0.80 16.8

    From 3rd

    country 21.0 0.05 1.05

    Data

    per MBn/a 36.4 1 36.4 36.4

    2011 costs to Australia HNs (AU cents, to one decimal point)

    Scenario

    WIK cost

    estimate

    (AU cents)

    Assumed

    proportionSub-total

    Assumed

    aggregate cost

    (AU cents)

    Voice outgoing

    per min

    Local 28.0 0.15 4.2

    28.0Home 28.0 0.80 22.4

    3rd

    country 28.0 0.05 1.4

    Voice incoming From local 31.3 0.15 4.695 31.3

  • 7/29/2019 TTR Final Report - 8 Feb 2013

    24/63

    23

    Scenario

    WIK cost

    estimate

    (AU cents)

    Assumed

    proportionSub-total

    Assumed

    aggregate cost

    (AU cents)

    per min From home 31.3 0.80 25.04

    From 3rd

    country 31.3 0.05 1.565

    SMS outgoing

    per text

    Local 17.8 0.15 2.6717.8Home 17.8 0.80 14.24

    3rd

    country 17.8 0.05 0.89

    SMS incoming

    per text

    From local 17.8 0.15 2.67

    17.8From home 17.8 0.80 14.24

    From 3rd

    country 17.8 0.05 0.89

    Data

    per MBn/a 31.0 1 31.0 31.0

    For the Draft Report, we assumed that these costs would have been 5 per cent higher in 2010 and 5

    per cent higher again in 2009. We further assumed, for outgoing voice calls and SMS, that 80 percent are calls/texts back to the home country, 15 per cent are calls/texts to a network within the

    visited country, and 5 per cent are calls/texts to networks in a third country. We used the cost

    estimates to help calculate the margins that HNs enjoy (profitdivided by costs).

    Several operators criticised WIKs price estimates, with Telstra and Optus submitting detailed

    critiques.

    Telstra expressed concerns about some of the parameters used by WIK in its analysis. In particular,

    some figures do not appear to have been updated from the levels used in [the ACCCs model of]

    2007.39

    Regarding revisions to the 2007 model, the ACCC has advised that they engaged WIK to provide a

    cost model in 2007 and WIK updated it in 2008 to replace 2001 Census data in the model with 2006

    Census data. The updated model was referred to in the ACCC MTAS pricing principles determination

    in March 2009, which Telstra notes in its submission.

    In response to Telstras claim, we note that, in its work for the current investigation, WIK took as a

    starting point the model with the 2006 Census data, which is what the ACCC has indicated was the

    basis for the revised model they used.

    Some of the more specific issues that Telstra raises for example, that dongles were not yet a factor

    during WIKs earlier work, but are now are fair points. However, the focus in the WIK study was on

    unit costs, not on total costs. Higher volumes from dongles and the like would (mostly) tend to imply

    lower unit costs. We consider that the numbers provided by Telstra to WIK40 suggest WIK has been

    conservative in its traffic assumptions and that this reinforces the view that WIKs results can be

    viewed as an upper bound.

    39Telstra, para 63

    40Internal Telstra information concerning voice and data traffic. See Telstras comments on the average

    traffic per SIO at para 63 of its submission.

  • 7/29/2019 TTR Final Report - 8 Feb 2013

    25/63

    24

    Optus, for its part, raised five specific criticisms of the WIK study. All of these had to do with the cost

    model derived from the previous work. Its five criticisms, and our discussion of them, are set out

    below, grouped into three categories:

    (i) Traffic assumptions

    According to Optus, the WIK study includes an incorrect treatment of data traffic, resulting in an

    over-estimation of total network traffic of between 90-190%. Optus also claims that the study

    includes an incorrect ratio of voice to data traffic, resulting in a significant cost allocation away from

    voice services towards data services.

    In the WIK model, we note that they use a GPRS MB per voice minute conversion of 0.080357. This is

    what was used in the original model. Using this conversion number and an estimate of the data

    traffic (measured in MB), WIK estimate the data traffic equivalent in voice minutes, which is what

    the model uses to dimension the network. The split of voice against data traffic is roughly 20%-80%,

    as noted by Optus.

    We do not consider that WIK should be using another conversion factor. In our view, WIK should be

    consistent with the modelling framework it is working with, which is 2.5G. WIK cannot in our view

    implement conversion factors that reflect, say, LTE when that is not achievable within the confines

    of the model.

    WIK knew it was using an outdated model (from a technology perspective) to derive costs. Using

    outdated or inefficient technology, it reasoned that the costs coming out of the model most likely

    were higher than efficient costs. What Optus is claiming is that, had WIK used another conversion

    factor, then voice share of direct costs would have been larger and hence would have attracted

    more common costs. This is correct, but WIK is also using outdated, less efficient technology to

    model costs. The issue becomes: which one of these effects dominates? We would suggest themodeling using old technology. In this context, making the adjustment Optus proposes would make

    little difference to the final result.

    (ii) Price assumptions

    Optus claims that the WIK study fails to update asset prices to 2012 levels. It makes similar claims

    regarding Australian spectrum prices.

    In respect of asset prices, Optus main critique relates to leased lines. It provides a table claiming

    that the leased line prices used in the WIK model are much lower than 2012 Regulated DTCS Prices.

    To reach its result, Optus has calculated prices assuming lines are 1 km in length. In our opinion, this

    approach greatly exaggerates the cost estimate. If one takes a more reasonable approach and

    calculates the cost of the line at the mid-point of the distance range, i.e. for a leased line that is

    between 0 and 10 km, take the price of a 5km line and divide by 5 (to get a price per km), the result

    is a much lower price (in fact lower than used in the WIK model41).

    41Leased line prices used in the WIK model reflect Telstra's wholesale leased line pricing in 2007. WIK assumed

    the price trend was 0%, i.e. no price change. The prices are quoted per km.

  • 7/29/2019 TTR Final Report - 8 Feb 2013

    26/63

    25

    In any event, WIK reran its calculations using the ACCCs DTCS calculator42. It confirmed that the

    prices WIK has used are in fact likely higher than the DTCS prices, and not lower as suggested by

    Optus. In other words, with its 2012 values for leased lines, WIK is not understating the regulated

    cost of leased lines in Australia.

    In respect of Australian spectrum prices, Optus' critique consists of two parts: first, that the price ofspectrum should be updated compared to 2007; and second, that additional spectrum costs should

    be included to account for spectrum in the 2.1 GHz and 850 MHz range.

    On the first point, Optus submits that the WIK cost model update should have taken into account

    the latest spectrum renewal prices for 900 MHz and 1.8 GHz. The latest yearly charge for 900 MHz

    licences is AU$23 million, and the total price paid by the three operators for 1.8 GHz renewal was

    AU$485 million. Optus submits that using the same 'simple average' method used in 2007 results in

    the value of 1.8 GHz being AU$162 million.

    In its cost model, WIK assumed as in 2007 a yearly charge for 900MHz of AU$20.4 million and an

    initial value for 1.8 GHz of AU$96.5 million. Hence it is correct when Optus states that the values arethe same as in 2007. In our opinion, it would therefore be appropriate to update the figures as Optus

    suggests, i.e. assume for 900 MHz an annual licence fee of AU$23 million and the value of 1800 Mhz

    being AU$162 million.

    We therefore asked WIK to run its model with revised spectrum values. WIKs conclusion was that

    the change proposed by Optus has nearly no impact on the results. The unit costs change in the

    order of plus 0.01 AU cents for origination and termination.

    On the second point, Optus submits that the updated WIK cost model should also include the

    valuation for other spectrum ranges over which data services are provided namely, 850 MHz, and

    2.1 GHz. Optus submits that it is incorrect for the WIK cost model to assume data usage consistentwith what is currently seen over hybrid 2G/3G/HSPA/LTE networks yet fail to include any of the

    costs. In Optus opinion, in the absence of the 2007 WIK cost model being able to structurally deal

    with data networks, such data volumes should not be included. However, failing this, Optus submits

    that the cost model update should include as many possible data-asset upgrades that can be

    handled. An obvious inclusion is the cost of spectrum over which data is supplied.

    We disagree with this point. The WIK model uses 900 and 1800 MHz frequencies and hence should

    only include the cost of this spectrum.

    To explain, WIK calculated the service unit costs within the confines of the WIK mobile model which

    is based on 2G/2.5G technology. Since this model was built, there have been significant

    developments in the mobile industry in both New Zealand and Australia, including a migration to

    3G/3.5G networks, increased penetration, growth of data services, etc. While WIK has tried to take

    as many of these developments into account as possible, upgrading the model to newer mobile

    technology was not possible. Hence the model uses 2G/2.5G as the basis for the cost calculations.

    In our opinion, WIKs approach leads to a conservative upper bound estimate of efficient costs.

    Optus submits that the updated WIK cost model should also include the valuation for other

    spectrum ranges over which data services are provided namely, 850 MHz, and 2.1 GHz. However,

    this would serve no purpose for the modelling of service costs, as the frequencies would not be

    42Available on the ACCC's website at www.accc.gov.au/content/index.phtml/itemId/990533

    http://www.accc.gov.au/content/index.phtml/itemId/990533http://www.accc.gov.au/content/index.phtml/itemId/990533
  • 7/29/2019 TTR Final Report - 8 Feb 2013

    27/63

    26

    used. If the model had been flexible enough to adequately deal with these additional frequencies

    and could be used to dimension the network then, in all likelihood, it would have been appropriate

    to include them, but since WIK would simply be inflating cost estimates that it already believes are

    conservative, we do not believe this is appropriate.

    On a related matter, Optus notes that in a consultation paper WIK suggests that Optus can onlydeploy HSPA technology using 2.1GHz spectrum. WIK did not apply this assumption in the current

    modelling. What WIK did, however, was to test the effect of using newer mobile technology by using

    other WIK mobile models that are more flexible from a technology perspective. This helped WIK

    understand the implications for service costs of applying 2G/2.5G technology compared to

    3G/3.5G/4G technology in a world that is much more data hungry than it was when the WIK model

    for Australia was built, and helped it decide whether it should be making any additional corrections

    to the outputs it calculated.

    (iii) Market share assumptions

    In WIKs study, it notes the following with regard to market share:

    "The update of the WIK-MNCM assumes the hypothetical operator has a 33.3 per cent market

    share. We note that the principle of competitive neutrality defines a reference point such that all

    operators in the market have the chance to reach a market position of equal market share. This

    means that in a three carrier scenario the efficient operator should represent a market share of

    33.3 per cent. Exhausting all economies of scale and therefore becoming the most efficient

    operator in the market may however, imply a significantly higher market share for individual

    MNOs."

    In its submission, Optus claims that a 33.3% market share is not a realistic assumption for a

    hypothetical future entrant, and that as a result the WIK model underestimates the efficient cost ofmobile services.

    In order to run the model, WIK needs to assume a market share. Clearly this market share will affect

    the overall level of economic costs calculated by the model and will generally result in lower costs

    the more traffic and subscribers.

    When we think of the hypothetical new entrant, as it may be, we should in our view be taking the

    long term view, i.e. what would the market share in the market evolve to be in the long run. In this

    case we have seen the market in both countries move to three operators in recent years and we

    cannot see any reason (technological or economic) why this is not a reasonable assumption for what

    the market in each country can sustain in the long term. Australia, of course, is geographically large

    and as such may be able to attract certain niche operators. However, the definition of the entrant

    should of course be that it targets the whole country and not just a subset (with domestic roaming

    arrangements in the rest of the country).

    An alternative approach would be to look at actual market shares. Other things being equal, the

    cost per unit of service will be higher for an operator with a smaller market share than for an

    operator with a larger market share, as this operator is less able to fill its base stations with traffic.

    In Australia, Telstra is slightly larger than Vodafone and Optus, but generally they are all of similar

    size and in that case 33% market share makes sense. WIK informs us that, previously in other

    projects, they have performed some sensitivity analysis of what market share might mean for service

  • 7/29/2019 TTR Final Report - 8 Feb 2013

    28/63

    27

    costs. Based on that work, WIK estimates that within the bounds of 41% (Telstra) and 27%

    (Vodafone) market share, service unit costs estimates would be within +/- 10% of those provided in

    the WIK study, with Telstras cost being roughly 10% lower and Vodafone 10% higher.

    For New Zealand and an operator like 2degrees the market share difference is fairly substantial.

    However, here another factor comes into play: the cost per unit will be lower for an operator thatcovers with its network a smaller and relatively more densely populated portion of the national

    territory and population. 2degrees relies on domestic roaming with Vodafone in certain areas. The

    two cost drivers mentioned above, market share and extent of coverage, have opposing impacts on

    the costs of 2degrees relative to the costs of the other operators. Unit costs of 2degress should be

    higher because of lower market share, but lower because of a lower extent of coverage.

    2.2 The wholesale market relevant to New Zealand roamers

    Given the discussion in Section 2.1 above (and in particular the fact that the one area where we

    agree that the WIK costs analysis should be amended Australian spectrum pricing in fact makesonly a minimal difference to WIKs cost estimates), we maintain our conclusions about the current

    state of competition in the wholesale market relevant to New Zealanders.

    That market is the market in which Australian VNs provide IMR-like services to New Zealand HNs

    (the Australian Wholesale Market). The relevant conclusions are that:

    - revenues per unit in the Australian Wholesale Market are trending down;

    - margins in the Australian Wholesale Market are trending down, although they remain

    significant;

    - the quality of traditional roaming services is high, although no Australian VNs offer

    wholesale MLA services to New Zealand HNs.

    In its submission, Telstra stresses what it calls the potentially meaningless nature of any assessment

    of [Australian] wholesale margins, given that Australian operators, being generally roaming out

    (i.e. net outbound) in their relationship with New Zealand operators, make a net loss at wholesale

    level.43 We would note only that a highly marked-up IOT is far from meaningless for the consumer,

    since if we are to believe the operators, they are constrained by the IOT when setting retail prices.

    2.3 The retail market relevant to New Zealand roamers

    Given the discussion in Section 2.1 above, we maintain our conclusions about the current state ofcompetition in the retail market relevant to New Zealand roamers.

    That market is the market in which New Zealand HNs (and potentially Australian VNs) provide IMR-

    like services to New Zealanders travelling in Australia (the New Zealand Retail Market). The

    relevant conclusions are:

    - revenues per unit for voice and SMS appear constant, while revenues per unit for data havedropped significantly, in the New Zealand Retail Market;

    - margins in the New Zealand Retail Market are trending down;

    43Telstra, para 92

  • 7/29/2019 TTR Final Report - 8 Feb 2013

    29/63

    28

    - the quality of traditional roaming services is high, although no New Zealand HNs (or

    Australian VNs) offer MLA services to New Zealand roamers.

    We wish to acknowledge here the most recent pricing of Telecom NZ. Since 21 December 2012,

    besides a cut to their outgoing voice rates, post-paid XT roamers have enjoyed flat-rate per-day

    prices for data usage. For trans-Tasman roaming, that rate is, at least until 30 June 2013, NZ$6.00per day for any day on which data is used. 44 To our mind, this represents a significant and innovative

    step.

    We also note with approval the launch by Vodafone NZ in November 2012 of the Data Angel

    Overseas service. Amongst other features, thisprompts travellers to consider purchasing a databundle when they arrive at their overseas destination. Data Angel Overseas also alerts data roamers

    when they reach 80% and 100% of their data bundle. Once the bundle runs out, the data session

    stops and roamers are redirected to a free website where they can choose to buy more from the

    selection range.

    A small point, though, is worthy of mention. In its submission, Telecom compares its (then) trans-Tasman roaming prices favourably to local prepaid prices. Vodafone NZ, for its part, stresses that its

    roamers pay the same rate to make calls on both sides of the Tasman. Operators have not pointed

    out, however, that:

    - identical headline rates do not equate to identical charges, because billing increments can

    differ (for example, Vodafone NZs post-paid customers are charged at a 60+1 increment

    domestically, but at a 60+60 increment when roaming);

    - it can be misleading to compare roaming prices with domestic prices because domesticcharges are inflated by GST.45

    2.4 The wholesale market relevant to Australian roamers

    Given the discussion in Section 2.1 above, we maintain our conclusions about the current state of

    competition in the wholesale market relevant to Australians. That market is the market in which

    New Zealand VNs provide IMR-like services to Australian HNs (the New Zealand Wholesale

    Market).

    That market is the market in which New Zealand VNs provide IMR-like services to Australian HNs

    (the New Zealand Wholesale Market). The relevant conclusions are that:

    - revenues per unit in the New Zealand Wholesale Market are trending down;

    - margins in the New Zealand Wholesale Market are trending down, although they remainsignificant;

    - the quality of traditional roaming services Is high, although no New Zealand VNs offerwholesale MLA services to Australian HNs.

    44NZ timezone applies, and subject to a fair use policy.

    45Section 11AB(b) of the Goods and Services Tax Act zero-rates residents roaming outside of New

    Zealand.

  • 7/29/2019 TTR Final Report - 8 Feb 2013

    30/63

    29

    2.5 The retail market relevant to Australian roamers

    Given the discussion in Section 2.1 above, we maintain our conclusions about the current state of

    competition in the retail market relevant to Australian roamers.

    That market is the market in which Australian HNs (and potentially New Zealand VNs) provide IMR-like services to Australians travelling in New Zealand (the Australian Retail Market). The relevant

    conclusions a