the industrial revolution in theory and in history

67
1 The Industrial Revolution Gregory Clark, University of California, Davis, CA 95616 [email protected] The Industrial Revolution decisively changed economy wide productivity growth rates. For successful economies, measured efficiency growth rates increased from close to zero to close to 1% per year in the blink of an eye, in terms of the long history of humanity, seemingly within 50 years of 1800 in England. Yet the Industrial Revolution has defied simple economic explanations or modeling. This paper seeks to set out the empirical parameters of the Industrial Revolution that any economic theory must encompass, and illustrate why this makes explaining the Industrial Revolution so difficult within the context of standard economic models and narratives. KEYWORDS: Industrial Revolution, Economic Growth, Growth Theory JEL CODES: N13, O33, O43, O47 Introduction The economic history of the world is surprisingly simple. It can be presented in one diagram, as in figure 1 below. Before 1800 income per capita for all the societies we observe fluctuated. There were good and bad periods. But there was no upward trend. The great span of human history - from the arrival of anatomically modern man to Confucius, Plato, Aristotle, Michelangelo, Shakespeare, Beethoven, and all the way to Jane Austen indeed - was lived in societies caught in the Malthusian trap. Jane Austen may write about refined conversation over tea served in China cups, but for the mass of people as late as 1813 material conditions were no better than their ancestors of the African savannah. The Darcys were few, the poor plentiful. 1 1 Clark, 2007 extensively reviews the evidence for this assertion.

Upload: phungdieu

Post on 10-Feb-2017

216 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: The Industrial Revolution in Theory and in History

1

The Industrial Revolution Gregory Clark,

University of California, Davis, CA 95616

[email protected]

The Industrial Revolution decisively changed economy wide

productivity growth rates. For successful economies, measured

efficiency growth rates increased from close to zero to close to 1%

per year in the blink of an eye, in terms of the long history of

humanity, seemingly within 50 years of 1800 in England. Yet the

Industrial Revolution has defied simple economic explanations or

modeling. This paper seeks to set out the empirical parameters of the

Industrial Revolution that any economic theory must encompass, and

illustrate why this makes explaining the Industrial Revolution so

difficult within the context of standard economic models and

narratives.

KEYWORDS: Industrial Revolution, Economic Growth, Growth Theory

JEL CODES: N13, O33, O43, O47

Introduction

The economic history of the world is surprisingly simple. It can be presented in

one diagram, as in figure 1 below. Before 1800 income per capita for all the societies

we observe fluctuated. There were good and bad periods. But there was no upward

trend. The great span of human history - from the arrival of anatomically modern

man to Confucius, Plato, Aristotle, Michelangelo, Shakespeare, Beethoven, and all

the way to Jane Austen indeed - was lived in societies caught in the Malthusian trap.

Jane Austen may write about refined conversation over tea served in China cups, but

for the mass of people as late as 1813 material conditions were no better than their

ancestors of the African savannah. The Darcys were few, the poor plentiful.1

1 Clark, 2007 extensively reviews the evidence for this assertion.

Page 2: The Industrial Revolution in Theory and in History

2

Figure 1: A Schematic History of World Economic Growth

Source: Clark, 2007, figure 1.1, 2.

Around 1780 came the Industrial Revolution in England. Incomes per capita

began a sustained growth in a favored group of countries around 1820. In the last

two hundred years in the most fortunate countries real incomes per capita rose 10-15

fold. The modern world was born. The Industrial Revolution thus represents the

single great event of world economic history, the change between two fundamentally

different economic systems. The puzzle is why it occurred only around 1780, and

why it occurred in a modest island nation on the northwest shores of the European

continent.

At one level the transformation the Industrial Revolution represents is very

simple. Beginning with the Industrial Revolution, successful modern economies

experience steady rates of efficiency advance. Every year more output is produced

per unit of input. At a proximate level the growth of income per work-hour in

modern societies can be represented as

gy = agk + gA (1)

0

2

4

6

8

10

12

-1000 -500 0 500 1000 1500 2000

Inco

me

per

per

son

(1800 =

1)

Year

Malthusian Trap

Industrial Revolution

Great Divergence

Page 3: The Industrial Revolution in Theory and in History

3

where gk is the rate of growth of capital per worker hour, a is the share of capital

payments in national income, and gA is the growth rate of efficiency. Since the

Industrial Revolution the capital stock has grown about as rapidly as output. Also

the share of capital in all earnings is about a quarter. Thus only about a quarter of all

modern growth in income per person comes directly from physical capital. The rest

is an unattributed rise in the measured efficiency of the economy, year by year.

But while equation (1) suggests that efficiency growth and physical capital

accumulation are independent sources of growth, in practice in market economies

there has been a strong correlation between the two sources of growth. Economies

with significant efficiency growth are also those with substantial growth rates of

physical capital. Something links these two sources of growth.

Some economists, most notably Paul Romer, have theorized that this correlation

stems from external benefits associated with physical capital accumulation (Romer,

1986, 1987, 1990). For this explanation to work, there would have to be $3 of

external benefit accruing to physical capital investments for every $1 of private

benefit. Most of the modern physical capital stock, however, is still such mundane

things as houses, buildings, roads, water and sewer systems, and bridges. These

types of investment do not seem to be associated with substantial external benefits.

So if productivity advance is systematically associated also with the growth of the

stock of such physical capital there must be another mechanism.

The most plausible one is that the association of physical capital accumulation

with efficiency advance stems just from the effects of efficiency advance on

increasing the marginal product of capital. In a world a relatively constant real

interest rates since the Industrial Revolution, such a rising marginal product will

induce more investment. And indeed if the economy is roughly Cobb-Douglass in

its production structure, efficiency advances will induce a growth of the physical

capital stock per person at a rate equal to the growth of output per person, so that

the capital-output ratio is constant. This is roughly what we observe.

Thus at a deeper level all modern growth seemingly stems from this unexplained

rise in economic efficiency, as a product of a rise in knowledge about production

processes. Somehow after 1780 investment in such knowledge increased, or enquiry

became much more effective in creating innovation.

Page 4: The Industrial Revolution in Theory and in History

4

Before the Industrial Revolution we find no sign of any equivalent efficiency

advances. This is true globally all the way from 10,000 BC to 1800, where we can

measure the implied rate of productivity advance just from the rate of growth of

population. In this long interval average estimated rates of efficiency advance are

0.01% per year or less. We know this because we can assume before the Industrial

Revolution, because of the Malthusian Trap, that output per person and capital per

person was, in the long run, constant. In that case any gains in efficiency will be

absorbed by population growth according to the formula

(2)2

We can thus approximate efficiency growth rates from population growth rates

if we look at sufficiently long intervals. Table 1 shows these calculations at a world

level. Implied rates of technological advance are always extremely slow.

But it is also true that implied rates of technological advance are also slow for

those economies where we can measure actual efficiency levels before 1800 through

measurements of the real payments to factors. Figure 2 shows the implied efficiency

in England 1250-2000. As can be seen there is, surprisingly, in England no sign of

any significant improvement in the efficiency of the economy all the way from 1250

to 1800. Only around 1800 does the modern age of steady efficiency advance

appear. Before that the measured efficiency of the economy fluctuated, peaking

around 1450, but with almost no upwards trend.

The Industrial Revolution thus seems to represent a singularity. A unique break

in world history. But also an event where we know clearly what we have to explain.

Why did the rate of expansion of knowledge about production efficiency increase so

dramatically in England around 1800. Figure 3 shows that the upturn in productivity

growth rates can be located to the 1780s/1790s. That upturn us preceded by seven

decades in which the average annual productivity growth rate was a mere 0.14% per

year. Fast by the standards of the pre-industrial world, but glacially slow in modern

terms. Overall productivity growth rates 1780-9 to 1860-9 averaged 0.58% per year,

about half way to fully modern levels.

2 For a more detailed explanation see Clark, 2007, 379-82.

Page 5: The Industrial Revolution in Theory and in History

5

Table 1: Population and Technological Advance at the World Level, 130,000

B.C. to 1800

Year

Population (millions)

Population

Growth Rate (%)

Technology Growth Rate

(%)

130,000 BC 0.1 - - 10,000 BC 7 0.004 0.001 1 AD 300 0.038 0.009 1000 AD 310 0.003 0.001 1250 AD 400 0.102 0.025 1500 AD 490 0.081 0.020 1750 AD 770 0.181 0.045

Source: Clark, 2007, table 7.1.

Figure 2: Estimated Efficiency of the English Economy, 1250-2000

Source: Clark, 2010.

0

50

100

150

200

250

300

350

400

450

1200 1300 1400 1500 1600 1700 1800 1900 2000

Eff

icie

ncy

(N

NP

) (1

860s

=100)

Page 6: The Industrial Revolution in Theory and in History

6

Figure 3: Efficiency Levels, England, 1700-1880

Source: Clark, 2010.

We also know what sectors contributed most of the productivity advance 1780-

9 to 1860-9. National productivity growth will be related to productivity advance in

individual sectors through the equation

∑ (3)

where is the growth rate of productivity by sector, and is the share of j in total

value added in the economy. These results are shown in table 2.

Textiles contributed nearly half, 43%, of all measured productivity advance.

Improvements in transport, mainly the introduction of the railway, was the next

biggest source of advance, contributing 20%. Agriculture, ironically, contributed

almost 20% also. Coal and iron and steel were in themselves minor contributions

despite the fame of these sectors and their innovations in this period. Productivity

growth in the half of the economy not covered in table 2 was modest, less than

0.20% per year.

0

20

40

60

80

100

120

1700 1720 1740 1760 1780 1800 1820 1840 1860 1880

Eff

icie

ncy

(N

NP

) (1

860s

=100)

Page 7: The Industrial Revolution in Theory and in History

7

Table 2: Sources of Industrial Revolution Efficiency Advance, 1780s-1860s

Sector

Efficiency Growth Rate (%)

Share

of value added

Contribution to

National Efficiency Growth Rate (%

per year)

All Textiles 2.3 0.11 0.25 Iron and Steel 1.8 0.01 0.02 Coal Mining 0.2 0.02 0.00 Transport 1.5 0.08 0.12 Agriculture 0.4 0.30 0.11 Identified Advance - 0.51 0.49 Whole Economy - 1.00 0.58

Source: Clark, 2007, table 12.1.

The decomposition in table 2 established some things already. The Industrial

Revolution has been thought of by some as essentially consisting of the arrival of the

first of what have been called General Purpose Technologies, the steam engine. General

Purpose Technologies, a rather nebulous concept, have been variously defined. They can

be loosely thought of as innovations that have pervasive application throughout the

economy, that go through a prolonged period of improvement, and that spawn

further innovation in the sectors they are employed in.3 Various GPTs have been

identified, such as the introduction of steam power in the Industrial Revolution, and

the introduction of electricity, and the recent IT revolution.

Steam power in England certainly touched a number of areas in the Industrial

Revolution. It was important in coal mining, on the railroads, and in powering the

new textile factories. The steam engine itself underwent a long process of

3 Bresnahan and Trajtenberg, 1996.

Page 8: The Industrial Revolution in Theory and in History

8

improvement in thermal efficiency, and in the ratio of power to weight, from its first

introduction by Thomas Newcomen in 1707-1712, to the 1880s. The earliest

engines had a thermal efficiency as low as 0.5%, while those of the 1880s could

achieve thermal efficiencies of 25%. The steam engine was associated also with the

widespread use of fossil energy in the economy to replace wind, water and animal

power sources in transport, home heating, and manufacturing.

Table 2 suggests, however, that whatever role steam power played in economy

wide productivity advance after the 1860s, its role up to then in the new productivity

advance of the Industrial Revolution was minor. Coal mining and iron and steel

production contributed very little to Industrial Revolution productivity advance, and

most of their productivity advance did not stem from the introduction of steam

power.4 Even in transport a substantial part of the productivity advance is

attributable to the improvement of the traditional road transport system, the

introduction of canals, and improvements in sailing ships. The textile factories of

the Industrial Revolution could, if necessary, have still been powered by water wheels

even as late as the 1860s. Advances in textiles and agriculture explain the majority of

the Industrial Revolution.

The diverse nature of productivity advance in this era makes the Industrial

Revolution all the more puzzling. The revolution in textiles came through

mechanical innovations that can be traced to a number of heroic individual

innovators: John Kay, Richard Arkwright, James Hargreaves, Edmund Cartwright.

But the improvements in agriculture stem from the advances of thousands of

anonymous farmers in improving yields, mainly involving non-mechanical changes.

Another important element in the Industrial Revolution era is the unimportance

of traditional investments in physical capital in explaining the growth of output per

worker. Capital per worker rose no faster than output per worker, so that right from

the onset of modern growth efficiency growth dominated.

Thus any satisfying account of the Industrial Revolution has to do the following

things. First explain why NO society before 1800 - not ancient Babylon, Pharaonic

Egypt, China through countless centuries, Classical Greece, Imperial Rome,

Renaissance Tuscany, medieval Flanders, the Aztecs, Mogul India, the Dutch

4 Clark and Jacks, 2007.

Page 9: The Industrial Revolution in Theory and in History

9

Republic – expanded the stock of knowledge by more than 10% a century. Then

explain why within 50 years of 1800 the rate of growth of knowledge rose to modern

rates in one small country on the margins of Europe, Britain. Then we will

understand the history of man.

Theories of the Industrial Revolution

The drama and the centrality of the Industrial Revolution has ensured that there

is a steady supply of new or recycled theories of this great transition. These theories

mostly fall into a number of discrete categories.

“Bad equilibrium” theories seek to explain the Malthusian stagnation as a

productive of a self-reinforcing system of poor economic incentives. The desires and

rationalities of people in all human societies are essentially the same. The medieval

peasant in Europe, the Indian coolly, the bushman of the veld, share a common set

of aspirations, and a common ability to act to achieve those aspirations. What differs

across societies, however, are the institutions that govern economic life. Thus

The United States inherited a set of institutions – among them common law and

property rights – from Great Britain. These institutions made Britain the world’s

leading nation by the end of the eighteenth century….The result has been two and

a half centuries of economic growth (North, 1994, ---).

Thus there is a caricature of the pre-industrial world that many economists

intuitively hold, which is composed of a mixture of all the bad movies ever made

about early societies. Vikings pour out of long ships to loot and pillage defenseless

peasants and burn the libraries of monasteries. Mongol hordes flow out of the

steppe on horseback to sack Chinese cities. Clerical fanatics burn at the stake those

who dare to question arcane religious doctrines. Peasants groan under the heel of

rapacious lords whose only activity is feasting and fighting. Aztec priest cut out the

hearts with obsidian knives from screaming, writhing victims. In this brutal and

chaotic world who has the time, the energy, or the incentive to develop new

technology?

Page 10: The Industrial Revolution in Theory and in History

10

The advantage of a theory which relies on some exogenous shock to the

economic system is that it can hopefully account for the seeming sudden change in

the growth rate of measured efficiency around 1800. Institutions can change

suddenly and dramatically – witness the French Revolution, the Russian Revolution,

and the Iranian Revolution that overthrew the Shah

These theories of an institutional shift in appropriability face two major

difficulties, however, one conceptual, one empirical. The conceptual difficulty is that

if modern economic growth can be produced by a simple institutional change, then

why in all the varied and various societies that the world has seen since 10,000 BC

and before was there none which stumbled upon the right set of institutions that

made knowledge property? Societies varied markedly in what could be property and

how property was transferred between owners. For example, in civil cases over

possession of land in the legal system established by the Normans in medieval

England after 1066, the party whose right to land was contested could elect to prove

his or her title through armed combat with his opponent! This may seem to us a

crazy way of settling property disputes to us, but the point is that societies have

made all kinds of different choices about institutional forms. Why did some not

stumble upon the right set of institutions? It seems that we cannot rely on chance

here in institutional choice. There must be something that is keeping the institutions

of the pre-industrial world in the “bad” state.

Thus a slightly more sophisticated version of the “bad institutions” theory are

those which seek to explain through the Political Economy of Institutions why

systematically early societies had institutions that discouraged economic growth (see,

for example, North and Thomas, 1973, North and Weingast, 1989, North, 1993,

Jones, 2002, Acemoglu, Johnson and Robinson, 2001, 2002, and Acemoglu and

Robinson, 2012).

The common feature that Douglass North and other such institutionalists point to

in early societies is that political power was not achieved by popular elections. In

pre-industrial societies, as a generalization, the rulers ultimately rested their political

position on the threat of violence. Indeed there is a close empirical association

between democracy and economic growth. By the time England achieved its

Industrial Revolution it was a constitutional democracy where the king was merely a

Page 11: The Industrial Revolution in Theory and in History

11

figurehead. The USA, the leading nation in the world in economic terms since the

1870s, has always been a democracy also.5

For economic efficiency in any society property rules have to be chosen to

create the maximum value of economic output. In such a case a disjuncture can arise

between the property rules in the society that will maximize the total value of output,

and the property rules that will maximize the output going to the ruling elite. Indeed

North and others have to argue that such a disjuncture systematically arises in all

societies before 1800. This idea has been restated recently as the idea that economic

growth is the replacement of extractive economic institutions, designed just to secure

income for a ruling clique, with inclusive economic institutions, designed to

maximize the output of societies as a whole (Acemoglu and Robinson, 2012).

One subset of such theories that has shown amazing persistence, despite its

inability to account for the most basic facts of the Industrial Revolution, is that

which links the Industrial Revolution to the earlier Glorious Revolution of 1688-9.

Thus the recent widely read book by Acemoglu and Robinson, Why Nations Fail, has

a chapter titled “How a political revolution in 1688 changed institutions in England and led to

the Industrial Revolution.”

The Glorious Revolution established the modern political system of the UK, a

system that has been continuously modified, but not fundamentally changed since

then. The new political system created Parliament, the representative of the

propertied classes in England in 1689, as the effective source of power in what is

nominally a monarchy.

A basic problem with placing political developments at the heart of the

Industrial Revolution is that changes in political regime before 1800 have no

discernible impact on the efficiency level of the economy, even 80 years later. The

Glorious Revolution had no discernible impact on economic efficiency before 1770,

two or three generations after the institutional change, as figure 4 shows. It is also

clear in the figure that even the earlier political and military disruptions of the Civil

War of 1642-9, and the Interregnum of 1649-1660, were not associated with any

decline in the efficiency of operation of the economy.

5 The recent rise of China is, however, an exception to the general association of growth and democracy.

Page 12: The Industrial Revolution in Theory and in History

12

Figure 4: Economic Efficiency and Political Changes, England, 1600-1770

Source: Clark, 2010.

Further there is no sign that private investors in England perceived a greater

security of property even as a result of the Glorious Revolution. The return to

private capital in the economy did not deviate from trend after 1689. Private

investors seem to have looked at the political changes with indifference. The return

to government debt did eventually decline significantly after 1689, and had fallen to

modern levels by the 1750s. This decline was no doubt driven in part by the

enhanced taxing power of the government after 1689. But almost all of the money

raised from those taxes went to finance the British Navy in the long struggle with

France that ended only with the defeat of Napoleon in 1815. Almost none of it

went into the subsidization of innovation or education.

And we do see long before the Glorious Revolution or the Industrial Revolution

societies that had stable representative political systems, the inclusive institutions of

Acemoglu and Robinson, but little or no productivity advance. The Dutch Republic

0

20

40

60

80

100

1600 1620 1640 1660 1680 1700 1720 1740 1760

Eff

icie

ncy

(N

NP

) (1

860s

=100)

Glorious RevolutionCivil War

Interregnum

Page 13: The Industrial Revolution in Theory and in History

13

of 1588-1795 was one such regime.6 Under the political arrangements of the

Republic the Netherlands experienced its Golden Age. Despite its modest size and

lack of substantial domestic natural resources, it conquered a substantial colonial

Empire in the East, possessing for a while the premier Navy in the world,

dominating world trade in the seventeenth century. It developed sophisticated

systems of banking and public finance, allowing substantial borrowing to develop a

modernized transportation system internally, and support the most urbanized society

in Europe. But because productivity advance stagnated in the Netherlands 1650-

1795, these political and institutional achievements led to no sustained growth, and

no break from the pre-industrial world.

From 1223 to 1797 Venice operated as a Republic, with the government under

control of a balance of popular and patrician representatives. Policy was geared

towards the needs of a trading and commercial empire. Venice again developed an

important trading empire in the Eastern Mediterranean, with colonies and

dependencies such as Dalmatia, Crete and Cyprus. It also developed important

manufacturing activities such as its glass industry. But again none of this was

reflected in the kind of sustained productivity advance seen in the Industrial

Revolution.

Similarly the free cities of the Hanseatic League were from the middle ages

dominated by a politics that emphasized the needs of trade and commerce. Lübeck,

for example, became a free city in 1226, and retained city state status till 1937. After

gaining its freedom Lübeck developed a system of rule and government, called

Lübeck Law, that spread to many other Baltic cities of the Hanseatic League in the

middle ages such as Hamburg, Kiel, Danzig, Rostock, and Memel. Under Lübeck

Law, the city was governed by a council of 20 that appointed its own members from

the merchant guilds and other town notables. It was thus government by the leaders

of the commercial interests of the cities. Though not democracy, this was

government by interests that should have fostered commerce and manufacturing.

Under such rule the Hansa cities became rich and powerful, engaging in substantial

manufacturing enterprises, such as shipbuilding and cloth production, as well as

trade. But again this was not associated with sustained technological advance.

6 The Dutch Act of Abjuration of 1581 has been argued by some to be the precursor of the Declaration of Independence of the USA of 1776.

Page 14: The Industrial Revolution in Theory and in History

14

It is true that the early societies we know of in detail seem to have lacked the

legal notion that you could own property in ideas or innovations. Thus in both the

Roman and Greek worlds when an author published a book there was no legal or

practical way to stop the pirating of the text. Copies could be freely made by anyone

who acquired a version of the manuscript (on papyrus rolls), and the copier could

amend and alter the text at will. It was not uncommon for a text to be reissued

under the name of a new “author.”7 It was common to condemn such pirating of

works or ideas as immoral. But writings and inventions were just not viewed as

commodities with a market value.8

While the ancients may have lacked them, there were systems of intellectual

property rights in place, however, long before the Industrial Revolution. The

earliest established foundations of a modern patent system were found in the

thirteenth century in Venice. By the 15th century in Venice true patents in the

modern sense were regularly being awarded. Thus in 1416 the Council of Venice

gave a 50 year patent to Franciscus Petri from Rhodes, who was thus a foreigner, for

a new type of fulling mill. By 1474 the Venetian patent law had been codified.

There is evidence for Florence also in the fifteenth century of the awarding of

patents. The Venetian innovation granting property rights in knowledge, which was

very important to the famous Venetian glass industry, spread to Belgium, the

Netherlands, England, Germany, France and Austria in the sixteenth century as a

consequence of the movement of Italian glass workers to these other countries.

Thus by the sixteenth century all the major European countries, at least on an ad hoc

basis, granted property rights in knowledge to innovators. They did this in order to

attract skilled craftsmen with superior techniques to their lands. The spread of

formal patent systems thus predates the Industrial Revolution by at least 350 years.

The claims of North and his associates for the superiority of the property rights

protections afforded by the patent system in eighteenth century England thus stem

from the way in which the system operated after the Glorious Revolution of 1688-9

established the supremacy of Parliament over the King. Under the patent system

introduced in the reign of Elizabeth I (1568-1603) the system was supervised by

government ministers. Political interference led to the creation of spurious

monopolies for techniques already developed, or the denial of legitimate claims.

7 This problem continued into at least the seventeenth century in England, where publishers quite freely pirated the works of authors. 8 See Long,1991, 853-7.

Page 15: The Industrial Revolution in Theory and in History

15

After the Glorious Revolution Parliament sought to avoid this by devolving the

supervision of patents to the courts. Generally the courts would allow any patent to

be registered as long a no other party objected. No other major European country

had a formal patent system as in England before 1791. But as Figure 5 shows, while

the Glorious Revolution produced a brief increase in patent rates, there was no

sustained increase in patenting rates until the 1760s, 75 years after the Glorious

Revoluton.

Page 16: The Industrial Revolution in Theory and in History

16

Figure 5: Patents per Year, England, 1660-1851

There also existed other institutions in, for example, medieval European society,

which we would think would promote innovation better than the modern patent

system. Producers in many towns were organized into guilds which represented the

interests if the trade. These guilds were in a position to tax members to facilitate

lump sum payments to innovators to reveal productive new techniques to the

members.

The empirical difficulty with the appropriability argument is the appallingly weak

evidence that there was any great gain in the returns to innovators in England in the

1760s and later. The textile industry for example was in the vanguard of

technological change in the Industrial Revolution period. Figure 6 shows TFP in the

production of cotton cloth, taking cotton as a basic input. From 1770 to 1869 TFP

rose about 22 fold.

Page 17: The Industrial Revolution in Theory and in History

17

Figure 6: Cotton Spinning and Weaving Productivity, 1770-1869

Note: The squares show the decadal average productivities. The years 1862-5 were

omitted because of the disruption of the cotton famine.

Sources: Cotton cloth prices, Harley, 1998. Labor costs, return on capital, Clark

2010.

Yet the gains of the textile innovators were modest in the extreme. The value of

the cotton textile innovations alone by the 1860s, for example, was about £115

million in extra output per year. But a trivially small share of this value of extra

output ever flowed to the innovators. Table 3, for example, shows the major

innovators in cotton textiles and the gains accruing to the innovators through the

patent system or other means. Patents mostly provided poor protection, the major

gains to innovators coming through appeals post hoc to public beneficence through

Parliament. Also the patent system shows none of the alleged separation from

political interference. The reason for this is that Parliament could, on grounds of the

public good, extend patents beyond the statutory 17 years to adequately reward those

Page 18: The Industrial Revolution in Theory and in History

18

who made significant innovations. James Watt was the beneficiary of such a grant.

But such grants depended on social and political protection just as much as in the

old days.

The profit rates of major firms in the industry also provide good evidence that

most of the innovation in the textile industry was quickly leaking from the

innovators to other producers with no rewards to the innovators. Knick Harley has

reconstructed the profit rates being made by some of the more successful cotton

spinning and weaving firms in the early Industrial Revolution period (Harley (1997)).

The cotton spinners Samuel Greg and Partners earned an average profit from 1796 to

1819 of 11.7% per year, just the normal commercial return for a risky venture such

as manufacturing. Given the rapid improvements in cotton spinning productivity

going on in the industry in these years it suggests that whatever innovations were

being introduced were spreading from one firm to another very quickly. Otherwise

leading firms such as Samuel Greg would have made large profits compared to their

competitors. Similarly the firm of William Grey and Partners made less than 2% per

year from 1801 to 1810, a negative economic profit rate. The innovations in the

cotton spinning industry seem to have mainly caused prices to fall, leaving little

excess profits for the firms that were innovating. Thus a third firm, Richard Hornby

and partners, in the years 1777 to 1809 was in a sector of the industry, hand loom

weaving, which had not yet been transformed by any technological advance. Yet its

average profit rate was 11.4%, as high as Samuel Greg in the innovating part of the

industry. The conclusion is that the host of innovations in cotton textiles do not

seem to have particularly rewarded the innovators. Only a few such as Arkwright

and the Peels became noticeably wealthy. Of the 379 people probated in 1860-9 in

Britain who left estates of £0.5 million or more, only 17 were in the textile industry,

even though as noted from 1760-9 to 1860-9 this one sector generated nearly half

the productivity growth in the economy (Rubinstein, 1981). The Industrial

Revolution economy was spectacularly bad at rewarding innovation. This is why

Britain has few foundations to rival the great private philanthropies and universities

of the U.S.A. Its innovators captured little of the rewards.

Thus there is no evidence that it was institutional changes providing better

rewards for innovators in the Industrial Revolution era that unleashed mankind’s

creative potential. To explain the Industrial Revolution we need other types of

theory.

Page 19: The Industrial Revolution in Theory and in History

19

Table 3: The Gains from Innovation in Textiles in the Industrial Revolution

Innovator

Device

Result

John Kay Flying

Shuttle, 1733

Impoverished by litigation to enforce patent. House destroyed by machine breakers 1753. Died in poverty in France.

James Hargreaves

Spinning Jenny, 1769

Patent denied. Forced to flee by machine breakers in 1768. Died in workhouse in 1777.

Richard Arkwright

Water Frame, 1769

Worth £0.5 m at death in 1792. By 1781 other manufacturers refused to honor patents. Made most of money after 1781.

Samuel Crompton

Mule, 1779

No attempt to patent. Grant of £500 from manufacturers in the 1790s. Granted £5,000 by Parliament in 1811.

Reverend Edmund Cartwright

Power Loom, 1785

Patent worthless. Factory destroyed by machine breakers. Granted £10,000 by Parliament in 1809.

Eli Whitney (USA)

Cotton Gin, 1793

Patent worthless. Later made money as a government arms contractor.

Richard Roberts

Self-Acting Mule, 1830

Patent revenues barely covered development costs. Died in poverty in 1864.

Source: Clark, 2007, table 12.2

Page 20: The Industrial Revolution in Theory and in History

20

Thus the host of innovations in cotton textiles do not seem to have particularly

rewarded the originators, famous or obscure. Only a handful, such as Arkwright and

the Peels, became wealthy. Of the 379 people probated in the 1860s in Britain who

left estates of more than £0.5 million, only 17, or 4 percent, were in textiles.9 Yet the

industry produced 11 percent of national output, and generated the majority of

Industrial Revolution efficiency advance. The Industrial Revolution economy was

still spectacularly bad at rewarding innovation. Wage earners and foreign customers,

not entrepreneurs, were the overwhelming beneficiaries of Industrial Revolution

innovation. This is why Britain has few foundations to rival the great private

philanthropies and universities of the U.S.A. The Industrial Revolution did not

make paupers into princes.

A similar tale can be told for the other great nexus of innovation in Industrial

Revolution England: coal mining, iron and steel, and railroads. Coal output, for

example, exploded in England in the Industrial Revolution era This coal heated

homes, made ore into iron, and powered railway locomotives. Yet there were no

equivalents of the great fortunes made in oil, railways and steel in America’s late

nineteenth century industrialization.

The new industrial priesthood, the engineers who developed the English

coalfields, railways and canals, made prosperous but typically moderate livings.

Though their names survive to history - Richard Trevithick, George and Robert

Stevenson, Humphrey Davy – they again captured very little of the social rewards

their enterprise wrought. Richard Trevithick, the pioneer of locomotives, died a

pauper in 1833. George Stevenson, whose famous locomotive The Rocket in a trial in

1829 ran loaded at 15 miles an hour, an unheard of speed for land travel in this era,

did much better. But his country house in Chesterfield was, however, a pitence

compared to his substantial contributions to railway engineering. But other

locomotives competed in the famous trial, and soon a swarm of locomotive builders

were supplying the railway network.

Innovation in the Industrial Revolution era typically benefited mainly consumers

in the form of lower prices. As coal output exploded real prices to consumers

steadily declined: the real price in the 1700s was 60 percent greater than in the 1860s.

9Rubinstein, 1981, ---.

Page 21: The Industrial Revolution in Theory and in History

21

Coal, iron and steel, and rail carriage all remained highly competitive in England in

the Industrial Revolution era. The patent system offered little protection to most of

the innovations in these sectors, and innovations quickly leaked from one producer

to another.

The rise in innovation rates in Industrial Revolution England was not induced

by unusual rewards to innovation, but by a greater supply of innovation at still

modest rates of reward. Figure 12.3 illustrated two ways in which innovation rates

might increase. The institutionalist perspective is that the rewards offered by the

market shifted upwards compared to all previous pre-industrial economies. There is

no evidence of any such change. The last significant reform of the patent system

was in 1689, more than 100 years before efficiency gains became common. And the

patent system itself played little role for most innovation in Industrial Revolution

England.

Instead the upsurge in innovation in the Industrial Revolution period, in terms

of figure 12.3, reflected a surge in supply. With the benefits to innovation no greater

than in earlier economies, the supply still rose substantially. Facing the same

challenges and incentives as in other economies British producers were more likely

to attempt novel methods of production.

Productivity growth in cotton textiles in England from 1770 to 1870, for

example, far exceeded that in any other industry. But the competitive nature of the

industry, and the inability of the patent system to protect most technological

advances, kept profits low. Cotton goods were homogenous. Yarn and cloth sold in

wholesale markets where quality differences were readily perceptible to buyer. The

efficient scale of cotton spinning and weaving mills was always small relative to the

market. New entrants abounded. By 1900 Britain had about 2,000 firms in the

industry. Firms learned improved technique innovating firms through hiring away

their skilled workers. The machine designers learned improved techniques from the

operating firms. Thus the entire industry – the capital goods makers and the product

producers - over time clustered more and more tightly in the Manchester area. By

1900 40 percent of the entire world output of cotton goods was produced within 30

miles of Manchester. The main beneficiaries of this technological advance thus

ended up being two parties: consumers of textiles all across the world, and the

Page 22: The Industrial Revolution in Theory and in History

22

owners of land in the cluster of textile towns which went from being largely

worthless agricultural land to valuable building sites.

The greatest of the Industrial Revolution cotton magnates, Richard Arkwright,

is estimated to have left £0.5 m. when he died in 1792.10 His son, also Richard

Arkwright, inherited his father’s spinning mills. But though his son had managed his

own mills and had much experience in the industry which was still showing rapid

productivity growth, he soon sold most of his father’s mills, preferring to invest in

land and government bonds. By 1814 he owned £0.5 m in government bonds alone.

He prospered mainly on government bonds and real estate, leaving £3.25 m when he

died in 1843 despite sinking much money into a palatial country house for his

family.11 But Arkwright Senior accumulated less wealth than Josiah Wedgwood, who

left £0.6 m in 1795, even though Wedgwood operated in a sector, pottery, which had

far less technological progress (potteries were still hand enterprises by and large even

in the late 19th c).

Though the first great innovations of the Industrial Revolution era did not offer

much in the way of supernormal profits because of the competitive nature of the

industry, the second, railroads seemed to offer more possibilities. Railways are a

technology with inherent economies of scale. At minimum one line has to be built

between two cities, and once it is built a competitor has to enter with a minimum of

a complete other line. Since most city pairs could not profitably support multiple

links, exclusion, and hence profits, thus seemed possible.

The success of the Liverpool-Manchester line in 1830 – by the 1840s equity

shares on this line were selling for twice their par value - inspired a long period of

investment in railways. Figure 14.9 shows the rapid growth of the railway network in

England from 1825 to 1869, by which time more than 12,000 miles of track had

been laid across the tiny area of England. This investment and construction was so

frenetic that so called railway manias struck in 1839 and 1846.

10Fitton, 1989, 219. 11Ibid., 296.

Page 23: The Industrial Revolution in Theory and in History

23

Figure 7 English Railroad Construction, 1825-1869

Source: Mitchell and Deane, 1971, 225. Table 4 Profit Rates on the Capital Invested in British Owned Railways, 1860-1912

Period

Rate of

Return, UK (%)

Rate of

Return, British Empire

(%)

Rate of Return. Foreign Lines

(%)

1860-9 3.8 - 4.7 1870-9 3.2 - 8.0 1880-9 3.3 1.4 7.7 1890-9 3.0 2.5 4.9 1900-9 2.6 1.6 4.4 1910-13 2.6 3.1 6.6

Source: Clark, 2007, table 14.7.

Page 24: The Industrial Revolution in Theory and in History

24

But again the rush to enter quickly drove down profit rates to very modest

levels, as table 4 shows. Real returns, the return on the capital actually invested, by

the 1860s were no greater than for very safe investments in government bonds or

agricultural land. While railway lines had local monopolies, they ended up in

constant competition with each other through roundabout routes.

Thus while, for example, the Great Western may have controlled the direct line

from London to Manchester, freight and passengers could cross over through other

companies to link up with the East Coast route to London. Again profits inspired

imitation which could not be excluded and the profit was squeezed out of the

system. Consumers were again the main beneficiaries.

It is for this reason that in Britain, unlike in the USA, there are very few

universities and major charities funded by private donors.12 The Industrial

Revolution did not result in great individual or family fortunes in England. By the

1860s the rich were still by and large the descendants of the landed aristocracy. Of

379 men dying between 1860 and 1879 in Britain who left at least £0.5 million, 256

(68 percent) owed their wealth to inherited land. Only 17 (4 percent) were textile

magnates, despite textiles being the driving industry in Industrial Revolution

productivity advance.13

The unsatisfactoriness of conventional institutional accounts – which emphasize

returns to innovation and to investment in general - has led to exploration of other

avenues by which institutions may matter. Avner Greif, Murat Iyigun, and Diego

Sasson have a recent paper which argues that the Industrial Revolution was

underpinned by English welfare institutions, dating to the early sixteenth century,

which insured against failure (Greif, Iyigun, and Sasson, 2012). It was not the size

of the rewards on the upside that distinguished England from other societies such as

China, but the cushion against failure for those who tried and did not succeed.

James Hargreaves, inventor of the Spinning Jenny, may have died in the workhouse

in 1777, but at least he did not die in the street. However, this seems a bit like saying

that New York has developed a high risk, high rewards financial sector because it

allows for financial support for adults without minor dependents in a way not found,

12 The industrialization of the United States created much greater private and family fortunes. 13 Rubinstein, 1981, 60-7.

Page 25: The Industrial Revolution in Theory and in History

25

for example, in Texas. Presumably the Harvard graduates in the financial sector have

backup plans other than general relief if their Hedge Fund fails.

One thing that is striking about institutionalist explanations in general is the

absence of any agreed metric for institutional quality. There is a belief in the physical

sciences that a basic element in any scientific analysis of any phenomenon is to have

a defined, objective and shared system of measurement. Institutionalists on this

standard are still in the pre-science world of phlogiston and other early theories.

Changes in People

The modest signs of any increase in returns to innovation at the time of the

Industrial Revolution suggests as an alternative that the transition was instead driven

by changes in the aspirations and capabilities of economic agents. And this has been

the theme of another set of explanations of the Industrial Revolution. In this

extensive set of theories a rise in human capital investment, and consequent

improvement in the capabilities of economic actors, is key to the transition between

the Malthusian regime and the modern (Becker, Tamura and Murphy, 1990, Lucas,

2002, Galor and Weil, 2000, Galor and Moav, 2002, Galor, 2011).

We certainly see that the English population on the eve of the Industrial

Revolution had characteristics that differed from most pre-industrial societies. In

particular the levels of literacy and numeracy were high by the standards of the pre-

industrial world. Even the great civilizations of the past, such as the Roman Empire,

or the city states of the Italian Renaissance, had general levels of literacy and

numeracy that were surprisingly low by the standards of Industrial Revolution

England. And we know as a general feature that modern high income, fast growth

economies are distinguished by high levels of human capital. So increases in human

capital that created knowledge externalities, at the gross level, would seemingly be a

candidate source of the Industrial Revolution.

We find interesting evidence that the average numeracy and literacy of even rich

people in most earlier economies was surprisingly poor. A prosperous land owner in

Roman Egypt, Isidorus Aurelius, for example, variously declared his age in legal

documents in a less than two year span in 308-9 AD as 37, 40, 45 and 40. Clearly

Page 26: The Industrial Revolution in Theory and in History

26

Isidorus had no clear idea of his age. Other sources show he was illiterate (Duncan-

Jones, 1990, 80). A lack of knowledge of their true age was widespread among the

Roman upper classes as evidenced by age declarations made by their survivors on

tombstones. In populations where ages are recorded accurately, 20% of the

recorded ages will end in 5 or 10. We can thus construct a score variable Z, which

measures the degree of “age heaping,” where

( ), and X is the

percentage of age declarations ending in 5 or 10 to measure the percentage of the

population whose real age is unknown. This measure of the percentage of people

who did not know their true age correlates moderately well in modern societies also

with the degree of literacy.

Among those wealthy enough to be commemorated by an inscribed tombstone

in the Roman Empire, typically half had unknown ages. Age awareness did correlate

with social class within the Roman Empire. More than 80% of office holder’s ages

seem to have been known by their relatives. When we compare this with death

records for modern Europe we find that by the eve of the Industrial Revolution age

awareness in the general European population had increased markedly, as table 5

shows.

We can also look at the development of age awareness by looking at census of

the living, as in table 6. Some of the earliest of these are for medieval Italy, including

the famous Florentine Catasto of 1427. Even though Florence was then one of the

richest cities of the world, and the center of the Renaissance, 32% of the city

population did not know their age. In comparison a census of 1790 of the small

English borough of Corfe Castle in Dorset, with a mere 1,239 inhabitants, most of

them laborers, shows that all but 8% knew their age. In 1790 again awareness

correlates with measures of social class, with universal knowledge among the higher

status families, and lower age awareness among the poor. But the poor of Corfe

Castle or Terling in Essex had as much age awareness as office holders in the Roman

Empire.

Page 27: The Industrial Revolution in Theory and in History

27

Table 5: Age-Heaping, Rome versus later Europe

Social Group

Sample Size

Innumeracy

rate

Imperial Rome

Rome All 3,708 48

Italy outside Rome All 1,395 43

Italy outside Rome Town Councilors 75 15

Modern Europe, death

records

Geneva, 1560-1600 All - 54

Geneva, 1601-1700 All - 44

Geneva, 1701-1800 All - 23

Liege, 1740 All - 26

Paris, c. 1750 All - 15

Source: Duncan-Jones, 1990, 84-90.

Page 28: The Industrial Revolution in Theory and in History

28

Table 6: Age Heaping Among Living Populations (23-62)

Place

Date

Type of

Community

Sample

Size

Z

Town of Florence 1427 Urban - 32

Florentine Territory 1427 Rural - 53

Pistoia 1427 Urban - 42

Pozzuoli 1489 Urban - 72

Sorrento 1561 Urban - 67

Corfe Castle, England 1790 Urban 352 8

Ardleigh, England 1796 Rural 433 30

Terling, England – Poor

relief recipients

1801 Rural 79 19

Notes: The total population of Corfe Castle was 1,239, and of Ardleigh 1,145.

Sources: Duncan-Jones, 1990. Terling, Essex Record Office D/P 299/12/3.

Ardleigh, Essex Record Office, D/P 263/1/5.

Another feature of the Roman tombstone age declarations is that ages seem to

be greatly overstated for many adults. Thus while we know that life expectancy in

ancient Rome was probably in the order of 20-25 at birth, tombstones record people

as dying at ages as high as 120. For North African tombstones, for example, 3% of

the deceased are recorded as dying at age 100 or more.14 Almost all of these 3%

must have been 20-50 years younger than was recorded. Yet their descendants did

not detect any implausibility in recording these fabulous ages. In contrast the Corfe

Castle census records a highest age of 90, well within the range of possibilities given

life expectancy in rural England in these years.

14 Hopkins, 1966, 249.

Page 29: The Industrial Revolution in Theory and in History

29

Thus another explanation for the Industrial Revolution is that while the

incentives to innovate were not greater, the capabilities and aspirations of economic

agents had improved. This raises two important issues. First why did history move

in a general direction towards increasing levels of literacy and numeracy? What

internal dynamic drove this move? Second, was England sufficiently distinct from

earlier societies in terms of the abilities of its economic agents to account for the

transition to modern growth?

Figure 8, shows, for example, literacy rates, measured by the ability to sign your

name, for England 1580-1920. Two things stand out. The first is that literacy rates

for men rose substantially long before the Industrial Revolution. If mass literacy was

the key to growth then seemingly the Industrial Revolution would have again

appeared 100 years before the 1780s. The second is that dramatic increases in

literacy rates are a phenomenon only of the late Industrial Revolution period, the

years 1850-1900. Literacy in the Industrial Revolution period itself rose by modest

amounts.

Also literacy rates in England in 1780 were not high by the standards of many

other parts of northwest Europe. Literacy rates then exceeded those of England in

Scotland, the Netherlands, much of Germany and in Scandinavia. But with those

caveats we can ask what might have driven the trend all across northern Europe to

greater levels of numeracy and literacy by the eve of the Industrial Revolution.

Another caveat about the role of numeracy and literacy is that given the

observed rates of return to schooling, the increased investment in countries like

England in the Industrial Revolution period can account little for faster productivity

growth rates. Thus we can modify equation (1) to allow for investment in human

capital to

(4)

where is the share of income attributable to human capital investments and is

the growth rate of the stock of human capital. But the growth rate of the human

capital stock in England 1760-1860 implied by figure 8 is very modest: less than 0.4%

per year. And even if we allowed one third of all the 60% share of wage

Page 30: The Industrial Revolution in Theory and in History

30

Figure 8: Literacy in England, 1580-1920

Sources: 1750s-1920s, Schofield (1973), men and women who can sign marriage

resisters. The north, 1630s-1740s, Houston (1982), witnesses who can sign court

depositions. Norwich Diocese, 1580s-1690s, Cressy (1977), witnesses who can sign

ecclesiastical court declarations.

Source: Clark, 2007, figure 9.3, 179.

Page 31: The Industrial Revolution in Theory and in History

31

payments in income in Industrial Revolution England to be attributed to human

capital, this would entail human capital investments increased income growth rates

by a mere 0.08% per year. If human capital lies at the heart of the Industrial

Revolution it must be because there are significant external benefits associated with

human capital investments, as Lucas, 1988, hypothesized.

Why, then, did education levels rise in the centuries leading up to the Industrial

Revolution? A theme of many economic models of the transition from Malthusian

stagnation to modern growth listed above is that there was a switch from quantity, or

at least desired quantity, to quality in families as we moved to the modern world.

This theme has been driven by the observation in modern cross sections, looking

across countries, that high income, high education societies are those with few

children per woman. Also within high income societies there was a period between

1890 and 1980 where again lower income families were those with more children.

Such theories face a number of challenges in modeling the actual world of

Industrial Revolution England. The first challenge is that these theories are

expressed always in terms of children surviving to adulthood. In the modern world

in most societies child survival rates are high, and so in practice births and surviving

children are closely equivalent. But in all known pre-industrial societies, including

pre-industrial England, large numbers of children did not survive even to their first

year. In these cases the distinction between births and surviving children becomes

important. Measured in terms of births, Malthusian societies witnessed high fertility,

with the average woman surviving to age 50 giving birth to 5 children. But in such

societies the average number of children surviving to adulthood could only be 2.

Further since children who died in the pre-industrial world tended to do so

fairly early, the numbers of children in any household at any time in the pre-

industrial world would typically be 3 or less. For example, of 1,000 children born in

England in 1700-24, nearly 200 would be dead within 6 months (Wrigley et al., 1997).

Pre-industrial families would look similar to the families of America in the high

growth 1950s and 1960s. Pre-industrial families thus faced remarkably similar

tradeoffs between the number and quality of children as do modern families. In

some sense there has been no change in fertility from the pre-industrial to the

modern world, measured in net as opposed to gross terms.

Page 32: The Industrial Revolution in Theory and in History

32

The second challenge these theories face is that in England the transition from

high births per woman to lower levels of births per woman did not occur at the

onset of the Industrial Revolution, but only one hundred years later in the 1880s.15

Fertility in England did not show any decline at the aggregate level prior to 1880.

Indeed the opposite occurred, as figure 9 illustrates. Births per woman, and also net

fertility, rose precisely in the period of the Industrial Revolution in England.

The third challenge is that in cross-section in pre-industrial England there was a

strong positive association between net fertility and the wealth or occupational status

of families. Figure 10, for example, shows by twenty year periods the numbers of

children alive at the time wills were made for married men in England marrying

1520-1879, where those leaving wills are divided into wealth terciles defined across

the whole sample. The lowest tercile in wealth would still be men of above median

wealth at death. Their implied net fertility is similar to that for men as a whole in

England, as revealed by figure 9. But the men of the top wealth tercile marrying

before 1780 were leaving on average 3.5-4 surviving children. The most educated

and economically successful men in pre-industrial England were those with the

largest numbers of surviving offspring. Matching these men to parish records of

births shows that this advantage in numbers of surviving children stems largely from

the greater fertility of the wives of richer men. Their gross fertility was equivalently

higher. This positive association of economic status and fertility pre 1780 has been

confirmed in an independent study of gross fertility in parish records in England

1538-1837 by Boberg-Fazlic, Sharp, and Weisdorf, 2011.

For marriages 1780-1879 this pattern of high fertility by the rich and educated

disappears. Instead we have for most of the Industrial Revolution period an interval

where fertility is unlinked to education, status or wealth. Figure 11 shows the

dramatic shift in pattern this represents, grouping married men by wealth deciles.

Another feature revealed in figure 11 is that the pattern of higher net fertility with

wealth before 1780 continues all through the wealth spectrum. There is no wealth

level at which we observe any decline in net fertility.

15 France was the only country to experience a decline in fertility starting in the late eighteenth century, and France of course lagged Britain in terms of the onset of modern growth.

Page 33: The Industrial Revolution in Theory and in History

33

Figure 9: The Fertility History of England, 1540-2000

Source: Clark, 2007, figure 14.6, p. 290.

Figure 10: Net Fertility by Wealth Terciles, marriage cohorts, 1520-1879

Source: Clark and Cummins, 2013a.

0

1

2

3

4

1540 1590 1640 1690 1740 1790 1840 1890 1940 1990

Gro

ss a

nd

net

rep

rod

uct

ion

rat

es

GRR

GRR

NRR

Demographictransition

0

1

2

3

4

5

6

Pre

dic

ted

Net

Fert

ilit

y

Marriage Cohort

Tercile 1

Tercile 2

Tercile 3

Page 34: The Industrial Revolution in Theory and in History

34

Figure 11: Net Marital Fertility by Wealth Decile, Marriages 1500-1779 and

1780-1879

Note: The lines at the top of the columns indicate the 95% confidence interval for

the net fertility of these groups relative to the decile of lowest asset income. All

assets normalized by the average wage in the year of death from Clark, 2010.

Source: Clark and Cummins, 2013a.

Figure 12: The Skill Premium, Building Workers, England, 1220-2000

Source: Clark, 2005.

0

1

2

3

4

5

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Pre

dic

ted

Net

Fert

ilit

y

Asset Income Decile

1500-1780

1780-1879

Page 35: The Industrial Revolution in Theory and in History

35

The delay in the decline in aggregate fertility levels in England till after the

Industrial Revolution represents a formidable challenge for theories that seek to

explain the Industrial Revolution through a quality-quantity tradeoff, and rising levels

of human capital. However, these recent findings that richer families did indeed

reduce their fertility just at the time of the onset of the Industrial Revolution offers

some hope for models based on heterogenous agents as opposed to a single

representative agent. But if richer families were changing their behaviors in response

to economic signals, we would expect to find in this period sign of greater returns to

human capital investments. Another problem for quality-quantity models of the

Industrial Revolution is that such evidence is lacking. Figure 12, for example, shows

the earnings of building craftsmen – carpenters, masons, bricklayers, plasterers,

painters, plumbers, pavers, tilers and thatchers – relative to unskilled building

laborers and assistants. The skill premium is actually at its highest in the interval

1220-2000 in the earliest years, before the onset of the Black Death in 1348, when a

craftsman earned nearly double the wage of a laborer. If there was ever an incentive

to accumulate skills it was in the early economy. Thereafter it declines to a lower but

relatively stable level from about 1370 until 1900, a period of over 400 years, before

declining further in the twentieth century. Thus the time of the greatest market

reward for skills and training was long before the Industrial Revolution. And the

period of the Demographic Transition in England, the switch towards smaller family

sizes circa 1880, is not associated with any rise in the skill premium.

The information on the skill premium in building may be criticized as showing

only the returns to a very limited form of human capital. What about wider

measures of the impact of quantity of children before and after the Industrial

Revolution on child outcomes? Do we find that for marriages prior to 1780 there is

little or no cost in terms of child outcomes where richer families have more children,

but that after 1780 a quality-quantity tradeoff becomes evident?

The same source that was used above to measure net fertility as a function of

wealth and socio-economic status, men’s wills, can also be employed to measure the

effects of the number of children on the outcomes for children before and during

the Industrial Revolution (Clark and Cummins, 2013b).

In measuring the quality-quantity tradeoff in the modern world the problem has

been that “high quality” families tend to have fewer children. The observed

relationship between quality and quantity may thus reveal no underlying causal

Page 36: The Industrial Revolution in Theory and in History

36

relationship. In capturing the true quality-quantity trade-off, researchers have had to

control for the inherent endogeneity of family size. We can thus portray parent

influences on child “quality” as following two potential routes, as in figure 13. Since

in the modern world high ‘quality’ parents also tend to have smaller numbers of

children, the observed negative correlation between n and child quality may stem just

from the positive correlation of parent and child quality. As figure 14 shows the

estimate of the tradeoff between quantity and quality will be too steep using just the

observed relationship. Estimates of β in the regression

q = βn + u, (5)

where q is child quality, n child numbers, and u the error term are biased towards the

negative, because of the correlation between n and u.

To uncover the true relationship investigators have followed a number of

strategies. The first is to look at exogenous variation in family size caused by the

accident of twin births (e.g. Rosenzweig and Wolpin, 1980, Angrist, Lavy, and

Schlosser, 2010, Li, Zhang, and Zhu, 2008). In a world where the modal family size

is 2, there are a number of families who accidentally end up with 3 children because

their second birth is of twins. What happens to the quality of these children

compared to the quality of the children of such families compared to those of two

child families? These studies find the uncontrolled relationship between quantity and

quality decreases. Indeed it is often insignificant and sometimes positive (Schultz,

2007, 20). For instance; Angrist, et al., 2010, find “no evidence of a quality-quantity

trade-off” for Israel using census data. Li, Zhang, and Zhu, 2008, however, do

report the expected relationship instrumenting using twins in China, but only in the

Chinese countryside. But in China there are government policies designed to

penalize couples who have more than the approved number of children, so we may

not be observing anything about the free market quality/quantity tradeoff.

In summary, there is a clear raw negative correlation in modern populations

between child numbers and various measures of child quality. However, once

instruments and other controls to deal with the endogeneity of child quality and

quantity are included, the quality-quantity relationship becomes unclear. The quality-

quantity tradeoff so vital to most theoretical accounts of modern economic growth

is, at best, unproven.

Page 37: The Industrial Revolution in Theory and in History

37

Figure 13: Parent influences on child quality

Figure 14: The True and Observed Quality-Quantity Tradeoff

Parent 'quality'

n children

child 'quality'

-ve

?

+ve

Ch

ild q

ual

ity

Number

Observed

True

Page 38: The Industrial Revolution in Theory and in History

38

However, we see above that in the period 1540-1780 in England the modern

negative relationship between child numbers and parent quality is reversed and is

instead positive. Thus in this period in estimating β in equation (5) we will find that

is in this case biased instead towards 0. Figure 15 shows this effect. Any negative

effects of quantity on quality found will be underestimated, as opposed to the bias in

estimating β in modern studies. Then there is the intermediate fertility regime in

England, marriages formed 1780-1880, where parent quality and numbers of children

are uncorrelated, so that will be unbiased.

The second advantage of the pre-industrial data from England for observing the

quality-quantity tradeoff is the much greater variation in family sizes before 1870

than in the modern world, and the evidence that this variance was largely the product

of chance, like modern twin births. Figure 16 shows the distribution of the number

of surviving children per father, at the time of the father’s will, for fathers marrying

1500-1799, and 1800-1869. This number will include children from more than one

wife, where a first wife died and the husband remarried.

As noted above we can measure family size in two ways. A second is the

number of births per family, gross fertility. This is shown in figure 17, giving the

distribution of births per mother for the wives of men marrying in England 1500-

1799, where the husband had only one wife. Thus despite the average of 5 births per

wife, in 10% of all marriages there was only one child born, in about 20% only two.

The number of baptisms is the overwhelming explanator of the number of surviving

children per man. The R2 of the regression predicting numbers of surviving children

from the number baptized is 0.73. On average 0.62 of each child born would be

alive at the time of the will. If we include in this regression indicators for location,

social status, wealth, and time period then the R2 increases only marginally to 0.75.

At the individual family level both gross fertility, births, and net fertility, the number

of surviving children, were largely random variables. Only a tiny fraction of the

variation in each is explained by correlates such as wealth, occupation, literacy and

location.

Page 39: The Industrial Revolution in Theory and in History

39

Figure 15: The True and Observed Quality-Quantity Tradeoff, marriages pre

1780

Ch

ild

qual

ity

Number

Observed

True

Page 40: The Industrial Revolution in Theory and in History

40

Figure 16: The distribution of net family sizes in pre-industrial England

Note: Number of observations before 1800, 6,940, after 1800, 1,418.

Source: Clark and Cummins, 2013b.

Figure 17: The Distribution of number of baptisms per wife, 1500-1799

Note: Number of observations before 1800, 818.

Source: Clark and Cummins, 2013b.

0.00

0.05

0.10

0.15

0.20

0.25

0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15

1800-1869

1500-1799

0.00

0.02

0.04

0.06

0.08

0.10

0.12

0.14

0.16

0.18

0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17

Page 41: The Industrial Revolution in Theory and in History

41

When the coefficient β in the equation

q = βn + u

is estimated by OLS estimate of β will be, in the limit,

( )

( )

But in pre-industrial England the degree of bias this will impart will be small because

n was largely a random variable, so the bias in estimating β will be correspondingly

very slight.

Thus suppose n = θ u + e. Then

( )

( )

( )

( ) ( )

The greater is var(e), the random component in n, then the less the bias in the

estimate of β. We show below that for marriages formed before 1870 var(e) was

enormous relative to θ2var(u). We can thus use the observed correlation between

quality and quantity in this period as a measure of the true underlying causal

connection between quantity and quality in the years before and during the Industrial

Revolution.

We have three measures of child quality for sons born over the years 1500-1879:

the wealth of those probated, the socio-economic status of those probated, and the

probate rates of all sons. The likelihood of a man being probated was strongly linked

to their wealth and social status. Probate was only required if the estate of the

deceased exceed a certain limit. In 1862 65% of men of high socio-economic status

(professionals and gentlemen) were probated, compared to 2% of laborers (Clark

and Cummins, 2013a).

The sample of father-son pairings is very much biased towards the rich. As

table 6 shows, will makers in the years 1500-1920 were disproportionately from the

Page 42: The Industrial Revolution in Theory and in History

42

upper social groups. In 1862 the bottom two social groups in the table were 40

percent of men dying, but they represent only 8 percent of fathers and sons where

both were probated (Clark and Cummins, 2013a, table A.12). In contrast the top 3

social groups represented 13 percent of men dying in 1862, but a full 67 percent of

those where both father and son were probated. Thus what we are principally

looking at here is the effects of family size on the outcomes for children of the upper

third of the population in pre-industrial England. But this is the group whose

behavior was changing first around 1780, then around 1880, in the two stage

demographic transition observed in Industrial Revolution England.

The effect of family size on wealth is estimated from the size of the coefficient b2 in

the expression

+ e (6)

Where N is the number of surviving children, lnWs the average log wealth of sons of

a given father, and DFALIVE the fraction of sons for whom the father was alive at

the time of son’s probate. DFALIVE is a control for the effects of sons who die

before fathers, and thus likely receive smaller transfers of wealth from fathers. Such

sons will also tend to be younger. And in this data wealth rises monotonically with

age until men are well past 60. Since some fathers had more than one probated son,

we averaged wealth across the probated sons and treated each family as the unit of

observation.

With this formulation, b3 is the elasticity of son’s asset income as a function of

the number of surviving children the father left. N varies in the sub-sample of

fathers and sons from 1 to 13. The coefficient b2 shows the direct link between

fathers’ and sons’ wealth, independent of the size of the fathers’ family.

Table 7 shows the estimated coefficients from equation (6) for father’s dying

1500-1920. The results are reported for the data pooled across all years, and for

fathers dying 1500-1819 (who would have sons born up until 1800 typically), those

dying 1820-1880 and post-1880. The link between father’s and son’s wealth as

revealed by the estimate of b1 is highly significant and stable across the sub-periods.

Page 43: The Industrial Revolution in Theory and in History

43

Table 6: Social Distribution among Will Makers, and Father-Son Pairs

Source: Clark and Cummins, 2013b.

The estimated coefficient on the log of surviving children is negative in all three

periods, as would be implied by a quality-quantity tradeoff. So this study is unusual

in finding for the early period a quantitatively and statistically significant effect of

family size on son outcomes. However, even though it will be potentially biased

towards zero for fathers dying before 1820, the value in these earlier years is

estimated as being similar to that in 1820-80.16 There is no indication in this data of

a substantially more adverse quality-quantity tradeoff with the arrival of the

Industrial Revolution. There is nothing in the estimates of table 7 to suggest that

changing family sizes among the wealthy and educated in Industrial Revolution

England were driven by a changing quality-quantity tradeoff. Again the economic

environment seems stable as the dramatic changes of the Industrial Revolution were

occurring.

16 The bias, as argued above, will be small before 1880 because of the randomness of family sizes.

Social group

N

all wills

%

all wills

N

father-son

%

father -son

Gentry/Independent 405 7 220 15

Merchants/

Professionals 506 9 167 11

Farmers 1,906 33 605 41

Traders 883 15 152 10

Craftsmen 1,132 19 217 15

Husbandmen 708 12 99 7

Laborers/Servants

268

5

16

1

Page 44: The Industrial Revolution in Theory and in History

44

Table 7: Son’s Wealth and Family Size

All

Pre 1820

1820- 1880

1880-

LnWf .502*** .560*** .527*** .457*** (.030) (.051) (.073) (.046) LnN -.311*** -.241*** -.312 -.390** (.082) (.090) (.227) (.176) Dfalive -.868*** -.710** -.611 -.866* (.258) (.314) (.643) (.448) Constant 2.032*** 1.929*** 2.024*** 1.696*** (.158) (.210) (.502) (.341) Obs 1,029 610 175 244 R-squared

.292 .306 .281 .302

Robust standard errors in parentheses, *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1 Source: Clark and Cummins, 2013b.

Figure 18: The Empirical QQ Effect, 1500-1920

Source: Clark and Cummins, 2013b.

0.00

0.20

0.40

0.60

0.80

1.00

1.20

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Ch

ild

Wealt

h

N

No QQ Fixed Pie Pre 1820 1820-1880 1880-

Page 45: The Industrial Revolution in Theory and in History

45

The predicted quantitative effects of sibling size on wealth at death are shown in

figure 18, where wealth at a family size of 1 fixed at 1. Pooling all the data, the

effects of family size on the outcomes for children measured in terms of wealth are

actually reasonably modest. Moving from a family of one child (with our data by

definition a boy), to one of 10 children, reduces the average wealth of sons by only

51 percent. This is demonstrated visually in figure 18.

This is not a very strong effect if the main transmission of wealth was through

division of a fixed pie of wealth among children (the red line in figure 18). For in

that case the expected coefficient on lnN should be -1. The average wealth of the

children of a family of 10 would be only 10% of that of a family with only one

sibling. We can derive similar estimates of the effect of family size by period on the

chances of being probated, and on occupational status. In each case the effects are

in the right direction, but even more modest than for wealth (Clark and Cummins,

2013).

The facts above about the transition from pre-industrial to modern fertility in

England in the Industrial Revolution era represent a formidable challenge to those

trying to model the Industrial Revolution in a child quality-quantity framework.

Since some of these patterns were discovered only in the last few years, such as the

strong positive association of wealth and fertility in pre-industrial England, many of

these models fail to capture essential features of the fertility transitions (Clark and

Hamilton, 2006, Clark and Cummins, 2013a, Boberg-Fazlic, Sharp, and Weisdorf,

2011).

Some of the theory papers mentioned above, such as that of Becker, Tamura

and Murphy, 1990, fail at the first challenge. They posit a pre-industrial world world

that never existed of high net fertility and rapid population growth. And while they

model a world with two equilibria – in one of which parents invest nothing in the

human capital of their children, and in the other considerable human capital – the

escape from the zero human capital Malthusian trap is exogenous to the model.

“Technological and other shocks” (Becker, Tamura and Murphy, 1990, S32)

somehow raise the level of human capital far enough above zero to lead to a

convergence to the high growth equilibrium. These shocks are conceived to be

“improved methods to use coal, better rail and ocean transports, and decreased

regulation of prices and foreign trade.” (Becker, Tamura and Murphy, 1990, S33).

But how such shocks get translated into human capital is never specified. The arrival

Page 46: The Industrial Revolution in Theory and in History

46

of highly paid unskilled work in textile factories in the Industrial Revolution, for

example, we would expect in the Becker, Murphy and Tamura model to reduce

educational investment.

Robert Lucas creates a Malthusian trap with many of the same characteristics of

Becker, Murphy and Tamura (Lucas, 2002), but which tries to model better pre-

industrial fertility, measured as surviving children, so that it increases in income. In

the low level equilibrium there is again no human capital investment. This arises

because Lucas specifies a land using sector where human capital plays no role, and a

“modern” sector where human capital enters with constant returns. Goods

production is thus (simplifying slightly)

)(max),,( 1

lBHxlHxF (4)

where x is land per person, H is human capital per person, l is the labor devoted to

production, and is the labor devoted to the land using sector. However, the

assumption that there is a crucial difference in character between the farm sector and

other areas of the economy is unsupportable both for the pre-industrial and for the

modern eras. We see above in table 2 that agriculture in England in the Industrial

Revolution era experienced unusually fast productivity growth rates also. And

agriculture had as much demand for skills and human capital as other sectors of the

economy.17

In Lucas, 2002, parents’ utility depends on goods consumption, the number of

children and the utility of the children, but with the slightly different functional form

17 Hanson and Prescott, 2002, is another model which produces an Industrial Revolution by

positing a difference between the farm and non-farm sectors. The inherent rate of

productivity growth in the non-farm sector is assumed to be higher. This means that

wherever the economy starts there will eventually be an Industrial Revolution. Why that

Industrial Revolution does not occur in 1800 BC as opposed to 1800 AD is not explained.

Also productivity growth rates in the “industrial” sector in England in reality increased at the

time of the Industrial Revolution. The Industrial Revolution was not the result of

composition effects only. And, as noted, productivity growth rates in the farm sector also

increased in the Industrial Revolution era, and since then have been as rapid as those in the

rest of the economy.

Page 47: The Industrial Revolution in Theory and in History

47

1

1

tttt VncV (5)

Human capital evolves according to

)(1 ttt hHH (6)

where h is the labor invested in education. This means that in the Malthusian

equilibrium there is no investment in human capital since H starts as 0. Thus all

production is conducted using the land using technology. Since there is a land

constraint, now there will only be a constant output Malthusian equilibrium if n = 1,

so that the population stabilizes. To ensure this Lucas assumes that each child

requires a fixed investment of goods, k. As population increases, so that output per

person declines, the relative cost of children thus rises. Eventually n will be driven to

1.

In the contrasting endogenous growth regime, H is large, so that nearly all

output comes from the technology where there are constant returns to H.

Consumption and human capital grow at the same rate, and fertility and educational

investment per child is constant. The number of children per parent chosen in this

steady state growth path will depend on the weights in the utility function for

children versus their utilities , and on the form of (h).

But like Becker et al., 1990 Lucas gives no mechanism that gets the economy

from the Malthusian trap to the sustained growth regime. Instead he has to assume

that somehow enough human capital, H, accumulates for non-economic reasons to

push the economy far enough from the Malthusian equilibrium for convergence on

the modern growth regime to begin. The Industrial Revolution is again the deus ex

machina.

We thus see a very poor match between the elements that would seem to go

into a human capital story of the Industrial Revolution – the Industrial Revolution

itself, the average size of families, and the premium paid in the labor market for

skills. If human capital is the key to the Industrial Revolution, the trigger for its

expansion in pre-industrial England remains mysterious if we assume a universal set

of preferences for all societies.

Page 48: The Industrial Revolution in Theory and in History

48

Endogenous growth theories such as those of Galor and Weil, 2000, and Galor

and Moaz, 2002, seek to avoid the need for some exogenous shock to trigger the

switch to higher human capital investment and the consequent Industrial Revolution.

This requires that some elements of the economy must be evolving endogenously

within the pre-industrial era. Since incomes and consumption are predicted to be

static within the Malthusian regime it is not these. Instead Galor and Weil, 2000, rely

on the accumulation of population in the pre-industrial era to drive up the rate of

innovation and the return to human capital. In this they rely on an interesting paper

by Michael Kremer which argues for population size as a driver of rates of

productivity advance (Kremer, 1993).

Kremer assumes that the social institutions that provide the incentives to

individuals to create knowledge are the same in all societies. Each person has a

given probability of producing a new idea. In this case the growth rate of

knowledge will be a function of the size of the community. The more people you

are in contact with the more you get to benefit from the ideas of others. There was

substantial but slow productivity growth in the world economy in the years before

1800, and that all got translated into a huge expansion of the world population,

through the effects of equation (2) above. That larger population produced more

ideas and more rapid growth. Sheer scale is what produces modern economic

growth. 18

Kremer supports the argument with two sorts of evidence

(a) The first is population growth rates for the world as a whole in the pre-

industrial era. World population growth rates are faster the greater the size of

populations. That implies, since population growth rates and the rate of

technological advance are proportionate, that productivity growth rates were

speeding up over time as population grew. This is shown in Figure 19.

(b) The second is population density, as an index of the level of technology in

the pre-industrial world, for major isolated geographic areas – Eurasia, the Americas

and Australia - as a function of the land area. The prediction is that the smaller the

18 Diamond, 1997, contains many of the same ideas, merged also with consideration of the role of geography in creating the community that benefits from knowledge expansion.

Page 49: The Industrial Revolution in Theory and in History

49

Figure 19: Population and the Rate of Technological Advance – Actual versus

predicted

land area, and hence the potential population, the lower will be the rate of

technological advance. In this case at any given time population density will depend

on land area. This is found for the three cases examined.

One immediate implication of the Kremer argument, however, would be that

ceteris paribus the Industrial Revolution should have occurred in China. Chinese

population in the pre-industrial world was large relative to that of Europe. Even as

late at 1800 it has been estimated that China contained 260 million people, while

Europe outside Russia had only 130 million, half as many as China. Thus Galor and

Weil, 2000, has no insight to offer on why the Industrial Revolution was British, as

opposed to Chinese. It is a more general theory about the world transition to

growth.

Page 50: The Industrial Revolution in Theory and in History

50

Interesting though Kremer’s ideas are, no matter how much population is a

driver of the rate of technological advance, population alone cannot produce a

discontinuity in the rate of technological advance circa 1800 of the magnitude

indicated in figure 19. Thus a simple specification for the effect of population on

changes in productivity would be

NA (7)

where A is now the stock of knowledge (the number of ideas). If every person has

some chance of producing a new idea then the expansion of the idea stock will be at

best proportional to the population size.19 This implies that the rate of growth of

ideas (=productivity) will be

A

N

A

Ag A

(8)

But integrating equation (2) above this is equivalent to the condition

cAN /1 (9)

where is just a parameter. That is the population size depends on the existing level

of the technology. Substituting from (9) for A in (8) gives

c

c

A NcN

cNg

1

(10)

This formula implies that the rate of efficiency growth, gA, rises less than

proportionately with population. Yet what we see in figure 19 is that the rate of

technological advance seems to rise faster than population growth. Figure 19 also

shows the rate of technological advance predicted by this Kremer argument (the

19 Assuming that there is no duplication of ideas with a larger population, where the same thing is discovered by multiple people. In actual fact we would expect that the gains in idea production would rise less than proportionately with population.

Page 51: The Industrial Revolution in Theory and in History

51

lowest curve). The increase of the rate of technological advance as we move to

modern population sizes is just not fast enough to explain what we observe.

Technology growth rates would be more responsive to population if instead of

(8) we posit

NAA (11)

This says that the stock of ideas grows as a product of the number of people,

and the existing stock of ideas (with again no duplication of ideas). This in turn

implies that

cNA

AgA

(12)

This predicted growth rate of technology as a function of population is also

shown in figure 19. Now the fit is closer before 1800, but there is still no close fit

with modern productivity growth rates. At best productivity growth rates would be

proportionate to population under the Kremer assumptions.

This feature of the Kremer model, that it is hard to produce with an

endogenous growth model a discontinuity of the magnitude seemingly observed in

the Industrial Revolution, is a general problem for all such endogenous growth

models. Thus the Galor and Weil endogenous growth model, which uses the

Kremer population size driver as the spark for the Industrial Revolution (and is

described further below), has been simulated in Lagerlöf, 2006. Figure 20 shows the

outlines of that simulation, where time is measured on the horizontal axes in terms

of generations. In the Galor-Weil model there is a transition period between the

Malthusian regime and modern growth in which technology advances more quickly,

incomes rise above subsistence, and population expands. But this transition period

here lasts 20 generations, which would be 500-600 years.20

20 Lagerlöf assumes a generation length of 20 years, but this is too short for any pre-industrial society, where 25-30 years would be more realistic.

Page 52: The Industrial Revolution in Theory and in History

52

Figure 20: Simulated the Galor and Weil, 2000, Endogenous Growth Model

Source: Lagerlöf, 2006, Figure 5, 130.

But we do not see at the world level in 1200-1800 any signs of the income

growth rates, or the population growth rates predicted in this simulation of the

Galor-Weil model. Table 1, for example, shows that at the world level population

growth rates remained in the range on 0.1-0.2% per year, far slower than figure 20

implies. Clark, 2007, shows that there is no sign on a world scale that incomes per

person had risen above those of the hunter-gatherer era, despite the prediction of

figure 20 that by then incomes per capita in the world would have risen to 3 times

their Malthusian level by 1800. Also, at least in England we see no sign of the abrupt

rise in human capital coincident with declining fertility portrayed in figure 20.

Measurements of human capital as in figure 8 suggest a much more modest

transition starting hundreds of years before the Industrial Revolution and continuing

through it.

Page 53: The Industrial Revolution in Theory and in History

53

Galor and Weil, 2000, as noted above, marry the key idea of Kremer that the

rate of technological progress depends on population size with the Beckerian human

capital approach. They posit a utility function of the form

)( 1

1

tttt nycV

(13)

Utility now is a weighted average of the consumption of the parents and the

aggregate potential income of their children, yt+1, in the next period. While in Lucas

children have a fixed cost in goods, in Galor and Weil they have a fixed cost only in

time. That means that at low incomes, when time is cheap, people would have more

children, as in the Becker, Murphy and Tamura (1990), and we would not get a

Malthusian steady state. To get a Malthusian equilibrium where income per capita is

stable, the authors make an additional assumption that there is a minimum physical

consumption level, . This means that as long as potential income is below some

level increases in income are associated with increases in fertility. As income falls

low enough we must reach a state where there is surplus enough beyond to allow

for 1 and only one child per family (treating families as having one parent).21

Potential income per worker is of the form

tttt HxAy

1

(14)

where x is land per person, and A is related to the efficiency of goods production.

Now human capital is required even in the Malthusian equilibrium. H evolves

according to the time invested in educating each child, h, through a function of the

form

Ht+1 = H(ht, gAt), (15)

21 A feature of these theoretical models is that the preferences specified over goods and children in all of them have no function other than allowing the modellers to get the desired outcome in terms of child numbers and human capital in a constrained maximization setting. They do not better explain the world, or offer further insight or predictions about fertility behavior. They are just ways of reproducing, in a desired mathematical format, observed behavior.

Page 54: The Industrial Revolution in Theory and in History

54

where H increases in gAt. The TFP variable A evolves according to a function of the

form

gAt = g(ht, Nt) (16)

where Nt is the total population size. Efficiency thus grows more rapidly in large

economies with more time resources devoted to each child. And the growth of

efficiency increases the human capital per child and the subsequent output per

person. Galor and Weil, 2000, thus at least tries to preserve some distinction

between human capital and the TFP of the economy. But it is not clear whether

there is any real substance to the formal mathematical separation. There is no way

observationally to distinguish economies which have high output because TFP is

high, or those that have high output because the human capital stock, as opposed to

educational input stock, is large.

The functional form chosen for the utility function is such that the share of time

devoted to raising children is always once families have achieved the subsistence

consumption. Thus there is a built in trade-off between the quality and quantity of

children. Any move to more education must be associated with lower fertility. Thus

the authors build in an inverse U shape to fertility as potential incomes rise – with an

increase caused by the subsistence constraint on the lower end, and then a decline

caused by the rising value of investment on education at higher potential incomes.

Again the utility function here does no real explanatory work. It captures an

observed empirical regularity.

The system is constructed so that the amount of time invested in each child

increases with the expected rate of technological progress, and the rate of

technological progress increases with the time investment per child. At the

Malthusian equilibrium the parents spend the minimum possible amount per child,

and the only determinant of technological progress is the population size N. By the

assumption that gA is positive, even without any educational investments, population

grows in the Malthusian equilibrium, so that the steady state potential income is

maintained by the balance of declining land per person and increasing technological

efficiency.

But as population increases so does the base rate of technological progress,

leading parents eventually to invest more than the minimum time in educating their

Page 55: The Industrial Revolution in Theory and in History

55

children. At moderate population levels this creates a Malthusian regime with still

the minimum consumption per person, but more children each getting some

education and a faster rate of technological progress. Eventually population is

sufficiently large so that education is productive enough that parents choose fewer

high quality children, the population growth rates decline, and potential incomes

begin a continuous increase.

Galor and Weil, 2000 still faces the fundamental problem of the earlier human

capital models, however, in that what drives parents to invest more in education in

the Industrial Revolution era is a rising perceived return to education. This, as we

noted, we do not observe. Nor do we observe any more adverse tradeoff between

quantity and quality as we move from 1500 to 1920.

Galor and Moav, 2002, employs many of the modeling elements of Galor and

Weil, 2000, except that the Kremer driver for the Industrial Revolution,

technological progress being a positive function of population, is replaced. The new

driver is a natural selection, either through genes or cultural transmission, of

individuals of a certain type in the Malthusian era. Individuals of type i are assumed

to choose between consumption, the number of children, and the quality of the

children according to a utility function of the form

))(()( 1

1 ii

t

i

t

i

t

i

t HncV

(16)

Now individuals care not about the potential income of their children, but the

amount of human capital they possess. The weight individuals give the human

capital of their children, indexed by i, thus varies with their type. High families

thus produce children with more human capital and more earnings potential. There

are assumed, for simplicity, to be just two types of individual, high and low . The

potential earnings of each type, yti, are a function of the land labor ratio, x, the level

of technology, A, and human capital, Hti, where

)(1 i

ttt

i

t HxAy

(17)

Now some of the return to education becomes externalized. “Low ” types gain

from the increases in A generated by the investments of the “high ” types. But

Page 56: The Industrial Revolution in Theory and in History

56

the idea is still that once efficiency starts growing more quickly a given amount of

time spent on education produces more human capital. You get more for each year

of education. Again this would seem to imply that the wage premium of skilled

workers would have to rise in the Industrial Revolution era, which as noted above we

do not observe.

Again in the Malthusian era a minimum consumption level, , binds and all gains

in potential income go to child rearing. The “high quality” types choose to endow

their children with more human capital, however, and this means that they have

higher potential incomes in the following period, which results in their descendants

having not only higher quality children, but also more children. Thus the

composition of the population changes in the Malthusian period towards individuals

with the “high quality” values.22 This increase in average education inputs, increases

the private return to education by speeding up the rate of technological advance

inducing both high and low types to invest in more education and fewer

children.

The Galor and Moav, 2000, model does have one potentially useful feature,

which is that the change in the composition of the population can proceed for

generations in a Malthusian state where rates of population growth and levels of

income remain low. It would be potentially consistent with the slow rise of

education levels in Europe in the 300 years preceding the Industrial Revolution.

The Galor and Moav, 2000, model thus fits the positive association of fertility

with wealth and socio-economic status in pre-industrial England detailed above.

However, if we were to elaborate the model to a large number of types we would see

that English demography before 1800 is inconsistent with this model. For in Galor

and Moav, 2000, the positive relation between income and fertility will only be found

at lower levels of income close to the consumption constraint, . Once income gets

high enough in the pre-industrial period we would see a negative connection

between income and fertility, as in the modern era. The highest quality types would

die out in the pre-industrial era along with the lowest quality types. Selection in

22 Interestingly the composition of the population in the post Malthusian period switches back towards the “low quality” types since once potential income for even the low quality types passes a certain boundary they begin to have more children since they spend they invest same time as the high quality families in child rearing but invest less in each child.

Page 57: The Industrial Revolution in Theory and in History

57

Galor and Moav, 2000, is for those whose quality type leads to income just modestly

above the subsistence consumption constraint.

Thus while the empirical evidence is clear that for at least 500 years before the

Industrial Revolution there was differential fertility in England towards those of

higher socio-economic status, there is no evidence that the selection was of the

specific type posited in Galor and Moav, 2000. In particular the evidence is that the

quality-quantity tradeoff that is central to Galor and Moav, 2000, while present, was

relatively weak in all periods in England before 1920.

As with the other endogenous growth models, Galor and Moav, 2000, would

also imply a much slower transition between a world of slow technological advance

and the modern era than is observed in practice in the total factor productivity data

for England.

Page 58: The Industrial Revolution in Theory and in History

58

Technological Change before the Industrial Revolution

We have been following the traditional assumption, so far, represented by

figures 2-3, that the Industrial Revolution was a relatively abrupt transition to

modern productivity growth rates around 1780. As figure 2 illustrates, for England

as a whole the efficiency of the economy showed no expansion 1250-1780. The

measured productivity growth rate before the Industrial Revolution is effectively 0.

This, as discussed above, makes it seem dauntingly difficult to discern reasons for the

transition to rapid economic growth. The underlying institutional, political, and

social variables were changing slowly if at all in England in the years 1700-1870 in

which this transition was accomplished.

The conclusion, from the aggregate productivity level of the economy, that the

transition to modern growth was rapid does, however, seem at variance with the

general historical picture of England 1200-1780 as a society that was over time

advancing in education, in scientific knowledge, in technical abilities in navigation,

warfare, in technical abilities also in music, painting, sculpture, and architecture.

England in 1780 was a very different place from England in 1250, even if the

standard of living of the average consumer measured mainly in terms of their

consumption of food, clothing, housing, heat and lighting changed little.

The reason for this mismatch is that, as noted above in equation 3, national

productivity growth will be related to productivity advance in individual sectors

through

∑ (3)

where is the growth rate of productivity by sector, and is the share of j in total

value added in the economy. National efficiency advance is measured by weighting

gains by sector with the value of output in that sector. The effects of innovation on

national productivity measures is thus crucially dependent on the pattern of

consumption.

Much of the technological advance of the period 1250-1780 had minimal impact

on measured productivity at the national level because the share of expenditure on

these goods was so small in the pre-industrial economy. The printing press, for

example, led to about a 25 fold increase in the productivity of

Page 59: The Industrial Revolution in Theory and in History

59

Figure 21: Efficiency of Production of Nails and Glassware, by Decade, 1250-

1869.

Source: Clark, 2010.

production of written material between 1450 and 1600 in England. But since the

share of income spent on printed materials in 1600 was only about 0.0005, the

productivity gains from this innovation at the national level were miniscule (Clark

and Levin, 2001).

We can see also in figure 21 that the production of such manufactured items as

iron nails and glassware saw significant productivity advances before 1780 also. But

this efficiency advance would be a negligible contribution to national productivity

advance because of the small share of total production value these goods represented

in a pre-industrial England where iron nails had limited use, and glasswares were

enjoyed only by the richest groups in the society.

Further, for many goods whose production was becoming more efficient

through technological advances, no consistent series of prices can be calculated.

There was, for example, a great advance in military technologies in European

countries such as England over the years 1250-1780. The infantry of 1780, or a naval

0

20

40

60

80

100

120

1250 1350 1450 1550 1650 1750 1850

Nails

Glasswares

Page 60: The Industrial Revolution in Theory and in History

60

ship of that period, would have swept from the field the equivalent medieval force.

English troops of 1780 would have quickly overwhelmed the fortifications of 1250,

but the fortifications of 1780 would have been impregnable even against medieval

armies of major size. But none of this would be reflected in conventional

productivity measures. There is no allowance in these measures for the delivery of

more effective violence by the English Navy over the years.

There is no allowance also in the national productivity measure for

improvements in the quality of literature, music, painting, and newspapers. These

sources also do not reflect medical advances such as the one third reduction in

maternal childbirth mortality between 1600 and 1750.23

This makes it possible that the rate of technological advance in the economy,

measured just as a count of innovations and new ideas, was actually increasing long

before the breakthrough of the Industrial Revolution. But accidents of where these

technological advances came in relation to mass consumer demand in the pre-

industrial economy create the appearance of a technological discontinuity circa 1780.

Suppose that prior to the Industrial Revolution innovations were occurring randomly

across various sectors of the economy - innovations in areas such as guns,

gunpowder, spectacles, window glass, books, clocks, painting, new building

techniques, improvements in shipping and navigation – but that just by chance all

these innovations occurred in areas of small expenditure. Then the technological

dynamism of the economy would not show up in terms of output per capita or in

measured productivity in the years leading up to the Industrial Revolution.

To illustrate this, suppose we consider a consumer whose tastes were close to

those of the modern university professor. Their consumption is much more heavily

geared towards printed material, paper, spices, wine, sugar, manufactured goods,

light, soap and clothing than the average consumer in the pre-industrial English

economy. Based on their consumption how would the efficiency growth rate of the

economy 1250-1769 look compared to 1760-1869 and 1860-2009? Figure 22 shows

the results, where efficiency is measured as an index on a log

23 Wrigley et al., 1997, 313.

Page 61: The Industrial Revolution in Theory and in History

61

Figure 22: Economic Efficiency from the Perspective of a Modern Consumer,

England, 1250-2009

Notes: The weights in consumption for the modern consumer are assumed to be

half from the consumption basket of the pre-industrial worker. But the other half is

composed of books (.1), manufactured goods (.1), clothing (.1), sugar (.03), spices

(.03), drink (.05), light (.05), soap (.02), and paper (.02).

Source: Clark, 2010.

scale on the vertical axis. Thus the upwards slope of the line indicates efficiency

growth rates. Now in the years 1300-1770 there is an estimated efficiency growth

rate of 0.09% per year for the goods consumed by a university professor. This is

followed by efficiency growth rates of 0.6% per year 1760-1870, and 0.9% a year for

1860-2010. Estimated efficiency advance is still very slow for the pre-industrial

period, but we can think of the economy in this period as going through a more

protracted transition between pre-industrial growth rates and modern growth rates.

Framed in this way, the possibility reopens of some variety of endogenous

growth explanation of the Industrial Revolution, with a more gradual transition to

higher rates of technological advance starting in the medieval period or earlier.

However, the existing endogenous growth models such as Galor and Weil, 2000, and

Galor and Moav, 2002, bring with them a set of assumptions and implications which

are difficult to reconcile with empirical reality, as was discussed above. The key idea

20

40

80

160

320

1250 1350 1450 1550 1650 1750 1850 1950

Efficiency GDP

Efficiency - ModernConsumer

Page 62: The Industrial Revolution in Theory and in History

62

in Galor and Moav, 2002, however, that in the Malthusian regime preferences might

be changed by differential net fertility, does seem to offer some promise. We do see

strong differences in fertility by social class in England all the way from 1250 to

1780. And there is evidence that parental characteristics in terms of wealth,

occupation and education were very strongly inherited in pre-industrial England,

allowing differential fertility to have significant effects on the characteristics of the

population even after relatively few generations.24 While we do not see sign in the

data of the specific selection for a preference for small family sizes and high child

quality, there is sign of a more generalized selection for characteristics associated

with economic success.

Conclusion

The Industrial Revolution remains one of histories great mysteries. We have

seen in this survey that the attempts by economists to model this transition have

been so far largely unsuccessful. The first approach emphasizing an exogenous

switch in property rights stemming from political changes, despite its continuing

popularity, fails in terms of the timing of political changes, and their observed effects

on the incentives for innovation. The second approach, which looks for a shift

between self-reinforcing equilibria again fails because there is little sign of any major

changes in the underlying parameters of the economy circa 1780 which would lead to

changed behavior by individuals. The most promising class of models are those

based on endogenous growth. The problem here is to find some kind of “driver”

that is changing over time that will induce changes in the rate of innovation.

Previously these models seemed to face insuperable difficulties in that they find it

very hard to model the kind of one time upward shift in productivity growth rates

that the Industrial Revolution seemed to involve. But as we gather more

information on the empirics of the Industrial Revolution, and the years before, the

discontinuity in technological innovation rates seems less than has been imagined,

and the transition between the old world of zero productivity growth rates and the

new world of rapid productivity growth much more gradual. This bodes well for

endogenous growth models.

24 As evidenced by the persistence of status of surnames in England 1300-2012, the correlation of underlying social status between fathers and sons seems always to have been of the order of 0.75, which is very high. See Clark, 2014.

Page 63: The Industrial Revolution in Theory and in History

63

Bibliography

Acemoglu, Daron, Johnson, Simon, and Robinson, James A.. 2005. 'The rise of

Europe: Atlantic trade, institutional change and economic growth', American

Economic Review, 95: 546-79.

Acemoglu, Daron, James A. Robinson and Simon Johnson. 2001. “The Colonial

Origins of Comparative Economic Development: An Empirical Investigation,”

American Economic Review, 91: 1369-1401.

Acemoglu, Daron, James A. Robinson and Simon Johnson. 2002. “Reversal of

Fortune: Geography and Institutions in the Making of the Modern World,”

Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117: 1231-1294.

Acemoglu, Daron and James A. Robinson. 2012. Why Nations Fail: The Origins of

Power, Prosperity, and Poverty.

Angrist, Joshua, Victor Lavy and Analia Schlosser. 2010, “Multiple experiments for

the causal link between the quantity and quality of children.” Journal of Labor

Economics , 28(4) (October): 773-824.

Becker, Gary, Kevin Murphy, and Robert Tamura. 1990. “Human Capital, Fertility

and Economic Growth.” Journal of Political Economy, 98: S12-37.

Boberg-Fazlic, Nina, Paul Sharp, and Jacob Weisdorf. 2011. “Survival of the

Richest? Testing the Clark hypothesis using English pre-industrial data from

family reconstitution records” European Review of Economic History, 15(3): 365-92.

Bresnahan, Timothy F., and Manuel Trajtenberg. 1996. “General purpose

technologies: engines of growth?” Journal of Econometrics, Annals of

Econometrics 65: 83-108.

Clark, Gregory. 1996. “The Political Foundations of Modern Economic Growth:

England, 1540-1800,” Journal of Interdisciplinary History, 26 (Spring).

Clark, Gregory. 2005. “The Condition of the Working-Class in England, 1209-

2004” Journal of Political Economy, 113(6) (December): 1307-1340.

Clark, Gregory and Gillian Hamilton. 2006. “Survival of the Richest. The

Malthusian Mechanism in Pre-Industrial England.” Journal of Economic History,

66(3): 707-36.

Clark, Gregory. 2007. “A Review of Avner Greif’s, Institutions, and the Path to the

Modern Economy.” Journal of Economic Literature, 45 (September): 727-743.

Clark, Gregory. 2007. “Coal and the Industrial Revolution, 1700-1869.” (with

David Jacks) European Review of Economic History, 11(1) (April): 39-72.

Page 64: The Industrial Revolution in Theory and in History

64

Clark, Gregory. 2007. “The Long March of History: Farm Wages, Population and

Economic Growth, England 1209-1869,” Economic History Review, 60(1)

(February): 97-136.

Clark, Gregory. 2007. A Farewell to Alms: A Brief Economic History of the World.

Princeton: Princeton University Press.

Clark, Gregory. 2010. “The Macroeconomic Aggregates for England, 1209-2008.”

Research in Economic History, 27, 51-140.

Clark, Gregory. 2014. The Son Also Rises: 1,000 Years of Social Mobility. Princeton:

Princeton University Press.

Clark, Gregory and Neil Cummins. 2013a. “Malthus to Modernity: England’s First

Fertility Transition, 1500-1880.” Working Paper, UC Davis.

Clark, Gregory and Neil Cummins. 2013b. “The Beckerian Family and the English

Demographic Revolution of 1800.” Working Paper, UC Davis.

Clark, Gregory and Patricia Levin. 2001. “How Different was the Industrial

Revolution? The Revolution in Printing, 1350-1869.” Working Paper,

University of California, Davis.

Crafts, N. F. R. 1985. British Economic Growth During the Industrial Revolution. New

York: Oxford University Press.

Crafts, N.F.R., and C. K. Harley. 1992. "Output Growth and the Industrial

Revolution: A Restatement of the Crafts-Harley View." Economic History Review

45:703-730.

Cressy, David. 1977. “Levels of Illiteracy in England, 1530-1730,” The Historical

Journal, 20: 1-23.

DeLong, Brad J. and Shleifer, Andre. 1993. 'Princes and merchants: European city

growth before the industrial revolution', Journal of Law and Economics, 36: 671-

702.

De Vries, Jan 1994. “The Industrial Revolution and the Industrious Revolution”

Journal of Economic History: 249-70.

Diamond, Jared M. 1997. Guns, germs, and steel : the fates of human societies. New York :

W.W. Norton.

Duncan-Jones, Richard. 1990. Structure and Scale in the Roman Economy. Cambridge:

Cambridge University Press.

Fitton, 1989. ----

Galor, Oded and David N. Weil. 2000. “Population, Technology and Growth:

From Malthusian Stagnation to the Demographic Transition and Beyond.”

American Economic Review 90: 806-828.

Page 65: The Industrial Revolution in Theory and in History

65

Galor, Oded and Omer Moav. 2002. “Natural Selection and the Origin of

Economic Growth.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117: 1133-91.

Galor, Oded. 2011. Unified Growth Theory. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

Greif, Avner. 2006. Institutions and the path to the modern economy: lessons from medieval

trade. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Greif, Avner, Murat Iyigun, and Diego L. Sasson. 2012. Social Institutions and Economic

Growth: Why England and Not China Became the First Modern Economy. Working

Paper.

Hansen, G. and Prescott, Edward C. 2002. “Malthus to Solow.” American Economic

Review, 92(4): 1205-17.

Harley, Knick. 1998. “Cotton Textile Prices and the Industrial Revolution,”

Economic History Review, 51(1): 49-83.

Harley, C. Knick. 2010. “Prices and Profits in Cotton Textiles during the Industrial

Revolution.” University of Oxford Discussion Papers in Economic History,

#81.

Hopkins, Keith. 1966. “On the Probable Age Structure of the Roman Population,”

Population Studies, 20(2): 245-264.

Houston, R. A. 1982. “The Development of Literacy: Northern England, 1640-

1750.” Economic History Review, New Series, 35 (2) (May), 199-216.

Jones, Charles I. 1995. “R&D-Based Models of Economic Growth.” Journal of

Political Economy 103 (August): 759-84.

Jones, Charles I. 2001. “Was the Industrial Revolution Inevitable? Economic

Growth over the Very Long Run.” Advances in Macroeconomics, 1.

http://www.bepress.com/bejm/advances/

Jones, Charles I. 2002. Introduction to Economic Growth. 2nd Edition. New York: W. W.

Norton.

Kremer, Michael. 1993. “Population Growth and Technological Change: One

Million B. C. to 1990.”Quarterly Journal of Economics, 107: 681-716.

Lagerlöf, Nils-Petter. 2006. “The Galor–Weil model revisited: A quantitative

exercise.” Review of Economic Dynamics, 9(1): 116-142.

Li, Hongbin, Junsen Zhang, and Yi Zhu. 2008. “The Quantity-Quality Trade-off of

Children in a Developing Country: Identification Using Chinese Twins.”

Demography, 45(1): 223-243.

Lindberg, Erik. 2009. “Club Goods and Inefficient Institutions: Why Danzig and

Lübeck Failed in the Early Modern Period.” Economic History Review, New

Series, 62(3) (Aug.): 604-628.

Page 66: The Industrial Revolution in Theory and in History

66

Long, Pamela. 1991. “Invention, Authorship, ‘Intellectual Property,’ and the Origin

of Patents: Notes Towards a Conceptual History.” Technology and Culture, 32:

846-884.

Lucas, Robert. 1988. "On the Mechanics of Economic Development," Journal of

Monetary Economics, 22: 3-42.

Lucas, Robert E. 2002. “The Industrial Revolution: Past and Future.” In Robert E.

Lucas, Lectures on Economic Growth. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

Mitchell, Brian R. and Deane, Phyllis. 1971. Abstract of British Historical Statistics.

Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Michell, Brian R. 1988. British Historical Statistics. Cambridge University Press,

Cambridge.

Mokyr, Joel. 1999, "Introduction" in Joel Mokyr (ed.), The Industrial Revolution: An

Economic Analysis. Boulder: Westview Press.

Mokyr, Joel. 2003. “Long-term Economic Growth and the History of Technology,”

in Philippe Aghion and Steven Durlauf, Handbook of Economic Growth.

North, Douglass C. 1981. Structure and Change in Economic History. New York:

Norton.

North, Douglass C. 1994. “Economic Performance Through Time.” American

Economic Review, 84(3): 359-368.

North, Douglass and Robert P. Thomas. 1973. The Rise of the Western World.

Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

North, Douglass and Barry Weingast. 1989. "Constitutions and Commitment:

Evolution of Institutions Governing Public Choice in Seventeenth Century

England," Journal of Economic History 49, pp. 803-832.

Romer, Paul M. 1986. “Increasing Returns and Long-Run Growth.” Journal of

Political Economy, 94: 1002-1037.

Romer, Paul M. 1987. “Crazy Explanations for the Productivity Slowdown.” In

NBER Macroeconomics Annual 1987, ed. Stanley Fischer. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT

Press.

Romer, Paul M. 1990. “Endogenous Technological Change.” Journal of Political

Economy, 98: S71-102.

Rosenzweig, Mark R. and Kenneth I Wolpin. 1980. “Testing the Quantity-Quality

Fertility Model: The Use of Twins as a Natural Experiment.” Econometrica, 48(1):

227-240.

Rubinstein, William D. 1981. Men of Property: The Very Wealthy in Britain Since the

Industrial Revolution. London: Croom Helm.

Page 67: The Industrial Revolution in Theory and in History

67

Schofield, Roger. 1973. “Dimensions of Illiteracy, 1750-1850,” Explorations in

Economic History, 10: 437-454.

Schultz, T. Paul. 2007. “Population Policies, Fertility, Women's Human Capital, and

Child Quality," Economic Growth Center Yale University, Discussion Paper

No. 954.

Solow, Robert M. 1956. “A Contribution to the Theory of Economic Growth.”

Quarterly Journal of Economics, 70: 65-94.

Wrigley, E. A., R. S. Davies, J. E. Oeppen, and R. S. Schofield. 1997. English

Population History from Family Reconstruction: 1580-1837. Cambridge; New York:

Cambridge University Press.