the economics of the new europe: from community to union

334

Upload: nigel-healey

Post on 08-Dec-2016

220 views

Category:

Documents


4 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union
Page 2: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

THE ECONOMICS OF THE NEW EUROPE

The European Union is in the process of a great transition. Theprogramme to complete the internal market ended on December 31, 1992,abolishing many of the remaining non-tariff barriers to the free movementof goods, services, labour and capital. The Maastricht Treaty, signed inDecember 1991, committed the EU to the introduction of a singlecurrency by no later than 1999. Outside the EU, the collapse ofcommunism has added many of the nations of East and Central Europe tothe queue of EFTA nations applying for EU membership.

Yet the road to closer economic and monetary integration inEurope is difficult and controversial and many issues remainunresolved. The partial breakdown of the EMS followingspeculative attacks on weaker currencies, has thrown the timetablefor monetary union into disarray. The onset of deep recessionacross Europe has reignited nationalist and ethnic tensionsparticularly in eastern Europe, casting doubts on hopes of unified‘family of Europe’.

This book takes a fresh look at the economics of the new Europe.Based on articles by some of the UK’s leading economiccommentators which were originally published in Economics andBusiness Education (here extensively revised and updated), it remainsaccessible and lively throughout. Chapter 1 looks at the theory andpractice of economic and monetary integration in Europe, giving anoverview of the history of the process and providing a lens throughwhich to view the other chapters. Chapters 2 to 6 examine macroissues especially those relating to EMS and EMU, while chapters 7 to14 examine a whole range of micro and social issues, including theSocial Charter, the Common Agricultural Policy and the prospects forfuture enlargement. The book is supplemented by a useful statisticalappendix describing the EU in figures from 1964 to 1994.

Nigel M.Healey is Jean Monnet Professor of European EconomicStudies at the University of Leicester and Visiting Lecturer at theUniversity of Gdansk and Kent State University, Ohio.

Page 3: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union
Page 4: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

THE ECONOMICS OFTHE NEW EUROPE

From Community to Union

Edited by Nigel M.Healey

London and New York

Page 5: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

First published 1995by Routledge

11 New Fetter Lane, London EC4P 4EE

This edition published in the Taylor & Francis e-Library, 2003.

Simultaneously published in the USA and Canadaby Routledge

29 West 35th Street, New York NY 10001

© 1995 Nigel M.Healey for the Economics and BusinessEducation Association

All rights reserved. No part of this book may be reprinted orreproduced or utilised in any form or by any electronic,

mechanical, or other means, now known or hereafterinvented, including photocopying and recording, or in anyinformation storage or retrieval system, without permission

in writing from the publishers.

British Library Cataloguing in Publication DataA catalogue record for this book is available from the British

Library

Library of Congress Cataloging in Publication DataThe economics of the new europe: from community to

union/edited by Nigel M.Healey.p. cm.

Includes bibliographical references and index.ISBN 0-415-10874-8 (hbk.)ISBN 0-415-10875-6 (pbk.)

1. European Economic Community. 2. EuropeanMonetary System (Organization) 3. European Union

countries—Economic policy.I. Healey, Nige.

HC241.2.C457 1995337.1´42–dc20 94–39620

ISBN 0-203-42730-0 Master e-book ISBN

ISBN 0-203-73554-4 (Adobe eReader Format)

Page 6: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

For Daniel, Jemma andNicola

Page 7: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union
Page 8: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

vii

CONTENTS

List of Figures and Tables ixList of Contributors xiiPreface xv

1 FROM THE TREATY OF ROME TOMAASTRICHT: THE THEORY AND PRACTICEOF EUROPEAN INTEGRATIONNigel M.Healey 1

Part I Macroeconomic perspectives

2 THE EUROPEAN MONETARY SYSTEMMichael Artis and Nigel M.Healey 45

3 FIXED EXCHANGE RATES AND DEFLATION:THE EUROPEAN MONETARY SYSTEM ANDTHE GOLD STANDARDJonathan Michie and Michael Kitson 68

4 WHITHER EUROPEAN MONETARY UNION?George Zis 83

5 EUROPEAN MONETARY UNION: PROGRESS,PROBLEMS AND PROSPECTSBarry Harrison and Nigel M.Healey 103

6 WHAT PRICE EUROPEAN MONETARY UNION?Patrick Minford 124

Page 9: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

CONTENTS

viii

Part II Microeconomic issues

7 COMPLETING THE INTERNAL MARKET INTHE EUROPEAN UNIONFrank McDonald 139

8 AFTER 1992: THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OFTHE SINGLE EUROPEAN ACTDavid Whynes 157

9 THE ECONOMIC IMPLICATIONS OFENLARGING THE EUROPEAN UNIONValerio Lintner 170

10 THE ECONOMICS OF SOCIAL RESPONSIBILITYIN THE EUROPEAN UNIONPeter Curwen 188

11 THE COMMON AGRICULTURAL POLICY:ITS OPERATION AND REFORMRobert Ackrill 206

12 JAPANESE FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT:THE IMPACT ON THE EUROPEAN UNIONGeorge Norman 223

13 COMPETITION POLICY IN THE EUROPEANUNIONEleanor J.Morgan 238

14 THE REGIONAL POLICY OF THE EUROPEANUNIONHarvey Armstrong 255

STATISTICAL APPENDIX: Data series on the EU,1964–94 277

Bibliography 292Index 303

Page 10: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

ix

FIGURES AND TABLES

FIGURES

1.1 Regional trade blocs within the broader frameworkof global integration 8

1.2 The welfare effects of protection 231.3 Effective supply (a) pre-customs and

(b) post-customs union 261.4 (a) Pure trade creation and (b) pure trade diversion

in a customs union 281.5 Trade creation versus trade diversion in a customs

union 311.6 Economies of scale in a customs union 351.7 The experience curve 371.8 Average costs and the experience curve effect 381.9 The benefits of increased competition and reduced

X-inefficiency 392.1 The forex market for sterling/deutschmarks 462.2 Real effective sterling exchange rate 653.1 World employment and unemployment, 1929–38 743.2 Number of countries on gold, 1919–37 765.1 Government policy preferences and the

Phillips Curve 1105.2 Central bank independence and the Phillips Curve 1126.1 Commission estimates 1306.2 Masson and Symansky (1992) estimates with

Multimod 1316.3 Minford et al. (1992) estimates on Liverpool model 1327.1 The welfare effects of protection revisited 140

Page 11: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

FIGURES AND TABLES

x

7.2 The welfare effects of subsidies to domesticproducers 142

7.3 A schematic logistics chain 1447.4 Economies of scale under pessimistic and optimistic

assumptions 15111.1 The price regime of the CAP 21012.1 Outflows of foreign direct investment, 1985–89 22512.2 Intra-Triad foreign direct investment, 1988 22612.3 Japanese foreign direct investment by industry

(stock as of March 1990) 22712.4 Sales of Japanese affiliates in manufacturing, 1987 22812.5 Japanese manufacturing enterprises in Europe 23012.6 Motivation for production in Europe 23312.7 Local content of parts and material 23412.8 Reasons for dissatisfaction with local suppliers 23514.1 GDP per capita in EU regions 25814.2 Regions eligible under Objective 1 of the EU’s

structural funds, 1994–99 26414.3 Regions eligible for the structural funds, 1994–99 266

TABLES

1.1 The dimensions of economic integration 51.2 Population and relative living standards in the EU 101.3 Degree of openness in EU member states 111.4 Population and income in the ‘Triad’ 111.5 Key developments in the history of the EU 131.6 The EU budget, 1993 181.7 Weighted votes in the Council of Ministers, 1994 191.8 European parliamentary seats by political grouping,

June 1994 211.9 National representation in the European Parliament 211.10 Production costs and market prices in the home

country before and after membership of a customsunion 29

2.1 Daily turnover in the major financial centres, 1992 482.2 The composition of the ECU (since 1989) 522.3 Central rates against the ECU 542.4 Exchange rate variability against ERM currencies 575.1 Measures of political independence 1145.2 Measures of economic independence 115

Page 12: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

FIGURES AND TABLES

xi

5.3 Seigniorage revenue as a percentage of national grossdomestic product 115

5.4 Measures of political independence 1175.5 Measures of economic independence 1175.6 Convergence criteria and out-turns in 1994 1195.7 Comparative inflation records, 1979–94 1217.1 Proposals presented to the Council of Ministers,

1992 1467.2 VAT rates in the EU, pre-1992 1497.3 The main results of the Cecchini Report 1509.1 Applicants and potential applicants for EU

membership 1829.2 Population of eastern Europe, 1992 185

10.1 Fundamental social rights: summary of thecontents of the Social Charter 191

12.1 Growth of foreign direct investment, exports andgross domestic product, 1973–89 223

12.2 Investment plans for the EU (number of projects) 23013.1 Individual formal Commission decisions under

Articles 85 and 86 published in the OfficialJournal, by sector 241

13.2 Decisions on cases notified under EC mergerregulation, September 20, 1990 to September 19,1993 245

14.1 The five priority objectives of the EU’s structuralfunds, 1994–99 263

14.2 EU commitments for structural fund operations,1989–99 268

14.3 The Community Programmes (CPs) adopted by theEU, 1989–93 271

A1 Unemployment rates, 1964–94 278A2 Gross domestic product, 1964–94 280A3 Per capita gross domestic product, 1964–94 282A4 Economic growth, 1964–94 284A5 Gross domestic fixed capital formation, 1964–94 286A6 Retail price inflation, 1964–94 288A7 Current account, 1964–94 290

Page 13: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

xii

LIST OF CONTRIBUTORS

Robert Ackrill Economics Teaching Fellow, Department ofEconomics, University of Nottingham, Nottingham.

Harvey W.Armstrong Senior Lecturer in Economics, Departmentof Economics, The Management School, University of Lancaster,Lancaster.

Michael Artis Professor, Department of Economics, EuropeanUniversity Institute, Badia Fiesolana, Via dei Roccettini 9, 1–50016San Domenico di Fiesole (Fl), Florence, Italy.

Peter Curwen Reader in Economics, Sheffield Business School,Pond Street, Sheffield.

Barry Harrison Senior Lecturer in Economics, Department ofEconomics and Public Administration, The Nottingham TrentUniversity, Burton Street, Nottingham.

Nigel M.Healey Jean Monnet Chair of European EconomicStudies, Department of Economics, University of Leicester,Leicester.

Michael Kitson Fellow, St Catherine’s College and Lecturer inEconomics, Newnham College, The Judge Institute ofManagement Studies, University of Cambridge, Fitzwilliam House,32 Trumpington Street, Cambridge.

Valerio Lintner Principal Lecturer in Economics, Department ofEconomics, Guildhall University, 84 Moorgate, London.

Page 14: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

LIST OF CONTRIBUTORS

xiii

Frank McDonald Senior Lecturer in Economics, InternationalBusiness Unit, The Manchester Metropolitan University, CavendishStreet, Manchester.

Jonathan Michie Fellow and Director of Studies in Economics,Robinson College, The Judge Institute of Management Studies,University of Cambridge, Fitzwilliam House, 32 TrumpingtonStreet, Cambridge.

Patrick Minford Edward Conner Professor of AppliedEconomics, Department of Economic and Business Studies,University of Liverpool, PO Box 147, Liverpool.

Eleanor J.Morgan Senior Lecturer in Industrial Economics,School of Management, University of Bath, Claverton Down,Bath.

George Norman Professor of Economics and Head ofDepartment, Department of Economics, University of Edinburgh,William Robertson Building, 50 George Square, Edinburgh.

David K.Whynes Reader in Health Economics, Department ofEconomics, University of Nottingham, University Park,Nottingham.

George Zis Professor of Economics, Department of Economics,The Manchester Metropolitan University, Cavendish Street,Manchester.

Page 15: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union
Page 16: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

xv

PREFACENigel M.Healey

The European Union (EU) is in a process of rapid transition. The‘1992’ programme to ‘complete the internal market’ ended onDecember 31, 1992, abolishing many of the remaining non-tariffbarriers to the free movement of goods, services, labour andcapital. The apparent success of the European Monetary System(EMS) during the 1980s inspired the Maastricht Treaty, signed inDecember 1991, which pledges the EU member states to theintroduction of a single currency by no later than 1999. Outside theEU, the collapse of communism added the former Warsaw Pactnations of eastern Europe to the queue of EFTA nations applyingfor EU membership.

Yet the road to closer economic and monetary integration inEurope is still difficult and controversial. A number of themeasures embodied in the 1992 programme remain unresolved.Before the ink on the Maastricht Treaty was dry, the EMS had beenbuffeted by damaging foreign exchange market volatility, whichdrove two of the main EU currencies—the pound sterling and theIrish punt—out of the system and forced the survivors to adoptultra-wide ±15% target bands, setting back the drive for a singlecurrency. And a combination of deep recession and the breakdownof communism in the east during the early 1990s reignitednationalist and ethnic tensions, casting doubt of hopes of a unified‘family of Europe’.

This book, based on articles originally published in Economics andBusiness Education (formerly Economics), the quarterly journal of thenational Economics and Business Education Association, takes anup-to-date look at the economics of the new Europe. Chapter 1provides an overview of the theory and practice of economic andmonetary integration in Europe, providing both a ‘lens’ through

Page 17: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

PREFACE

xvi

which to view the following chapters and documenting the mainsteps along the road to closer European integration. Chapters 2–14,which are written by some of the leading British academiccommentators on Europe, explore the changing economic landscapein the EU, reviewing the arguments surrounding monetary union,examining the reasons for the breakdown of the EMS, speculatingon the implications of the ‘single market’ and discussing theoperation of regional, social and competition policy in the EU.

All the articles have been thoroughly revised and updated to takeaccount of developments since they first appeared. Thanks are dueto all the authors, who skilfully blended new information with theiroriginal manuscripts, while tolerating my unhelpful suggestions andeditorial changes. For any remaining errors of commission oromission in the revised chapters, I alone am responsible. I wouldlike to thank Emma Dickinson for her invaluable assistance inpreparing the final manuscript. Finally, I would like to thank mycolleagues and friends at the University of Leicester for theirsupport and the members and officers of the Economics andBusiness Education Association, (especially the general editor ofEconomics and Business Education, Peter Maunder), without whom thisbook would not have been possible.

Page 18: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

1

1

FROM THE TREATY OF ROMETO MAASTRICHT

The Theory and Practice of EuropeanIntegration

Nigel M.Healey

INTRODUCTION

The year 1990 is widely regarded as a high water mark in thehistory of postwar European integration. During the second half ofthe 1980s, a combination of special factors coincided to produce aheady, almost euphoric, mood in the ‘old world’. The dream of a‘United States of Europe’—a seamless market stretching fromDublin to Bucharest—seemed at last within grasp. The pace ofeconomic integration received its first real boost for a quarter of acentury in 1985, with the launch of the single European market(SEM)—or ‘1992’—programme by the member states of theEuropean Union (EU). Despite two difficult enlargements duringthe 1980s which brought in the less developed Mediterranean statesof Greece (1981) and Spain and Portugal (1986), the SEMremained well on course during the late 1980s. This success, takentogether with the demonstrable achievements of the exchange ratemechanism (ERM) in promoting exchange rate and price stability,inspired the EU to go further and plan for the introduction of asingle currency. In 1989, the Delors Committee published itsblueprint for full economic and monetary union (EMU) in Europe,a plan which was formally adopted with the signing of the Treatyon European Union in 1991 (see Council of Ministers, 1992).

The other states of western Europe, which had previouslybelonged to a parallel trade grouping known as the European FreeTrade Association (EFTA), reacted to the acceleration of the paceof integration within the EU by seeking closer ties with the

Page 19: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

NIGEL M.HEALEY

2

‘Twelve’ (Haaland, 1990; Church, 1991). Although initially confinedto a bilateral agreement between EFTA and the EU to jointlyadhere to the main provisions of the SEM programme—creatingthe European Economic Area (EEA), which came into effect in1994—almost all the EFTA members had declared their intentionto apply for full membership of the EU long before negotiationsover the EEA had been concluded.

More dramatically, the late 1980s witnessed the collapse ofcommunism in eastern Europe. During 1989–90, a ‘domino effect’rippled through the region as, one by one, the former Sovietsatellites rejected central planning and elected democraticgovernments for the first time in 40 years. The rush to embracefree market capitalism peaked in 1990, with the reunification ofGermany symbolising the final end of the ‘iron curtain’ that haddivided east and west Europe. The stage seemed set for the rapid‘marketisation’ of eastern Europe, with almost all the states in theregion negotiating association agreements with the EU with a viewto eventual full membership.

As the new decade progressed, however, the optimism of thelate 1980s gradually evaporated. The onset of a deep recession inmost of the EU states reignited nationalist and protectionistsentiments. The Treaty on European Union (more commonlyknown as the ‘Maastricht Treaty’) was ratified by member statesonly after protracted political wrangling, including an initial ‘no’vote in the Danish popular referendum. The resulting uncertaintiessurrounding the commitment of the member states to EMUcontributed to a series of damaging speculative attacks on theERM. The pound and the lira were forced to withdraw from thesystem in autumn 1992 and, after repeated devaluations by theweaker currencies, ultra-wide ±15% target bands were introduced inAugust 1993.

The enthusiasm of certain EFTA members for full EUmembership began to weaken, with Switzerland abandoning itsapplication and popular hostility to the EU mounting in the Nordicstates, notably Norway which ultimately rejected membership in1994. In eastern Europe, the transition to a market economy provedmuch more painful than expected, with the region experiencing acala-mitous collapse in living standards (see Healey, 1994). Withoutthe social control formerly exercised by the communist system,growing poverty, unemployment and social unrest fuelled ethnic andnationalist tensions. The result was widespread inter-communal

Page 20: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

FROM THE TREATY OF ROME TO MAASTRICHT

3

violence and, in extr emis, civil war, most horrifically in theformerYugoslavia. By the mid-1990s, there was a general feelingthat the ‘grand design’ of an integrated pan-European economy hadbeen derailed.

Yet just as the euphoria of the late 1980s was unrealistic, failingto take account of the economic and political difficulties that layahead, so the current prevailing mood of ‘Euro-pessimism’underestimates the significance of the changes that have alreadytaken place and the momentum that is continuing to take theprocess forward. European economic integration has never been alinear, incremental process; rather it has been characterised byperiods of very rapid advance, followed by episodes of stagnationand backsliding. In the 1970s, for example, little progress was madein a decade plagued by recession and divergent national economicpolicies. During the long boom of the 1980s, in contrast, whenmember states enjoyed steady growth and shared a commoncommitment to fighting inflation, the EU successfully managed twoenlargements, completed the internal market and redrafted itsconstitution in preparation for full monetary union.

The mid-1990s now sees the EU in a state of flux. Thelegislative and constitutional changes wrought in the 1980s are onlynow starting to have significant effects and these will continue tobuild up well into the next century. The 1992 programme, inparticular, has set in train a wholesale restructuring of Europeanindustry, unleashing a wave of mergers and acquisitions andprompting savage labour-shedding as companies brace themselvesfor intensified competition. Reforms in the area of social, regionaland competition policy promise to reshape the economicenvironment in the EU, while changes in the Common AgriculturalPolicy (CAP) have already had a major impact on the farm sector.In other areas, notably monetary and exchange rate policy, theoutlook is altogether more uncertain, following the currencyinstability of the early 1990s. However, even in this sphere, there isa strong political momentum behind monetary unification which hassurvived the travails of the ERM.

This book is about the changes taking place in the EUeconomy. Part I focuses on macroeconomic issues, specifically thecoordination of exchange rate and monetary policy and theoutlook for macroeconomic policy coordination. Part IIconcentrates on a range of microeconomic issues, examining theimplications of further EU enlargements and the reforms that are

Page 21: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

NIGEL M.HEALEY

4

taking place in the area of social, regional, competition andindustrial policy, as well as a comprehensive discussion of the1992 programme and its likely effects in the years ahead. Thepurpose of the present chapter is to provide an overview ofdevelopments within the EU and thereby provide a context inwhich to view the other chapters that make up the book. It openswith a discussion of the basic principles underpinning economicintegration. It then briefly reviews the present state of the EU,documenting the main historical events since the EU wasestablished in 1958 and outlining the institutional frameworkwithin which policy is made. Finally, it offers an introduction tothe theory of economic integration.

WHAT IS ECONOMIC INTEGRATION?

The term, ‘economic integration’, refers to the merging together ofnational economies and the blurring of the boundaries that separateeconomic activity in one nation state from another—see El-Agraa(1994) or McDonald and Dearden (1992) for a more detaileddiscussion. Over the postwar period, the world’s economies havebecome increasingly open and mutually interdependent. Whetherthey live in Moscow, London or Tokyo, today’s teenagers drinkCoca-Cola, eat McDonald’s hamburgers, wear Levi jeans and listento the same music on MTV; giant corporations like Ford, Toyotaand IBM manufacture and market their products in almost everymajor economy. The relentless search for new markets and newproduction locations has led to the so-called ‘globalisation ofbusiness’, as companies restructure their activities across frontiers,weaving national economies ever closer together in the process(Dunning, 1988; Healey, 1991c).

This increasing integration of the world’s economies hasundoubtedly been accelerated by such ‘enabling’ technologicaladvances as cheap air travel, computers, telephones, faxes andsatellite television, but it has ultimately stemmed from the deliberatetrade policies of the main capitalist states. The trade rulesnegotiated during successive rounds of the General Agreement onTariffs and Trade (GATT), most recently during the ‘UruguayRound’ which ended in 1993, together with the trade liberalisationpolices orchestrated by the International Monetary Fund (IMF) andthe International Bank for Reconstruction and Development (IBRDor ‘World Bank’), have succeeded in eliminating many of the

Page 22: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

FROM THE TREATY OF ROME TO MAASTRICHT

5

artificial barriers to trade and cross-border investment whichplagued the prewar era.

The postwar period has been characterised not just by the steadyliberalisation of trade and the globalisation of business, but by theformation of regional trade blocs designed to deepen and wideneconomic integration between participating member states. Somehave simply attempted to free trade in certain designatedcommodities (e.g., the North American Free Trade Agreement);others have sought to integrate their economies so absolutely thatthey share a common currency and pool political decision-makingacross a range of areas (e.g., the monetary union between Belgiumand Luxembourg). The EU is, of course, the best known of theseregional blocs. It currently offers its member states freedom ofmovement of goods, services, labour and capital and holds out thepromise of a common currency by the end of the decade. Thefollowing sub-sections set out the different forms that regionalintegration may take (see Table 1.1 for a summary).

The free trade area

The ‘free trade area’ is the weakest form of economic integration.It involves the removal of tariffs and quotas (quantitativerestrictions) on trade between member states. The North AmericanFree Trade Agreement (NAFTA) between the United States, Canadaand Mexico, formed between 1988 and 1994, and the Associationof South East Asian Nations (ASEAN), set up between Indonesia,Brunei, Malaysia, Philippines, Singapore and Thailand in 1967,

Table 1.1 The dimensions of economic integration

Page 23: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

NIGEL M.HEALEY

6

arecontemporary examples of free trade areas. Free trade may belimited to certain sectors, as in the case of EFTA (see above),which initially abolished tariffs and quotas on industrial goods only.

The customs union

One step up from a free trade area is a ‘customs union’. Itembraces all the provisions of a free trade area—namely, theabolition of restrictions on trade between members—but alsoobliges member states to pursue a common trade policy in theirdealings with the rest of the world (e.g., by adopting a commonexternal tariff). This additional dimension avoids the problem of‘trade deflection’, which occurs when goods from the outsideworld are ‘deflected’ to whichever country in a free trade areaimposes the lowest tariff on imports, before being reshipped(tariff-free) to their ultimate destination elsewhere in the samefree trade area.

Trade deflection distorts trade f lows and robs high-tariffmember states of potential tax revenue on goods arriving fromthird countries. The disadvantage of coordinating external tradepolicy to prevent trade deflection—which is the only alternative tocomplicated ‘rules of origin’ designed to prevent low-tariffcountries re-exporting imported goods to other members tariff-free—is that countries with complex, highly-selective tradingarrangements with the outside world (like Britain in the 1950s andthe United States today) are forced to conform to a commoncommercial policy. It is largely for this reason that countries withwider geopolitical interests have typically resisted membership of acustoms union.

The common market

A common market encompasses the trade-related provisions of acustoms union, together with measures to promote the freemovement of factors of production (i.e., labour and capital).Creating a common market in goods, services, labour and capital is,however, a bigger jump up from a common market than simplyextending the principles of free trade to cover labour and capital. Acustoms union (like a free trade area) ensures the free movementof goods and services only in the limited sense that its membersabolish explicit, trade-related restrictions on imports from other

Page 24: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

FROM THE TREATY OF ROME TO MAASTRICHT

7

membersof the union. In contrast, a common market impliescreating a single, borderless market for products and factors ofproduction (see Nevin, 1990; Healey, 1992b; Vickerman, 1992).

Attaining the goal of a common market requires not just theabolition of explicit controls on trade, immigration and capitalmovements, but also the harmonisation of government policies inareas like taxation and social security, public procurement andindustrial and regional policy to prevent the hidden barriers thatwould otherwise continue to segment national markets. For example,if governments subsidise domestic steel producers, then allowing inimports from other member states tariff-free is not sufficient tocreate a common market in steel (see Chapter 13). Instead of a‘level playing field’, on which all producers compete openly forbusiness, preferential government policies and inconsistent technicalstandards would make the pitch so uneven that competition wouldcontinue to be stifled.

Economic and monetary union

Economic and monetary union (EMU) is the strongest form ofeconomic integration. Economic union involves making economicpolicy centrally, rather than seeking to harmonise or coordinatepolicy as in a common market. The distinction between a commonmarket and an economic union is blurred and essentially one ofdegree, rather than of kind. The second dimension, namely amonetary union, entails the extension of central policymaking tomonetary policy, as well as other areas of economic policy (seeChapters 4–6). To the extent that the fear of exchange ratefluctuations and the transactions costs of switching betweennational currencies are major factors preventing the cross-bordermovements of goods, services, labour and capital, it could beargued that monetary union—the move to a single currency issuedby a single central bank—is a necessary condition for theattainment of a common market (see Emerson and Huhne, 1991;Artis, 1989). Nevertheless, it is conventional to view the pooling ofpolitical sovereignty necessary to achieve economic and monetaryunion as sufficiently wholesale to make it qualitatively differentfrom the negotiated harmonisation and coordination of policywhich characterises a common market.

It is important to recognise that these various stages ofeconomic integration may be viewed either as a process or as

Page 25: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

NIGEL M.HEALEY

8

alternative end-points. To paraphrase the comment of a member ofthe 1985 House of Lords Committee studying Europeanintegration,

just as Dover is a step on the road to Paris, so a customsunion is a step on the road to economic and monetary union.But having reached Dover, there is no reason why one cannotchoose to stay there and never go to Paris at all. By the sametoken, one can also decide to stick with a customs union andgo no further.

There are many examples of free trade areas (e.g., NAFTA,ASEAN) and customs unions (e.g., the former customs unionbetween Uganda, Kenya and Tanzania) which their members neverintended should evolve further. The history of the EU, however,has been characterised by a collective desire for ‘an ever closerunion’, so that there is a strong tendency amongst the memberstates to view economic integration as an irreversible process whichmust continue until the ultimate goal of economic and monetaryunion is achieved (see Chapter 9; Brittan, 1991).

It is useful to conceptualise regional trade blocs as ‘zones ofdifferential integration’ (or ‘concentric circles’, as current EU jargonputs it) within the broader framework of global integra tion, which

Figure 1.1 Regional trade blocs within the broader framework of globalintegration

Page 26: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

FROM THE TREATY OF ROME TO MAASTRICHT

9

may overlap to a greater or lesser extent (see Figure 1.1). Thefigure shows the EU as one trade bloc within the GATTframework, enjoying a special relationship with EFTA (i.e., theoverlapping EEA), paralleled by other blocs like NAFTA andembracing a sub-set of member states which may proceed to anexclusive EMU. This approach highlights the fact that economicintegration can take place at different rates between differentgroupings and sub-groupings of countries. Within many EUmembers, there is undoubtedly a vision of a ‘two-speed’ Europe—in which a core of states integrates rapidly, while a second tier ofmore peripheral states integrates more slowly, signing up to certainmeasures later and phasing them in over longer time periods.

In fact, the existence of the EU has never prevented subsets ofits membership accelerating their integration via separate bilateralagreements: for example, the Netherlands and Germany agreed tomaintain their ±2.25% exchange rate bands after the EuropeanMonetary System moved to ±15% bands in 1993, while nine of thestates of the EU have now signed the 1990 Schengen Agreement(eliminating border controls on individuals) outside the frameworkof the 1992 programme—only Britain, Ireland and Denmark havenot yet signed. Moreover, the EU has increasingly recognised thelimitations of forcing all member states to integrate at the samepace, allowing so-called ‘opt-out’ clauses to be written into treaties(e.g., Britain’s opt-out from the social chapter of the MaastrichtTreaty—see Chapter 10), giving rise to the union’s ‘variablegeometry’ (i.e., a union in which different sub-groups of membersare integrated to different degrees in different areas).

AN OVERVIEW OF THE EUROPEAN UNION

Table 1.2 provides a brief overview of the twelve member statesthat presently comprise the EU. It shows that there exist sharpdifferences both between the relative size of the member states,as measured by their populations, and levels of economicprosperity, as measured by per capita gross domestic product(GDP). In population terms, the EU is dominated by the ‘bigfive’—France, Germany, Italy, Britain and Spain—which togetheraccount for approximately 85% of the total population of theEU. In terms of relative living standards, there is an enormousgulf between the rich, northern European states and the poor,southern Mediterranean states. Per capita income in countries

Page 27: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

NIGEL M.HEALEY

10

like Denmark and Germany is roughly three times higher than inGreece and Portugal. These imbalances raise important questionsfor the conduct of EU regional policy, while also impacting onsocial, competition and agricultural policymaking (see Chapters7– 14).

Table 1.3 shows the degree of ‘openness’ (i.e., the proportionof GDP which is internationally traded) of the EU memberstates. Unsurprisingly, openness varies inversely with size—largercountries tend to be relatively more self-sufficient than smallercountries. Luxembourg, for example, trades 91.4% of its GDP, incontrast to Germany where trade accounts for only 24.5% ofGDP. The table shows that, with the exception of Denmark, themember states of the EU have become increasingly open over thelast 35 years. When attention is focused on intra-EU trade (i.e.,trade with other member states) rather than total trade, thispattern is even more marked. Again, with the exception ofDenmark, trade with other EU partners has increased as apercentage of GDP for all member states, in most cases byproportionately more than total trade. In France, for example,total trade has roughly doubled its share of GDP from 12.4% to20.4%, while intra-EU trade has increased almost three-fold from3.6% to 9.7% of GDP. In other words, EU membership has had

Table 1.2 Population and relative living standards in the EU

Source: European Economy.

Page 28: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

FROM THE TREATY OF ROME TO MAASTRICHT

11

the effect of accelerating the opening up of member economiesby promoting trade between member states.

Table 1.4 provides a guide to the relative size of the EU, ascompared to the other two major economic powers. It shows thatin population terms, the EU dwarfs both the United States andJapan with a total population (since German reunification) of 350m.In terms of total GDP, however, the EU is broadly on a par withthe United States, reflecting the rather lower per capita income levelin the former. Indeed, on this basis, the EU is the poorest of theworld’s three major trading powers (the so-called ‘Triad’), with percapita GDP approximately half that of Japan.

Table 1.3 Degree of oppenness in EU member states1 (figures inparentheses are for intra-EU tradde only)

1. Defined as percentage share of imports in GDP.Source: European Economy.

Table1.4 Population and income in the ‘Triad’

Note: ECU 1=£0.80approx. (1994).Source: European Economy.

Page 29: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

NIGEL M.HEALEY

12

A BRIEF HISTORY OF THE EUROPEAN UNION

‘Jaw-jaw is better than war-war’—Winston Churchill

The formation of the EU must be seen against the backcloth oftwo catastrophic world wars, both triggered by rivalries between themajor European powers. In the immediate aftermath of World WarII, the British wartime prime minister, Winston Churchill, floatedthe idea of a ‘United States of Europe’, in which he proposed thatthe national economies of Europe should be fused together intosuch a complete and mutually interdependent union that warbetween its member states would be rendered unthinkable. Todaysuch faith in the cohesive power of economic integration has beenshaken by the nationalist and ethnic unrest in the former nations ofthe Soviet Union and Yugoslavia, both of which have been tornasunder since 1989 after decades of economic unification undercommunist rule. Nevertheless, in the early postwar years,negotiations to build an economic community in Europe wereprimarily driven by political, rather than economic, considerations(see Lintner and Mazey, 1991). See Table 1.5 for summary of keydevelopments to date.

The concept of a pan-European federation received an earlysetback with the division of Europe into the (communist) east and(capitalist) west in the late 1940s. A second blow was delivered bythe British government which, despite its early enthusiasm forChurchill’s vision, withdrew its support as it became clear thatcloser ties with mainland Europe would entail severing itspreferential trading relations with the Commonwealth. Britaincame to favour a less comprehensive arrangement, restricted tofree trade in industrial goods (see above), and subsequentlypersuaded the Nordic countries (Finland, Sweden, Norway, Icelandand Denmark), Spain, Portugal, Switzerland and Austria tocollaborate in the creation of EFTA, which came into being in1960. In the event, only six western European states (France, WestGermany, Italy, Belgium, the Netherlands and Luxembourg) signedthe Treaty of Rome in 1957, the agreement which created theforerunner of today’s EU, the European Economic Community(EEC), on January 1, 1958 (see Chapter 9 for a more detailedsurvey).

The early years of the EU were plagued by internal disputes andwrangles, with the French government becoming increasingly

Page 30: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

FROM THE TREATY OF ROME TO MAASTRICHT

13

Table 1.5 Key developments in the history of the EU

Page 31: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

NIGEL M.HEALEY

14

politically isolated over its farm policies and boycotting meetings inretaliation. The failure of other member states to discipline Franceled to the ‘Luxembourg Compromise’ in 1966, an agreement whichrecognised the inability of a voluntary ‘club’ like the EU to imposethe will of the majority on a reluctant minority by allowing amember state to veto proposals if it felt its ‘special nationalinterests’ were being threatened. The Luxembourg Compromisemeant that all important decisions thereafter were made on aconsensus basis. This state of affairs was only altered by thepassage of the Single European Act (SEA) in 1986, which restrictedthe use of the veto to certain areas only (see Chapter 8).

Between 1966 and 1986, the pace of economic integration wasrelatively sluggish. Since almost any proposal made by theCommission during this period normally involved costs to one ormore member states—even though the EU as a whole would havegained—potential losers invariably blocked progress by using theirveto. Resistance to change was further strengthened by the fact thatall EU countries (except Britain) elect their national governmentsusing a system of proportional representation. This often results inminority governments, which rely for their political survival onsupport from smaller parties representing particular groups insociety (e.g., farmers—see Chapter 11). Such an arrangement givesspecial interest groups a disproportionate influence in nationalparliaments which, until the Luxembourg Compromise was partiallysuspended by the SEA, tended to paralyse decisionmaking at theEU level as well.

The birth of the 1992 programme

During the early 1980s, frustration with the slow pace ofintegration within the EU began to mount. There was a growingfeeling that the failure to unify its national markets was causing theEU to fall behind its other Triad rivals, the United States andJapan. ‘Eurosclerosis’ (i.e., economic paralysis) became a popularterm. Capital investment within Europe was lagging behind that inthe United States and Japan, while unit labour costs (a majorcomponent of international competitiveness) had accelerated aheadof costs in the other two Triad members. Superimposed on thisdeepening sense of economic insecurity in the EU was thestrengthening position within key member states of right-winggovernments committed to supply-side reform in the early 1980s.

Page 32: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

FROM THE TREATY OF ROME TO MAASTRICHT

15

Led by the Thatcher government in Britain, but followed closely by,inter alia, the Kohl administration in Germany and—after an abruptU-turn in 1982—the Mitterand government in France, EUgovernments came to see free trade and free markets, rather thanprotectionism and state intervention, as the recipe for economicsuccess.

Against this background of economic stagnation and growingpolitical pressure for supply-side reform, the Commission switchedtack in 1985. Instead of proposing new laws and directives one byone as it had done in the past, so ensuring that there was always atleast one loser to obstruct the way forward, the Commissionoutlined all 300 of the measures it deemed necessary to completethe single market in one ‘White Paper’. The logic of this change oftactics was to show each member state that the package overallwould be to its advantage; hence, each could be induced to acceptindividual proposals which would damage its national interests inorder to guarantee the success of the programme as a whole (seeChapters 7 and 8). Progress could thereafter be made in a giant‘horse-trading’ exercise. For example, Britain might accept astandard two-pin plug (incurring the cost of changing from three-pin plugs) if the French agreed to abolish capital controls (soallowing British financial institutions into the hitherto protectedFrench financial market).

The Commission’s masterplan for ‘completing the internalmarket’ was formally approved and the following year, 1986, theSEA was passed. The SEA pledged the member states toachieving the single market and, more importantly, altered thedecision-making processes—limiting the use of the veto (thelegacy of the Luxembourg Compromise) to a few key areas—toensure that the enabling measures could all be voted into EU lawby the agreed deadline of December 31, 1992. Despite ongoingdisagreement about a limited number of sensitive issues, thenecessary legislation was almost entirely adopted by the EU beforethe self-imposed deadline, creating a unified market in the EU forthe first time in 1993.

From the single market to monetary union

Inspired by the revitalisation of the process of economicintegration and encouraged by the apparent success of the EMS inpromoting ‘monetary stability’, the European Council (see below)

Page 33: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

NIGEL M.HEALEY

16

directed the Commission to prepare a blueprint for EMU in 1988.The result was the ‘Delors Report’, published in 1989, whichproposed a radical, three-stage plan (see Chapters 4 and 5). In StageOne, it recommended that all EU currencies should join the ERM‘on equal terms’. In practice, this meant that the currencies outsidethe system must be incorporated and that, in due course, allmembers should respect the then mainstream, ±2.25% band (it hassince been widened to ±15%—see Chapter 2). Taken in conjunctionwith the elimination of barriers to the free movement of capital—which under the ‘1992’ programme was to take place in July 1990—the Delors Plan argued that Stage One would represent a solidfoundation on which the EU could build by gradually reducing thewidth of the target band.

The Delors Plan envisaged that Stage Two would be atransitional phase, during which monetary policy would beincreasingly coordinated, thereby allowing the margin forpermissible exchange rate fluctuations to be progressively cut tozero and realignments phased out. The report recommended theestablishment of a European central bank (ECB), which wouldsupervise and harmonise national monetary policies, althoughthroughout Stage Two, member governments would retain ultimatesovereignty in monetary affairs. Stage Three would involve themove to irrevocably fixed exchange rates and ‘the replacement ofnational currencies by a single [EU] currency…as soon as possibleafter the locking of parities’.

The Council of Ministers (see below) judged thatimplementation of Stages Two and Three would requireinstitutional changes within the EU which could not be achievedwithout substantive changes to the Treaty of Rome. To this end, aspecial intergovernmental committee (IGC) was convened inDecember 1990, charged with drawing up concrete proposals toturn the Delors Plan into reality. The IGC finally concluded itsdeliberations in December 1991, when the heads of the twelvemember states (the ‘European Council’—see below) met in theDutch town of Maastricht to sign a new Treaty on EuropeanUnion (see Chapters 4–6 for a discussion of the implications ofmonetary union). Reflecting concern over the possible costs ofEMU to the less-developed, higher-inflation countries of the EU,the treaty envisages that the move to a single currency willdepend on certain ‘convergence’ conditions being fulfilled (e.g.,applicants must have inflation and interest rates that are close to

Page 34: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

FROM THE TREATY OF ROME TO MAASTRICHT

17

the average of the ‘best’ three states and must not exceed limitson public debt and budget deficits, etc.).

The logic of these conditions is that, if satisfied, the costs ofgiving up monetary sovereignty will be modest and, by implication,outweighed by the likely benefits (see Chapter 5). If at least sevenmember states meet all these prerequisites in 1996, this group mayset a date for a limited monetary union that—initially at least—willexclude the other EU countries. The remaining states can then joinas and when their circumstances allow. Should the 1996 conferencefail to set a date for EMU, it will be reconvened in 1998. At thistime, if at least five member states meet the prerequisites agreed atMaastricht, those that qualify will automatically adopt a commoncurrency in 1999, leaving the others to apply for membership indue course.

THE INSTITUTIONAL STRUCTURE OF THEEUROPEAN UNION

To achieve the objectives set out in the Treaty of Rome, ‘the Six’created four key institutions, whose role and functions have beengradually modified by successive treaty amendments, most recentlyby the Maastricht Treaty which revised the interrelationship betweenthe Council of Ministers and the European Parliament (see Nicolland Salmon, 1994, for a more detailed discussion).

The Commission

The Commission is the EU’s civil service or executive. It is basedin Brussels and has a staff of approximately 17,000 permanent civilservants, of whom approximately 15% are translators. TheCommission is structured into 23 departments of state (known asdirectorate-generals). Its work is overseen by seventeencommissioners, who each control one or more departments of state(e.g., agriculture, economic and financial affairs, etc.). Thecommissioners are appointed for five-year terms by nationalgovernments, but take an oath not to represent their narrownational interests. Germany, France, Italy, Britain and Spain eachappoint two commissioners, while the other seven member stateseach provide one. The Commission has a president (currently theformer Luxembourg prime minister, Jacques Santer), who isappointed by the European Council.

Page 35: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

NIGEL M.HEALEY

18

In relative terms, the Commission is tiny, employing fewer civilservants than most national ministries. In part, this is possiblebecause much of its day-to-day work is orchestrated via thenational departments of its member states. For example, theMinistry of Agriculture carries out the practical business ofimplementing EU farm policy, acting as the Commission’s ‘agent’ indealing with British farmers. However, the size of the EU budget isalso smaller than popularly believed. Table 1.6 shows the scale andcomposition of the EU budget for 1993. While nationalgovernments spend approximately 40% of GDP in most memberstates, the total EU budget is less than 2% of the EU’s GDP.

The Council of Ministers

The Council of Ministers is the ultimate decision-taking body in theEU, although in certain policy areas it can no longer overrule theEuropean Parliament since the ratification of the Maastricht Treaty(see below). It comprises the ministers of national governments. Ameeting dealing with budgetary policy will be attended by thetwelve finance or treasury ministers, for example, while a meetingaddressing security policy will involve interior (i.e., home) ministers.Of its many guises, ‘Ecofin’ (the council of finance ministers) and

Table 1.6 The EU budget, 1993

Source: European Economy.

Page 36: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

FROM THE TREATY OF ROME TO MAASTRICHT

19

the Council of Agricultural Ministers are the most important in theeconomic sphere, although meetings of foreign affairs ministersfrequently warrant the greatest public attention.

The Council of Ministers normally meets in Brussels, where itsgatherings are serviced by a secretariat of approximately 2,000 staff,organised into directorates-general which parallel those of theCommission. Each member state holds the ‘presidency’ of theCouncil for a revolving six-month term (January–June or July–December), which allows its national representatives to chairmeetings, set agendas and generally direct the activities of theCouncil for the direction of its term.

The deliberations of national ministers are supported by aCommittee of Permanent Representatives (COREPER), a group ofnational civil servants based in Brussels for the purpose of liaisingwith the Commission and generally assisting their nationalministerial representatives to make decisions efficiently. Votingwithin the Council takes place on a ‘qualified majority’ basis. Eachnational minister has an allocated number of votes, depending onthe size of his/her state (see Table 1.7). At present, 54 (of the totalof 76) votes are needed for a ‘yes’ vote to be carried. Theallocation of votes between member states is to be altered with theaccession of the three EFTA states in 1995 and the proposedincrease in the number of votes necessary to ‘block’ a proposal inthe Council (presently 23) proved to be a source of some

Table 1.7 Weighted votes in the Council of Ministers, 1994

Source: EC Commission.

Page 37: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

NIGEL M.HEALEY

20

controversy, with Britain in particular opposing what its governmentsaw as an attempt to ‘dilute’ its voice in the EU.

The council of prime ministers (and heads of state) is known asthe ‘European Council’ and, although it historically has had no cleararea of responsibility, it has become the key forum for makingmajor strategic decisions within the EU. The European Council firstbegan meeting in 1974 at the suggestion of the then Frenchpresident, Giscard d’Estaing, and its role was formally recognisedby the SEA in 1986. It comprises the French president and theprime ministers of the other eleven states, together with theirforeign ministers and the president and a vice-president of theCommission. The European Council normally meets three times ayear, once in each of the countries holding the six-monthlypresidency of the Council and once in Brussels.

The European Parliament

Despite recent constitutional reforms, the European Parliamentremains a primarily consultative body with limited legislative powers.It essentially discusses EU matters, makes recommen-dations to theCouncil of Ministers and the Commission and monitors theexecution of EU policy. Its powers were, however, extended by theMaastricht Treaty, which introduced the so-called ‘co-decisionprocedure’. This allows the Parliament to block legislation whichhas been approved by the Council of Ministers in some fifteenareas of policymaking. The co-decision procedure was first used in1994 and it remains unclear how much real power this innovationwill actually give parliamentarians.

The European Parliament is elected every five years and has 567members, who arrange themselves into political groupings accord-ing to ideology rather than nationality. Following the 1994 elections,the socialists comprise the single largest grouping, with the BritishLabour Party (which belongs to this group and chairs its meetings)being the largest national party (see Table 1.8). The EuropeanParliament conducts most of its business in Brussels, but once amonth it has plenary sessions in Strasbourg, where it is housed in anew purpose-built building.

Seats are allocated to member states on the basis of population,but, as Table 1.9 shows, there is considerable variation in thenumber of electors per Member of the European Parliament(MEP). This imbalance arises primarily due to the large differ-ences

Page 38: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

FROM THE TREATY OF ROME TO MAASTRICHT

21

in total population between member states—standardising thenumber of electors per member of parliament would reduce therepresentation of the smaller member states to such an extent thattheir voice would effectively not be heard.

The European Court of Justice

The European Court of Justice rules on interpretations andbreaches of EU law. The Court is based in Luxembourg andpresently consists of thirteen judges and six advocates-general. Ithas made a number of important legal rulings which have altered

Table 1.8 European parliamentary seats by political grouping, June 1994

Source: European Parliament.

Table 1.9 National representation in the European Parliament

Source: Eurostat.

Page 39: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

NIGEL M.HEALEY

22

the course of European economic integration (for example, byestablishing key principles about unfair practices). The famous‘Cassis de Dijon’ ruling, for example, outlawed the use ofregulations calculated to have the effect of favouring domesticproducers over those in other member states, while its rulings onequal pay have had profound effects on the provision of pensionsin the EU. However, the Court’s relatively small size means that itseffectiveness is limited by the number of cases it can process.

THE WELFARE EFFECTS OF ECONOMICINTEGRATION

In analysing the welfare effects of economic integration, a goodstarting point is to consider the costs of segmenting nationalmarkets by the imposition of various barriers to trade. Thesebarriers can be conveniently represented by a tariff, which increasesthe market price of imported goods and therefore serves tocompletely or partially exclude them from the home market. Theanalysis can, however, be equally applied to less transparent (non-tariff) barriers like discriminatory technical standards, all of whichhave the ultimate effect of making it more costly for an importerto sell in the home market and thereby protecting local producersfrom overseas competition. The only difference is that a tariffgenerates revenue for the government, whereas a non-tariff barrier(NTB) inflates the true opportunity cost of imports and sorepresents a complete deadweight loss.

The simplest way of analysing the effects of such obstacles totrade is to utilise familiar supply and demand analysis. In Figure1.2, SH and DH represent the domestic supply of, and the domesticdemand for, the good being considered. It is conventionallyassumed that the country concerned is small, in the sense that itspurchases (imports) of the good on the world market have noimpact on the world price, PW. In other words, the country is a‘price-taker’, with consumers facing a perfectly elastic world supplycurve, SW, at price PW.

Trade barriers are intended to restrict imports. In their absence,the effective supply schedule (showing the total amount from allsources supplied to the market at each price) would be ABSW,which intersects DH at point E. The market price would be simplythe world price, PW, at which domestic producers would supply Q1

and consumers would demand Q4, with the difference between the

Page 40: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

FROM THE TREATY OF ROME TO MAASTRICHT

23

two, Q4-Q1, being imported. Suppose the government nowintroduces the simplest form of trade barrier, a ‘specific’ tariff—that is, a tariff of a specific amount (e.g., £10) per unit imported.

In Figure 1.2, the imposition of the specific tariff, t, has theeffect of shifting the world supply schedule vertically upwards bythe amount of the tariff to SW+t, so that the new effective supplyschedule becomes ACSW+t. As a result, the market price rises toPW+t. At the higher price of PW+t, domestic producers expand outputto Q2, increasing their profits (‘producer surplus’) by the areaPWPW+tCB. Domestic consumption, conversely, is choked off by theprice rise, falling to Q3. Consumers are now paying more toconsume less and the welfare loss they suffer is represented by thereduction in their consumer surplus of area PWPW+tDE. Imports aresqueezed by both the increase in domestic production and thedecline in demand, falling to Q3-Q2. From the government’s pointof view, the tariff has achieved its objective of reducing importsand boosting domestic production. Bear in mind also that althoughconsumers are now paying PW+t, when they buy imported goods thisprice includes the tariff, ‘t’, which goes not to overseas producers

Figure 1.2 The welfare effects of protection

Page 41: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

NIGEL M.HEALEY

24

but to the government. In total, the government raises an amountof tariff revenue given by area CDFG (NB, this offsetting welfaregain would be absent in the case of an NTB which raised importcosts by an amount t).

In net terms—that is, taking the economy as a whole andcombining the gains and losses of producers, consumers andgovernment—it is clear that the welfare loss suffered by consumersoutweighs the gains enjoyed by the other two groups by an amountBCG+DFE. (NB, the larger the tariff, the larger these two ‘welfaretriangles’ and the greater the net loss to society.) Throwing thisanalysis into reverse and abolishing the tariff implies a net welfaregain to society of BCG+DFE (or BCDE in the case of an NTB),so providing a neat diagrammatic summary of the economic casefor free trade.

Membership of a grouping like the EU does not, however,unambiguously constitute a move to freer trade; rather, it implies ashift to a discriminatory trade policy, in which tariff (and nontariff)barriers are reduced or eliminated on intra-union trade, whileremaining on trade between union members and the outside world.For a country initially protecting its producers against overseascompetition, joining the EU thus involves two major changes intrade policy. The first is that it agrees to eliminate tariffs—andother NTBs—against imports from its fellow member countries.The second is that it adopts a discriminatory or preferential tradepolicy, allowing free access for goods from other EU members, butimposing a common external tariff (CET) against the rest of theworld. This latter feature of the EU injects additional distortionsinto the relative prices faced by domestic consumers (i.e., other EUproducers become artificially competitive vis-à-vis the rest of theworld) and this may, under certain circumstances, cause offsettingwelfare losses. It is to a more detailed analysis of these issues thatthe next section turns (see also Chapter 7).

The welfare effects of the European Union

The analysis of economic integration typically focuses on theeffects of forming a customs union and, to the extent that the EUis still in the process of progressing beyond this stage to create agenuine common market, in what follows attention will be focusedon the welfare effects of this form of integration. Remem-berthroughout this sub-section that, while the traditional economic

Page 42: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

FROM THE TREATY OF ROME TO MAASTRICHT

25

analysis examines the effect of switching from a universal to adiscriminatory tariff on imports, this framework can also be used toassess the effect of selectively dismantling NTBs (as in the 1992programme to complete the internal market). As noted above, theonly difference is that, in the former case, tariff revenue accrues tothe government, whereas in the latter, the true opportunity cost ofimports is increased by NTBs.

To further simplify the analysis, consider the formation of ahypothetical customs union between only two countries, H (the‘home’ country) and P (the ‘partner’ country). Assume that bothcountries initially impose the same tariff on imports, so that theCET levied on imports from the rest of the world after the unionis created is the same as the original non-discriminatory tariff. Thepurpose of this second assumption is to focus attention on thefundamental impact of joining a customs union, namely thatimports from the partner country escape the tariff to which theywere formerly subject. Any difference between the original tariffand the new CET would simply confuse the issue, since the changesin imports from the outside world it would induce are not anecessary consequence of joining the union; they could equally havebeen engineered by a unilateral alteration of the original nondiscriminatory tariff.

In Figure 1.3a, SH represents the domestic supply curve and t isboth the pre-union tariff (on all imports) and the CET (on importsfrom the outside world). SW is the world supply schedule (perfectlyelastic as before, since both the home country and the customsunion are assumed to be too small to affect the world price, PW)and SP represents the supply of goods to the home country marketby the partner country. Before the union is formed, when importsfrom both the outside world and partner country are subject to thesame tariff, t, the effective supply schedule is given by ABSW+t.Because SP is above SW at every level of output, imports from thepartner country are completely excluded from the home market bythis tariff.

Once the customs union has been formed, however, importsfrom the partner country enter tariff-free and compete on equalterms with domestic goods. At any given price, therefore,producers in the customs union collectively supply an amount ‘x’,of which ‘y’ is supplied by domestic firms and ‘x-y’ by firms fromthe partner country. The total union supply curve is shown inFigure 1.3b, where SCU is simply the partner’s supply, SP,

Page 43: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

NIGEL M.HEALEY

26

(horizontally) added to the domestic supply, SH. The new effectivesupply curve becomes ACDSW+t. The scene is now set to assessthe welfare implications of union membership for the homecountry, which clearly depend on a range of factors, including: the

Figure 1.3 Effective supply (a) pre-customs and (b) post-customs union

Page 44: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

FROM THE TREATY OF ROME TO MAASTRICHT

27

relative competitiveness of the partner’s producers vis-à-vis the restof the world; the sizes of the pre-union tariff and the CET; andthe relative elasticities of the various supply schedules anddomestic demand schedules.

The theoretical analysis of customs unions was pioneered byViner (1950) and, in what follows, his original terminology will beretained. Figures 1.4a and 1.4b illustrate the two possible extremeoutcomes of membership for the home country. In Figure 1.4a, thetariff, tc, is so high that before joining the customs union, the homecountry imports from neither the partner country nor the outsideworld. The effective supply schedule is ADSW+tc, which intersectsthe domestic demand schedule at point D. At price P1, domesticdemand Q2 is entirely met by domestic producers. After theformation of the union, the effective supply schedule becomesABFSW+tc, since goods from the partner country can now enter thedomestic market tariff-free. The new supply schedule cuts thedemand schedule at point E. The price falls to P2, with demandincreasing to Q3 and domestic supply contracting to Q1. The ‘gap’between Q3 and Q1 is filled by imports from the relatively moreefficient partner country’s producers.

In this scenario, the effect of forming the customs union hasbeen to create trade where before there was none. Vineraccordingly labelled this ‘trade creation’ and argued that this was anunambiguously positive result. Although universal free trade wouldstill be the optimal solution (allowing the domestic price to fall toPW, further increasing both consumption and output by the least-cost producers), trade creation within a customs union neverthelessimplies that resources are more efficiently allocated after thanbefore. Focusing on the ‘welfare triangles’ involved confirms thisconclusion. Consumers clearly gain, since they are consuming more(Q3-Q2) at a lower price, P2. Consumer surplus thus increases by thearea P1DEP2. The losers are domestic producers, suffering a loss ofsurplus given by the area P1DCP2. The net gain to the country as awhole is represented by the triangle CDE.

Joining a customs union will always be trade-creating for thehome country provided the pre-union tariff is set at tc or above (sothat it initially ‘prohibits’ all trade). Consider instead the situationillustrated in Figure 1.4b. In this case the tariff is much lower at td.Before joining the customs union, the effective supply schedule isACSW+td and the domestic price is P1. At this price, consumersdemand Q2, but domestic producers supply only Q1, leaving the gap

Page 45: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

NIGEL M.HEALEY

28

to be filled by imports from the outside world. Notice thatconsumers pay the price P1 to buy these imports in the shops,although importers only pay PW to the overseas suppliers. Thedifference between P1 and PW, of course, is simply the tariff, td,

Figure 1.4 (a) Pure trade creation and (b) pure trade diversion in a customsunion

Page 46: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

FROM THE TREATY OF ROME TO MAASTRICHT

29

which is added on by the government. Area CDFE thus representsthe total tariff revenue received by the government on the Q2-Q1

imported.As before, the immediate effect of joining the customs union is

that imports from the partner country now enjoy tariff-free access,so that the effective supply schedule becomes ABDW+td. This newsupply schedule also cuts the demand schedule at point D, so thatthere is no change in the domestic price, nor in domesticconsumption (which remains at Q2) and supply (which stays fixed atQ1). The only difference is that the gap Q2-Q1 is now filled byimports from the partner country, which (being tariff-free) canundercut the post-tariff price of imports from the outside worldfor all quantities up to Q2.

However, when consumers buy Q2-Q1 from the partner country’sproducers, the price they pay, P1, is no longer inflated by thegovernment-imposed tariff, but reflects the full opportunity cost ofthe good. In other words, in Figure 1.4b, the effect of joining thecustoms union is to divert trade patterns away from the cheapestworld suppliers towards the relatively less efficient partner country.Far from promoting a more rational allocation of the world’sresources, in this latter case the customs union is operating to makematters worse. The negative welfare implications of what Vinerdubbed ‘trade diversion’ can be confirmed by referring to the

Table 1.10 Production costs and market prices in the home country beforeand after membership of a customs union

Page 47: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

NIGEL M.HEALEY

30

welfare triangles. Since there is no change in price, neitherconsumer nor producer surplus is affected; but the tariff revenueformerly accruing to the government, CDFE, is now lost to thecountry, constituting a net welfare loss.

Table 1.10 illustrates the extreme possibilities of trade creationand diversion in simplified numerical form. In Scenario 1, the homecountry imposes a general, non-discriminatory tariff of 100%before joining the customs union. Consumers are faced with a setof relative prices (column two) which induces them to buyexclusively from domestic suppliers at £100 (i.e., the 100% tariff is‘prohibitive’, excluding all imports from the home market). Whenthe home country joins the union, goods from the partner countrycan now enter the home market unrestricted (see column three). Nolonger hindered by the tariff, the more efficient producers in thepartner country can undercut their home country rivals by £20.Consumers accordingly switch to imports from the new partnercountry and trade creation takes place. Although goods are still notbeing bought from the most efficient producers (in the outsideworld), the formation of the customs union still improves matters,shifting production from less efficient (home country) to moreefficient (partner country) producers.

Scenario 2 shows the alternative extreme possibility. Here thepre-union tariff is set at only 50%, which is not high enough tomake home producers competitive (see column 2). Consumerstherefore buy from world suppliers at £90. Once the union isformed, however, the partner country’s producers can undercut therest of the world by £10, causing consumers to switch from thelatter to the former, thus diverting trade from the more to the lessefficient source. In this second case, the consequences of thecustoms union are negative.

In the first scenario, the formation of the customs union resultsin ‘pure’ trade creation, turning a hitherto closed economy into anopen economy and promoting a more rational allocation of theworld’s resources. In the second, the union causes pure tradediversion, skewing the trade patterns of an economy already activelyengaged in international exchange from lower- to highercostproducers and worsening the global allocation of resources. In mostreal-world situations, however, neither one of these extremes islikely to arise. Almost by definition, countries with such high tariffbarriers that they have no trade with the outside world are unlikelyto be interested in joining a customs union, so that pure trade

Page 48: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

FROM THE TREATY OF ROME TO MAASTRICHT

31

creation is only a remote possibility. And it would be bycoincidence only if the pre- and post-union tariff structures weresuch that imports from the partner country exactly displaced thosefrom the outside world, giving rise to pure trade diversion. Figure1.5 sets out a more plausible situation. Here there is trade beforeentering the union, so that some trade diversion takes place, but theinflux of cheaper imports from the partner country also allowssome fall in domestic prices, stimulating an expansion of trade aswell.

To assess the net impact of union membership on the homecountry, it is now necessary to set the welfare losses caused by thetrade diversion (loss of tariff revenue) against the net gains fromtrade creation (the increase in consumer surplus less the reductionin producer surplus). Before the union is formed, the effectivesupply curve is ADSW+tm, the price is P1 and domestic supply anddemand are Q2 and Q3 respectively, with the gap (Q3-Q2) being filledby imports from the rest of the world, which yields a tariff revenueto the government of DEKJ.

Once the customs union comes into existence, the new effectivesupply schedule becomes ABFSW+tm. The price falls to P2, increasingconsumption to Q4 (and consumer surplus by P1EGP2) and reducing

Figure 1.5 Trade creation versus trade diversion in a customs union

Page 49: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

NIGEL M.HEALEY

32

domestic production to Q1 (and producer surplus by P1DCP2). Theimport gap is larger than before and represents trade creation, thenet welfare gain from which is given by the area DEGC (P1EGP2-P1DCP2). However, because the partner country’s producers cannow undercut the post-tariff world price, they are also able to seizethe share of the home market previously supplied by the rest ofthe world, giving rise to trade diversion and the loss of the tariffrevenue DEKJ.

Overall, then, the net welfare effect of joining the customsunion is DEGC-DEKJ or, since these areas overlap, the differencebetween the area of the two hatched triangles (CDI+EHG) and thatof the shaded rectangle (IHKJ). Whether the net result is positiveor negative depends on a range of factors. If the tariff levied ishigh and the partner country only slightly less efficient than the restof the world, it is likely that the positive, tradecreating benefits willoutweigh the negative, trade-diverting costs; and vice versa, if thetariff is low and the partner country much less efficient than therest of the world.

Tariffs versus non-tariff barriers

As noted above, the welfare effects of NTBs can be analysed usingthe same tools as tariffs. Inconsistent national technical and safetystandards, for example, have the effect of inflating the cost ofimports by forcing foreign manufacturers to modify their standardproducts before they can be shipped. Lengthy frontier delayssimilarly impose costs on imported goods. From the point of viewof overseas producers, NTBs thus raise the selling price of theirproducts in the market in the same way that a tariff would haveincreased the price of unmodified goods. For this reason, thereduction of NTBs within the EU under the 1992 programme canbe expected to have effects on trade patterns which are similar tothe earlier reduction in tariffs on intra-EU trade (see Chapters 7and 8). In some cases, removing NTBs will create intra-EU tradewhere there was previously none, resulting in an unambiguouswelfare improvement. For example, the 1992 programme attackedmany state monopolies (e.g., in telecommunications) and sopromises to improve the range of services available to EUconsumers, while reducing prices.

In other cases, however, scaling down the NTBs previouslyimposed against other EU producers, while leaving them intact

Page 50: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

FROM THE TREATY OF ROME TO MAASTRICHT

33

against non-EU competitors, may lead to trade diversion (seeHealey, 1992b). In the approach to 1992, foreign companies clearlybelieved that they would be disadvantaged by the selective removalof NTBs on intra-union trade and fear of a resulting ‘FortressEurope’ is widely cited as the main reason for the sharp increase inforeign direct investment in the late 1980s, as US and Japanesecompanies scrambled to establish new production facilities withinthe EU (but see Chapter 12). But in terms of the welfareimplications for EU members, there is an important differencebetween the trade diversion that results from the selective removalof tariff as opposed to NTBs. In the former case, the welfare lossis normally dominated by the loss of tariff revenue to thegovernment when trade is diverted from the cheaper world sourceto the new partner country (see above). In the latter case, there isno tariff revenue. The price paid by consumers includes the non-tariff barrier (NTB) and reflects the full opportunity cost of thegoods to the importing country. Thus, when the NTB is removed,the opportunity cost of the goods from the partner country fallsbelow that of the world suppliers. Thus, while trade diversion stillrepresents a reallocation of resources away from the most efficientworld suppliers to the partner country, from the point of view ofthe importing union member, there is a welfare improvement ratherthan the welfare loss associated with the selective removal of tariffs.

The dynamic benefits of EU membership

Viner’s theoretical framework suggests that the benefits (of tradecreation) to member states of joining a regional bloc like the EUmay be small and possibly outweighed by the negative effects oftrade diversion. However, this conclusion is based on ‘comparativestatic’ analysis, a technique which allows economists to comparestable or ‘static’ equilibrium states before and after some event (inthis case the formation of a customs union) on the assumption that‘all other things remain equal’. Hence this model ignores theprocess by which the new equilibrium state is actually achieved andabstracts from complicating issues like changes in capital stocks,industrial concentration, technical innovation, etc., all of which mayactually be influenced by the formation of the EU. Manyeconomists stress that it is the very factors which Viner’s analysisignores that give rise to the major benefits of union membership(e.g., Balassa, 1961; Baldwin, 1989; Hughes, 1992). For example,

Page 51: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

NIGEL M.HEALEY

34

both trade creation and trade diversion imply an expansion ofproduction by the partner country’s suppliers. Since manymanufacturing industries enjoy declining long-run average coststructures, the resultant economies of scale and experience may, ofthemselves, yield important welfare gains.

Moreover, both trade creation and trade diversion imply that theformation of a customs union allows the partner country’sproducers to seize market share, in the former case from homeproducers and in the latter from the rest of the world. In practice,whichever of the established producer groups is threatened by thisnew source of competition, it is unlikely to passively allow itself tobe squeezed out of the market it hitherto dominated withoutretaliating in some way. Such competitive retaliation may involverestructuring to lower costs, accepting lower profit margins,investing in new technology and a whole host of other responseswhich carry with them gains for the consumer. Both by allowingfirms within the union to more fully exploit economies of scale andexperience and by intensifying internal competitiveness, the EU maytherefore generate ‘dynamic’ ongoing benefits which will, over time,increasingly dwarf the net balance of once-for-all static costs andbenefits (Borts and Stein, 1964).

Economies of scale

The welfare benefits that potentially stem from exploitingeconomies of scale can be explored more formally using thestandard tools of the theory of the firm. Figure 1.6 shows theaverage cost (AC) curves for a declining cost industry. ACP is belowACH at every level of output, reflecting the relatively greaterefficiency of producers in the partner country, while neither is ascost efficient as the world producers at any level of output (i.e., theworld supply schedule, SW, is below both ACP and ACH). Forsimplicity, demand in the home and partner countries is assumed tobe identical, so that DH,P represents the (identical) national demandcurves, while DH+P is their combined joint demand curve after theunion is formed. Given the shape of the national average costcurves, the only way to protect the domestic industry from overseascompetition is to exclude all imports. Before the union, the ‘made-to-measure’ tariff which achieves this result is JA for the homecountry (so that home demand, Q1, is met by home produ-cers) and

Page 52: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

FROM THE TREATY OF ROME TO MAASTRICHT

35

JC for the partner country (so that the partner country’s demand,Q2, is satisfied by partner producers).

Note that the marginal cost and revenue curves to which aproducer would normally refer in making price and output decisionsare ignored in this analysis. This is because, with a horizontal worldsupply schedule, producers in the home and partner countrieseffectively face a horizontal demand curve at the tariffinclusiveworld price (so that their average and marginal revenues are equal).Moreover, because the marginal cost curve for a declining costindustry is always below average cost, setting marginal cost equal tomarginal revenue would (with a horizontal demand curve) lead themonopolist to make a loss, so that the best such a producer can dois to set average cost equal to price and make normal profits; i.e.,the average cost curve is the effective supply curve for such anindustry.

When the customs union is formed, the more efficient partnerproducer can supply the entire union market, with the made-tomeasure common external tariff now being JF. With this tariff,home producers leave the market and the partner producerscompletely satisfy the joint union demand, DH+P, supplying Q4. Thewelfare implications of the union can be calculated in the normal

Figure 1.6 Economies of scale in a customs union

Page 53: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

NIGEL M.HEALEY

36

way. The formation of the union has allowed union producers tomore fully exploit economies of scale, leading to lower prices (theunion-wide price is now F) and higher consumption (Q4, rather thanQ1+Q2). The increase in consumer welfare is simply FABI for thehome country, plus FCEI for the partner country. The bulk ofthese welfare gains (FABG for the home country and FCEH forthe partner country) are due to the ‘dynamic’ benefits fromexploiting economies of scale and are termed the ‘cost reduction’effects. Because average cost always equals average revenue forhome and partner producers, there are no welfare implications interms of changes in producer surplus, although there may, ofcourse, be additional social costs and benefits associated with theclosure of the industry in the home country and its expansion inthe partner country.

Economies of experience

It has long been observed in industrial economics that averagecosts depend not just on output per period (i.e., due to economiesof scale), but on cumulative output over time. The latter effect isdue to the phenomenon known as experience or ‘learning’economies, ref lecting the role of organisational learning inefficient production. For example, a fast-food company likeMcDonald’s that has cumulatively produced 90bn hamburgers overa 30-year period is likely to be on a completely different (i.e.,lower) set of cost curves than a new entrant which tries to breakinto the market with first-year sales of 3bn units. The incumbenthas refined its production, distribution and marketing logisticsover three decades in the industry. The new entrant, in contrast,will inevitably make mistakes, suffer bottlenecks and generally findthings take time to settle down; all other things equal, therefore,its average costs will initially be much higher than those of itsestablished rival. The existence of experience economies is one ofthe main reasons it is so difficult for a new entrant to break intoa mass market, unless it has some technological advantage (e.g.,access to new plant and equipment, etc.) over the incumbentswhich will compensate for its cost-increasing lack of experience.Figure 1.7 illustrates a standard experience or learning curve,which can be algebraically represented by:

Cn=an-b

Page 54: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

FROM THE TREATY OF ROME TO MAASTRICHT

37

where Cn is the cost of nth unit produced, a is the cost of first unitand b is the learning rate. So-called ‘90%’ learning curves arecommon in many industries. This means that, because of the valueof b in the equation above (b=0.1540), unit costs fall 10% witheach doubling of cumulative output. For example, if the first unitcost £100 to produce, the second would cost £90 (£100×90%), thefourth would cost £81 (£90×90%) and so on. While the size of theincremental cost savings from higher cumulative output slowlydeclines, it nevertheless continues to build up indefinitely over time.

In terms of conventional average cost curve diagrams, thisphenomenon implies that as cumulative output increases over time,firms are driven onto ever-lower average cost curves (see Figure1.8). By allowing the most efficient firms to increase output perperiod—and so the rate at which cumulative output is building up—the formation of a customs union may therefore accelerate the rateat which its producers slide down their learning curves, reducingaverage costs over time and delivering welfare benefits in agenuinely dynamic fashion.

Figure 1.7 The experience curve

Page 55: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

NIGEL M.HEALEY

38

Reduced economic rents and X-inefficiency

A final dynamic benefit concerns the disciplining effect of greatercompetition within a customs union on national monopolies. Whennational markets are segmented by the existence of tariffs or otherNTBs, the domestic producers accordingly enjoy a degree ofmonopoly power, allowing them to exploit consumers by restrictingoutput and raising prices, and thereby earning supernormal profits(i.e., economic rent). By opening up national markets to competitionfrom other union producers, a customs union may have the effectof making ‘price-takers’ of former ‘pricemakers’.

Figure 1.9 shows a producer in the home country, with amarginal cost curve, MCH, and average cost curve, ACH. Before theunion is formed, the producer is protected from overseascompetition and enjoys a monopoly position in the home market,facing a demand, DH. The firm sets marginal cost equal to marginalrevenue, producing Q1 at a price A and earning economic rent ofCABD. When the union is formed, the firm becomes a price-takerin the union-wide market, facing competition from other producersat price, PCU. By setting marginal cost equal to marginal revenue(which, as a price-taker, is equal to the union price), the firm

Figure 1.8 Average costs and the experience curve effect

Page 56: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

FROM THE TREATY OF ROME TO MAASTRICHT

39

expands output to Q2, losing its economic rent and earning onlynormal profits. Consumers in the home country benefit, withincreased consumer surplus equal to the area PCUABE (n.b., Q3-Q2

is imported from the rest of the union).The effect of the formation of a customs union on X-ineffi-

ciency can also be shown in the same figure, X-inefficiency refersto the tendency of secure monopolies to eschew cost minimisation(profit maximisation) in favour of alternative, non-economic goals.Freed from the need to watch costs in order to survive (or, indeed,the incentive to cut costs in order to grow), the management of amonopoly may engage in grandiose schemes to boost the selfesteemof themselves and their workforce, building expensive, prestigiousheadquarters and luxurious social facilities, paying inflated salariesand bonuses, tolerating over-manning and waste-ful demarcationpractices and generally inflating the company’s costs in pursuit ofan easy life at the expense of their shareholders’ profits. The abilityof the management of a monopoly to advance its own agenda islimited only by the threat of a shareholder revolt (which ousts the

Figure 1.9 The benefits of increased competition and reduced X-inefficiency

Page 57: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

NIGEL M.HEALEY

40

management) or a hostile takeover (which normally has the sameeffect) which, while not uncommon, is normally significantlyblunted by the asymmetry of information available to the twoparties involved (i.e., the management and the shareholders).Stripped of the protection afforded by tariff and NTBs, however,the firm will be forced to trim costs to survive.

In Figure 1.9, suppose that the new union supply schedule wererepresented by the horizontal broken line, S’ CU, rather than SCU.The formation of the customs union would drive the union pricebelow PCU to P’ CU. If the firm were already operating as costeffectively as possible, it would inevitably go out of business in thelong run, since the union price fails to cover its average costs. If,on the other hand, the management had allowed significant X-inefficiency during the days when the firm enjoyed monopolypower, it may be able to cut costs and shift down its costs curvesto AC’ H and MC’ H respectively, remaining competitive against itsnew rivals elsewhere in the union. In the process, consumers wouldenjoy a further increase in consumer surplus (equal to area PCUEGP’CU), providing an additional benefit which stems from the reductionof X-inefficiency.

CONCLUSIONS

The EU is the most integrated of the world’s regional trade blocs,with a combined GDP equal to that of the United States. Througha series of treaty revisions, the EU has evolved from a customsunion to become a common market and, despite the currencyupheavals of the early 1990s, is scheduled to become an EMU bythe end of the century. Since its inception in the aftermath ofWorld War II, the motivating force behind integration in the EUhas been primarily political rather than economic, with the coremember states (notably the original Six) driven by a vision of asupranational ‘United States of Europe’. This view of the futureshape of the EU has not been shared to the same extent by thenewer member states, in particular Britain. Disagreements about thepace and nature of integration have spawned a growing number ofopt-outs from joint policy initiatives and the resultant variablegeometry has meant that the EU is becoming less uniform, withdifferent sub-groups signing up to different agreements. Thispattern looks set to continue for the foreseeable future.

Economic theory suggests that the nature of integration in the

Page 58: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

FROM THE TREATY OF ROME TO MAASTRICHT

41

EU to date may give rise to mixed welfare effects. Theestablishment of the customs union may create genuine new tradebetween partner states, but it may also displace trade with theoutside world. Britain, for example, has undoubtedly suffered to theextent that EU membership diverted agricultural trade away fromcheaper Commonwealth sources (e.g., Canada, Australia, NewZealand) towards less efficient producers in continental Europe(e.g., El-Agraa, 1983; Winters, 1987). The elimination of NTBsunder the 1992 programme may also be trade-diverting, but thewelfare effects are much more positive. In addition, economicintegration gives rise to a raft of dynamic benefits, including thefuller exploitation of scale and experience economies and thereduction of economic rents and X-inefficiency.

Page 59: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union
Page 60: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

Part I

MACROECONOMICPERSPECTIVES

Page 61: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union
Page 62: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

45

2

THE EUROPEAN MONETARYSYSTEM

Michael Artis and Nigel M.Healey

INTRODUCTION

The European Monetary System (EMS) was established in 1979after almost a decade of unprecedented exchange rate volatility andrapid global inflation. The objective of member countries was ‘tocreate a zone of monetary stability’ within the European Union(EU). By stating their goal in such broad terms, its architectsintended to make clear that the aim of the EMS was not just tostabilise exchange rates; in addition, EMS members accepted anobligation to pursue a common, anti-inflationary policy.

This ‘twin-track’ approach would, the EU hoped, restore bothexternal monetary stability (by stabilising exchange rates) and internalmonetary stability (by curbing inflation) to its member states. In theevent, inflation rates across the EU fell sharply during the 1980s,while bilateral exchange rates (i.e., the exchange rates between onemember currency and another) became significantly more stable.The apparent success of the EMS on these two, interrelated frontsinspired the EU to consider full European monetary union(EMU)—see Chapters 4 and 5. The fundamental difference betweenthe EMS and EMU is that the latter implies a common inflationrate and the complete fixity of bilateral exchange rates betweenmember countries. This constitutes a stark contrast to the presentEMS arrangements, which allow margins within which bilateral ratesare allowed to f luctuate and periodic ‘realignments’ (i.e.,devaluations and revaluations of target rates) to neu-tralise theimpact of differential national inflation rates on countries’international competitiveness.

The events of 1992–93, when the EMS came under repeated andsustained attack, resulting in the withdrawal of the pound and the

Page 63: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

MICHAEL ARTIS AND NIGEL M.HEALEY

46

lira (in autumn 1992), a series of devaluations by the weakercurrencies and, most damagingly, the abandonment of thelongstanding ±2.25% in favour of ultra-wide ±15% target bands inAugust 1993, are widely regarded as having derailed the move tofull monetary union. This chapter examines the history of the EMS,exploring the reasons for its apparent success in the 1980s and itssubsequent travails in the early 1990s.

THE BASICS OF EXCHANGE RATEMANAGEMENT

The benefits of exchange rate stabilisation are well known (see, forexample, Krugman, 1989; Artus and Young, 1979; Healey, 1988; deGrauwe, 1988). To illustrate the basic principles of an exchange ratearrangement like the EMS, consider Figure 2.1, which shows thesupply of, and demand for, sterling against the deutschmark. Thevertical axis measures the price of £1 in terms of deutschmarks,while the horizontal axis measures the quantity of sterling beingsupplied and demanded. Suppose that, as was the case betweenOctober 8, 1990 and September 16, 1992, the British government‘pegs’ its exchange rate (i.e., the deutschmark price of sterling) at a

Figure 2.1 The forex market for sterling/deutschmarks

Page 64: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

THE EUROPEAN MONETARY SYSTEM

47

central rate of DM2.95±6%. This commitment obliges the Bank ofEngland to ensure that sterling rises to no more than DM3.13(DM2.95×106%) and falls to no less than DM2.77 (DM2.95×94%).Maintaining the pound within such narrow bands requires both‘open market operations’ in the foreign exchange market—officialsales and purchases of sterling—and adjustments in interest rates asnecessary.

For example, if sterling were to fall to the floor of its targetband (DM2.77), either because the supply of sterling shifted to theright (e.g., from S

0 to S

1) or the demand for sterling shifted to the

left (e.g., from D0 to D

1), the Bank of England would be obliged to

buy up the excess supply of sterling, using deutschmarks from itsforeign exchange reserves. It could also attempt to lift the poundoff its trading floor by raising British interest rates which, all otherthings equal, would tend to shift the supply of sterling to the left(as holders of sterling find switching into deutschmark assets lessattractive) and the demand for sterling to the right (as deutschmarkholders are tempted to switch into higher yielding sterling assets).Conversely, if sterling were to rise to its trading ceiling (DM3.13),the Bank of England would be required to satisfy the excessdemand for sterling by selling sterling, buying deutschmarks for itsforeign exchange reserves. At the same time, it could reduce Britishinterest rates with the aim of boosting the supply of, and curbingthe demand for, sterling.

There is clearly an important difference between trying to propup the pound when it has sunk to its trading floor and trying to‘cap’ the rise in sterling when it has appreciated to its tradingceiling. In terms of open market operations, official purchases ofsterling when it is weak are limited by the size of the Bank ofEngland’s foreign exchange reserves (and whatever it can borrowfrom other central banks); in contrast, official sales of sterlingwhen it is strong can be made in unlimited amounts, since the Bankof England effectively creates ‘new’ sterling as it purchasesdeutschmarks in the market.

THE ROLE OF THE FOREIGN EXCHANGEMARKET

This asymmetry between weak and strong currencies is given acrucial significance by the size of today’s foreign exchange market.A recent survey by the Bank of England reported that average daily

Page 65: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

MICHAEL ARTIS AND NIGEL M.HEALEY

48

turnover in the London foreign exchange market during the surveyperiod (April 1992) was $300bn (approximately equal to one-thirdof Britain’s annual GDP). Interestingly, the consensus view amongstdealers surveyed was that, during April 1992, business wassomewhat lower than normal, suggesting that $300bn may be anunderestimate of London’s daily turnover. Table 2.1 summarises theBank’s findings for the seven largest financial centres. These figuresmust be set against Britain’s official reserves, which averagedroughly $45bn during 1992—less than one-sixth the daily turnoverof the London foreign exchange market. The implication is that theability of a central bank to mop up the excess supply of a weakcurrency—once international investors have decided thatdevaluation is imminent—is very limited.

Once a speculative run against a currency has begun to gathermomentum, interest rate increases may also be ineffective. A rise inBritish interest rates, all other things equal, makes sterling assetsmore attractive relative to deutschmark assets. But if investors feara devaluation in sterling, they will have to set against the extra yieldon sterling assets the expected fall in the value of the currency inwhich they are denominated. For example, suppose that investorsbelieve that the probability of a 10% devaluation within the nextweek is 0.5. The expected capital loss on a sterling asset is therefore5% (i.e., the 10% devaluation multiplied by the probability ofdevaluation, 0.5). To offset this expected capital loss, the interestrate necessary to induce investors to hold sterling over thefollowing week would have to be 5% over and above the Germanrate, per week; an interest rate differential of 5% per week amountsto an annual interest rate of 1160% above the German rate.

The higher the perceived probability of devaluation, the greaterthe selling pressure on the weak currency and the larger the

Table 2.1 Daily turnover in the major financial centres, 1992

Source: Bank of England.

Page 66: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

THE EUROPEAN MONETARY SYSTEM

49

required interest rate hike. Because investors know that massive,sustained interest rate increases are likely to be politicallyunacceptable to the government of the weak currency, a speculativecrisis can feed on itself: the larger the interest rate hike needed tostabilise the currency, the less likely it is to take place, so thatexpectations of a devaluation can get continuously revised upwards(towards a probability of unity) once a crisis is under way, leadingto truly massive selling. In terms of Figure 2.1, as investors loseconfidence in the currency, the supply and demand schedules moveexplosively to the right and left respectively, giving rise to anunbridgeable excess of supply over demand. Once a currency hasfallen to its trading floor, therefore, central banks may findthemselves incapable of arresting the speculative pressure either byopen-market purchases or by interest rate hikes. The need tomaintain confidence in the declared parities was thus the major taskfacing the architects of the EMS in 1979 and, during the upheavalsof the system in 1992–93, it was the failure to assuage the fears ofspeculators that led to its near collapse.

THE BACKGROUND TO THE EUROPEANMONETARY SYSTEM

The attempt to bind the currencies of the EU countries moreclosely together did not start with the EMS. Indeed, an importantpart of the background to the establishment of the EMS was thefailure of its predecessor, the so-called ‘Snake’. The Snake wasinstituted in April 1972. This came shortly after the demise of theBretton Woods system and the attempt to resur rect aninternational monetar y system along the same lines in theSmithsonian Agreement reached in Washington in December 1971.In the Smithsonian, margins of fluctuation of the exchange ratesagainst the dollar were widened from the previous ±1% ofBretton Woods to ±2.25%, implying that, against each other, theEuropean currencies could fluctuate by ±4.5%. The Europeancountries felt this to be too large and, in the Snake arrangement,intra-EU parties were to be narrowed to ±2.25%. There weregood practical reasons for wanting to maintain a discipline overintra-EU exchange rates. First, the Common Agricultural Policydepended upon setting EU-wide prices for agricultural produce:exchange rate changes could play havoc with these arrangements.They could result in a quite different distribution of incentives to

Page 67: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

MICHAEL ARTIS AND NIGEL M.HEALEY

50

farmers across the member states than that envisaged when theprices were first set (see also Chapter 11). Second, and moregenerally, the achievements of the EU in removing elements ofnational protection could be severely compromised by a change inexchange rate parities involving a sharp change in competitiveness.Looking further into the future it was also clear that the desire tocreate a ‘United States of Europe’ on the American model wouldrequire monetary union—a single currency and a single centralbank. This was indeed projected by the Werner Committee, whichin 1970 published an ambitious plan for monetary union by theend of the 1970s.

Despite the desirability of greater exchange rate certainty andthe long-run attractions of monetary union, the Snake proved inpractice a disaster—sterling left the arrangement very early (by June1972, whereafter sterling floated against all other currencies); theFrench franc left the Snake in January 1974 and rejoined in July1975 only to leave it once more in March 1976; Italy did notparticipate in the system. The arrangement terminated as a groupingof less important currencies—including some non-EU currencies(notably those of the Nordic states)—around the deutschmark in a‘deutschmark zone’. This unhappy experience was to influence theEMS in a number of ways. Besides colouring initial attitudes ofscepticism (e.g., no pretensions to monetary union were present inthe deliberations leading to the establishment of the system—butsee Jenkins, 1978), it bred a determination to avoid a repetition ofthe mistakes of the Snake and profoundly influenced the preciseprovisions of the EMS, as detailed below.

THE KEY PROVISIONS OF THE EUROPEANMONETARY SYSTEM

The EMS began operation on March 13, 1979, its membershipcomprising all those countries which were then members of theEU, including Britain. It has since been expanded to incorporateGreece, Spain and Portugal. The core of the system, however,consists of those member countries which participate in itsexchange rate mechanism (ERM), which Britain declined to do until1990 (Spain and Portugal both joined within five years of accedingto the EU in 1986). The provisions of the EMS are basically four-fold (see Bank of England, 1990):

Page 68: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

THE EUROPEAN MONETARY SYSTEM

51

1 a set of provisions regarding exchange rates;2 a supporting set of provisions regarding access to credit

facilities;3 a common currency of denomination, the European Currency

Unit (ECU); and4 special provision for a ‘divergence indicator’ the purpose of

which is to impose a symmetrical adjustment process.

The most important feature of the ERM is that a member shouldintervene to maintain its currency’s bilateral exchange rate againstevery other country within a target band-±2.25% of central paritybetween 1979 and 1993, increased to ±15% in August 1993. Thisobligation is symmetrical, applying equally to the weak and to thestrong currency. Exceptionally, Italy (later to be joined by Spain in1989 and Britain and Portugal in 1990) negotiated a wider band offluctuation for its currency of ±6%, which the Italians only cededfor the then regular EMS band in January 1990. The central paritiescan be renegotiated in realignments, in collaboration with all otherERM members.

As intervention in the foreign exchange markets is obligatory toprevent a cur rency from breaking through its bands,corresponding credit provisions are also obligatory and the issuerof the hard currency is required to lend—without limit—to theissuer of the weak currency for purposes of intervention at themargin. The most important component of the credit mechanismis the socalled Very Short Term Financing Facility (VSTF),repayment under which was initially required within 45 days.Finally, central banks also pool 20% of their gold and foreignexchange reserves in exchange for ECU in a central fund, theEuropean Monetary Cooperation Fund (EMCF), which has beensuperseded since January 1994 by the Frankfurt-based EuropeanMonetary Institute—see Chapters 4 and 5.

The identity of the EMS was enhanced, as contrasted with thatof the Snake, by the provision for a common currency, the ECU.The ECU is a literal composite currency, consisting of a fixedquantity of French francs, German deutschmarks and so on.Table2.2 lists the current currency composition of the ECU afterthe revisions made to accommodate the new currencies (the pesetaand the escudo) in September 1989. (The composition is chosen sothat the respective currency weights in the ECU broadly reflect anaverage of their shares in the EU’s GDP and trade.) The ECU is

Page 69: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

MICHAEL ARTIS AND NIGEL M.HEALEY

52

used as the currency of denomination for EU transactions (e.g., forthe EU Budget, farm support prices, etc.) and the central exchangerates of the ERM currencies are expressed in ECU.

It is easy enough to imagine a set-up in which the central ratesfor the bilateral parity ‘grid’ were denominated, not in ECU, butsimply in national currencies; but the ECU, or a device like it, isnecessary to underpin the divergence indicator. The central functionof the divergence indicator is to enforce symmetry in adjustment.Recall that, when originally established, the bilateral limit was set at±2.25%. The divergence indicator for a currency is allowed todeviate from all the other currencies by three-quarters of the widthof the target band; i.e., 0.75×2.25%=1.6875%. Because theindicator is dominated in ECU—an artificial currency unit which iscomposed of the individual EMS currencies—when a currencyappreciates (or depreciates) by x% against the other eleven, itsvalue against the ECU changes by only (1-w)x%, where w is thecurrency’s weight in the value of the ECU (see Table 2.2). Thus,the divergence indicator will be triggered when a currency’s ECUvalue has moved by more than (1-w)×1.6875%; the larger thecurrency’s weight in the ECU, the smaller the permitted deviationagainst the ECU (thus the deutschmark’s ECU value does not haveto move so far from its central parity as, say, the Irish punt,

Table 2.2 The composition of the ECU (since 1989)

Source: EC Commission

Page 70: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

THE EUROPEAN MONETARY SYSTEM

53

because the weight of the former in the ECU—at around 35%—ismuch higher than the weight of the latter—at around 1%).

The reason the ECU (or something like it) is essential to thenotion of a divergence indicator is simply that some means of‘adding-up’ the currencies is necessary to give force to the idea ofone currency ‘diverging’, not simply from some other individualcurrency, but from all the others together. This concept of singlingout a particular currency and forcing the presumption ofadjustment upon it whatever the direction of its deviation (i.e.,weak or strong) through the device of the divergence indicator wasgreeted at the time of the inception of the system as a radical newinnovation, promising a correction of the bias against weakcurrency countries which most analysts had come to regard asendemic in fixed exchange rates systems (see especially Chapter 3).More directly, it was an attempt to free the EMS from thedominance of the strong deutschmark which was seen as one ofthe ingredients of the Snake disaster. Principle and practice are twoquite different things however. In some critical ways, the operationof the system as it turned out denied the expectations of itsfounders. We now turn to discuss the experience of the EMS inpractice.

THE EUROPEAN MONETARY SYSTEM AS ACRAWLING PEG, 1979–83

The early years of the EMS featured a number of realignments ofcentral parities. Table 2.3 shows the dates and sizes involved of allthe realignments undertaken to date, from which the concentrationin the early years is more than obvious. The frequency of the initialrealignments was rather unexpected and gave the lie to those whohad foreseen that the EMS would be one of rigidly fixed exchangerates. Indeed, the frequency with which realignments occurredprovoked the description of the EMS as a mere ‘crawling peg’. Thiswas a reference to the concept devised by Williamson (1965) of anexchange rate system in which real rates of exchange (i.e., nominalexchange rates adjusted for differential national inflation rates—seeAppendix A) would be kept constant by changing nominal rates inline with inflation differentials (see also Holtham, 1989). Uncoveredinterest parity (see Appendix B) would imply in such a case thatinterest rate differentials would match the inflation differentials,which themselves would indicate the expected rates of change of

Page 71: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

Tabl

e 2.

3 C

entr

al r

ates

aga

inst

the

EC

U (

natio

nal

curr

ency

uni

ts p

er E

CU

)

Page 72: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

Sour

ce: E

urop

ean

Eco

nom

y.

Page 73: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

MICHAEL ARTIS AND NIGEL M.HEALEY

56

the nominal exchange rates. Such a system would protect countries’competitiveness (their real exchange rates), but would accommodateinflation. At the time, inflation differentials were indeed high andcountries found it easy to resort to realignments to ape a crawlingpeg arrangement.

This phase of the EMS proved temporary as countries began toadopt a more determined counter-inflationary policy stance; but thepace at which countries adopted this new determination varied fromone to another, so for the system as a whole, the switch was agradual one. A more determined counter-inflationary postureimplied using a commitment to a fixed exchange rate as a means oftaking the steam out of domestic inflationary pressures, losingcompetitiveness if necessary while these pressures subsided. At theEMS level, this change of emphasis was recognised in thetransformation of realignments into multilateral decisions, which forthe smaller countries, at least, implied a stronger discipline ondevalua-tionist tendencies; at the country level, the key indicator ofthe change of emphasis was the decision taken by France early in1983 to undertake severe measures of retrenchment to squeezeinflation out of the economy. This was quite critical for, at thetime, the option of leaving the EMS altogether was a real one forFrance—one which the Mitterand administration recognised andrejected. But for this decision, the future of the EMS would havebeen quite different.

THE ‘OLD EUROPEAN MONETARY SYSTEM’, 1983–88

The end of the ‘crawling peg’ period—which is difficult to dateprecisely because of the differing speed at which countries decidedto change their policies, but where the momentous French decisionof 1983 must stand out as a marker—gave way to a period whichwe can call the classical ‘Old EMS’. It is in this period that theoperation of the system as it has come to be generally describedsettled down.

It is convenient to summarise this period in terms of thefollowing ‘stylised facts’ concerning its operation. First,realignments became less frequent, so much so that statisticalinvestigations of the behaviour of exchange rates since thebeginning of the EMS were able to come to the conclusion thatthe system had had a stabilising effect; second, member countriesconsciously used their membership of the EMS as a means of

Page 74: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

THE EUROPEAN MONETARY SYSTEM

57

disciplining inflationary expectations and as a reason for takingpolicy action to reduce inflation; third, the desire to reduceinflation helped to make Germany the centre of the EMS—encapsulated in the suggestion that the system was, in reality, agreater deutschmark zone.

The conclusion that the EMS had a stabilising effect onexchange rates comes from statistical investigations and is one thatapplies to both nominal and real exchange rates (e.g., see vonHagen and Neumann, 1991). It applies most certainly to intra-EMSrates, less clearly to overall effective rates. A representative sampleof results, culled from an authoritative IMF study, is quoted inTable 2.4. This compares measures of exchange rate volatility forthe main ERM currencies with similar measures for the non-ERMcurrencies before and after the establishment of the system. Atendency for volatility within the ERM to decline between 1979 and1985 is clear. Moreover, whilst results quoted in Table 2.4 onlycover the period to the end of 1985, the fact that there wererelatively few realignments until 1992 indicates that the stabilisingeffect of the EMS suggested by the table can only be reinforced ifthe period 1979–92 is taken as a whole.

The stabilisation of exchange rates was accompanied by ageneral reduction of inf lation towards the German level—aconvergence on the ‘German standard’. The EMS was seen to bean important component in this achievement, not simply anincidental. The argument draws on the modern theory of‘reputational policy’ (e.g., Barro and Gordon, 1983; Backus and

Table 2.4 Exchange rate variability against ERM currencies (period means)

Source: Ungerer et al. (1986).

Page 75: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

MICHAEL ARTIS AND NIGEL M.HEALEY

58

Driffill, 1985). According to this theory, a country’s ability toreduce its inflation rate and the cost it may have to pay to do soboth depend on its ability to establish a good ‘reputation’. Agovernment which is credible (i.e., has a good reputation) is ableto make announcements about its counter-inflationary intentionswhich are believed; and, because they are believed, inflationaryexpectations are reduced and the unemployment-cost of gettinginflation down is cut. Because the cost is cut, it is easier to doand more likely to be done (Neumann, 1990). In short, reputationhas some very valuable Virtuous circle’ properties. The problem isto see how a reputation can be established (see also Chapter 5).In this respect, it is argued that membership of the EMS may behelpful. Membership implies maintaining an exchange rate which isat least ‘fair ly-f ixed’ against low-inf lation Germany; thiscommitment is very visible and easy for people to monitor andunderstand and, to this extent, a government which participates inthe EMS may be well on the way to making a good reputation foritself; i.e. it may be able to ‘import’ the Bundesbank’s reputation.So put, the argument clearly requires the dominance of Germanyas the rationale for the system and this invites the familiardescription of the EMS as a ‘deutschmark zone’.

There are some respects in which this description of the ‘OldEMS’ seemed well justified. For, although all the formal provisionsof the EMS are symmetrical, it was noticeable that Germanysterilised the effect of foreign exchange intervention to a greaterextent than other countries, thus pursuing its own independentmonetary policy; equally, foreign exchange intervention was itselfalmost all conducted ‘intra-marginally’ (i.e., before the exchange ratehit the band) and by countries other than Germany. Germany neverdevalued against any other currency in any realignment and thedivergence indicator fell into disuse (see Bank of England, 1991;Meade, 1990). It is easy to see that when the name of the policygame is the reduction of inflation, the divergence indicator wouldbecome useless—it would be inconsistent to ask Germany to raiseits inflation rate towards the average in the name of symmetrywhen the overriding purpose of policy was to cut inflation (Healey,1993a).

However, as an offset to German dominance in this periodcountries could recourse to two protective devices. First, theycould—within limits, for realignments had become multilateraldecisions—realign their currencies. Second, they could rely upon

Page 76: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

THE EUROPEAN MONETARY SYSTEM

59

exchange controls over capital flows to permit a degree of decou-pling of domestic monetary policy from German monetary policy.

THE ‘NEW EMS’, 1988–92

It was the decision to remove capital exchange controls under theprovisions of the ‘1992’ project (see Chapters 7 and 8)—con-sciously accepted by 1987—which, as much as anything, marks thebeginning of the ‘New EMS’. The removal of these controls, it wasfelt, would have two effects. First, it would oblige countries tofollow the lead of Germany more closely than ever; second, itwould make realignments a risky business which could expose thesystem to destructive speculation. It was not difficult to recall thatthe end of the Bretton Woods system had been marked by massivespeculative capital flows, triggered by expectations of exchange raterealignments.

Recognising these consequences, measures were taken tostrengthen the system’s ability to deal with speculation in thesocalled ‘Basle-Nyborg’ agreements in 1987, as a result of whichthe credit provisions—which hitherto had applied only tointervention at the margins—were extended in scope and made toapply also to intra-marginal intervention. Concurrently, therepayment period under the VSTF was extended from 45 to 60days. At the same time it was resolved that there should be a closercoordination of monetary policies and that realignments, if theyoccurred, should be small in scope—so that the central rate and thebands could be changed without causing a discrete movement in themarket rate.

Such was the early success of these measures that, between 1988and 1992, the system was widely believed to suffer from a problemof ‘excess credibility’ (see Davies, 1989). The symptom of this‘problem’ was that for much of this period, the strongest currenciesin the EMS were the highest inflation currencies, notably the Spanishpeseta and the Italian lira. Because these member states wereattempting to address their inflation problems by deploying highrates of interest and their currencies were seen as less likely to bedevalued than under the ‘Old EMS’, high interest rates forced thesecurrencies towards the top of their bands. This unac-customedposition posed a policy problem. If they were not to allow theircurrencies to go through the top of the band, the governments ofthe high inflation countries had either to:

Page 77: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

MICHAEL ARTIS AND NIGEL M.HEALEY

60

1 relax their fight against inflation; or2 substitute fiscal for monetary policy; or3 deliberately create the impression that devaluation might occur;

or4 introduce administrative measures which would deter capital

inflows (see van der Ploeg, 1989).

THE CURRENCY UPHEAVALS OF 1992–93

The phenomenon of high inflation countries choosing to followGermany’s anti-inflationary example, rather than devaluing againstthe deutschmark (or leaving the ERM altogether) became known as‘German policy leadership’. While this feature of the ERM wasentirely unintended, by the end of the last decade, it had come tobe regarded as the system’s greatest attraction. Germany provided astrong, anti-inflationary anchor for Europe. By setting domesticinterest rates at whatever level was necessary to maintain theirexchange rates within their target bands against the deutschmark,other ERM states could effectively be guaranteed that their inflationrates would come down to low German levels. For countries (likeBritain) which had unsuccessfully experimented with monetarytargets and were left with no clear guide for monetary policy, ERMmembership thus offered the prospect of both greater exchangerate stability and, perhaps more importantly, low and stable inflationrates (Healey, 1990).

After the débâcle of the ill-fated ‘Lawson boom’, when broadmonetary growth was allowed to accelerate to almost 25% p.a. andinflation reached 10%, there is no question that a key motive inBritain’s entry to the ERM in October 1990 was a desire to bringdown inflation. Critics of previous British policy welcomed ERMmembership as a transfer of monetary sovereignty to theBundesbank. The Bundesbank, they argued, was politicallyindependent; ERM membership meant British policy being made bythe Bundesbank, which was immune from the pressures that hadgiven rise to Britain’s unhappy experience of ‘stop-go’ policies anda high, underlying rate of inflation.

However, while being one of its most attractive features, theGerman anti-inflation anchor also created a ‘fault-line’ in thesystem (see Healey, 1993a, 1993b). The Bundesbank’s knownhostility to unlimited intervention in support of weak currenciesmeant that currencies which fell to their trading floors were

Page 78: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

THE EUROPEAN MONETARY SYSTEM

61

vulnerable to speculative attack. In other words, the ERM paritieswere simply not credible. During the 1980s, German policyleadership became steadily established, but the significance of thefaultline was not fully realised for two reasons. First, until 1990almost all the ERM members maintained some form of capitalcontrols, which placed legislative restrictions on capital movementsand artificially limited the scale of a speculative attack on a weakcurrency. Second, the business cycles of the EU economies werebroadly synchronised during the 1980s, so that the policyadjustments necessary for other countries to follow the Germanlead and keep comfortably within their target bands against thedeutschmark were relatively painless.

Unfortunately, Britain’s entry (with a much higher inflation ratethan the other ERM states) coincided with both the abolition ofcapital controls and the reunification of Germany. In order tocontrol mounting inflationary pressures, the Bundesbank was forcedto adopt a much tighter monetary stance, at a time whendeflationary pressures were already intensifying in other EU states(notably Britain, France and Italy). The protection that capitalcontrols had given to weak currencies was thus removed just as thecosts (in terms of higher unemployment and lost output) offollowing the German policy lead were temporarily increased. Thosecountries which could not, or would not, continue to matchGerman monetary policy accordingly became increasingly vulnerableto speculative attack, as high German interest rates forced theircurrencies towards their trading floors. For Britain in particular,international investors watched as growing political pressure toaddress the recession forced the government into a series ofinterest rate cuts between October 1990 and September 1992,despite the fact that German rates were rising over the sameperiod. In the immediate run-up to Black Wednesday, clear signalsgiven by the Bundesbank—to the effect that it regarded sterling asover-valued at DM2.95 due to a premature relaxation of Britishmonetary policy—contributed to a massive speculative attack onsterling which (despite a 5% interest rate rise on September 16,1992) drove the pound below its floor and culminated in its formalsuspension from the ERM. The Italian lira was forced out at thesame time and a series of devaluations by the remaining weakercurrencies failed to settle the financial markets, eventually forcingthe EU to introduce ultra-wide ±15% bands in August 1993 tohead off a politically embarrassing devaluation of the French franc.

Page 79: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

MICHAEL ARTIS AND NIGEL M.HEALEY

62

CONCLUSIONS

The Bundesbank’s refusal to guarantee unlimited, unsterilisedintervention in support of weak currencies meant that the ERM hasalways been potentially vulnerable to speculative attack. However,during the 1980s, this fault-line was disguised by the presence ofcapital controls and the synchronisation of business cycles amongstthe ERM states. At the same time, the Bundesbank’suncompromising stance provided a valuable anti-inflation anchor forthose countries that followed the German policy lead. As more andmore member states chose to match Germany’s monetary leadrather than opt for devaluation and continuing inflation, Germanybecame the anchor for the ERM as a whole. This dimension of theERM was widely regarded as its most attractive feature and wasundoubtedly one of the main factors that lay behind Britain’s entryin October 1990. In this sense, it was clearly disingenuous for theBritish government to claim that the ERM is flawed by a fault-line,in the shape of the Bundesbank’s unwillingness to aid overvaluedcurrencies, since it was the obverse of this fault-line (i.e., Germanpolicy leadership) that induced the government to join in the firstplace.

On the other hand, developments since 1990, notably theabolition of capital controls and German reunification, haveserved to make this fault-line in the EMS much more significant.In retrospect, given the inflation rate at which Britain entered thesystem and the scale of the recession into which the economy wassliding, it is difficult to see that the ERM as it then existed couldhave managed to embrace sterling for any length of time. In theabsence of capital controls and given the scale of internationalcapital movements, orderly devaluations would have provedimpractical: after the first, the confidence of the market wouldhave been so severely dented that subsequent speculative attackswould have occurred at any sign of sterling weakness. It issignificant in this regard that several of those states (e.g., Spain,Portugal, Ireland) which have devalued within the framework ofthe ERM since September 1992 have either retained or reimposedcapital controls. The importance that the French governmentascribed to its ‘franc fort’ policy, silencing any serious political talkof devaluation, reflects its view that unless devaluation is regardedas unthinkable, a speculative attack on the franc will beoverwhelming.

Page 80: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

THE EUROPEAN MONETARY SYSTEM

63

Against the background of the analysis outlined above, the EUnow finds itself in something of a quandary. The ERM’s widelyacknowledged success in stabilising exchange rates and bringingdown inflation in the EU in the 1980s was primarily due to theunplanned emergence of German policy leadership. Yet this featureof the system created a fault-line, which means that weakercurrencies will always be vulnerable to irresistible speculative attack.Given that the EU is committed (under both the Treaty of Romeand the Single European Act) to the free movement of capital,which seems to preclude the restoration of widespread capitalcontrols, it is difficult to see how the EU will be able to recreatethe ‘monetary stability’ enjoyed in the late 1980s in the near-to-medium term. It is to be hoped that, as the effects of Germanreunification slowly dissipate, the business cycles across the EU willmove sufficiently into line to make German policy leadership onceagain acceptable to the higher inf lation states. It is to aconsideration of the prospects for EMU that Chapters 4–6 turn(see also Temperton, 1993; Currie, 1991; Collignon, 1994).

APPENDIX A: THE REAL EXCHANGE RATE

Economists have several theories to explain the long-run,equilibrium value of a currency, but all are essentially variations onan old theme, namely the concept of purchasing power parity(PPP). In its simplest form, the PPP theory states that, inequilibrium, the purchasing power of £1 in Britain should be equalto that of its deutschmark equivalent in German, its dollarequivalent in the United States and so on. For example, if bakedbeans were the only commodity purchased in Britain and Germanyand the prices in each country were £0.25 and DM0.75 respectively,then the equilibrium exchange rate that ensured PPP would beDM3/£ (i.e., DM0.75/£0.25). At this exchange rate, £1 would buythe same quantity of baked beans (four cans) as its deutschmarkequivalent (DM3) in Germany.

At this exchange rate, moreover, producers in Britain andGermany would be equally competitive, with neither having an edgeover the other by virtue of an advantageous exchange rate. If theexchange rate were lower than DM3/1, for example, Britishproducers could undercut their German rivals, leading to a currentaccount surplus in Britain; and vice versa. This is a crucial point,for what underpins the PPP theory is the proposition that, in the

Page 81: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

MICHAEL ARTIS AND NIGEL M.HEALEY

64

long run, the current account must be in balance. Countries withovervalued exchange rates cannot finance current account deficitsindefinitely by borrowing from overseas and, at some point, theirexchange rates must fall to the equilibrium (PPP) value consistentwith current account balance.

These same ideas can be expressed with reference to the ‘realexchange rate’. As the name suggests, the real exchange rate is thenominal exchange rate (e.g., DM3/£) adjusted for prices in the twocountries concerned. The real exchange rate is defined as:

ERr=ER×P/P* where ERr is the real exchange rate, ER is the nominal exchangerate, P is the domestic price level and P* is the foreign price level.For the simplified, baked beans example used above, the realexchange rate would be:

ERr=DM3.00/£1×£0.25/DM0.75

ERr=1.00 In other words, when the PPP condition is fulfilled, the realexchange rate is unity. A real exchange rate above one suggests that,given the prevailing price levels in the two countries, the nominalexchange rate is too high; that is, the currency is overvalued, itscurrent account will be in deficit and its exchange rate will tend tofall in the long run; and vice versa for a real exchange rate belowone. To give a real-world example, when sterling entered the ERMin October 1990, inflation in Britain was much higher than inGermany. Although the gap subsequently closed, in the interimprices in Britain (expressed at the former DM2.95/£ exchange rate)climbed above those in Germany (and other EU countries). Inother words, between entry to the ERM in 1990 and sterling’sultimate withdrawal in 1992, the real exchange rate rose sharply (seeFigure 2.2). Evidence that sterling was overvalued at its formerERM parity, in the sense that British producers were finding itincreasingly difficult to compete on price with their German (andother European) rivals, was reflected in the trade figures. Despitethe severity of the recession, Britain still had a current accountdeficit of £12bn in 1992.

Page 82: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

THE EUROPEAN MONETARY SYSTEM

65

APPENDIX B: UNCOVERED INTEREST PARITY

PPP considerations play a central role in shaping the foreignexchange market’s view of which currencies (like the pound) areovervalued, leading speculators to sell, and which are undervaluedand therefore an attractive buy. But PPP is only part of the story.Casual observation reveals that, even when central banks do notintervene to support an overvalued currency (or hold down anundervalued currency) with open-market operations, exchange ratescan deviate from their PPP values for long periods. The missingvariable in the equation is the interest rate. When currencies areovervalued, rational investors will expect their value to fall overtime, resulting in a capital loss. All other things equal, thisexpectation will lead them to sell the currency until it eventuallyfalls to its PPP value. But suppose the interest rate obtainable ondeposits in this currency is higher than those on other currencies.If the interest differential in favour of the overvalued currency issufficiently high to fully compensate investors for the expectedcapital loss, the currency will remain at its overvalued exchange ratein the absence of central bank intervention.

The relationship between interest rates and exchange rates can be

Figure 2.2 Real effective sterling exchange rateSource: Goldman Sachs.

Page 83: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

MICHAEL ARTIS AND NIGEL M.HEALEY

66

summarised using a simple example. Suppose an investor has £X toinvest. If she invests in a sterling deposit, she will receive £X(1+r);that is, the principal, £X, plus interest of £Xr, where r is theBritish rate of interest over the term of the deposit. Alternatively,she might switch the money into deutschmarks at the presentexchange rate, ER, and invest in deutschmark deposits which willyield an amount DM(ER×£X)(1+r*), where DM(ER×£X) is theoriginal deutschmark deposit and DM(ER×£Xr*) is the interestreceived on the deposit at the German rate of interest, r*.

Whether she believes that the latter option will give her a higheror lower return, in sterling terms, depends on the exchange rate sheexpects to prevail at the time the deutschmark deposit is to bewithdrawn and converted back into pounds. Her expectation of thefuture exchange rate, ERe, in turn, will be influenced by: (i) theexchange rate consistent with PPP in the long run (which may beabove or below the present exchange rate); and (ii) if the exchangerate is being pegged, the perceived likelihood of the governmentrealigning the exchange rate to a level more in line with the PPPrate.

If, for example, there is an interest differential in favour ofsterling which exceeds (in percentage terms) the amount by whichshe expects the pound to fall, she will invest in a sterling deposit.Conversely, if the interest differential is insufficient to compensatethe expected capital loss, she will sell sterling and switch into adeutschmark deposit. She will be indifferent between the twooptions only if:

£X(1+r)=DM(ER×£X)(1+r*)/ERe

That is, if:

ER/ERe=(1+r)/(l+r*) If ER is greater than ERe, in equilibrium the expected rate ofdepreciation of the currency, ER/ERe, must be equal to the interestdifferential in favour of the currency, (1+r)/(1+r*). Investors canprofit by switching between currencies whenever this equilibriumcondition is not satisfied. However, by so doing, their transactionsquickly eliminate the opportunities which initially inspired them. Forexample, if ER/ERe were greater than (1+r)/(1+r*), investorswould en masse choose to invest in deutschmark rather than sterling

Page 84: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

THE EUROPEAN MONETARY SYSTEM

67

deposits. The excess demand for deutschmarks would push downsterling’s value, ER, until the expected depreciation, ER/ERe, fellinto line with the interest differential. Conversely, if ER/ERe wereless than (1+r)(1+r*), investors would buy sterling, pushing up thevalue of sterling until ER/ERe rose into line with the interestdifferential.

This review of the role of the rate of interest reveals two keypoints. First, it illustrates why, if countries run divergent monetarypolicies that result in different interest rates, currencies may bepersistently under- or overvalued. And second, it demonstrates whychanges in interest rates exert such a significant and immediateeffect on the present exchange rate: in the equation above, anychange in either r or r* will cause an instantaneous change in ERfor a given ERe.

Page 85: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

68

3

FIXED EXCHANGE RATES ANDDEFLATION

The European Monetary System and theGold Standard

Jonathan Michie and Michael Kitson

INTRODUCTION

As noted in Chapter 1, there is now a widespread belief that the‘European project’ has been blown off course, if not sunkcompletely. In light of the apparent divide between Europe’selectorate and what might be termed—or what at least gives theimpression of being—the political elite, it is interesting to evaluatethe economic policy agenda of the past few years, dominated as ithas been by the Maastricht Treaty and the unsuccessful attempt totransform the exchange rate mechanism (ERM) into a permanentlyinflexible system, in light of Keynes’s 1925 evaluation of TheEconomic Consequences of Mr Churchill:

The gold standard, with its dependence on pure chance, its faithin ‘automatic adjustments’, and its general regardlessness ofsocial detail, is an essential emblem and idol of those who sit inthe top tier of the machine. I think that they are immensely rashin their regardlessness, in their vague optimism and comfortablebelief that nothing really serious ever happens. Nine times out often, nothing really serious does happen—merely a little distressto individuals or to groups. But we run a risk of the tenth time(and are stupid into the bargain), if we continue to apply theprinciples of an economics, which was worked out on thehypotheses of laissez-faire and free competition, to a society whichis rapidly abandoning these hypotheses.

(Keynes, 1925)

Page 86: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

FIXED EXCHANGE RATES AND DEFLATION

69

Certainly, we would argue that the governments of the EuropeanUnion (EU) did pursue deflationary policies in the early years ofthe 1990s, exacerbated by the operation of the ERM (see alsoChapter 2). The resulting unemployment should have come as nosurprise. Further, we would argue that these policies were in somerespects similar to those pursued under the gold standard of the1920s, with parallel results in terms of deflationary governmenteconomic policies and the creation of mass unemployment. Itseems that nothing has been learned. Finally, we argue in thischapter that the world economy only managed to pull itself out ofthe Great Depression in the 1930s by abandoning fixed exchangerates, cutting interest rates and employing independent nationalmonetary policies.

THE GOLD STANDARD

From the mid-1920s, the cornerstone of international economicmanagement was the gold standard. Founded on the questionablesuccess of the classical gold standard in operation during thequarter-century before World War I, the 1920s’ variant was intendedto bring stability to international trading relations and increaseworld prosperity. It failed to achieve these objectives. Its actualeffect was to depress real variables such as output and employmentand undermine the capacity of individual governments to deal withdomestic economic problems.

The adjustment process integral to the gold standard created asevere deflationary bias for the world economy. To capture thisbias, the main trading countries can be broadly classified into those‘constrained’ and those ‘unconstrained’ by their trade performance.Those countries that could maintain a sufficient level of exports,relative to imports, at a high level of economic activity were notbalance of payments constrained. Such countries could pursueeasier monetary policies or could accumulate increased reserves.Conversely, a country that could not maintain balance of paymentsequilibrium at a high level of economic activity had to reducedomestic demand in order to import only those goods and serviceswhich it could afford to finance.

The two key unconstrained countries were France and the UnitedStates. France recovered successfully from World War I, with anundervalued exchange rate helping to generate export-led growth.The United States had become the world’s leading economy during

Page 87: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

JONATHAN MICHIE AND MICHAEL KITSON

70

the late nineteenth century. Its strength was based on huge naturalresources of land and minerals, sustained investment which hadsignificantly raised its capital stock, a large internal market and thedevelopment of an industrial structure that encouraged research anddevelopment and the exploitation of economies of scale.

The two major constrained countries were Britain and Germany,both of which emerged from the aftermath of war with severeeconomic problems. The British economy had been in relativedecline since the 1870s. In addition, the commitment to return togold necessitated tight monetary policies and the economy suffereda severe slump in 1920–21. The German economy, which had beenrapidly expanding from the 1880s, was devastated by World War I.It lost financial and physical assets and reparations constituted acontinual drain on its income and wealth. The reconstructed goldstandard, therefore, created a fixed exchange rate regime withmembers at different stages of economic development withdifferent economic structures and different economic problems. Itsprospects were not good.

WHAT PRICE AUTOMATIC ADJUSTMENT?

To be effective, the gold standard depended on a process ofautomatic adjustment to correct payments imbalances. Under thissystem, the price level would adjust in response to deficits andsurpluses on the balance of payments. A deficit would lead to aloss of gold and a contraction in the money supply, leading to afall in prices, a reduction in the real exchange rate (see Chapter 2,Appendix A) and the eradication of the deficit. Similarly, a surpluswould lead to an accumulation of gold, a rise in the money supplyand prices and hence a return to a balance of paymentsequilibrium. But the real world did not work like this. The theorywas based on various unrealistic assumptions, including theassumption that all the burden of adjustment would be borne bychanges in prices rather than in changes in quantities produced.

As the main trading nations entered the exchange rate systemwith different initial conditions, it was apparent that the efficacy ofthe adjustment process would be central to the regime’s impact. Theoption of adjusting the nominal exchange rate was effectivelyprecluded. The adjustment of the real exchange was slow anderratic. For Britain, most studies indicate a significant averageovervaluation of the sterling effective exchange rate in the period

Page 88: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

FIXED EXCHANGE RATES AND DEFLATION

71

1925–31. Keynes’s contemporary estimate of a 10% overvaluationhas proved to be a reasonable approximation of recent empiricalestimates. The result was lower growth and higher unemployment.Conventionally, it had been assumed that the unravelling of theprice-quantity adjustment process would eventually return theeconomy to its previous position with only a temporary loss ofoutput and jobs. However, the legacy of slow growth in factlowered the long-run capacity of the economy itself.

The sluggishness of real exchange rate changes left twoadjustment alternatives: (i) changes in the level of demand—deflation in constrained countries and reflation in surplus countries;or (ii) the financing of the deficits of constrained countries bycapital flows from the unconstrained countries. In fact, the ultimateburden of adjustment was borne by domestic deflation. The surpluscountries were reluctant to reflate. The classical adjustmentmechanism assumes that gold flows will provide the means ofchanging the level of demand via prices. But price adjustment wasslow, and the reflationary impact of gold flows into France and theUnited States were negated (i.e., sterilised) by domestic monetarypolicy. Both countries, which by the late 1920s had between themaccumulated 60% of total gold reserves, prevented these reservesfrom boosting their domestic money supplies. Americanpolicymakers were increasingly concerned with curbing stock marketspeculation, whereas the French were wary of inflation. Deflationwas transmitted abroad. Low import demand, particularly inAmerica, led to widening balance of payments deficits in many ofthe key European economies.

The unconstrained countries’ export growth was reasonable andclose to the 5.7% growth of world trade. Additionally, due totheir reluctance to reflate, they were able to maintain large balanceof payments surpluses throughout the 1920s. During 1925–29,France maintained a surplus that averaged over 2% of grossdomestic product (GDP), while the US surplus averaged justunder 1% of GDP. The US surplus was particularly significantgiven the size of its economy, averaging 2.5% of world tradecompared to 1% for the French. The growth of world trade wastherefore limited by the domestic policies of the unconstrainedcountries. Whereas these nations could choose whether or not toreflate, the constrained countries had no such options. The entireburden of adjustment fell on them—they could either deflate toeradicate balance of payments deficits or they could borrow to

Page 89: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

JONATHAN MICHIE AND MICHAEL KITSON

72

fund them. The effective approach of the British economy wasthe former and Germany the latter.

Deflation could be achieved either through allowing reserves toflow out, depressing the money supply and domestic expenditure—the classical mechanism—or by policies that directly affected thecomponents of demand. In Britain, it was interest rates that actedas the key deflationary tool. From 1923, there was a trend rise inthe Bank of England’s discount rate as the authorities adoptedpolicies consistent with the return and maintenance of the exchangerate at the prewar parity. At the same time the general trend ofother central banks’ discount rates was downward. The deflationaryimpact of such policies helped to keep the overall balance ofpayments (i.e., on current and capital accounts) in surplus andprevented the loss of gold.

The Bank of England also deployed gold market and foreignexchange operations to maintain its stock of international reserves.The impact on the real economy was slow growth, with theeconomy failing to reap its growth potential (for more detail, seeKitson and Solomou, 1990). Despite the level of GDP in 1924being below that of 1913, the growth rate of the British economywas significantly below the world average. Unemployment remainedpersistently high, averaging 7.5% for the period 1924–29.

Unlike Britain, Germany maintained a persistent balance ofpayments deficit throughout the 1920s. Along with reparations thisdeficit had to be financed and Germany became heavily reliant onforeign loans, particularly from the United States. Although initiallyable to attract sizeable capital inflows, the rising debt burdenundermined creditworthiness. Germany became increasingly relianton short-term funds and by 1931 had accumulated net foreigndebts equivalent to 25% of GDP. The subsequent concern aboutthe German economy and the collapse of American lending abroadfrom 1928 led to capital flight, the loss of reserves, a creditsqueeze and the raising of interest rates. Germany had been able tocope with its balance of payments constraint in the short term byborrowing; ultimately, however, this only postponed the requirementto deflate.

The asymmetry in the adjustment processes showed in therelative trade performance of the two groups of countries duringthe ‘successful’ operation of the gold standard. The trading positionof the constrained countries, Britain and Germany, differedsignificantly to that of the unconstrained countries. Although

Page 90: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

FIXED EXCHANGE RATES AND DEFLATION

73

Britain managed to maintain a balance of payments surplus, itsexport performance was poor, exhibiting slow growth and adeclining share of world markets. Britain’s share of world marketsin 1929 was 3.2% below its 1913 level—the result of an averageannual decline of 1.6%. The German trading position was also in aprecarious position, the deficit on the balance of paymentsaveraging 1.2% of GDP between 1925 and 1929. Germany’s exportgrowth was rapid during this period, but this was catching-up froma very low postwar base and was boosted by enforced exportsthrough reparations in kind. Despite this rapid growth, Germany’sshare of world exports in 1929 was more than 25% below its 1913level.

THE DEFLATIONARY BIAS OF FIXED EXCHANGERATE REGIMES

Thus the deflationary bias of the gold standard not only failed todeal with the structural problems of constrained countries, itpositively accentuated them. Countries which had entered thesystem with major structural problems left the system weakened, asthey had to bear the burden of adjustment by deflating theirdomestic economies. This not only lowered growth and raisedunemployment; it also hampered long-run competitiveness. Thedampening of domestic demand reduced the benefits of massproduction and the exploitation of scale economies. Deflation tomaintain external equilibrium raised unit costs and generated afurther loss of competitiveness and declining shares of worldmarkets. Such a process of cumulative causation led the constrainedcountries to suffer a vicious cycle of stagnation. Locked into afixed exchange rate system, there were few policy options to reversethe process.

If the gold standard failed to maximise world growth in the1920s, its shortcomings were also evident with the onset of theGreat Depression. The causes of the Great Depression are subjectto continual debate, but key factors were certainly the cumulativeimpact of structural problems, adverse demand shocks and policymistakes. One such policy mistake was the constrained countries’adherence to gold. The severity of the Great Depression cancertainly be attributed to the operation of the gold standard—theimpact of adverse shocks, such as the recession in the United Statesand the collapse in capital exports, were transmitted to the rest of

Page 91: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

JONATHAN MICHIE AND MICHAEL KITSON

74

the world through the exchange rate regime. As foreign loans werecalled in due to developments in the domestic economy, the goldflows to the United States increased. The draining of reserves inthe debtor countries accelerated and monetary policy was tightenedto ensure gold convertibility. Thus the deflationary bias of the goldstandard system resulted in a perverse reaction to adverse demandshocks. Rather than facilitating an expansion of demand toameliorate the depression, the system magnified the problem leadingto a collapse in world trade and a sharp rise in globalunemployment (see Figure 3.1).

As countries moved into recession, they needed the capacity toinitiate domestic policies in order to insulate themselves from thecollapse in the world economy. The structure, characteristics andpaths of development of the major economies were different andthus the timing and the composition of the policy mix required wasalso different. The phasing of the depression of the majorcountries differed: there was approximately a three-year gapbetween the onset of decline in Germany and that in Denmark. Yetduring this period, economic policy was constrained by the goldstandard, leaving little flexibility to deal quickly with domesticproblems.

Figure 3.1 World employment and unemployment, 1929–38Notes: (1) Employment index excludes the USSR. (2) Unemployment seriesis the average of two series (A and B) presented in ILO (1940).Source: ILO (1940) Table 3.

Page 92: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

FIXED EXCHANGE RATES AND DEFLATION

75

The impact of the Great Depression also varied acrosscountries: GDP in the United States collapsed by an annual ratein excess of 10% between 1929 and 1932, whereas other countriessuch as Denmark and Norway witnessed little or no decline. Inpart these variations reflected the speed with which countries leftgold, although another major factor was the difference ineconomic structures and institutions. Britain’s relatively moderatedepression, an annual decline of less than 2% compared to aworld average of over 6%, in part reflected the low dependenceon agriculture and the stability of its financial institutions. Thus,shocks had different national and sectoral impacts. Binding nationstogether in a fixed exchange rate regime made no allow-ance forthis.

The interwar gold standard system was structurally f lawed.Even if cooperation between countries had managed to limit thedeflationary bias, it would most likely have only extended the lifeof the system rather than preventing its ultimate demise. Indeed,had the system lasted longer, it might have resulted in a greaterdivergence in growth performance. Reflation in the strongercountries could well have led to faster growth of output andproductivity, leading to a virtuous cycle of growth, but withdeflation limiting the growth potential of the relatively weakercountries. Also, the system combined together countries withdifferent economic conditions and problems. These problems werenot eradicated by the regime; rather they were accentuated.Discretion over the use of monetary, fiscal and exchange ratepolicy was removed. And finally, the regime was not able toaccommodate adverse economic shocks to the system; on thecontrary, the operation of the international monetary systemmagnified the impact of any such recessionary forces. The regimewas inappropriate for members with different economic structuresand a recession phased differ-ently amongst the internationalcommunity (see Chapters 4 and 5 for a discussion of theimplications of monetary union for countries vulnerable toasymmetric shocks).

The extent and magnitude of the Great Depression put the goldstandard regime under severe strain. A series of financial andbalance of payments crises ultimately undermined the system,culminating in Britain’s decision to abandon the gold standard anddevalue in September 1931. This decision marked the effectivecollapse of the regime. Other countries quickly followed sterling

Page 93: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

JONATHAN MICHIE AND MICHAEL KITSON

76

off the gold standard, including most of the dominions andEmpire, the Scandinavian countries, Canada and Japan. It was notuntil March 1933 that the United States devalued, while a core ofcountries including France, Belgium and the Netherlands remainedon gold until later in the decade (see Figure 3.2). Devaluation wasnot the only uncoordinated trade policy implemented; tariffs andquotas were increased while many of the central Europeancountries including Germany and Italy resorted to extensiveexchange controls (see Chapter 2).

ECONOMIC RECOVERY IN THE 1930s: THEMECHANISMS

Devaluation can have beneficial impacts through a number ofmechanisms. First, it can directly alleviate the balance of paymentsconstraint on growth. Shifts in relative prices and improvedcompetitiveness can raise exports and depress imports. Theconventional account of this process is that it is a ‘beggar-my-neighbour’ policy (see Healey and Levine, 1992a), as the

Figure 3.2 Number of countries on gold, 1919–37Note: The three countries on gold in 1937 were on the ‘qualified goldstandard’.Source: Eichengreen (1992) Table 7.1, pp. 188–91.

Page 94: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

FIXED EXCHANGE RATES AND DEFLATION

77

improvement in trade performance is reflected in an improvingtrade balance for the initiating country and a deteriorating tradebalance for trading partners. This account, however, ignores theeffects of an independently pursued trade policy on the level ofeconomic activity. Increasing exports and reducing the propensity toimport will raise the level of demand in the domestic economy.With unemployment and excess capacity, such a policy initiative willraise output and employment as well as leading to an income-induced increase in imports, so that there need be no change in theactual trade balance. Indeed, this is precisely the reason why,although Britain devalued and adopted widespread protectionism in1931, the current account deficits persisted throughout the 1930s.If countries get locked into a pattern of trade which constrainsdomestic expansion, an active and independent trade policyprovides one means of overcoming the problem without necessarilyaffecting adversely other trading partners.

The second benefit of devaluation is that it removes theexchange rate constraint on domestic policy, encouragingexpansionist policies. In particular, monetary policy can be relaxedand therefore interest rates can be determined by domesticeconomic conditions rather than by the need to maintain theexchange rate or by the need to prevent excessive loss of reserves.For instance, Britain’s suspension of the gold standard allowed thegovernment to pursue a more expansionist policy after 1932. This‘cheap money’ policy has been identified as a permissive policy foreconomic revival, especially important in stimulating a housingboom. Conversely, the reason that the British Government’s claimson September 16, 1992 (that it would remain in the ERM by raisinginterest rates as far as was necessary) lacked credibility was thatraising interest rates by 5% in one day in the midst of the longesteconomic recession for 60 years was not believed to be a feasiblepolicy option.

Devaluation and the accompanying introduction of otherexpansionist policies also led to a third, less mechanistic, benefit.Under the prevailing world conditions of uncertainty and monetaryand financial turbulence, the reorientation of policy towards thedomestic economy improved business confidence. The prospect ofa stable and growing economy encourages home producers toincrease, or at least bring forward, investment and expandproduction.

Page 95: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

JONATHAN MICHIE AND MICHAEL KITSON

78

ECONOMIC RECOVERY IN THE 1930s: THEEVIDENCE

Although a wide range of uncoordinated policies were implementedin the 1930s, including devaluation, it is possible to classify themajor trading nations into different trade policy regimes (see Kitsonand Solomou, 1990): 1 the sterling bloc that devalued with or soon after Britain and

linked their currencies to sterling;2 other countries which also devalued either early (before 1932)

or later (1932 and after);3 the exchange control group, that was reluctant to devalue for

fear of inflation; and4 the gold bloc countries which remained, at least in the short

term, committed to the system. During the 1929–32 depression, ‘world’ output declined by morethan 6% per annum. The sterling bloc exhibited the mildestcontraction, with GDP falling by an annual rate of less than 2%per annum, and just 0.5% if Canada is excluded from the sample(Canada was particularly adversely affected by its large agriculturalsector and its links with the United States). This suggests thatdevaluation policies may have helped to mitigate the adverse effectsof the depression. Leaving gold provided less help for the ‘otherdevaluers’ group although there is evidence that those who devaluedearly experienced a milder depression than those who delayed anddevalued late. Thus, the timing of the policy response wasimportant.

For the period of recovery, from 1932–37, most countriesexhibited reasonable cyclical growth. The exception was the goldbloc countries. Constrained by their commitment to their exchangerate parities they had to adopt tight monetary and fiscal policies tomaintain internal and external balance. Thus although output wasdepressed, the French government in the early 1930s adoptedcontractionary fiscal policies to prevent destabilising exchange ratespeculation.

A simple comparison of growth performance during recoverycan be misleading, as it will include both a cyclical component (theautomatic recovery from a deep depression) and policy inducedeffects. An alternative is to examine inter-period, peak to peak

Page 96: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

FIXED EXCHANGE RATES AND DEFLATION

79

growth performance. Looking at the change in the annual rate ofgrowth of GDP during 1929–37 relative to 1924–29, the results forthe ‘world’ economy indicate a retardation of the growth path. Thisis consistent with other findings that the shock of the GreatDepression had persistent effects on the level of output. Theperformance of the different policy regimes, however, providesimportant contrasts. The countries that devalued, particularly thosethat devalued early, experienced only a small (or zero) fall in trendgrowth. Those countries that had the limited benefits of exchangecontrols experienced a deterioration in annual growth of 3.3%. Thepoorest performing group was the gold bloc, which had littleflexibility to initiate policies for domestic recovery.

Further evidence of the striking contrasts in performance ofdifferent policy regimes is shown in figures for annual growth ofindustrial production. These indicate that those countries whichdevalued, and to a lesser extent those that introduced exchangecontrols, had a milder industrial depression, faster recovery and abetter inter-period growth performance. Evidence on theunemployment performance of the different policy regimes showsthat the high unemployment that developed during the depressionpersisted throughout the period of recovery. Only for the sterlingbloc was there any fall in the unemployment rate; for the otherregimes unemployment increased during 1933–37. In part thisreflects employment lagging output, plus changing activity rates anddemographic shifts. But it is also evidence of the persistent effectsof the Great Depression, the long-term unemployed havingdifficulty re-entering the labour market.

As always, there are some authors (e.g., Beenstock et al., 1984)who argue that it was wage movements that accounted for thecyclical fluctuations in output, both for the Great Depression andthe subsequent recovery. It is true that real wages (adjusted forprice changes) did move counter-cyclically over the 1929–37 cyclein Britain—rising relative to trend in the recession and then fallingrelative to trend during the recovery—but the causes of the outputfluctuations lay elsewhere, and the timing of the wage fluctuationsdo not actually fit the claim that recession was caused by wage risesand recovery caused by wage cuts. We have shown elsewhere(Michie, 1987) that this wage-output correlation itself does not, inany case, hold outside those particular years—a finding whichreinforces the argument that the output and wage series areindependently generated, with output influenced crucially by the

Page 97: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

JONATHAN MICHIE AND MICHAEL KITSON

80

level of demand for output and wages by factors such asproductivity levels and bargaining strength.

Growth and improved economic performance during the 1930swas dependent on countries untying themselves from the stricturesof the gold standard and adopting independent policies, withdifferent exchange rate regimes created and with some countriesalso reaping the advantages of increased protectionism and fiscalexpansion. What is apparent, however, is that the cooperativeregime failed and uncoordinated policies were a vast improvement.

The use of uncoordinated policies may have led to someresource misallocation effects. The overriding impact, however, waspositive as independent policies overcame the deflationary bias ofthe gold standard and led to increased resource mobilisation.Despite these economic gains some commentators persist inidentifying the 1930s as a period of ‘economic nationalism’ whichhelped to usher in totalitarian and fascist political regimes. This is acomplete misreading of history. The rise of racism and fascism inthe 1920s and 1930s was fuelled by mass unemployment and thedestructive economic policies imposed on Germany at Versaillesand on the rest of the world by the gold standard. Keynes (1919,1925) had warned as much in The Economic Consequences of the Peaceand The Economic Consequences of Mr Churchill, but to no avail.Currency stability was, of course, paramount.

CONCLUSIONS

The similar experience of deep slumps and widespreadunemployment has led to comparisons between the interwar periodand recent economic events, including by analogy between the ERMand the interwar gold standard. Both resemble ‘adjustable pegsystems’ in theory, but proved to be rather less adjustable inpractice. Both failed to deal with external shocks. Both sufferedadversely from speculative attacks. And both limited the flexibilityof domestic policy. As in 1931, Britain disengaged itself from theexchange rate system, allowed the exchange rate to fall, andintroduced cheap money. As in 1931, policy initiatives today reflectcrisis management rather than any coherent strategy, although thebenefits of devaluation were at least more fully discussed 60 yearsago than they were prior to September 1992. Similarly, the French‘franc fort’ policy of the 1980s and 1990s resembles the ultimatelymisconceived French commitment to gold in the 1930s (although at

Page 98: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

FIXED EXCHANGE RATES AND DEFLATION

81

least the French now have the flexibility to introduce expansionarypolicies, despite their reluctance to take advantage of thisopportunity).

Despite the historical similarities some important differencesremain. International capital markets are now more integrated,making it more difficult to engineer unilateral reductions in interestrates. The British experience of 1992–93 suggests, however, thatsuch unilateral action is still possible, with the leaving of the ERMallowing interest rate cuts despite claims prior to September 1992that interest rates would actually have to increase in suchcircumstances to compensate for loss of confidence and credibility.Also, the economic problems faced by European economies in theearly 1990s had different causes and different characteristics fromthe interwar period. For instance, depressed demand in the Britisheconomy reflected the high level of debt in the private sectorresulting from government policy mismanagement and the impactof financial deregulation in the mid-1980s. However, someimportant lessons can still be drawn.

First, macroeconomic policies which retard growth may havepersistent effects on the real economy. The magnitude of the GreatDepression did lasting damage to the level of world GDP. We haveyet to observe the long-term impacts of the early-1990s’ recession.What is apparent, however, is that governments should react toexternal shocks quickly by using accommodating monetary andfiscal policies and that internal deflation is an inappropriate tool forpermanently reducing inflation.

Second, policies which are based on trying to achieveconvergence of inflation rates and other monetary and financialindicators can have adverse effects on the real economy. This isparticularly so when those policies fail to accommodate differentinitial conditions or when they tend to have a deflationary bias orwhen they fail to successfully accommodate economic shocks. Theexperience of the gold standard supports this warning, as doesmore recent evidence. Thus the notion, for example, that becauseGermany had a strong economy and a strong currency, imposing astrong currency on Britain would thereby strengthen the domesticeconomy, was fatally flawed. Causation runs from the real economyto the exchange rate, not vice versa. Britain’s decision to join theERM at DM2.95 in October 1992 served to weaken Britain’s tradingsector and removed the policy options required to deal withdomestic recession.

Page 99: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

JONATHAN MICHIE AND MICHAEL KITSON

82

One of the keys to economic growth during the 1930s was theuse of independent and uncoordinated policies. This is not thesame as saying that coordination itself is necessarily ineffective:what is ineffective is a coordination based on convergence towardsmonetary and financial targets which has adverse impacts on thereal economies of the participants. During the 1930s, coordinationbased on structured reflation and the effective redistribution ofresources to regions or countries of the world with difficultieswould have been appropriate. The limitations of such policypackages is that the level of cooperation required is significant andthe rules required are complex and not easily enforced (Levine,1990). In the absence of such an agreed and enforced policypackage, independent policies were the next best option, and assuch proved successful during the 1930s. Unless current Europeaneconomic policy is reoriented towards the objective of fullemployment, embracing an active industrial and regional policy,rather than with the myopic concern with zero inflation, the routeforward must once again be based on independent national growthstrategies which would not only allow countries to help themselves,but by doing so would help each other. Competitive deflation is thereal ‘beggar my neighbour’ policy of the 1990s.

And third, despite economic revival in the 1930s, unemploymentremained high. It was a constant source of poverty, disease andmalnutrition. The implementation of a growth strategy today,whether it be of a national or European variety, is a necessarycondition for tackling unemployment, but may not of itself besufficient. It is important, therefore, first that the pursuit of marketflexibility does not further erode the welfare state upon which thebasic needs of so many depends; and second that policies foremployment are pursued alongside those for economic recovery andgrowth. These need to include measures such as reducing the lengthof the working week and year; expanding employment-intensivepublic services and public works, such as a major environmentalprogramme; and supply-side measures on education and training,and on research, development and design to see through newproducts and production processes (see Chapter 10).

Page 100: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

83

4

WHITHER EUROPEANMONETARY UNION?

George Zis

INTRODUCTION

On January 1, 1994, Stage Two of the process towards thecomplete monetary unification of the European Union (EU)formally came into effect. However, it no longer seems as likely asit did at the time of the signing of the Maastricht Treaty that theEU will, in fact, implement the third and final stage of this processin 1997 or, at the latest, on January 1, 1999, as prescribed by theTreaty. Doubts exist as to whether the European Monetary System(EMS) can provide the policy anchor for the EU member countriesduring the transition period. Persistent speculative pressures fromthe summer of 1992 to the end of July 1993 forced Italy andBritain to drop out of the system’s exchange rate mechanism(ERM) in September 1992, a series of realignments in intra-EMSexchange rates and, finally, on August 1, 1993, the decision to alterthe mechanism’s rules for intervention in the foreign exchangemarkets by widening the permissible band of fluctuation from±2.25% to ±15% on either side of the agreed central parities. The1992–93 turmoil has raised doubts not only about the capacity ofthe EMS to fend off speculative pressures, even when parities arenot inconsistent with market fundamentals, but also regarding thepolitical commitment of EU member countries to the objective ofeconomic and monetary union (EMU).

Is the balance between the benefits and costs of monetary unionsuch that it can provide a justification for EU member countries torefrain from fully implementing the Maastricht Treaty and insteadseek alternative monetary arrangements? Will all EU membercountries move at the same pace towards monetary union or are thedemands of the transition to such a union likely to result in the

Page 101: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

GEORGE ZIS

84

emergence of a ‘two-speed’ Europe? How can the EMS bestrengthened so as to ensure that speculative pressures on intraEMSexchange rates can successfully be contained during Stage Two? Inaddressing these questions, first, the principal features andalternative forms of monetary union will be outlined. Second, thebenefits and costs for countries that enter into a monetary unionwill be briefly considered. Third, the provisions of the MaastrichtTreaty for Stage Two of the transition towards the completemonetary unification of the EU will be discussed. Fourth, thenature and implications of the 1992–93 turmoil will be assessed.Finally, some conclusions will be presented, the principal one beingthat a ‘two-speed’ Europe is likely to emerge.

MONETARY UNION: DEFINITION ANDALTERNATIVE FORMS

Monetary union can be defined as a monetary association betweencountries that results in common inflation and interest rates acrossall participating member states. The necessary, but not sufficient,conditions for this to occur are: 1 that there exists a fully integrated union financial sector;2 capital movements are perfectly free within the union; and3 intra-union exchange rates are either de facto or de jur e

irrevocably fixed. If these conditions were satisfied and there emerged union-wideinf lation and interest rates then, necessarily, union membercurrencies would be perfect substitutes. It follows, therefore, that, inprinciple, the creation of a monetary union does not necessitate thereplacement of union member countries’ currencies by a singleunion currency (see also Healey, 1993c).

Vaubel (1988) in his survey of the literature on monetaryintegration discusses a number of alternative sets of arrangementswhich have been perceived to constitute a monetary union. Thereis, first, the case of currency union which involves union membercountries in adopting a single currency. For a currency union to beviable, it is necessary that there exists only one independentsupplier of the currency in use in the union; i.e., there must exist acentral bank which is responsible for the monetary and exchangerate policies of the union. In a currency union, then, member

Page 102: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

WHITHER EUROPEAN MONETARY UNION?

85

countries cease to enjoy any degree of monetary autonomy,however limited.

Second, many economists have identified monetary union withexchange rate union. In an exchange rate union, exchange rates areirrevocably fixed and there are no restrictions on the movement ofcapital across the union’s member countries. The Werner Plan,adopted in 1970, envisaged the monetary unification of Europethrough ‘the irrevocable fixing of parities and the total liberalisationof capital movements’ by 1980. Vaubel (1988) emphasises that thecrucial distinction between a currency union and an exchange rateunion is that the former, in contrast to the latter, involves no intra-union exchange rate uncertainty. So long as there exists a numberof national currencies, it is always possible for the ‘irrevocably’fixed exchange rates to be altered or restrictions on the movementof capital to be imposed. But in a currency union the replacementof union member countries’ currencies by a single union currencyeliminates the exchange rate uncertainty that would necessarilypersist if, instead, these countries were to be members of anexchange rate union.

Third, in a free intercirculation union, member countries’currencies are allowed to circulate freely within the union. In such aunion, exchange rates may, but not necessarily, be fixed. Fourth, itis possible to perceive a state of affairs which involves a parallelcurrency circulating side-by-side with the national currency. Such anarrangement Vaubel (1988) has termed as a parallel currency union.Again, exchange rates between the parallel currency and thenational currencies need not be fixed. The parallel currency unionresembles the currency union in that both involve a commoncurrency for all union member countries. Similarly, the parallelcurrency union is like the free intercirculation union in terms ofcurrency competition. In the former, a member country’s currencycompetes with the parallel currency, while in the latter it competeswith the other member countries’ currencies.

DEGREES OF MONETARY INTEGRATION

Gros (1989) in his assessment of the alternative forms of monetaryunion observes that they involve different degrees of monetaryintegration. A currency union necessarily implies perfect monetaryintegration. However, this is not necessarily the case with theexchange rate union. Gros (1989) draws attention to the differences

Page 103: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

GEORGE ZIS

86

in interest rates in Germany and the Netherlands, despite the factthat the German deutschmark/Dutch guilder exchange rate haseffectively been fixed since 1983, there are no barriers to themovement of capital between the two countries, monetary policiesare closely coordinated and the real sectors of the two economiesare highly integrated. If the essence of monetary union is thatthere prevail the same conditions as if a single currency exists, thenfixity of the deutschmark/guilder exchange rate, perfect capitalmobility and monetary policy coordination have not resulted in thede facto monetary unification of Germany and the Netherlands.Continuing exchange rate uncertainty, reflected in the persistentinterest rate differentials, has impeded the complete monetaryintegration between these two countries. Thus, a currency union andan exchange rate union involve different degrees of monetaryintegration.

A second set of issues relates to the process by which monetaryunion is achieved, whatever its form. A group of countries candecide to adopt any of the four forms of union outlined above asthe end-state of the desired degree of monetary integration.However, they also have to decide how this end-state is to bereached. Transitional arrangements inevitably depend, at least inpart, on the ultimate objective. For example, if an exchange rateunion is the eventual target, the introduction of a parallel currencyin the transition would not be necessary. Similarly, if a parallelcurrency union or a free intercirculation union is the ultimate aim,then exchange rates need not be fixed. Again, these forms ofmonetary union imply different degrees of monetary integration.

It is possible, on the other hand, to perceive a particular formof monetary union facilitating the transition to the ultimatelydesired degree of monetary integration. For example, a freeintercirculation union may serve as the transition stage to currencyunion. It is, in principle, conceivable that through currencycompetition the weaker currencies could be driven out ofcirculation and that eventually one of the member countries’currencies would become the common currency for the wholeunion. The same is true of the parallel currency union. Undercertain assumptions, the parallel currency could displace all nationalcurrencies and emerge as the union’s only currency. But for this tooccur, it is necessary that the parallel currency is not a basket of theunion member countries’ currencies. If it were, there would alwaysbe a national currency which is more attractive than the parallel

Page 104: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

WHITHER EUROPEAN MONETARY UNION?

87

currency. If, however, national currencies were dropped from thebasket as they were driven out of circulation, then this processwould result in the parallel currency being identical with the‘strongest’ national currency.

In summary, there are different forms of monetary union, witheach involving a different degree of monetary integration. Currencyunion implies perfect monetary integration. Depending on theultimately desired degree of monetary integration, alternativetransitional arrangements are feasible. In principle, a freeintercirculation or a parallel currency union could serve as thetransition stage to currency union. The same is true of theexchange rate union.

THE COSTS AND BENEFITS OF MONETARYUNION

The implications of exchange rate uncertainty feature prominentlyin the case against flexible exchange rates (see Artus and Young,1979). Since the breakdown of the Bretton Woods system in March1973, nominal exchange rate changes have been large and almostentirely unpredictable. As these changes have not tended to offsetinflation rate differentials in the short and medium term, thebehaviour of real exchange rates has been highly erratic withcountries experiencing sharp fluctuations in their competitiveness(see Chapter 2, Appendix A). Exchange rates have substantiallydeviated from their long-run equilibrium values for significantperiods of time. Examples of such exchange rate misalignments arethe external values of sterling during 1979–81 and of the dollarduring 1981–85. The creation of the EMS partly ref lecteddisillusion with exchange rate flexibility. If the focus were to be therelative merits and disadvantages of flexible exchange rates whenassessing the costs and benefits of monetary union, it would, inprinciple, suffice to consider the case for and against an exchangerate union. But the Maastricht Treaty envisages the creation of acurrency union in 1997 or, at the latest, on January 1, 1999.Therefore, for our purposes, it is necessary also to contrast anexchange rate union against a currency union. The case for acurrency union rests on a number of arguments (for surveys, seeBrociner and Levine, 1992a; Begg, 1991; Goodhart, 1991;Eichengreen, 1990a).

First, it can be maintained that an exchange rate union is

Page 105: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

GEORGE ZIS

88

preferable to a system of flexible exchange rates as it encouragestrade growth by generating a greater degree of exchange ratepredictability. De Grauwe (1988) has presented empirical evidenceindicating that intra-EU trade would have grown less than it didduring the 1980s had the EMS not been successful in dramaticallyreducing the unpredictability of intra-EMS exchange rates. But anexchange rate union cannot eliminate exchange rate uncertainty. AsGros (1989) observes, it is not possible to rule out that anexchange rate union member country may not decide to change itsexchange rate. Therefore, a currency union is superior to anexchange rate union in its potential to stimulate trade acrossmember countries. The quantitative significance of this advantageof a monetary union, whether in its exchange rate or currencyunion form, over a regime of flexible exchange rates has beendisputed on the grounds that forward exchange markets allowtraders to hedge currency risk. However, such hedging does involvea cost and in that sense constitutes an impediment to the growthof international trade (see Artis, 1989).

Second, it may be argued that exchange rate uncertainty dis-courages international investment. Morsink and Molle (1991) havepresented empirical evidence which supports the proposition thatexchange rate uncertainty has had a depressing effect on investmentamong EU member countries. In the case of foreign investmentforward exchange markets cannot provide adequate hedgingfacilities, even at a cost, as agreements involving the forward sale/purchase of currencies rarely cover a period beyond a year—whichfalls significantly short of the life of plant and equipment. Itfollows, therefore, that a currency union is superior to an exchangerate union, as it potentially provides a framework conducive to themore efficient allocation of capital across the union membercountries.

Third, Sumner and Zis (1982) have argued that the natural rateof unemployment in a country operating flexible exchange rateswill be higher than if it pursued fixed exchange rates. Theyextended Friedman’s (1975) argument that the higher the inflationrate is, the more unpredictable it will be. Therefore, pricesbecome less efficient in transmitting information and, as a result,other things equal, the natural rate of unemployment will behigher. Similarly, they argued, the more uncertain the exchangerate is, the less efficient the price mechanism will be. Again, asonly in a currency union is exchange rate uncertainty eliminated,

Page 106: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

WHITHER EUROPEAN MONETARY UNION?

89

this form of monetary union is preferable to an exchange rateunion.

Fourth, exchange rate flexibility has an asymmetrical impact onfirms. It is significantly more difficult for small and medium-sizedfirms to absorb the costs of foreign exchange risk managementthan it is for large corporations. It follows, then, that the biasagainst the former can only be eliminated under a currency union(see de Grauwe, 1992). Fifth, the existence of national currenciesimplies, whether exchange rates are fixed or flexible, that economicagents incur costs whenever they exchange their domestic currencyfor a foreign currency. These transaction costs are less under fixedthan flexible exchange rates. But in a currency union they areentirely eliminated.

Sixth, governments often succumb to the temptation of mani-pulating money supply growth rates for, among other reasons,electoral purposes (see Alesina and Grilli, 1991; Alesina, 1989). Thishas largely reflected the constitutional status of central banks.Except for Germany, where the Bundesbank is constitutionallyindependent and responsible for maintaining price stability, centralbanks in the other EU member countries effectively have toimplement government-determined monetary policies. Themanipulation of monetary policies for electoral purposes has usuallyresulted in the generation of increasingly severe inflationarypressures. In an exchange rate union the ability of governments toabuse monetary policy is more limited than under a regime offlexible exchange rates. But in a currency union, with monetarypolicy being the responsibility of the union central bank, necessarilyno member country can manipulate the money supply growth rate(see Chapter 5 for a further discussion of this point).

In a currency union, member countries cannot engage inindependent monetary policies or employ exchange rate changes inpursuit of domestic economic objectives. An exchange rate unionallows some scope, albeit very limited, for independent monetarypolicies in the short run while it is always feasible, howeverpolitically costly it may be, for a member country to effect anexchange rate change. The implied loss of autonomy in the conductof monetary and exchange rate policies, relative to alternativeregimes involving greater degrees of exchange rate flexibility, isperceived as the principal cost of monetary unions. The questionthen arises as to how significant this loss of autonomy is,particularly in the context of the EU. It is, however, important to

Page 107: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

GEORGE ZIS

90

note that it is no longer possible to argue that even completeexchange rate flexibility is sufficient for any individual country topursue independent policy objectives.

The post-1973 experience has demonstrated that exchange rateflexibility does not, per se, insulate economies from externaldisturbances. Indeed, nominal disturbances have generatedprolonged real changes. The correlation between nominal exchangerate changes and inflation rate differentials is weak, particularly inthe short and medium term. Further, the increasing tendency foreconomic agents to hold diversified currency portfolios implies that,for any single country, the control of the money supply growth ratecannot ensure the control of the domestic long-run inflation rate.This line of argument suggests that the potential benefits ofmonetary policy autonomy are rather limited.

On the other hand, some economists would argue that, contraryto what was originally argued, the natural rate of unemployment isnot independent of monetary policy. An unanticipated expansionarychange in monetary policy, for example, reduces unemployment.This involves newly employed workers acquiring new skills. Somewill remain in employment when the economy fully adjusts to themonetary policy change in the long run. The implication of thisline of reasoning is that a currency union potentially deprivesmember countries of their ability to affect unemployment—notonly in the short run, but also in the long run. Whether or notmonetary policy can have a lasting effect on output andemployment is an empirical issue. The extensive statisticalinvestigation of this issue has yet to yield unambiguous evidenceregarding the capacity of monetary policy to affect the realeconomy.

For the sake of argument, however, suppose that monetarypolicy is an effective policy instrument for the purpose ofstabilising output and employment. This is not sufficient forasserting that a currency union will necessarily result in significantcosts for member countries (see also Healey and Levine, 1992a). Itdepends on the nature of the shocks to which the union issubjected. If these are country-specific, then the sacrifice of themonetary policy instrument will involve a cost for the affectedcountry. But if disturbances are symmetrical and impact all membercountries, no cost need be incurred as the union monetaryauthorities can appropriately adjust the union’s monetary policy.This is an issue which will be considered further in the following

Page 108: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

WHITHER EUROPEAN MONETARY UNION?

91

sections. For the moment, it may be argued that the propositionthat a currency union necessarily implies a potentially significantcost for member countries, because it deprives them of the abilityto employ monetary policy to affect output and employment, is lessthan convincing.

Changes in nominal exchange rates may facilitate adjustment todifferences among countries with respect to trend developments inreal variables which require changes in real exchange rates. Byexcluding nominal exchange rate changes as a means of adjustment,a monetary union forces the burden of adjustment on othermarkets which may be less flexible and efficient than the foreignexchange markets. The quantitative significance of the cost thusincurred is highly uncertain. Further, it may be argued that otherpolicies may well be more effective than exchange rate policy forthe resolution of adjustment problems arising from differences inthe performance of countries’ real sectors.

What, then, can be concluded from this discussion? A currencyunion is superior to an exchange rate union as it involves all thebenefits of the latter plus the gains associated with the eliminationof exchange rate uncertainty and exchange rate-related transactioncosts. Second, there exists now a perception that the benefits of acurrency union exceed the costs. This perception rests on disillusionwith independently determined monetary policies and theeffectiveness of exchange rate policy as an instrument ofmacroeconomic management.

THE RATIONALE OF THE MAASTRICHT TREATY

On January 1, 1994, Stage Two of the process leading to themonetary unification of the EU began. During the third, and final,stage of this process, envisaged to commence in 1997 or, at thelatest, on January 1, 1999, EU national currencies are to be replacedby the new union currency, the ECU; that is, the Maastricht Treatyprescribes the eventual transformation of the EU into a currencyunion. The decision of EU member countries to opt for a currencyunion rather than, for example, an exchange rate union or, alternately,perseverance with the EMS exchange rate arrangements, wasultimately dictated by the objectives of the Single European Act(SEA). The SEA provided for the completion of the internal marketthrough the dismantling of all barriers to the movement of goods,services, capital and labour—see Chapters 7 and 8.

Page 109: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

GEORGE ZIS

92

The complete integration of the EU member countries’ financialsectors is a necessary condition for the completion, consolidationand development of the internal market. First, these sectors aresufficiently significant that without their becoming fully integratedthe concept of a single European market is meaningless. Second,the markets for goods and services cannot become completelyintegrated in the absence of financial integration. The latter isincompatible with member countries operating exchange and capitalcontrols. Thus, the 1988 Directive provided for the abolition ofsuch controls by July 1990, by all EU member countries exceptSpain, Portugal, Greece and Ireland for which the end of 1992 wasspecified as the date by which they had to dismantle their exchangeand capital controls. In compliance with the 1988 Directive, Franceand Italy abolished all exchange restrictions and controls on capitalmovements during the first half of 1990 and Belgium abandonedits dual exchange rate system. But the removal of exchangerestrictions and controls on capital movements, though necessary, isnot sufficient to ensure the creation of a single European financialmarket. It cannot eliminate the exchange rate uncertainty whichcontinues to act as a barrier to the complete financial integration ofthe EU. Thus, the need for the EU to evolve into a monetary unionand, more specifically, into a currency union.

There is a second reason why the complete monetary integrationof the EU through the replacement of member countries’currencies with a single currency is necessary for the creation,consolidation and development of the single European market.Assume that the EU were to proceed with the dismantling of allbarriers to intra-union trade in goods and services and the abolitionof all exchange restrictions and controls on capital movements, butpersisted with the EMS exchange rate arrangements. Nationalindustries would have to adjust to the abolition of barriers to intra-union trade. The EMS, as operated during the 1980s and early1990s, could not prevent the accumulation of pressures, or thesudden outbreak of severe speculative attacks, on intra-EMSexchange rates. The defence of prevailing parities became moredifficult without exchange and capital controls (see Chapter 2).Thus, there would remain the risk that exchange rate changes couldbe forced on member countries. It follows, then, that nationalindustries would have to adjust not only to the removal of allbarriers to intra-EU trade in goods and services, but also toperiodic exchange rate changes. Therefore, resistance to the full

Page 110: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

WHITHER EUROPEAN MONETARY UNION?

93

implementation of the 1992 programme could develop. This wouldoccur especially if the enforced exchange rate realignments werenot consistent with market fundamentals, as was the case with the1992–93 EMS turmoil.

Pressures on governments to reintroduce exchange and capitalcontrols would be generated (indeed, this was precisely whathappened during 1992–93). The temptation to delay, or evenabandon, the dismantling of barriers to intra-union trade wouldbecome increasingly difficult to resist. Ultimately, exchange rateuncertainty and unpredicted exchange rate realignments could forcethe abandonment of the objective of completing the internalmarket. In committing member countries to the principle ofmonetary union, the SEA recognised that the EMS could notprovide the monetary framework necessary for the creation of thesingle European market. The choice, then, that confronted EUmember countries was between a currency union and an exchangerate union. But, as already argued, the concept of ‘irrevocably’ fixedexchange rates, on which the latter rests, lacks credibility. Therefore,only a currency union is consistent with the single European marketobjective of the SEA. In brief, then, the internal logic of the SEAdictated the Maastricht Treaty prescription that the EU evolves intoa currency union.

AN OVERVIEW OF THE MAASTRICHT TREATY

The SEA came into effect in 1987 (see Chapter 8). The followingyear the Committee for the Study of Economic and MonetaryUnion, under the chairmanship of the President of theCommission, Jacques Delors, was established. The Delors Report(1989) was presented in April 1989. It recommended a three-stageprocess leading to the complete monetary integration of the EUthrough the replacement of member countries’ currencies with asingle currency. The principal features of the Delors Plan wereadopted in principle at the Rome meeting of the European Councilin October 1990. In December 1990 an Inter-GovernmentalConference (IGC) began deliberations with the view of preparingamendments to the Treaty of Rome on the basis of the DelorsReport. The IGC presented its proposals in the form of a Treatyon European Union at the Maastricht meeting of the EuropeanCouncil in December 1991. The Maastricht Treaty was signed inFebruary 1992 (see Bank of England, 1992, for a useful summary).

Page 111: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

GEORGE ZIS

94

By the end of October 1993, the Treaty had been ratified by allmember countries. Thus the EU came into existence on November1, 1993 (see Chapter 1).

Ar tis (1992) in his assessment of the Maastricht Treatyobserves that the debate following the publication of the DelorsReport centred on the relative merits of a market-driven and aninstitu-tionally-driven transition process towards the completemonetary integration of the EU. The proponents of the marketapproach, with the British government being the principal one,argued for the introduction of a parallel currency (the so-called‘hard ECU’ proposal). It was maintained that market forces wouldeventually force the emergence of the parallel currency as thesingle EU currency as it would possess better inflation-proofingproperties than national currencies. A number of objections wereraised against the parallel currency approach. First, even if theparallel currency were superior to national currencies, it is notnecessarily the case that it would eventually replace the latter.Second, assuming that such a replacement would occur at sometime in the future, the duration of the process through which theintroduction of a parallel currency would lead to a currency unionwould be so long as to jeopardise the creation of the singleEuropean market.

Third, there is no reason why the parallel currency wouldnecessarily outperform, in terms of inflation-proofing properties, allnational currencies. Fourth, foreign exchange market crises werelikely to occur with increasing frequency. Fifth, there would exist apotential for destabilising friction between the EU authorityresponsible for the parallel currency and the national monetaryauthorities. Sixth, exchange rate-related transactions costs wouldincrease. This type of consideration led to the Delors Committee toreject the parallel currency approach to the creation of a Europeancurrency union. When the British government sought to reviveinterest in the approach through its ‘hard ECU’ proposal, itattracted negligible support from the other member countries,particularly when it became evident that the British government hadconceived its plan as a means of frustrating the eventualreplacement of national currencies by a single EU currency. Thus,the IGC adopted the approach recommended by the Delors Reportin the Maastricht Treaty.

The Treaty assumed that Stage One had begun on July 1,1990 and set January 1, 1994 as the date for the start of Stage

Page 112: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

WHITHER EUROPEAN MONETARY UNION?

95

Two. The principal feature of this stage is the establishment ofthe European Monetary Institute (EMI). The EMI, which isbased in Frankfurt, commenced operations as the second stagebegan. The EMI is entrusted with the administration of theEMS. Further, it is responsible for promoting a greater degreeof economic policy coordination among member countries. Itcan comment and advise on national monetary policies, but hasno powers to enforce particular directions. National authoritiesremain responsible for their respective monetary policies. Third,the EMI will prepare the procedures and instruments that willenable the European System of Central Bank (ESCB) to assumecontrol of the EU monetary policy at the start of Stage Three.At the end of Stage Two, the EMI will cease to exist. It isfurther envisaged that during Stage Two, the barriers to the useof ECU will be abolished, intra-EMS exchange rate changes willbecome less frequent and member countries will introduce thenecessary legal changes to transform their central banks intoindependent institutions (see Chapter 5).

The Maastricht Treaty prescribes that during 1996 theEuropean Council will meet to determine whether a majority ofEU member countries satisfy the specified convergence criteriaand, accordingly, set a date for the start of Stage Three. Thus, thefinal stage could begin as early as January 1997. However, if sucha majority cannot be identified and during 1997 no date is set forthe start of Stage Three, then the Maastricht Treaty prescribesthat the final stage will begin on January 1, 1999—even if only aminority of member countries meet the criteria for membershipof the currency union. At the start of Stage Three, intra-Unionexchange rates will be irrevocably fixed and the European CentralBank (ECB), which is to head the ESCB, will commenceoperations and assume responsibility for the currency union’smonetary policy. Member countries will decide the date for thereplacement of national currencies with the new union currency,the ECU.

The ESCB will consist of the national central banks with theECB at its head (see Lomax, 1991; Harden, 1990). The ECB willdetermine the EU’s monetary policy. The Maastricht Treaty definesthe maintenance of price stability as ‘the primary objective’ of theECB. Further, the ECB has been assigned a significant role in thedetermination of the currency union’s exchange rate policies vis-à-visnon-EU currencies. The Treaty provides for the complete

Page 113: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

GEORGE ZIS

96

independence of the ECB and of the ESCB from membercountries’ governments and EU institutions. However, the ECB willbe accountable to the European Parliament, the Commission and tothe European Council. In summary, the Maastricht Treaty providesa coherent and internally consistent strategy for the transformationof the EU into a currency union.

THE CONVERGENCE CRITERIA

The Maastricht Treaty specifies five criteria that a member countrymust satisfy in order to qualify for membership of the currencyunion (see also Chapter 5). First, its rate of inflation during theyear immediately before its joining the union must not exceed bymore than 1.5% the three lowest rates of inflation in the Union.Second, the country’s long-run interest rate during the year beforeits becoming a member of the union must not exceed by more than2% the three lowest long-run interest rates in the EU. Third, thecountry must have participated for at least two years in the ‘normal’band of fluctuation of the ERM (currently ±15%, since August1993), without a devaluation of its currency. Fourth, its budgetdeficit must not exceed 3% of its GDP and, fifth, the ratio of itsnational debt to GDP must not exceed 60%.

These convergence criteria, particularly the fiscal ones, havebeen the subject of intense debate (see Healey and Levine, 1992b;Levine, 1992; Levine and Pearlman, 1992). Some have questionedwhether it was at all necessary to require member countries tosatisfy well-defined criteria in order to qualify for membership ofthe currency union. It could have been left up to each country todecide whether or not it was ready to join the union. However,such an approach would have severely complicated the transitionperiod and, ultimately, placed the entire process of monetaryunification in jeopardy. To have allowed member countriescomplete independence in deciding whether or not they wereready to join the currency union would have been inconsistentwith the rationale for the complete monetary integration of theEU and could have resulted in a reversal of the significantprogress achieved during the 1980s in effecting a substantialreduction in inflation rates under the discipline of the ERM (seeChapter 2). The rationale for the EU evolving into a currencyunion can be unambiguously sustained only if placed within thecontext of the monetary conditions that must be generated for

Page 114: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

WHITHER EUROPEAN MONETARY UNION?

97

the creation, consolidation and development of the singleEuropean market to be achieved.

Suppose that a date for the start of Stage Three were set andmember countries’ governments were allowed to decide immediatelyprior to that date whether or not they would join the currencyunion. If that were the case, the individual member country wouldhave an incentive to maximise and fully exploit its economic policyautonomy during the transition period. Thus it could pursueexpansionary fiscal policies and monetary policies that resulted inthe progressive overvaluation of its currency in the expectation thatit would devalue before the start of Stage Three and then wouldrely on the ECB to effect a reduction in its inflation rate. If thatwere to occur, it would not be possible to control the timing of thedomestic currency’s final devaluation prior to its replacement by theEU currency. Indeed, if a number of member countries were toseek to exploit their economic policy autonomy during thetransition period, it is likely that foreign exchange market criseswould increase in frequency and severity, forcing, perhaps, repeatedexchange rate realignments.

At that point, the temptation to reintroduce exchange and capitalcontrols would become increasingly difficult to resist. Thecompletion of the internal market would, at least, be slowed down.But suppose that such difficulties could be overcome. Theimplication would be that Stage Three would start with prevailingnational inflation rates being significantly different. The ECB wouldthen be under pressure to target the EU’s monetary policy towardsthe average of the prevailing inflation rates. Thus countries whichpursued cautious monetary policies during the transition periodwould be penalised. But, perhaps, more significant, the ECB wouldstart its operations under conditions not particularly conducive to itrapidly establishing an anti-inflation reputation.

Thus, though in theory there is no reason why a group ofcountries need to converge before they form a currency union,given the specific conditions in and characteristics of the EU, therequirement that member countries satisfy a set of criteria in orderto qualify for membership of the currency union is well-foundedand justifiable. The Maastricht Treaty by prescribing explicitconvergence criteria ensures that the transition period has anoperational content while national authorities continue to controltheir respective monetary policies. Second, by seeking to satisfythese criteria, member countries can consolidate their successes in

Page 115: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

GEORGE ZIS

98

reducing their inf lation rates during the 1980s. Third, theconvergence criteria provide an explicit incentive for countries likeGreece and Italy to improve their performance and reform theirhighly inefficient fiscal systems. Fourth, they provide the founda-tions on which the ECB can rapidly establish its credibility. Fifth,their pursuit can serve as a signal of member governments’commitment to the objective of completing the internal market.Sixth, they provide a basis for objective judgements to be maderegarding the unsuitability of particular countries to join thecurrency union from the start, thus maximising the likelihood thatthe union will yield the desired benefits—even if only for aminority of the EU member countries.

To support the convergence criteria in the Maastricht Treaty isnot to deny that their pursuit will not be costly, particularly in thecase of the fiscal criteria. Indeed, for some EU member countries itis no longer possible to satisfy these criteria even by 1999 (seeChapter 5). However, as Artis (1992) emphasises, the Treatyperceives these criteria as well-defined ‘guidelines’, rather than asrules to be rigidly applied when deciding whether or not a membercountry qualifies for membership of the currency union. The Treatyis unambiguous in that what is significant is the progress that amember country achieves towards meeting the fiscal criteria. Thus amember country whose budget deficit and national debt:GDP ratiosexceeded the values specified in the Maastricht Treaty could stillqualify for membership of the currency union if these ratios wereon a clearly established downward trend. If the budget deficitcriterion appears not to be satisfied, the Treaty requires theCommission to report and identify whether that particular country’sbudget deficit exceeds its government’s investment expenditure (theso-called ‘golden rule’); that is, in judging a country’s eligibility tojoin the currency union the current rather than the overall budgetdeficit may be used.

Some critics of the fiscal criteria have focused on theirimplications after the currency union has been formed. Membercountries will no longer be able to employ monetary and exchangerate policies in response to asymmetric shocks. In thesecircumstances fiscal policy autonomy could have a useful role toplay. However, countries that become members of the currencyunion will have their ability to pursue independent fiscal policiesseverely restricted. This can be justified in terms of the argumentthat without fiscal discipline as a principal feature of the currency

Page 116: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

WHITHER EUROPEAN MONETARY UNION?

99

union, a member country could, by abusing its fiscal policyautonomy, ultimately undermine price stability in the union (seeSargent and Wallace, 1981; Healey and Levine, 1992b). It is furthermaintained that as the completion of the internal market pro-gresses, the likelihood of country-specific shocks occurring willcorrespondingly diminish. In other words, the potential benefits ofmember countries retaining fiscal policy autonomy are exaggerated.

In summary, the specification of convergence criteria that EUmember countries must satisfy in order to qualify for membershipof the projected currency union is justifiable. The fiscal criteria,which have attracted considerable attention, are not as rigid as theyhave been presented to be. This of course does not imply that theirpursuit will not be costly and for some member countriesimpossible to satisfy even by 1999.

THE MAASTRICHT TREATY: PROSPECTS OFIMPLEMENTATION

The optimism that prevailed at the time the Maastricht Treaty wassigned in February 1992 has given way to widely-held doubts as towhether the Treaty will in fact be fully implemented. The climateof opinion changed suddenly and rather rapidly. The initial rejection(subsequently overturned after treaty revisions) of the Treaty in thefirst Danish referendum in June 1992 can be identified as theturning point. The referendum result and the reaction it provokedin other member countries, and particularly in Britain, generated thesuspicion that EU governments’ commitment to the objectives ofthe Treaty could not be sustained and that they would not even bein a position to proceed with the ratification of the Treaty in theface of mounting popular opposition. Indeed, in Britain theEurosceptics argued that the result of the Danish referendumimplied the end of the road for the Treaty and, therefore, that itcould not be brought before Parliament for ratification. Underpressure the British government changed the timetable for thediscussion of the Treaty in Parliament, thus encouraging the viewthat it could be forced to abandon the Treaty altogether.

On the other hand, France—in an effort to maintain themomentum in favour of the Maastricht Treaty—announced the dayafter the Danish referendum that it would hold its own referendumon September 20, 1992. France need not have held a referendum.The decision to do so can be rationalised. What, however, was a

Page 117: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

GEORGE ZIS

100

serious error of judgement was to set a date so far ahead. TheFrench government was highly unpopular. Inevitably, the campaignfocused on the weaknesses of a ‘lame duck’ government rather thanon the Maastricht Treaty. Opposition to the Treaty came to be seenas the best means of expressing dissatisfaction with thegovernment. Thus, gradually the prospect of the French electoraterejecting the Treaty became real. Doubts regarding the ultimate fateof the Treaty increased in severity. The Treaty, all agreed, could notsurvive a second rejection.

The markets sought to test the EU governments’ commitment tothe Treaty by challenging their resolve to defend the intra-EMSexchange rates. Following Portugal’s decision in April 1992 toparticipate in the system’s ERM, only Greece was not operating themechanism. There had been no intra-EMS exchange raterealignment since January 1987. The Maastricht Treaty hadeffectively assigned a new role to the EMS. It was to serve as apolicy anchor during the transition towards the complete monetaryintegration of the EU. Therefore, if governments were notprepared to defend the EMS, this would signal a weakening of theircommitment to the objectives of the Maastricht Treaty. Further, itwould question their willingness to proceed with the fullimplementation of the 1992 programme.

The day after the Danish referendum, the Italian lira came underpressure in foreign exchange markets. By July 1992, the increasinglysevere turmoil was engulfing sterling. As support for the opponentsof the Maastricht Treaty in France gathered momentum, reflectingthe ever increasing unpopularity of the incumbent government, theoutcome of the French referendum became highly uncertain,despite the fact that all the major parties were campaigning infavour of a vote for the Treaty. This uncertainty further intensifiedthe pressures on the intra-EMS exchange rates. That sterling andthe Italian lira were the first currencies to come under sustainedpressure was not accidental. Many had argued that Britain hadjoined the ERM at an unsustainable exchange rate. Similarly, theItalian lira had been judged to have become progressivelyovervalued. Further, in the spring of 1992, the collapse of Italy’spolitical system had begun. At the same time, the newly electedgovernment in Britain was making no progress in establishing itscredibility. Finally, sterling was forced to drop out of the ERM onSeptember 16, 1992, and was followed the next day by the Italianlira. In the following weeks and months the Spanish peseta was

Page 118: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

WHITHER EUROPEAN MONETARY UNION?

101

devalued three times, the Portuguese escudo twice and the Irishpunt once (see Chapter 2).

By the spring of 1993 the pressures on intra-EMS exchangerates had significantly subsided. France had elected a newgovernment. The performance of the German economy wasrapidly deteriorating under the impact of the country’sreunification. In contrast, the French economy was proving to behighly resilient and emerging as the strongest in the EU. In May1993, prior to the general election, a politically engineereddevaluation was forced on the Spanish government by oppositionforces. However, the EMS appeared to have entered a period oftranquillity. But relations between France and Germany wererapidly deteriorating. Suddenly during July 1993 the French francwas subjected to speculative pressures of unprecedented intensity.On August 1, 1993, the EU member countries decided to changethe rules of intervention of the ERM but not the prevailing intra-EMS exchange rates. Thus the band of fluctuation was widenedfrom ±2.25% to ±15% on either side of the central parities.Germany and the Netherlands decided to continue with thenarrow band of fluctuation. There was no economic justificationfor the speculative attack on the French franc. In the weeks thatfollowed the broadening of the fluctuation band, the franc’sdevaluation never exceeded 3% relative to the floor implied by theoriginal narrow band. By the end of 1993, the French currencyhad climbed back to values within the narrow band.

There is no commonly accepted economic explanation of eitherthe timing or the rapidity with which speculative pressures on intra-EMS exchange rates emerged. It is true that Germany ought tohave revalued immediately after unification. But the failure to do sois not sufficient to explain the 1992–93 turmoil. Nor can it bevalidly argued that any reduction of German interest rates couldhave prevented the Italian lira or sterling from dropping out of theERM. The crisis that engulfed the EMS was a crisis of confidencein EU member governments’ ability and/or willingness to proceedwith the ratification and full implementation of the MaastrichtTreaty. In the event, the Treaty was ratified by all EU membercountries by the end of October 1993. EU member countries didnot rush to take advantage of the broad band of fluctuation andintroduce expansionary monetary policies. Thus, since the July 1993crisis, no evidence had emerged that member countries were in factabandoning the policies that had resulted in the reduction and

Page 119: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

GEORGE ZIS

102

convergence of national inflation rates. Artis (1994) identifies twooptions. Convergence can be further developed while the broadband of fluctuation is retained and, in terms of the MaastrichtTreaty, treated as the ‘normal’ band. However, such a strategy doesentail risks. Alternatively, the band of f luctuation could berenarrowed and provide the foundation for countries to proceed toStage Three. The indications are that the narrow band offluctuation is unlikely to be restored in the near future.

The most likely outcome is that a ‘two-speed’ Europe willdevelop (see also Chapter 5). The Benelux countries, France andGermany are almost certain to proceed to Stage Three. This is alsothe case with Austria. Denmark is likely to join the core countries.On the other hand, it is difficult to envisage such politicaldevelopments in Italy as to enable the country to join the currencyunion from the start. Similarly, it is unlikely that the Britishgovernment will have the authority to take the country into thecurrency union. Spain and Ireland are committed to the objectivesof the Maastricht Treaty but may not be in a position to be amongthe first to join the currency union. Greece is unlikely to join theunion both for economic and political reasons. Portugal, too, islikely to delay joining the union. Finally, it is difficult to predict theattitudes of Sweden, Finland and Austria, which accede to the EUin 1995.

CONCLUSIONS

A currency union in the EU would unambiguously provideimportant economic benefits to member states, while the costs arelikely to be modest. The Maastricht Treaty provides a well-foundedstrategy for the complete monetary integration of the EU, which isconsistent with the objectives of the SEA. It was designed so as toenable all EU countries to join the proposed currency union.However, political developments since the signing of the Treatynow suggest that the most likely development is the emergence of‘two-speed’ Europe, with the core member states pressing aheadwith EMU and leaving the peripheral, less integrated states to applyfor membership at some later stage.

Page 120: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

103

5

EUROPEAN MONETARYUNION

Progress, Problems and ProspectsBarry Harrison and Nigel M.Healey

INTRODUCTION

The Treaty on European Union signed at Maastricht in December1991 commits the European Union (EU) to establishing a singlecurrency. Of all EU countries, only Britain has retained the right toopt out of the final destination of economic and monetary union(EMU). Despite the recent tensions within the European MonetarySystem (EMS), which culminated in the withdrawal of sterling andthe Italian lira, the imposition of emergency capital controls inseveral countries and an increase in the margins of fluctuationwithin the exchange rate mechanism (ERM) to ±15%, theMaastricht Treaty was successfully ratified and came into effect inNovember 1993. However, it has now become clear that somecountries will be ready for EMU before others (see also Chapter 4).This article reviews the progress that has been made towards EMU,the problems that remain and the prospects for achieving EMU inthe foreseeable future.

WHAT IS EMU?

EMU has two dimensions: an economic dimension and a monetarydimension. In brief, economic union implies the creation of a singlemarket without artificial barriers to trade, a union-wide competitionpolicy, a common regional policy and coordination ofmacroeconomic policymaking. EU members are in agreement aboutthe benefits of economic union and many of the requirements arenow in place. By any standards, progress towards economic unionhas been swift and the single market was completed by January 1,

Page 121: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

BARRY HARRISON AND NIGEL M.HEALEY

104

1993 (see Chapter 7). However, monetary union is morecontroversial and involves agreeing to irrevocably fixed exchangerates or the establishment of a single currency (see Chapter 4 for adetailed discussion of the alternative forms of monetary union). Acountry that agrees to either of these (the latter is the preferredoption of most EU members) automatically relinquishes anypossibility of an independent monetary policy. EU members haveaccepted the ‘principle of parallelism’, which implies that economicand monetary union are integral parts of the same ultimate goal.

THE ADVANTAGES OF EMU

The advantages of EMU are well documented and are clearly setout in Goodhart (1991)—see also Chapter 4. In brief, it is arguedthat by removing barriers to trade and eliminating exchange raterisk, greater specialisation and trade will be encouraged. Theelimination of exchange rate risk will also encourage lower interestrates because it will no longer be necessary for them to embody anexchange rate risk premium. As a result, it is argued that economicgrowth and living standards will improve.

It is further argued that the creation of EMU will lead to realresource savings for the EU. One important source of such savingsarises because it will no longer be necessary to exchange currenciesto settle debts arising from intra-EU trade. The Commission hasestimated that savings on such transaction costs alone will amountto about 4% of the EU’s gross domestic product (GDP) per annum(EC Commission, 1990b). In addition, those instruments such asfutures, options and swaps, developed to provide a hedge againstexchange rate risk, will no longer be required for intra-EU trade. Inboth cases, the resources released can then be used for purposeswhich more directly influence living standards than simplyeliminating risk (Levine, 1990). Similarly, if the elimination ofexchange rate risk within the union makes a reduction in reservesheld by central banks possible, this will again free resources whichcan be put to more productive purposes.

Another potential benefit from the adoption of a single currencyis that it will improve efficiency in the allocation of resources. Themost obvious way in which this will happen is that capital will befree to move to where returns are greatest. There will also beincreased competition in goods markets because any pricedifferentials would be immediately apparent to potential consumers.

Page 122: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

EUROPEAN MONETARY UNION

105

In addition it is likely that for most member states prices will bemore stable and therefore the price mechanism will more accuratelyconvey the ‘correct’ signals to producers about changes in society’spreferences. It is also alleged that low inflation will be achieved at alower cost in unemployment.

THE DISADVANTAGES OF EMU

Any country which belongs to a monetary union accepts thatpolicy will be dictated from the centre and that, in particular,there will be no possibility of pursuing an independent monetarypolicy or of adjusting the exchange rate to restorecompetitiveness. As part of a monetary union with Europe, nocountry could pursue its own monetary policy any more thanScotland can pursue its own monetary policy vis-à-vis the rest ofBritain. For each country, therefore, the question to be asked iswhether its economic interests are better served inside the union oroutside the union. Different countries will not always give the sameanswer. For some countries, it might be possible to improve theperformance of the economy by increasing money growth at afaster rate than would be possible inside the union—offsetting anyloss in competitiveness by adjusting the exchange rate (seeEichengreen, 1990b; Feldstein, 1992). For others, the degree ofeconomic integration might be such that an independent monetarypolicy is already impossible. In such cases, monetary union mightbe thought desirable and even inevitable.

THE GROWTH OF INTEREST IN EMU

Interest in EMU is not new. Perlman (1991) has noted that in 1865France, Belgium, Italy and Switzerland formed a monetary unionand in 1867 a conference of twenty nations convened in Paris toexplore the ‘desire to see the union, as yet restricted to fourcountries, become the germ of a union more extended, and of theestablishment of a general circulation among the civilised nations’.In the event, agreement proved impossible and this early attempt atmonetary union collapsed in the 1870s.

In more recent years interest in EMU has grown since the EMSstarted operating in 1979 with the aim of establishing ‘a zone ofmonetary stability’ (see Chapters 2 and 3). However, at its inceptionthere was no agreement that the ultimate aim of the EMS was the

Page 123: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

BARRY HARRISON AND NIGEL M.HEALEY

106

creation of EMU. There was simply a desire among participants toensure that prices and exchange rates were more stable in thefuture than they had been in the past. To ensure exchange ratestability, the ERM was created and thereafter participatingcurrencies were allowed only to fluctuate within agreed bandsaround central rates (originally ±2.25% for most participatingmember states, now ±15%).

In the early years after the EMS was created, there were frequentrealignments of currencies, sometimes twice in the same year. Nostable equilibrium emerged in this early period. Some realignmentof currencies might have been expected because newly-agreedparities inevitably ‘locked in’ existing price and cost disparities.However, the problem was exacerbated in these early years, becauserealignment was not accompanied by a comprehensive set ofdomestic policy measures to ensure the newly-agreed parities werestable. This situation changed decisively in 1983 when the Frenchgovernment shifted the emphasis of economic policy in favour ofcontrolling inflation and away from domestic expansion. As Germaninflation had traditionally been the lowest in the ERM, thedeutschmark became the anchor to which policy was harnessed andthe need to maintain a stable exchange rate was used to justify aprogramme of disinflationary measures. A similar approach wasadopted by other participants in the ERM and as a result thenumber of realignments fell. This was an important milestone onthe road to EMU because it marked a fundamental change in thenature of the ERM, which effectively became a deutschmark zone.The ERM subsequently expanded to include the peseta, the escudoand sterling (although the latter’s membership, along with the lira, isat present in temporary suspension) and was generally perceivedduring the 1980s as having been successful in aiding thedisinflationary process and stabilising exchange rates.

Two other economic developments led to growing interest inEMU. The decision to create a single market led many to argue thatmaximum benefit could only be achieved if exchange rates wereirrevocably fixed, and increasingly this has been interpreted as thecreation of a single currency. The second development was thedecision taken in 1988 to eliminate capital controls by 1990. It wasargued that, without capital controls, any uncertainty aboutexchange rates would motivate capital flows on such a scale thateither realignment would be necessary or domestic monetary policywould have to be geared to avoiding a capital outflow.

Page 124: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

EUROPEAN MONETARY UNION

107

The commitment to fixed exchange rates rules out realignment andthis implies that, even in the absence of monetary union, acompletely independent monetary policy would cease to be arealistic option. Since policy sovereignty would be lost by choice ordesign, there is a clear incentive to create monetary union in whichcapital would be free to move to where returns are greatest withoutimposing any strain on the exchange rate.

There is also a political momentum towards EMU which hasbecome increasingly important since the reunification of Germany.The reunified Germany now dominates the European economies(see Chapter 1) and EMU is perceived by many states (especiallyFrance) as the most effective way of constraining Germaneconomic power. In EMU, there would be more pressure onGermany to consider the interests of the rest of the EU in theconduct of economic policy (see Levine, 1990). There is noguarantee that, outside EMU, German economic policy will notoperate to the detriment of other EU members.

THE DELORS REPORT

Officially the growth of interest in EMU was recognised at theHanover Summit of 1988 which set up a committee to be chairedby Jacques Delors, the then President of the Commission, to setout ‘concrete stages’ which would lead to EMU. The Delors Reportidentified three preconditions for a monetary union (Delors, 1989): 1 unlimited and irreversible convertibility of all currencies;2 complete liberalisation of capital flows and full integration of

banking and other financial markets; and3 irrevocably fixed exchange rates and the complete elimination

of margins of fluctuation. These conditions would establish monetary union, but the DelorsReport also indicated that the adoption of a common currency,while not strictly necessary for monetary union, might seem ‘anatural and desirable further development of the monetary union’.The Report also indicated that the adoption of a single currencyshould follow as quickly as possible after the establishment ofirrevocably fixed exchange rates.

The Delors Report identified three stages that would lead toEMU. Stage One involved completing the internal market, the

Page 125: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

BARRY HARRISON AND NIGEL M.HEALEY

108

adoption of measures to reduce regional disparities within the EU,increased macroeconomic policy coordination and surveillance bythe Council of Finance Ministers (Ecofin) and the Committee ofCentral Bank Governors (CCBG), and full participation in thenarrow band of the ERM. Stage Two is more controversial,particularly because it calls for the establishment of a EuropeanSystem of Central Banks (ESCB) whose ultimate role would be todesign and implement a common monetary policy. In Stage Two,the ESCB would also carry out the tasks of Ecofin and the CCBG.Additionally, exchange rate realignments would only be made duringStage Two in exceptional circumstances and the margins offluctuation would be reduced. During Stage Three, the DelorsReport proposed, the ESCB would assume full responsibility for theconduct of monetary policy within the EU and participatingcurrencies would be irrevocably fixed. At the Madrid Summit ofJune 1990, the Delors Report was accepted and it was agreed thatStage One should begin in July 1990.

The Delors Report was very clear on the conditions necessaryfor monetary union but left many points of detail deliberatelyvague. Stage One is non-controversial. It deals with mattersrelevant to completing the internal market and simply aims topromote greater convergence between EU members. One problemwas to decide when Stages Two and Three should begin and theissue hinged on whether convergence should precede moves towardsEMU, or whether a more rapid move to EMU throughinstitutional change was preferable, in the hope that this wouldforce convergence. Other major problems were to define preciselyhow the ESCB was to formulate policy and perform its tasks, howto guarantee its independence from official control, howaccountable it should be, who would formulate the EU’s exchangerate policy, what sort of rules would govern the size of nationaldeficits and so on.

These are major issues. The Rome Summit of 1990 went someway to dealing with the first problem when eleven of the twelvemember states (i.e., the twelve excluding Britain) agreed that StageTwo should start in January 1994 and that Stage Three would beginwhen a sufficient degree of convergence between members hadbeen achieved. However, it did not specify the degree ofconvergence required to proceed to Stage Three and much was leftto the Inter-Governmental Conference (IGC) which convened a fewweeks later and which reported to the Maastricht Summit.

Page 126: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

EUROPEAN MONETARY UNION

109

THE POLITICAL DIMENSIONS OF EMU

The IGC also spent a considerable time discussing the politicaldimensions of EMU. In popular discussion about the advantagesand disadvantages of EMU, it is often implicitly assumed thatmember states make domestic monetary policy to maximise nationalwelfare, whereas in the real world, democratically electedgovernments typically make economic policy with the intention ofbeing re-elected. In multi-party systems with periodic elections andmyopic or only partially informed electorates, the policy whichmaximises the probability of a governing party (or coalition ofparties) being re-elected is unlikely to accord precisely with thepolicy that maximises some broader concept of national welfare. Inthis context, the constitutional framework within which monetarypolicy is conducted—notably in the way that it divides policymakingpowers between elected governments and unelected central banks—becomes of prime importance. In Britain, for example, the centralbank (the Bank of England) is an arm of the government and actson instructions from the Chancellor of the Exche-quer. InGermany, in contrast, the central bank (the Bundesbank) isconstitutionally independent of the government and has a statutoryduty to use monetary policy to maintain price stability.

It is now well known that the effectiveness of monetary policydepends critically upon the political and institutional context withinwhich policy decisions are formulated and executed (see Currie,1991). The IGC’s discussion of the shape of a future EMUtherefore gave great weight to the constitutional framework withinwhich future EU monetary policy is to be made. Modern economictheory suggests that if the ultimate power over monetary policy isvested with democratic governments (or a central EU bodyrepresenting their interests, like the Council of Ministers), theoutcome is likely to be higher inflation (and a higher average rateof unemployment) than if it is delegated to an independent centralbank (Kydland and Prescott, 1977; Barro and Gordon, 1983).Consider each constitutional arrangement in turn.

The political appeal of surprise inflation

The difficulty of allowing governments to make monetary policyis most easily illustrated using the familiar expectations-augmentedPhillips Curve model. Figure 5.1 shows that in this model, the

Page 127: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

BARRY HARRISON AND NIGEL M.HEALEY

110

long-run Phillips Curve, LRPC, is vertical at the natural rate ofunemployment, UN. The short-run Phillips Curves represent thetemporary inflation—unemployment trade-offs that exist for agiven set of inflationary expectations. For example, SRPC(Pe=P0)maps out the relationship between inflation and unemploymentwhen the expected rate of inflation Pe (which is built into wagesettlements) is P0: if actual inflation were to exceed P0, real wagesand so unemployment, U, would fall; and vice versa. In the longrun, when expectations have fully adjusted and the actual rate ofinflation is completely reflected in wage settlements, the economywill be on its long-run Phillips Curve.

Figure 5.1 also shows a set of indifference curves, I0-I4, whichrepresent combinations of inflation and unemployment betweenwhich the government is indifferent. They are concave rather thanconvex because inflation and unemployment are both ‘bads’ ratherthan ‘goods’; that is, governments prefer less inflation and lessunemployment to more. For the same reason, the indifferencecurves closer to the origin represent higher levels of utility thanthose further away. Figure 5.1 shows that I2 is the ‘best’ indifferencecurve that the government can attain in the long run. In other words,point B, which represents zero inflation at the natural rate of

Figure 5.1 Government policy preferences and the Phillips Curve

Page 128: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

EUROPEAN MONETARY UNION

111

unemployment, is the best feasible choice for a government thatcares about both inflation and unemployment.

The paradox is that utility-maximising behaviour by thegovernment will inevitably make this outcome unattainable. Forexample, suppose that the economy were at point B and inflationaryexpectations were zero. The utility-maximising response of thegovernment would be to adopt a more expansionary monetarypolicy, because, with expectations of zero inflation, the governmentcan (temporarily) improve its utility by sliding up the short-runPhillips Curve, SRPC(Pe=P0) to point A, reaching indifference curve,I1. In the long run, however, as inflationary expectations adjust, theeconomy would converge on point C, with inflation entrenched atP1. Note that, given the shape of the indifference curves in Figure5.1, there is no temptation for the government to try and moveaway from point C. Any attempt to push the economy up or downthe new, higher short-run Phillips Curve, SRPC(Pe=P1), will drive itonto a worse indifference curve. The result is that, if thegovernment tries to maximise its utility each period, the economywill be driven to point C, with equilibrium inflation of P1 andunemployment at its natural rate.

The case for an independent central bank

The analysis above suggests that vesting control over monetarypolicy with the government will inevitably lead to persistentinflation. Given the need to face periodic re-election, governmentstypically act in a short-termist fashion, attempting to maximise theirutility period by period. Such behaviour results in an inflationaryequilibrium (point C in Figure 5.1). One solution to this impasse isto transfer responsibility for monetary policy to an independentcentral bank. Because central bankers are normally appointed forlong periods and do not have to face re-election in a popular vote,it is argued that they are in a better position than electedgovernments to take a long-term view. Whereas the temptation fora government to inflate the economy in the run-up to a generalelection may be irresistible, there exists no equivalent incentive fora central bank to depart from the optimal, long-run goal of pricestability.

In terms of the indifference curves set out in Figure 5.1, centralbanks will thus tend to attach less importance to low unemploymentthan governments, since there is no electoral advantage to be

Page 129: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

BARRY HARRISON AND NIGEL M.HEALEY

112

gained. In other words, the indifference curves of an independentcentral bank are likely to be much flatter than those of agovernment. The widespread image of central bankers as‘conservative’ accords closely with this interpretation of their likelyobjective function. Moreover, if the central bank were statutorilybound to pursue price stability (and, by implication, give no weightat all to employment and output), it will always pursue the long-runutilitymaximising policy. Figure 5.2 shows that, if the central bankwere concerned only with inflation (giving no weight tounemployment), its indifference curves would be horizontal. Thebest indifference curve it could attain would be the one runningalong the horizontal axis; i.e., I0.

If the economy were at point B with inflationary expectationsequal to P0, the central bank would (unlike the government) haveno incentive to move to a higher inflation rate. And if the economywere at point C, the central bank would move to point D. Althoughthis would cause a temporary increase in unemployment (from UN

to U2) which would persist until inflationary expectations moder-ated and thereby shifted the short-run Phillips Curve downwardsfrom SRPC(Pe=P1) to SRPC(Pe=P0), these costs would be once-for-

Figure 5.2 Central bank independence and the Phillips Curve

Page 130: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

EUROPEAN MONETARY UNION

113

all and offset by the benefits of price stability which would besustained over time (but see Rogoff, 1985; Healey et al., 1995).

THE DIMENSIONS OF CENTRAL BANKINDEPENDENCE

There are two dimensions to central bank independence. First, thecentral bank must be politically independent, in the sense that itsdecisions should not be subject to the approval or direction of thegovernment. Ideally, the government of the day should not be ableto ‘rig’ the bank’s policymaking executive by appointing either thegovernor or its senior staff. To the extent that the government hasthe power to make such appointments, the interests of politicalindependence are best served by having lengthy, secure terms oftenure for key executives, which are spread out so that only a smallproportion falls due for renewal within the lifetime of any onegovernment. Mandatory government representatives on the bank’sexecutive also militate against political independence.

Second, the central bank should be economically independent,in the sense that it can execute monetary policy without beingblown off course by government actions. For example, in manycountries, the government has an account with its national centralbank, which it can effectively overdraw at will—thereby increasingthe money supply. Central banks may also be obliged to buy anyissue of government bonds that is not taken up by the generalpublic, with the same effect on the money supply. Under suchcircumstances, a tight monetary policy could be undermined by anincrease in the budget deficit. Some instruments of monetarypolicy may also be under the control of the government. Forexample, historically British governments have imposed bothqualitative and quantitative controls on commercial bank lending.Tables 5.1 and 5.2 show how the national central banks of theEU member states presently rank on these measures of politicaland economic independence.

The implications of EMU for public finances

The creation of an independent ECB, with a statutory responsibilityfor maintaining price stability, will clearly have importantimplications for the governments of member states. As notedabove, it will end the ability of national governments to use

Page 131: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

BARRY HARRISON AND NIGEL M.HEALEY

114

surprise inflation for electoral purposes. But EMU will also affectnational public finances in two other ways (see Healey and Levine,1992b).

First, the right to issue fiat money (i.e., notes and coin) will betransferred from national governments to the ECB, so that‘seigniorage’ profits will be lost to member governments (Drazen,1989; Grilli, 1989). Table 5.3 shows that the southernMediterranean countries (Greece, Portugal and Spain) will beparticularly adversely affected by this change. At present, thesecountries have relatively undeveloped financial systems, whichmeans that their currency ratios (i.e., currency as a proportion ofthe money stock) are higher than in northern states. This regionalso suffers relatively high inflation rates, which continuously erodethe real value of currency in circulation, obliging the private sectorto hold ever-larger cash balances for transactions purposes. Againstthe backdrop of inflation, the seigniorage profits from currencyissue afford a significant source of revenue for nationalgovernments. And the higher the currency ratio and the higher the

Table 5.1 Measures of political independence

Key:1. Governor not appointed by government.2. Governor appointed for 5+ years.3. Executive not appointed by government.4. Executive appointed for 5+ years.5. No mandatory government representative on executive.6. No government approval of policy decision required.7. Statutory requirement for central bank to pursue price stability.8. Explicit conflicts between central bank and government possible.9. Index of political independence (sum of asterisks in each row).Source: Alesina and Grilli (1991).

Page 132: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

EUROPEAN MONETARY UNION

115

Table 5.2 Measures of economic independence

Key:1. Government credit from central bank not automatic.2. Government credit from central bank at market interest rate.3. Government credit from central bank for temporary period only.4. Government credit from central bank limited in amount.5. Central bank does not take up unsold government bond issues.6. Discount rate set by central bank.7. No government qualitative controls on commercial bank lending since 1980.8. No government quantitative controls on bank lending since 1980.9. Index of economic independence (sum of asterisks in each row).Source: Alesina and Grilli (1991).

Table 5.3 Seigniorage revenue as a percentage of national gross domesticproduct

Source: Bank for International Settlements.

Page 133: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

BARRY HARRISON AND NIGEL M.HEALEY

116

rate of inflation, the greater the importance of the seignioragerevenue as a means of financing government expenditure.

The second obvious implication of EMU for national publicfinances is that the requirement of economic independence for theECB will deny governments the right of automatic, unlimited accessto central bank credit (Demopoulos et al., 1987). In contrast to thepresent arrangements within many member states, nationalgovernments will no longer be able to finance budget deficits—orrefinance maturing government debt—by selling bonds to theircentral banks and increasing the money supply. To the extent thatboth the loss of seigniorage revenues and the ending of automaticcredit facilities will make it more difficult for national governmentsto finance large budget deficits and refinance large national debts(i.e., as fixed-term bonds mature), many economists have arguedthat member states should have their public finances in order priorto joining EMU.

THE MAASTRICHT TREATY

Reflecting concern over the constitutional status of the new ECB,the Maastricht Treaty requires that the proposed European centralbanking system will be constitutionally independent of electedgovernments and legally bound to maintain price stability within theEU. Although collectively termed the ECB, the system willcomprise:

1 the ECB, which will have a president and an executive of sixmembers appointed by the European Council for eight-yearterms, and a governing council (the executive plus governors ofthe national central banks from participating member states); plus

2 the European System of Central Banks (ESCB), consisting ofparticipating national central banks, which will act as regionalagents in carrying out the policy instructions of the ECB.

To the extent that all the significant decision-making power willreside at the centre with the ECB, the use of the term, ECB, todescribe the system as a whole is retained in what follows. Tables5.4 and 5.5 show that on all indices of political and economicindependence the proposed ECB will be identical to the GermanBundesbank, which is presently the most independent of all EUcentral banks (see Tables 5.1 and 5.2).

Page 134: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

EUROPEAN MONETARY UNION

117

Since the ECB will embrace, and operate through, nationalcentral banks, the Maastricht Treaty requires that the latter endtheir present links with their national governments, becoming fullypolitically and economically independent before they may beadmitted to the ESCB. Article 7 of the Treaty, for example,specifically forbids any national central bank in the ESCB seekingor taking instructions from any other EU institution, including itsnational government (Council of Ministers, 1992).

To minimise the transitional unemployment costs of EMU to thehistorically high-inflation countries of the EU (e.g., Britain, Italy,Spain, Portugal, Greece), the Treaty envisages that the move to asingle currency will depend on the fulfilment of certain‘convergence criteria’ (see also Chapter 4). The logic of theseconditions is that, if satisfied, the short-run costs of giving upmonetary sovereignty will be modest and, by implication,outweighed by the likely benefits. The criteria include threeindicators of inflation convergence:

1 successful candidates must have inflation rates no more than1.5% above the three EU countries with the lowest inflationrates;

2 long-term interest rates should be no more than 2% above thethree countries with the lowest rates; and

3 the national currency must not have been devalued and must

Table 5.4 Measures of political independence

Note: Key as Table 5.1 above.Source: Alesina and Grilli (1991).

Table 5.5 Measures of economic independence

Note: Key as Table 5.2 above.Source: Alesina and Grilli (1991).

Page 135: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

BARRY HARRISON AND NIGEL M.HEALEY

118

have remained within the ‘normal’ bands of the ERM(currently ±15%) for the previous two years.

With the exception of (2), these three criteria are self-explanatory.The significance of (2) lies in the fact that long-term interest ratesprovide a guide to the financial markets’ expectations of inflation inthe longer term. Put simply, today’s long-term interest rate is aweighted average of expected future short-term interest rates. Ifinvestors expect inflation to be high in the future, they will expectshort-term interest rates to be correspondingly high in the future aswell. Today’s long-term interest rate will accordingly be higher than ina country where inflation is expected to remain low in the future.

There are two further convergence criteria which relate to theability of member states to bear the fiscal discipline entailed byEMU membership. As noted above, the loss of seigniorage profitsand the ending of automatic borrowing facilities will mean thatgovernments will find it harder to finance budget deficits andrefinance large public sector debts. The Maastricht Treaty thereforerequires limits on both measures of the public finances:

1 national budget deficits must be less than 3% of GDP; and2 the national debt must be less than 60% of GDP (or at least

satisfactorily falling towards this level).

If at least seven member states meet all five prerequisites by theend of 1996, a specially convened IGC may set a date for a morelimited EMU that—initially at least—will exclude the other EUcountries. The remaining states may then join as and when theircircumstances allow. Should the 1996 conference fail to set a datefor EMU, it will be reconvened in 1998. At this time, if at least fivemember states meet the prerequisites agreed at Maastricht, thosethat qualify will automatically adopt a common currency in 1999,leaving the others to apply for membership in due course.

THE WAY FORWARD

At the end of 1994, only Luxembourg met the five convergencecriteria and few of the remaining member states looked likesatisfying them by the end of 1996 (see also Chapter 4). Table5.6 i l lustrates the convergence criteria as they would haveapplied had they been in force in 1994, together with the actual

Page 136: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

EUROPEAN MONETARY UNION

119

economic performance of the EU member states at that time. Itshows that, reflecting the severity of the early 1990s’ recessionin the EU, almost all the member states violated the budgetdeficit ceiling of 3% of GDP, while only four had debt:GDPratios below the 60% limit. Moreover, the turmoil in the foreignexchange markets in 1992–93, which led to the withdrawal ofsterling and the lira from the EMS and a series of devaluations(despite the enforced widening of the ‘normal’ target bandsfrom ±2.25% to ±15%), has set back the prospect of the weakercurrency states meeting the convergence criteria for exchangerate stability. Although the Edinburgh Summit in December 1992reaffirmed the commitment of the EU member states to thetimetable for EMU embodied in the Maastricht Treaty, theconcept of a monetary union embracing all twelve memberstates (plus those members of the European Free Trade Areawhich join in 1995) now looks very remote.

A more likely scenario—inspired by, but separate from, theMaastricht Treaty—is the emergence of a ‘mini EMU’ between

Table 5.6 Convergence criteria and out-turns in 1994

Note: *denotes convergence criteria met.Source: European Economy.

Page 137: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

BARRY HARRISON AND NIGEL M.HEALEY

120

Germany, France, the Benelux countries and (possibly) Denmark.The prospect of a two-speed Europe has always been a possibleoutcome, given that several of the poorer EU states were unlikelyto satisfy the convergence criteria by either 1996 or 1998. But acombination of deepening recession and exchange rate volatility,culminating in Britain and Italy’s withdrawal from the ERM anddevaluations by the weaker currencies, has seriously weakened theenthusiasm for EMU in the poorer member states and increased thelikelihood of an informal mini EMU being established by a core ofrich northern European states. The momentum for the ‘granddesign’ envisaged by the Maastricht Treaty may now have beenlargely lost, at least for the foreseeable future.

A mini EMU would have several important advantages over themodel envisaged by the Maastricht Treaty: 1 it need only involve those countries that really want to

participate in monetary union (as opposed to those, like Britain,which reluctantly acquiesced in the Maastricht initiative for fearof being left behind);

2 it would follow naturally from economic convergence, ratherthan forcing convergence on would-be members;

3 the arbitrary convergence criteria set out in the MaastrichtTreaty, which if interpreted strictly would permanently excludemembers like Belgium on the grounds of its high debt ratio,could be ignored (but see Chapter 4); and

4 it would obviate the need for major institutional changes in theEU, leaving the basic framework of national central bankscooperating within the EMS unchanged.

The shape of a mini EMU

The most probable shape of any mini EMU would be a ‘hard’version of the EMS as it presently exists. The central feature of theEMS is, of course, the ERM, an arrangement by which memberstates undertake to maintain their bilateral exchange rates withinnarrow margins around predetermined central parities. The width ofthe official standard band is now ±15%. As noted above, in theabsence of capital controls, maintaining exchange rates within thesebands requires a high degree of monetary policy coordination (i.e.,a significant sacrifice of monetary sovereignty). Higher interest rates

Page 138: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

EUROPEAN MONETARY UNION

121

in one member state imply higher interest rates in all others topreserve the desired pattern of bilateral exchange rates.

In the original design of the EMS, which came into operation in1979, it was intended that the national central banks ofparticipating states would cooperatively agree a joint monetarystance that maximised collective welfare. In practice, however, theGerman Bundesbank—an independent central bank charged with astatutory duty to maintain German price stability (see above)—hasconsistently refused to be tied by such collective decisions, fearingthat it might be obliged to adopt a monetary stance that wouldcompromise its domestic inflation objectives (see Chapter 2). TheBundesbank’s reluctance is understandable. Its record of low andstable inflation stands in marked contrast to the performance ofthe other major EU states (see Table 5.7). Accordingly, theBundesbank continued to set German interest rates exclusively withreference to German economic conditions after 1979, pre-sentingother, more inflation-prone members with a stark choice: 1 either they followed the German lead and adjusted their own

interest rates accordingly; or2 their currencies would depreciate against the deutschmark,

eventually forcing them to devalue; or3 they left the ERM altogether. While there were, as a direct result of this inherent tension withinthe EMS, a number of exchange rate realignments during the earlyyears, there was a growing realisation by other EU governmentsthat acceding to so-called ‘German policy leadership’—i.e., passivelyfollowing Germany’s monetary stance—might offer a means ofachieving greater exchange rate stability (i.e., by reducing thepressure for realignments) and guaranteeing greater domestic pricestability. By the mid-1980s, the EMS had grown into a ‘deutschmark

Table 5.7 Comparative inflation records, 1979–94

Source: European Economy.

Page 139: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

BARRY HARRISON AND NIGEL M.HEALEY

122

bloc’, with the German Bundesbank setting a common monetarystance for all participating member states. As a monetaryarrangement, the EMS offers many of the advantages anddisadvantages of EMU: 1 it reduces exchange rate uncertainty;2 it entails the sacrifice of monetary sovereignty by non-German

member states; and3 at its heart lies the independent Bundesbank, with an established

reputation for price stability. The recent tensions within the EMS have, in turn, largelystemmed from a sharp increase in the perceived costs ofsacrificing monetary sovereignty by the weaker member states. Asnoted above, adher-ing to a common monetary policy imposesshort-run costs on member states unless inflation performance ineach is harmonised. The key problem of recent years has been thelarge economic shock which struck Germany just as the othermember states were moving into recession. The impact ofGerman reunification delivered a huge stimulus to the Germaneconomy, resulting in strong economic growth during 1990–91 andthe build-up of inflationary pressures. The northern Europeaneconomies (e.g., Denmark, the Benelux countries and, to a lesserextent, France) which are highly integrated with Germany sharedsome of the fruits of this temporary boom, but for Britain andthe poorer southern states, reunification served to desynchronisetheir business cycles from the cycle in Germany. As theBundesbank raised interest rates to bear down on Germaninflation, following the German lead imposed unwelcome andunnecessary deflationary pressure on the weaker member states.

As the recession deepened and unemployment mounted, the callsfor governments in countries like Britain to cut interest rates anddevalue against the deutschmark mounted. In turn, fear ofdevaluation generated such intense foreign exchange marketspeculation that the weaker currencies came under irresistiblepressure and, one by one, they were either driven out of the EMSor devalued. For those northern states that remain in the EMS,however, the present arrangements provide the basis for asustainable mini EMU that could emerge without the need forformal EU approval by all member states. Already Belgium andLuxembourg have a monetary union between their states (i.e., their

Page 140: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

EUROPEAN MONETARY UNION

123

currencies are interchangeable). These two states, together with theNetherlands, informally adhere to very narrow target bands vis-à-viseach other’s currencies and the deutschmark, notwithstanding theEU’s decision in August 1993 to officially move to ultra-wide ±15%bands. France and other countries wanting to join the mini EMU(probably only Denmark) could follow suit, steadily reducing thebands for their exchange rate fluctuations until their bilateral rateswere irrevocably fixed. All these changes could occur within thepresent EMS, without the need for fixed timetables or formaltreaties. Via this evolutionary approach, a mini EMU mightgradually unfold, in which member currencies would be seen asvirtually interchangeable—providing many of the benefits of asingle currency without actually introducing one.

CONCLUSIONS

Despite the recent upheavals in the currency markets, EU memberstates remain committed to EMU, and the Maastricht Treaty is animportant milestone along the road. It establishes clear and specificcriteria to assess whether member states are sufficiently convergentin certain key areas to move to Stage Three and sets a time limit,January 1, 1999, for its commencement. Agreement was alsoreached on the objectives and independence of the ESCB, thoughnot on the operational procedures it will use to conduct itsmonetary policy. The task of obtaining agreement on operationalprocedures is delegated to the European Monetary Institute (seeChapters 4 and 6), which was set up at the commencement ofStage Two in 1994. Although there are several difficult hurdles toclear, such as the way in which the ESCB will operate so as toachieve a uniform interest rate throughout the EU, the reserveratios it will hold and the extent of prudential supervision it willexercise over the banking system, these problems are notinsurmountable. However, it is clear that all member states will notsatisfy the convergence criteria and it seems likely that there will bea two-speed approach, with the emergence of a mini EMU takingplace—either inside or outside the Maastricht framework.

Page 141: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

124

6

WHAT PRICE EUROPEANMONETARY UNION?

Patrick Minford

INTRODUCTION

The ratification of the Maastricht Treaty in 1993 led, ironically, toa renewed debate in the European Union (EU) over the future ofmonetary union. This debate was no longer confined to Britain,but spread to Germany, where there is concern over thepremature disappearance of the deutschmark, and to France,where one concern is the potential dominance of Germany in afuture European central bank (ECB). In Italy, while there remainsenthusiasm for monetary union, there is concern about theMaastricht conditions on public debt and deficits that must bemet. This chapter reviews the main issues involved and sets outsome new proposals for both the long-term objectives ofEuropean monetary union (EMU) and the short-term methods oftransition.

THE LONG-TERM CASE FOR EUROPEANMONETARY UNION: A CRITIQUE

A good starting point for discussing the advantages of a commoncurrency is the report of the EC Commission (1990b), which madean heroic attempt to measure the potential benefits. The reportspeculates that the efficiency gain from removing currencyuncertainty and exchange costs may be worth as much as 10% ofthe EU’s gross domestic product (GDP). Virtually all of this comesfrom the effect of a supposed reduction in the ‘risk premium’ onthe cost of capital. Various other gains are adduced from thecommon currency—increased price stability (including through

Page 142: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

WHAT PRICE EUROPEAN MONETARY UNION?

125

enhanced credibility), more disciplined public finance and greatermacroeconomic stability.

However, it is important to note that price stability, on which thereport places much emphasis, is attainable with or without EMU, as isgreater credibility. Whether EMU makes these benefits more easilyattainable is a matter of political economy, which is not tackled bythe Commission’s report. What will the European central bank’spowers and incentives be? What legitimacy will be conferred on itby the twelve democratic peoples of the EU? These questions areunderstandably not addressed in the Commission’s report, butmerely assumed away.

But even if they were convincingly answered, there would still bethe alternative of pursuing price stability credibly by domesticmeans. Domestic means of commitment exist, and are effectivelyachieved in many OECD economies such as Germany, the UnitedStates and Japan. Essentially they involve some form of domesticnominal target, whether the money supply or nominal income orsimply price behaviour, with the commitment penalties supplied bythe political process. To put it crudely, governments that fail todeliver acceptable inflation performance lose votes. Ultimately thismust be the only effective penalty for macroeconomicmismanagement in a sovereign democracy.

This issue of domestic commitment highlights the difficultiesinherent in designing a Europe-wide commitment process formonetary policy. As the Germans have persistently pointed out,there is a ‘democratic deficit’ in the EU. Without democraticpolitical union, there would indeed be a lack of democraticlegitimacy for a European central bank imposing tough monetarypolicies on twelve (or more) national regions of Europe, some ofwhich may well be suffering from severe recession in spite of anEU-wide inflation. This lack of democratic accountability wouldalso fatally undermine credibility.

If we turn to public finance, the report envisages greaterdiscipline arising from the inability of a national government toraise taxation through printing money (‘seigniorage’ or the ‘inflationtax’); this inability is reinforced by the Maastricht fiscal criteria,designed to limit the risks of country bail-outs (see also Chapter 5).Here a virtue is made of what the literature conventionally regardsas a problem, namely making optimal taxation more difficult.However, the Commission’s report offers no mechanisms, onlypious hopes and peer country pressure, for achieving movement to

Page 143: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

PATRICK MINFORD

126

fiscal balance under EMU. Abolishing seigniorage without analternative fiscal mechanism for raising revenue hardly seems toconstitute a fiscal improvement. The distressing implications areillustrated by the difficulties of Italy, which is unable to raise taxthrough inflation, while being condemned by the Maastricht criteriato ambitious targets for primary budget surpluses without (judgingby its long-standing performance) the political capacity to deliverthe necessary taxes or spending cuts.

The large efficiency gain speculated on in the EU report comesfrom removing the transaction costs of currency exchange and thehedging costs of guarding against currency uncertainty. There aretwo arguments which suggest its estimate is likely to be well on thehigh side: 1 currency risk is diversifiable in a world of many currencies and

investment vehicles whose risks are correlated with currencyrisk. Hence the cost of hedging should tend to the premium onspecific risk (i.e., zero); and

2 a transaction involving currency exchange should not, on theface of it (given the negligible cost of keying in electronicorders), cost any extra in credit transactions than an ordinarytransaction in home currency, other than the cost of hedgingnet balances in any one currency between clearings.

These considerations suggest that the only saving comes in theexchange of notes and coin. But this is extremely limited. Notesand coin is generally a small percentage of the total money supply(with one or two exceptions such as Italy and Greece) and that partof it which is exchanged for foreign notes and coin is a smallpercentage of that again.

The Commission’s estimate of the transactions cost saving on itsown is 0.4% of GDP. This is based on a survey of financial firms’commission charges, and these are applied to estimates of thevolume of business attracting these charges. While this is a morebelievable estimate than the huge aggregate figure, it may still be onthe high side. Indeed, the report suggests that it is heavilyconcentrated among the smaller countries with less sophisticatedbanking systems (and for a country with a sophisticated system likeBritain may be as low as 0.1% of GDP).

We have seen so far that the only firm gain from EMU adducedby the Commission is that connected with transactions costs

Page 144: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

WHAT PRICE EUROPEAN MONETARY UNION?

127

savings. And this, at 0.1% of GDP for a country like Britain orGermany, is extraordinarily small. Indeed, if the gain were as largeas the EU estimate, then other pairs of nations enjoying a similardegree of bilateral trade would have surely actively considered acommon currency. Yet the countries of EFTA, of North America,of eastern Europe, to name but a few candidates, have neverseemed to put this idea seriously on the treaty agenda.

This last point suggests that, whatever the truth in theCommission’s estimate, there must be some key drawback to nationshaving a common currency. Indeed, the extensive literature on the‘optimum common currency area’ (Mundell, 1961) points to justsuch a drawback. Its thrust is that exchange rate adjustment,because it is more rapid than national wage and price adjustment, ismore effective in stabilising an open economy in the face ofdifferential national shocks (an extreme example of which would beGerman reunification in 1990). This thrust is contrary to theCommission’s assertion that EMU would bring greatermacroeconomic stability. The optimum currency literature invokes avariety of factors that may improve the stabilising capacity ofmonetary union—notably, a high degree of labour mobility, and acentral budget capable of making large fiscal transfers. But thesefactors are, as we shall see, absent in the case of the EU.

I wish now to examine how serious a drawback this is for EMU.How damaging is the loss of a flexible exchange rate (and so offlexible national interest rates) in reacting to economic shocks? Ishall loosely call this the ‘stabilisation’ aspect. In order to examineit, I use the method of ‘stochastic simulation’ on a macroeconomicmodel of the EU and other G7 economies. This involves pepper-ing the model with a large number of typical economic shocks. Thesimulated economies’ stability with regard to prices and output isthen compared under EMU and floating exchange rates. While thismethod has its weaknesses, which are discussed below, there is noviable alternative. Econometrics cannot disentangle the effects ofmonetary union from other influences on long-functioning unionssuch as the United States, and there is no data on the EU. Whateconometric work exists merely bears on the extent of integrationacross European countries—for example, Bayoumi and Eichengreen(1992) show that the United States is more integrated than the EU,while de Grauwe and Vanhaverbeke (1991), as well as von Hagenand Neumann (1991), show that the EU is less integrated acrosscountries than it is within countries.

Page 145: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

PATRICK MINFORD

128

STABILISATION GAINS AND LOSSES OFMONETARY UNION

In evaluating the stabilisation aspect for any given commoncurrency proposal, one must make assumptions about theinstitutional framework. As noted in Chapter 4, it makes a lot ofdifference, whether there is a high degree of labour mobility andwhat the fiscal transfer arrangements are. In the case of the EU, ithas been noted by Eichengreen (1990b) that the fiscal offset to anynational or regional decline in GDP is less than 1% (as against 30%in the United States, for instance); nor are there any plans to raisethis offset coefficient to any number remotely comparable with theUS figure. The Delors Committee (Delors, 1989) called for adoubling of EU expenditure, but even that may well not be agreedby the nations that have to double their fiscal contribution toBrussels, still less the much larger amounts suggested as theminimum necessary by MacDougall (1977).

Labour mobility is also limited, for the vast bulk of nationals inthe richer countries of the EU. The key reason appears to belanguage and cultural differences, which make a Frenchman pausebefore resettling in Frankfurt. What significant migration there istakes place from the poorer countries to the richer, as theimmigration controls that normally stop this are graduallydismantled under the 1992 programme (see also Chapter 10). Buteven this population movement is not great because capital mobilitywithin the free EU market enables workers in poorer countries,such as Spain and parts of Britain and Italy which are on the‘periphery’ of the EU, to attract investment and enjoy improvedwages without the cost of moving.

We assume that trade is free for our purposes here, eventhough in reality the full effects of the 1992 programme havenot yet fully come through and may not do so until the nextcentury (see Chapter 7). We also assume that capital is perfectlymobile within the EU and that there are no exchange controls. Itis obvious, as the optimum currency area literature stresses, thatwhatever stabilisation task is performed by flexible exchangerates and divergent monetar y pol icy, i t can par t ia l ly besubstituted for by either labour mobility or fiscal transfers. Tothat extent, the EU is handicapped in its bid to be an optimumcurrency area. Our calculations below reflect this handicap. (IfEMU goes ahead regardless, that might well lead to demands for

Page 146: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

WHAT PRICE EUROPEAN MONETARY UNION?

129

further progress on fiscal policy and labour mobility, but that isanother matter.)

Before proceeding, we should note a point frequently made bythose in favour of EMU, namely that monetary arrangements assuch should not alter the long-run equilibrium state of the realeconomy, but merely change national price levels. Real businesscycle theorists would go further and argue that even the short-runbehaviour of real variables should be immune to monetaryarrangements, provided that they do not constitute a change intransactions technology. The approach here is straightforward. Themodels used explicitly assume that real long-run equilibria areimmune to monetary arrangements. But these models feature avariety of ways in which short-run behaviour differs under differentmonetary arrangements, so my position is not that of the realbusiness cycle approach. That approach has not yet come up with arepresentation of European economies which can rival thatproduced by more conventional modern models with their stress onnominal contracts, monetary surprises and ‘rational’ (informationallyefficient) expectations.

We still have to answer the question of whether one canproperly capture behavioural differences across such differentregimes as flexible rates and the totally fixed rates of a commoncurrency. This problem, which was first highlighted by Lucas(1976)—and termed the ‘Lucas critique’—is inherent in most piecesof applied work that address issues of policy interest, which usuallyinvolve consideration of different policy regimes. Ultimately, thereis no satisfactory answer. Either one comes up with a model ofstylised consumers and producers whose tastes and technology canbe identified and assumed not to change, accepting that such amodel will have a poor fit and lack institutional relevance. Or oneproduces a model of aggregate supplies and demands, as used here,in which the estimates fit reasonably but the estimated coefficientsthemselves may shift as people change their behaviour in changedenvironments.

I make use of two multilateral models linking separate modelsof the major OECD economies: Multimod and Liverpool. Both arereasonably well-known representatives of the class of modeldescribed above. The Multimod model (see Masson et al., 1990)estimated conventionally but is a simulation rather than aforecasting model; it assumes fairly long overlapping wage contracts.The Liverpool model (see Minford et al., 1986; Matthews, 1992) is

Page 147: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

PATRICK MINFORD

130

fully estimated. It uses a ‘new classical’ framework, in whichcontracts do not overlap but are disturbed by annual monetarysurprises. In both models, adjustment costs produce long drawn-outadjustment.

Before embarking on this comparison, it is worth asking whatone might expect to find. Holding money supplies of relevantcountries constant (as in the ‘k-percent rule’ suggested byFriedman, 1968), one would observe the relative capacity of thetwo exchange rate regimes to stabilise shocks, leading to ‘modelstability’. We have already explained how, following the argumentsof the optimum currency area literature, we would expect greaterstability under floating exchange rates (with the implied flexibilityof national interest rates).

When one turns to the possibilities for active monetaryresponses to shocks—something that few would wish to rule out,especially when shocks are large and identifiable—there may appearto be a trade-off between the number of independent monetaryinstruments for dealing with differential national shocks (maximisedunder floating) and the extent of monetary coordination (whichmust be total under fully fixed exchange rates). Nevertheless,

Figure 6.1 Commission estimates (variability measured by standarddeviation)

Page 148: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

WHAT PRICE EUROPEAN MONETARY UNION?

131

coordination under fixed rates will not imply the same set ofmonetary policies as coordination under floating rates. It must, inprinciple, be the case that cooperation using the full scope ofindependence granted by floating will be optimal. Again, therefore,we would expect floating to have the advantage in this aspect ofthe competition.

The results of the available studies are summarised in Figures6.1 to 6.3. Full details of these studies are in EC Commission(1990b), Minford et al. (1992), and Masson and Symansky (1992).Both the Commission and Masson and Symansky use Multimod fortheir stochastic simulations. However, the Commission’s study hasbeen criticised by the later studies cited above for two main aspectsof its approach. First, it attributes an implausibly high variability tothe risk premia on interest differentials between EU currencies(these risks are, of course, eliminated under EMU). Second, itassumes somewhat unusual monetary policy regimes (rules whereinterest rates vary in response to inflation and output targets).Using these assumptions, the Commission finds that EMU is

Figure 6.2 Masson and Symansky (1992) estimates with Multimod(variability measured by standard deviation)Key: R3, 3% bands, real exchange rate trigger for realignment; E5, 5%bands, equilibrium realignment; M(E/F), money target; Y(E/F), nominalincome target: E, EMU; F, floating.

Page 149: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

PATRICK MINFORD

132

superior in stability to floating. When Masson and Symansky allowfor plausibly lower-risk premium variability and for alternativemonetary regimes they obtain results more in line with the priorexpectations described above.

Altering the Commission’s simulations for risk premia alonereduces substantially the ‘advantage’ it found for EMU. However,this is not the whole story; the monetary policy assumptions madeunder the differing exchange rate regimes must also be appropriate.If a destabilising monetary policy is assumed under floating, while astabilising one is assumed under EMU, then the relative stability ofEMU will clearly be biased upwards. In principle, one wishes toassume under each exchange rate regime the optimal monetary policywithin the feasible set: that reveals the best potential performanceof each exchange rate regime. It is also reasonable to ask how eachexchange rate system will perform under optimal automatic rulesfor monetary policy. It may be better for such rules to be embracedby politicians, because of the difficulties surrounding successful

Figure 6.3 Minford et al. (1992) estimates on Liverpool model (variabilitymeasured by standard deviation)Key: 1, money supply fixed; 2, non-cooperative contingent response; 3,cooperative contingent response.

Page 150: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

WHAT PRICE EUROPEAN MONETARY UNION?

133

discretionary policy (see Chapter 5). Again, though, one would wishto choose the best automatic rule for monetary policy under eachexchange rate regime.

Masson and Symansky (1992) make two main comparisons: (i)under fixed money supply rules; and (ii) under rules where interestrates target money GDP (or nominal income). Their work makes itpossible to put the Multimod simulations alongside those using theLiverpool model produced by Minford et al. (1992). These authorslooked at a different set of monetary regimes. In respect ofregimes with non-automatic responses (discretionary policy inwhich, however, there is assumed to be no attempted manipulationof expectations by false promises, a phenomenon known as‘timeinconsistency’), they investigated fully optimal monetarypolicies, both under ‘Nash’ non-cooperative policies and under EUcooperation. However, among automatic rules, they restrictedthemselves solely to fixed money supplies.

The main point which emerges from the three sets of resultsshown in Figures 6.1 to 6.3 is that, whether one uses the Liverpoolor the Multimod models, once shocks are put on a comparablebasis, then floating gives scope for substantially better stability(provided monetary policies are suitably chosen) than EMU. Thisresult for Multimod is not as strong as for the Liverpool model,which may well reflect the absence of optimisation in the Multimodexercise. However, what emerges overall is essentially the conclusionone would reach from following the logic of the optimum currencyarea literature in its modern stochastic version.

I have avoided any discussion of the political passions raised bythe issue of sovereignty. But, in fact, no nation would be abandoningits sovereignty under the proposals for union so far discussed (seeChapters 4 and 5 for a more detailed discussion). Effectively thesehave been for little more than totally fixed exchange rates with asingle monetary authority. Any country which dislikes the resultcould, in principle, leave it and issue its own currency again,supposing this to have been merged without trace. This is not, infact, proposed, given the intentions to allow member states to issuenationally distinct ECU notes—for example, in Britain, future ECUnotes may have the monarch’s head on one side.

It is this very lack of a political dimension (and so lack of aserious central budget, as well as limited labour mobility) that loadsthe dice against macroeconomic stability, besides raising theproblem of legitimacy. Yet, as is widely conceded, it is totally

Page 151: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

PATRICK MINFORD

134

unrealistic to discuss any political dimension. In thesecircumstances, one can perhaps discuss the merits of a move tototal exchange fixity in purely economic terms. If the economicgains were great then a treaty—reversible, like all treaties—acquiringthem could be worthwhile, even though there would still beinevitable doubts about the practical problems of reversibility andthe resulting political hostage to fortune. In this sense, politicaldoubts over sovereignty place the burden of proof on EMU.

THE TRANSITION TO MONETARY UNION

The macroeconomic instability likely to be caused by EMU at thepresent stage of economic integration in the EU, when set againstthe small gain in transactions costs discussed earlier, seems to makea strong case against moving to a common currency. This is not tosay that increasing integration (that is, greater intra-EU trade ingoods, services and factors of production, which is nothingwhatever to do with the ‘convergence’ hitherto discussed inChapters 4 and 5) will not eventually push the calculation the otherway, for a gradually increasing set of nations (giving rise to ‘variablegeometry’ or an ‘n-tier’ union). Increasing integration both raisesthe gain from transactions costs and reduces the loss frominstability (as shocks become more similar across member states innature and impact). So there is a need for a transitional regimewhich both permits this evolving union to occur at the appropriatemoments and works effectively for the united as well as the not-so-united member states.

So far, I have not commented on the results for the exchangerate mechanism (ERM) in Figures 6.1 to 6.3. They are palpablyworse than for EMU, illustrating the generally appreciated featurethat the ERM creates a degree of fixity without full credibility orultimate policy commitment. This gives the worst of both worldsand accounts for the one element of agreement on all sides—thatthe system should move either to complete fixity (and so EMU) orback to floating.

There is, however, one regime which gives both good results andachieves the sort of cooperation that has been one of theproclaimed aims of those who set up the ERM. The cooperationthat it involves between central banks should also smooth the pathto monetary union as and when appropriate. At such a moment, thecooperation would become a lockstep by agreement. The regime in

Page 152: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

WHAT PRICE EUROPEAN MONETARY UNION?

135

question is illustrated in Figure 6.3 for the Liverpool results(unfortunately it is not available for Multimod) and entails‘cooperative floating’, numbered 3 among the floating regimes. Thisregime, of course, achieves the best of both worlds, exploiting the‘degrees of freedom’ in floating, while enjoying the cooperationintended by the ERM.

There are those who argue that such cooperation is inconceivablewithin Europe, without the rules of an exchange rate arrangementlike the ERM. Yet in game-theoretic terms, cooperative equilibrium(which respects individual country interests, but arranges mutuallyimproving policy trades) is a dominant one when players cancommunicate, since they have a joint interest in achieving it. Hence,the argument can be turned on its head. It is unlikely that, in theabsence of the sub-optimal constraints of the ERM, central bankswhich are used to communicating with each other would abstainfrom such a cooperative equilibrium. Politically, too, thearrangement would be attractive, given the concerns mentioned atthe start of this chapter.

In short, what I am proposing is a reformed Stage Two, in whichthe European Monetary Institute could take on the role of acoordinating forum in which the twelve governments, representedby their central banks under whatever national controls are desired,could meet regularly and share their monetary plans. All exchangerate bands and intervention targets would be abandoned. Thecentral banks would set monetary targets, both for suitable moneysupply measures and for operating instruments, especially interestrates. They would also design their own detailed rules and operatingprocedures for achieving this cooperative equilibrium in everydaypractice.

CONCLUSIONS

It is widely believed that the currency upheavals of 1992–93 havederailed the Maastricht route to EMU. However, while the politicalfeasibility of EMU is now in doubt, the idea that, if achieved,EMU would generate major benefits for the EU member states interms of reduced transactions costs and greater monetary stabilityis well established. This chapter challenges this received wisdom,testing the EMU proposals against alternative monetary regimes andshowing that cooperative floating is the optimal arrangement. Itproposes a route out of the present monetary impasse in Europe,

Page 153: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

PATRICK MINFORD

136

where there is little enthusiasm (rightly on the view here) for EMUand yet substantial—and again justified—dissatisfaction with thecurrent ERM. The proposed route is an evolving structure ofcentral bank cooperation that exploits the full stabilising potentialof floating exchange rates.

Page 154: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

Part II

MICROECONOMICISSUES

Page 155: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union
Page 156: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

139

7

COMPLETING THEINTERNAL MARKET IN THE

EUROPEAN UNIONFrank McDonald

INTRODUCTION

It is somewhat ironic that in the 1970s and 1980s the European Union(EU) was often referred to as the ‘common market’. For in this period,the EU had not created the conditions which are necessary for acommon market to exist (see Chapter 1). The Treaty of Rome calledfor the creation of a customs union and a common market. Theseobjectives are clearly outlined in Article 3 of the Treaty of Rome.Indeed, many of the articles of the Treaty are concerned withestablishing the so-called ‘four freedoms’—that is, freedom ofmovement of goods, services, capital and labour. Yet in spite of thiscommitment, the EU had not created a common market by the 1980s.

However, in 1987 the Single European Act (SEA) was agreedand it committed all the member states to the creation of acommon market by the end of 1992. A legislative programme witha detailed timetable had been published in the 1985 White Paper,Completing the Internal Market (EC Commission, 1985). Thisprogramme acquired many different names: the ‘internal market’,the ‘1992 programme’ and the ‘single market’ or the ‘singleEuropean market’ (SEM). This chapter provides an overview of the1992 programme, including an assessment of its likely effects (seealso Cecchini, 1988; EC Commission, 1988b; Healey, 1992b).

THE ECONOMIC RATIONALE FOR THE SINGLEEUROPEAN MARKET

When the SEA was signed, the EU had achieved a customs unionof sorts, with some minor exceptions that related to Spain and

Page 157: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

FRANK MCDONALD

140

Portugal. The customs union had only been completed in terms ofthe elimination of tariffs and quotas and by the erection of aCommon External Tariff. However, the Treaty of Rome requiredthe removal of ‘customs duties and of quantitative restrictions onthe import and export of goods, and of all other measures havinglike effect’ (Article 3a). Customs duties and quantitative restrictionsrefer to tariffs and quotas while other measures can be summed upby use of the term, ‘non-tariff barriers’ (NTBs). Any measures thatact in a similar manner to tariffs and quotas can be classified asNTBs. These include the laws, regulations and policies of nationalgovernments that limit or prevent international trade.

The welfare effects of tariffs, quotas and non-tariff barriers

In what follows, it will be assumed that trade is conducted in anenvironment of perfect competition and that any tariffs or NTBsdo not alter prices in international markets. In Figure 7.1, theeffects of a tariff are illustrated (see Chapter 1 for a fullerdiscussion of the welfare effects of protectionism). In this figure,DH represents domestic demand, SH is domestic supply, SW is worldsupply, PW is the price in the world market and PW+t is price plus

Figure 7.1 The welfare effects of protection revisited

Page 158: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

COMPLETING THE INTERNAL MARKET

141

the amount of the tariff (assumed to be a lump-sum tariff). Beforethe implementation of the tariff, demand at price PW would be Q4,domestic supply would be Q1 and consequently the difference, Q4-Q1, would be imports. If a tariff, t, was imposed, the domestic pricewould rise by the amount of the tariff, that is, to PW+t, domesticdemand would contract to Q3, domestic supply would increase to Q2

and the level of imports would fall to Q3-Q2.The welfare effects of this can be measured using the concept

of consumer surplus. As a result of the tariff-induced price rise,there would be a fall in consumer surplus shown by the area PWPW+t

BF. Of this loss, PWPW+t AD would be transferred to domesticsuppliers in order to obtain the increase in domestic supply. Thearea CAD indicates the extra cost of supplying the increaseddomestic output. This is a net welfare loss to society because it isthe cost incurred as a result of the increase in domestic supply. Ofthe remaining consumer surplus loss of ABFD, an amount equal tothe level of imports times the size of the tariff would betransferred to the government as revenue from the tariff; that is,area ABED. The remaining consumer surplus loss, shown by thearea BFE, arises from the reduction in domestic demand thatresults from the tariff. This is a net welfare loss to society resultingfrom the imposition of the tariff. The effect of the tariff is totransfer income from consumers to producers and the governmentand there is also a net welfare loss to society equal to the sum ofareas CAD and BFE.

If a quota of Q3-Q2 was used instead of a tariff, the net welfareloss would be the same, because the quota would push the price upto PW+t, demand would fall to Q3 and domestic supply would rise toQ2. The major difference is that the government would not receiveany revenue from the quota. In these circumstances, the areaABED accrues to the importers of the good.

The use of an NTB would have a very similar effect to that of aquota. Suppose that in order to sell good X, the exporter mustcomply with the national regulations which govern the sale of thatgood in the country to which they wish to sell. As the exporter hasto comply with the regulations, he or she would face an additionalcost which is assumed to be equivalent to the tariff, t, in Figure 7.1.In this case, the effect of the NTB would be to push the domesticprice to PW+t, leading to the same welfare effects as a quota of Q3-Q2. The difference is that, instead of accruing to the importer asprofit, the area ABED would represent the opportunity cost of

Page 159: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

FRANK MCDONALD

142

supplying the modified products to the domestic market. If the costof complying with the NTB rose high enough, the exporter wouldbe excluded from the market.

There are other forms of NTBs, such as subsidisation ofdomestic producers. These can take many forms, for example,subsidies, preferential loans, grants and tax concessions (see Chapter13). In EU terminology, such practices are called ‘state aids’. Thewelfare effects of such state aids are illustrated in Figure 7.2.

The symbols in Figure 7.2 have the same meanings as in Figure7.1. The amount of the subsidy is shown by Z; SH+Z is domesticsupply after allowing for the subsidy and the price plus the subsidywould be R. Before the imposition of the subsidy, demand at pricePW would be Q3, domestic supply would be Q1 and the level ofimports would be Q3-Q1. If a subsidy of Z were introduced,domestic supply would increase to Q2 and imports would fall to Q3-Q2. No consumer surplus loss would result from the subsidybecause the domestic price remains at PW. There is a cost to thegovernment of PWRAB (the cost of the subsidy) of which ABC isa net welfare loss due to the opportunity cost of producing theextra domestic output. This method of protection can be less costlythan tariffs, quotas or different national regulations. It does lead toa net welfare loss to society, but this is of a lower magnitude thanthe other methods of protection (as there is no consumer surplus

Figure 7.2 The welfare effects of subsidies to domestic producers

Page 160: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

COMPLETING THE INTERNAL MARKET

143

loss). However, the subsidy would cause welfare losses due to thedistortions caused by the taxes necessary to finance this method ofprotection.

The above analysis ignores the fact that the customs union andthe common market of the EU exclude non-members. It also onlyconsiders static welfare effects; that is, the effects with a givenquantity and quality of resources. Furthermore, the analysis isconcerned with trade in goods and services. A common market,however, also requires free movement of capital and labour. Theexclusion of non-members from the trade liberalisation measures ofthe EU can lead to welfare losses if the excluded countries arelower-cost suppliers of goods and services than the member statesof the EU. In these circumstances, trade liberalisation within theEU could lead to a shift to higher-cost suppliers. This would resultin net welfare losses because the EU would not reap the fullbenefits of comparative advantage. Such an outcome is referred toby the term, ‘trade diversion’. Conversely, if trade liberalisation bythe EU led to ‘trade creation’ (when the member states include thelowest-cost producers) the members of the EU would reap all thebenefits of comparative advantage. The concepts of trade creationand diversion are explained in more detail in Chapter 1 (see alsoMcDonald and Dearden, 1994).

Over a period of time, trade liberalisation should lead to areallocation of resources as a result of companies responding tothe new opportunities for trade and to the increase in competitionwhich arise from the removal of trade barriers. This results indynamic welfare effects (see Chapter 1; Emerson, 1988). The mainfactors that lead to such dynamic welfare effects are: 1 economies of scale;2 reductions in supernormal profits;3 decreases in the level of X-inefficiency;4 improvements in the qualities of goods and services; and5 changes to the logistical systems of companies. The removal of trade barriers induces some companies to expandtheir output levels in order to supply expanding or new exportmarkets. This expansion of output results in the reaping ofeconomies of scale for those companies which are operating on thedeclining portion of their average cost curve. If the subsequentreduction in cost is passed on to consumers by a decrease in price a

Page 161: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

Figu

re 7

.3 A

sch

emat

ic l

ogist

ics

chai

n

Page 162: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

COMPLETING THE INTERNAL MARKET

145

consumer surplus gain would arise and thereby welfare gains wouldbecome possible.

The creation of a common market results in an increase incompetition by inducing companies to expand sales or entermarkets that had previously been protected by trade barriers. Thiscan lead to reductions in supernormal profits and levels of X-inefficiency and possibly in prices as companies seek to improvetheir competitive position. These changes in the competitivesituation can also stimulate non-price competition factors such asimprovements in the qualities and characteristics of goods andservices. Such improvements can provide benefits to consumersbecause they enhance the value which buyers place on products.Providing that these enhanced values are not fully matched byincreases in prices, a gain of consumer surplus would arise.

The increase in competition resulting from the removal ofNTBs may also induce companies to modify their logisticalsystems; that is, the chain of activities ranging from thedetermining of sources for inputs through to productionprocesses and distribution procedures. A schematic logistics chain,with indications of possible cost-reducing measures resulting fromthe removal of NTBs, is shown in Figure 7.3. Restructuring ofthe logistics chains of companies could lead to lower-costproduction and better quality goods and services. Such changesshould provide welfare gains by inducing reductions in price andalso by releasing resources which could be used more effectivelyin other economic activities.

Welfare gains would also arise from the removal of NTBs thatprevent the free movement of capital and labour and from those thatdistort the allocation of these resources. These gains would arisefrom the downward pressure (for the common market as a whole) onthe price of capital and labour and by allowing for a more efficientallocation of factors of production (see El-Agraa, 1994).

Theory thus suggests that the creation of a common marketshould lead to welfare gains that would be largely brought aboutby reductions in the price of goods, services, capital and labourand by the releasing of factors of production for use in areaswhere the country has a comparative advantage. However, thesebenefits can only be secured by changing trade patterns and byrestructuring the business activities of companies. Theseadjustments can lead to costs in terms of unemployment andredundant capital equipment if the workers and owners of capital

Page 163: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

FRANK MCDONALD

146

that are affected by such company restructuring are unable tofully redeploy their resources.

THE PROPOSAL TO CREATE A COMMONMARKET

The 1985 White Paper identified three main types of barriers whichhad to be removed if a common market were to be created (seeTable 7.1 for a summary of the range of measures involved): 1 physical barriers;2 technical barriers; and3 fiscal barriers.

Physical barriers

These barriers refer to customs formalities at national frontiers.They affect foreign trade by interrupting the flow of tradedcommodities to allow for the checks and form-filling necessary toensure adherence to national indirect taxation systems and thevarious technical regulations of importing countries. These customsformalities lead to costs for companies in that they have tocomplete paperwork and submit to inspections at frontiers. TheWhite Paper proposed that indirect taxation systems and thenational frameworks for technical regulations should be harmonised,

Table 7.1 Proposals presented to the Council of Ministers, 1992

Source: EC Commission.

Page 164: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

COMPLETING THE INTERNAL MARKET

147

so that the need for such frontier controls would be eliminated.Consequently, the removal of physical barriers depended on theremoval of technical and fiscal barriers.

Technical barriers

The free movement of goods and services can be hampered bytechnical regulations, such as differences in health/safety rules andlaws governing the technical specif ications of products; forexample, French law required yellow headlights for all cars sold inFrance. Trade in services within the EU was also hampered bydiverse and often contradictory legal frameworks. Cross-frontiertrade in areas such as insurance, banking, transport and other typesof services were rendered very difficult due to these diverse legalframeworks. These differences in technical regulations led toincreased costs for companies as they had to modify their standardproducts to enable them to meet the technical regulations ofimporting countries. In some cases the differences in regulationscould prevent cross-frontier trade (for example, trade in bankingand insurance services). The White Paper proposed to eliminatethese barriers by use of mutual recognition of technical regulationswith selective harmonisation of essential factors. Mutual recognitionrequires member states to accept the technical regulations of allmembers of the EU providing that traded products fulfil anytechnical regulations which exist at EU level. Such EU leveltechnical regulations were to be restricted to essential factors inareas connected to technical compatibility and health and safety.

Free movement of labour was restricted by nationalityrequirements for some public sector jobs, difference in taxation andsocial security systems, and incompatible education and vocationaltraining and qualifications. These barriers were also to be removedby the use of mutual recognition and selective harmonisation.

Free movement of capital was restricted by exchange controls,barriers to the free movement of financial services and distortionscaused by exchange rate fluctuations. The elimination of exchangecontrols together with EU laws to enable free movement offinancial services along with participation in the exchange ratemechanism of the European Monetary System (EMS) were regardedas the appropriate methods of creating the conditions for the freemovement of capital (see also Chapters 4–6).

The White Paper identified public procurement practices and the

Page 165: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

FRANK MCDONALD

148

use of state aids as barriers to free movement in a competitivemarket setting. Public procurement contracts were often explicitlyor implicitly restricted to domestic suppliers by the use of laws orby specifying that public sector contracts must comply with nationalstandards. This meant that a large amount of potential trade washampered by these procurement policies. The White Paper proposednew laws to ensure that most public procurement contracts wouldbe open to tender from any company which was based in the EU.The widespread use of state aids by national governments toprotect domestic industries were also regarded as a majorimpediment to the completion of the SEM (see Chapter 13). TheWhite Paper proposed that the competition policy of the EUshould be vigorously applied to eliminate those state aids that weredeemed to reduce competition.

Fiscal barriers

Differences in national taxation systems can cause price distortionswhich may result in obstacles to the reaping of comparativeadvantage. If goods are exported with VAT and excise duties whichprevail in the exporting country, with no adjustment at borders, theprice of such goods in the importing country would reflect therates of tax levied in the supplying country. In cases where therewere significant differences in taxation systems, in terms ofcoverage (i.e., goods’ and services’ liability to tax) and tax rates, theprice of traded goods would be subject to taxationinduceddistortions. This problem did not occur in any major way in the EUbefore the SEM programme because exports were subject to zerorating for VAT and excise duties when they crossed frontiers. Inorder to operate this system of tax adjustment, it was necessary tohave frontier controls to check the claims for refunds of VAT whengoods were exported at zero rate and to ensure goods subject toexcise duties were indeed exported and therefore were no longersubject to such duties.

The problem of cross-border shopping (buying goods in memberstates with lower rates of VAT and/or excise duties) was controlledby specifying limits on personal imports and policing this byfrontier controls. However, the removal of frontier controls wouldmake this system of adjustment for taxation differences impossibleto operate (see Table 7.2 for a summary of VAT differencesprevailing the year before the 1992 programme ended).

Page 166: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

COMPLETING THE INTERNAL MARKET

149

The White Paper proposed to eliminate these fiscal barriers byending the zero rating of VAT on exports and by introducing asystem of bonded warehouses with a marking procedure for goodssubject to excise duties; therefore, these goods could only be legallysold in the country which imposed the excise duty. Importers wouldpay VAT at the rate imposed by the exporting country, then theywould reclaim the VAT they had paid from their national taxationauthorities when they sold the goods. This system would haverequired an international clearing-house arrangement because somecountries in the EU are net importers and/or have lower thanaverage rates of VAT. In these circumstances such countries wouldrefund more VAT on imports than they would receive from VAT onexports. In order to allow this system to operate it was deemed to benecessary to harmonise both the coverage and rates of indirect tax.This was seen to be necessary to avoid problems of cross-bordershopping both by personal visits to countries with lower rates ofindirect tax and by the use of mail ordering from such countries.

THE CECCHINI REPORT

A report on the economic implications of completing the SEM waspublished in 1988. This report is commonly called the CecchiniReport. Summaries of this report can be found in Cecchini (1988)and Emerson (1988), while the full report was published by the ECCommission (1988b). In order to identify the net benefits that

Table 7.2 VAT rates in the EU, pre-1992

Source: HM Treasury.

Page 167: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

FRANK MCDONALD

150

could be expected from the removal of NTBs, the Cecchini Reportutilised theoretical schemes somewhat similar, but more complex, tothose outlined above. These net benefits were then estimated by useof surveys and also by statistical/econometric estimation. Somerather strong assumptions had to be made about the significance ofthese NTBs and on the likely impact of removing them. Estimatesof the gains from removing NTBs were made for the main sectorsin the major member states and then the results were aggregatedand extrapolated to provide estimates for the EU as a whole (seealso EC Commission, 1990c). The main results of the CecchiniReport are presented in Table 7.3.

The Cecchini Report has been subject to widespread criticism forfailing to accurately estimate the net benefits of creating the SEM.The report is accused of being over-optimistic with respect to thepossible benefits which are available from economies of scale. Thiscriticism arises from scepticism about the potential for reapingeconomies of scale from the removal of NTBs and also withregard to the scope for companies to achieve such scale effects.These issues are examined in Figure 7.4.

Table 7.3 The main results of the Cecchini Report

a. Assuming no accompanying macroeconomic measures,b. Assuming expansion of public investment and/or reductions in

taxation made possible because of the savings in the costs ofprocuring goods and services by governments and the increase intaxation revenues from the growth in GDP which results from theSEM programme. The microeconomic benefits are based on theoriginal six member states plus the UK, at 1985 prices. Themacroeconomic benefits are for all 12 member states; 6 years after thefull implementation of the SEM programme (assumed to be 1 January1993). These estimates are subject to a margin of error of ±30%.

Source: EC Commission (1988b).

Page 168: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

COMPLETING THE INTERNAL MARKET

151

In Figure 7.4, two possible long-run average cost (AC) curvesare shown: AC1 and AC2. The former illustrates, relative to AC2, alarger fall in average cost as output is expanded. The output level,Q1, refers to the level of sales before the removal of NTBs. Q2 andQ3 refer, respectively, to pessimistic and optimistic estimates ofoutput after the removal of NTBs and Q4 indicates the minimumefficiency scale; that is, the point at which the average cost reachesits minimum point. If it is assumed that the plant is operating onAC1, and the optimistic expansion of output is realised, a reductionin cost of A to C will be possible; the pessimistic outcome wouldlead to a cost reduction equal to A to B. However, if the plant wasoperating on AC2, the reduction in cost would be considerablylower—from D to F or D to E. If the plant were operating at orabove the output level, Q4, there would be no cost advantage fromexpanding output.

There has also been criticism that the report failed to assessproperly the costs of the restructuring process that would beinduced by the SEM programme. It was assumed that over a periodof six years the unemployed resources would be fully reemployed inareas where the countries had comparative advantage. Indeed,

Figure 7.4 Economies of scale under pessimistic and optimistic assumptions

Page 169: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

FRANK MCDONALD

152

Baldwin (1989) has suggested that the restructuring process couldresult in an increase in the long-run trend rate of growth of theEU. In other words, the SEM programme can be regarded as morethan a one-off supply-side boost to the economy. This view isimplicitly taken in the Cecchini Report. However, some economists,for example Grahl and Teague (1990) and Culter et al. (1989), haveexpressed the opinion that, at least for some parts of the EU, theSEM programme could lead to a downward spiral in employment assome companies in the less competitive regions lose market shareto more efficient producers in the heartland of the EU (seeChapter 14). If such regions cannot develop new markets theywould suffer a decline in income. If labour mobility out of theseregions was not sufficient to solve the unemployment created bythis process, permanent damage would be inflicted on these regions.The Cecchini Report tends to ignore this ‘regional effect’ of theSEM programme. This issue is more fully examined in Vickerman(1992).

In general, the report assumed that the SEM programme wouldbe sufficient to ensure the removal of most NTBs and that thisprocess would automatically lead to large-scale changes in tradepatterns and, subsequently, to the reconstruction of the economiesof the member states. Critical evaluations of the Cecchini Reportcan be found in Culter et al . (1989), Davies et al . (1989),McKenzie and Venables (1991), McDonald and Dearden (1994)and Swann (1992).

THE POSITION POST-1992

In principle, the SEM programme was technically ‘completed’ onJanuary 1, 1993. Frontier controls were abolished and most of theproposed legislative changes had by then been adopted by theCouncil of Ministers. However, in some areas, notably financialservices, some major pieces of legislation have not yet beenadopted. For example, a directive to allow for cross-frontier tradein life insurance did not come into effect until July 1994.Awareness campaigns have brought the challenges andopportunities of the SEM to the attention of companies. Manycompanies have responded to this by constructing new strategicplans and some have altered their operational activities andorganisational structures by the use of mergers and acquisitionsand strategic alliances and by changing their production, marketing

Page 170: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

COMPLETING THE INTERNAL MARKET

153

and distribution systems (see, for example, Prescott and Welford,1992; Preston, 1992).

However, the legislative programme is not yet complete and areport by the Commission—the Sutherland Report (see below)—suggests that there may have to be another batch of new legislationbefore the legal conditions are right for the effective operation ofthe SEM. Fiscal barriers have not been fully eliminated and thewave of company restructuring was connected to a wide range offactors and the SEM programme may have played only a small partin this process.

The Sutherland Report

This report found that by January 1, 1992, some 264 of the 282pieces of legislation proposed in the White Paper had been adoptedby the Council. However, only 194 directives had been implementedinto the national laws of the member states and just 79 had beenimplemented in all member states. Concern was also expressedabout the knowledge of these new laws, especially among small andmedium-sized enterprises (SMEs) and consumers. This led to fearsthat the new laws may not be respected because of this lack ofunderstanding. If the laws are not effectively understood andimplemented, it will be very difficult for mutual recognition oftechnical regulations to be widely accepted. Such a situation wouldundermine the expected change in trade flows and therefore therestructuring process would be limited because of the relativelysmall changes in intra-EU trade and the competitive environment.

The report also expressed the view that more legislation wasrequired if the SEM was to operate effectively, particularly in theareas of consumer protection and public procurement. Consumersare unlikely to buy goods and services from companies in othermember states when their rights (e.g., if products fail to meetacceptable standards) are not clearly specified. These concerns arelikely to be most evident in the purchase of services and inmanufactured goods with complex technical characteristics and/orwhere health and safety aspects are of importance. Concern wasalso expressed about how effective the laws on publicprocurement will be in the absence of effective monitoring andpolicing systems.

The Sutherland Report indicated that there were someshortcomings in the legislative programme and in the effectiveness

Page 171: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

FRANK MCDONALD

154

of the implementation of this programme. The report alsoconsidered that there were significant problems with regard to theunderstanding by companies and consumers about the content andimportance of the SEM legislation. To ensure the smooth operationof the SEM, new EU laws were deemed to be required, especiallyin the areas of mutual recognition, consumer protection and publicprocurement.

The removal of fiscal barriers

The member states could not agree on the harmonisation of VATand excise duties. However, a compromise agreement was reachedto allow for the removal of frontier controls. This agreementrequired the acceptance of a minimum standard rate of VAT of15% with a reduced rate of not less than 5%. Permission was alsogranted to allow for the continuance of exemptions and zero ratesfor some products. However, exemptions and zero rates could notbe introduced or re-introduced if they had been changed bygovernments. Allowances for personal imports have been greatlyexpanded and have, in effect, become irrelevant in terms of anymeaningful control by national governments. This has already led toa large increase in the personal importation of alcoholic beveragesinto Britain. Such taxation revenue loss caused by personalimportation may limit the willingness of the British government toincrease excise duties on alcoholic beverages. An incentive alsoexists for large increases in mail order shopping from low indirecttaxation countries. In the absence of firm agreement on theharmonisation of indirect taxation, it is difficult to see how such agrowth in direct mail ordering can be prevented. The problems ofcross-border shopping are consequently likely to become moresignificant as economic agents react to the new opportunities thathave been created by the failure to harmonise indirect taxationsystems.

The restructuring of companies

That there have been significant changes in the strategies andorganisational structures of many companies since the SEMprogramme began to be implemented is beyond question. Manycompanies have become more European-oriented in theirproduction, marketing and distribution activities. However, there is

Page 172: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

COMPLETING THE INTERNAL MARKET

155

no clear evidence at this stage as to the significance of thesechanges to the logistics chains of companies. The SEM programmehas also stimulated foreign direct investment into the EU,particularly from Japan. This issue is examined in Chapter 12.

The Financial Times reported, on September 17, 1993, thatcrossborder merger and acquisition activities in the EU hadincreased from $23.1bn in 1991 to $42.0bn in 1992. However, inthe first half of 1993, the volume of such cross-border merger andacquisition activities had reached only $12.3bn. The recession mayhave played an important part in the decline in merger andacquisition activities. It is not clear how important the creation ofthe SEM is as an incentive for merger and acquisition activities.The need to respond to changes in global competitiveness has alsostimulated such activities. Reasons such as this seem to have beenimportant in the merger and acquisition activities of European-based companies in the food processing industry, such as Nestlé,Unilever and BSN. They seem to have been influenced not only bythe SEM, but also by the need to compete in global terms withlarge American companies, such as Mars, Philip Morris, Campbelland Kellogg in the branded food products market.

Attempts to rationalise in static or declining markets have beenimportant in promoting strategic alliances such as the joint venturebetween ICI and Enchem—the European Vinyls Corporation. Thefear that deregulation may lead to an increasingly competitivemarket has also induced some companies to enter into mergers orjoint-ventures. This can be most clearly seen in the airline sector.For example, British Airways acquired the French carrier TAT, andKLM, SAS, Swissair and Austrian Airlines have sought to establishstrategic alliances. The telecommunications services sector has alsowitnessed a growth in mergers and strategic alliances in response tothe forthcoming privatisation of state-owned companies and movesby the Commission to deregulate this industry.

It is very difficult to ascertain whether the reorganisation ofcompany structures that have taken place since the SEMprogramme began are due to this programme or to other factors.The report in the Financial Times indicated that a series ofconsolidations are taking place within Europe and that the SEM isan important factor in stimulating such merger and acquisition andstrategic alliance activities. However, the privatisation programmesin Germany, France, Italy and Britain, the deregulation of the airtravel and telecommunication services industries and the

Page 173: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

FRANK MCDONALD

156

increasingly global competition in many markets may be at least asimportant in this consolidation process. These issues are explored inHarris and McDonald (1993).

Such consolidation also raises problems with regard to the futurecompetitive environment in the EU. The dynamic benefits from theSEM depend upon creating and sustaining a more competitiveenvironment than that which existed before the SEM programmestarted. However, it may be necessary to allow some companies toconsolidate their positions in order to allow let to take advantageof the opportunities offered by the SEM. Nevertheless, suchconsolidations may also lead to the growth of market dominancewhich could lead to the potential for welfare loss resulting fromcompanies abusing their market power. It would appear that theCommission will need to use wisely its powers with respect to thecompetition policy of the EU (see Chapter 13).

CONCLUSIONS

The SEM programme has moved the EU to a position where acommon market among the member states is very nearly complete.However, some barriers and distortions to the effective working ofthe SEM still exist and these may impede the process of freemovement. The Sutherland Report has raised doubts about theeffectiveness of EU laws on free movement. Distortions caused bythe failure to harmonise fiscal systems within the EU may also limitthe effectiveness of the SEM. It is also not clear if therestructuring of the operational and organisational structures ofcompanies was primarily due to the SEM programme or to otherfactors such as deregulation and the pressures of globalcompetition.

The process of changing trading patterns and the restructuringof company operations in response to the SEM programme has notstopped because the 1992 deadline has been passed. The EU willhave to take further steps to create an effective common market;including the removal of the remaining fiscal barriers; new laws onconsumer protection; mutual recognition; and the monitoring andpolicing of the laws on free movement. Companies will continue torespond to the changes that have already been made and to thosethat will be made to improve the effectiveness of the SEM.

Page 174: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

157

8

AFTER 1992

The Political Economy of the SingleEuropean ActDavid Whynes

INTRODUCTION

By the mid-1980s, the European Union (EU) remained rather morethan a customs union, but rather less than a common market (seealso Chapter 7). The former status, entailing the elimination oftariffs and quotas between members and a common trade policy vis-à-vis the rest of the world, had been accomplished quite rapidly inthe decade following the signing of the Treaty of Rome in 1957.Thereafter, the pace of progress had slowed considerably and theunified market, embodying a standardised legal framework for theconduct of economic affairs and a harmonised taxation andmonetary system, seemed simply a panEuropean’s dream. Successiveobstacles to its creation had regularly emerged, including Unionenlargement, political disagreement over the long-term goals of thealliance and the severe economic difficulties experienced by allmember states during the 1970s.

Beginning in the early 1980s, however, the drive towards thecommon market received a fresh impetus with a suite of policyproposals referred to simply by a date—‘1992’. After their essentiallyindividualistic responses to the economic crises of the 1970s, EUmembers were, quite simply, looking for something to be Europeanabout. In Copenhagen in 1982, a meeting of the European Councilmade economic unification a high priority, a pledge reiterated at the1984 meeting (see Chapter 1). In consequence, as the theme of itsprogramme for 1985, the Commission outlined a proposal for marketunification within the EU:

Unifying the market [of 320m] presupposes that memberstates will agree on the abolition of barriers of all kinds,

Page 175: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

DAVID WHYNES

158

harmonisation of rules, approximation of legislation and taxstructures, strengthening of monetary cooperation and thenecessary flanking measures to encourage European firms towork together. It is a goal that is well within our reachprovided we draw the lessons from the setbacks and delays ofthe past. The Commission will be asking the EuropeanCouncil to pledge itself to completion of a fully unifiedinternal market by 1992.

(EC Commission, 1985) The accompanying White Paper, entitled Completing the InternalMarket, provided operational details of this, the 1992 proposal. Theproposal was accepted and the twelve member states approved the1986 Single European Act (SEA), formally committing themselvesto market unification by the appointed date.

In view of the extremely slow progress which many proposalsfor greater European unity had achieved prior to this time, it isinstructive to consider briefly why the 1992 package won such rapidand wholehearted respect. In the first place, much can be attributedto the strong personal advocacy of the then Commission president,Jacques Delors, who campaigned tirelessly for the project. Second,the ideological basis of the proposal was market liberalisation, aphilosophy which greatly appealed to the liberal—conservativegovernments of Britain, Germany and, to some extent, France.Third, the proposal seemed to resolve satisfactorily a Europe-widesearch for a new initiative to combat the high and rising levels ofunemployment then existing in all member states (so-called‘Eurosclerosis’). Fourth, there was strong and vocal support in mostcountries on the part of leading industrialists, who viewed thecreation of a single market as an expansion of the opportunitiesfor profit. Fifth, the 1992 package gave the appearance of beingnarrowly and primarily economic; it thus seemed to steer well clearof the emotive political issues involving supra-nationalism and thesurrender of national autonomy which had caused similar EUproposals to founder in the past.

A final reason for the rapid enactment of the proposal, and notone of least importance, was its administrative construction; theCommission had certainly ‘drawn the lessons from the delays of thepast’. The White Paper noted that the attainment of progress inEurope had often been hampered by attempts to developpredefined, all-embracing Union-wide targets and by the unanimity

Page 176: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

POLITICAL ECONOMY OF THE SINGLE EUROPEAN ACT

159

requirement in the Council of Ministers. It noted, first, that scopeexisted within the Treaty for the unanimity requirement to berelaxed to a majority requirement in certain policy areas and anextension of this facility was recommended. Second, it advanced anotion of ‘sufficient harmonisation’, implying that around a generaltarget individual countries could be permitted a degree of policyidiosyncrasy. Finally, it extended the concept of harmonisation to‘mutual recognition and equivalence’. Thus with respect to atechnical standard, for example, members would no longer have toagree on a common EU specification; rather, goods manufacturedto the producing country’s standards would have to be regarded asacceptable in all other member states (subject to conformity withgeneral EU guidelines). Such easements, embodied in the 1986 SEA,naturally tended to facilitate an increase in enacted legislation.

THE SINGLE EUROPEAN ACT AND THE 1992PROGRAMME

A unified market is one in which free trade and unimpeded factormobility prevails and the potential benefits of such a market,including gains from comparative advantage and economies ofscale, are easily demonstrated by economic theory (McKenzie andVenables, 1989). The 1986 SEA recognised that, whilst much hadalready been accomplished towards the creation of a commonmarket within the EU (such as the elimination of internal tariffbarriers), a number of obstacles remained. In effect, the SEAcharged the Commission with the preparation of directives tomember states to eliminate such obstacles. These directives (ofwhich slightly less than 300 were involved in the 1992 package)were statements of required outcome, it being left to membersindividually to decide how the outcomes could best be achieved intheir own contexts and to devise legislation to fulfil theirrequirements. Thus in Britain, for example, the 1985 ProductLiability Directive became the 1987 Consumer Protection Act.

In that they were designed essentially to tidy up a very largenumber of loose ends, the directives covered an enormous range ofsubjects, ranging from the manifestly important to the franklybizarre. However, some order can be imposed if we consider why afree flow of goods and services and factors of production in theEU was being impeded. In the first place there existed a series oftechnical impediments. Labour mobility, for example, was hampered

Page 177: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

DAVID WHYNES

160

by the lack of acceptance of the equivalence of trainingqualifications throughout the Union.

The flow of enterprise was constrained by the existence oftwelve different sets of company law, making the formation oftruly European companies a near impossibility. Goods made in onecountry might have been unacceptable to others owing to failure tomeet technical specifications (e.g., wavebands for mobile telephones)or health and safety standards (e.g., permissible noise levels, exhaustemissions, food additives). On the principle of mutual recognition,subject to agreed EU standards, the SEA legislated away suchtechnical impediments.

Second, there existed quite obvious fiscal barriers to trade,namely, differential rates of indirect taxation and excise duty whichengendered price distortions. It was quite conceivable for low-costproducers in countries with high indirect tax rates to be out-competed by high-cost producers in countries with low tax ratesand this was clearly economically perverse. One set of SEAdirectives involved the harmonisation of tax and duty rates and theestablishment of a centralised payments mechanism. Third, and inspite of the removal of tariff barriers, all EU members tended tooperate forms of restrictive practice which discriminated againstproducers in other member countries. Transport industries regularlyoperated under a quota system, giving preference to nationalsuppliers, and government procurement was rarely put out to tenderbeyond the boundaries of the country in question. Under the SEA,these restrictive practices were to be eliminated.

The final set of barriers may be termed administrative, anexample being the use of non-standardised documentation forimport and export which contributed greatly to delays. To dealwith this problem the SEA envisaged the use of standardiseddocumentation to cover all intra-EU trade (the SingleAdministrative Document). Many administrative barriers weremanifested at border crossings, although the SEA aimed tostandardise customs procedures at these points. In any case, anumber of administrative bar riers were to be automaticallyremoved by the elimination of the obstacles to trade mentionedabove. Thus, products accepted as having been manufactured to alegitimate standard would not require a standards’ inspection whencrossing frontiers; also, a uniform structure and system oftaxation would make this particular aspect of customs checkingless significant.

Page 178: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

POLITICAL ECONOMY OF THE SINGLE EUROPEAN ACT

161

Thus, the 1992 proposals were concerned to remove all theseexisting barriers, by creating consistent and mutually acceptablestandards, by harmonising taxation, by eliminating nationalrestrictive practices and by simplifying administrative procedures.According to a team of enquiry appointed by the Commission, thelikely effects over the medium term were to be substantial. In theirreport (see Cecchini, 1988), the team classified expected futureeconomic benefits under four main headings. In the first place, theeasing of customs formalities and the streamlining of administrativeprocedures was expected to engender a price fall in traded goodsowing to the elimination of excess costs (bureaucracy, border delaysand complications arising). Price falls would precipitate demand andoutput rises and thus stimulate employment. The EU’s overallbalance of payments position was expected to improve, becausedemand for imports would fall with domestic price falls whilstdemand for exports would rise.

Second, the liberalisation of public procurement would lead tofalls in purchasing costs owing to enhanced competition betweensuppliers. Governments would then be able either to allocate thesaved resources to other growth-inducing activities or to cut taxes,thereby stimulating consumer demand. Third, the harmonisation ofregulations and procedures in the financial sector in particular would,via the creation of a truly European financial market and increasedcompetition, lower the cost of credit. Public and private borrowingwould become cheaper, leading to increased consumer demand andinvestment. Finally, a larger, more open and more competitiveinternal market could be expected to give rise to the aggregatesupply-side effect of increased productive efficiency. Efficiencymeans lower costs and lower prices which, in turn, stimulate supplyand demand. The harmonisation of standards was to be significanthere, ensuring that the potential market was indeed 320 millionpeople, thereby permitting economies of scale to be reaped inabundance. Overall, the ‘1992 effect’ on EU prices was estimated tobe a 6% fall, giving rise to output growth approaching 5% and anemployment increase approaching 2 million across the EU.

THE ROCKY ROAD TO 1992

In common with all economic predictions, those given above wereconjectural. As the expected price fall was the driving force behindthe demand and supply growth, much would depend upon its

Page 179: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

DAVID WHYNES

162

precise extent and the speed of behavioural responses. Althoughthese broad outcomes remained well in the future, some directconsequences of the 1992 programme soon emerged at themicrolevel. By the late 1980s, a not insubstantial industry had setitself up in all member states to prepare entrepreneurs for 1992,entailing the imparting of language, legal and management skills.There was also a merger boom amongst small and medium-sizedfirms throughout Europe, merger being an effective method ofobtaining increased capacity and trans-European market penetrationin the brief period of time available before the unified marketbecame established. It now seems clear that the anticipation of thesingle market contributed generally to an acceleration of Europeantrade and investment during the late 1980s (but see Chapter 12).

All this having been said, 1992 was not quite so straightforwardas some of its advocates apparently believed. To begin with, as thedate approached, it became abundantly clear that, whenever 1992was going to happen, it was not going to be in 1992. With thebenefit of hindsight, it is now evident that the great majority(perhaps 95%) of the 300-odd directives had indeed been adoptedby the Commission by the beginning of 1993. However, less thanhalf of the 1992 programme had actually been translated into thelegislations of the twelve national governments by that time(Barber, 1993). Even prior to the magic date, the simultaneousappearance in twelve statute books of laws embodying all thedirectives was logistically inconceivable. Put another way, that whichhappened by 1992 was not quite the same as that which wasostensibly intended. In fairness, however, this should not be toosurprising because to have expected completion by the specifieddate would have been to misunderstand the nature of the exercise.The White Paper itself concluded as follows:

Europe stands at the crossroads. We either go ahead—withresolution and determination—or we drop back intomediocrity…. What this White Paper proposes is that theUnion should now take a further step along the road soclearly delineated in the Treaties. To do less would be to fallshort of the ambitions of the founders of the Union…itwould be to betray the trust invested in us…. That is themeasure of the challenge facing us. Let it never be said thatwe were incapable of rising to it.

(EC Commission, 1985)

Page 180: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

POLITICAL ECONOMY OF THE SINGLE EUROPEAN ACT

163

This is rhetoric with a familiar ring and it has much in commonwith that accompanying indicative planning in the 1960s. The realpurpose of the exercise was unambiguously to ‘bounce’ themembers of the EU, to get things moving at an urgent pace bycreating a sense of purpose with an imminent time horizon and ahigh public profile. Bouncing works by committing people and bysweeping them along with events. Without urgency, withoutdeadlines, without positive involvement reinforced by the strengthand momentum of a cause, no one feels the need to do anything.The year 1992 was clearly an attempt to reawaken a Europeanismwhich had lain dormant since the 1950s.

Turning to more specific matters, the harmonisation of taxationrates and excise duties along the lines suggested in the White Paperproved an immense stumbling block and a great many voices wereraised in dissent. That this would inevitably have been the case canbe seen immediately one considers the variation in VAT practicesacross member states by the end of the 1980s (see Table 7.2). Allmembers, for example, had both a low-rate band (0–15%) and astandard band (12–25%); six, however, had an additional high-rateband (25–38%). Within these bands, specific rates differed betweencountries, some countries having multiple rates within a given band(Bos and Nelson, 1988). There was not, moreover, completeconsistency across the membership of band classification for givencommodities. Excise duties also varied enormously—beer, forexample, was taxed at ECU 0.03 per litre in France and ECU 1.13per litre in Ireland, whilst petrol duties per litre ranged from ECU0.2 in Spain to ECU 0.53 in Italy (Smith, 1988). The 1992proposals initially aimed at a harmonisation tending towards theUnion average for tax rates and duties. Thus the suggested low ratefor VAT became 4–9%, the standard band becoming 14–20% (thehigher band was intended to be abandoned). Beer and petrol dutieswere to be harmonised at ECU 0.17 and ECU 0.34 per litrerespectively, other duties following a similar averaging procedure.

Of the twelve member states only Germany operated with VATrates in line with the original 1992 proposal (7% and 14%); allothers would have been obliged to revise their rates and the scopefor resistance was considerable. Countries required to move one orboth of their rates upwards were concerned about the inflationaryimpact of such a movement. Countries whose low rates were toolow or whose high rates were too high argued that harmonisationwould precipitate adverse distribution consequences (lower rates

Page 181: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

DAVID WHYNES

164

generally being applied to necessities and higher rates to luxuries).Consequent increases in the cost of living on the part of thepoorer groups in an economy would require compensation in theform of increased public spending, which would conflict with othernational policy objectives. Governments required to lower their taxrates were concerned about the tax revenue and inflationaryimplications; those required to raise rates were concerned aboutdomestic employment and, again, inflation.

Broadly equivalent remarks were made with respect to theharmonisation of duties. In the case of Britain, for example,alcohol and tobacco duties would have had to fall considerably tomeet the 1992 targets (a requirement guaranteed to strike terrorinto the heart of any British Chancellor on Budget Day). Inaddition to the uncertain tax revenue implications, duty falls wouldhave entailed price decreases and demand increases withconsequences for public health. Increases in tobacco and alcoholconsumption as a result of duty harmonisation were estimated at4% and 39% respectively, which would have been likely to furtherincrease the cost—several billion pounds annually—of treating theadverse health consequences of the consumption of suchcommodities (Appleby, 1988).

In order to prevent the VAT/excise controversy from destroyingthe momentum of the 1992 initiative, the Commission was soonobliged to signal the possibility of a greater degree of flexibility inthis area. In 1989, Christiane Scrivener, the commissionerresponsible for fiscal harmonisation, announced the abandonmentof an upper ceiling on VAT rates and suggested that ways might befound of retaining the option of a zero VAT rate (as employed inBritain). The proposal for a common rate of excise duty wasjudged to have been misguided and revised policies on this matterwere prepared (The Economist, 1989a). As events transpired, 1993opened with a complex provisional VAT agreement, intended toameliorate price distortions across borders. By that time, anagreement had been reached to set a minimum standard VAT rateat 15% and Germany, having been the model for the original VATproposals, now emerged as the main deviant in this respect. A finalagreement on VAT harmonisation has now been deferred until1997, subject to a consensus being forthcoming.

Although flexibility might have been a necessary strategy toensure compliance on the part of member states, it is not withoutits pitfalls with respect to the longer term. Assuming that the high

Page 182: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

POLITICAL ECONOMY OF THE SINGLE EUROPEAN ACT

165

degree of VAT flexibility will be retained in the future, the pricedistortions (which 1992 was trying to eliminate) will remain.Possibly internal competition might force rates into line (alwaysassuming that such a competitive environment actually comes toprevail) although, if differential tax rates actually do representmajor trade barriers (as they will if everything else is harmonised),then it will be the economically strong members of the EU whichdetermine the final outcome. The combination of an open marketwith large disparities in duties would also tend, in the long run, toproduce duty harmonisation. In the short term, however, weshould anticipate substantial exportation from lowduty to high-duty countries. Individual states might well view this withdisfavour on market protection (e.g., indigenous wine industry)and public health grounds. Many EU countries have persistentlycampaigned for the retention of a controlled market in dutiablecommodities which, of course, hardly squares with the intentionsof the 1992 proposals.

One aspect of the 1992 package frequently overlooked at thetime was its ‘social dimension’, which embraced a series of policiesspecifically concerned with the implications for labour of thecreation of a unified market (see Chapter 10). ECU 50bn wereinitially committed to cover the dislocation costs of structuraladjustment (e.g., factory closures) but negotiations still continue oncommon health and safety standards at work, a European socialcharter (enshrining rights to social security, trade union membership,equal pay and rights to company information) and, mostcontroversial of all, a European company statute incorporatingworker participation in management. Some degree of long-termharmonisation on this issue is naturally vital to ensure the operationof fair competition within the EU, because firms operating withlow safety standards and paying non-union or discriminatory wageswould incur lower production costs and be in a position toundercut their more scrupulous rivals (a phenomenon known as‘social dumping’). Whilst member states agree on the objective ofthe social dimension, however, there remain wide differences abouthow such a suite of policies should be enforced. For example, theviews of the former British prime minister, Mrs Thatcher, in1988—‘We emphatically do not need new regulations which raisethe cost of employment and make Europe’s labour market lessflexible’ (The Economist, 1989b)—do not appear to vary from thoseof her successor, Mr Major.

Page 183: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

DAVID WHYNES

166

This social dimension is, in principle, an issue of enormouspolitical weight. It is evident that, at the present stage of theproceedings, it has not been fully thought through and a great dealremains to be accomplished. Similar remarks can be made aboutmonopoly policy (see also Chapter 13). EU monopoly policyremains rudimentary and relies heavily on individual monopoly andcartel control in member states. However, we have already notedthat one of the most immediate effects of the 1992 programmewas a merger boom, a trend which can only continue with theharmonisation of company law, the liberalisation of financialmarkets and increased factor mobility. Basic economic theorypredicts that a likely outcome of a free competitive process ismonopoly control and collusion, especially where the gains fromeconomies of scale are substantial and the 1992 programme meansthat the environment for competitive battles to create monopolieswill be improved. Other than its proposals to control very largemergers (The Economist, 1989a), the Commission has yet to developan operational strategy to deal with Euro-monopolies. Were suchmonopolies to arise in the medium term they could well exert theirpowers in such a way as to nullify the economic gains to bebrought about by price reductions.

THE LONG-TERM IMPLICATIONS OF 1992

Irrespective of the caveats noted above, it goes without saying thatsomething recognisable as the creation of a unified market hashappened and continues to happen. It is equally evident that, in itsattempts to meet its own deadline, the EU was obliged to dilutesome of the original proposals and to delay the implementation ofothers; many of the elements of the 1992 programme are unlikelyto be effected until well into the next century. Accordingly, therehas not been a sudden shift between 1992 and the yearsimmediately following; the transition over time will be gradual. Themost immediate impact over the next decade is likely to be felt inthe financial and transport sectors. Finance capital is extremelymobile and is capable of responding almost instantly to regulatorychanges—this proposition is evidenced by the profound changes inthe London financial markets following deregulation in 1986.Variable capital in the transport industry (e.g., lorries, railway rollingstock) is likewise easily enhanced although fixed capital (e.g., roads,rail tracks) will prove more problematic. Furthermore, competitive

Page 184: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

POLITICAL ECONOMY OF THE SINGLE EUROPEAN ACT

167

pressure within the EU is certain to increase as a result of the 1992package and this will lead, with equal certainty, to localisedproblems of structural adjustment. The most successful firms willbe those which can merge or otherwise grow to a size sufficient toreap the economies of scale available in the extended market. Theconcentration of production is also likely to increase, for similarreasons.

Over the longer term, two implications of 1992 will be ofparticular interest. The first concerns the relationship of the EU toother trading economies. Ever since its formation, the Union hasbeen viewed by outsiders in a dual light (see Chapter 1). On theone hand, the EU is an evolving giant economy, representingenhanced opportunities to foreign traders; trading with Europeoffers better prospects than trading with any single Europeancountry. On the other hand, increasing economic integrationthreatens to strengthen ‘Fortress Europe’, a self-contained, insularand protected economic unit becoming increasingly impenetrable toforeign economies. The 1992 programme seemed set to enhance thedepth of the dilemma—Europe was becoming more tempting as amarket, but harder to penetrate owing to increased internalcompetition and external tariff protection.

The strategies of the Japanese economy with respect to the EUin recent years are instructive on this point (see also Chapter 12).Finding certain of their exports priced out of the market by penalduties, Japanese manufacturers began to move product assemblyinto Europe (Heitger and Stehn, 1990). In 1987, the EU respondedby imposing rules of local content, requiring that, for duty to bewaived, a proportion of the value of the final product had to beadded using local resources. Since then there have been calls withinthe EU to increase this proportion, from the original 40% towards70–80%, entailing a far more substantial employment of EUresources by Japanese companies. By 1990, the Commission hadbegun to consider even more stringent rules of origin requiring, ineffect, not merely the transfer of capital from Japan to the EU, butthe transfer of technology. In the case in point, semiconductorswere considered to be only EU products (and thus exempt fromduty and/or permitted entry) if the diffusion process (etching) tookplace locally (The Economist, 1989c).

In global terms, the EU is prosperous and, following 1992, givesevery sign of becoming more so. It is not an economy, therefore,that the rest of the world can afford to ignore, as is evidenced by

Page 185: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

DAVID WHYNES

168

the fact that it can now seriously contemplate the extraction ofsubstantial gains in the form of employment and investment fromJapanese producers. Naturally, the Japanese do not regard theenhanced bargaining strength of the EU with a great deal ofenthusiasm but, in extremis, they do not have a great deal of choice.Broadly similar remarks can be made with respect to the UnitedStates. Closer to home, non-EU economies elsewhere in Europewere already anticipating the effects of 1992 well before theimplementation date. In 1989, EFTA proposed talks on closerEFTA/EU cooperation (which culminated in the creation of theEuropean Economic Area in January 1994) and almost all theEFTA members subsequently announced their intention of applyingfor EU membership (The Economist, 1989d); see Chapter 9 fordetails. Such behaviour would seem to have indicated a globalperception of 1992 as strengthening the walls of ‘Fortress Europe’,the appropriate strategy being to get within them.

The second implication of 1992 concerns the future style andscope of domestic policymaking. The 1992 programme can beseen as further evidence of a shift in economic and politicalpower away from national governments and towards the centralEU institutions. The SEA directives were no longer negotiable ata national level and the proposals implied the removal of certainconventional economic management tools from the hands ofnational governments. This was especially evident in the case ofthe tax/duty harmonisation proposals and, one suspects, formsone reason why that element of the package caused suchwidespread consternation. Further, the creation of a liberalisedmarket in loanable funds severely constrains any independentmonetary policy on the part of a national government (seeChapters 4–6).

It seems clear that the very momentum of the 1992 programmeinto the future must inevitably bring pressure to bear on economieswho might attempt to continue an independent stance. For example,any country whose tax rates are consistently and significantly out ofline with those of its partners will find itself at an economicdisadvantage, being less able to compete. Britain’s negative attitudeto the monetary union appears to represent a particular obstacle inthis respect. The full logic of 1992 requires a coherent monetarysystem (in the limit, monetary union) to prevent distortions anduncertainty in prices and to facilitate capital flows. Participatingmembers will gain in these respects and non-participants will not.

Page 186: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

POLITICAL ECONOMY OF THE SINGLE EUROPEAN ACT

169

Such an asymmetry of benefits and costs will increase the pressureon deviant nations to conform to the norm.

CONCLUSIONS

Even from the time of the first visions of a united Europe, duringWorld War II, the destination of the EU has been negotiable. Oneobvious tension has been between those who have seen the Unionas an inter-governmental association of nation states and those whohave viewed it as a step on the way towards the ‘United States ofEurope’. In terms of this polarity, the initial acceptance of the1992 package was a clear victory for the pan-Europeans. Moreimportantly, 1992 involved policy outcomes which, had they beenfully realised, would have acted as a major force predisposingEurope towards continuing in that direction into the future. Thatthis was appreciated within the Union could be seen by theopposition to the Delors faction on the part of those unhappy bothwith the implied consequence and with the Commission’s overtlyinterventionist approach to liberalisation (see The Economist, 1989e).Clearly, in its ultimate manifestation, 1992 limited choices, bothfrom the point of view of member states equivocal about theirpositions in Europe and of those outside the Union. In mostrespects, therefore, the precise details of the 1992 package, whetheror not a specific piece of legislation was enacted by a certain dateand the estimation of the economic benefits following fullerintegration, are of far less significance than the overall tenor of themovement. The year 1992 was a crusade and crusades are neversubject to a naïve economic calculus.

Page 187: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

170

9

THE ECONOMICIMPLICATIONS OF

ENLARGING THE EUROPEANUNION

Valerio Lintner

INTRODUCTION

Up to the early 1980s, it is probably fair to say that the issue ofenlarging the European Union (EU) came to prominence only attimes when the Union was actually busy absorbing new members,notably when the original six became ‘the Nine’ and when the Ninethen incorporated the three Mediterranean states of Greece, Spainand Portugal to become the present EU of twelve. This ‘widening’of the EU has always been, of course, of importance to itsdevelopment in the sense that membership of the club was beingincreased, but during its early development most of the attention ofthe EU was probably concentrated on ‘deepening’ the Union; i.e.,completing the customs union and the common market, developingcommon policies such as the Common Agricultural Policy (CAP) andregional policy and generally promoting economic convergence andmonetary and political integration among the existing members.

More recently, however, enlargement has moved to the verycentre of the EU’s agenda. Recent events in Europe and elsewherehave called into question the whole direction in which the EUshould develop and there is considerable debate as to whether theemphasis should be on widening, on deepening, or indeed on bothin equal measure. The renewed interest in widening has resultedfrom a number of developments, principally: 1 the emergence of new independent states in eastern Europe

following the collapse of the Soviet empire after 1989. These

Page 188: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

ENLARGING THE EUROPEAN UNION

171

states are almost universally eager to cement their newlyacquired pluralist democratic systems and to embrace westerncapitalism as a means of securing greater material prosperity.They regard membership of the EU as the principal means ofsecuring these objectives;

2 the increasing tendency for the deepening process to run outof steam. The middle and late 1980s were years of rapiddevelopment of the EU, with the 1992 programme and themoves towards monetary union contained in the Delors Reportand the Maastricht Treaty. With the recession of the early1990s and the economic problems caused by Germanunification, there has been a tendency for many Europeancitizens and some European nation states to retrench andquestion the whole concept of further integration and theshape that this should take (see Chapter 1);

3 the increasing economic interdependence, or globalisation, thathas resulted from expanding trade and vastly increased capitalmobility. This has resulted in losses of real economicsovereignty (the ability of individual nation states to controltheir own economic affairs independently of events and policiesin other nations), particularly among small and medium-sizedEuropean nation states. Many of these states have come toregard membership of the EU and the pooling of sovereigntythat this involves as the only realistic means of maintainingcontrol over their economic (and, indeed, political) destinies;

4 the temptation to use widening as a tactical weapon designed toslow down the deepening process. This has arguably been theBritish position over the last few years, culminating in itsinsistence on pushing forward the widening process at theEdinburgh Summit of December 1992;

5 the increasing tendency for the EU to be regarded as a vehicle forthe provision of security in the context of the increasinglyinsecure world that has emerged from the upheavals of 1989; and

6 the trade gains and scale economies inherent in an expandedEuropean market, particularly in the context of ever-increasingcompetition from newly industrialised countries (NICs) and ofthe increasing propensity for the world to operate in tradingblocs, have proved attractive to countries, particularly those ofthe EFTA bloc. This process has of course been accelerated bythe ‘1992’ programme for the completion of the internalmarket and can be seen as in many ways a defensive posture on

Page 189: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

VALERIO LINTNER

172

the part of applicants to avoid being ‘frozen out’ of the EUtrading bloc.

These factors have led to the emergence of a long list of applicantsand potential applicants, the process of widening having beenaccelerated by the decision taken at the European Council held inEdinburgh in December 1992 to begin accession negotiations withthe EFTA applicants at the beginning of 1993, thus removing theprevious insistence that negotiations could not begin until theMaastricht Treaty had been ratified.

This, then, is the context within which this chapter is written. Thesecond part of the chapter will outline the light that the economictheory of integration can shed on the likely effects of enlargement.The third part briefly surveys the nature and impact of previousenlargements, with particular reference to the entry of Britain. Thefollowing section will look at the situation with current and possiblefuture applicants, while some conclusions will be presented in thefinal part. It should be noted from the outset that the motivation forand the impact of enlargement is not just, or often even primarily, todo with economics. To fully understand the issues here one has toadditionally consider political and strategic factors.

THE ECONOMICS OF ENLARGEMENT: SOMETHEORETICAL ASPECTS

Membership of the EU involves complete acceptance of the‘Acquis Communautaire’; i.e., the full diet of the Union’s rules andlegislation. The implications of membership are thus numerous andnot all of them have an overtly economic dimension. From astrictly economic point of view and starting from the albeit unlikelyassumption that there are no associations or other agreements priorto the enlargement, the main aspects of membership are:

1 membership of the customs union, which involves acceptanceof internal free trade and adoption of the common tradepolicy vis-à-vis the rest of the world;

2 the common market aspect of the EU, which involvesacceptance of the free movement of labour and capital withinthe EU. These first two aspects involve accepting all or mostof the battery of standardisation and harmonisation measureswhich form part of the ‘1992’ programme to complete the

Page 190: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

ENLARGING THE EUROPEAN UNION

173

internal market. These include the removal of frontiers, theadoption of common standards, accepting the principle ofmutual recognition, new competitive rules on publicprocurement, the end of state monopolies, fiscal harmonisation,limits on industrial subsidies, etc. The costs here will include asurrender of economic and political sovereignty, to the extentthat control over decisions such as whether to charge VAT onbooks or whether to operate state monopolies for tobacco andalcohol may be lost;

3 participation in the common policies of the EU, notably theCAP (Chapter 11), regional policy (Chapter 14), industrial andcompetition policy (Chapter 13) and social policy (Chapter 10).These policies are financed from the EU’s budget, towardswhich new members have to make contributions in the form ofcustoms revenues, a proportion of VAT receipts and a (atpresent small) payment related to gross domestic product(GDP); and

4 participation in moves towards full monetary union, althoughthe prospects for this aspect of integration look dubious in thesense that the Maastricht Treaty is unlikely to be implementedin anything like its present form within the timetable envisaged.Nevertheless it is clear that the process has advanced to asignificant extent over the last few years and will in allprobability regain momentum at some time in the future.

These economic implications of EU membership have all to betaken into consideration when assessing the impact of anenlargement. An important dimension of assessing the impact of anenlargement concerns the question: effects on whom? For thedistribution of any gains or losses will naturally be of considerablesignificance. In this context the approach adopted here is broadly toexamine the economic effects of enlargement from three separateperspectives: the overall economic effects, the effects on applicantcountries and the effects on existing members.

If we begin by examining the overall trade effects of anenlargement, then from a strictly neoclassical perspective what weare essentially concerned with is whether the enlargement is onbalance a ‘trade-creating’ one or a ‘trade-diverting’ one (seeChapters 1 and 7). The factors that will determine the outcomeare complex, but the following are likely to be of particularimportance:

Page 191: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

VALERIO LINTNER

174

1 whether the structure of the traded goods and services sectorof the entrant is competitive (overlapping) or complementary(dissimilar) vis-à-vis that of existing members. In general,competitive structures are more likely to result in welfare-enhancing trade creation; i.e., the displacement followingenlargement of more expensive and less efficiently produceddomestic goods and services by cheaper and more efficientlyproduced products from a customs union partner.Complementary structures, on the other hand, are more likelyto result in trade diversion; i.e., the displacement of cheap andefficiently produced third country products by less efficientlyproduced partner products;

2 differences in costs of production between the entrant andexisting members. In general, the greater the difference incosts, the more scope for trade creation and vice versa; and

3 the effect that enlargement has on tariffs and non-tariff-barriers(NTBs). If, on balance, it leads to an increase in tariff levels,then trade diversion is likely to be the result. On the otherhand, if the enlargement results in an overall reduction intariffs, then trade creation is more likely. NB, for a fullertreatment of the theory of customs unions and other aspectsof the theory of integration, see, for example, Lintner andMazey (1991).

Additionally, one has to consider the so-called ‘dynamic’ customsunion effects of an enlargement. These consist principally of thepossibility of exploiting economies of scale as a result of thegrowth of firm size that typically accompanies the change in theinternational division of labour following accession to a customsunion. Clearly, these will depend on the scope for scale economiesin the industries that are likely to grow in size after enlargementand the extent to which exclusion from the EU is, in fact, a barrierto their exploitation. Of some significance in this context is alsothe increased power that a larger EU is able to wield on theinternational trading scene and on its own terms of trade. Customsunions of increased size have more power to influence worldmarket prices for the commodities they import and can thus betterengineer increases in their own welfare by imposing (optimum)tariffs that cut imports and thus world prices (Johnson, 1965). This,it should be noted, can only be achieved at the expense of othercountries and thus constitutes a classic ‘beggarthy-neighbour’ policy.

Page 192: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

ENLARGING THE EUROPEAN UNION

175

In one way or another, what the above amounts to is the factthat enlargements are more likely to prove welfare-enhancing andthus desirable from a trade and welfare point of view when theyinvolve the incorporation of countries whose economies are similarto those of existing members, which would explain why regionaltrade groupings tend to involve predominantly countries at similarstages of economic development. Conversely, one could argue thatenlargement involving the accession and assimilation of dissimilareconomies will tend to be more problematic. A furtherconsideration here involves enlargements that encompass severalstates whose economies are similar to one another, but differentfrom those of existing members. Here there may be scope for tradecreation and welfare enhancement between the new membersthemselves and this may offset any losses that arise from relationswith existing members.

If one then considers the trade effects from the specific pointof view of the entrant(s) and/or existing members, then clearly themajor considerations that will determine the distribution of thetrade effects of enlargement and whether they will on balance befavourable to each party will be: 1 the extent to which accession results in the opening of

domestic markets to competition from new partners and theextent to which domestic firms have enhanced access topartner markets. Put another way, the extent to which thesemarkets were protected prior to accession;

2 (most crucially) the competitiveness of domestic firms in thetraded goods and services sector vis-à-vis similar firms inpartner countries;

3 the extent of trade diversion which results; i.e., the extent towhich production from new partners competes with currentimports from third countries; and

4 the dynamic response on the part of domestic firms to thecompetition from existing members.

The danger from the point of view of less economically developedentrants is that the welfare gains from entry may be skewed infavour of more advanced and competitive existing members. This islikely to happen if there are insufficient competitive industries inthe acceding countries. What may ensue in this case is a transfer ofeconomic activity from new entrants to existing members; i.e., an

Page 193: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

VALERIO LINTNER

176

export of jobs and increased domestic unemployment. In thiscontext, the length and nature of any transition period will becritical, as well as the dynamic response of domestic producers tocompetition; that is, the extent to which these respond to newchallenges by becoming more efficient and developing new productsthat are in demand in existing member states.

From the point of view of existing members, enlargement mayoffer new markets for their industrial and other products, as well ascheap and secure sources of certain raw materials and primaryproducts, but may also pose a threat to the extent that entrants areable to compete in existing domestic and EU markets in, forexample, agricultural products. From a neoclassical perspective, theeffect of the factor mobility aspect of EU membership can beshown to be welfare enhancing. Free movement will lead to labourand (particularly) capital moving to where it is most productive,thus improving the allocation of resources (but see Chapter 14).From the point of view of existing members this may result ingains from an increased supply of cheap migrant labour, althoughrealistically the current importance of this is doubtful in thecontext of the high unemployment which the EU is now suffering.

The potential problem here again concerns distribution, needlessto say to the possible detriment of any less advanced new entrants.Neoclassical theory would suggest that the free movement offactors tends to equalise factor earnings and thus lead to economicconvergence between existing members and new entrants. However,the radical critique of this approach, pioneered in the 1950s by theSwedish economist Gunnar Myrdal, would suggest that the freemovement of capital will tend to exacerbate national and regionaldifferences in real income and welfare by causing a ‘PolarisationEffect’ by means of a process of ‘Cumulative Causation’ (Myrdal,1957).

Broadly, the inflow of capital into areas where its marginalproduct is greatest may set in motion a dynamic process thatreinforces the attractiveness of these areas at the expense of lessprosperous ones. Thus, the more developed parts of existingmember states grow in prosperity and attract more and morecapital, while poorer entrants are gradually relatively pauperised.The free movement of labour may lead to similar effects, since it isthe people with the greatest amount of human capital andenterprise who are typically the most mobile. There may be a flowof capital from the prosperous economic centre towards poorer

Page 194: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

ENLARGING THE EUROPEAN UNION

177

new entrants, but this is unlikely to compensate for the polarisationeffects. It is very difficult to test this hypothesis empirically, but itshould at the very least serve as a salutary warning to the queue ofpotential EU applicants and potential applicants from easternEurope and the Mediterranean area.

The impact of participation in the EU’s common policies is, ofcourse, likely to be dominated by the entrant’s relationship with theCAP and, to a lesser extent, its claims on the EU’s structural funds,particularly the European Regional Development Fund. The impactof the CAP on entrants will be determined by the size andcompetitiveness of their agricultural sectors, the agricultural supportregime prior to entry and the extent to which, after entry, the pricesupport mechanism covers the range of products they produce (seeChapter 11). The latter is likely to be largely determined by thepolitical process in the EU and thus the degree of influence thatthe entrant wields at this level becomes crucial. A possibility is thatprices to consumers will increase as a result of the CAP’s systemof subsidising agriculture via the price mechanism and ofprotecting the sector from foreign competition by means of tariffs(the Variable Levy). Claims on the structural funds will bedetermined by the objective needs of the entrant in terms ofregional imbalances, but also by their influence in the EU’s politicalprocess.

Entrants will have to contribute to the EU’s budget. Thebudgetary implications of membership will depend on the extent towhich contributions outweigh receipts from the budget or viceversa. This, in turn, will be largely a function of an entrant’ssuccess in obtaining funds from the CAP and the structural funds.The hope on the part of eastern European and the Mediterraneanapplicants is that the balance here will be favourable, but even ifthis proves to be the case, the overall impact is unlikely to be ofexcessive significance given the relatively modest size of the EUbudget. In any case, entrants will have to compete with politicallypowerful existing members for the limited redistribution fundsavailable to the EU. A more likely scenario is that the CAP and theEU’s structural funds may be thrown into disarray by theabsorption of relatively poor entrants with large agricultural sectors.A further problem may arise for existing members if the entrantscan compete effectively in certain agricultural markets.

The impact of monetary integration concerns primarily the factthat integration in this area involves the most visible losses of

Page 195: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

VALERIO LINTNER

178

economic sovereignty, since it involves surrender over key aspects ofmonetary and other macroeconomic tools and objectives, for exampleinterest rates and the exchange rate. The importance of this will bedetermined by the extent to which such sovereignty exists in the firstplace in an increasingly interdependent world characterised by highlevels of capital mobility (see Chapter 2). Also, monetary integrationmay involve accepting economic leadership from strong existingmembers. This may be advantageous or otherwise for new members,depending on the quality of the leadership available and the extent towhich the economic philosophies and policies imposed by the leadersare appropriate to the needs of acceding countries. From the pointof view of existing members, enlargement may exacerbate theproblems involved in achieving the economic convergence requiredfor monetary union or indeed other less ambitious forms ofmonetary cooperation.

Finally, it is worth noting that there may be economic benefitsfor new entrants from a variety of other sources, such asdemonstration effects, spillover effects and an increased ability toattract Japanese, US and other direct investment (or indeedincreased prospects of maintaining current levels of multinationalactivity in the domestic economy)—see Chapter 12. The likelyextent of these is probably impossible to estimate.

ENLARGEMENT IN PRACTICE: FROM THE ‘SIX’TO THE ‘TWELVE’

Having outlined some theoretical aspects of the economics of EUenlargement, we can now apply these to examining the experienceof the EU in practice. The original Union of six countries (WestGermany, France, Italy, Belgium, the Netherlands and Luxembourg)remained in place from March 1957, when the Treaty of Rome wassigned, until 1973 when the United Kingdom, Ireland and Denmarkbecame members and thus completed the first enlargement of theEU. The second phase of enlargements, usually referred to as the‘southern enlargement’, involved the absorption of Greece (in 1981)and the Iberian states of Spain and Portugal (in 1986).

In many ways, the first enlargement was eminently logical from aneconomic point of view. It mainly involved countries (Britain andDenmark) that were at roughly the same stage of economicdevelopment as the existing members and whose production andconsumption patterns were broadly compatible with those of the

Page 196: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

ENLARGING THE EUROPEAN UNION

179

original six. Ireland was somewhat different, being less wealthy andhaving a relatively large agricultural sector. But then Ireland is a smallcountry whose needs could be accommodated with relative ease andwhich could hope to benefit from the CAP, redistributive EUexpenditures and the increased foreign direct investment thatmembership might produce. In any case, the original EU six had hardlybeen a completely homogeneous grouping and agricultural areas suchas the Italian Mezzogiorno had been accommodated with somesuccess. The main economic effects of enlargement at this stage ofEuropean integration concerned trade and to a lesser extent the CAPand the EU budget. The overall economic effects were thus likely tobe positive and what empirical work is available tends to confirm this.

If the global economic effects of Britain’s entry were favourable,from a purely British perspective the economic impact ofmembership has been less clear cut—once again the issue ofdistribution rears its head. It is beyond the scope of this chapter toexamine Britain’s economic experience within the EU in detail—seeEl-Agraa (1983) or EC Commission (1983) for fuller accounts ofthis—but the economic impact of accession essentially consisted of: 1 the costs involved in joining the CAP. These included

considerably higher food prices as a result of abandoning the‘deficiency payments’ system of duty-free imports allied tosubsidy of domestic agriculture directly from the exchequer. Inaddition, Britain had to abandon the highly favourable dealsthat had been struck with food suppliers from theCommonwealth. In fact, food prices in Britain increased bysomething like 300% in the decade between 1971 and 1981,partly no doubt reflecting increased world food prices duringthis period, while the Labour Party estimated that in the late1980s every family was paying £13.50 each week to finance theCAP (Labour Party, 1989). The indirect impact of the CAP onemployment has also been considerable. The best estimatessuggest a job loss of around 860,000 in the largest four EUcountries with Britain and Germany suffering most severely, asthe result of a loss of potential gross output of between 1.1%and 2.5% (and between 4.4% and 6.2% of exports inmanufacturing industries) in these countries (Demekas, 1988).The costs of the CAP have furthermore included the netbudgetary contributions that resulted from Britain’s smallagricultural industry (employing approximately only 2.5% of the

Page 197: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

VALERIO LINTNER

180

population) in the context of a CAP that accounted for over70% of EU expenditure and which resulted in the muchpublicised haggling over British rebates that took place duringthe early Thatcher administrations; and

2 the effects on British trade and production. These are againhard to estimate, since it is difficult to isolate the EU effectfrom other influences, such as long-term trends of fallingcompetitiveness and inappropriate economic policies, on theBritish position. Nevertheless, the best estimates tend tosuggest that membership of the EU reduced British output ofmanufactures and significantly worsened the trade balance inthis area. Winters (1987) suggests that the loss of output thatresulted from accession was at least £3bn (1.5% of grossdomestic product), but that these losses might well have beenoutweighed by gains in welfare enjoyed by British consumers asa result of cheaper imports from EU partners.

These ‘impact costs’ were to an extent foreseen and were expectedto be outweighed by longer-term ‘dynamic’ gains. For example, itmay well be that membership has helped Britain to attract a greateramount of foreign direct investment from the United States, Japanand elsewhere. The overall impact of accession is impossible toquantify and is in any case largely immaterial, given that there isnow no prospect of Britain withdrawing from the EU.

The southern enlargement was more problematic, involving as itdid countries at a less advanced stage of economic development,with largely complementary productive structures and largeagricultural sectors. On the other hand, there was the possibility ofsome welfare-enhancing trade creation between the new entrantsthemselves, given the competitive nature of their productivestructures. This phase of the EU’s development was, as ever,probably more motivated by political factors: the need to defendnewly acquired pluralist democracies and the desire to integrate keyparts of ‘the soft underbelly of Europe’ into the NATO block. Fora full treatment of the southern enlargement, see Tsoukalis (1991).

Greece, in fact experienced severe difficulties in integrating itsrelatively weak industrial sector into the EU, despite a lengthytransition period. There was some internal pressure for withdrawalfor a period, but on the whole the evidence seems to suggest thatthe impact of membership on the Greek economy has been positiveand that it has been a net beneficiary from the CAP (Yannopoulos,

Page 198: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

ENLARGING THE EUROPEAN UNION

181

1986). In addition, Greece has benefited from the structural fundsand in particular the Integrated Mediterranean Programmes. Fromthe point of view of existing members, it is probably fair to saythat the impact of Greek entry on the CAP has been contained,partly by excluding a proportion of Greek products from the pricesupport mechanism (Nicholson and East, 1987). However, theGreek economy remains weak and its economic divergence fromthe rest of the EU has been a major problem in the context ofrecent moves towards monetary union (see Chapter 5).

Spain’s entry was potentially extremely difficult, given that it hadbeen a closed economy under the dictatorship of General Francoand that its productivity and quality standards had been well belowthose in the rest of the EU. In addition, Spain’s agricultural sectorthreatened to exacerbate CAP surpluses, its olive oil output, forexample, being greater than the rest of the EU put together.Nevertheless, the country has been integrated into the EU relativelypainlessly and membership has proved to be a success. Spanishgrowth rates have been very rapid and its industrial sector inparticular has grown impressively with the help of investment fromthe rest of the EU. Partly because of this, fears of large-scalelabour migration into northern member states have proved to beunfounded. Portugal had more established links with the worldtrading system, having been a member of EFTA and having hadtraditional links with Britain. On the other hand, Portugal has thelowest per capita income in the EU (see Chapter 1) and low levelsof productivity, particularly in agriculture. Portuguese membershiphas probably not been as great a success as that of Spain, but theworst fears of industrial decimation have yet to materialise.

In summary, we can conclude that, to date, enlargement has beenbroadly successful from an economic point of view and that theworst potential problems have been avoided. The distribution ofany economic gains has been, however, less clear.

THE NEW APPLICANTS AND POTENTIALAPPLICANTS

As has been mentioned, the early 1990s has seen a veritableexplosion in the number of states seeking or potentially seekingmembership of the EU. Table 9.1 illustrates the enlargementposition as it stands at the time of writing. The membershipaspirants, actual or potential, can be conveniently divided into four

Page 199: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

VALERIO LINTNER

182

groups of states that, albeit diverse, have certain characteristics incommon. The first of these are the applicants from EFTA: Austria,Sweden, Norway and Finland. These countries are currently part ofthe European Economic Area (EEA), an arrangement promoted byJacques Delors since 1989. This comprises a common marketbetween EU and EFTA countries, created by removing NTBs tothe movement of goods (with some exceptions in the case ofagricultural trade), services, labour and capital within the area by

Table 9.1 Applicants and potential applicants for EU membership

Page 200: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

ENLARGING THE EUROPEAN UNION

183

applying most of the EU internal market legislation throughout theEEA. Switzerland and (later) Norway rejected membership of theEU in popular referenda. Iceland has shown no interest in EUmembership.

The EFTA enlargement is scheduled to take place on January 1,1995, and is the least controversial and economically logical of theoutstanding enlargements. It will probably be the last of thetraditional or ‘classical’ enlargements, in that it involves theintegration into the EU of economies that have broadly similarcharacteristics to the existing members. In fact, the EFTA countriesare considerably richer: in the early 1990s Austrian per capita GDPwas $16,592, Finland’s $23,196 and Sweden’s $22,443, comparedwith the EU average of $14,805. They are all small countries ofbetween 4m and 8.5m inhabitants, with open economies in whichtrade accounts for 35–40% of GDP, most of it (55–60%) with theEU (Church, 1991).

There were a number of delicate problems in these negotiationswith the EFTA applicants in which the EU insisted on fullacceptance of the acquis communautaire: the issue of traffic transit,Sweden’s state alcohol monopoly, Finland’s Arctic and Sub-Arcticagriculture and its relationship to the CAP, the right to buyproperty in Austria and elsewhere. Nevertheless, all finally provedresolvable and ultimately accession depended on the ability of theEFTA countries’ governments to sell membership to theirpopulations at the referenda which were held to endorsemembership. Popular approval was ultimately forthcoming in allEFTA states apart from Norway, where resentment against the EUis considerable.

The integration of the EFTA countries into the EU shouldprove to be relatively unproblematic and should, on the whole, leadto positive economic effects. Many of the trade effects of EUmembership have already been experienced, given the close relationsthat already exist between the EU and EFTA, but there is likely tobe substantial welfare enhancement as a result of the removal ofNTBs. The Centre for Economic Policy Research (CEPR) hasrecently estimated that the EEA will increase EFTA’s GDP by upto 5% (Centre for Economic Policy Research, 1992) and,interestingly enough, the distribution of welfare gains that arisefrom the removal of NTBs are likely to be skewed in favour of theEFTA countries (see Haaland, 1990).

The relationship between the EFTA enlargement and the CAP is

Page 201: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

VALERIO LINTNER

184

unlikely to be too problematic, given that the issue of ‘remote’agriculture has been resolved, since EFTA’s agriculture is alreadyeven more heavily protected than its EU counterpart. In fact,EFTA subsidies amount to 68% of the value of farm output,compared to 49% in the EU and thus there may be gains forEFTA consumers from what would be a relative liberalisation ofagricultural trade in EFTA. The EFTA countries are unlikely to callexcessively on the structural funds and are likely to be netcontributors to the EU’s budget. The CEPR estimates that Swedenmight be making net payments to the budget of around ECU1.1bn, Finland of ECU 261m and Austria of ECU 661m, while intotal an EFTA accession might increase the size of the EU budgetby around 14% (Centre for Economic Policy Research, 1992). Inaddition, the EFTA countries satisfy most of the Maastrichtconvergence criteria for EMU and it is thus possible that theiraccession may actually accelerate moves towards integration in thissphere. Apart from the welfare gains that may result, the EFTAcountries are keen on membership in order to attract foreign directinvestment and to keep their own multinationals from locatingelsewhere in the EU. However, their main reasons for seeking fullmembership are predominantly political (security), as are the maindrawbacks (for example, the issue of neutrality).

From an EU perspective, the main problems are also political,for the prospect of an EU of fifteen containing three more smallcountries calls into question the efficacy of the whole institutionalstructure of the Union, while the whole issue of enlargement raisesfundamental questions about the future direction and shape of theEU. For a fuller treatment of EU-EFTA relations, see Journal ofCommon Market Studies, Special Issue (1990).

The potential enlargements after the EFTA group are analtogether different proposition. The first group of these are theMediterranean states of Turkey, Cyprus and Malta, which have beenreferred to somewhat unfortunately by Jacques Delors as the‘Mediterranean Orphans’. Turkey currently has an AssociationAgreement with the EU, providing some access to EU markets. It isof course much larger than the two small islands and has longsought membership. Its progress has been blocked by its dubioushuman rights record and by Greece, in protest over the partition ofCyprus. Turkish application would provide problems andopportunities analogous to those of the Greek case and itseconomic integration into the EU might prove difficult.

Page 202: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

ENLARGING THE EUROPEAN UNION

185

Furthermore, for some people, Turkey’s application calls intoquestion the whole concept of ‘Europe’ and whether Turkey canlegitimately be considered part of it. Malta and Cyprus have bothapplied for membership. The integration of the latter wouldprobably be easier than that of Malta, given the structure andopenness of the Cypriot economy. Their size poses potentialproblems, since it calls into question the EU’s principle of treatingapplicants on the same basis as existing members of the same size.

The next group of potential applicants consists of the formernon-Soviet Union members of the COMECON block, sovereignstates that became independent following the collapse of the Sovietempire in the late 1980s. Arguably, the first ex-COMECON statehas already been integrated into the EU with the unification ofGermany. These states have new and fragile pluralist democraciesand are almost universally attempting to establish market economiesin a hurry. They are at present poor—average per capita GDP ofthe six potential eastern European members is around 13% of theEU average and (including the former Soviet Union) this group hasa population which exceeds that of the EU (see Table 9.2).

The EU has, as yet, no concerted policy towards these countries,but it has negotiated a number of ‘Europe Agreements’ with them.So far Poland, Hungary, the Czech Republic, the Slovak Republic,Romania and Bulgaria have negotiated such interim agreements.These Europe Agreements have both an economic and a politicaldimension to them: they offer limited and selected access to EU

Table 9.2 Population of Eastern Europe, 1992

Source: Economist Intelligence Unit.

Page 203: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

VALERIO LINTNER

186

markets, together with some limited financial cooperation and theyestablish the principle of eventual membership, which was agreed atthe Copenhagen Summit.

There is widespread unhappiness among these countries aboutthe Europe Agreements, which are claimed to favour EU membersin their trade provisions and provide insufficient help in dealingwith the enormous problems that arise from the draconianstructural change which is being attempted. They are also criticisedfor what in many quarters is regarded as the excessively neo-liberaleconomic agendas which they attempt to force on the new easternEuropean democracies. There is clearly a risk of social dislocationinherent in this approach, ‘monetarism is the quickest route fromsocialism to socialism’, as it has recently been put. Nevertheless, inthe final analysis, the Europe Agreements are accepted as the bestat present available.

Full membership is clearly out of the question for these states atthe moment. The economic impact would be devastating for thenascent and fragile economies of the entrants and there would bepotentially enormous problems for existing members, principallyconcerning claims on the structural funds and potential large-scalemigration that might occur from East to West. The integration ofthe former German Democratic Republic into the united Germanyprovides a good case study of the problems that might be involved.The CEPR has estimated that annual budget transfers to the easternEuropean applicants might amount to ECU 13bn and that this maypreclude membership for another twenty years, although this maybe an unduly pessimistic view.

The potential economic and political benefits of accession aresuch that membership at some stage, perhaps in the early 2000s, islikely, assuming that the transition towards a market economycontinues successfully in these states. Membership would providesignificant economic stability and opportunities for the newcountries of eastern Europe, while the existing members would beprovided with new markets and investment opportunities. These arerelatively large countries in population terms (see Table 9.2) that theEU is bound to regard as desirable future members. Even fears thatfreer trade with the eastern European states would threaten theeconomies of existing members may be unfounded. Rollo andSmith (1993) suggest that opening up trade in agriculture may leadto small losses in Greece, Ireland, Portugal and Spain, but thatgains elsewhere would more than compensate for these, resulting in

Page 204: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

ENLARGING THE EUROPEAN UNION

187

overall annual net gains of as much as 3bn, shared more or lessequally between existing members and the eastern European six.

Next in the queue from this part of Europe are Slovenia and theBaltic States and conceivably even Croatia, Serbia and Macedonia ifthe war in the former Yugoslavia can be acceptably concluded.Membership for these countries is a more unlikely, but notinconceivable, prospect early in the twenty-first century. The samemight also be said for the former Soviet Union itself, although atpresent the prospects of Russian or Ukrainian accession seemremote.

CONCLUSIONS

We are looking at the possibility of an EU with twenty or moremembers by around the year 2005. This, of course, assumes thateverything runs smoothly, for example, that there are no furtherupheavals in eastern Europe, that the market transformation of theeastern European economies is a success and that existing membersdecide not to concentrate on deepening the EU. The extent towhich this actually happens will probably be determined by factorssuch as the economic cycle, the quality of political leadership in theUnion and the extent to which the EU can democratise itsoperations.

What is clear is that, at present, the EU has no concerted policytowards enlargement and needs to develop one. Also the process ofenlargement calls into question the very nature of the Europe thatis to be created. At the very least there are likely to have to bechanges in EU institutions to accommodate enlargement and theremay be a need to explore possibilities such as two-speedintegration, partial integration and reversible integration, with thepossibility of exclusion if relevant criteria cease to be met.

In 1989, something fundamental changed in economics, politicsand international relations and there is a need to develop apost1989 model for the EU. In particular, the EU needs to findsome way of addressing the problems and challenges thrown up bythe integration of small countries, given that most if not all of thelikely new members fall into this category.

Page 205: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

188

10

THE ECONOMICS OF SOCIALRESPONSIBILITY IN THE

EUROPEAN UNION Peter Curwen

INTRODUCTION

The European Union (EU), remains a collection of nation statesdespite the expanding body of supranational rules and laws arisingout of the Treaty of Rome, the Single European Act (SEA) and theTreaty on European Union (the Maastricht Treaty). The main thrustof supranationality is economic, but social responsibility has comeincreasingly to the fore in the debates about the future of the EU.The purpose of this chapter is to outline the economic effects ofissues related to social responsibility and to examine theconsequences of decisions reached at Maastricht in December 1991.

Social responsibility is approached via the social policy provisionsof the EU. These arose initially in the provisions of the Treaty ofRome and were very limited in practice. Title III of Part Three(Articles 117 to 128) referred, under the heading of ‘social policy’,to the need for ‘close co-operation between member states’ inmatters relating to employment, labour legislation, occupationaltraining, accidents and diseases and social security.

It was clear at the time, however, and indeed subsequently, thatno member state had the slightest intention of altering its socialprovisions in order to bring them into line with some Europeannorm, nor indeed in the case of wealthier members to providemuch by way of any subsidies to less-well-off members in order,for example, to equalise rates of unemployment.

The only specific provision of the Treaty applied to theintroduction of national rules in relation to equal pay for equalwork for males and females (Article 119). Some idea of thelethargic progress characteristic of the EU at that time can be

Page 206: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

ECONOMICS OF SOCIAL RESPONSIBILITY

189

gauged by the fact that this provision was supposed to have beenimplemented by the end of 1961, but could not be said to havebeen implemented in all member states (and even then in a lessthan clear-cut manner) until 1976. Given that this was the onlyspecific matter referred to in the Treaty, it is hardly surprising thatits more general aspirations mostly fell by the wayside.

THE SINGLE EUROPEAN ACT 1986

The passing of the Single European Act (SEA) which came intoeffect on July 1, 1987, provided a blueprint for the creation of thesingle European market (SEM). Whilst it was only peripherallyconcerned with social policy, it did contain two new social Articles,118A and 118B, to be added to those contained in the Treaty ofRome and, perhaps more importantly, the SEA introduced a muchimproved system for implementing changes based upon theseArticles.

The task set out in the SEA was necessarily more ambitious thanthat envisaged in the Treaty of Rome, if only because Greece,Portugal and Spain had joined the EU by the end of 1986 and theireconomic and social circumstances were quite different from thoseof established northern members. The need for unanimity agreed inthe 1966 ‘Luxembourg Compromise’ (see Chapter 1) could,therefore, have placed a block on progress as it had done inprevious years, but this was prevented by a change in thedecisionmaking procedures of the Council of Ministers.

In respect of social policy, the Treaty of Rome was amended byArticle 118A of the SEA to provide for qualified majority votingon proposals to encourage improvements in the workingenvironment, on proposals in respect of the health and safety ofworkers and in respect of harmonisation of conditions in theseareas. This did not, however, remove all barriers to progress sincethe term ‘working environment’ was something of an ambiguouscatch-all, the interpretation of which has remained an ongoingmatter of dispute between member states, especially sinceunanimous voting was retained in the SEA for measures affecting‘the rights and interests of employed persons’ (Article 100A) andthe free movement of workers.

The passing of the SEA was seen as potentially threatening tosocial welfare. According to Rhodes (1992) the underlying rationaleof the SEA was that:

Page 207: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

PETER CURWEN

190

market integration was the means by which pressure would beplaced on the member states to sign up for politicalintegration. This meant that social affairs were initiallymarginalised from the integration process and that marketoriented forces dominated in defining the shape of the newEurope. For this reason the fight for a social dimension hasbeen very much a rearguard action…against the deregulatorythreat of the 1992 programme and the market orientation ofthe SEA.

THE SOCIAL CHARTER

In the period subsequent to the SEA there were extensivediscussions concerned with how to take account of the newpressures for social policy convergence. The outcome, in May 1990,was the European Union Charter of the Fundamental Social Rightsof Workers, usually known as the Social Charter. The purpose ofthe Charter was to guarantee the basic rights of workers in the EU.It was formally adopted by eleven of the twelve member states onDecember 9, 1989, with Britain unilaterally objecting to a good halfof its contents.

For a variety of reasons the Charter started out as a declarationwithout legal force. However, it contained a mandate allowing theCommission to set out detailed proposals on workers’ rights in thetwelve areas set out in Table 10.1. For the most part the twelveareas were outlined in very broad terms. Item (2), for example,stated that ‘all employment shall be fairly remunerated’ and that ‘adecent wage shall be established’ (EC Commission, 1990a). Thisapproach recognised that national laws and negotiations betweenemployers and unions within each country would already enshrineworkers’ rights such that it remained to be discovered to whatextent it would be necessary to introduce detailed supranationallaws in these areas.

The link between the SEA and the Social Charter was reiteratedthroughout the latter document. For example, ‘completion of thesingle market cannot be regarded as an end in itself; it pursues amuch wider objective, namely to ensure the maximum well being ofall’ (EC Commission, 1990a). Unfortunately, achievement of thisobjective raised a host of awkward issues, not least those pertainingto subsidiarity (see below) and ‘social dumping’.

Page 208: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

ECONOMICS OF SOCIAL RESPONSIBILITY

191

Table 10.1 Fundamental social rights: summary of the contents of theSocial Charter

Page 209: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

PETER CURWEN

192

SOCIAL DUMPING

Those who advocate that supranational rules are necessary in therealm of social policy have recourse to the social dumpingargument. One variant of this argues that, in the absence of labourmarket regulation, poorer members of the EU will hold downwages and social benefits in order to control imports from richermembers and to create better opportunities to export to them (ineffect exporting unemployment). The other variant states that ifinvestment is free to go wherever it wishes within the bounds ofthe SEM, it will end up for the most part in those countries wherepay and working conditions are inferior. Hence, it is alleged,northern member states where standards of worker protection arerelatively high will be obliged to lower them in order to maintaincompetitiveness. The purpose of the Social Charter is thus toprotect the living standards and working conditions of employeesthreatened by the move towards the SEM.

There can be no doubt that there are at present large differencesbetween gross wage costs in different member states. Takingsalaries/wages together with various social benefits, the labour costper worker in western Germany is five times as high as in Portugaland four times as high as in Greece (see EC Commission, 1990a).Nevertheless, it does not follow as a matter of simple logic thatwage differences in a single market will lead to the distortion ofcompetition once adjustments are made for differences inproductivity, since in practice wage differences tend to be veryclosely related to productivity differences.

Furthermore, locational decisions are not driven purely bydifferences in wage costs. The existence of a pool of trainedlabour, high quality component suppliers or excellent transportlinks may have much to do with a preference to locate in ahighwage economy. Under such circumstances, relativelyunderdeveloped countries must rely upon cheap labour in order tocompete effectively and this should not be opposed on ‘socialdumping’ grounds (Kotios and Schafers, 1990). It may be counter-argued that deliberate social dumping is analogous to economicdumping (that is, export prices held below domestic prices).However, there is little evidence to support the idea that thishappens in practice, especially since countries engaged indeliberate dumping of any kind should be exhibiting (much larger)trade surpluses (than they are).

Page 210: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

ECONOMICS OF SOCIAL RESPONSIBILITY

193

But if social dumping is a naturally occurring phenomenon,upward harmonisation of labour regulations may serve only toworsen the position of less-developed member states. As Rhodes(1992) has noted:

Unless the southern countries are able to upgrade theirproduct quality…market integration could well mean furtherspecialisation in labour-intensive, low demand growth sectorssuch as clothing and footwear where fierce competition fromthe NICs is already occurring. Rather than convergence, thiscould produce cumulative divergence. For contrary to thefears expressed in the ‘social dumping’ argument (whichignores the dependence of capital productivity on labourquality) a vicious circle could develop in which investment inwell-regulated, high wage/high productivity economies offersconsistently better returns than the loosely-regulated, lowwage/low productivity areas, permitting neither convergencenor social harmonisation.

THE SOCIAL ACTION PROGRAMME

It is hardly surprising that organised labour has been anxious toformalise the Social Charter and the governments of the countriesallegedly threatened by social dumping are understandablysympathetic. It is curious, on the face of it, that there is so muchsupport from Spain, Portugal and Greece which seem unlikely tobenefit from explicit regulations governing the labour market. A‘Eurosceptic’ would argue that their support stems from theknowledge that they will anyway be unable to enforce suchregulations and that it represents a trade-off for improved financingvia the Cohesion Fund (see Chapter 14). Nevertheless, it has to berecognised that the Social Charter provided a rallying call forsocialists throughout the EU in the face of the increasinglydominant economic doctrine of deregulation in the SEA.

Mrs Vasso Papandreou, the then EU Commissioner for SocialAffairs, latched upon the apparent widespread enthusiasm (other thanin Britain) for the Social Charter to push through a series of draftdirectives as part of what is known as the Social Action Programme.It was quickly appreciated that most of these directives, which whenapproved by the Council of Ministers must be converted intonational law in each member state, needed to be subject to qualified

Page 211: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

PETER CURWEN

194

majority voting rather than unanimity, given Britain’s entrenchedposition, if they were to have a realistic chance of success.

The Social Action Programme presently consists of 47 individualmeasures, of which 27 are in the form of directives or otherbinding measures (see Addison and Siebert, 1993). The Programmeis to all intents and purposes fully issued, but it is not yet fullyenacted. The sections below analyse some of the most contentiousdirectives and provide specific illustrations of the opposing viewstaken of social legislation.

WORKING TIME

The draft directive for the Adaptation of Working Time was issuedon July 25, 1990 (EC Commission, 1992c). This was proposed as ahealth and safety directive because such directives can be approvedby qualified majority vote and it was clear from the outset that boththe British government and UNICE, the European employers’federation, would be utterly opposed to the directive. At the time,all member states except Britain and Denmark had laws governingthe maximum daily working period, although many exceptions werepermitted. The limit to the working week ranged from 39 hours inFrance to 48 hours in half a dozen states, although in practice onlyPortugal actually had a working week in excess of 41 hours with allother states falling between 39 and 41 hours. It followed, therefore,that the main impact of the directive was inevitably going to be feltin Britain in respect of aggregate hours worked (although it isinteresting to note that workers in relatively poor member stateshave become much less willing than in the mid-1980s to forgo anominal rise in income for shorter working hours)—see ECCommission (1991a).

However, the directive was more controversial insofar as itaddressed shift and night work. On average, 20% of EU employeeswere doing shift work, with the highest rates in Britain and Spain(roughly 30%) and the lowest in Germany, Portugal and Denmark(below 15%). According to the Commission there was anestablished link between long hours of night work and ill health.On the other hand, several surveys had shown that, given thechoice, many workers preferred to work longer shifts over shorterperiods and it was observed that British workers habitually tookfewer days off work on average than their counterparts in Germanyand the Netherlands.

Page 212: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

ECONOMICS OF SOCIAL RESPONSIBILITY

195

The prevalence of extended shift work and overtime in Britainmeant that it would bear the main brunt of the draft directive, withadjustment costs estimated initially at roughly £2bn a year. TheBritish government accordingly fought hard to hold back thedirective, but finding itself continually isolated it eventuallyabstained on June 1, 1993, with the other eleven member statesvoting in favour. The main provisions of the directive are:

1 a minimum daily rest period of eleven consecutive hours;2 at least one day off a week;3 mandatory daily rest breaks after six hours;4 four weeks’ annual paid holiday; and5 no more than eight hours per shift for night work averaged

over a period to be determined by each member state.

The directive was formally adopted in 1994. All countries barBritain will be required to implement its contents within three years,whereas Britain will need only guarantee three weeks’ holiday for afurther six years and has ten years overall for full implementation (a‘derogation’ which may be extended subject to ‘review’). There arealso exemptions for transport, agriculture, fisheries, all work at seaand doctors in training. British employees who wish to work morethan 48 hours a week will be able to do so; those who do not willhave the protection of the law.

PART-TIME AND TEMPORARY WORK

There are currently three directives under consideration concernedwith part-time and temporary work. Because there are so manydifferent contractual forms which fall under this heading, theCommission has been driven to refer to contracts and employmentrelationships ‘other than full-time open-ended contracts’ (ECCommission, 1990a; 1992a). The Commission (1990a) justifies theneed to legislate in this area on the grounds that:

Unless safeguards are introduced, there is a danger of seeingthe development of terms of employment such as to causeproblems of social dumping or even the distortion ofcompetition at Community level.

The intention of the draft directives is to provide the sametreatment for part-time and temporary workers as that accorded to‘typical’ full-time employees (hence the common use of the term

Page 213: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

PETER CURWEN

196

‘atypical workers’ to refer to the former). Given that thediscrimination against part-timers comes in many forms, thedirective seeks to encompass working conditions, access to trainingand social security and other measures of social protection.

The first draft directive is essentially concerned with theharmonisation of working conditions. The second concentrates onharmonising the laws on employment relationships and a key clauserequires member states to ‘ensure that part-time workers areafforded the same entitlements to annual holidays, dismissalallowances and seniority allowances as full-time employees, inproportion to the total hours worked’ in the pursuit of the levelplaying field. The third draft directive extends health and safetyprotection for temporary workers. A key issue here is the thresholdof weekly working hours below which protection will not apply. InBritain this was until recently sixteen. It was argued that such ahigh threshold invites employers to offer slightly lower hours thanthis figure in order to avoid even the impact of existing Britishlegislation. The draft directives set the threshold at eight hours,thereby encompassing the great majority of part-time workers andproposed that permanent status must be provided once workershave been ‘temporary’ for three years.

Britain, like the United States, has a particularly large proportionof its workforce employed in a part-time capacity and was expectedto be significantly affected by new legislation in this area (Jackmanand Rubin, 1991). For example, the qualifying period for thoseworking sixteen hours or more per week in respect to statutoryredundancy payments was two years, whereas for those workingfewer hours it was five years. Not surprisingly, therefore, theConfederation of British Industry (CBI) went on record that ‘theadded costs would force employers to reduce the number ofparttime and temporary contracts’. However, the House of Lordsruled in 1994 in a case brought by the Equal OpportunitiesCommission that the government was obliged under nationallegislation against sex discrimination to give statutory rights to part-timers in line with the directive, and the government agreed to thison 21 December 1994.

Temporary working is not all that common and hence is not amajor issue in Britain, whereas it has become extremely prevalent incountries such as Spain precisely because it is extremely costly thereto hire and fire permanent employees.

The opposition to the draft directives has caused them to be

Page 214: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

ECONOMICS OF SOCIAL RESPONSIBILITY

197

held back from consideration by the Council of Ministers sinceNovember 1990.

The UK government once again vetoed the part-time workdirective only days before conceding the House of Lords’ ruling.Further opposition would accordingly appear to be pointless,although the government remains convinced that part-timers willhave little to celebrate as the playing-field will tilt back in favour offull-time employment. In addition, meeting the provisions of thethree directives can be expected to impose a substantial additionalcost on British industry and discourage the offering of new jobs insmall businesses.

PROTECTION IN PREGNANCY

A particularly contentious attempt to improve the position ofwomen workers relates to the provision of maternity leave. It isinteresting to note that the United States is the only advancedeconomy which provides no statutory maternity benefits norpermits a job-protection leave of absence. An attempt to introducethis in a draft Family and Medical Leave Act was vetoed byPresident Bush in 1990. Whilst a number of US states grant unpaidleave of varying duration, the effect is said to be a dramaticreduction in the pay of full-time female workers with childrenrelative to their male counterparts because of the ‘lost years’ whilecaring for babies.

The current situation in Britain is somewhat better, but is theworst among the EU member states. Currently, women qualify formaternity leave only if they have two years’ continuous service infull-time employment or five years in part-time employment andhave no rights if working fewer than eight hours a week. As aresult, almost one-half of working women in Britain do not qualifyfor maternity benefits, which amount to six weeks’ leave at 90% ofregular pay followed by a flat-rate £47.95 for a further twelveweeks (which can be compared to the minimum sick pay of£52.50). Any additional period of leave is unpaid.

It may be noted that even relatively poor member states such asPortugal and Greece provide much longer periods of leave thanBritain—and at full pay. The draft directive concerning measures toencourage improvements in the safety and health of pregnantworkers, women workers who have recently given birth and thosewho are breastfeeding, originally proposed that all women be

Page 215: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

PETER CURWEN

198

granted fourteen weeks’ leave at full salary together with aguaranteed return to the job being done prior to going on leave. Inaddition, women were to be granted two weeks’ compulsory restbefore birth, whether working full-time or part-time and pre-natalvisits to the doctor were to be counted as paid work time.Employers were also expected to improve workplace facilities forpregnant and breastfeeding women.

At a meeting in October 1990, the draft directive was laid beforethe Council of Ministers concerned with social affairs (ECCommission, 1992c). It was proposed that maternity benefits (forwomen who had paid social security contributions for one year)should be set at the same level as sick pay, thereby much reducingthe payments made to pregnant women and new mothers in mostof the EU. Mrs Papandreou responded by threatening to withdrawthe directive on the grounds that pregnant women were not sick,but normally very healthy. In the event, although there was generalsupport for the draft directive in the Council, there were alsosubstantive disagreements about whether jobs should be protectedsince there could be legitimate reasons for dismissing workers whohappened also to be pregnant and, more significantly, as to whetherthe draft directive was a health and safety directive and hencesubject only to majority vote or concerned with social securityprovisions requiring unanimity.

The directive was eventually accepted on October 19, 1992, ina watered-down version, on a majority vote, with a deadline ofOctober 1994 for introduction in member states as national law.Its key provisions were contained in the Trade Union Reformand Employment Rights Act 1993, operative from the end ofAugust 1993, which gave British employees the right, whenpregnant, to a minimum entitlement of fourteen uninterruptedweeks’ maternity leave and enhanced protection against dismissalon maternity—related grounds, but omitted any details beyondmaxima and minima. Proposals publ ished during Augustreaffirmed that maternity benefit would be raised to equivalencewith sick pay, but left open whether this would be for fourteenor eighteen weeks and also whether women would qualify aftereither six or nine months with their employer for the six-weekperiod on 90% of pay.

These measures will accordingly be more costly than thosecurrently ruling and also because women eligible for current higherrates of maternity pay can continue to claim under existing

Page 216: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

ECONOMICS OF SOCIAL RESPONSIBILITY

199

regulations. All told, additional costs are expected to amount tobetween £55m and £75m, which the British government hasdecided to pass on to employers.

WORKER REPRESENTATION

Currently under discussion are draft directives concerned withworker representation which, whilst they are in many ways thedescendants of more ambitious attempts to impose workerrepresentation such as the ‘Vredling Directive’, are different incertain significant respects. One key difference, for example, relatesto the fact that previous directives have been exclusively concernedwith national bodies whereas the current directives are essentiallytransnational in nature.

A draft directive on informing and consulting employees wasissued in December 1990 which, if implemented, will requireworker representation on boards of directors of companies withmore than 1,000 employees where at least 100 workers areemployed in each of two member states. Also, a draft directiveconcerned with the establishment of a ‘European works council’will, if implemented, require any company with more than 1,000employees and at least 100 employed in each of two member statesto set up a European works council, effectively a consultativecouncil at group level where strategic decisions will be discussedwhich touch on plant closures, employment contracts, new workingpractices and the introduction of new technology. Each council willbe obliged to meet at least once a year.

British companies would be most affected by the plans formandatory works councils since Britain has 332 qualifyingcompanies representing more than one-third of the 900 total.Germany has 257, France 117 and the Netherlands 83.Furthermore, Britain is also the base for nearly half of allcompanies passing the threshold (130 out of 280) which havetheir headquarters outside the EU. By contrast, Germany hasonly 50.

It is possible to argue that Britain’s continual use of the vetofor a directive which requires unanimity (two other member statesalso have reservations) is unnecessary, given that little more thanannual briefings appear to be required. It is equally possible toargue that the entire exercise is anyway pointless, because forward-looking companies have already learned from the evidence of

Page 217: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

PETER CURWEN

200

Japanese team-working methods that it pays to keep employeesinformed. The majority of British employers nevertheless arguestrongly that the councils will merely serve to interfere withexisting channels of information. They are also very concernedthat the enthusiasm shown by the unions reflects the latters’ viewthat councils will promote the introduction of EU-wide collectivebargaining systems.

Some twenty European multinationals have already created EU-wide councils, including most recently Ford, and a further 30 arebeing planned, but they are mostly operated in a fashion which isinsufficiently well-defined to meet the requirements of the directive.Nevertheless, it is anticipated that works councils will be a priorityitem under the Social Protocol (discussed below) from whichBritain has opted out and which could be operational in 1995. Ifso, British companies will not remain untouched since more than ahundred will qualify for councils even if their British operations areexcluded.

BRITAIN VERSUS THE REST?

Both the Commission and many member states have exertedcontinuous pressure to subject as much as possible of the SocialAction Programme to majority voting, while Britain has grimly heldto the view that majority voting should apply only to health andsafety legislation narrowly defined. On many occasions, Britain hasstood ready to exercise its veto if need be and, as a consequence, ithas created the image that Britain is wholly antithetical to EU-widesocial legislation.

Such a conclusion would nevertheless be quite erroneous. Manyof the Social Action Programme measures outlined rights to, forexample, a safe working environment, training and trade unionrepresentation which already existed under British law. Such lawsalso covered equal opportunities and the protection of young,disabled and elderly workers (see EC Commission, 1992c).Furthermore, measures designed to enhance the transferability ofbenefits or pensions and the mutual recognition of vocational andeducational qualifications, are very much in line with the Britishgovernment’s free-market philosophy. Indeed, it is slightly ironicthat Britain was the first member state to implement at nationallevel all of the eighteen directives on social policy which theEuropean Council had adopted by the end of 1990.

Page 218: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

ECONOMICS OF SOCIAL RESPONSIBILITY

201

It is of particular interest, given the scale of unemploymentthroughout the EU, to note the underlying philosophy of the SocialCharter:

In addition, and this is possibly more fundamental than thequestion of social dumping, the creation of jobs must not beachieved at too high a price (in particular in terms of healthand safety and social protection.

(EC Commission, 1990a) By way of contrast, the then British employment secretary stated inJune 1991 that ‘the most important social dimension of the singlemarket is the creation of jobs’. This is a view with which theunemployed might well concur, even if their governments areobsessed with the level playing field, the avoidance of socialdumping and the view that relative inequality is socially damagingand a cause of labour unrest.

In the latter respect, however, the British government hasarguably been resisting the inevitable because the Social ActionProgramme can be seen as an attempt to persuade employees thatthe SEM is not simply a charter for capitalists. As the SocialCharter stated:

This is why [the Commission] will continue to take andpropose whatever measures are needed to strengthen cohesionbetween social groups. The Union is concerned to showsolidarity.

(EC Commission, 1990a) Nevertheless, the Commission has embarked upon a path whichclearly runs the risk of, first, making labour markets much morerigid at precisely the time that they need to be made more flexiblein order to tackle the problem of unemployment and, second,raising labour costs relative to those in Japan and the United Statesand thereby creating for the EU a competitive disadvantage inworld trade at a time of recession. This does not appear to worrythe Commission overmuch. Indeed, it argues that:

Flexibility of employment may be a factor which isdetrimental to competitiveness as it acts as a disincentive forworkers. For firms too, flexibility may have negative effects in

Page 219: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

PETER CURWEN

202

the medium and long term, as it may reduce the motivation toinvest in ‘human capital’, which has become one of thefactors essential to growth.

(EC Commission, 1990a) Similar sentiments were expressed by the Commissioner for SocialAffairs and Employment in September 1993. On the other hand, itworries the British government very deeply that more than a decadespent fostering the deregulation of the labour market (see Patersonand Simpson, 1992) has produced results which are incompatiblewith the Commission’s vision of a supranational labour market.Politicians in other member states beset by unemployment havebecome increasingly sympathetic with the views expressed by theBritish government and it must be remembered that whereas theyare often constrained from stating this in public for fear ofoffending coalition partners, they have found it helpful to treatBritain as a scapegoat when it has delayed measures about whichthey themselves are unenthusiastic.

As the full programme of directives comes into force, smallermember states will face the realisation that they are no longer ableto exploit their comparative advantage in trade. This will probablyoblige them either to seek additional EU funds by way ofcompensation, or alternatively protection against ‘technologicaldumping’ by northern members (Kotios and Schafers, 1990). Muchthe same effect will be felt in individual regions even withinnorthern states. Harmonising social conditions must inevitablyassist core regions at the expense of those on the periphery andthis must be viewed as undesirable at a time when relocationdecisions are increasingly necessitated by the advent of the SEM(see Chapter 14).

Harmonisation of social standards will anyway come about in thenatural course of events as living standards rise in poorer memberstates. It can therefore be argued that it is unnecessary to enforce itand indeed that it is inadvisable at this stage. It is also worthobserving that once the directives come into force, it will be muchmore difficult to widen the EU’s membership by the addition ofless-developed states such as those from eastern Europe.

Eurosceptics in Britain are somewhat cynical about theenthusiasm of certain other member states for the Social ActionProgramme. They note, first, that those among them who (unlikeBritain) trade comparatively little outside the EU feel little concern

Page 220: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

ECONOMICS OF SOCIAL RESPONSIBILITY

203

about any loss of competitive advantage relative to the UnitedStates and the Far East; second, that industry in countries such asGermany is already so heavily regulated that the directives willmake them more competitive relative to other member states; andthird, that some governments, notably Italy and Greece, have apatchy record of implementing and enforcing directives and thosethey do not really support are rendered de facto inoperative.

THE TREATY ON EUROPEAN UNION

When the Inter-Governmental Conference (IGC) on Economic andPolitical Union convened at Maastricht in December 1991, it washoped that social policy would form a Social Chapter within thedraft Treaty on European Union. However, a Treaty amendmentrequires unanimity and, predictably, the British government rejectedoutright any such amendment to the Treaty of Rome.

The original five pages in the draft Treaty were reduced to‘Present EEC Treaty Provision Unchanged (cf. Annex III)’. Theannex contains a Protocol on Social Policy (frequently referred to inpractice as the Social Chapter) which as part of the Treaty has beenratified by the British government. However, annexed to thisProtocol is an Agreement signed by all member states bar Britain(which ‘opted-out’). The Protocol contains the agreement of thetwelve signatories to authorise the eleven parties to the Agreementto give effect to its contents.

The Protocol is undoubtedly a Treaty amendment. TheAgreement may or may not be (see Whiteford, 1993). Article 1 ofthe Protocol commits its eleven signatories to:

the promotion of employment, improved living and workingconditions, proper social protection, dialogue betweenmanagement and labour, the development of human resourceswith a view to lasting high employment and the combating ofexclusion.

In the Council of Ministers, from which Britain will absent itself,there will be qualified majority voting (52 out of 78 votes required)in five areas covered by the Protocol, namely improvement of theworking environment to protect workers’ health and safety; workingconditions; information for and consultation of workers; genderequality; and the integration of persons excluded from the labour

Page 221: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

PETER CURWEN

204

market. However, unanimity will be required in respect of: (i)employee representation and co-determination; (ii) social security;and (iii) protection against dismissal. In addition, the Protocolexcludes consideration of pay, the right of association, the right tostrike and the right to impose lock-outs.

It is unclear how all of this will operate in practice. For example,matters stemming from the Treaty of Rome and the Social Charterprior to the enactment of the new Treaty are unaffected and hencerequire the participation of the British government even if theyalso form part of the Agreement. Second, certain draft directives,such as that on works councils, are now likely to go before theeleven, acting as the European Social Union in order to circumventa British veto, whereupon, as noted previously, many Britishcompanies may either compulsorily or voluntarily become subject totheir prescriptions. A third complication is that if at some futuredate the British government should decide to accept the Agreement,it will have to honour any decisions previously agreed in itsabsence. Finally, it is possible that where practices in Britain areperceived to provide an ‘uneven playing field’, they will be takenbefore the European Court of Justice and struck down.

SUBSIDIARITY

It is possible to argue that the extension of the competence of theCommission in the field of social responsibility represents adevelopment which is incompatible with the principle ofsubsidiarity, itself a recurrent theme in the Social Charter. TheTreaty on European Union defined subsidiarity as follows:

in areas which do not fall within its exclusive competence, theUnion shall take action, in accordance with the principle ofsubsidiarity, only and insofar as the objectives of the proposedaction cannot be sufficiently achieved by the member states andcan therefore, by reason of the scale or effects of theproposed action, be better achieved by the Union.

In practice, this can be interpreted in various ways, the Britishgovernment’s preference being for the view that the EU should onlydo things which Britain cannot do at all. Clearly, this principle wouldexclude virtually any attempt by the Commission to introduce newsocial policy legislation and the Commission understandably prefersto interpret the concept in a less restrictive manner.

Page 222: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

ECONOMICS OF SOCIAL RESPONSIBILITY

205

Nevertheless, the initial rejection of the Treaty in Denmark andthe manifest lack of enthusiasm for further supranational controlover their lives among the general public in, for example, France asmuch as in Britain, has induced the Commission to tone downconsiderably its ambitions for a new improved Social Europe. TheGreen Paper on social policy is less detailed and introduces‘framework directives’ which will set binding objectives, but leavegovernments and companies to decide how they should be met.One area where this could be applied is that of works councils.

CONCLUSIONS

In the end, Britain may feel obliged to join in Social Europe,although it will take a change of government for this to be a trulyvoluntary act. If so, Mrs Thatcher’s nightmare vision of ‘socialismby the back Delors’ may yet come to pass. In the meantime, theSocial Action Programme will largely come to fruition in Britain,although there may be some dragging of feet in other memberstates ostensibly more enthusiastic about its content.

It is worth reiterating that, irrespective of the merits oflegislation to enforce social responsibility, it cannot be divorcedfrom the economic circumstances of the time and these haveundoubtedly deteriorated badly over the past few years. It is thelow-skilled, poorly paid sections of the workforce who aresupposed to be protected by existing and proposed legislation, yetthey tend to bear the brunt of a levelling of the playing field, as dosmall companies which have provided a disproportionate number ofnew jobs over the past decade (see Addison and Siebert, 1993;Johnson, 1992).

In refusing to be party to the Agreement Britain may indeedgain at the expense of other member states, but it also suffersmany ongoing disadvantages in respect, for example, of itseducation and training systems, so it is not unreasonable that itshould utilise such comparative advantage as is available, especiallyas the Cohesion Fund does not exist for its benefit. It is easy tolevel accusations of social irresponsibility at the British government,but under present circumstances they are largely wide of the mark.

Page 223: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

206

11

THE COMMONAGRICULTURAL POLICY

Its Operation and ReformRobert Ackrill

INTRODUCTION

For a variety of reasons, the European Union (EU) has in recentyears become an important focus for economic analysis. The mostimportant development has been the movement towards closereconomic integration between the member states of the EU, knownas the 1992 programme (see Chapters 7 and 8), and subsequentlythe debate over even closer links in the future under the MaastrichtTreaty (see Chapters 4–6). There has, however, been one policyoperated by the EU for a number of years that has continually putthe EU in the public eye—that is, the operation and effects of theCommon Agricultural Policy (CAP). This is the means by which theEU provides financial support for its farmers. It has been popularlyassociated with massive budgetary expenditures and the infamousmountains and lakes of surplus products as diverse as cereals,skimmed milk powder, beef and alcohol.

These problems have, of themselves, caused great consternationand have brought forth a number of attempts to correct imbalancesin agricultural production and the resulting rising expenditures.However, these problems have had wider implications. For thesuccess of the 1992 programme, a larger EU budget was necessaryto fund larger and new policies (for example, greater regionalspending and the expansion of the EU’s activities into areas likeresearch and development and new high-technology industries—see,for example, Chapter 14). This had to be accompanied by aneffective reform of the CAP in order to ensure the larger budgetwas not simply swallowed up by ever-expanding support costs foragriculture.

Page 224: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

THE COMMON AGRICULTURAL POLICY

207

In this chapter, simple microeconomic theory is used toconsider the principles underlying the operation of the CAP, thereasons why the levels of surpluses and budgetary expenditureshave risen over time as a result and how the reforms implementedto tr y and control the growth of ag ricultural output andexpenditures have actually operated. The system of supportoperating up to 1993 will receive particular attention, in order tounderstand how the problems of the CAP came about and whythe reforms implemented prior to the MacSharry reforms agreedin 1992 proved ineffective. Although reference will be made to anumber of the different products supported under the CAP, themain reference will be to cereals, because of its importance tofarmers across the EU, both as a final product and as an inputinto other production processes, notably as a feed input intolivestock production.

WHY SUPPORT AGRICULTURE?

Most developed economies’ governments intervene in agriculture tosome degree, with a variety of aims in mind. The two principalmotives conventionally stated are: (i) to counter unstable marketprices; and (ii) to support farmers’ incomes. Taking the question ofprice stability first, the nature of the agricultural production processmeans that for most products, arable and livestock, one productioncycle lasts several months. Thus, ceteris paribus, supply is relativelyprice-inelastic in the short run.

Moreover, there is a relatively low income elasticity of demandfor food, so that in the high-income western economies, arelatively low proportion of income spent goes on food. Thusfood takes a smaller and smaller proportion of total consumerexpenditure over time. This, coupled with the fact thatunprocessed farm products face relatively price-inelastic demand(even when a processed form of the food may face relativelyelastic demand), as well as the more obvious point that ‘food’ intotal has no close substitutes, results in farmers facing a relativelyprice inelastic demand schedule. It therefore follows that, giveninelastic demand and supply, changes in either demand or supplywill result in proportionately greater changes in the equilibriumprice. Moreover, whilst demand tends to be relatively stable overtime, supply can fluctuate quite significantly, given its reliance onsuch external factors as the climate (witness, for example, the high

Page 225: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

ROBERT ACKRILL

208

potato prices in Britain in 1976 when the drought of that year cutharvests significantly).

The second point, that of supporting farmers’ incomes, stems (atleast in part) from the argument stated above, namely that indeveloped economies demand for food rises more slowly thangeneral demand in the economy as a whole. In addition to this,whilst consumers’ expenditure on food is rising over time, this inno way guarantees a rising return to farmers, with the food boughtby consumers increasingly being processed (e.g., convenience foods,‘TV dinners’, etc.). Thus a larger and larger fraction of totalexpenditure on food goes on the marketing margin—processing,etc. Moreover, technological progress acts to increase supply overtime, by developing higher-yielding varieties of seeds and improvedinputs. Coupled to relatively static demand for farmers’ products, ifnot for food in total, the price faced by farmers will be driven downover time.

SUPPORT UNDER THE CAP PRIOR TO 1993

During the period under consideration, the EU has used a numberof different methods of support, all aimed at fulfilling the aims ofthe CAP as laid down in Article 39 of the Treaty of Rome. Thesewere and remain (author’s emphases): 1 to increase agricultural productivity;2 to promote the optimum utilisation of factors especially labour;3 to ensure thereby a fair standard of living for the agricultural

community;4 to stabilise markets; to ensure certain supplies; and5 to ensure supplies to consumers at reasonable prices. The principal method of support involved maintaining a marketprice for each commodity within the EU which was normallyhigher than the price in the rest of the world and, moreover,above the equilibrium price. Simple microeconomics suggests that,without further intervention, this policy would result in the pricecharged being driven down to the equilibrium level. In theparticular case of the CAP, there were two ways in which thishigh price could be undermined and thus there were two distinct,but closely related, policies operated by the EU to protect thishigher price.

Page 226: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

THE COMMON AGRICULTURAL POLICY

209

First, the EU had to protect against cheap imports from the restof the world entering the EU and undermining the high EU price(see Chapters 1 and 7 for a discussion of the welfare effects oftrade protection). It achieved this by applying variable import levies(VILs) to all imports coming into the EU. These were set byreference to the ‘target price’. This was defined as the market priceat Duisburg in the Ruhr, assumed to be the place of greatestcereals deficit in the EU and therefore the place with the highestmarket price. From this were deducted transport costs fromRotterdam (the main point of import into the EU) to Duisburg.This then gave the ‘threshold price’; that is to say, the minimumprice at which imports were allowed into the EU. Thus the VIL wascalculated as the difference between the price of the cereals landingat Rotterdam and the threshold price.

Second, to prevent domestic over-supply from putting excessivedownward pressure on the EU price, a system of interventionbuying was available for most products. This acted to put a floorin the market, so that when the market price fell below this level,the member states, on behalf of the EU, were obliged to buy inwhat farmers decide to offer to them for sale, subject to certainrequirements such as minimum quality and current stock levels.When the products were sold out of intervention, they normallywent for export to third countries. Resale onto the EU marketwould have undermined the reason for the intervention buying inthe first place, namely that of domestic over-supply, by simplyadding to that over-supply. This, like all exports to third countries,required a payment to cover the difference between the EU priceand the world price—the export restitution payment (though morecommonly called the export refund or subsidy, funding theprocess popularly known as ‘dumping’). Note that, for a numberof reasons, the unit export refund was generally lower than theunit VIL. This system of protection operated by the EU can beseen in Figure 11.1.

The target price, Pt, is above the threshold price, P

th, by the

transport costs from Rotterdam to Duisburg. Pin is the ‘intervention’

or buying-in price and PW

is the world price. SEU

and DEU

are theEU’s supply and demand curves for this particular commodity.What these show is that at the institutional prices set by the EU,the EU is a net exporter; i.e., supply is greater than demand atthose prices. At the world price, however, the EU is assumed to bea net importer. Because the intervention price theoretically put a

Page 227: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

ROBERT ACKRILL

210

floor in the market, the effective demand curve facing producers isgiven by ABC.

Over time, the EU moved from being a net importer to being anet exporter. Demand for many agricultural products remainedfairly stable over time, but technological advances, encouraged byhigh support prices, continually increased supply. Given a higherunit VIL than export refund, being a net importer meant that thissystem of supporting agriculture was originally a net incomegenerator for the EU. More recently however, as the EU movedfrom being a net importer for most products to being a netexporter (the situation shown in Figure 11.1), the cost ofsupporting agriculture rose. Although the unit VIL was still greaterthan the unit export refund, a far greater quantity of manyproducts was exported than imported.

This last point also demonstrates that whilst small cerealsfarmers are often cited as an example of perfectly competitiveproducers (even ignoring the impact of government intervention onthis point), this example is highly questionable. The output of smallcereals farmers can be highly differentiated. Thus the EU importslarge quantities of ‘hard’ wheats suitable for milling, whilstsimultaneously exporting larger quantities of ‘soft’ non-milling

Figure 11.1 The price regime of the CAP

Page 228: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

THE COMMON AGRICULTURAL POLICY

211

wheats—all basically wheats, but very different in consumption andtrading at very different price levels on international markets.

As production rose, not only were greater quantities of thesurplus products exported, requiring greater expenditure on exportrefunds, but for most products, greater quantities were also soldinto intervention. Thus expenditures rose here as well, to cover theoperations involved in moving the products into and out of store,as well as the costs of keeping them there. Therefore, as surplusproduction rose over time for the reasons set out above, so too didthe level of stocks (the ‘mountains’ and ‘lakes’ the media havealways been so ready to highlight) with the costs of the CAPthreatening, inter alia, the progress of the EU towards thecompletion of the internal market in 1992—a danger highlighted bythe Commission president when the Single European Act (SEA)was first agreed upon. We have now established the principles thatunderpinned EU support to agriculture until 1993 and showed howthis led to the emergence of surpluses. By considering the financialimplications of dealing with these surpluses, we have also seen howthe EU’s expenditure on agricultural support has risen over time.

THE ATTEMPTS AT REFORM

Because of the market developments outlined above and theconsequent rise in expenditure, by 1984 the EU was, in a technicalsense, bankrupt, though the member states provided sufficientshort-term injections to ensure the continued functioning of boththe EU and the CAP. The fact that these additional payments weremade reflected the value placed by the member states on the EU.Rather than let this imbalance in agriculture risk the future of theentire EU, as some commentators suggested a budgetary crisiswould, the EU was able to continue functioning. It was apparent,however, that this situation could not continue indefinitely and that,moreover, simply providing more money would not solve theproblem, since if the CAP were left unchanged, the extra moneyprovided would simply go straight into agricultural support.

Thus in 1984 an attempt was made to secure both extra fundsfor the EU budget as a whole, while at the same time trying tocontrol the amount spent on agricultural support via rules on‘budgetary discipline’. The formula agreed was one which set aninformal limit equating the growth of agricultural expenditure tototal EU expenditure. The agricultural price decisions (i.e., the

Page 229: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

ROBERT ACKRILL

212

setting of the target price, the threshold price and the interventionprice) were to be taken so as to respect this lower growth inagricultural expenditure, but there was no legally bindingmechanism to guarantee that the expenditure guidelines wererespected. In practice, the measures simply failed, as the pricedecisions taken left no chance of total expenditures falling belowtotal revenues. The lower real prices paid to farmers were intendedto slow or halt the growth in agricultural production, but thedecisions taken were insufficient to outweigh the effects of steadilyimproving technologies and so extra payments were needed fromthe member states in 1984 to 1987 as production, and hence costs,kept rising.

THE 1988 REFORMS

In February 1988, the European Council took the decisions thattightened the budgetary discipline guidelines referred to earlier andmade them legally binding. It was, however, a time when certainexternal (and internal) factors were also coming to the aid of theEU. Principally, there was a drought in the United States during thesummer of 1988. International cereals prices tend to be determinedby US domestic policy, since it is the dominant supplier to theworld market. Thus the large fall in US output caused by thedrought led to a sharp rise in world cereal prices and so savings bythe EU on unit export refunds. Also, the seemingly inexorable risein nominal EU support prices began to slow. Support prices hadbeen increased very dramatically during 1980–81. Indeed, for thefirst (and only) time, the prices increased in real as well as nominalterms. Since then, however, the real price had fallen. Indeed, theautomatic increase in the nominal price every year had become athing of the past, with the target price and the intervention pricebeing frozen in nominal terms during the mid- and late-1980s.

Increases in production have been driven by yields, rather thanarea planted, for some time now. Thus the effect of measures suchas ‘set-aside’, whereby farmers receive a financial inducement totake land out of the production of certain surplus crops, wasalways going to be debatable (especially as only around 1% of thetotal arable area was set aside each year). For example, with cerealsthe area planted has been in secular decline for many years, butrising yields have outweighed this effect, resulting in steadily risingproduction.

Page 230: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

THE COMMON AGRICULTURAL POLICY

213

In addition, reform measures known as ‘stabilisers’ were passedat this Brussels summit. The principal weapon was an automatic cutin the intervention price whenever production exceeded a particularlevel, known as the Maximum Guaranteed Quantity (MGQ). This,ceteris paribus, also cut the per-unit export refund. This price cut tofarmers, it was also hoped, would slow down the rate of growth ofagricultural production—i.e., slow down the rate at which thesupply schedule shifted to the right over time. Coupled to thisagreement was an increase in the EU’s ‘own-resources’ (i.e., totalrevenues), which was felt necessary to fund the policies needed toachieve a single market by December 31, 1992, and extend thenumber of common policies operated by the EU.

AN ASSESSMENT OF THE REFORMS OF THE1980s

The foregoing discussion of policy reforms suggests that,although the EU introduced a number of ways of trying tocontrol agricultural production and resultant expenditure, perhapsthe most significant feature to note is that the underlying principleof high prices (i.e., prices maintained well above their worldlevels) remained unaltered. Reform simply consisted of a graduallowering of this price, in the hope that farmers would respond byproducing less, therefore yielding savings to the EU budget. Ifone considers the experience of the EU’s cereals sector, however,it can be seen that this path would prove to be ineffective.Calculations by this author suggest that between the early 1970sand 1989, the real price paid to cereals farmers in the EU roughlyhalved. During this same period, the total area planted to cerealsin the EU fell by around 4–5%. Yet despite these two effects,total cereals production in the twelve member states rose byapproximately 33%.

These figures show that the EU’s reform policy of graduallycutting support prices paid to farmers in order to correct marketand financial imbalances would not work. The reason can be seenquite clearly in Figure 11.1. Whilst the levels of the differentsupport prices were changed over time, those changes were toosmall to have any significant effect on production and expenditurelevels. The intervention price was cut, but it was always chasing amoving target, as the steady increase in excess supply pushed downthe world equilibrium price.

Page 231: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

ROBERT ACKRILL

214

This point is further evidenced by the market events of late1990 and early 1991. Following the reforms of 1988, CAPexpenditures did fall, but this was against the background of thedrought in the United States. Most commentators felt that the causeof the expenditure cut was the drought, rather than the stabiliserreforms. Their prediction was, therefore, that once worldproduction rose (with production in the United States returning to‘normal’ levels and production elsewhere responding to the higherworld prices realised in 1988), CAP expenditures would once againrise. This process started in earnest in 1990, with rising surpluses ina number of sectors and increasing quantities of products goinginto store and for export. Official stock figures (taken at the end ofthe accounting year) indicate that the previous highest level ofcereals intervention stocks in the EU occurred at the end of 1985,when the figure was 18.5m tonnes. The data indicate that, by mid-1993, cereals stocks had risen to about 29m tonnes—i.e., considerablyabove the level of the mid-1980s.

In addition to the cereals sector, a number of other sectorsfaced major difficulties. Among those was the beef sector. Here,however, the causes of the problems were somewhat different.First, there were large quantities of cheaper beef ‘entering’ the EUfrom the former East Germany, resulting in more producers in therest of the EU trying to sell their beef into intervention. Second,in Britain in particular, demand was affected by the BSE ‘mad-cowdisease’ scare, causing producers to increase their ‘demand’ forintervention, as ‘market’ demand fell.

From all of this, it can be seen that attempts at reform failed defacto, because they in no serious way altered that fundamentalunderlying method of support under the CAP. Those ‘adjustments’that were made can be seen to have failed to address theimbalances in both the product markets and also in the budgetaryexpenditures incurred.

A RADICAL REFORM OF THE CAP

The discussion so far therefore begs the question of what sort ofreforms could be implemented that would succeed in containing thegrowth in production and support expenditure. What is set out nowis a consideration of the MacSharry Reforms agreed upon in May1992. The MacSharry Reforms represent the most radical changesin the CAP ever undertaken. The reason for this is that, for the

Page 232: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

THE COMMON AGRICULTURAL POLICY

215

first time, the basis for support has been changed fundamentally.Over a three-year transition period, the selling price of farmers’output will fall, with farmers being compensated for this with directgovernment payments. Additionally, all who produce more than 92tonnes of cereals (calculated at average historical regional yieldsrather than actual yields, ex post) must set aside 15% of their arableland (defined as the area of land on which they grow cereals,oilseeds and protein crops—peas, beans and lupins—and also landthat was set aside under the schemes agreed upon in 1988).

The larger farmers are not compelled to set aside their land, butif they do not, they will not be eligible for the compensatorypayments which offset the lowering of the selling price of theiroutput. This is the first time ‘cross-compliance’ (i.e., having tosatisfy a pre-condition before being eligible to receive support) hasplayed a major role in the operation of the CAP. By setting asideland, these larger farmers then also become entitled to claimcompensation for that obligation as well. In all cases, the per-unitlevel of compensation is initially stated as a sum per tonne ofproduction. The actual payment, however, is now based on area, sothe per-unit or per-tonne compensatory payment must be multipliedby the average regional yield figure, in order to establish the sumpaid. It must also be noted that this ‘base’ yield figure is not theactual current yield, but the average of the yields over the period1986–90, excluding the highest and lowest figures. Thus support isnow based on area planted rather than the level of production,unlike the old system of support. The principle is best illustrated bya simple example.

The new versus the old regime

To illustrate the difference between the two regimes, suppose afarmer has 100 hectares planted to different cereals, oilseeds andprotein crops. He must now set aside 15% of this area (i.e., fifteenhectares) and farm only 85 hectares. Suppose also his average baseyield is five tonnes per hectare. With a per-unit compensatorypayment of ECU 45 per tonne, he is eligible for a per-hectarepayment of (ECU 45×5=) ECU 225. This is payable on the 85hectares that he is allowed to plant and thus he receives, for thisarea of his farm, a total compensatory payment of (ECU 225×85=)ECU 19,125. In addition, he can claim compensation for having toset aside 15 hectares of his land. This is compensated at a rate of

Page 233: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

ROBERT ACKRILL

216

ECU 57 per tonne. Thus, he also receives a per-hectare set-asidecompensatory payment of (ECU 57×5=) ECU 285, giving total set-aside compensation of (ECU 285×15=) ECU 4,275. The farmerthus receives total compensatory and set-aside payments of ECU23,400. In addition, he will also receive the revenue from selling hiscrop at the (lower) market price. Assuming the producer pricecontinues to follow the level of the intervention or buying-in price,this will be ECU 100 per tonne. He is producing on 85 hectares atfive tonnes per hectare, which gives him a total revenue of ECU42,500. Thus, he has a total income of (ECU 42,500+ECU23,400=) ECU 65,900.

Under the old system, in contrast, the price received by farmersalso tended towards the level of the intervention or buying-in price.This was approximately ECU 155 per tonne. He would, however, beproducing on all his 100 hectares. Thus, the same farmer under theold regime would sell his crop for (ECU 155×5×100=) ECU77,500. The hypothetical farmer is therefore worse off under thenew system by ECU 11,600. This calculation, however, only looksat income and thus excludes costs incurred in production. One wayin which a farmer could make savings is via the lower use ofvariable inputs such as fertilisers and pesticides. Under the newsystem, the yield figure (here taken as five tonnes per hectare) isbased on past yields, not current levels. Thus, whilst a lower use ofsuch inputs may cut current yields, this would not affect thecalculation set out above. Hence, savings on purchased inputs maybe made.

In terms of the effect on production, economists predict thatthe growth in output will be affected. The large fall in crop sellingprices will be most influential in this. Over the space of thethreeyear transition period, the drop in nominal selling price will beabout ten times the average annual price cut under the stabilisermechanism. Moreover, there will be a much larger area of landtaken out as set-aside. Under the schemes agreed in 1988, the areacame to approximately 1% of all arable land. Under MacSharry,however, allowing for small farmers who are exempt from set-asiderequirements, about 9% of all arable land will be removed fromproduction. One forecast (see Ackrill et al., 1993) suggests that by1999 production may be at least 15–16m tonnes per annum lowerunder MacSharry than had the old stabiliser system continued.

Regarding the control of production, therefore, it appears thatthe new policy could be relatively successful. The main grey area

Page 234: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

THE COMMON AGRICULTURAL POLICY

217

surrounding this forecast remains ‘slippage’. This occurs when thecut in area planted is not fully represented in the cut in production.Whilst it has been suggested that farmers could cut the use ofinputs and therefore cut production more than proportionately, it isalso conceivable (based on years of experience in the United States)that farmers could farm their remaining 85% of land moreintensively. This would push up average yields and reduce theeffects of set-aside on cuts in production. Thus a net 9% cut inarea may only result in perhaps a 6–7% cut in production.

For consumers, there is generally modest and qualified goodnews. As noted earlier, there is an increasing element of processinggoing into food nowadays and it is unlikely that the price cutsunder MacSharry will make any serious difference to the marketingmargin. Thus whilst food processors will be paying less for theirraw material inputs, their other costs are unlikely to change and sothe net effect on the price of food in the shops is likely to bemodest at best.

The third main group in the analysis—i.e., the taxpayers who payfor the EU budget via their domestic tax contributions—are alsolikely to suffer. The costs incurred in paying for export refunds andintervention storage are expected to fall significantly underMacSharry. Estimates put the savings at about ECU 2.4bn by 1999(see Ackrill et al., 1993). The problem, however, is that the budgetmust now pay for the difference between the price paid byconsumers of the farmers’ production and the final sum receivedby producers; i.e., the total compensatory payments. Ackrill et al.(1993) estimate that this figure could exceed ECU 7bn by 1999.Other estimates have put the figure even higher.

There are, however, two possible gains for the EU with theexpenditure under the new system, even though total expenditure islikely to rise. First, the bulk of the expenditures (the two forms ofcompensation payments) will be much more stable and predictablethan the expenditures on export refunds and intervention storage.This gives an advantage to the EU in trying to predict the level ofown resources needed in any year to cover total expenditure plans.Second, the total expenditure arising from CAP support will now bemuch more directly under the control of the EU. It was shownearlier how cutting support prices had no significant effect onproduction and budget costs. Now, however, by cutting the per-tonne level of the compensation payment and/ or set-asidepayment, the EU can realise immediate and significant savings.

Page 235: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

ROBERT ACKRILL

218

Estimates suggest that, for 1997, a one-off cut on the levels of thetwo compensatory payments of ECU 5 per tonne would result inbudget savings of between ECU 750m and ECU 800m (Ackrill etal., 1993).

THE CAP AND GATT

It is also worth referring in this discussion to the internationalpressures that have helped, albeit only indirectly, in shaping the newCAP. The EU and its member states are all members of theGeneral Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT). Within therecently concluded ‘Uruguay Round’ of trade negotiationssponsored by GATT (1986–93), there was great pressure on the EUfrom the United States and the ‘Cairns Group’ of agriculturalfreetraders, which all want the EU to reduce its support foragriculture because of the trade-distorting effects such interventionhas—notably the use of export refunds, which depress the worldprice and permit the EU to compete, unfairly as these othercountries perceive it, in export markets.

Considering the MacSharry Reforms detailed above, it can beseen that these will reduce the trade distortion resulting from theCAP since they will cut the market prices of agricultural productswithin the EU to levels much closer to world prices, therebyrequiring much lower export refunds on trade. Indeed, if worldprices were to rise by about 15–20% for whatever reason, then sucha strong market would mean that the EU would be able to exportwithout subsidy. It is, however, worth examining the commitmentsthat might be asked of the EU in more detail. If the CAP reformsoutlined above do not achieve these requirements, further changesto agricultural support in the EU will be necessary. Ingersent et al.(1993) sets out in detail both the proposals contained in the‘Dunkel Draft’ paper of 1991 and also the amendments containedin the bilateral Blair House Accord, agreed between the EU and theUnited States late in 1992. In brief, the key issues as outlined in theDunkel Paper are: 1 to improve market access by tariff reductions. These were to be

reinforced by specific minimum import figures for each year;2 to reduce domestic support by 20%, this to be applied to all

supported commodities. In this process, credit is given wherereductions in support for a commodity have occurred since

Page 236: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

THE COMMON AGRICULTURAL POLICY

219

1986. In addition, support policies that create little or no tradedistortion (so-called ‘green-box’ policies) are to be exempt; and

3 export volumes are to be cut by 24%, with budgetaryexpenditure on exports being cut by 36%. Both requirementsrelate to each commodity individually.

The CAP reforms of 1992 unquestionably made the possibility of amultilateral GATT agreement more likely and the purpose of thesubsequent bilateral talks was to try to iron out specific concernsbetween the EU and the United States. Included in this was anattempt to finally resolve the long-standing disagreements betweenthe EU and United States over the EU’s support policy for oilseeds(now incorporated into a broader ‘arable’ regime under theMacSharry Reforms). The Blair House Accord amended the issuesoutlined above in a number of ways: 1 on market access, the EU was permitted to retain 10%

Community Preference. Community Preference has always beena key pillar of the CAP and in practice this now means thatthe EU would be able to retain a tariff on imports of 10%;

2 on domestic support, the EU got the United States torecognise the new area and headage payments as ‘green-box’support instruments, even though they are not fully ‘decoupled’(i.e., not fully independent of the level of production);

3 on exports, the 24% volume reduction figure was lowered to21%. This applies to all exporters; and

4 on oilseeds, the EU agreed to a minimum figure of the 15%setaside requirement that should come from areas planted tooilseeds. The purpose of this is to contain oilseed productionwithin the EU to 10m tonnes.

In the end, an agreement was reached between the EU and theUnited States in early December that permitted a full GATTagreement to be completed on December 15, 1993, the deadlinedate for the Uruguay Round. To a great extent, the final dealaccepts the proposals from the Blair House Accord, although with afew noteworthy amendments. In accordance with the earlierproposals, domestic support is to be cut by 20%, with the agreedexemptions for ‘green-box’ policies. In addition, subsidised exportsare to be cut by 36% in value and 21% in volume.

There is, however, an important change to the base against

Page 237: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

ROBERT ACKRILL

220

which this cut is judged. As agreed between the EU and the UnitedStates immediately prior to the conclusion of the Uruguay Round,the base period is to be changed from the average of the period1986–90, to the average of 1991–92. In practical terms this meansthat over a six-year period, the EU will be able to export anadditional 8m tonnes beyond the limit had the earlier base periodapplied. Finally, it was agreed that all import barriers are to beconverted to tariffs or tariff equivalents and reduced by 36%. Thisrelates to the simple mathematical average of all tariffs—eachindividual tariff must be reduced by a minimum of 15% over thesix-year period. It is estimated that world prices will rise by up to10%, resulting in gains to the EU in terms of lower unit exportrefunds (important in terms of the required 36% reduction inexport refund expenditures).

One feature of this reform package is that it asks countries toreduce domestic support and address trade issues (notably, marketaccess and export competition). Both the EU and the United Stateshave now made significant changes to their domestic policies andfurther major cuts would be politically very difficult. It needs to beconsidered, however, if further changes to the CAP will be neededin order to meet the requirements of the GATT agreement.Considering first the 20% reduction in domestic support required,this has already been met, aided by the classification of new EUsupport measures as ‘green box’.

With regard to the trade measures, things are rather less clearcut.A number of studies have been carried out to see if the MacSharryReforms of the CAP would actually result in the EU being able tomeet the requirements of the GATT agreement without furtherchanges. The results are dependent on the assumptions made aboutthe affects of price cuts on, inter alia, production and consumptionand hence on the exportable surplus. Some studies feel that forcereals, the new EU regime will lead to the GATT commitmentbeing met, whilst others feel further change would be necessary. Forbeef, however, there appears to be more general agreement thatfurther changes would be needed. Work by Rayner et al. (1993)perhaps summarises the work best by showing that, for cereals, theresult is very much on a knife-edge. It is suggested that for theperiod 1998 to 2000, the EU may well breach the subsidised exportvolume limit. If, however, the world price were to rise, it may befeasible to export some cereals without refund, thus meeting therequirement concerning subsidised exports. A few straightforward

Page 238: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

THE COMMON AGRICULTURAL POLICY

221

ways in which the EU could, if necessary, match the GATTobligations are: 1 to increase the set-aside requirement, by either or both of

increasing the set-aside percentage for farmers already settingaside land and reducing the exemptions for small farmers(either by reducing the ceiling for a farmer to be exempt, orrequiring all ‘small’ farmers to set aside a low percentage ofland); and/or

2 to cut intervention price, thus lowering the internal price. Thiswould reduce the per-unit export refund and could ultimatelylead to the abandonment of subsidised exports; and/or

3 to subsidise exports up to the ceiling permitted and export therest without subsidy (such as occurs in the EU’s sugar sectorcurrently); and/or

4 to store the extra quantities if, for 1998–2000, the EU is unableto meet its GATT obligations by the above means. Given thebudgetary reforms implemented since 1988, however, this couldonly ever be a short-term palliative.

One point here is that an implicit assumption is made about theconditions in the rest of the world remaining unchanged. As wasseen in 1988 with a drought in the US mid-West, changedcircumstances elsewhere in the world could affect the EU’s positionquite dramatically, for the good in the case of such a drought withbudget savings and greater export opportunities. It could benegative, however, if, for example, a major grain importer were topurchase less grain and the supplies they would have bought thenneeded to find a new market elsewhere. This has often meant largersubsidies being used, driving down the world price and increasingthe EU’s unit export refund.

Overall, therefore, it can be seen that the various reformsimplemented unilaterally by the EU and multilaterally by GATT areto a large extent compatible. For the key cereals sector, some ofthe support reductions asked for by GATT have already been metby the EU. Other reductions meeting the GATT obligations will, toa large extent, depend on variables outside the control of the EU.Even if these work against the EU, it is suggested that it would bestraightforward to amend the CAP as it now stands (‘reform’ isperhaps too strong a word) so that it will become compatible withGATT.

Page 239: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

ROBERT ACKRILL

222

CONCLUSIONS

Since its inception, the CAP has been a cornerstone of theoperations of the EU. The policy has, however, generated muchpolitical and economic discussion over the way in which it operates.It has been shown that the method of support used under the CAPsince its inception was instrumental in generating the muchpublicised surpluses of agricultural products and also creatingfinancial crises for the EU. Both outcomes are shown to be entirelyconsistent with simple microeconomic theory.

Although it was ‘reformed’ throughout the 1980s, the policy was,in essence, the same as when it was instituted over 30 years ago. Ithas also been shown that the ‘radical’ reform of the CAP agreedupon in 1992 will help to contain production and thereforeintervention storage and export refund expenditures. The EUbudget will, however, have to face the significant added burden ofthe compensatory payments agreed in 1992. These are effectivelycomparable to the ‘hidden’ transfers from consumers that occurredunder the old support system, but now, coming from taxpayers, theyare quite ‘visible’. Consumers may be a little better off, althoughonly marginally, and it is suggested that producers may be better orworse off, depending on specific circumstances, although it is alsoindicated that larger farmers, like many in Britain, may well beworse off. Taxpayers, it is suggested, will also be worse off, becauseof the extra cost incurred with the compensation payments.

Future further changes to the policy will depend to a greatextent on whether or not the reformed CAP is able to meet theEU’s international obligations determined during the UruguayRound of the GATT. It has been suggested here that even if thenew CAP cannot meet these without further change, for somesectors at least, notably cereals, the additional changes needed willnot be significant and could be met by simple adjustments to thepolicy variables under the reformed CAP.

Page 240: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

223

12

JAPANESE FOREIGN DIRECTINVESTMENT

The Impact on the European UnionGeorge Norman

INTRODUCTION

The past decade has seen a remarkable transformation in trade anddirect investment flows, particularly between the developed economies,but also between the developed economies and the newlyindustrialising nations. This transformation has been characterised by aparticularly rapid growth in foreign direct investment (FDI). Over theperiod 1983–89, the outflows of FDI grew at an annual rate ofapproximately 29%, more than twice as fast as the previous decade andthree times faster than the growth of world exports and the growth ofworld output (see Table 12.1). There is an intensified effort on the partof most countries to attract this investment. Transnational companiesare emerging from the developing countries as well as the developedeconomies and they are increasingly adopting an explicitly globalstrategy in many of their business activities.

This implies: (i) that FDI is likely to become the dominantmethod for international economic integration; and (ii) thatmultinational firms will produce an increasing share of world output.

Table 12.1 Growth of foreign direct investment, exports and grossdomestic product, 1973–89

Source: Dunning (1988), United Nations (1991), OECD.

Page 241: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

GEORGE NORMAN

224

It might be felt that this is of little consequence since, in aHeckscher-Ohlin-Samuelson world, trade in factors of production canbe treated as a substitute for trade in goods (Mundell, 1957), but thegenerality of this proposition can be questioned. In an imperfectlycompetitive or, in particular, an oligopolistic international economicenvironment, the relationship between trade in goods and trade infactors is at best ambiguous. It is possible, and indeed likely asNorman and Dunning (1984) and Markusen (1987) have suggested,that international factor flows are complementary to trade in goods.

The implications for trade, technology f lows and thecompetitiveness of individual nations are significant. Rather thanbeing neutral as suggested by Mundell’s analysis, FDI is likely tohave a direct and important influence on a host economy in anumber of ways that the same volume of trade flows need nothave, notably:

1 the effect on the local economies in which the investment islocated;

2 the potential for effective technology transfer;3 export/import-substitution potential; and4 employment and growth in the host economies and the

receiving regions.

It is impossible to cover all of these issues within the confines of asingle chapter. This chapter will, therefore, present an overview ofJapanese FDI in the manufacturing sector in the EU. The motivesfor this investment are then considered, since these will shed lighton the consequences of the investment for the EU. The impact onthe local economies is likely to be determined both by why Japanesecompanies choose to establish operations in Europe and by howthose operations have developed. There is more likely to be alongterm, beneficial impact if the investment is closely integratedwith the local economies, exercises effective local decision-makingand is associated with research activities.

THE EMERGENCE OF THE TRIAD

The United States remains the dominant source of FDI in terms ofthe stock of investment but the rapid growth of FDI flows in thepast decade has been accompanied by the emergence of a newleading source of this investment (see Figure 12.1). Japan hasovertaken both Britain and the United States to become the major

Page 242: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

JAPANESE FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT

225

source of new FDI outflows. This has had the effect of changingthe global pattern of FDI stocks and flows. In the early 1980s thispattern could be described as being roughly bi-polar, dominated bythe United States and the EU. By the beginning of the 1990s atripolar pattern is emerging based upon the United States, the EUand Japan (see Figure 12.2).

This Triad accounts for approximately 80% of total outwardFDI stocks and flows but only about 50% of world trade. Inaddition, an increasing share of the investment flows are beingconcentrated in the Triad. Nevertheless, there remains aconsiderable asymmetry in the flows. Recent years have seen thegrowth, not only in intra-industry trade but also in intra-industryFDI, but the latter has occurred primarily between the UnitedStates and the EU: see Cantwell (1989), Norman and Dunning(1984). By contrast, there have been relatively low FDI inflows toJapan, a phenomenon that has emerged as an important source offriction between Japan and her trading partners.

Figure 12.1 Outflows of foreign direct investment, 1985–89 (US$bn)Source: International Monetary Fund.

Page 243: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

GEORGE NORMAN

226

THE GROWTH OF INTERNATIONALREGIONALISM

Over the same period there have been considerable changes in FDIflows within the EU that are likely to have significant impacts onthe investment decisions of non-EU members. The 1992programme (see Chapters 7 and 8) and the general process ofregional integration in the EU have been reflected in a rapidgrowth in intra-EU FDI: from 25% of the total inward stock in1980 to 40% by 1988. In a number of industries, in particular thetechnology-intensive industries, EU corporations are becomingincreasingly regionalised within the Union. The home markets ofsuch firms are seen as the EU rather than the country of origin ofthe firms within the EU.

Similar comments can be applied to those firms from the UnitedStates that have been long-established within the EU. Many ofthese companies have developed a pan-European view (e.g., Ford,General Motors), with high levels of local sourcing and highlydevolved local management structures to such an extent that it isdifficult to think of them as being other than EU companies. While

Figure 12.2 Intra-Triad foreign direct investment, 1988Source: UNCTC.

Page 244: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

JAPANESE FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT

227

few of the Japanese companies currently established in the EU canyet be described as ‘Euro-giants’, this can primarily be explained bytheir relative youth—as will become clear when their motives andobjectives in establishing their European bases are established.

There has been a change in strategy by Japanese firms. The1970s and early 1980s could be characterised as a period ofmarket dominance through exports, with FDI intended mainly tosupport exports. In more recent years, by contrast, ‘there isevidence that Japanese transnational corporations are buildingregionally integrated, independently sustainable networks ofoverseas investments centred on a Triad member (“regional corenetworks”)’ (United Nations, 1991). These networks are intendedto secure access to the relevant Triad markets and to protect theJapanese companies from the real or imagined threat of tradesanctions by the United States and the EU—see also Gittelmanand Dunning (1991).

Until recently, the majority of Japanese investment has beentargeted at North America but there is evidence of a change inemphasis with an increased focus on the EU and the rapidlygrowing markets in the Far East. The industrial structure ofJapanese investment varies across the three members of the Triad(see Figure 12.3). More than 50% of the investment in the EU is inthe service sector, whereas in North America and Asia the emphasisis much more on manufacturing and (in Asia) mining or resource

Figure 12.3 Japanese foreign direct investment by industry (stock as ofMarch 1990)Source: Ministry of Finance, Japan.

Page 245: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

GEORGE NORMAN

228

extraction. These differences are reflected in the very differentproportions of outputs exported (see Figure 12.4).

These data are only partly consistent with the suggestion thatFDI by Japanese corporations replaces intra-Triad exports. Suchsubstitution appears to be strongest in the United States where thevast majority of sales are intended for the US market. This is lesstrue of investment in the member states of the EU, where ahigher proportion of sales is exported. It should be noted,however, that there is a high proportion of intra-EU exports (92%of total sales exported in 1987). If the EU is treated as anintegrated market in much the same way as the United States,then the EU strategy has much in common with that adopted inthe United States.

The strategy underlying investment in Asia is rather different,reflecting only in part the longer history of this investment. It is nolonger possible to explain such investment solely by the desire togain access to sources of relatively cheap labour and raw materials.That such an explanation still has some force can be seen by the

Figure 12.4 Sales of Japanese affiliates in manufacturing, 1987 (billion yen)Source: United Nations.

Page 246: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

JAPANESE FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT

229

high proportion of affiliate sales that are exported intra-firm.Nevertheless, we can perceive a clear shift in focus with theJapanese corporations positioning themselves to take advantage ofthe spectacular growth in consumer demand in the rapidly growingeconomies of the Asia—Pacific region.

If attention is confined to the United States and the EU, thesedata further support the idea that the Japanese transnational areadopting a regional core network strategy—in the United Statesbecause it is already an integrated market and in the EU because itis becoming one with the completion of the single-marketprogramme. The establishment of extensive networks of localsuppliers to serve the overseas affiliates discussed below isconsistent with this hypothesis, as is the fact that the Japanesetransnationals are attempting to form close, long-term relationshipswith these suppliers and are now developing regional researchpotential through the creation of research and developmentfacilities in the EU.

What we are seeing is the emergence in the EU of Japanesetransnational corporations whose market orientation is towards thewhole EU region rather than any one country within the region.This is likely to lead, as these companies mature within the EU, tocharacteristics that are already common in EU and UStransnationals in the EU—increased cross-border trade betweenaffiliates to take advantage of economies of scale and the benefitsof specialisation.

One feature that remains unclear is the extent to which thesecompanies will be oriented to exports to countries outside the EUregional bloc. If the ‘regional core network’ hypothesis is correct,then such exports are unlikely to be extensive. Rather, there will bean emphasis on deepening the intra-regional network of tradingrelationships. This should, however, be interpreted as a benignrather than malign characteristic of the investment. The size of theEU and the North American regional markets are each sufficient toallow an operation sited in either one of these regions to achievemost of the available economies of scale without exporting to anyof the other regional markets in the Triad.

JAPANESE INVESTMENT IN THE EU

There has been a rapid growth of Japanese FDI in the EU (seeFigure 12.5) with Britain as the major recipient, although we are

Page 247: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

GEORGE NORMAN

230

Figure 12.5 Japanese manufacturing enterprises in EuropeSoure: JETRO (1991).

Table 12.2 Investment plans for the EU (number of projects)

Source: Export-Import Bank of Japan.

Page 248: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

JAPANESE FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT

231

now beginning to see the re-emergence of Germany as a hostcountry. A recent survey by the Export-Import Bank of Japan(1991) indicated that nearly as many companies have investmentplans involving location in Germany as in Britain (see Table 12.2).The majority of this investment is in high-technology,engineeringbased industries, notably consumer electronics, chemicals,general machinery and transport.

THE MOTIVATION FOR JAPANESE INVESTMENTIN THE EU

Simply stated, a world view lies at the heart of the overall FDIstrategy of the majority of the larger Japanese transnational andinvestment in the EU forms part of this world view. The Japanesetransnationals have switched increasingly from exporting to overseasproduction and in doing so have chosen to establish operations inthe EU as well as elsewhere in the Triad. There have been severalsurveys aimed at identifying the reasons for this change: see, forexample, Dunning (1986), Export-Import Bank of Japan (1991,1992) and JETRO (1984–91). A major problem in comparing thesesurveys and in trying to draw conclusions from them is that theydo not share a common methodology. Each survey offers differentpossible responses to those being surveyed. Even the JETROsurveys that have been conducted on a regular basis since 1984 usequestions that have been changed over the years, making inter-temporal comparison difficult.

Given this caveat a number of conclusions can be drawn fromboth the JETRO surveys and others such as those of the Export-Import Bank of Japan. One prediction of theory suggests thatmuch of the Japanese investment in the EU has been motivated bynegative influences such as, for example, the apparent increased useof anti-dumping actions by the EU (Tharakan, 1991) and thepossibility that the regional integration that is part of 1992 will leadinevitably to the emergence of closed regional blocs—‘FortressEurope’ as it has occasionally been labelled. If this is indeed themain motivation for the investment, then it is probable that theinvestment has merely been brought forward in time rather thanincreased in volume compared to what would have happenedwithout the change in policy—see Thomsen and Nicolaides (1991).

The evidence does not, however, appear to support thisnegative view. In addition, theory can be used to give a richer and

Page 249: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

GEORGE NORMAN

232

more positive set of predictions. There is no question thatJapanese companies feel that increased regional integration withinthe EU will make market access more difficult. In addition, theyhave been influenced by factors that come under the generalheading of trade friction as a consequence of which, ceteris paribus,FDI from Japan is likely to continue at least at its present level.But even here it is possible to discern a positive rather thanpurely defensive response in the reasons for continuation ofoverseas investment.

By far the greatest motives for investment in the EU relate tothe positive factors already discussed. Regional integrationincreases accessibility to the host-country market. Rather thantalking of the ‘British’, or the ‘French’ or the ‘German’ markets asa series of separated markets, we should talk of the European orEU market. Improved market accessibility resulting from theSingle European Act (SEA) is increasingly encouraging companies,no matter what their original nationalities, to adopt a pan-European view. Since the change in market accessibility isadditional to any increase in market size it will lead to moreinvestment in the EU than would have occurred as a consequencesolely of market growth. As one Japanese businessman recentlystated, ‘even if “Fortress Europe” is a reality, it is better to be inone single, unified and large fortress than in a number of small,separated fortresses’.

This is reflected in the JETRO and Export-Import Bank ofJapan surveys of Japanese manufacturers’ motives for establishingEU operations (see, for example, Figure 12.6). The evidence of theinvestment being a negative or defensive response to increasedprotectionism within the EU is weak. Much greater importance isplaced upon market access and, more recently, upon theestablishment of a global corporate strategy. This is consistent withthe suggestion that the investment is intended to establish regionalcore networks and in turn is consistent with the view that economicintegration, by improving intra-EU market access, will encourageinvestment by companies from countries that are not members ofthe EU.

Such surveys must, of course, be treated with caution. It hasbeen suggested by at least one Japanese businessman, for example,that the importance of ‘Fortress Europe’ is not fully reflected inthe survey responses to JETRO. Nevertheless, the largely positivemessage coming from these survey results suggests that the volume

Page 250: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

JAPANESE FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT

233

of investment will be greater than would have been the casewithout regional integration.

THE IMPACT OF JAPANESE INVESTMENT

While there have been some studies of the local regional impact ofJapanese investment in the EU—see, for example, Munday (1990)—I shall concentrate upon a number of broader issues. Apart fromthe immediate impact of new FDI, significant long-term benefitsare dependent upon the quality of that investment measured alongat least three important dimensions: 1 the extent of local sourcing;2 the degree to which managerial autonomy is granted to the EU

affiliate; and3 research and development (R&D) activity in the EU.

Local sourcing

The higher the degree to which inputs are sourced locally, thegreater the likelihood that there will be multiplier effects from theincoming investment and that there will be effective technology andknowledge transfer. Progress in this area has been significant. Arecent JETRO survey (1991) indicates (see Figure 12.7) that theaverage local content has increased from 55.1% at the start ofoperations to 68.9% in 1990. Local content is highest amongenterprises bought out by the Japanese and lowest among those

Figure 12.6 Motivation for production in EuropeSource: JETRO (1991).

Page 251: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

GEORGE NORMAN

234

which have 100% Japanese ownership, but the rate of increase inlocal content is greatest in the latter group of companies. Theinitial level of local content is particularly high among companiesthat have entered the EU after 1989—over 67%. While this hasundoubtedly been influenced by pressure from within the memberstates of the EU, it is also consistent with the establishment ofcorporations in the EU that are European in outlook.

There is, however, a significant negative side that must berecognised, as illustrated in Figure 12.8. The degree of satisfactionexpressed with respect to local suppliers remains depressingly low.The 1991 JETRO survey indicates that nearly 70% of respondentshave expressed some degree of dissatisfaction with their localsuppliers, roughly evenly split between quality, price and delivery.

It is clear from these results that local suppliers still have muchto learn if they, and the local economies in which they operate, areto benefit fully from the incoming investment. This evidence alsopoints to at least two potential future developments. First, if theEU supply base is inadequate there is at least the possibility that

Figure 12.7 Local content of parts and material (per cent) (per centsourced within the EC and EFTA)Source: JETRO (1991).

Page 252: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

JAPANESE FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT

235

new investment will be diverted from the EU to other regions inthe Triad, in particular to the rapidly growing economies in theAsia-Pacific region. Second, a natural response to dissatisfactionwith local suppliers in the EU is to encourage a secondary flow ofinvestment by Japanese specialist suppliers who are well versed inthe requirements of their Japanese clients. This secondary flow ofinvestment may supplant local (EU) suppliers and so limit thetechnology, knowledge and managerial skills transfer that couldotherwise be achieved.

Managerial autonomy

Here the message is much more positive. A significant minority(about 30%) of Japanese companies in the EU now have locallyrecruited chief executive officers (CEOs), and determined moveshave been made to localise management. It does appear that theJapanese transnational are aiming to become regional ‘insiders’rather than foreign companies operating in the EU. It also appears

Figure 12.8 Reasons for dissatisfaction with local suppliers (per cent)Source: JETRO (1991).

Page 253: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

GEORGE NORMAN

236

that they are satisfied with the quality of managerial staff available.What remains to be seen, of course, is the extent to which localmanagement finds itself at the centre of decision-making within thecorporation. It has been suggested that local management will neverfind its way into the inner circle but much the same was said aboutUS transnational when they first came to the EU. Only time willtell whether real and extensive decision-making independence isceded to the European affiliates.

Research and development

The same positive message appears. There has been a rapid buildupof design centres and R&D facilities in the EU, with the numbernearly doubling between 1990 and 1991. A significant proportion ofthese have been created as part of the global strategy of the parentcompany. Their prime motivation is to design products for theregional (in this case the EU) market. It is felt increasingly that thisis most effectively achieved by being close to the market and to thecompetition.

CONCLUSIONS

Conclusions are inevitably mixed. The rapid growth of JapaneseFDI in the EU is a response only in part to increasedprotectionism. It is to a much larger extent a response to theincreased market accessibility that has followed from the completionof the single market in 1992. While both negative and positivefactors are important, surveys of the motivations of thosecompanies that have established operations in the EU indicate thattheir actions have been much more influenced by the positive ratherthan the negative implications of 1992. This implies that moreJapanese FDI has and will come to the EU than would haveoccurred without the policy changes.

Japanese investment in the EU is part of a wider strategy. Whatis emerging with the continued flow of FDI from Japan is a set ofglobal corporations whose aim is to develop as regional insiders inthe three big regional blocs of the Triad. These corporations aretaking an integrated view of the EU and other Triad markets. Tocompete with them both within the EU and in other parts of theTriad, it is clear that EU and US corporations will have torationalise their activities along roughly similar lines. This will lead

Page 254: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

JAPANESE FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT

237

in the future to an increasing proportion of trade flows takingplace within the relevant Triad region rather than between regions ofthe Triad. It also implies that countries that are not currently partof the Triad will have increasing difficulties in penetrating the Triadmarkets. This might mean, of course, that we shall see yet furtherregional blocs emerging in the future.

The quality of the investment coming to the EU is high,particularly with respect to progress in devolving managerialautonomy and establishing EU-based research and developmentactivities, but problems remain. In particular there are importantconcerns with the supply base that is such a crucial part of makingthe Japanese investment in the EU work to the real long-termbenefit of the host countries and regions. It is to be hoped that theEU can make significant progress to be made in this respect in thefuture.

Page 255: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

238

13

COMPETITION POLICY INTHE EUROPEAN UNION

Eleanor J.Morgan

INTRODUCTION

The progressive reduction of trade barriers to create a singleEuropean market (SEM) has exposed many firms in the EuropeanUnion (EU) to increased competitive pressures (see Chapters 7 and8). There are two possible responses to this change in thecompetitive environment. Firms may take advantage of theopportunities offered by the larger internal market to become morecompetitive, so benefiting consumers. Alternatively, they may reactdefensively to protect themselves from increased competition byacting anticompetitively through restrictive agreements andmonopolistic practices, for example. National governments may alsotry to protect their domestic firms from the increased competitionby granting subsidies and other forms of assistance.

Competition policy has an important role in the context of theSEM to ensure that anti-competitive behaviour, both by firms andnational governments, is controlled so that the potential benefits ofintegration are realised and consumers gain, not simply theproducers and shareholders. Its importance was recognised in theTreaty of Rome, and Articles 85–94 of this Treaty provide a systemto ensure that ‘competition in the common market is not distorted’.As the pace of integration gathered momentum from 1985, theexisting framework of competition policy has been more activelyapplied and new powers have been introduced so that this is nowone of the most prominent parts of EU policy.

Decisions on competition are taken largely by the EuropeanCommission although appeals can be made against its decisions tothe European Court of Justice. Cartels and restrictive practices andthe ‘abuse of a dominant position’ (i.e., misuse of monopoly power)

Page 256: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

COMPETITION POLICY IN THE EUROPEAN UNION

239

can be prohibited under Articles 85 and 86 respectively of theTreaty of Rome. Powers have been extended beyond the originalTreaty provisions with the introduction of a Merger Regulation in1990. Article 90 of the Treaty of Rome provides control overnationalised undertakings and Articles 92 and 93 allow theCommission to restrict ‘state aids’ (i.e., government assistance orsubsidy). These aspects of policy will now be discussed withparticular emphasis on the recent developments associated with themove towards the SEM.

RESTRICTIVE PRACTICES

Under Article 85 of the Treaty of Rome, any agreements betweenenterprises which affect trade between member states and prevent,restrict or distort competition within the EU are generallyprohibited. The main targets of this prohibition have been marketsharing, price fixing and quota arrangements between competitors,supply restrictions and certain types of discriminatory distributionarrangements.

Such arrangements are seen as not only leading to costlyinefficiencies but also as conflicting with the aims of the EU inestablishing a single market. For example, market sharingagreements have the same effects as quotas on trade. The Europeansugar cartel is a good example of such an arrangement. This cartel,which was banned in the early 1970s, was based on the ‘homemarket rule’ under which the members agreed to operate only intheir own territories rather than competing across the larger internalmarket.

Most cartels are treated as illegal but more generally, anagreement which limits competition may be exempted under Article85 where its harmful effects on competition are counter-balancedby a number of possible beneficial effects. The conditions forexemption, laid down in Article 85, are that the agreementcontributes to ‘improving the production or distribution of goodsor to promoting technical or economic progress, while allowingconsumers a fair share of the resulting benefit’. Further conditionsfor exemption are that the agreement is the only way of achievingthe benefit and that competition is not eliminated from asubstantial part of the industry.

If the agreement eliminates competition in a substantial part ofthe industry, it must be condemned, no matter how beneficial its

Page 257: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

ELEANOR J.MORGAN

240

other effects. This still gives the Commission considerablediscretion to trade-off competition against efficiency orinternational competitiveness. For example, an agreement in 1990between the French company Alcatel Espace and ANT NachrichtenTechnik of Germany on research and development, production andmarketing of electronic components for satellites was allowedlargely to help them compete with their larger non-Europeancompetitors (especially those in the United States) which have awider spread of space technology activities.

As well as case-by-case investigations under Article 85, blockexemptions have been granted for some types of collaborativearrangements where it is expected that cooperative behaviour, whilerestricting competition, may still lead to efficiency and other sociallydesirable benefits. These include arrangements relating to jointresearch and development, patent licensing, specialisation in themanufacture of products involving small and medium-sizedenterprises (SMEs) and the development and application ofcommon standards. This system of exempting classes of agreementfrom the requirement to notify allows industrial policy objectives tobe recognised and avoids the necessity for detailed scrutiny by theCommission, reducing its workload as well as the degree ofdiscretion in Commission policy.

Article 85 has been vigorously applied towards price fixing andmarket-sharing arrangements in recent years but its powers werelittle used until 1962. This was mainly due to disagreements amongthe member states, especially concerning possible grounds forexempting agreements from the competition rules. The problem wasdealt with in 1962 when the Council of Ministers adoptedRegulation 17/62 which clarified policy and gave the Commissionwide powers of enforcement.

If the Commission finds against an agreement, the companiesconcerned usually agree to end the agreement voluntarily or tomodify it so that it is acceptable after an informal recommendationfrom the Commission. Otherwise the agreement can be ended byissuing a formal decision. Table 13.1 reveals a gradual increase inthe number of formal decisions. Most of the decisions relate tomanufactured products and, over the period 1960 to 1990, servicesaccounted for only 12% of all decisions. From 1980 to 1990,however, 20% of decisions were concerned with services (see Sapiret al., 1993). This was due to the Commission’s efforts to completethe internal market in previously protected areas such as futures

Page 258: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

COMPETITION POLICY IN THE EUROPEAN UNION

241

markets, insurance, banking, transport, construction and the media.Emphasis on the service sector has increased since and fourteen ofthe 40 formal Article 85 decisions related to the service sector in1991 and 1992.

The number of unnotified agreements which are actually inoperation is unknown but the Commission has wide powers toobtain evidence and, if it finds that Article 85 is being infringed,the agreement is automatically banned. Heavy fines of up to 10%of the turnover of each company concerned can be levied. Therehas been a marked increase in the level of fines actually imposed incartel cases in recent years. This indicates a substantial tougheningof policy towards cartels in contrast to the relatively relaxedtreatment of other types of collaboration which have become morecommon in recent years.

MONOPOLIES

EU competition policy towards monopoly is contained in Article 86which provides that ‘any abuse by one or more undertakings of adominant position within the common market or in a substantialpart of it shall be prohibited as incompatible with the commonmarket insofar as it may affect trade between member states’. Thereare three important elements in this policy:

1 there has to be a dominant position;2 it is abuse of the dominant position which is controlled rather

than dominance itself; and3 there must be the possibility of an effect on trade between

member states (as is the case with Article 85).

Before being able to assess the degree of market dominance, theCommission has to decide the boundaries of the relevant market

Table 13.1 Individual formal Commission decisions under Articles 85 and86 published in the Official Journal, by sector

Source: Sapir et al. (1993).

Page 259: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

ELEANOR J.MORGAN

242

both in terms of the products involved and its geographic extent.Defining a market has been problematical and in Continental Can,the first case considered under Article 86, the company won anappeal against the Commission on the grounds that the Commissionhad defined the product market too narrowly and had thereforeunderestimated competition from substitute products.

Article 86 does not define what a ‘dominant position’ is.However, past decisions suggest that a firm with less than 40% ofthe market will not be regarded as dominant and usually muchhigher shares are involved. A high market share does notautomatically give monopoly power so other factors are taken intoaccount to see whether the firm has the ability to act independentlyof competitive pressures. These include the structure of the firm,including the degree of vertical integration and control overdistribution channels, as well as the structure of the market, forexample the number and strength of actual competitors and thedegree of potential competition. The judgements have also referredto behavioural and performance aspects such as a firm’s success indefending market share even when prices are higher than thosecharged by competitors.

The dominant position itself is not illegal, only the abuse ofdominance. Certain types of abuse have been singled out forparticular attention, namely unfair buying or selling prices,limitations on production, applying dissimilar conditions toequivalent transactions and ‘tying agreements’ whereby amanufacturer, for example, will sell product ‘A’ to customers only ifthey agree to accept product ‘B’ as well.

The recent Tetra Pak decision provides a good example of theabuse of dominance which Article 86 is designed to control. TetraPak, a Swiss-based company, is the largest supplier of cartons forliquid food (mainly milk and fruit juices). In some of its markets,such as packaging machinery and cartons for long-life products,Tetra Pak has a virtual monopoly with about 95% of the market. In1992, it was fined ECU 75m and required to end the various abusesof its dominant position.

The Commission found against on Tetra Pak on four maingrounds involving almost all aspects of its commercial policy.First, it had a marketing policy aimed at separating nationalmarkets within the EU. Second, its consumer contracts policy wasdesigned to exclude potential competition by imposing exclusivityclauses on customers, for example by requiring that on Tetra Pak

Page 260: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

COMPETITION POLICY IN THE EUROPEAN UNION

243

machines, only Tetra Pak cartons could be used. Third, its pricingpolicy discriminated between member states with differences ofsome 50–100% for cartons and 300–400% for machines. Fourth, itoperated various predatory pricing and other practices aimed ateliminating competitors. For example, in Italy, Tetra Pak’s sale ofcertain types of cartons at a loss forced Elopak, its maincompetitor, to close a new production plant and almost forced itout of the market.

The Commission first applied Article 86 in 1971 and, as Table13.1 shows, there have been comparatively few formal Article 86decisions. In total, 25 were published by the end of 1992. Thiscompares with the 340 formal decisions published in relation toArticle 85 over the same period. As with Article 85, attention givento services has increased with the services sector accounting forabout half of all recent cases.

MERGERS

The Treaty of Rome contained no specific powers to controlmergers, and although both Article 85 (e.g., Philip Morris) andArticle 86 (e.g., Continental Can) had been used to try to controlmergers, the Commission was hampered by the lack of a mergerregulation. It first proposed such a regulation in 1973 but could notgain acceptance from the member states, some of which (notablyBritain and West Germany) already had well-developed mergerpolicies of their own.

In the late 1980s, there was a substantial increase in mergers,acquisitions and joint ventures between firms as they restructuredtheir operations in readiness for the SEM. The increase incrossborder activity was particularly marked and led to theagreement to adopt a European Merger Regulation in December1989. One aim was to reduce the transactions costs large firmscould face in getting approval for cross-border mergers byintroducing a ‘onestop shop’ and eliminating the need to getapproval nationally, often in more than one country, as well as inBrussels. Another was to ensure that the gains from marketintegration were not eroded by defensive mergers whereby firmsattempted to build up market share and protect themselves fromthe increased competitive pressures.

The new regulation, which came into operation in September1990, gives the Commission prime responsibility for controlling

Page 261: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

ELEANOR J.MORGAN

244

mergers involving the very largest firms. The scope of theregulation is defined by the size of turnover and its geographicaldistribution within the Union. It covers mergers and merger-liketransactions where total turnover of all the parties concernedexceeds ECU 5bn and the total Union-wide turnover of each ofthe parties is more than ECU 250m. The ECU 250m figure isdesigned to exclude relatively insignificant transactions where largefirms acquire very small ones. If two-thirds or more of totalUnionwide turnover is within the same member state, the merger isexcluded from the regulation, as it is considered better dealt withnationally. The legislation and regulatory structures of memberstates remain in place and mergers which do not meet the criteriafor EU intervention are dealt with by the relevant nationalauthorities.

Mergers which satisfy the regulation thresholds have to benotified to the Commission and are examined solely by theCommission (subject to limited exceptions which have so far rarelybeen requested). Each case is examined individually in terms of itslikely effects on competition. Investigations are conducted for theCommission by a Mergers Task Force, which was set up for thispurpose. Decisions have to be reached within tight time-scales; afternotification, the Commission has a month to decide whether toopen a full enquiry and if so, a further four months to reach adecision. As with Articles 85 and 86, the Commission has wideremedial powers and can, for example, require divestiture, imposeconditions on the merger and levy fines for breaches of theregulation.

Before the regulation came into force, it was estimated that theCommission would have to examine between 50 and 60 mergers ayear. This estimate has been fairly accurate; in the first three yearsof operation, 178 transactions were notified to the Commission (seeTable 13.2). In view of the strength with which the case for aneffective merger control at Union level had been advocated, it isperhaps surprising how few of the small number of mergers fallingwithin the scope of the regulation were fully investigated. Theapproach to date appears fairly lenient, and the Commission hasbeen prepared to accept undertakings from firms to remove theanti-competitive features of their transactions as a condition forclearance, rather than banning them outright. Of the 178 cases,fourteen went to full proceedings and only one of these has beenbanned (ATR/De Havilland). Three of the mergers which were

Page 262: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

COMPETITION POLICY IN THE EUROPEAN UNION

245

fully investigated were cleared unconditionally and eight have beencleared subject to conditions designed to eliminate aspects of themerger causing concern about the likely effects on competition.

The regulation is based on a competition test and the frameworkwithin which the likely effects are assessed is very similar to that ofArticle 86 (Morgan, 1993). A merger can be prohibited if it createsor strengthens a dominant position which will impair competition inthe EU or a substantial part of it. In the Nestlé/Perrier decision ofJuly 1992, the interpretation of dominance under the regulation wasextended to include structures where no single firm dominates, buta group of firms together have a dominant position and theoligopoly seems likely to act in a coordinated way.

Unlike Article 85(3), the appraisal criteria allows no trade-offbetween competition and other aspects of performance; thedevelopment of technical and economic progress can be taken intoaccount only ‘if it is to the consumer’s advantage and does notform an obstacle to competition’. It was difficult to reachagreement on this aspect of the regulation as the way in whichmergers are assessed in different member states varies, reflectingdifferences of philosophy towards the respective roles ofcompetition and industrial policy considerations. French competitionpolicy allows mergers to be cleared if the anti-competitive effectsare counterbalanced by beneficial effects in terms of the costsavings and effects on technical innovation, for example, but theGerman and British governments, in particular, were concerned that

Table 13.2 Decisions on cases notified under EC merger regulation,September 20, 1990 to September 19, 1993

Source: Commission decisions.

Page 263: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

ELEANOR J.MORGAN

246

the Commission might be tempted to use an efficiency defence as ameans of introducing industrial strategy into decisions—e.g.,attempting to create ‘European champions’ to compete with largeJapanese and American companies—and that competitiveness mightactually suffer rather than improve as a result.

The November 1991 decision to ban the proposed acquisition ofDe Havilland, the Canadian subsidiary of Boeing by ATR, a jointventure between two state-owned companies, Aerospatiale FNI(France) and Alenia Spa (Italy) was particularly contentious andtested the Commission’s resolve to apply a strict competitionyardstick in the assessment of mergers. The acquisition wasprohibited because it would create a dominant position in theturbo-prop aircraft market, with adverse effects on competition inthe EU. The Italian and French governments, in particular,demanded a re-examination of the case, claiming that the analysiswas flawed and the Commission had taken insufficient account ofthe need to build up the European aerospace industry. TheCommission refused, stating that any appeal should be made to theEuropean Court of Justice. The membership of the Commissionwas split on the decision and it is reported that the prohibition ofthe merger was based on a majority of only one vote and that thedecision owed much to the strong line taken by Sir Leon Brittan.Following the ban on ATR/De Havilland, it remains to be seenwhether the Commission will resist calls for a more broadly basedanalysis of mergers, taking into account considerations other thanthose solely concerned with competition effects.

Beside the standard of assessment to be applied, anotherstumbling-block in the original negotiations was over the size ofmergers to be included within the scope of the regulation. TheCommission only accepted the high thresholds to gain approval andprovision was made in the regulation for the thresholds to bereviewed by December 1993. The Commission proposed that whenthe thresholds were reviewed, the scope of the regulation should beextended by reducing the aggregate turnover thresholds from ECU5bn to ECU 2bn and the Union-wide turnover threshold from ECU250m to ECU 100m.

Thresholds based on size are bound to be arbitrary and,wherever they are set, some mergers with effects going beyond asingle country will be excluded and mergers with effects in onlyone member state will be included. There are a number ofinstances of recent mergers which appear to raise possible

Page 264: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

COMPETITION POLICY IN THE EUROPEAN UNION

247

competition concerns at EU level, but which were not subject toUnion control because of their failure to satisfy the thresholds forinvestigation. For example, Reed (Britain) and Elsevier (theNetherlands) merged their activities in the publishing industry in1992 to form the largest publishing group in the Union and thesecond largest in the world, yet escaped scrutiny under theregulation because their combined world turnover was less thanECU 5bn. The merger of Hoesch and Krupp to create one of thelargest steel producers in the world was outside EU control becauseboth of the parties had more than two-thirds of their turnover inGermany. Instead, the national competition authorities had to beconsulted in Germany, France, Ireland and Belgium.

Any lowering of the size thresholds and, particularly, anylowering or abolition of the two-thirds rule would be bound toincrease the number of purely national mergers falling within themerger regulation. One way of dealing with this would be to have amore liberal policy of referral back to the member states and thishas already been proposed. Many member states are now betterequipped to deal with mergers nationally, having recently introducedmerger controls of their own. However, more liberal referral wouldbe at the cost of detracting further from the ‘one-stop shop’principle on which the regulation was intended to be based.

Recent unease about the centralisation of power in Brussels, aswell as the substance of some of the merger decisions (e.g., ATR/De Havilland) meant that the Commission’s attempt to widen thescope of the regulation in 1993 was strongly resisted, especially bythe French, German and British competition authorities. Someindustry representatives were also concerned that any significantincrease in the workload of the Commission in this area wouldreduce the speed of decision-making and possibly divert resourcesfrom other parts of EU competition policy where there is already asubstantial backlog of cases.

REGULATED INDUSTRIES

In recent years, major new initiatives in the application of existingcompetition law have been taken in policy towards ‘regulated’enterprises. There are a number of important fields of activitywhere member states have traditionally granted special or exclusiverights, essentially giving monopoly positions to enterprises providingbasic or essential services. Energy, post and telecommunications are

Page 265: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

ELEANOR J.MORGAN

248

the major examples, although similar rights often exist in railwaysand other transport facilities, broadcasting and financial services.Along with the special rights, the ownership of these sectors hasoften been partially or wholly nationalised.

A number of countries, most notably Britain, have recently takensteps to privatise the ownership of some of these industries and atthe same time to liberalise their provision. The Treaty of Romedoes not regulate the system of ownership, but Article 90 isdesigned to ensure that public enterprises and state monopoliesoperate in accordance with EU competition rules. Article 90(1) ofthe Treaty of Rome states that competition law is to apply topublic undertakings and to undertakings to which member statesgrant special or exclusive rights. According to Article 90(2), thesame goes for enterprises which provide services of generaleconomic interest as long as the application of these rules does nothinder them from carrying out the particular tasks assigned tothem. Even then, ‘the development of trade must not be affectedto such an extent as would be contrary to the interests of theUnion’. Article 90(3) allows the Commission to lay down generalrules (‘directives’) setting out the obligations of member states withregard to such undertakings and to require compliance by memberstates if a particular national measure is found incompatible withthe competition rules.

Article 90 was not used by the Commission until 1985. Itsprevious interpretation of Article 90 was in favour of grantingmonopoly rights on the basis that this was the best way ofproviding goods and services to all consumers on an equal basis,especially in utilities which tend to be ‘natural monopolies’. It didnot require member states to prove that their exemption fromcompetition rules was necessary for them to perform their tasks.

Commission policy has become much more active in this arealargely as a result of efforts to move towards a single market inpreviously regulated service sectors. The need for member states togrant exclusive rights is being closely scrutinised. It is now arguedthat by dividing the market on national lines, such rights not onlylimit the scope for domestic competition and facilitate the abuse ofthe dominant positions, but are also in conflict with the right offreedom of establishment and the right to provide services acrossall member states which are among the fundamental principlesunderlying the EU.

As well as trying to ensure that any monopoly or exclusive right

Page 266: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

COMPETITION POLICY IN THE EUROPEAN UNION

249

is defined as narrowly as possible (compatible with providing thenecessary services), more radical alternatives to state-fundedmonopolies are currently being considered at EU level as well as insome member states. First, the implications of changes intechnology are being examined to see if the original reason forgranting a monopoly still holds or whether supply conditions havechanged as a result of technical change or the removal of tradebarriers so that the industry no longer has the features of a naturalmonopoly. Second, if monopoly provision is regarded as necessarybecause of the characteristics of the service, alternatives topermanently granting a monopoly position which might be lessdetrimental to competition are being investigated. For example, onepossibility is that firms can compete for the right to offer theservice, perhaps with a direct subsidy as part of the contract toensure services are provided on reasonable terms to all customers.

Markets are being liberalised through the removal of exclusiverights in a number of ways. Some countries are taking the initiativein altering their own national policies, but Article 90 is the mainpolicy instrument at EU level. Article 90 is most frequently used todeal with individual cases in individual countries, in particular inpostal services (e.g., the Netherlands) and air transport (e.g., inGermany). However, perhaps the best known application of Article90 is in the telecommunications sector across the EU.

The market for terminals equipment (e.g., telephones and faxmachines) was opened up by an Article 90 directive in 1990 sothat purchasers would not be dependent on the monopolytelephone suppliers for these ancillary services. In 1991, anotherdirective introduced competition in telecommunications providingfor the abolition of exclusive rights for all telecommunicationsservices other than satellite and mobile communications (the latterwas already liberalised in most EU countries) and voice telephony.Telephone calls, which account for the majority of services, werenot included in the original liberalisation measures because it wasargued that a national monopoly was regarded as important togenerate sufficient revenue to allow a universal service to bemaintained. This is now being reassessed as technical changemeans that several competing networks can now coexist and thelarge price differences between member countries imply that theintroduction of competition might reduce prices to the benefit ofconsumers.

Liberalisation of the voice telephony market is likely to be

Page 267: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

ELEANOR J.MORGAN

250

strongly resisted. The Commission’s power to adopt the two Article90(3) telecommunications directives was highly controversial andchallenged by several member states. They argued that Article 90only gives the Commission powers to oversee existing rules underthe Treaty of Rome, not to take a proactive stance in breaking upmonopolies. The decision of the European Court of Justice inNovember 1992 confirmed the Commission’s powers, but althoughthe decision could be seen as giving the Commission the ‘greenlight’ to continue using Article 90 in this way, the level ofresistance from the individual member states makes it likely that thespeed of liberalisation itself will be slowed down for politicalreasons.

STATE AIDS

Until recently, the Commission’s reluctance to conflict openly withthe governments of member states has also constrained its use ofArticle 92 of the Treaty of Rome. This deals with the various typesof assistance national governments may give to their domestic firmswhich affect trade between member states.

Subsidies (‘state aids’) which distort competition by favouringcertain enterprises and giving them an artificial advantage areconsidered incompatible with the common market, and theCommission can require such aid to be abolished or modified. Ifthe government responsible does not comply, the matter can betaken to the Court of Justice. Difficulties in enforcing controls onstate aid have not been uncommon. Investigation of aids is alsodifficult as the Commission does not have the same sweepinginvestigatory powers as under Articles 85 and 86 and has to rely oncooperation from member states.

Article 92 condemns all state aids which distort competition.There are, however, large areas which are either exempted or maybe considered in the common interest despite the harmful effect oncompetition because of their contribution to economic growth, tostructural adjustment and to encouraging development in poorerregions. Examples of aids allowed on these grounds includeregional aids, support for research and development and for stafftraining, development aid for SMEs and aid to help export to thirdcountries.

There is a considerable temptation for individual states to usesubsidies as a means of protecting domestic industry, especially in

Page 268: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

COMPETITION POLICY IN THE EUROPEAN UNION

251

recessions. This pressure has increased as the tariff and othernontariff barriers (NTBs) to intra-Union trade have beenprogressively dismantled and competition from the newly-industrialising countries has intensified. Member states have beeningenious in exploiting the available exemptions and introducingnew types of aid schemes.

Initially the controls over state aids were not rigorously applied.In the 1970s, recession and the addition of new Union membersresulted in a proliferation of aids. The first survey of state aidsacross the member states which was published in 1989 revealed theextent of state support to industry. According to the report:

in 1986, the volume of state aids…amounted to ECU 93bn or3% of gross domestic product (GDP) and represents anaverage of 9% of public expenditure. In the manufacturingsector, state aids represent over 6% of value added andamount to ECU 49bn…. In most member states, expenditureon aids exceeds the corporate taxes paid by companies.

(EC Commission, 1989a) Evidence about the high level of industrial subsidies, especially inthe relatively prosperous regions of the Union, and the drive tocomplete the SEM encouraged the Commission to apply theexisting Article 92 provisions more comprehensively and strictly andto require more information about their aid schemes from memberstates. Recognising that the mix of public and private companiesdiffers in each member state, the application of the rules has beenextended to public enterprises to control the subsidies they receiveand ensure that they compete on more equal terms with privateoperators. In addition, since 1990, aid schemes already in existenceare being reviewed as well as new notifications.

In 1983, the Commission warned that the repayment of illegalaid could be required. The implementation of this policy hasrecently led to a number of well-publicised confrontations withnational governments, especially in the case of aid to the motorindustry. The challenge to a debt write-off granted to Renault inFrance (1990) led to eventual agreement that Renault should repayor start paying interest on FFr6bn, half the sum originallydemanded by the Commission, after Renault agreed to certainconditions. In the case of Rover in Britain, £44.4m had been paidto British Aerospace by the British government in addition to the

Page 269: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

ELEANOR J.MORGAN

252

approved sum as a ‘sweetener’ after it acquired Rover in May 1988.After lengthy proceedings, it was finally agreed in March 1993 thatthis sum should be fully repaid, including the repayment of interestof some £13m.

Partly as a result of these various initiatives to apply state aidpolicy more strictly, the level of aid notifications rose markedly to326 in 1987, 429 in 1990 and 459 in 1992. According to theCommission, this reflects the increased efficiency of Union policyin controlling aids. However, as a higher percentage of the casesconsidered under Article 92 are being allowed than previously, thenumber of cases regarded as incompatible with the common markethas not risen so significantly.

The third survey of state aids (EC Commission, 1992a) providesdata for 1989 and 1990 and shows that although spending hasdecreased slightly, the overall level is still high. It averaged ECU89bn in the period 1988–90, excluding aid given to easternGermany. Control of aid to the former GDR and extending theapplication of the competition rules is, of course, one of the majortasks now facing the Commission. Of the ECU 89bn of total aid,40% went to manufacturing, transport received 29%, coal 18% andagriculture and fisheries received 13%. Steel and shipbuilding arethe main recipients in the manufacturing sector.

The negotiations for the reduction of subsidies in the steelindustry concluded towards the end of 1993 provide a goodillustration of the problems the Commission faces in controllingstate aid to specific sectors in recession. A ‘crisis’ cartel was allowedin the steel industry under Article 85 as a means of achieving aplanned reduction in capacity. The Commission can requireproduction quotas and capacity cutbacks, but rationalisation planshave often been thwarted by national government subsidies. Thelogic of competition policy is that ‘lame duck’ enterprises which areotherwise uncompetitive should not be allowed to receive subsidyon a continuing basis. However, pressure from individual memberstates to continue state aids in steel as elsewhere has been hard toresist.

CONCLUSIONS

The framework of existing EU competition policy was laid down inthe Treaty of Rome and the aims have remained much the same asthey were when the Union was first founded in 1958. Since the

Page 270: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

COMPETITION POLICY IN THE EUROPEAN UNION

253

mid-1980s, the existing rules have been applied more vigorously,especially in the control of aid, to help create and protect faircompetition in the emerging SEM. The application of theCommission’s powers has been extended to areas such astelecommunications, energy, transport and financial services, whichwere previously little affected by EU competition policy, as part ofthe drive to complete the internal market in services. In addition,the introduction of a merger regulation in late 1990 has givenimportant new powers to regulate the build-up of uncompetitivemarket structures.

As the application of EU competition policy has intensified andits scope increased, it has also become more controversial. Twoaspects of the debate which surrounds its operation have becomeparticularly prominent recently. The first concerns the objectives ofpolicy, particularly the part that the promotion of competition canplay in ensuring international competitiveness (see, for example,Hughes, 1992). The second concerns the division of responsibilityfor competition policy between member states, the EU and morewidely in the post-Maastricht era, an issue which is usefullyexplored in Gatsios and Seabright (1993).

It is generally agreed that EU competition policy is necessary tosecure the benefits of European integration but there is an ongoingcontroversy about whether encouraging competition in the EU isthe best means of ensuring that Europe is competitive ininternational markets. This is a source of continuing tension in theapplication of policy. A concern for the competitiveness of industryis built into the possibilities for exemption in Article 85, forexample, but each of the annual competition reports published bythe Commission stresses the paramount importance of competition.In the run up to the SEM, Sir Leon Brittan (the Commissionerresponsible for competition policy between 1989 and 1992), stronglychampioned the cause of competition, as illustrated in ATR/DeHavilland. However, others, both inside and outside theCommission, would prefer a more sympathetic approach to anti-competitive strategies and such pressures have become strongerwith the general slowing of economic growth in the Union. TheCompetition Commissioner has considerable discretion in theapplication of the competition rules, so much will depend on theapproach of the current Commissioner, Mr Van Miert, and whetherhe will continue to adopt the tough stance of his predecessor. Earlyindications suggest that this is unlikely (Hill, 1993).

Page 271: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

ELEANOR J.MORGAN

254

As EU competition policy has become increasingly assertive,relationships with member states have become moreconfrontational. The recent vigorous policy towards publicundertakings and state aid has been strongly resisted nationally.There has been much debate about the appropriate division ofjurisdiction over competition policy within the EU as well as howthe powers are applied. This is particularly acute in the case of themerger regulation which gives the Commission exclusive powers(subject to referral back to member states at its discretion) overmergers within the thresholds for investigation. This is in contrastto restrictive agreements and monopolies, for example, where theCommission has jurisdiction if there is an appreciable effect ontrade between member states but the national authorities can alsoinvestigate and act in such cases. The backlog of cases at theCommission, which have resulted in lengthy delays, and the formaladoption of the principle of ‘subsidiarity’ at Maastricht, haveencouraged the Commission to work more closely with the nationalcourts in the application of Articles 85 and 86. However, self-policing of state aids and privileges enjoyed in public undertakingsby the national authorities is unlikely to be successful, so anydevolution of responsibility is unlikely here.

This chapter has focused on the development of EUcompetition policy in the context of the SEM. It must not beforgotten that many types of agreement and anti-competitivebehaviour still only have effects in one country or even a regionalsub-market. In parallel with the development of European policy, anumber of member states (e.g., Belgium, Ireland, Italy and Portugal)have introduced new competition laws to fill previous gaps. Thismeans that there is now a more adequate machinery to cope withpurely domestic cases nationally than there was before.

At the other end of the spectrum, as business globalises andmarkets extend beyond EU borders, behaviour by firms andgovernments outside the Union which affects the prospects of EUbusinesses is increasingly a matter of concern (see Healey, 1991c).For the future, it seems likely that policymakers will put greateremphasis on trying to secure a more ‘level playing field’ forbusiness at international level, whether by bilateral agreements (asrecently concluded with the United States), regional agreements (aswith the EFTA countries in the 1992 European Economic AreaAgreement) or multinationally (through GATT, for example).

Page 272: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

255

14

THE REGIONAL POLICY OFTHE EUROPEAN UNION

Harvey Armstrong

INTRODUCTION

The final ratification of the Treaty on European Union, orMaastricht Treaty (Council of Ministers 1992), in 1993 representedan important step towards full integration. The economic andmonetary union (EMU) provisions of the Maastricht Treaty willhave far-reaching effects on regional disparities within the EU,particularly as they will be superimposed upon the effects of thesingle European market (SEM), most of which have yet to be fullyexperienced (see Chapters 7 and 8).

With these considerations in mind, the EU has introduced anew package of regional policy reforms and has agreed a series ofchanges to the financing of EU regional policy for the period1994–99 (EC Commission, 1993). These reforms have beendeliberately designed to coincide with the implementation of theMaastricht Treaty. They represent an attempt to build upon anearlier major reform package introduced in 1989, which wasdesigned to accompany the SEM process (EC Commission,1989b).

This chapter examines the 1994–99 EU regional policy. Thefollowing section begins with an examination of the growthprocesses which lie at the heart of Europe’s distinctive pattern ofregional disparities. This is followed by a discussion of theimportance of regional policy for the attainment of economic andsocial cohesion in the EU. The particular regional effects of theSEM and EMU are considered. The 1994–99 EU regional policy isthen set out and appraised in the final section.

Page 273: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

HARVEY ARMSTRONG

256

THE REGIONAL GROWTH PROCESS IN THE EU:CONVERGENCE OR DIVERGENCE?

One of the most important, and as yet unresolved, controversies iswhether growth and economic integration in the EU leads to anarrowing of regional disparities (‘convergence’) or a widening(cumulative growth or ‘divergence’). Those favouring a convergenceview of regional disparities have drawn their arguments fromneoclassical economic theory. Neoclassical models have a longhistory in economics (Borts, 1960; Borts and Stein, 1964) and haveevolved into the more sophisticated ‘catch-up’ models in use at thepresent time (Barro and Sala-i-Martin, 1991, 1992). In neoclassicalconvergence theories of regional growth, the main equilibratingmechanisms are:

1 labour migration and capital mobility—regions with lower percapita income levels will automatically shed labour throughoutmigration and attract capital inflows seeking to exploit thehigher returns available in regions with lower labour costs.These factor flows will continue until returns to both labourand capital are equalised;

2 technology diffusion—regions with a technological head-startfind that the knowledge spreads rapidly to the lagging regions;

3 capital accumulation—regions with higher productivity and percapita income levels find further growth more difficult ascapital accumulation inevitably runs into diminishing returns.Regions starting from a lower base do not face thisdisadvantage and, as a result, will grow faster. This is the keyequilibrating process in neoclassical growth models; and

4 free trade—which allows regions to concentrate on those goodsand services in which they have a comparative advantage. If,for example, a region has surplus labour, then it willconcentrate on goods which intensively use the labour available.The resulting surge in exports will reduce unemployment andincrease incomes.

Views of the growth process as a cumulative one in western Europealso have a long pedigree. A series of alternative cumulative growththeories have, however, evolved over time, the main ones being:

1 cumulative growth models of Myrdal (1957) and Hirschman(1958). These models distinguish between a series of forces,

Page 274: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

REGIONAL POLICY OF THE EUROPEAN UNION

257

some of which cause divergence (i.e., ‘backwash effects’) andsome of which cause convergence (i.e., ‘spread’ or ‘trickle-down’ effects). If the former predominate, cumulative growthwill result and regional disparities will widen. In an EU context,this can occur if the central regions having initial advantages inthe form of lower assembly and distribution costs andproximity to the richest markets, build on their head-start byexploiting plant economies of scale, external and agglomerationeconomies (e.g., skilled labour pools, transport and businessfacilities, etc.). These backwash effects are then reinforced byinward migration of the youngest and most skilled members ofthe workforces of the peripheral regions. Any spread effects(e.g., higher congestion costs, land and labour costs in thecentral regions tending to encourage firms to leave) may beoverwhelmed by the backwash effects;

2 growth pole theory of Perroux (1950). This stresses the role ofkey (i.e., propulsive) manufacturing industries. These draw otheractivities towards themselves through a combination of input-output links to ‘upstream’ activities (e.g., steel fabricators usingthe output of iron and steel works) and also ‘downstream’activities (e.g., components and equipment suppliers). Localdemand multiplier effects reinforce this process; and

3 modern cumulative growth theories. These include those ofKaldor (1970) and Dixon and Thirlwall (1975) which stress therole of Verdoorn’s Law, in which regions with a head-start reapadditional productivity gains through scale economies andspecialisation of production. More recently, new growtheconomics has pointed to technological change and skillsacquisition as a key cause of cumulative growth (see Crafts,1992, for a survey).

With supporters of convergence and divergence theories atloggerheads, it is not surprising that attention has switched to theanalysis of actual regional disparities within the EU. As Figure 14.1shows, the EU exhibits a pronounced core—periphery pattern inregional GDP per capita disparities. The more prosperous regionslie close to the centre of the EU. Patterns of regionalunemployment rate disparities and other indicators such as netmigration rates also bear out the broad core-periphery nature ofEU regional disparities (see EC Commission, 1991a, 1991c, 1992b).

Further support for those favouring a cumulative view of EU

Page 275: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

Figu

re 1

4.1

GD

P pe

r ca

pita

in

EU

reg

ions

in

1990

(E

U=

100)

Sour

ce: E

uros

tat

(199

3) R

apid

Rep

orts:

Regi

ons

1993

(1),

Luxe

mbo

urg.

Page 276: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

REGIONAL POLICY OF THE EUROPEAN UNION

259

regional disparities is provided by international comparisons ofregional disparities. EU disparities are very wide by internationalstandards. Regional disparities in per capita gross domesticproduct (GDP), for example, are over twice as large in the EU asin the United States (EC Commission, 1991c; OECD, 1989).Comparisons with other countries produces even starker contrasts(OECD, 1989).

While the existing pattern of regional disparities within the EUsuggests that forces in the past may have systematically favouredthe more central regions, this does not necessarily mean thatcurrent growth is cumulative. If the poorer peripheral regions arecatching up with the more prosperous core of the EU, but theprocess is a slow one, then the neoclassical explanation may becompatible with the evidence of Figure 14.1. Analysis of percapita GDP data for the period 1950–90 suggests that a processof very slow convergence over time in regional disparities seemsto be occurring. The best evidence currently available suggeststhat the regional inequality gap appears to be closing within theEU at approximately 2% per annum (Barro and Sala-i-Martin,1991). Some idea of just how slow the convergence process is canbe seen from Barro and Sala-i-Martin’s estimate that at this rate itwould take eastern Germany 35 years to halve its per capitaincome gap with western Germany in the absence of governmentintervention.

In summary, the debate on whether EU regional growth isconvergent or divergent remains a finely balanced one. The bestavailable evidence suggests that an extremely slow process ofconvergence is under way, but with wide disparities remaining.Whether the convergence process will continue in the futuredepends in part on the regional impact of EU integration,particularly the SEM and EMU. It is to these that attention is nowturned.

ECONOMIC AND SOCIAL COHESION AND EUREGIONAL POLICY

The fact that convergence appears to be taking place within the EUleaves no room for complacency. As we have seen, the process is anextremely sluggish one. This in itself constitutes a strong case forintervention in the form of an EU regional policy as a means of‘speeding’ matters along.

Page 277: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

HARVEY ARMSTRONG

260

In addition, the EU is in the middle of two programmesdesigned to greatly improve economic integration—the SEM andEMU. The SEM, in the form of legislation phased in between 1989and 1993, is designed to create a genuine single market for goods,services, labour and capital in Europe. Its principal targets are themany non-tariff barriers (NTBs) which still exist within the EU(Emerson, 1988). Prime candidates picked out by the SEMlegislation are technical and safety standards in different countrieswhich are frequently used as an excuse to block imports, thedeliberate bias of member state governments in placing governmentcontracts with local firms (‘public procurement’), internal frontierformalities and a whole raft of barriers to trade in services (e.g.,banking and insurance). While the legislative programme of theSEM has gone well and is largely now in place, the full economiceffects will take many years to work their way through theEuropean economy, even with the active steps being undertaken bythe EU in the wake of a special committee (the SutherlandCommittee) designed to push matters along (see Chapter 7).

Alongside the profound economic changes being introduced asthe SEM takes effect is another major step forward in economicintegration, namely EMU. While the initial Maastricht Treatytimetable for attaining monetary union now seems optimistic, theratification of the Treaty does mean that in the years to come aslow process of further integration in the EU will be set in motionwith a single currency as a final outcome (see Chapters 4–6).

Each successive strengthening of economic integration in Europebrings with it far-reaching structural changes to EU industry. Inorder to reap the benefits of additional trade in the form of lowerprices for consumers, more jobs and more competitive Europeanindustries, it is necessary that a process of large-scale reorganisationtakes place. Indeed, the faster the process of restructuring ofEuropean industry, the quicker will the benefits of integration berealised. As trade becomes freer, industries in some regions willdecline, while other industries will expand. Industrial concentrationis likely and considerable movement of labour and capital betweenindustries and regions is necessary if the gains from freer trade areto be realised. EU regional policy can be seen as a vital adjunct tothe SEM and EMU programmes. It can be used to help to speedup the structural changes which accompany them and it can beused to ameliorate the problems of industrial decline andunemployment which inevitably surface as restructuring occurs.

Page 278: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

REGIONAL POLICY OF THE EUROPEAN UNION

261

The case for an EU regional policy to accompany SEM andEMU is reinforced by the fact that no two ‘rounds’ in the processof EU integration ever have the same regional impact. Take theSEM process, for example. Some industries are more affected byNTBs such as technical and safety standards than others (e.g., foodprocessing, telecommunications). Removing the barriers willtherefore affect these industries (and hence the regions where theyare concentrated) more than others. Some 40 manufacturingindustries and a number of key service sectors are thought likely tobe the ones eventually most affected by SEM (see EC Commission,1990c; Booz Allen and Hamilton, 1989; PA Cambridge EconomicConsultants, 1989). EMU too will have its own distinctive regionalimpact across the EU (Emerson, 1992).

In view of the likely regional restructuring effects accompanyingSEM and EMU, it is not surprising that the EU has stepped up itsregional policy effort since the SEM programme began in 1989, andhas chosen to step it up again in the aftermath of the MaastrichtTreaty (see below). The EU has placed great emphasis ondeveloping a stronger regional policy in order to attain economicand social cohesion. Article 130A of the Maastricht Treaty sets outthis goal as follows:

In order to promote its overall harmonious development, theCommunity shall develop and pursue its action leading to thestrengthening of its economic and social cohesion. Inparticular the Community shall aim at reducing the disparitiesbetween the various regions and the backwardness of the leastfavoured regions, including the rural areas.

(Council of Ministers, 1992) While it is possible to argue that the precise meaning of ‘cohesion’has not been spelled out adequately and is therefore open tointerpretation (European Parliament, 1991), its importance for thefuture of the EU is not in doubt.

EU REGIONAL POLICY: THE STRUCTURALFUNDS

The structural funds lie at the heart of EU regional policy. Theycomprise the European Regional Development Fund (ERDF),the European Social Fund (ESF) and the Guidance Section of

Page 279: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

HARVEY ARMSTRONG

262

the European Agricultural Guidance and Guarantee Fund(EAGGF). The 1993 reforms to the structural funds weretriggered by the need to increase the financial resources availablefor regional policy in the aftermath of the Maastricht Treaty, andby a desire to finetune the regional policy which had been set inplace in 1989 at the t ime of the SEM legis lat ion (ECCommission, 1989b). The 1989 legislation formed by far themost impor tant piece of regional pol icy legis la t ion everintroduced by the EU and laid the foundations of the regionalpolicy which we see today.

The three structural funds have, since 1989, been required to actin a closely coordinated manner even though each plays are ratherdifferent role. The ERDF is designed to provide help principally forindustrial and infrastructure projects in the disadvantaged regions. Aswith the other two structural funds, assistance is in the form ofgrants. Help is by no means confined to manufacturing industries.Many service sectors (e.g., tourism) are also assisted. Since the 1980sthere has been a much greater emphasis on helping small andmedium-sized enterprises and innovating sectors. The ESFconcentrates on what in Britain would be called employment policy.Help is targeted on schemes for training and retraining, helpingunemployed persons back into work, and on reducing labour marketdiscrimination (e.g., against women and disabled workforce members).Although not strictly a ‘regional’ fund, the ESF by virtue of the typeof help it gives inevitably operates with a bias towards the moredisadvantaged regions of the EU. Indeed, under the 1989 and 1993regulations the ESF is required to operate with a deliberate regionalbias. The EAGGF Guidance Section is designed to be an instrumentfor restructuring the farming sector (e.g., new investment in farmingand agri-businesses, land consolidation, etc.), and is also used to tryto stimulate new firms in the non-farm sectors of the rural economy.As the traditionally dominant Guarantee Section (used to pay for theEU’s price support policy) is reined in, the Guidance Section isgradually becoming more important.

Table 14.1 sets out the five common objectives of the structuralfunds for the period 1994–99. Table 14.1 also shows the variousstructural funds responsible for tackling each objective. As can beseen from the table, only three of the objectives are explicitlyregional policy objectives in the sense that they involve the ERDF.These are Objective 1 (‘lagging regions’), Objective 2 (‘regionsaffected by industrial decline’) and Objective 5b (‘rural areas’). It is

Page 280: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

REGIONAL POLICY OF THE EUROPEAN UNION

263

the three ‘regional’ objectives on which this section will focus. Itshould be noted, however, that although the other objectives arenon-regional in the sense that all parts of the EU are eligible forhelp under them, the nature of the objectives (e.g., help for the

Table 14.1 The five priority objectives of the EU’s structural funds,1994–99

Notes:1. ERDF=European Regional Development Fund; ESF=European Social

Fund; EAGGF (Gu)=European Agricultural Guidance and GuaranteeFund, Guidance Section; FIFG=Financial Instrument for FisheriesGuidance.

2. The Financial Instrument for Fisheries Guidance (FIFG) is a newinstrument created in 1993 to group the funds available to tackle theserious problems being faced by communities dependent on fishingand aquaculture. The 1993 regulations chose to follow this routerather than creating a separate priority objective solely concerned withthe fisheries and aquaculture sector (for which there had been intenselobbying prior to the 1993 reforms).

Source: EC Commission (1993).

Page 281: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

HARVEY ARMSTRONG

264

long-term unemployed) means that they inevitably result in aregional bias in operations designed to tackle them.

In orchestrating its attempts to meet the priority objectiveswhich it has set itself, the EU has devised a regional policy whichembodies four key principles: 1 concentration of help where it is most needed;2 partnership between the EU and other participants (e.g.,

member states, regional and local authorities);3 the careful programming of help (effectively a system of regional

planning);

Figure 14.2 Regions eligible under Objective 1 of the EU’s structuralfunds, 1994–99Note: The Objective 1 regions are those whose development is laggingbehind that of the rest of the EU. Source: EC Commission (1993).

Page 282: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

REGIONAL POLICY OF THE EUROPEAN UNION

265

4 stress on the principle of ‘additionally’ (i.e., the use of EUfunds as a complement to member state money and not as asubstitute).

Concentration of policy assistance

The need to target help where it is most needed is an obvious one.EU regional policy has several mechanisms for concentratingfinancial help on the most disadvantaged regions. The firstmechanism involves limiting the areas eligible for help. Figure 14.2sets out the regions of the EU eligible for help under Objective 1(the lagging regions). These are supposed to be limited to regionswith GDP per capita levels under 75% of the EU average. Inpractice, special reasons are also used to justify an extension toother areas (e.g., Northern Ireland, Merseyside). A worrying featureof Figure 14.2 is the way in which the Objective 1 regions haveexpanded from the 21.7% of the EU’s population covered by theareas between 1989 and 1993, to the 26.6% designated for theperiod 1994–99. Any laxity in the targeting of Objective 1 money isparticularly worrying given that some 70% of all structural fundexpenditure is earmarked for Objective 1 (a figure rising to 80% ofthe total when the ERDF alone is considered).

Figure 14.3 shows the map of Objective 2 (‘industrial decline’)and Objective 5b (‘rural areas’) regions, as well as Objective 1. TheObjective 2 regions are initially for a three-year period (1994–96),after which further revisions are possible. Objective 5b regions arefor the full budget period 1994–99, as are the Objective 1 regionsshown in Figure 14.2. The Objective 2 and 5b regions are based onvery different criteria to those of Objective 1 regions. TheObjective 2 regions are designated using data on unemploymentrates and employment in declining sectors. Special considerationshave been brought in to handle West Berlin and the fisheriesareas—communities for which there is currently a heightenedconcern. The Objective 2 regions encompass 16.8% of the EUpopulation. Objective 5b regions (encompassing 8.2% of the EUpopulation) are designated using a combination of criteria, includingthe level of economic development, the level of employment inagriculture, agricultural incomes and measures of depopulation.Again, as with the Objective 2 regions, special provision is made toidentify areas where the decline of fishing is having an effect.

Simply controlling the designation of maps of assisted areas is

Page 283: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

Figu

re 1

4.3

Regi

ons

elig

ible

for

the

str

uctu

ral

fund

s, 19

94–9

9So

urce:

Com

miss

ion

of t

he E

urop

ean

Com

mun

ities

.

Page 284: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

REGIONAL POLICY OF THE EUROPEAN UNION

267

not, in itself sufficient to ensure that the bulk of the money goesto the worst affected regions of the EU. Three other mechanismsare used to concentrate structural funds’ spending: 1 the deliberate earmarking of the bulk of EU structural fund

money for the Objective 1 regions. Table 14.2 sets out thesituation which has prevailed between 1989 and 1993, togetherwith the EU’s plans for the 1994–99 budget period. As can beseen, there has been a huge increase in the overall size of theresources devoted to the structural funds. This reflects the EU’sconcern for the regional implications of the SEM and EMU.The process of concentration of money is encouraged bydeliberately earmarking money for the very poor Objective 1regions (e.g., 80% of ERDF allocations between 1989 and1993, and no less than 70% of all structural funds spendingbetween 1994 and 1999);

2 the Commission makes indicative allocations for each objectiveand for each member state. These are best interpreted as targetsfor the country-by-country breakdown of spending under eachobjective. These indicative allocations are deliberately ‘indicative’and are not rigid country quotas. That is, their attainmentdepends in part on the quality of the applications for helpcoming to the EU from the member states. Careful manipulationof these indicative allocations does, however, allow the EU somecontrol on where the money is eventually spent and is thereforepart of the targeting process; and

3 the targeting of money on the most disadvantaged regions canalso be controlled to a limited extent by detailed day-to-daydecisions by the Commission on which schemes put forward bythe member states to give approval to. The EU also has a sumof money set aside for initiatives of its own (called CommunityInitiatives) and for which very flexible targeting rules apply.

Partnership and programming

The EU is not content to simply pay over the money from itsstructural funds to the member states. In involving itself in theimplementation of its regional policy, however, the EU has aserious problem in that it does not have an established civil serviceat member state, regional and local level. The EU therefore has nochoice but to work closely in partnership with the member state

Page 285: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

HARVEY ARMSTRONG

268

governments and to use the bureaucracy of the member states asthe ‘delivery system’ for regional assistance. There are two otherreasons for the EU’s emphasis on a partnership approach toregional policy. First, the EU is committed to ‘subsidiarity’; that is,wherever possible, powers are decentralised within the EU. If theEU wishes to be involved in regional policy, therefore, it musttolerate an active role by the member states, regional governmentsand local authorities. Second, the EU can play an important role asa coordinator, bringing together all of the organisations andgovernments trying to regenerate industry in the depressed regions.

In encouraging a partnership approach to its regional policy theEU has not been content to deal only with the member state

Table 14.2 EU commitments for structural fund operations, 1989–99

Note: The Cohesion Fund is not strictly one of the structural funds, buthas been introduced as part of the broader financial packageaccompanying the 1993 reforms.

Page 286: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

REGIONAL POLICY OF THE EUROPEAN UNION

269

governments. It has tried to involve regional and local organisations,too, at all stages. This has not always been popular with memberstate governments, particularly in countries such as Britain wherethe central government is all-powerful. Most notably of all, the EUhas encouraged partnership by developing a distinctive system ofregional planning (or ‘programming’) which is designed to involveregional and local participants as well as the member stategovernments. As well as ensuring a good mix of partners, theprogramming system is the key instrument for trying to get thevarious participants to coordinate activities. Money from thestructural funds is used as an inducement to closer coordination.For 1994–99, the programming system is essentially a four-stageone: 1 stage one—member states, together with regional and local

partners, draw up detailed regional development plans. The bestdesigned of these plans will contain an analysis of the problem,clear quantified goals, an indicative financial table showing howeach partner (including the EU) will contribute, and the mainthrust of the regional strategy. These plans are supposed todove-tail with the EU’s own analysis of the regional situation(see EC Commission, 1991c, for an example) and the EU’sstated regional policy guidelines;

2 stage two—after considering the regional development plans,the EU responds, in consultation with the member state, with aCommunity Support Framework (CSF) or Single ProgrammingDocument (SPD). This sets out the EU’s priorities and theamount and manner of its structural fund help for the 1994–99period. Care is taken to tie in the EU’s help closely with thatoffered by the member state and the other participants;

3 stage three—the implementation of the jointly agreedprogrammes of help is normally left in the hands of themember state governments and the other regional and localorganisations involved. EU money can be used in a hugevariety of flexible ways. These range from direct grants tofirms for investment to advisory services and infrastructureprovision. The vast bulk of the aid is channelled throughOperational Programmes (OPs). These are detailed regional andsub-regional schemes. Each is designed to run for several years(usually on a renewable basis), with clear local goals, drawing in

Page 287: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

HARVEY ARMSTRONG

270

a range of public and private partners and using coordinatedpackages of different types of help; and

4 stage four—the programmes of assistance are subject to aprocess of continuing monitoring and evaluation. The planningprocess is therefore a continuing, iterative one. At each newround, the results of the monitoring and evaluation are used todesign improvements to the programmes.

Although the bulk of the EU’s structural funds’ help for depressedregions is channelled through OPs, there are a number of othermechanisms for providing help. Direct help to individual large(mostly infrastructure) projects on a one-off basis can be given.The EU can also simply part-finance member state aid schemes ifit wishes. There is also a limited use of global grants. These involvethe EU paying money to some intermediary agent which acts on itsbehalf. Global grants are particularly useful in channelling help tosmall firms where ‘hands-on’ work would simply swamp the EU ormember state government. Finally, mention must be made ofCommunity Initiatives (CIs). These are programmes of aid initiatedby the EU from the 9% of the money set aside for this purpose.Unlike the OPs, which are confined to a single member state (orpart of a single member state), the CIs are designed to tackleregional problems which are common to many member states. Table14.3 sets out the CIs introduced between 1989 and 1993. As can beseen, some of the CIs attack problems caused by an EU-widedecline of a single industry (e.g., RECHAR and the coal industry),or are designed to meet a common goal (e.g., REGEN and energysupply networks to disadvantaged regions).

Additionality

The principle of additionality is one of the most important for thesuccess of EU regional policy and at the same time one of the mostdifficult to achieve. Additionality refers to the situation in which theEU structural funds inject money into the depressed regions in amanner which prevents member states from exploiting the opportunityto cut back their own domestic regional spending. There are threemain reasons for the importance of the concept of additionality: 1 EU regional policy is designed in part to meet new regional

problems arising from processes such as the SEM and EMU.

Page 288: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

REGIONAL POLICY OF THE EUROPEAN UNION

271

New problems call for a net injection of new money, somethingwhich is frustrated if additionality is avoided by member states;

2 the EU’s structural funds budget, large though it now is, cannotpossibly solve Europe’s regional problems on its own. Themoney must therefore act as a catalyst, triggering matchinginjections from the member states, regional and localorganisations and from the private sector. Additionality iscrucial if this is to occur; and

3 the period 1994–99 will see member states desperatelyattempting to fulfil the convergence criteria of the MaastrichtTreaty (see especially Chapter 5). Cutting budget deficits is akey element in this struggle for economic convergence. Thetemptation for member states to use EU money as a substitutefor their own regional spending will be strong.

The EU attempts to ensure additionality by two methods. The firstis its use of a matching-grant process in awarding structural funds’help. The EU will not be the sole provider of assistance to projectsand programmes. Member state aid must also be given and ceilingson the EU contribution are set. Second, the EU operates a‘maximum disclosure of information’ policy designed to putpressure on member states to stick to their additionality promises.Under the 1993 regulations, for example, member states arerequired to ‘maintain, in the whole of the territory concerned, itspublic structural or comparable expenditure at least at the same

Table 14.3 The Community Initiatives (CIs) adopted by the EU, 1989–93

Source: EC Commission (1993).

Page 289: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

HARVEY ARMSTRONG

272

level as in the previous [i.e., 1989–93] programming period’ (ECCommission, 1993). Information checks are also included in theregional development plans and at the monitoring and evaluationstage. It must be admitted, however, that member states in the pasthave often proved masters at disguising cut-backs in regional policyspending and there is little to guarantee that the 1993 regulationswill be any more successful than their predecessors.

THE REGIONAL POLICY ACTIVITIES OF OTHEREU FINANCIAL INSTRUMENTS

In addition to the EU’s structural funds, a number of otherfinancial instruments also operate with a pro-regional policy bias,including: 1 the Cohesion Fund—an entirely new fund created in 1993 as

part of the Maastricht Treaty process. It is designed to helpcertain member states to become more fully integrated into theEU economy as part of the EMU process. Member states withGDP per capita under 90% of the EU average are eligible,currently Spain, Portugal, Greece and Ireland. Eligibility will bereviewed in 1996. The money is earmarked for transportinfrastructure and environmental improvement projects. TheCohesion Fund will increase from ECU 1.5bn in 1993 to ECU2.6bn in 1999 (at 1992 prices). Spain is to get between 52%and 58% of the fund’s spending, Greece 16–20%, Portugal 16–20% and Ireland 7–10%;

2 the Financial Instrument for Fisheries Guidance (FIFG)—anew financial instrument set up as part of the 1993 reforms(EC Commission, 1993). It reflects a growing concern withinthe EU of the severe problems being experienced bycommunities dependent on fishing and aquaculture. It isdesigned to operate alongside the structural funds in attemptingto attain Objective 5a (see Table 14.1);

3 the European Investment Bank (EIB)—an investment bankwhich uses its own capital together with money borrowed oninternational capital markets to make loans in all parts of theEU (and, indeed, some outside the EU). A deliberately highproportion of EIB loans, however, are made to industrial,infrastructure and environmental projects in the disadvantagedregions of the EU. In 1991, for example, the EIB made some

Page 290: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

REGIONAL POLICY OF THE EUROPEAN UNION

273

ECU 14.4bn of loans inside the EU and, of these, no lessthan ECU 8.5bn were for regional development purposes; andfinally

4 the European Coal and Steel Community (ECSC)—a bodyestablished in 1952 which continues to have a separate budgetand policy existence within the EU. Although not strictly aregional policy instrument, the coal and steel areas are amongsome of the most disadvantaged regions of the EU. The ECSCmakes loans to the coal, steel and associated industries forrestructuring purposes (ECU 1.1bn in 1992). It also makes‘conversion loans’ to other industries setting up in coal andsteel areas (ECU 426m in 1992), together with a variety oftypes of ‘redaptation’ assistance designed to help ex-coal andsteel workers to relocate, retrain and to migrate and re-housethemselves.

COMPETITION POLICY REGULATIONS FORSTATE AIDS

The EU has adopted a number of competition policy regulationsdesigned to control the activities of member state regional policies,particularly member state subsidies (EC Commission, 1988a)—seealso Chapter 13. These regulations are designed to prevent memberstates from using their own regional subsidies to aggressively bidfor inward investment projects from overseas (e.g., Japanese carassembly plants) or for firms from other EU countries. Theregulations take the form of differentiated ceilings on the size ofsubsidies which can be offered, with poorer regions having lessrestrictive ceilings. Subsidies which are difficult to quantify (i.e.,‘opaque’ subsidies) are banned, as are subsidies which are paid on acontinuing basis (rather than one-off grants).

RESEARCH AND ANALYSIS OF REGIONALPROBLEMS IN THE EU

The EU underpins i ts regional pol icy with wide-rangingprovision for research and analysis of regional problems. Thereis a substantial amount of in-house research undertaken atBrussels, quite a lot of which finds its way into the regularperiodic repor ts on regional problems in the EU (ECCommission, 1991c). These periodic reports, in turn, form the

Page 291: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

HARVEY ARMSTRONG

274

basis of the EU’s regional policy guidelines which serve as aframework when regional plans and CSFs are being drawn up.The EU also funds a large number of studies and consultancyreports from external researchers and organisations. Among themost important types of research undertaken are the regionalimpact assessment studies which are designed to identify, at anearly stage, those EU policies likely to have adverse regionaleffects (see, for example, EC Commission, 1984).

CONCLUSIONS

The EU regional policy as it has now evolved is a rather complexone. Many of the developments contained in the key 1989 and1993 reform packages are to be welcomed, particularly the largeincrease in the real value of the financial resources devoted toregional policy.

The regional policy of the EU will, however, continue to faceproblems in the years ahead. Five main difficulties can behighlighted. First, serious doubts remain on the ability of EUregional policy to solve regional problems. The experience ofindividual member states such as Britain suggests that manyregional problems are highly intractable and require much largerbudgets than that available to the EU. In addition, the SEM andEMU will pose new regional problems. Second, and closelyassociated with the funding problem, is the unusual nature of theEU’s economic powers. In most federal systems such as the UnitedStates, the central government has wide fiscal powers which can beused to help to reduce regional disparities. Automatic stabiliserssuch as federal income taxation tend to damp down regional percapita income differences by taxing richer regions more heavily. Inaddition, in genuine federal states there is a powerful system ofinter-personal transfers (e.g., unemployment benefits and otherwelfare payments) and inter-government transfers (e.g., grants fromthe federal government to state governments). Both sets oftransfers tend to narrow regional disparities, yet the EU hasvirtually none of these systems in place.

Third, despite the provisions in the 1993 reforms, the ability ofthe EU to force member states to use EU regional policy money inan ‘additional’ manner cannot be guaranteed, particularly as we areentering a period of severe pressure on member states’ budgetdeficits. Fourth, the 1993 reforms have failed to settle the issue of

Page 292: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

REGIONAL POLICY OF THE EUROPEAN UNION

275

‘who does what’ in regional policy. This goes to the heart of thecurrent high-profile debate on subsidiarity. The struggle for powerto control regional policy between the member states and the EUwill continue until a final balance of authority is clearly set out. Weare a long way from this stage.

Finally, an issue which will undoubtedly emerge into muchsharper focus in the years ahead will be the relationship betweenregional policy and the external trade performance of the EU. Withthe EU facing severe competitive pressures from other parts of theworld, it cannot be long before voices are raised questioning theeffectiveness of EU regional policy. Some will see thedisadvantaged regions as inherently poor locations forinternationally competitive firms. Others will argue the contrarycase. In the meantime, it is vital that the existing EU expendituresbe very carefully spent if the policy is not to be discredited in theyears ahead. In this respect it would be better to proceed withextreme caution in managing the sudden large increase in spendingfor the peripheral regions envisaged in the 1993 reforms. If certainperipheral regions are simply unable to efficiently absorb a suddenlarge increase in assistance, it would be safer for the spending to bephased in more slowly.

Page 293: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union
Page 294: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

277

STATISTICAL APPENDIX

Key for abbreviations in Tables A1–A7:

B BelgiumDK DenmarkD GermanyGR GreeceE SpainF FranceIRL IrelandI ItalyL LuxembourgNL The NetherlandsP PortugalUK United KingdomEU European UnionUSA United States of AmericaJ Japan

Page 295: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

Tabl

e A

1 U

nem

ploy

men

t ra

tes

(per

cen

t of

civ

ilian

lab

our

forc

e)

Page 296: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

Sour

ce: E

urop

ean

Eco

nom

y.

Page 297: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

Tabl

e A

2 G

ross

dom

estic

pro

duct

(E

CU

, bn

)

Page 298: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

Sour

ce: E

urop

ean

Eco

nom

y.

Page 299: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

Tabl

e A

3 Pe

r ca

pita

gro

ss d

omes

tic p

rodu

ct (

EU

=10

0)

Page 300: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

Sour

ce: E

urop

ean

Eco

nom

y.

Page 301: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

Tabl

e A

4 E

conn

omic

gro

wth

(pe

r ce

nt o

f ch

ange

in

gros

s do

mes

tic p

rodu

ct p

er a

nnum

)

Page 302: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

Sour

ce: E

urop

ean

Eco

nom

y.

Page 303: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

Tabl

e A

5 G

ross

dom

estic

fix

ed c

apita

l fo

rmat

ion

(per

cen

t ch

ange

per

ann

um)

Page 304: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

Sour

ce: E

urop

ean

Eco

nom

y.

Page 305: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

Tabl

e A

6 Re

tail

pric

e in

flatio

n (p

er c

ent

per

annu

m)

Page 306: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

Sour

ce: E

urop

ean

Eco

nom

y.

Page 307: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

Tabl

e A

7 C

urre

nt a

ccou

nt (

per

cent

of

gros

s do

mes

tic p

rodu

ct)

Page 308: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

Sour

ce: E

urop

ean

Eco

nom

y.

Page 309: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

292

BIBLIOGRAPHY

Ackrill, R.W. (1992), ‘The EU Budget and Agricultural Policy Reforms,with Special Reference to Cereals’, unpublished PhD thesis, Universityof Nottingham

Ackrill, R.W., Rayner, A.J., Ingersent, K.A. and Hine, C. (1993), ‘Reform ofthe Common Agricultural Policy and Budgetary Expenditures: TheCereals Sector’, Department of Economics Discussion Paper, No. 93/3,University of Nottingham

Addison, J. and Siebert, W. (1993), Social Engineering in the European Union:The Social Charter, Maastricht and Beyond, IEA

Agra Europe, various issuesAlesina, A. (1989), ‘Politics and Business Cycles in Industrial Democracies’,

Economic Policy, Vol. 8Alesina, A. and Grilli, V.U. (1991), ‘The European Central Bank: Reshaping

Monetary Politics in Europe’, CEPR Discussion Paper Series, No. 563,Centre for Economic Policy Research

Appleby, J. (1988), ‘Why 1992 may be Disastrous for Health’, British MedicalJournal 296:1620

Artis, M. (1989), ‘The Call of a Common Currency’, The Social MarketFoundation, Paper No. 3

Artis, M. (1992), ‘The Maastricht Road to Monetary Union’, Journal ofCommon Market Studies, Vol. XXX

Artis, M. (1994), ‘Stage Two: Feasible Transition to EMU’, in D.Cobham(ed.), European Monetary Upheavals, Manchester University Press

Artus, J.R. and Young, J.H. (1979), ‘Fixed and Flexible Exchange Rates: ARenewal of the Debate’, IMF Staff Papers, Vol. 26

Backus, D. and Driffill, J. (1985), ‘Inflation and Reputation’, AmericanEconomic Review, Vol. 75

Balassa, B. (1961), The Theory of Economic Integration, Allen and UnwinBaldwin, R. (1989), ‘The Growth Effects of 1992’, Economic Policy, Vol. 9Bank of England (1990), ‘The Exchange Rate Mechanism of the European

Monetary System’, Bank of England Quarterly Bulletin, Vol. 30, No. 4Bank of England (1991), ‘The Exchange Rate Mechanism of the European

Page 310: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

BIBLIOGRAPHY

293

Monetary System: A Review of the Literature’, Bank of England QuarterlyBulletin, Vol. 31, No. 1

Bank of England (1992), ‘The Maastricht Agreement on Economic andMonetary Union’, Bank of England Quarterly Bulletin, Vol. 32, No. 1

Barber, L. (1993), ‘Now Comes the Hard Part’, Financial Times SurveyBarrell, R. (1992), Economic Convergence and Monetary Union in Europe, SageBarro, R.J. and Gordon, D.B. (1983), ‘Rules, Discretion and Reputation in a

Model of Monetary Policy’, Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 12Barro, R.J. and Sala-i-Martin, X. (1991), ‘Convergence across States and

Regions’, Brookings Papers, No. 1Barro, R.J. and Sala-i-Martin, X. (1992), ‘Convergence’, Journal of Political

Economy, Vol. 100Bayoumi, T. and Eichengreen, B. (1992), ‘Shocking Aspects of European

Monetary Unification’, CEPR Discussion Paper, No. 643, Centre forEconomic Policy Research

Beenstock, M., Capie, F. and Griffiths, B. (1984), ‘Economic Recovery inthe United Kingdom in the 1930s’, in Bank of England Panel PaperNo. 23, The UK Recovery in the 1930s

Begg, D. (1991), ‘European Monetary Union—The Macro Issues’, in TheMaking of Monetary Union, Centre for Economic Policy Research

Begg, D (1992), Monitoring European Integration: The Making of MonetaryUnion, Centre for Economic Policy Research

Begg, I. and Weale, M. (1990), ‘Monetary Integration and the Balance ofPayments’, Oxford Review of Economic Policy, Vol. 6, No. 3

Booz, Allen and Hamilton (1989), The Effects of the Internal Market onGreece, Ireland, Portugal and Spain, EC Commission

Borts, G.H. (1960), ‘The Equalization of Returns and Regional EconomicGrowth’, American Economic Review, Vol. 50

Borts, G.H. and Stein, J.L. (1964), Economic Growth in a Free Market,Columbia University Press

Bos, M. and Nelson, H. (1988), ‘Indirect Taxation and the Completion of theInternal Market of the EC’, Journal of Common Market Studies, Vol. XXVII

Brittan, L. (1991), ‘European Monetary Union: What Money for Europe?’,TSB Forum

Brociner, A. (1991), ‘Credibility, Fiscal Policy and EMU’, University ofLeicester Discussion Paper, No. 143

Brociner, A. and Levine, P. (1992a), ‘EMU: A Survey’, Discussion Papers inEuropean Economic Studies, No. 92/3, Centre for European EconomicStudies

Brociner, A. and Levine, P. (1992b), ‘Fiscal Policy Coordination andEMU:A Dynamic Game Approach’ , CEPR Discussion Paper, No. 420, Centrefor Economic Policy Research

Cantwell, J. (1989), Technological Innovation and Multinational Corporations, BasilBlackwell

Cantwell, J. (1992), ‘The Relationship between International Trade andInternational Production’, Discussion Papers in International Investment andBusiness Studies, No. 161, University of Reading

Page 311: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

BIBLIOGRAPHY

294

Cecchini, P. (1988), The European Challenge: 1992 The Benefits of a SingleMarket, Wildwood House

Centre for Economic Policy Research, (1992), ‘Is Bigger Better? TheEconomics of EU Enlargement’, Monitoring European Integration, No. 3

Centre for Economic Policy Research (1991), The Road to EMU: Managingthe Transition to a Single Currency

Church, C. (1991), ‘EFTA and the European Union’, PNL European Dossier,No. 21

Cohen, D. and Wyplosz, C. (1990), ‘Price and Trade Effects of ExchangeRate Fluctuations and the Design of Policy Coordination’, CEPRDiscussion Paper, Centre for Economic Policy Research

Collignon, S. (1994), Europe’s Monetary Future, Pinter PublishersCouncil of Ministers (1992), Treaty on European UnionCrafts, N. (1992), ‘Productivity Growth Reconsidered’, Economic Policy, Vol. 15Culter, T, Haslem, C., Williams, J. and Williams, K. (1989), 1992—The

Struggle for Europe, BergCurrie, D. (1991), ‘EMU: A Rocky Road from Maastricht’, International

Economic Outlook, DecemberCurrie, D. (1992), ‘European Monetary Union: Institutional Structure and

Economic Performance’, The Economic Journal, Vol. 102, No. 411Davies, E., Kay, J. and Swales, C. (1989), 1992: Myths and Realities, London

Business SchoolDavies, G. (1989), ‘Britain and the European Monetary Question’, Institute

of Public Policy Research Economic Study, No. 1de Grauwe, P. (1988), ‘Exchange Rate Variability and the Slowdown in

Growth of International Trade’, IMF Staff Papers, Vol. 35de Grauwe, P. (1992), The Economics of Monetar y Integration, Oxford

University Pressde Grauwe, P. and Vanhaverbeke, W (1991), ‘Is Europe an Optimum

Currency Area? Evidence from Regional Data’, CEPR Discussion Paper,No. 555, Centre for Economic Policy Research

Delors, J. (1989), Report on Economic and Monetary Union in the EuropeanCommunity, Committee for the Study of Economic and Monetary Union,EC Commission

Demekas, D.G. (1988), ‘The Effects of the Common Agricultural Policy ofthe European Union: A Survey of the Literature’, Journal ofCommonMarket Studies , Vol. XXVII

Demopoulos, G., Katsimbris, G. and Miller, S. (1987), ‘Monetary Policyand Central Bank Financing of Government Budget Deficits’, EuropeanEconomic Review, Vol. 31

Dixon, R.J. and Thirlwall, A.P. (1975), ‘A Model of Regional Growth RateDifferentials along Kaldorian Lines’, Oxford Economic Papers, Vol. 27

Drazen, A. (1989), ‘Monetary Policy, Capital Controls and Seigniorage inan Open Economy’, in M.De Cecco and A.Giovannini, (ed.), AEuropean Central Bank? Perspectives on Monetary Unification after Ten Years ofthe EMS, Cambridge University Press

Page 312: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

BIBLIOGRAPHY

295

Dunning, J.H. (1986), Japanese Participation in British Industry, Croom HelmDunning, J.H. (1988), Explaining International Production, Unwin Hyman

Dunning, J.H. (1990), Transnational Corporations and the Growth of Services:Some Conceptual and Theoretical Issues, UN Centre on TransnationalCorporations

EC Commission (1983), Britain in the Union, 1973–83: Ten Years in EuropeEC Commission (1984), ‘Study of the Regional Impact of the

Community’s External Trade Policy’, Regional Policy Series, No. 24EC Commission (1985), Completing the Internal Market—White Paper from the

Commission to the European CouncilEC Commission (1988a), ‘Commission Communication on the Method of

Application of Article 92(3) (a) and (c) to Regional Aid’, OfficialJournalEC Commission (1988b), The Costs of Non-EuropeEC Commission (1989a), ‘First Survey on State Aids in the European

Communities’, Press ReleaseEC Commission (1989b), Guide to the Reform of the Community’s Structural

FundsEC Commission (1990a), ‘European Union Charter of the Fundamental

Social Rights of Workers’, Social Europe, No. 1EC Commission (1990b), ‘One Market, One Money—An Evaluation of the

Potential Benefits and Costs of Forming an Economic and MonetaryUnion’, European Economy, No. 44

EC Commission (1990c), ‘The Impact of the Internal Market by IndustrialSector’, European Economy, Special Edition

EC Commission (1991a), ‘Developments in the Labour Market in theUnion: Results of a Survey Covering Employers and Employees’,European Economy, March

EC Commission (1991b), Europe 2000: Outlook for the Development of theCommunity’s Territory

EC Commission (1991c), The Regions in the 1990s: Fourth Periodic Report onthe Social and Economic Situation and Development of the Regions of theCommunity

EC Commission (1992a), Third Sur vey on State Aids in the EuropeanCommunity in the Manufacturing and Certain Other Sectors

EC Commission (1992b), ‘Unemployment in the Regions of theCommunity in 1992’, Rapid Report 2

EC Commission (1992c), ‘First Report on the Application of the UnionCharter of the Fundamental Social Rights of Workers’, Social Europe,No. 1

EC Commission (1992d), The Internal Market after 1992EC Commission (1993), Community Structural Funds 1994–1999Eichengreen, B. (1990a), ‘Costs and Benefits of European Monetary

Unification’, CEPR Discussion Paper, No. 435, Centre for EconomicPolicy Research

Eichengreen, B. (1990b), ‘One Money for Europe? Lessons from the USCurrency Union’, Economic Policy, April

Page 313: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

BIBLIOGRAPHY

296

Eichengreen, B. (1992), Golden Fetters: The Gold Standard and the GreatDepression, 1919–39, Oxford University Press

El-Agraa, A. (1983), Britain within the European Union, MacmillanEl-Agraa, A. (1994), The Economics of the European Community, Harvester

WheatsheafEmerson, M. (1988), The Economics of 1992: the EC Commission’s Assessment

of the Economic Effects of Completing the Internal Market, Oxford UniversityPress

Emerson, M. (1992), One Market, One Money: An Evaluation of the PotentialBenefits and Costs of Forming an Economic and Monetary Union, OxfordUniversity Press

Emerson, M. and Huhne, C. (1991), The ECU Report, Pan BooksEuropean Parliament (1991), ‘A New Strategy for Social and Economic

Cohesion after 1992’, Regional Policy and Transport Series, No. 19Export-Import Bank of Japan (1991), Survey of Japanese Overseas Direct

Investment 1990–93, Research Institute of Overseas Investment, Export-Import Bank of Japan

Export-Import Bank of Japan (1992), Results of FY1991 Foreign DirectInvestment Survey, Research Institute of Overseas Investment, Export-Import Bank of Japan

Feldstein, M. (1992), ‘Europe’s Monetary Union: The Case AgainstEMU’ ,The Economist, June 13

Financial Times (1993), ‘International Mergers and Acquisitions’, FinancialTimes, September 17

Fourcans, A. (1992), ‘One Currency for Europe: From Theory to Practice’,European Research, Vol. 3, No. 3

Friedman, M. (1953), ‘The Case for Flexible Exchange Rates’, in Essays inPositive Economics, University of Chicago

Friedman, M. (1968), ‘The Role of Monetary Policy’, American EconomicReview, Vol. 58

Friedman, M. (1975), ‘Unemployment versus Inflation?’, Occasional Paper49, Institute of Economic Affairs

Gatsios, K. and Seabright, P. (1993), ‘Regulation in the EuropeanCommunity’, Oxford Review of Economic Policy, Vol. 5, No. 2

Gittelman, M. and Dunning, J.H. (1991), ‘Japanese Multinationals inEurope and the United States: Some Comparisons and Contrasts’, inM.W.Klein and P.J.J.Welfens (eds), Multinational Enterprises in the NewEurope and Global Trade, Springer

Goodhart, C.A.E. (1991), ‘An Assessment of EMU’, The Royal Bank ofScotland Review, No. 171

Grahl, J. and Teague, P. (1990), 1992: The Big Market, Lawrence andWishart

Grilli , V. (1989), ‘Seigniorage in Europe’, in M.De Cecco and A.Giovannini (eds), A European Central Bank? Perspectives on MonetaryUnification after Ten Years of the EMS, Cambridge University Press

Page 314: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

BIBLIOGRAPHY

297

Gros, D. (1989), ‘Paradigms for the Monetary Union of Europe’, Journal ofCommon Market Studies, Vol. XXVII, No. 3

Haaland, I.J. (1990), ‘Assessing the Effects of EU Integration on EFTACountries: The Position of Norway and Sweden’, Journal of CommonMarket Studies, Vol. XXVII

Harden, I. (1990), ‘EuroFed or “Monster Bank”?’, National Westminster BankQuarterly Review, August

Harris, P. and McDonald, F. (1993), European Business and Marketing: StrategicIssues, Paul Chapman Publishing

Healey, N.M. (1988), ‘The Case for Britain Joining the European MonetarySystem’, Economic Affairs, Vol. 8, No. 3, February/March

Healey, N.M. (1990), ‘Taking the Plunge: Britain and the EuropeanMonetary System’, The Contemporar y Review, Vol. 257, No. 1499,December

Healey, N.M. (1991a), ‘The European Road to Monetary Union’, FinancialReview, Spring

Healey, N.M. (1991b), ‘EC92: The Coming of “Fortress Europe”?’, BusinessQuarterly, Vol. 55, No. 4, Spring

Healey, N.M. (1991c), ‘The End of Nation States?’, The Contemporary Review,Vol. 259, No. 1510, November

Healey, N.M. (1992a), ‘Sterling and the Exchange Rate Mechanism’, BritishEconomy Survey, Vol. 22, No. 1, Autumn

Healey, N.M. (1992b), ‘From the Treaty of Rome to the Single Market’,Developments in Economics, Vol. 8, Causeway Press

Healey, N.M. (1992c), ‘European Monetary Integration’ in A.Griffiths (ed.),European Community Survey, Longman

Healey, N.M. (1993a), ‘Germany Policy Leadership and the Exchange RateMechanism: Anti-Inflation Anchor or Fault Line?’, Financial Review, Summer

Healey, N.M. (1993b), ‘The Exchange Rate Mechanism in Crisis’, BritishEconomy Survey, Vol. 23, No. 1, Autumn

Healey, N.M. (1993c), ‘European Monetary Union’, Developments inEconomics, Vol. 9, Causeway Press

Healey, N.M. (1994), ‘The Transition Economies of Central and EasternEurope: A Political, Economic, Social and Technological Analysis’, TheColumbia Journal of World Business, Vol. XXIX, No. 1

Healey, N.M. and Levine, P. (1992a), ‘The Economics of EuropeanMonetary Union’, The Economic Review, Vol. 9, No. 4

Healey, N.M. and Levine, P. (1992b), ‘Unpleasant Monetarist ArithmeticRevisited: Central Bank Independence, Fiscal Policy and EuropeanMonetary Union’, National Westminster Bank Quarterly Review, August

Healey, N.M. and Levine, P. (1995), ‘Should an Independent EuropeanCentral Bank be Independent?’, Bulletin of European International Tradeand Economic Issues, Vol. 1

Healey N.M., Levine, P. and Pearlman, J. (1994), ‘The Political Economy ofan Independent European Central Bank’, Current Politics and Economics ofEurope, Vol. 4

Page 315: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

BIBLIOGRAPHY

298

Heitger, B. and Stehn, J. (1990), ‘Japanese Investment in the EC—Responseto the Internal Market 1993?’, Journal of Common Market Studies, Vol.XXIV

Hill, A. (1993), ‘No Soft Touch for Business’, Financial Times, January 15Hirschman, A.O. (1958), The Strategy of Economic Development, YaleUniversity Press

Holtham, G. (1989), ‘Foreign Exchange Markets and Target Zones’, OxfordReview of Economic Policy, Vol. 5, No. 3

Hughes, K. (1992), ‘Competition and the Single Market’, Policy Studies, Vol.13, No. 3

ILO (1940), Year Book of Labour Statistics, 1940, International LabourOffice

Ingersent, K.A., Rayner, A.J. and Hine, R.C. (1993), ‘Agriculture in theUruguay Round: The Blair House Agreement and SubsequentDevelopments’, CREDIT Research Paper, No. 93/11, Department ofEconomics. University of Nottingham

Jackman, R. and Rubin, M. (1991), ‘Should We Be Afraid of the SocialCharter?’, Employment Institute Economic Report, August Jenkins, R. (1978),‘European Monetary Union’, Lloyds Bank Review, No. 127

JETRO (1990), Curr ent Situation of Business Operations of Japanese-Manufacturing Enterprises in Europe, JETRO International Economic andTrade Information Center

JETRO (1991), 7th Survey of European Operations of Japanese Companies in theManufacturing Sector, JETRO International Economic and TradeInformation Center

Johnson, H.G. (1965), ‘An Economic Theory of Protectionism, TariffBargaining and the Formation of Customs Unions’, Journal of PoliticalEconomy, Vol. 73

Johnson, P. (1992), ‘New Firms: The Key to Employment Creation?’, inN.M.Healey (ed.), Britain’s Economic Miracle: Myth or Reality?, RoutledgeJournal of Common Market Studies, Special Issue, Vol. XXVIII, 1990 (‘TheEuropean Union, EFTA and the New Europe’)

Kaldor, N. (1970), ‘The Case for Regional Policies’, Scottish Journal ofPolitical Economy, Vol. 17

Keynes, J.M. (1919), ‘The Economic Consequences of the Peace’, in TheCollected Writings of John Maynard Keynes. Volume IX: Essays in Persuasion,Royal Economic Society/Macmillan.

Keynes, J.M. (1925), ‘The Economic Consequences of Mr Churchill’, in TheCollected Writings of John Maynard Keynes. Volume IX: Essays in Persuasion,Royal Economic Society/Macmillan.

Kitson, M. and Solomou, S. (1990), Protectionism and Economic Revival: TheBritish Interwar Economy, Cambridge University Press

Kotios, A. and Schafers, M. (1990), ‘The Social Dimension and Cohesion:Complementary or Contradictory?’, Intereconomics, May/June

Krugman, P. (1989), ‘The Case for Stabilising Exchange Rates’, OxfordReview of Economic Policy, Vol. 5, No. 3

Page 316: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

BIBLIOGRAPHY

299

Kydland, F. and Prescott, E.C. (1977), ‘Rules Rather Than Discretion: TheInconsistency of Optimal Plans’, Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 85

Labour Party (1989), Meeting the Challenge in EuropeLevine, P. (1992), ‘Fiscal Policy Coordination under EMU and the

Choiceof Monetary Instrument’ , Discussion Papers in European EconomicStudies, No. 92/8, Centre for European Economic Studies

Levine, P. and Pearlman, J. (1992), ‘Fiscal and Monetary Policy underEMU: Credible Inflation Targets or Unpleasant Monetary Arithmetic?’,Discussion Papers in European Economic Studies, No. 92/10, Centre forEuropean Economic Studies

Levine, P. (1990) ‘The European Road to Monetary Union’, EuropeanResearch, Vol. 1, Pt 6

Lintner, V. and Mazey, S. (1991), The European Union: Economic and PoliticalAspects, McGraw-Hill

Lomax, D.F. (1991), ‘A European Central Bank and Economic andMonetary Union’, National Westminster Bank Quarterly Review, May

Lucas, R.E. (1976), ‘Econometric Policy Evaluation: A Critique’, in K.Brunner and A.H.Meltzer (eds), The Phillips Curve and Labour Markets,Carnegie Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, North-Holland.

MacDougall, D. (1977), Public Finance in European Integration, ECCommission

Markusen, J.R. (1987), ‘Multinationals, Multiplant Economies and Gainsfrom Trade’, Journal of International Economics, Vol. 16

Masson, P. and Merlitz, J. (1990), ‘Fiscal Policy Interdependence in aMonetary Union’, CEPR Discussion Paper, Centre for Economic PolicyResearch

Masson, P. and Symansky, S. (1992), ‘Evaluating the EMS and EMU UsingStochastic Simulations: Some Issues’, Mimeo, International MonetaryFund

Masson, P., Symansky, S. and Meredith, G. (1990), ‘Multimod Mark II: ARevised and Extended Model’, IMF Occasional Paper, No. 71, July

Matthews, K. (1992), ‘Britain’s Economic Renaissance’, in N.M.Healey (ed.),Britain’s Economic Miracle: Myth or Reality?, Routledge

McDonald, F. and Dearden, S. (1994), European Economic Integration, secondedition, Longman

McDonald, F. and Zis, G. (1989), ‘The European Monetary System:Towards 1992 and Beyond’, Journal of Common Market Studies, Vol.XXVIII

McKenzie, G. and Venables, A. (1991), The Economics of the Single EuropeanAct, Macmillan

McKenzie, G. and Venables, T. (1989), ‘The Economics of 1992’, TheEconomic Review, Vol. 6, No. 5

Meade, J. (1990), ‘The EMU and the Control of Inflation’, Oxford Review ofEconomic Policy, Vol. 6, No. 4

Michie, J. (1987), Wages in the Business Cycle: An Empirical and MethodologicalAnalysis, Pinter Publishers

Page 317: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

BIBLIOGRAPHY

300

Michie, J. and Grieve-Smith, J. (1993), Unemployment in Europe, AcademicPress

Minford, P. and Rastogi, A. (1990), ‘The Price of EMU’, in R.Dornbuschand R.Layard (eds) Britain and EMU, Centre for Economic Performance

Minford, P., Agenor, P. and Nowell, P. (1986), ‘A New ClassicalEconometric Model of the World Economy’, Economic Modelling, Vol. 3

Minford, P., Rastogi, A. and Hughes-Hallett, A. (1992), ‘The Price of EMURevisited’, CEPR Working Paper, No. 656, Centre for Economic PolicyResearch

Morgan, E.J. (1993), ‘Merger Appraisal under the EC Merger ControlRegulation’, in M.Gasson and J.Greedy (eds), Economic Inequality andIndustrial Concentration: Essays in Honour of Peter Hart, Edward Elgar

Morsink, R.L.A. and Molle, W.T.M. (1991), ‘Direct Investments andMonetary Integration’, European Economy, Special Edition No. 1

Munday, M. (1990), Japanese Manufacturing Investment in Wales, University ofWales Press

Mundell, R.A. (1957), ‘International Trade and Factor Mobility’, AmericanEconomic Review, Vol. 47

Mundell, R.A. (1961), ‘A Theory of Optimum Currency Areas’, AmericanEconomic Review, Vol. 51

Myrdal, G. (1957), Economic Theory and Underdeveloped Regions, Duckworth.National Farmers’ Union (1990), Farm Support Policies—The Reasons Why, NFUNeumann, M. (1990), ‘Central Bank Independence as a Prerequisite of

Price Stability’, Mimeo, University of BonnNevin, E. (1990), The Economics of Europe, MacmillanNicholson, F. and East, R. (1987), From the Six to the Twelve: The

Enlargement of the European Communities, LongmanNicolaides, P. and Thomsen, S. (1991), ‘Can Protectionism Explain Foreign

Direct Investment?’, Journal of Common Market Studies, Vol. XXIXNicoll, W. and Salmon, T.C. (1994), Understanding the New European

Community, Harvester WheatsheafNorman, G. and Dunning, J.H. (1984), ‘Intra-industry Foreign Direct

Investment: Its Rationale and Trade Effects’, Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv,No. 120

Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development (1989),Employment Outlook, July, OECD

PA Cambridge Economic Consultants (1989), The Regional Consequences ofthe Completion of the Internal Market for Financial Services, Study for theEC Commission

Paterson, I. and Simpson, L. (1992), ‘The Economics of Trade UnionPower’, in N.M.Healey (ed.), Britain’s Economic Miracle: Myth or Reality?,Routledge

Perlman, M. (1991), ‘In Search of Monetary Unions’, Financial MarketsGroup Special Paper, No. 39, October

Perroux, F. (1950), ‘Economic Space: Theory and Applications’, QuarterlyJournal of Economics, Vol. 64

Page 318: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

BIBLIOGRAPHY

301

Prescott, K. and Welford, R. (1992), European Business: An Issue-basedApproach, Pitman

Preston, J. (1992), Cases in European Business, PitmanRayner A.J., Ingersent, K.A., Hine, R.C. and Ackrill, R.W. (1993), ‘Does the

CAP fit the GATT? A model of EU cereals’, CREDIT Research Paper,No. 93/14, University of Nottingham

Rhodes, M. (1992), ‘The Future of the “Social Dimension”: Labour MarketRegulation in Post-1992 Europe’, Journal of Common Market Studies,March

Robinson, J. (1966), The New Mercantilism, An Inaugural Lecture, CambridgeUniversity Press

Rogoff, K. (1985), ‘The Optimal Degree of Commitment to anIntermediate Monetary Target’, Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 100

Rollo, J. and Smith, A. (1993), ‘The Political Economy of Eastern Europe’sTrade with the EU: Why So Sensitive?’, Economic Policy, Vol. 16, April

Sapir, A., Buigues, P. and Jacquemin, A. (1993), ‘European CompetitionPolicy in Manufacturing and Services: A Two Speed Approach’, OxfordReview of Economic Policy, Summer

Sargent, T.J. and Wallace, N. (1981), ‘Some Unpleasant MonetaristArithmetic’, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review, Vol. 5,No. 3

Smith, S. (1988), ‘Excise Duties and the Internal Market’, Journal of CommonMarket Studies, Vol. 27, No. 2

Sumner, M.T. and Zis, G. (1982), ‘On the Relative Bias of FlexibleExchange Rates’, reprinted in M.T.Sumner and G.Zis (eds) (1993),European Monetary Union: Progress and Prospects, Macmillan

Swann, D. (1992), The Single European Market and Beyond: A Study of theWider Implications of the Single European Act, Routledge

Temperton, P. (1993), The European Currency Crisis: What Chance Now for aSingle European Currency?, Probus Publishing

Tharakan, P.K.M. (1991), ‘The Political Economy of Anti-dumpingUndertakings in the European Communities’, European Economic Review,Vol. 35

The Economist (1989a), ‘Sorry, I’ll Read That Again’, April 15The Economist (1989b), ‘The Passionate Dimension’, April 8The Economist (1989c), ‘Set Up or Stay Out’, February 18The Economist (1989d), ‘March in the EEC’, April 1The Economist (1989e), ‘A Tilt in the Internal Balance’, May 20Thomsen, S. and Nicolaides, P. (1991), The Evolution of Japanese Direct

Investment in Europe: Death of a Transistor Salesman, Harvester WheatsheafTsoukalis, L. (1991), The European Union and its Mediterranean Enlargement,

Allen and UnwinUngerer, H. et al. (1986), ‘The European Monetary System—Recent

Developments’, Occasional Papers, No. 48, International Monetary FundUnited Nations (1991), World Investment Report 1991, United Nations

Page 319: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

BIBLIOGRAPHY

302

van der Ploeg, F. (1989), ‘Monetary Interdependence under AlternativeExchange Rate Regimes: A European Perspective’, CEPR DiscussionPaper, No. 358, Centre for Economic Policy Research

Vaubel, R. (1988), ‘Monetary Integration Theory’, in G.Zis (ed.),International Economics, Longman

Vickerman, R.W. (1992), The Single European Market, Harvester WheatsheafViner, J. (1950), The Customs Union Issue, Carnegie Endowment for

International Peacevon Hagen, J. and Neumann, M. (1991), ‘Real Exchange Rates Within and

Between Currency Areas: How Far Away is EMU?’, Center for GlobalBusiness Discussion Paper, No. 62, Indiana University

Walters, A.A. (1986), Britain’s Economic Renaissance, Oxford University PressWhiteford, E. (1993), ‘Social Policy After Maastricht’, European Law Review,

Vol. 18Williamson, J. (1965), ‘The Crawling Peg’, Essays in International Finance, No.

50, Princeton UniversityWinters, L.A. (1987), ‘Britain in Europe: A Survey of Quantitative Trade

Studies’, Journal of Common Market Studies, Vol. XXVYannopoulos, G.N. (1986), Greece and the EEC, Macmillan

Page 320: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

303

Ackrill, Robert W. 216, 217, 218Acquis Communautaire 172Addison, J. 194, 205additionality principle 270–2Alesina, A. 89, 115Appleby, J. 164Article 85: block exemptions 240;

exemptions 239–40; market-sharing arrangements 240;mergers 243; price fixing 240;restrictive practices 239–41; steelindustry cartel 252

Article 86: Continental Can 242;dominant position 242; mergers243; monopolies 241–3; relevantmarket 241–2; Tetra Pak 242–3;tying agreements 242

Article 90 248–51Article 92 250–2Artis, Michael 7, 88, 94, 98, 102Artus, J.R. 46, 87Association of South East Asian

Nations (ASEAN) 5, 8ATR/De Havilland merger

244, 246atypical workers see temporary workAustria: currency union and 102;

EFTA membership 12; EMUStage Three 102; EU membership13, 102, 182, 183, 184

Backus, D. 58Balassa, B. 34Baldwin, R. 34, 151

INDEX

Baltic States: membership ofEU 187

Barber, L. 162barriers to trade: administrative

160; Cassis de Dijon 22;customs formalities 146–7;customs union see customsunion; documentation 160; fiscalbarriers 148–9, 154;frontiercontrols 9, 146–7, 148,152, 154, 260; health and safetyrules 147, 160; non-standardiseddocumentation 160; non-tariffsee non-tariff barriers; physicalbarriers 146–7; publicprocurement practices 147–8,161, 260; removal of 92, 93,104, 140, 146–9, 161; safetystandards 260, 261; state aids148; tariffs see tariffs; technicalbarriers 147–8, 160, 260, 261;training qualifications 160;welfare effects of 22–4

Barro, R.J. 58, 109, 256, 259Basle—Nyborg agreements 59Bayoumi, T. 127Beenstock, M. 79Begg, D. 87‘beggar-my-neighbour’ policies 76,

82, 174Belgium: competition laws 254;

dual exchange rate system 92;ECSC membership 13; EECand 12; EMU Stage Three 102;gold standard and 76; mini

Page 321: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

INDEX

304

EMU 120; monetary union withFrance, Italy and Switzerland105; monetary union withLuxembourg 5, 122

Black Wednesday 61Blair House Accord 218, 219bonded warehouses 149Booz, A. and Booz, H. 261border controls see frontier controlsBorts, G.H. 34, 256Bos, M. 163Bretton Woods system 49, 59, 87Britain: Black Wednesday 61; CAP

and 179–80; currency union and102; deflation 61, 72; effects ofEU membership 179–80; EFTAmembership 13; EMSmembership 50; ERM and 2,13, 45–6, 50, 51, 60, 61, 83,100, 101, 103, 119, 120; EUmembership 13, 178; exchangerate band 51; foreign directinvestment in 180, 229; goldstandard and 70, 72–3, 75, 77;inflation rate 60, 61, 117;interest rates 48, 72, 122; Japan,foreign direct investment by180, 229; ’Lawson boom’ 60;maternity leave 197; mergerpolicies 243; night work 194;overtime 194–5; privatisationprogramme 155, 248; SchengenAgreement and 9; shift work194–5; Social ActionProgramme and 200–3, 205;Social Chapter opt-out 9, 203;Social Charter opt-out 190, 204;Thatcher government 15, 180;United States, foreign directinvestment by 180; withdrawalof sterling from ERM 2, 45–6,50, 51, 61, 83, 100, 101, 103,119, 120; working time 194,195; works councils 199–200

Brittan, Leon 8, 246, 253Brociner, A. 87Brunei: ASEAN and 5Brussels Summit 213Bulgaria: Europe Agreements

185–6, see also eastern EuropeBundesbank 60–1, 62, 89, 109, 121

Bush, George 197business cycles: real business cycle

theory 129; synchronisation of61, 62, 63

Cairns Group 218Canada: gold standard and 76;

NAFTA and 5Cantwell, J. 225capital: free movement of 5, 16,

59, 63, 91, 92, 128, 143, 145,147, 176

capital controls 61, 62, 63, 92, 97,106

cartels 166, 239; home market rule239; steel industry 252

Cassis de Dijon 22Cecchini, P. 139, 149, 161Cecchini Report 149–52central banks 49, 50, 51, 109, 134;

currency union 89; EuropeanCentral Bank (ECB) seeEuropean Central Bank;European System of CentralBanks (ESCB) 95–6, 108, 116,117, 123; independence of111–16

children and adolescents: protectionof 191

Church, C. 2Churchill, Winston 12Cohesion Fund 193, 205, 272collective bargaining: right to 191Collignon, S. 63COMECON see eastern EuropeCommission 17–18; ECB and 96;

president of 17; structure of 17Commissioners: appointment of 17;

role of 17Committee of Central Bank

Governors (CCBG) 108Committee of Permanent

Representatives (COREPER) 19Committee for the Study

ofEconomic and MonetaryUnion 93

Common Agricultural Policy (CAP)3, 49, 170, 173, 177, 206–22;attempts at reform 211–12;Blair House Accord 218, 219;Britain and 179–80; British

Page 322: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

INDEX

305

rebates 180; budgetary discipline211, 212; Cairns Group and218; costs of joining 179;deficiency payments and 179;drought in United States and212, 214, 221; EFTAenlargement and 184; GATTand 218–21; Greece and 180–1;indirect impact on employment179; intervention buying 209,212, 213, 221; MacSharryreforms 207, 214–18,220;Maximum GuaranteedQuantity (MGQ) 213; 1980sreforms 212–14; radical reformof 214–18; reasons forsupporting agriculture 207–8;set-aside 212, 215, 221; Spainand 181; stabilisers 213, 214;support prior to 1993 208–11;United States and 218–21;variable import levies(VILs) 209

common currency see EuropeanCurrency Unit; single currency

Common External Tariff 140common market 6–7, 40, 157, 172;

welfare gains 143, 145–6, seealso single European market

Community Support Framework(CSF) 269

companies: cross-border mergers155; European company statute165; joint ventures 155; nationalcompany law and 160; SEMprogramme and 154–6, see alsofirms; small and medium-sizedenterprises

company law 160, 166competition policy 148, 238–

54;Article 85 see Article 85;Article 86 see Article 86; Article90 248–51; Article 92 250–2;cartels 239; in France 245;mergers 243–7; monopolies241–3; regulated industries 247–50; restrictive practices 239–41;state aids 250–2, 273; tyingarrangements 242

Confederation of British Industry(CBI) 196

Consumer Protection Act 1987 159Continental Can 242convergence criteria of

MaastrichtTreaty 95, 96–9,117–19, 184

Copenhagen Summit 157, 186COREPER 19Council of Agricultural

Ministers 19Council of Finance Ministers

(Ecofin) 18–19, 108Council of Ministers 18–20;

composition of 18; COREPER19; Ecofin 18–19; EuropeanParliament and 18; presidencyof 19; qualified majority voting19; secretariat 19; weightedvotes 19

Crafts, N. 257credit facilities 51; Very Short

Term Financing Facility (VSTF)51, 59

cross-border shopping 148, 149Culter, T. 152currency union 84–5, 93, 96,

central bank 89; convergencecriteria 95, 96–9, 117–19, 184;degrees of monetary integration85, 86; exchange rateuncertainty and 87, 88;exchange rate union compared87–91; international investmentand 88; loss of autonomy 89;Maastricht Treaty and 87, 91–102, 103; monetary policy 89,90; parallel currency union 86;transaction costs and 89, 126;unemployment and 88–9, 90; seealso economic and monetaryunion; exchange rate flexibility;monetary union; single currency

Currie, D. 63, 109customs formalities: removal of

146–7customs union 6, 8, 24–32, 139–

40, 157, 172; economies ofexperience 36–7; economies ofscale 34–6; reduced X-inefficiency 39–40, 143, 145;reduced economic rents 38–9;trade creation 27–32; trade

Page 323: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

INDEX

306

diversion 29–32; welfare effectsof 22–40

Cyprus: EU membership and184–5

Czech Republic: EuropeAgreements 185–6; see alsoeastern Europe

Davies, E. 152Davies, G. 59de Grauwe, P. 46, 88, 89, 127Dearden, S. 4, 143, 152deficiency payments 179deflation: competitive 82; fixed

exchange rate regimes and 73–6;gold standard and 69, 70–6, 80

deflationary policies of EU 69Delors, Jacques 93, 107, 128, 158,

169, 182, 184Delors Committee 1, 128Delors Plan 16Delors Report 13, 16, 93, 94, 107–

8, 171Demekas, D.G. 179democratic deficit in EU 125Demopoulos, G. 116Denmark: EFTA membership 12,

13; EMU Stage Three 102; EUmembership 13, 178; GreatDepression and 74, 75; miniEMU 120; openness of 10;referendum on MaastrichtTreaty 2, 99, 205; SchengenAgreement and 9; shiftwork 194

d’Estaing, Giscard 20devaluation 48–9, 75–6; benefits of

76–7direct investment see foreign direct

investmentdisabled: Social Charter and 191Dixon, R.J. 257documentation 160dominant position, abuse of see

Article 86; monopoliesDrazen, A. 114Driffill, J. 58Dunkel Paper 218–19Dunning, J.H. 4, 223, 224, 225,

227, 231

EAGGF see Guidance Section ofthe European AgriculturalGuidance and Guarantee Fund

East, R. 181eastern Europe: COMECON block

185; end of communism 2;Europe Agreements 185–6;membership of EU and 170–1,177, 185–6; nationalist andethnic unrest 12; population of185; transition to marketeconomy 2–3

EC see European CommunityECB see European Central BankEcofin 18–19, 108economic integration 4–9; barriers

to trade see barriers to trade;common market see commonmarket; customs union seecustoms union; economic andmonetary union see economicand monetary union; free tradearea 5–6; welfare effects of seewelfare effects

economic and monetaryunion(EMU) 1, 7–9, 15–17,advantages of 104–5, 124–7;barriers to trade, removal of seebarriers to trade; central bankindependence 111–16; DelorsReport 13, 16, 93, 107–8, 171;disadvantages of 105; EMS and45; fixed exchange rates 106–7;futures and 104; growth ofinterest in 105–7; HanoverSummit 1988 107; inflation and105, 109–11, 117; Inter-Governmental Conference (IGC)108, 109; internal market,completion of 107, 108; labourmobility 128; long-term case for124–7; lower interest rates 104;meaning 103–4; mini EMU seemini EMU; monetary union,definition of see monetaryunion; options and 104; politicaldimensions of 109–13;preconditions for 107; pricestability 125; principle ofparallelism 104; public finance125–6; public finances,

Page 324: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

INDEX

307

implications for 113–16;seigniorage revenue 114, 115,116, 125–6; single currency 104,107, 127; stabilisation gains andlosses 127, 128–34; Stage One13, 16, 94, 107–8; Stage Two16, 84, 91, 94–5, 108, 135;Stage Three 16, 91, 95, 97, 102,108, 123; surprise inflation 109–11; swaps and 104; trade,encouragement of 104;transaction costs 104, 126, 134;transition process 94; transitionto 134–5; unemployment and105, 109, 117; see also monetaryunion

economies of scale 34–6, 143, 150,161, 171

ECU see European Currency UnitEdinburgh Summit 1992 119,

171, 172EEA see European Economic AreaEEC see European Economic

CommunityEFTA see European Free Trade

AssociationEichengreen, B. 87, 105, 127, 128El-Agraa, A. 4, 41, 145, 179elderly: Social Charter and 191EMCF see European Monetary

Cooperation FundEmerson, M. 7, 143, 149, 260, 261employment: Social Charter

and 191EMS see European Monetary

SystemEMU see economic and monetary

unionenlargement of EU 1, 3, 170–87;

Baltic States 187; dynamiccustoms union effects of 174;eastern European states(COMECON block) 185–6;economics of 172–8; EFTAcountries 182–4; Mediterraneanstates 184–5; new applicants181–7; potential applicants 181–7; in practice 178–81; Slovenia187; southern states 180–1;trade effects of 173–4, 175

equal pay 22, 188

equal treatment: right to 191ERM see exchange rate mechanismESCB see European System of

Central BanksESF see Euorpean Social FundEuratom 13Euro-pessimism 3Europe Agreements 185–6European Central Bank (ECB) 16,

95–6, 97, 124, economicindependence 113–16; fiatmoney, right to issue 114;Maastricht Treaty and 116–18;see also central banks

European Coal and SteelCommunity (ECSC) 13, 273

European Community (EC):creation of 13, 178

European Council 20; ECB and 96European Court of Justice 21–2;

composition of 21European Currency Unit (ECU)

51–3, 91, 95, 133; currencycomposition of 51–2;divergence indicator 52–3; hardECU 94

European Economic Area (EEA)2, 9, 13, 168, 182–3, 254

European Economic Community(EEC): creation of 12, 13

European Free Trade Association(EFTA) 1, 2, 6, 119, 171,182–4; bilateral agreements with2; creation of 12, 13; specialrelationship with EU 9, 168

European Investment Bank (EIB)272–3

European Monetary CooperationFund (EMCF) 51

European Monetary Institute (EMI)13, 51, 95, 123, 135

European Monetary System (EMS)9, 45–67, 103, 105; backgroundto 49–50; Basle-Nyborgagreements 59; Britain and 13,45–6, 50, 51, 60, 61, 83, 100,101, 103, 119, 120; CAP and49–50; as crawling peg 1979–8353, 56; currency realignment58–9, 83, 106, 107; currencyupheavals 1992–93 45–6, 48, 49,

Page 325: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

INDEX

308

60–1, 83, 100–1; divergenceindicator 51, 52–3; ECU 51–2;EMU and 45; establishment of13; excess credibility 59;exchange rate mechanism seeexchange rate mechanism;France and 56; gold standardand see gold standard; inflation57–9; Italy and 51, 61, 83, 100,101, 103, 119, 120; keyprovisions of 50–3; lira,withdrawal of 2, 46, 61, 83,100, 101, 103, 119, 120; miniEMU see mini EMU; monetarystability 15; new EMS 1988–9259–60; objectives of 45; oldEuropean monetary system1983–88 56–9; reputationalpolicy theory 57–8; role offoreign exchange market 47–9;Snake and 49, 50, 51; sterling,withdrawal of 2, 45–6, 51, 61,83, 100, 101, 103, 119, 120;Very Short Term FinancingFacility (VSTF) 51, 59; WernerCommittee 50

European monetary union seeeconomic and monetary union(EMU)

European Parliament 20–1;allocation of seats 20–1; co-decision procedure 20; Councilof Ministers and 18; ECB and96; Maastricht Treaty and 20;national representation in 21;political groupings 20, 21;powers of 20

European Regional DevelopmentFund 177, 261; see alsostructural funds

European Social Fund (ESF) 262;see also structural funds

European System of Central Banks(ESCB) 95–6, 108, 116, 117,123; see also central banks

European Union Charter of theFundamental Social Rights ofWorkers see Social Charter

European works council 199Eurosclerosis 14, 158

exchange rate flexibility: economicshocks and 127; exchange rateunion compared 87–91; firmsand 89; international investmentand 88; national currencies 89;small and medium-sized firmsand 89; transaction costs and89; unemployment and 88–9,90; see also currency union

exchange rate mechanism (ERM) 1,50, 134, 147; Black Wednesday61; Britain and 13, 50, 51, 60,61, 83, 100, 101, 103; businesscycles, synchronisation of 61,62, 63; capital controls 61, 62,63; currency realignment 58–9,83, 106, 107; currency upheavals1992–93 45–6, 48, 49, 60–3, 83,100–1; exchange rate bands 9,16, 46–7, 51, 61, 83, 96, 101,106, 120, 123, 135; France and61, 101; Germany and 9, 60–1,101; intervention to maintainbilateral exchange rate 51;Ireland and 101; Italy and 2,46, 51, 61, 83, 100, 101, 103,119, 120; lira, withdrawal of 2,46, 51, 61, 83, 100, 101, 103,119, 120; management of 46–7;Netherlands and 9, 101;Portugal and 50, 51, 100, 101;purchasing power parity (PPP)63–4; Spain and 50, 51, 100,101; speculative runs againstcurrencies 2, 48–9, 60–1, 83,100–1, 122; sterling, withdrawalof 2, 45–6, 50, 51, 61, 83, 100,101, 103, 119, 120; uncoveredinterest parity 65–7

exchange rate system: automaticadjustment and 70–3; fixedexchange rate regimes see fixedexchange rate regimes

exchange rate union 85, 93,currency union compared 87–91; degrees of monetary union85–6; exchange rate uncertaintyand 87, 88; flexible exchangerates system compared 87–91;international investment and 88;monetary policy 89, 90;

Page 326: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

INDEX

309

transaction costs 89;unemployment and 88–9, 90; seealso monetary union

excise duties 148, 160, 163,164, 165

FDI see foreign direct investmentFeldstein, M. 105fiat money: right to issue 114Financial Instrument for Fisheries

Guidance (FIFG) 272financial services: free movement

of 147, 152Finland: currency union and 102;

EFTA membership 12, 13; EUmembership 13, 102, 182,183, 184

firms: exchange rate flexibility and89; see also companies; small andmedium-sized enterprises

fiscal barriers 148–9, 154, 160fixed exchange rate regimes:

deflationary bias of 73–6foreign direct investment (FDI):

Japan 33, 167–8, 180, 223–37;United States 33, 180, 224–5

foreign exchange market 47–9;devaluations 48–9; interest rateincreases 48–9; speculative runsagainst currencies 2, 48–9,60–1, 83, 100–1, 122

Fortress Europe 33, 167, 168,231, 232

France: competition policy 245;deflationary pressures 61; ECSCmembership 13; EEC and 12;EMS and 56; EMU Stage Three102; ERM and 61, 101;exchange and capital controls,abolition of 92; excise duties163; franc fort policy 62, 80;gold standard and 69, 71, 76;inflation 106; intra-EU trade 10;mergers 245; mini EMU 120;Mitterand government 15, 56;monetary union with Belgium,Italy and Switzerland 105;openness of 10; privatisationprogramme 155; referendum onMaastricht Treaty 99–100;relations with Germany 101;

speculative attacks on franc 101;works councils 199

Franco, Francisco 181free intercirculation union 85,

degrees of monetary integration86; see also monetary union

free movement of factors 5, 176,see also capital; goods; labour;services

free trade areas 5–6freedom of association: right

to 191freedom of movement: right

of 191Friedman, M. 88, 130frontier controls: removal of 9,

146–7, 148, 152, 154, 260;Schengen Agreement 9; see alsobarriers to trade

futures: EMU and 104 Gatsios, K. 253General Agreement on Tariffs and

Trade (GATT) 4; CAP and218–21; EU and 9; UruguayRound 4, 218, 219–20, 222

Germany: as anti-inflation anchor60–1, 62; Bundesbank 60–1, 62,89, 109, 121; ECSC membership13; EEC and 12; EMUStageThree 102; ERM and 60–1, 101; exchange rate bands 9;foreign direct investment in231; gold standard and 70, 72,73; Great Depression and 74;inflation 106; interest rates 48,60, 86; Japan, foreign directinvestment by 231; Kohladministration 15; labour costsin 192; merger policies 243;mini EMU 120; openness of10; privatisation programme155; relations with France 101;reunification, effects of 61, 63,101, 107, 122, 186; shift work194; VAT 163, 164; workscouncils 199

Gittelman, M. 227globalisation of business 4, 5gold standard 68–82; automatic

adjustment 70–3; Belgium 76;

Page 327: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

INDEX

310

Britain and 70, 72–3, 75, 77;Canada 76; constrainedeconomies 69–70, 71; deficits70; deflationary bias of 69, 70–6, 80; devaluation and 75–6;France 69, 71, 76; Germany 70,72, 73; Great Depression and73–6; Japan 76; Netherlands 76;surpluses 70; unconstrainedeconomies 69–70, 71;unemployment and 69, 71;United States 69–70, 71, 76

Goodhart, C.A.E. 87, 104goods: free movement of 5, 91Gordon, D.B. 58, 109Grahl, J. 152Great Depression 69, 73–6;

recovery from 76–80Greece: CAP and 180–1; Cohesion

Fund and 272; currency ratios114; currency union and 102;effects of EU membership 180–1; EMS and 50, 100;enlargement of EU and 186;EU membership 1, 13, 178,189; exchange and capitalcontrols 92; inflation 117;Integrated MediterraneanProgrammes 181; labour costsin 192; maternity leave 197;structural funds 180–1

Grilli, V.U. 89, 114, 115Gros, D. 85–6, 88Guidance Section of the European

Agricultural Guidance andGuarantee Fund (EAGGF) 262,see also structural funds

Haaland, I.J. 2, 183Hanover Summit 1988 107Harden, I. 95Harris, P. 156Healey, Nigel M. 2, 4, 7, 33, 46,

58, 60, 76, 84, 90, 96, 99, 113,114, 139, 254

health and safety: protection inpregnancy 198; Social Charterand 191; standards 147, 160,165, 189; working time 194–5

Heitger, B. 167Hill, A. 253

Hirschman, A.O. 256history of EU 12–17Holtham, G. 53home market rule 239House of Lords Committee on

European integration 8Hughes, K. 34, 253Huhne, C. 7Hungary: see also eastern

EuropeEurope Agreements185–6

IBRD see International Bank for

Reconstruction andDevelopment

Iceland: EFTA membership 12, 13IMF see International Monetary

Fundindirect taxation systems 146, 160Indonesia: ASEAN and 5industrial decline: structural funds

and 263, 265inflation: Britain 60, 61, 117;

currency ratios and 114, 116;EMS and 57–9; EMU and 105,109–11, 117; France 106;Germany 106; Greece 117; Italy117; Portugal 117; Spain 117;surprise, political appeal of109–11

Ingersent, K.A. 218institutional structure of EU 17–

22; Commission 17–18; Councilof Ministers 18–20; EuropeanCouncil 20; European Court ofJustice 21–2; EuropeanParliament 18, 20–1

Integrated MediterraneanProgrammes 181

Inter-Governmental Conference(IGC) 16, 93, 108, 109, 203

internal market see single Europeanmarket

International Bank forReconstruction andDevelopment (IBRD) 4

International Monetary Fund (IMF)4

international regionalism: growthof 226–9

Page 328: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

INDEX

311

Ireland: Cohesion Fund and 272;competition laws 254; currencyunion and 102; EFTAmembership 13; enlargement ofEU and 186; ERM and 101;EU membership 13, 178;exchangeand capital controls 92;excise duties 163; SchengenAgreement and 9

Italy: competition laws 254;currency union and 102;deflationary pressures 61; ECSCmembership 13; EEC and 12;ERM and 2, 46, 51, 61, 83,100, 101, 103, 119, 120;exchange and capital controls,abolition of 92; inflation 117;monetary union with Belgium,France and Switzerland 105;privatisation programme 155;seigniorage revenue 126;withdrawal of lira from ERM 2,46, 51, 61, 83, 100, 101, 103,119, 120

Jackman, R. 196Japan: foreign direct investment 33,

167–8, 180, 223–37; goldstandard and 76; income level11; investment in EU 229–36;local sourcing 233–5; managerialautonomy 235–6; populationsize 11; research anddevelopment 236; rules oforigin and 167; work methods199–200; see also Triad

Jenkins, R. 50Johnson, H.G. 174Johnson, P. 205joint ventures 155 Kaldor, N. 257Kenya 8Keynes, John Maynard 68, 71, 80Kitson, Michael 78Kohl administration 15Kotios, A. 192, 202Krugman, P. 46Kydland, F. 109

labour: free movement of 5, 91,128, 143, 145, 147, 152, 160,176, 189; see also workers

Levine, P. 76, 82, 87, 90, 96, 99,104, 107, 114

Liechtenstein: EFTAmembership 13

life insurance services 152Lintner, Valerio 12, 174lira: withdrawal from ERM 2, 46,

51, 61, 83, 100, 101, 103,119, 120

Liverpool model 129–30, 133, 135living conditions: improvement of

191local content rules 167Lomax, D.F. 95Lucas, R.E. 129Lucas critique 129Luxembourg: ECSC membership

13; EEC and 12; EMU and102, 118; mini EMU 120;monetary union with Belgium 5,122; openness of 10

Luxembourg Compromise 13, 14,15, 189

Maastricht Treaty 1, 13, 16, 17, 83,

188, 203–4; convergence criteria95, 96–9, 117–19, 184; currencyunion and 87, 91–102, 103;Danish referendum on 2, 99,205; ECB and 116–18; ESCBand 116; European Parliament,powers of 20; exchange andcapital controls 92–3; Frenchreferendum on 99–100;maintenance of price stability95; monetary union 92, 93, 171,260; overview of 93–6;prospects of implementation99–102; Protocol on SocialPolicy 203–4; ratification of 2,101, 124, 172, 255; rationale of91–3; regional policy 261; SocialChapter 203–4; subsidiarity204, 254

McDonald, Frank 4, 143, 152, 156MacDougall, D. 128McKenzie, G. 152, 159

Page 329: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

INDEX

312

MacSharry reforms see underCommon Agricultural Policy(CAP)

Madrid Summit 1990 108mail order shopping 154Major, J. 165Malaysia: ASEAN and 5Malta: EU membership and 184–5market-sharing arrangements 240Markusen, J.R. 224Masson, P. 129, 131, 132, 133maternity benefits 198–9maternity leave 197–8Matthews, K. 130Maximum Guaranteed Quantity

(MGQ) 213Mazey, S. 12, 174Meade, J. 58Mediterranean states see Cyprus;

Greece; Malta; Portugal; Spain;Turkey

Merger Regulation 239, 243Merger Treaty 13mergers 243–7; ATR/De Havilland

244, 246; control of 166; cross-border 155; 1992 programmeand 162, 166; size of 246–7;small and medium-sizedcompanies 162

Mergers Task Force 244Mexico: NAFTA and 5Michie, Jonathan 79Minford, Patrick 129, 131, 132, 133mini EMU: advantages of 120;

emergence of 119–20; shapeof 120–3

Mitterand government 15, 56Molle, W.T.M. 88monetary union 84–5, 92, 93, 105,

173, 177–8, 260, Belgium andLuxembourg 5, 122; benefits of87–91; costs of 87–91; currencyunion 84–5, 86; definition 84;degrees of monetary integration85–7; exchange rate union 85,96; free intercirculation union85; preconditions for 107;Werner Plan 85; see alsoeconomic and monetary union;single currency

monopolies 166, 241–3; Article 90248–51; relevant marketdefinition 241–2; statemonopolies 248;telecommunications industry249–50; tying agreements 242

Morgan, Eleanor J. 245Morsink, R.L.A. 88Multimod model 129, 131, 133,

135Munday, M. 233Mundell, R.A. 127, 224Myrdal, G. 176, 256 NAFTA see North American Free

Trade AgreementNelson, H. 163Netherlands: ECSC membership

13; EEC and 12; EMU StageThree 102; ERM and 101;exchange rate bands 9, 123;gold standard and 76; interestrates 86; mini EMU 120; workscouncils 199

Neumann, M. 57, 58, 127Nevin, E. 7newly industrialised countries

(NICs) 171Nicholson, F. 181Nicolaides, P. 231Nicoll, W. 17night work 194–51992 programme 1, 2, 13, 14–15,

157, 158, 171, 173, EFTA andsee European Economic Area;long-term implications of166–9; merger boom 162, 166;removal of capital exchangecontrols 59; Single EuropeanAct (SEA) and 159–61; socialdimension 165–6; see also singleEuropean market

non-tariff barriers (NTBs) 22,32–3, 140, 260, 261; frontiercontrols 9, 146–7, 148, 152,154, 260; health and safety rules147, 160; public procurementpractices 147–8, 161, 260;removal of 32–3, 150; safetystandards 260, 261; technical

Page 330: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

INDEX

313

barriers 147–8, 160, 260, 261;welfare effects of 140–6

Nordic states: accession to EU 19;see also Denmark; Finland;Iceland; Norway; Sweden

Norman, George 224, 225North American Free Trade

Agreement (NAFTA) 5, 8, 9Norway: currency union and 102;

EFTA membership 12, 13; EUmembership 13, 182, 183, 184;Great Depression and 75;hostility to EU 2; referendumon EC membership 13, 183

openness of EU member states10–11; Denmark 10; France 10;Germany 10; Luxembourg 10

opt-out clauses 9; Britain’s opt-outfrom Social Chapter 9, 203;Britain’s opt-out from SocialCharter 190, 204

optimum currency area 128, 130options: EMU and 104origin: rules of 167overtime 194–5 Papandreou, Mrs Vasso 193, 198parallel currency union see

currencyunionparallelism: principle of 104part-time work 195–7, 198Paterson, I. 202Pearlman, J. 96pensions: provision of 22Perlman, M. 105Perroux, F. 257personal imports 148, 154Philippines: ASEAN and 5Phillips Curve 109–13Poland: Europe Agreements 185–6;

see also eastern Europepopulation of EU member states

9, 10Portugal: accession to EU 1, 13,

178, 189; Cohesion Fund and272; competition laws 254;currency ratios 114; currencyunion and 102; effects of EUmembership 181;EFTAmembership 12, 13; EMS

and 50; enlargement of EU and186; ERM and 50, 51, 100, 101;exchange and capital controls92; inflation 117; labour costsin 192; maternity leave 197;shift work 194

pregnancy: protection in 197–9Prescott, E.G. 109Prescott, K. 152presidency of the Council of

Europe 19President of the Commission 17Preston, J. 152prevailing parities defence 92price fixing 240privatisation programmes

155–6, 248Product Liability Directive

1985 159proportional representation 14Protocol on Social Policy 200, 203,

see also Social Chapterpublic procurement practices

147–8, 161, 260purchasing power parity (PPP)

63–4 qualified majority voting 19, 189,

194quotas: welfare effects of 140–6 Rayner, A.J. 220real business cycle theory 129recession in EU 2, 122redundancy payments 196regional policy of EU 255–75;

additionality principle 270–2;backwash effects 257; CohesionFund 193, 205, 272; CommunityProgrammes (CPs) 270, 271;Community Support Framework(CSF) 269; competition policyregulations for state aids 273;convergent growth theories256–9; cumulative growthmodels 256–7; divergentgrowththeories 256–9; economicand social cohesion and 259–61;European Coal and SteelCommunity (ECSC) 273;European Investment Bank

Page 331: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

INDEX

314

(EIB) 272–3; FinancialInstrument for FisheriesGuidance (FIFG) 272; growthpole theory 257; MaastrichtTreaty 261; manufacturingindustries 257; moderncumulative growth theories 257;Operational Programmes (OPs)269–70; partnership approach267–8; programming system269–70; research and analysis ofregional problems 273–4; spreadeffects 257; structural funds seestructural funds; subsidiarity and268; trickle-down effects 257;Verdoorn’s Law 257

regional trade blocs see trade blocsregulated industries 247–50remuneration, fair 190, 191reputational policy theory 57–8restrictive practices 239–41Rhodes, M. 189, 193Rogoff, K. 113Rollo, J. 186Romania: Europe Agreements 185–

6; see also eastern EuropeRome Summit 1990 108Rubin, M. 196rules of origin 167rural areas: structural funds and

263, 265 Sala-i-Martin, X. 256, 259Salmon, T.C. 17Santer, Jacques 17Sapir, A. 240Sargent, T.J. 99Schafers, M. 192, 202Schengen Agreement 9; Britain

and 9; Denmark and 9; Irelandand 9

Scrivener, Christiane 164SEA see Single European ActSeabright, P. 253seigniorage revenue 114, 115, 116,

125–6services: free movement of 5, 91,

147, 260set-aside 212, 215, 221, see also

Common Agricultural Policyshift work 194–5

shocks: Liverpool model 129–30,133, 135; Multimod model 129,131, 133, 135

Siebert, W. 194, 205Simpson, L. 202Singapore: ASEAN and 5Single Administrative

Document 160single currency 1, 16, 260, benefits

of 104; Delors Report 93, 107;EMU and 104, 106, 127; see alsocurrency union; EuropeanCurrency Unit; monetary union

Single European Act (SEA) 13, 15,63, 91, 93, 139, 158, 189–90,232; 1992 programme and 159–61; political economy of 157–69; qualified majority voting189, 194; Social Charter and190; veto powers and 14, 15

single European market (SEM): seealso 1992 programmebarriers totrade see barriers to trade;Cecchini Report 149–52;companies, restructuring of154–6; creation of 146–9; crossborder shopping 148, 149;economic rationale for 139–46;fiscal barriers, removal of148–9, 154; frontier controls,removal of 146–7, 148, 152,154, 260; launch of 1; personalimports 148, 154; physicalbarriers, removal of 146–7;post-1992 position 152–6; publicprocurement practices and147–8, 161, 260; regional effectof programme 152; state aids148; Sutherland Report 153–4;technical barriers, removal of147–8, 260; unemployment and152; VAT and 148–9, 154;White Paper on 13, 15, 139,146, 147, 148, 153, 158–9,162, 163

single market see single Europeanmarket

‘the Six’ 13, 17, 40, 178Slovak Republic:

EuropeAgreements 185–6; seealso eastern Europe

Page 332: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

INDEX

315

Slovenia: membership of EU 187small and medium sized enterprises

(SMEs): exchange rate flexibilityand 89; merger boom 162; newlaws and 153; see alsocompanies; firms

Smith, A. 186Smith, S. 163Smithsonian Agreement 49Snake 49, 50, 51Social Action Programme 193–4;

Britain and 200–3, 205; parttimework 195–7; protection inpregnancy 197–9; temporarywork 195–7; workerrepresentation 199–200; workingtime 194–5

Social Chapter 203; Britain’s opt-out 9, 203

Social Charter 165, 190–1, 204;Britain’s opt out 190, 204;fundamental social rights 191;SEA and 190; Social ActionProgramme see Social ActionProgramme; unemploymentand 201

social dumping 165, 190,192–3, 195

social protection: right to 191Social Protocol 200, 203, see also

Social ChapterSolomou, S. 78sovereignty 133, 173, 177–8Spain: CAP and 181; Cohesion

Fund and 272; currency ratios114; currency union and 102;devaluation in 101; effects ofEU membership 181; EFTAmembership 12, 13; EMSmembership 50; enlargementof EU and 186; ERM and 50,51, 100, 101; EU membership1, 13, 178, 189; exchange andcapital controls 92; exciseduties 163; Francodictatorship 181; inflation 117;shift work 194; temporaryworking 196

state aids 148, 239, 250–2, 273Stehn, J. 167Stein, J.L. 34, 256

sterling: withdrawal from ERM 2,45–6, 50, 51, 61, 83, 100, 101,103, 119, 120

structural funds 177, 261–72;additionality principle 270–2;Community Programmes (CPs)270, 271; Community SupportFramework (CSF) 269;concentration of policyassistance 265, 267; EuropeanRegional Development Fund177, 261; European Social Fund(ESF) 262; five priorityobjectives 262–5; GuidanceSection of the EuropeanAgricultural Guidance andGuarantee Fund (EAGGF) 262;lagging regions 262; long-termunemployed and 264;Operational Programmes (OPs)269–70; partnership approach267–8; regions affected byindustrial decline 263, 265; ruralareas 263, 265

subsidiarity 190, 204–5, 254, 268subsidies see state aidsSumner, M.T. 88supply-side reform 14–15Sutherland Report 153–4Swann, D. 152swaps: EMU and 104Sweden: currency union and 102;

EFTA membership 12, 13;EU membership 13, 102, 182,183, 184

Switzerland 2; EFTA membership12, 13; monetary union withBelgium, France and Italy 105

Symansky, S. 131, 132, 133

Tanzania 8tariffs 22, 32–3, Common External

Tariff 140; Variable Levy 177;welfare effects of 32–3, 140–6;see also barriers to trade

Teague, P. 152technical barriers 147–8, 160,

260, 261technological dumping 202telecommunications industry 4,

249–50

Page 333: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

INDEX

316

Temperton, P. 63temporary work 195–7Tetra Pak 242–3Thailand: ASEAN and 5Tharakan, P.K.M. 231Thatcher, M. 165, 205Thatcher government 15, 180Thirwall, A.P. 257Thomsen, S. 231trade blocs 171; concentric circles

8–9; regional 5, 8–9; zones ofdifferential integration 8–9

trade creation: customs union and27–32, 33, 34

trade diversion: customs union and29–32, 34

Trade Union Reform andEmployment Rights Act1993 198

training: right to 191transaction costs: currency union

and 89, 126; EMU and 104,126, 134; exchange rateflexibility and 89; exchange rateunion and 89

transport industry 160, 166Treaty on European Union see

Maastricht TreatyTreaty of Paris 13Treaty of Rome 12, 13, 17, 63, 93,

140, 157, 178, 188, 204; Article85 see Article 85; Article 86 seeArticle 86; Article 90 248–51;Article 92 250–2; publicenterprises 248; social policy188; state aids 250–2; statemonopolies 248

Triad 14, emergence of 224–5;population and income 11;regional core networks 227, 229;see also Japan; United States

Tsoukalis, L. 180Turkey: Association Agreement

184; EU membership 184–5‘two-speed’ Europe 9, 84, 102, 120tying agreements 242 Uganda 8uncovered interest parity 65–7unemployment 82, 122, 145, 158,

175, 176; CAP, effects of 179;

currency union and 88–9, 90;deflationary policies and 69;EMU and 105, 109, 117;exchange rate union and 88–9,90; flexible exchange rates and88–9, 90; gold standard and 69,71; Great Depression see GreatDepression; monetary policyand 90–1; natural rate of 88,90; SEM programme and 152;Social Charter and 201;structural funds and 264

UNICE 194United States: CAP and 218–21;

drought of 1988 212, 214, 221;foreign direct investment 33,180, 224–5; gold standard and69–70, 71, 76; Great Depressionand 73, 75; income level 11;NAFTA and 5; population size11; see also Triad

Value Added Tax (VAT) 148–9,

154, 163, 164–5; exemptions154; reclaiming 149; zero—rating 148, 149, 154

van der Ploeg, F. 60Van Miert, Karel 253Vanhaverbeke, W. 127variable geometry of EU 9, 134Variable Levy 177Vaubel, R. 84, 85Venables, T. 152, 159Verdoorn’s Law 257Very Short Term Financing Facility

(VSTF) 51, 59veto powers: Luxembourg

Compromise 13, 14, 15; SEAand 14, 15

Vickerman, R.W. 7, 152Viner, J. 27, 29, 33vocational training: right to 191von Hagen, J. 57, 127Vredling Directive 199 wage costs 192–3, see also social

dumpingWallace, N. 99welfare effects: of common

markets 143, 145–6, 150–2; ofcustoms union 22–40; of

Page 334: The Economics of the New Europe: From Community to Union

INDEX

317

economic integration 22–40;economies of experience 36–7;economies of scale 34–6, 143,150, 171; of EU 24–32, 175; ofNTBs 24–32, 140–6; ofprotectionism 22–4, 140–6; ofquotas 140–6; reduced X-inefficiency 39–40, 143, 145;reduced economic rents 38–9;of subsidies to domesticproducers 142; of tariffs 140–6;tariffs versus non-tariffbarriers 32–3

Welford, R. 152Werner Committee 50Werner Plan 85Whiteford, E. 203Williamson, J. 53Winters, L.A. 41, 180women: maternity benefits 198–9;

maternity leave 197–8; part-timeand temporary work 197, 198;protection in pregnancy 197–9

worker representation 165, 191,199–200, draft directive on 199;Vredling Directive 199; see alsoworkers

workers: collective bargaining 191;European Union Charter of theFundamental Social Rights ofWorkers see Social Charter; freemovement of 5, 91, 128, 143,

145, 147, 152, 160, 176, 189;freedom of association 191;health and safety see health andsafety; part-time 195–7;pregnancy, protection in 197–9;redundancy payments 196;remuneration 190, 191;representation see workerrepresentation; rights 190;temporary 195–7;vocationaltraining, right to 191;women see women; workingconditions, improvement of191; see also workerrepresentation; working time;works councils

working conditions: improvementof 191

working time 194–5; draft directiveon 194; night work 194–5; shiftwork 194–5

works councils 199–200World Bank 4 X-inefficiency: customs union and

39–40, 143, 145 Yannopoulos, G.N. 180Young, J.H. 46, 87

Zis, George 88