the bottom billion or a logical argument against rebellions

Upload: saed-kakei

Post on 07-Apr-2018

214 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 8/4/2019 The Bottom Billion or a Logical Argument Against Rebellions

    1/7

    Kakei 0

    The bottom billion or a logical argument against rebellions

    A review of:Collier, P. (2007). The Bottom Billion: Why the Poorest Countries are Failing and WhatCan Be Done About It. Oxford: Oxford University Press, $35.00, Hardback, 224 pp.ISBN: 978-0-19-531145-7

    By:

    Saed Kakei, Ph.D. Student,

    CARD 5000 DL1/Book Review Assignment

    Professor Cheryl Duckworth, Ph.D.

    Nova Southeastern Universitys Department of Conflict Analysis & Resolution PhD Program

    September 18, 2011

  • 8/4/2019 The Bottom Billion or a Logical Argument Against Rebellions

    2/7

    Kakei 1

    The bottom billion or a logical argument against rebellions

    When a notable scholar writes a book, he or she usually uses a holistic approach for the

    topic of his or her book. Paul Collier,1 a celebrated scholar whose work rarely covers a

    thorough understanding of the multidimensional conflict, has written a controversial book

    in 2007 on the failing states with the title of The Bottom Billion.

    In this book, Collier intuitively argues that the proper attention for todays poorest

    countries should be on development efforts. This is because citizens of these countries

    have not been empowered to show some economic growth. According to Collier, these

    sovereign countries are forming fifty-eight states and are home to fewer than one billion

    of the six billion population of our world in 2007. Collier provides that seventy percent of

    the bottom billion live in Africa. Therefore, for proper referencing, he developed the term

    Africa + for the poorest countries of the world that happen to develop far less

    governing experience (2007, p.7). Collier goes on to brand leaders of the bottom billion

    as villains, crooked politicians, and rebels who are starving children (P. 7). With

    such haughtiness, Collier attempts to hide faults of the past colonialist powers and greed

    of current neocolonialists which left permanent damages on the lives of people residing

    in the worlds poorest countries.

    In Part 2 of his book, made of five parts comprising eleven chapters, Collier

    argues that the poorest countries are failing because of one or more of the four traps. He

    identifies these traps as civil war, the natural resources trap, landlocked with bad

    neighbors, and bad governance in a small country (Pp. 17-75). Throughout his book,

    1Paul Collier is a British Professor of Economics at Oxford University. He was the head of research at the

    World Bank. Collier is an expert on the underdeveloped countries of Sub-Saharan Africa.

  • 8/4/2019 The Bottom Billion or a Logical Argument Against Rebellions

    3/7

    Kakei 2

    Collier mentions statistical data from research studies without providing a single figure,

    continuum or chart to help explain his claims. This is not to discount the twenty-two

    references provided under the rubric of Research on Which This Book Is Based (Pp.

    193-95).

    Collier states that countries of the bottom billion did miss the boat because they

    didnt show economic growth. Besides, when it comes to international trade

    competitions, these failing states are in no position to compete with fast developing

    countries like China and India. Collier provides that China and India have been actively

    supplying western markets with competitive yet cheap labour intensive goods and

    services (Pp. 79-96). He furthers that, except for exploiting natural resources, private

    capital from developed countries will not easily flow to these troubling countries.

    Consequently, the only viable option to keep residents of the Worlds poorest countries

    from sinking into further miseries is to keep the flow of international aid (Pp. 46-8).

    Collier suggests that for international aid to make a difference, checks and

    balances must be put in place (P. 100). Otherwise, foreign aid will end up in the wrong

    hands funding the wrong causes. To manage aid for turnaround purposes, Collier

    suggests economic incentives should follow strict reforms (P. 103). He elaborates that

    with governance conditionality and careful capacity building measures, more aid could

    achieve turnarounds (P. 110; p. 184). Else, fragile turnarounds could tip backward and

    become liabilities for aid providing developed countries. For example, trained with

    western aid, skilled but unemployed citizens of the bottom billion will end-up migrating

    to the west (Pp. 93-6). Then, these migrants not only will sympathize with rebellions

  • 8/4/2019 The Bottom Billion or a Logical Argument Against Rebellions

    4/7

    Kakei 3

    back in their home countries, but also may involve in terrorist activities against their host

    states!

    Collier concludes his aid argument by stating that aid alone will not save the

    failing states from the four traps that he identified. Therefore, he suggests a few other

    options. Most strikingly, by committing a small size mandated military intervention to

    last no less than ten years (P. 124). In concert with this, Collier recommends introducing

    changes to laws and charters to fight corruption, strengthen codes of accountability and

    transparency, and introduce charters on democracy (Pp. 135-56). Finally, he asks for

    diversifying failing states export capacities and broadening their access to the markets of

    the developed countries with trade preferences (P. 167).

    Although much of Colliers argument about the economic causes of conflict is

    noteworthy, it is equally important to identify some of the pitfalls which the thesis of his

    book holds. For example, Colliers four traps are all based on a single yet important cause

    of conflict. That cause undoubtedly is economic. However, without meeting the

    psychological needs of humans, the economyas a tangible needmay not be part of

    the core values of any society. Collier not only ridicules this, but also he sacks it. To

    augment economics as the most critical cause of conflict, Collier sarcastically says: I

    hear the phrase root causes a lot. It is bandied about at many of the conferences on

    conflict to which I am invited. Surprisingly frequently, a hypothesized root cause turns

    out to be predictable if you already know the hobbyhorse of the speaker (P. 22). With

    this statement, Collier indirectly tells his readers that he takes everything at face value. In

    other words, Collier uses economic statistics based on quantitative research methods to

    assert what he perceives as the only cause for conflict.

  • 8/4/2019 The Bottom Billion or a Logical Argument Against Rebellions

    5/7

    Kakei 4

    Collier drew his description of the proneness to war based on variables of

    intrastate wars. To his surmise, abstract data taken from the Correlates of War (COW) led

    him to conclude that [a]s an approximation, a typical low-income country faces a risk of

    civil war of about 14 percent in any five-year period (P. 20). Collier draws his

    conclusion from this description assuming that because low income means poverty, and

    low growth means hopelessness, young unemployed men in pursuit of easy money

    become recruits for rebel armies (P. 20).

    As a former Kurdish rebel myself, I find such a conclusion not only faulty, but

    also distastefully offensive. Just as not all economists think and work for a symmetric

    motive, not all rebels fight for a similar cause. If only Collier be fair in his conflict

    studies, he will surely see a conflict as a multidimensional event occurring between two

    or more interacting yet incompatible parties while trying to achieve their intended goals.

    In other words, not all conflicts have economic causes. Also, not all rebels and their

    rebellions are economically motivated. I am sure that Collier knows the various

    differences of human needs and interests. If not, he could read them from the work of

    Abraham Maslow (1970).

    It is a common knowledge that governments, as well as rebellion organizations,

    around the worldbe them democratic, autocratic or otherwise; do not release true

    figures regarding their intrastate civil war casualties. This is because casualties have

    political, social and economic consequences. Therefore, data collected by the COW

    project on combat casualties of wars occurred from 1816 to 2007 is highly questionable.

    It is either based on statistical assumptions or represents abstracts taken from the warring

    parties. For instance, Version4.1 of the Intrastate War Data (Sarkees & Wayman, 2010)

  • 8/4/2019 The Bottom Billion or a Logical Argument Against Rebellions

    6/7

    Kakei 5

    provides inaccurate data on Kurdish rebellions in Iraq.2 When I compared the COWs

    data on other Iraqi intrastate wars as Kurds being a party to, I discovered deliberate data

    manipulation as well as critical data exclusion. Against all historical records on Iraq, the

    authors of the COW project are accusing the Kurds for massacring 1,000 Assyrians in

    1933. Additionally, their collected data holds the Kurds responsible for initiating two

    intrastate wars. More strikingly, however, the data does not show any records for Saddam

    Husseins usage of chemical gas against Kurdish civilians and their Peshmarga forces

    (freedom fighters) in 1987, 1988, and 1989.3

    As widely reported, the fall of Halabjathen had a population of 65,000 Kurds

    into the hands of the Peshmarga forces, had driving Saddam to his insanity. On March 16,

    1988, the deposed Iraqi tyrant permitted his cousin, Ali Hassan Al-Majeed (a.k.a.

    Chemical Ali), to bomb the town by deadly combinations of chemical gas. The instant

    outcome of the massacre was at least 5,000 innocent civilians and approximately 350

    Peshmargas. Therefore, if the COW statistics represent a body of comprehensive data,

    as hailed by Collier, then why critical data had been manipulated and omitted? One

    wonders that if the quality of the data on Kurdish rebellions is problematic as such, what

    2Version 4.1 of the Intrastate War Data released by the COW in 2010 does not show any records on two

    Kurdish rebellions occurred during the first half of the twentieth century. The first rebellion is known as the1919-21 Sheikh Mahmoud Hafidh rebellion against the British Colonial occupation of Iraq. The secondrebellion is known as the 1934-35 Barzan rebellion. Mullah Mustafa Barzani led this rebellion againstGreat Britains backed Iraqi monarchy. Data collected by the British Foreign Office on these two intrastatewars show annual combat casualties exceeding the threshold of 1,000 combat casualties in a given year set

    by the authors of the COW.3Celebrated students concede that unless a warring party is guilty of a crime, sustains heavy casualties, and

    feels desperate to survive, weapons of mass killings may never be a conventional choice for such a party.The main reason why Saddams regime decided to gas the Kurds from late 1986 until early 1989 wasbecause the Peshmarga forces, or Kurdish rebels as Collier wishes to call them, had changed their hit andrun tactics to embrace a front-line war kinetics. With such a manoeuvre, Kurdish rebels were able to kill atleast 10,000 Iraqi soldiers during the said period. Additionally, they were able to liberate seven Kurdishtowns each with a population of at least 20,000. As for the rebels themselves, they lost fewer than 1,000armed Peshmargas. For more on this subject, see David McDowalls 3rd edition book titled: A ModernHistory of the Kurds, P.p. 352-63.

  • 8/4/2019 The Bottom Billion or a Logical Argument Against Rebellions

    7/7

    Kakei 6

    about the quality of data in relation to so many other non-state actors involved in

    intrastate wars.

    Collier wholeheartedly believes that with semi-autocratic reforms enforced by

    governance conditionality and intended aid packages, the failing states could be saved.

    If not, he is of the opinion that these failing states could be bombed and occupied with

    limited yet long lasting military interventions. Ironically, however, as Collier has

    identified the economic traps of the bottom billion, he also has showing the reader some

    of his own communication traps. The communication traps of Collier include: name-

    calling (e.g., villains and crooked politicians), inapt questioning (e.g., Ask each third-

    world army where it got its money? (P. xii)), and logical argument (e.g., Each rich, resource

    hungry country is locked into a prisoners dilemma of inaction (P. 52)).

    Bibliography

    Collier, P. (2007). The Bottom Billion: Why the Poorest Countries are Failing and WhatCan Be Done About It. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Maslow, A. (1970).Motivation and personality (2nd ed.).New York: Harper & Row.McDowall, D. (2007).A Modern History of the Kurds. London: I.B. Tauris.Sarkees, M. R., & Wayman, F. (2010).Resort to War: 1816 - 2007. CQ Press.