_slides - lecture9

Upload: mohanad-dahlan

Post on 05-Apr-2018

229 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 8/2/2019 _slides - Lecture9

    1/15

    Financial Option Pricing

    Lecture 9

    Arbitrage Based Option Pricing

    Sandra Nolte

    [email protected]

    KE 515Office Hours: TBA

    School of Management, University of Leicester

  • 8/2/2019 _slides - Lecture9

    2/15

    Outline

    Non-Arbitrage Theorem Reminder

    Arbitrage Option Pricing

    Other kind of Options

    30th March 2012 2/

  • 8/2/2019 _slides - Lecture9

    3/15

    Non-Arbitrage Theorem

    We have 3 assets and two states of nature. Assume that the

    states of nature are: a good economy which is state 1 and abad economy which is state 2.

    1. Asset 1 (riskless): bond with price now of1 and returns of

    1+r in both states - where r is the risk free rate.

    2. Asset 2 (risky): a stock with costs now S(t) and will cost in

    the future, at time t + 1, either S1(t + 1) or S2(t + 1)

    3. a call on the underlying stock which costs now c(t) and will

    cost in the future, at time t + 1, either c1(t + 1) or c2(t + 1)

    30th March 2012 3/

  • 8/2/2019 _slides - Lecture9

    4/15

    Non-Arbitrage Theorem

    The non-arbitrage theorem says that if we find positive

    constants,1, 2 so that the system of equations:

    1 = (1 + r)1 + (1 + r)2

    S(t) = S1(t + 1)1 + S2(t + 1)2

    c(t) = c1(t + 1)1 + c2(t + 1)2

    is satisfied, then there are no arbitrage possibilities. And if there

    are no arbitrage opportunities then positive constants, 1, 2

    satisfying the above system of equations can be found.

    Note that we can set: (1 + r)1 = p1, where p1 is some

    probability and (1 + r)2 = p2, is also some probability. Both

    probabilities add up to unity: p1 + p2 = 1.

    30th March 2012 4/

  • 8/2/2019 _slides - Lecture9

    5/15

    Non-Arbitrage Theorem

    If we multiply S(t) with unity 1 = 1+r

    1+r :1 + r

    1 + rS(t) =

    1 + r

    1 + r(S1(t + 1)1 + S2(t + 1)2)

    S(t) =

    1

    1 + r (S1(t + 1)1(1 + r) + S2(t + 1)(1 + r)2)

    S(t) =1

    1 + r(p1S1(t + 1) + p2S2(t + 1))

    Because (1 + r)1 = p1 and since (1 + r)2 = p2

    But p1S1(t + 1) + p2S2(t + 1) is the expected value of the stock

    price, E[S(t + 1)] The above equation can be rewritten as:

    S(t) = 11 + r E[S(t + 1)]

    We can discount the risky stock value at the risk free rate,

    using the probabilities p1 and p2

    30th March 2012 5/

  • 8/2/2019 _slides - Lecture9

    6/15

  • 8/2/2019 _slides - Lecture9

    7/15

    Non-Arbitrage Theorem

    From the third equation: for the call price of 25 2 = 0.5

    From the second equation we get 1 = 0.25.

    From the first equation you get: 1.1 0.2 5 + 1.1 0.5 = 0.825!

    25 must not be the arbitrage free price.

    30th March 2012 7/

  • 8/2/2019 _slides - Lecture9

    8/15

    Non-Arbitrage Theorem

    All concepts we have see so far are based on the assumption of noarbitrage

    Put-Call Parity, volatility smile, binomial tree,..

    Under the assumption of no-arbitrage, we can write the

    Black-Scholes portfolio like d = rdt

    But arbitrage opportunities exist in the real world!

    30th March 2012 8/

  • 8/2/2019 _slides - Lecture9

    9/15

    Arbitrage Option Pricing Model

    Models dealing with arbitrage option pricing are the models by Ilinski

    & Stepanenko (1999) or Fedotov & Panayides (2005), among others.

    The idea here is to introduce an arbitrage return, sayx

    , so thatthe return on the Black-Scholes portfolio, , becomes:

    d = rdt + xdt;

    where r is the risk free rate of interest.

    x can follow a specific random process like the

    Ornstein-Uhlenbeck process as in Ilinski & Stepanenko (1999)

    Named after Leonard Ornstein and George Eugene Uhlenbeck.The process is stationary, Gaussian, and Markov. Over time, the

    process tends to drift towards its long-term mean.

    30th March 2012 9/

  • 8/2/2019 _slides - Lecture9

    10/15

    Arbitrage Option Pricing Model

    This process is defined there as:

    dx

    dt= x(t) + (t)

    where (t) is noise and is the parameter which reflects the

    speed the market reacts on the arbitrage opportunity.

    The derivative price obtained in the Ilinski models is an average

    derivative price

    30th March 2012 10/

  • 8/2/2019 _slides - Lecture9

    11/15

    Arbitrage Option Pricing Model

    Fedotov & Panayides (2005) assume that the fluctuations aroundthe risk free rate of interest are not restricted to follow a

    particular process, like the Ornstein-Uhlenbeck process. More

    general approach.

    2 sources of uncertainty:

    1. fluctuation from the stock (usual geometric Brownian motion)

    dS = Sdt + SdW,

    where W is a Wiener process

    2. uncertainty from a random arbitrage return from the bond

    dB = rBdt + (t)Bdt;where r is the risk free interest rate, B the bond price and

    (t) is some random process (which does NOT have to obey

    any specific stochastic differential equation).

    30th March 2012 11/

  • 8/2/2019 _slides - Lecture9

    12/15

    Arbitrage Option Pricing Model

    They assume that the variations on the risk free return, which

    mimic arbitrage returns, are on a different time scale.

    The time scale is on a scale of hours and denoted by

    As the authors remark, this time lies in between the time scale

    for the stock return (infinitely Brownian motion fluctuations)

    and the maturity time of the derivative (months): 0

  • 8/2/2019 _slides - Lecture9

    13/15

    Arbitrage Option Pricing Model

    Using Itos Lemma, they obtain the classical Black-Scholesequation:

    V

    t+ rS

    V

    S+

    1

    2

    2V

    S22S2 = rV

    But using both uncertainties they obtain:

    V

    t+rS

    V

    S+

    1

    2

    2V

    S22S2+r+(t)+(t)

    V

    SS V

    +

    = rV

    Solving the equation, the authors find that the option price,

    when taking into account arbitrage returns will be of the general

    form: VBS(S) 2

    U(S, )

    where is defined as

    T , U(S, ) is a function of (t) and VBS isthe Black-Scholes option price.

    We get an option pricing interval!

    30th March 2012 13/

  • 8/2/2019 _slides - Lecture9

    14/15

    Other kind of Options

    Employee Stock Options: call options on a companys stockgranted by the company to its employees, see chapter 157 in Hull.

    Options on Currencies: large trades are possible, strike price,

    expiry date and other features tailored to meet the needs of

    corporate treasurers

    Future Options: is the right not the obligation to enter into a

    future contract at a specified time in the future, at a specified

    future price , see chapter 17 in Hull.

    Exotic Options: Packages, Nonstandard American Options

    (Bermuda), Gap Options, Forward Start Options, Cliquet

    Options, Compound Options, Chooser Options, BarrierOptions,Binary Options, Lookback options, Shout Options,

    Asian Options, see chapter 25 in Hull.

    Real Options: Options on real assets

    30th March 2012 14/

  • 8/2/2019 _slides - Lecture9

    15/15

    Readings

    Hull J. C. (2000); Options, Futures and Other Derivatives ;Prentice Hall, Chapter 19.

    Fedotov S., & S. Panayides (2005): Stochastic Arbitrage return

    and its implication for option pricing, Physica A, 345, 207-217.

    Ilinski K. & A. Stepanenko (1999): Derivative pricing with

    virtual arbitrage, Quantitative Finance Papers Nr. 9902046

    30th March 2012 15/