philosophy of tax law

38
1 The Philosophy of Tax KPMG’s Tax Business School ® Victoria Heard Abstract This paper has been written to provide an overview of research relating to taxation undertaken by academics in several different disciplines. Research from the disciplines of philosophy, psychology, the law and economics has been included in this paper together with other work by business commentators and social scientists. This summary hopes to provide a platform from which further research can be commissioned within these differing disciplines in order to gain more insight into how tax is perceived and how frustrations with the tax system from taxpayers, tax gatherers and advisers that are currently gaining publicity could be resolved. The paper begins with the identification of a number of topics where further research would be valuable; also the concerns that business and the tax authorities are facing in the current tax climate are highlighted. The main body of the paper then discusses in more detail some of the themes alluded to in these dilemmas. © 2005 KPMG LLP, the UK member firm of KPMG International, a Swiss cooperative. All rights reserved. KPMG and the KPMG logo are registered trademarks of KPMG International. KPMG’s Tax Business School is a registered trademark of KPMG in the UK, a member firm of KPMG International.

Upload: oliver-owuor

Post on 28-Nov-2014

70 views

Category:

Documents


1 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Philosophy of Tax Law

1

The Philosophy of Tax KPMG’s Tax Business School®

Victoria Heard

Abstract

This paper has been written to provide an overview of research relating to taxation undertaken by academics in several different disciplines. Research from the disciplines of philosophy, psychology, the law and economics has been included in this paper together with other work by business commentators and social scientists. This summary hopes to provide a platform from which further research can be commissioned within these differing disciplines in order to gain more insight into how tax is perceived and how frustrations with the tax system from taxpayers, tax gatherers and advisers that are currently gaining publicity could be resolved. The paper begins with the identification of a number of topics where further research would be valuable; also the concerns that business and the tax authorities are facing in the current tax climate are highlighted. The main body of the paper then discusses in more detail some of the themes alluded to in these dilemmas.

© 2005 KPMG LLP, the UK member firm of KPMG International, a Swiss cooperative. All rights reserved. KPMG and the KPMG logo are registered trademarks of KPMG International.

KPMG’s Tax Business School is a registered trademark of KPMG in the UK, a member firm of KPMG International.

Page 2: Philosophy of Tax Law

2

Contents 1. Introduction 1.1 Questions for further research 1.2 Dilemmas of the government and the tax authorities 1.3 Dilemmas facing businesses 2. Tackling avoidance 2.1 Introduction 2.2 The context 2.3 The existing legislative framework 2.4 The emergent frustrations 2.5 Legislative based solutions 2.6 The case for a social solution 2.7 Adapting an existing framework – the case for CSR 2.8 Tools to consider 3 Perceptions of tax and of the tax authorities 3.1 Introduction 3.2 Taxpayer behaviour 3.3 Using behavioural models to change behaviour 3.3.1 The Compliance Pyramid 3.3.2 Applications of the principles of the ATO compliance model 3.3.3 The compliance model and creative compliance 3.4 Regulation, self-regulation and the role of a code of conduct 3.5 How certain taxes are perceived 3.6 Providing incentives and disincentives

4 Conclusions and further research for academia

© 2005 KPMG LLP, the UK member firm of KPMG International, a Swiss cooperative. All rights reserved. KPMG and the KPMG logo are registered trademarks of KPMG International.

KPMG’s Tax Business School is a registered trademark of KPMG in the UK, a member firm of KPMG International.

Page 3: Philosophy of Tax Law

3

1. Introduction

The aim of this paper is to bring together facets of tax research from fields such as philosophy, psychology, law and economics to highlight some of the dilemmas facing the world of tax at present and identify some paths toward resolving these issues by suggesting where further research could be used to gain fuller understanding of how tax and tax behaviour is perceived by businesses, individuals and the tax authorities. The paper begins with the identification of these potential research topics; also the concerns that business and the tax authorities are facing in the current tax climate are highlighted. The main body of the paper then discusses in more detail some of the themes alluded to in these dilemmas. This begins with a discussion of the issue of tax avoidance and examines the problem of defining and tackling tax avoidance and observes how the frustrations of the tax authorities and the taxpayer are manifesting themselves. This section goes on to discuss some potential solutions to the problem suggested by different disciplines. The third section of the paper is concerned with how the perceptions of a tax system and those who administer it may affect the appetite of taxpayers for compliance with the system. Finally, the paper goes on to look at how tax policy is influenced by taxpayers’ perceptions of it and how incentives and dis-incentives are used to shape the behaviour of these taxpayers.

1.1 Questions for further research In light of the corporate philosophy debate more generally, should companies be required to give regard to ideas of morality in respect of their tax affairs? Can considerations of ethical theory assist in finding a resolution to the debate surrounding “unacceptable” tax avoidance that is satisfactory to all sides? Do the political beliefs of the boards of corporations influence the tax behaviour of the companies they run? Are companies who exhibit other “beyond compliant” activities such as ISO 9000 or ISO 14001 compliance, more likely to adopt a less aggressive tax stance? Do companies consider tax when looking at their Corporate Social Responsibility (CSR) policies and do companies with developed CSR policies have a more moderate tax planning attitude? In light of the work that has been done in the field of psychology regarding how important a taxpayer’s perception of the tax system is to voluntary compliance, it would be interesting to conduct further research into how both individuals and representatives of businesses perceive the current tax system and what changes they would recommend in order to enhance fairness.

Can the themes of evasion literature be applied to avoidance activities? Does the fact that the former is illegal while the latter is legal change a taxpayer’s behaviour?

Is it possible to estimate the amount of tax lost to avoidance activities. What definition of avoidance should be used for these purposes?

Research on individuals has moved away from the “rational actor” theory of tax behaviour. However, intuitively it would seem that this is a more likely explanation for corporate behaviour. Is this the case?

Is there any correlation between business environment and participation in tax avoidance schemes? If companies operate in a field of higher than average regulation, such as banking, does this influence their tax planning activities?

© 2005 KPMG LLP, the UK member firm of KPMG International, a Swiss cooperative. All rights reserved. KPMG and the KPMG logo are registered trademarks of KPMG International.

KPMG’s Tax Business School is a registered trademark of KPMG in the UK, a member firm of KPMG International.

Page 4: Philosophy of Tax Law

4

What do company directors think of some of the tax planning schemes that are reported in the press? Are their opinions changed by whether their company was able to adopt them? Or by how much money they could have saved them?

Is a legislative approach the best way to reduce the incidence of “unacceptable” tax avoidance?

How would a code of agreed conduct help to resolve the current frustrations? Could a non statutory approach produce a better result than legislative approaches?

Is it the role of business or government to create a responsible working environment? To what extent are tax reputational effects of concern to shareholders and institutional investors? Could some of the experiments discussed in this paper be repeated in the UK with avoidance as their focus? How do reputational issues affect the share price of a company? If tax policy could be designed with taxpayer behaviour in mind, might it help reduce problems with avoidance? There is a taxpaying attitude that Kristina Murphy, of the Centre for Tax System Integrity, calls “game-playing”. Could further research into this attitude help to understand the behaviour of those who undertake avoidance activities? If further study of how businesses feel they are affected by different taxes was undertaken, could this lead to the design of tax policies that were more acceptable to both businesses and the tax authorities? 1.2 Dilemmas of the government and the tax authorities

The role that the government plays in respect of tax is to balance the need to collect sufficient monies to fund the social needs of the country with the requirement to create a competitive economy in which business can flourish. The O’Donnell report (March 2004) entitled Financing Britain’s Future, examines the best organisational arrangements for achieving the tax objectives set by the government and it is this document that developed the issue of a merger between the Inland Revenue and Customs and Excise. This proposal was accepted and HM Revenue and Customs (HMR&C) came into being in April 2005. Other proposals were a more customer focused administration and increased analytical resources for the Treasury. The report details how the government wish the UK to be a hub for global business and also the aspects of a modern tax system to which the government aspires – namely fairness, efficiency, minimisation of cost and impact of compliance administration and the need to influence investment decisions and overall economic stability. The document sets out a blue print for a modern tax administration focused on achieving a competitive tax system for a competitive economy. To achieve this will require a commitment to the principles underlying that blueprint and requires a response from all of those involved in the administration of the tax system – including taxpayers, tax policy setters, tax administrators and tax advisers.

Some of the functions of taxation are to raise money to pay for government spending; to discourage people from buying harmful goods; to influence the level of total demand in the economy and to redistribute wealth. A government needs to raise revenue to fund the welfare state, whatever the level of welfare provision their political philosophy deems to be required. One presumes that the government is concerned that if it is possible for taxpayers to use complex arrangements created for the specific purpose of avoiding tax, the tax take will drop significantly and reduce the ability of the government to provide necessary services. In addition to tax avoidance, the UK tax system is under pressure for two other reasons – international tax competition and the effect of recent decisions by the European Court of Justice. These factors may both act to narrow the revenue raising powers of the

© 2005 KPMG LLP, the UK member firm of KPMG International, a Swiss cooperative. All rights reserved. KPMG and the KPMG logo are registered trademarks of KPMG International.

KPMG’s Tax Business School is a registered trademark of KPMG in the UK, a member firm of KPMG International.

Page 5: Philosophy of Tax Law

5

government. However, when entering into the European Union and adopting provisions of EU law, parts of the UK tax law may no longer be valid and therefore steps need to be taken to rectify the situation. Developments such as the new UK-UK transfer pricing legislation show how the UK government are trying to tackle this situation – in this case by removing the exemption than was previously enjoyed between two UK companies. Other countries have adopted different strategies for dealing with this issue. For example, Spain dis-applied its versions of transfer pricing and CFC rules for countries within the EU. Tax competition that arises from the lowering of tax rates across Europe means that the government need to consider whether a lower rate of tax would attract investment and wealth creation into the UK such that overall revenues did not diminish or indeed could increase. As an aside, it has been suggested (e.g. by the Adam Smith Institute) that avoidance may be mitigated by a reduction in effective tax rates. A further concern, the budget deficit, is discussed further on in this paper.

Other worries to the tax authorities may include their defeat in tax planning cases in the courts (Barclays Mercantile Business Finance Limited v Mawson which the Inland Revenue recently lost in the House of Lords and Debenhams Retail Plc v C&E Commissioners, which Customs and Excise are taking to the Court of Appeal), although the authorities have also had “wins” in cases such as Scottish Provident Institution. With regard to the tax avoidance issues discussed later in this paper, specific concerns to the tax authorities might be that they do not receive enough information to determine which planning activities they should be investigating and which are innocuous, or that the information they receive is deliberately vague. A report by the Taw Law Review Committee (1997) suggested that participation in avoidance schemes might encourage taxpayers to be less than completely honest because when the authorities obtain knowledge about the scheme in question they may seek to render it ineffective with legislation. Any government also will be concerned that any radical overhaul of the tax system might adversely affect its popularity. As tax is such a sensitive subject for voters, there appears to be a lack of political will to initiate wide ranging change to the tax system. Therefore one dilemma for the government and tax authorities would be whether the risk of attempting to change the tax system or legislation in order to make it clearer and simpler can be justified. The benefits of radical simplification appear to be a system that is administratively less expensive to run and more certain for taxpayers and tax authorities alike. The drawbacks could be major disruption and significant loss of revenue. It is a subject that would benefit from cross party support.

1.3 Dilemmas facing businesses Businesses also have a balancing act to perform. The board of a company needs to balance its responsibility to its shareholders with other responsibilities to its employees, suppliers, customers and communities. It needs to ensure that the company can be competitive in its market place; otherwise the people to whom the company has responsibilities will suffer. Businesses need to try to innovate and develop their products and services; they also need to ensure that they comply with the myriad of regulations existing in the field in which they operate. The initial reaction of a business is to see tax as just another cost (albeit a major one) which needs to be managed, and therefore any legitimate means of reducing its tax costs are welcomed. As stated above, one of the roles of the government is to create an environment in which businesses can grow, and although the tax rate of the UK has been lowered over the last decade, the corporation tax take of the Exchequer has increased. The average tax rate (excluding the UK) in the EU is 26.2 percent, although this does include all the new entrants who have lower tax rates than the more long-standing EU member states.

When press attention is focussed on the amount of corporation tax paid by companies, they often neglect the other taxes paid by companies – for example irrecoverable VAT, business rates, employers NIC, customs duties and excise duties. A survey on this subject was undertaken recently by PricewaterhouseCoopers and the results of this are summarised on its website. The PwC survey showed that among 70 companies, 36 of which are quoted on the FTSE 100, 57 percent of respondents estimated their total tax contribution was over 40 percent of profit, and 30 percent estimated that it was over 50 percent of profit. This is a large amount of money for a company to

© 2005 KPMG LLP, the UK member firm of KPMG International, a Swiss cooperative. All rights reserved. KPMG and the KPMG logo are registered trademarks of KPMG International.

KPMG’s Tax Business School is a registered trademark of KPMG in the UK, a member firm of KPMG International.

Page 6: Philosophy of Tax Law

6

contribute to the Exchequer. There is also a compliance cost to companies, both in terms of its own compliance but also in its unpaid job as tax collector for the government for PAYE and NIC. Also, a company cannot affect tax policy in the same way as an individual – it cannot vote and therefore is unable to directly shape the fiscal policies under whose remit it falls. Perhaps there should be a role for business in helping to influence fiscal policy in a far wider way than it can now.

The spate of rises in the lesser taxes, such as stamp duty and national insurance will have hit many businesses hard, especially smaller businesses, as these taxes are not proportional to profits. Economically, tax has large cash flow implications for businesses in a way that other costs do not. Businesses will also be concerned about the uncertainty resulting from rapidly changing legislation. Companies may also feel unfairly treated by the recent press comments from those in opposition to tax mitigation and worry that the company’s reputation is being damaged despite the fact that it is operating wholly within the law. Because one function of tax laws is to encourage desired investments, even the most conscientious taxpayer may have trouble deciding when legal strategies to minimise taxes are appropriate responses to intentionally enacted tax incentives and when they merely exploit loopholes. This is without taking into account the ethical judgement that some feel a taxpayer should make in respect of whether to undertake planning that falls within the second category.

Companies are also affected by the uncertainty that the tax system can introduce into their finances. Due in part to complex legislation, enquiries into tax returns can last for many years for large companies and even if no adjustment is made to a tax return the company will incur costs in dealing with these enquiries. Companies may suffer cash flow problems if repayments are delayed or they may have to retain creditors on the balance sheet in case of any unexpected liabilities arising as a result of the enquiries. These things also affect a company’s ability to attract investment. The quarterly instalment payment system for large companies forces tax payments to be made before any realistic estimate of the final liability, which means that the company risks punitive interest if it does not pay enough tax or sub-optimal cash flow if it pays too much. In addition to this, as discussed throughout this paper, some now argue that a company should adopt a moral approach to its tax affairs, which could leave businesses without even the shaky certainty of the legislation to rely on. Tax has been mentioned as a factor that could be included in corporate social performance considerations. There are two main sides to the argument for a more socially responsible corporate citizen. The first is that of “enlightened self interest”. This basically implies that in some cases it is in a company’s best interests to undertake socially responsible behaviour. This can be due to additional or more satisfied consumers, attractiveness to employees and voluntary actions that can forestall restrictive legislation. Secondly, taking a more long term view, it has been argued that making a more positive contribution to society might be a long term investment in that the existence of a safer, better educated and more equitable society might create an improved and more stable context in which the company can do business. It would appear more difficult to tie tax into these economic arguments than it is the more traditional topics for CSR debate, such as supply chain rights or the environment. However, it has been acknowledged that overly aggressive tax policies might have a negative effect on the reputation of a company which could be to its detriment financially. There is a definite balancing act to be performed here – pay too little tax and risk reputational risk amongst investors and consumers, uncertainty over whether your planning will be accepted by the authorities and a poor profile with HMR&C or pay too much and risk the wrath of your shareholders, less cash to invest in your business and therefore potentially poorer financial performance.

Calls have been made, for example by the Tax Justice Network, to align tax regulation with corporate governance legislation and guidance. This would increase burdens for businesses but might help the transition of tax policy decisions from the tax function to the boardroom, ensuring that the company has a clear decision making process laid out and that all planning undertaken has the unequivocal support of the company’s leaders. However, arguably it is crucial that businesses and tax and accounting bodies are involved in the development of any such regulation in order to help ensure a fair and workable system that is not too burdensome to businesses.

© 2005 KPMG LLP, the UK member firm of KPMG International, a Swiss cooperative. All rights reserved. KPMG and the KPMG logo are registered trademarks of KPMG International.

KPMG’s Tax Business School is a registered trademark of KPMG in the UK, a member firm of KPMG International.

Page 7: Philosophy of Tax Law

7

2. Tackling avoidance

2.1 Introduction

The first section of the paper looks at the issue of tax avoidance. Tax avoidance, by definition, is legal but there has been increased scrutiny by the tax authorities of taxpayers who adopt tax planning arrangements and recent condemnation of these taxpayers by Government officials. This section of the paper first discusses the context of this debate, how legislation has been used in an attempt to combat avoidance and the frustrations that have emerged on the part of the tax authorities and the taxpayer. Ethics and morality are often mentioned in this context, so this paper has included a discussion of some of the major schools of thought within the academic discipline of ethics to see if this can help determine a solution. Corporate social responsibility is also discussed, as this can be viewed as a framework within which companies are encouraged to adopt more socially beneficial behaviour. Finally, there is an account of some of the tools that have been suggested to tackle the problems facing the tax system together with some approaches used in different disciplines.

2.2 The context

The issue of taxation has once again been evident in the press in recent months and one of the topics attracting the most passionate debate is tax avoidance. There are those who believe that it is our right to organise tax affairs as we will, as long as we do not break the law. This concept was introduced into law by Lord Tomlin in the case of IRC v Duke of Westminster 1936 – “Every man is entitled to arrange his affairs so the tax attaching under the appropriate acts is less than it could be”. There are others who think that those who employ tax planning to reduce their tax burden are effectively robbing their communities and their country. The idea of a moral attitude to tax has been spawned from the debate that has gone on for many years regarding the difference between tax avoidance and tax evasion. This distinction appears to be straightforward; the former being in agreement with the letter of the law and the latter, involving some kind of dishonesty, being illegal – as Denis Healey (the former Chancellor of the Exchequer) said, the difference between avoidance and evasion is “the thickness of a prison wall”. However, the new frontier of this debate is wider ranging and questions where the line should be drawn between acceptable tax mitigation and unacceptable “immoral” tax avoidance. There have been recent instances of members of the government, such as the Chancellor and the Paymaster General, criticising tax planning arrangements, those firms that sell them and the taxpayers that adopt them, but without being able to draw a “bright line” between acceptable and unacceptable planning. The increasing globalisation and sophistication of business has meant that wealth generating activities can take place in multiple locations and can be moved more quickly. Intense competition has forced businesses to constantly reduce costs and competition between countries for investment using tax as a competitive lever forces tax onto the business agenda. This competitive environment may ultimately be of benefit, but when looked at from a tax revenue perspective, it adds to the opportunities for tax avoidance and results in advantages for multinational companies over domestic companies that may have fewer opportunities to lower their tax bills. A number of advocates of the application to tax of corporate social responsibility have pointed out that developing countries may be harmed by some current tax practices for example because companies operating in developing countries may use tax planning to take the profits earned in those companies offshore. Also, multinationals impose a great deal of pressure on developing countries to provide them with tax “breaks” (eg tax holidays for inward investment) and low corporation tax rates. A study by Oxfam (2000) discusses how a survey of the corporation tax rates of developing nations shows that these are generally much lower than the OECD average, few offering tax rates over 20 percent. With respect to tax havens, the UK government has estimated that 60 percent of international trade consists of intra-group transactions and the value of assets held offshore in low-tax or no-tax jurisdictions is estimated to be US$11 trillion (Oxfam 2000). This is one third of the world’s gross

© 2005 KPMG LLP, the UK member firm of KPMG International, a Swiss cooperative. All rights reserved. KPMG and the KPMG logo are registered trademarks of KPMG International.

KPMG’s Tax Business School is a registered trademark of KPMG in the UK, a member firm of KPMG International.

Page 8: Philosophy of Tax Law

8

domestic product. Data from the United Nations Conference on Trade and Development (UNCTAD) has shown that in the early 1990’s there were 37,000 international companies with 175,000 overseas subsidiaries. By 2003, there were about 64,000 such companies, with 870,000 subsidiaries. A real concern for the government is balancing income and expenditure. The UK government was warned by the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) in January 2005 that the rising UK budget deficit might force the government to raise taxes or slow the rise in public spending. In its 2004 Economic Survey of the United Kingdom, the OECD states that its projections suggest "the need for further fiscal action" to avoid "diminishing the credibility of the fiscal framework". The OECD also warned that "the jury is still out on whether the massive spending increases will fully pay off in terms of improved service." In January 2005 the Institute for Fiscal Studies estimated in its Green Budget that £11 billion is required in order for the UK government to pay for its spending plans and put public finances back on track. The IFS also indicated that at the end of this year, the government would be taking 2.1 percent more of national income in tax and other receipts than the previous government in their last year in power. With these major concerns to contend with it is understandable that the government are concentrating their efforts on trying to plug the so-called tax gap. The tax gap is the difference between current tax revenues and what revenues would be if there were no artificial avoidance schemes. It is a very difficult amount to estimate, although an article by Prem Sikka in the online journal www.publicfinance.co.uk estimates the amount to be £25-85 billion per annum. However, the impact of removing rights to undertake tax mitigation activities is just as difficult to assess. As Barry Bracewell Milnes, a tax reform scholar said “An economy breathes through its tax loopholes” – implying that excessively stringent enforcement can reduce productivity, innovation, output and work incentives. In addition, the taxpayer also has concerns - about the increasing burden of taxation that he bears and the plethora of taxes that are used to try and raise revenue. Taxpayers are also concerned about the use to which their money is put. A group of pacifists who opposed the war in Iraq and do not wish their tax money to be used for military purposes is threatening to take the government to court under the freedom of religion provisions of the Human Rights Act (Harding, March 2005). Stories of government waste are in the newspapers every day; the James review (sponsored by the Conservative party) uncovered several areas where government waste could be substantially reduced. It does not seem altogether surprising that individuals and corporations are concerned about the fairness and efficiency of the tax system and, as this paper goes on to discuss, moral objections and concerns about waste are both factors that can have an effect on compliance with tax laws. UK corporation tax revenues have fallen from 28.1 percent of total Inland Revenue income in 1989 to 19.4 percent in 2003 (although the absolute level of corporate tax revenue has increased). The breadth of anti-avoidance legislation encompassing personal tax, employment taxes, VAT, stamp duty and corporate taxes gives an indication of how the burden of all taxes are sought to be reduced by planning from personal income tax through to corporate taxation. It is not surprising however that tax planning is so pervasive as decisions by ordinary taxpayers and businesses are influenced by tax incentives with consequent anomalies and inequities. Decisions to save; go to work; the form of pay package; set up a business; finance a business; sell a business; share wealth or retire all require tax decisions created by the use of tax incentives to influence behaviour. 2.3 The existing legislative framework It could be argued that Parliament and the tax authorities should find it straightforward to direct taxpayers regarding what tax planning should and should not be done. Initially, Parliament approves the legislation. This should provide clear guidance as to what is and is not permitted. HMR&C then have the opportunity of taking to court any taxpayers who implement schemes that they deem unacceptable. If they lose the cases, they can then proceed through the appeals systems and if they ultimately lose the final appeal, they can advise ministers to put legislation before Parliament to ensure the tax planning cannot be repeated. Now, with the new disclosure rules introduced by Finance Act 2004 promoters and users of tax planning arrangements have to inform HMR&C what

© 2005 KPMG LLP, the UK member firm of KPMG International, a Swiss cooperative. All rights reserved. KPMG and the KPMG logo are registered trademarks of KPMG International.

KPMG’s Tax Business School is a registered trademark of KPMG in the UK, a member firm of KPMG International.

Page 9: Philosophy of Tax Law

9

these plans are. Consequently, on coming across an arrangement that they disapprove of, the tax authorities can announce that from that date, such arrangements will no longer be effective and that the necessary legislation will be brought forward in the next Finance Bill. This has always been within their power, but due to the disclosures rules the process will be accelerated. The legislation itself already has specific anti-avoidance provisions, in some cases where clearance applications can be made and in others where it cannot. There are sections of anti-avoidance legislation such as s703 ICTA 1988 which applies to transactions in securities and s776 ICTA 1998 which applies to transactions in land. Clearance applications can be made to ascertain whether or not HMR&C consider these anti-avoidance sections apply to the transaction in question. The clearance operates in slightly different ways under each of these sections and if HMR&C are seeking to use s776 in respect of land that is held to realise a gain of a capital nature from development; clearance cannot be obtained. Also, many areas of the legislation in existence to date include their own specific anti-avoidance clauses, for example Enterprise Investment Scheme (EIS) relief (s289(6) ICTA 1988) - “An individual is not eligible for relief in respect of any shares unless the schemes are subscribed for, and issued, for bona fide commercial purposes and not as part of a scheme or arrangement the main purpose or one of the main purposes of which is the avoidance of tax”. The 2005 budget initially suggested provisions in order to prevent avoidance of corporation tax through schemes which create a tax advantage because different jurisdictions classify business entities in different ways (“arbitrage schemes”). These provisions were removed from later versions of the finance bill, but it is expected that they will be adopted in some format later in the year. If these provisions were adopted in the same format in which they originally appeared in the draft finance bill; then in a similar manner to the transactions in securities provisions the rules would only apply if HMR&C issues a notice directing that this legislation will apply (the “direction”). There would be no formal clearance mechanism, but the draft HMR&C guidance discusses the possibility of obtaining a ruling on specific transactions under the usual Code of Practice 10 provisions. However, for the purpose of this paper it is the uncertainty created for the taxpayer by these provisions that is of relevance. If these provisions were to be introduced, a company would not know whether or not it is caught by them until HMR&C informs it so. The provisions were also expected to apply to all companies regardless of size, but the HMR&C guidance suggested that directions would only be made where the tax at stake is in excess of £50,000. Therefore, the decision as to whether a direction will be made might rest upon the HMR&C’s estimate of the tax that may be at stake if it could subsequently be proven that the legislation did actually apply to the situation. It will be interesting to chart the development of this potential legislation. It would seem, not surprisingly, that there are two conflicting objectives regarding tax planning. The government would prefer that no taxpayer pays less than expected by Parliament, whereas taxpayers will rarely seek to pay more than required by the law. Also, from a legal perspective, it is important to note that taxpayers can only be taxed on what the legislation says. Many members of the judiciary have opined eloquently on this subject, but perhaps the neatest summary is from a non-tax case (Black-Clawson v Papierwerke 1975), where Lord Reid said “We are seeking, not what Parliament meant, but the true meaning of what they said”. Case law throughout the decades has developed the concept of acceptable and unacceptable planning with the cases from Ramsay v IRC through Furniss v Dawson, Macniven v Westmoreland Investments Limited and most recently Barclays Mercantile Business Finance Limited v Mawson. However, the judiciary appear reluctant to be too prescriptive when dealing with tax cases – indeed in Macniven v Westmoreland, Lord Hoffman noted that creating an overlying principle that would guide tax behaviour was beyond the constitutional authority of the courts. In the past the idea of a “substance over form” approach has been suggested, in that the overall aim of the transaction should be considered, as well as its actual legal form. However, the recent cases of Barclays Mercantile and Scottish Provident Institution seem to have simplified the issue by showing that what is required is the application of the words of the legislation to all the facts of the case. Where this leads to ambiguity, a

© 2005 KPMG LLP, the UK member firm of KPMG International, a Swiss cooperative. All rights reserved. KPMG and the KPMG logo are registered trademarks of KPMG International.

KPMG’s Tax Business School is a registered trademark of KPMG in the UK, a member firm of KPMG International.

Page 10: Philosophy of Tax Law

10

purposive approach should be taken. This “common sense” approach may simplify tax cases in the future, but again there is a lack of certainty for the taxpayer. Anti-avoidance questions have reached the European courts too. The Advocate General (AG) gave his Opinion in the joined cases of Halifax, the University of Huddersfield, and BUPA on 7 April 2005 each of which have been referred to the European Court of Justice (ECJ). The cases concern whether there is any rule in EU law that prevents transactions carried out by a taxpayer for the purpose of avoidance of VAT from having the effect intended by the taxpayer. If the ECJ follows the AG’s opinion, taxpayers will not be prevented from structuring their businesses in a tax efficient manner. However, tax avoidance structures which aggressively seek to undermine the fundamental principles of VAT neutrality may fall foul of the principle of abuse. This appears to provide some clarification as to how anti-avoidance, at least in the case of VAT, will be treated in the European courts and give a little more guidance to taxpayers when structuring transactions.

Overall therefore, there is a legal process to determine the amount of tax that a taxpayer is required to pay and that legal process can be used as policy objectives change or taxpayer behaviour does not produce the expected tax revenues. It would seem, however, that this process is not working satisfactorily.

2.4 The emergent frustrations

The HMR&C, the Chancellor and other Treasury officials have begun to be more and more vocal in condemning those who use tax avoidance to legally ensure that they pay as little tax as possible. For example when announcing the creation of an international tax force to counter tax avoidance on 23 April 2004, John Healey, Economic Secretary to the Treasury, stated: “Tax avoidance and the industry that drives it are increasingly an international phenomenon and it is vital that we have effective international co-operation to tackle it, as we do for tackling terrorism, organised crime, money laundering and fraud.” However, it must be pointed out that tax avoidance is currently legal and it would seem somewhat inflammatory to compare it with terrorism and money laundering, which clearly are not. It is acknowledged that there is a point of view that any tax avoidance arrangements which obey the letter of the law but not its spirit are unacceptable, but provocative statements such as these may damage the cause of those who believe this. On the same occasion, Paymaster General, Dawn Primarolo, a vocal critic of tax planning, says: “Tax avoidance works to the detriment of everyone who pays their fair share and robs our public services of billions of pounds”. This of course begs the question – what is a “fair” share? What is unfair about using the legislation to one’s best advantage? Further research is needed in order to estimate accurately the tax lost due to tax avoidance, although it is acknowledged that this is a difficult task. As noted earlier, estimates that have been made range between £25 billion and £85 billion. It has been argued (e.g Avery Jones 1996) that it is the complicated tax legislation that adds to the problem of tax avoidance, and that the increasing instances of laws being rushed through Parliament without the level of necessary review and consultation only compound the effect. Several academic studies have made the point that the more complex and rigidly rule based tax systems are, the more opportunities for tax avoidance abound (e.g McBarnet 2002). A further concern is that the government is able to announce that certain arrangements will be unacceptable from a certain date, with no draft legislation available to allow the taxpayer to know exactly what is contrary to the legislation and what is not. Is this a fair way to ensure that people are taxed correctly? It would appear to allow a taxpayer to be penalised for doing something that at the time he had no way of knowing was incorrect. This approach may leave the government open to litigation under human rights legislation, although this view is not shared by all. An article in the British Tax Review by Philip Baker QC provides an insight into this issue (Baker 2005). The new approach by HMR&C to combating arrangements they deem unacceptable is clear. “We will be

© 2005 KPMG LLP, the UK member firm of KPMG International, a Swiss cooperative. All rights reserved. KPMG and the KPMG logo are registered trademarks of KPMG International.

KPMG’s Tax Business School is a registered trademark of KPMG in the UK, a member firm of KPMG International.

Page 11: Philosophy of Tax Law

11

aggressive” said Chris Tailby, head of HMR&C’s new anti-avoidance group when describing their plans to bring finance directors into the courts to explain their involvement in tax planning arrangements (Rae 24/02/2005). HMR&C also intend to report accountancy firms to their professional bodies where they feel that these firms have been aggressively pursuing tax mitigation and where HMR&C consider them to be acting unethically.

Again it should be pointed out that tax avoidance activities are legal and what may or may not be unethical is far from defined. Is a grey area of the law made black and white just because HMR&C want it to be? On the other hand, it might be argued that the law is indeed black and white, and what it states is that tax avoidance is by definition legal. Perhaps it is the tax authorities who are trying to introduce grey areas by adding considerations of morality to the debate. For all the heated argument, there does not appear to have been a suggestion (that would be acceptable to all sides of the argument) of what to do about the fact that taxpayers are permitted to undertake tax avoidance activities by the law. Inland Revenue figures show corporation tax receipts of £28.1 billion for the tax year 2003/2004. This is only the tip of the iceberg where the tax contributions of companies are concerned and if the other taxes that companies pay were included, the amount contributed would be far higher. The above quotations show the level of emotion surrounding this subject, but it is not law that a taxpayer must not do something because HMR&C do not want him too.

Tax avoidance is not illegal, but outside the tax world there are many instances where the law and morality do not stand on the same line. For example, most people would consider infidelity to their spouses immoral. Yet, it is not illegal. On the other hand, speeding is against the law yet if the opinions of motorists were canvassed, a spectrum of differing beliefs as to whether or not it is acceptable behaviour would be obtained. Obviously the key problem is that morality is difficult to define. Something that is anathema to one person may be considered perfectly acceptable by another. What seems clear however is that a long term solution to the issues raised by the tax avoidance debate needs to be found.

2.5 Legislative based solutions The idea of an overlaying principle or rule has been mooted to a certain degree in the form of a general anti-avoidance rule (GAAR). It is possible that this former would act to impose a further layer of rules onto the already extremely complicated legislation. The general anti-avoidance rule has been rejected so far in the UK on the basis that it would not provide the certainty required by taxpayers and that it is difficult to define a general rule that does not impact genuine business transactions. Advance clearance mechanisms have been proposed; however this would be labour intensive for HMR&C and would increase the cost of collection for the tax in question. Every genuine commercial transaction found to have a tax consequence would need advance clearance if those carrying it out were to have certainty about its effect. The resulting flood of applications for clearance could swamp HMR&C and potentially introduce delays of many months into the process. A further disadvantage of clearance applications under the GAAR is that it could empower HMR&C to decide (at least in the first instance) what is and is not an acceptable interpretation of the tax legislation. The taxpayer would still have the option of taking the matter through the courts, but would naturally be discouraged from doing so by HMR&C’s refusal to give clearance. It is for the courts to hand down binding interpretations of legislation, not civil servants at the HMR&C. A further criticism of the clearance procedure is that it would only apply if the transaction was carried out precisely as described in the clearance applications. As anyone involved in commercial transactions will be aware, the nature of a commercial scheme can change from day to day, even hour to hour. Would advance clearance need repeated applications? Some nations around the world have introduced general anti-avoidance rules, notably New Zealand, Australia and Canada. Canadian tax law has contained a general anti-avoidance rule since 1988. The governments view is that the GAAR is intended to prevent abusive or artificial avoidance schemes, without interfering with legitimate commercial transactions. It does so by giving the Canadian tax

© 2005 KPMG LLP, the UK member firm of KPMG International, a Swiss cooperative. All rights reserved. KPMG and the KPMG logo are registered trademarks of KPMG International.

KPMG’s Tax Business School is a registered trademark of KPMG in the UK, a member firm of KPMG International.

Page 12: Philosophy of Tax Law

12

authorities the ability to deny any tax benefit obtained as a result of the particular offensive avoidance transaction, or series of transactions. The key tests are whether there has been a misuse or abuse of a provision of the Act and whether the primary purpose of the plan is to obtain a tax benefit. Therefore as a result of the latter condition, as long as a taxpayer can justify the transactions from a business perspective, they should not be at risk from the GAAR. In general, Canadian courts have used the GAAR restrictively, imposing a high threshold on the tax authorities to show there has been a misuse or abuse of the Canadian tax legislation. In applying the GAAR, Canadian courts still generally look to the legal form of a transaction as opposed to its economic substance. A second anti-avoidance provision has been suggested (Freedman 2004) – the general anti-avoidance principle (GANTIP). This might be preferable as it would not attempt to define in detail the type of planning or transaction that would be halted. In acting upon such a principle, anybody whose goal was to comply with the law would be better able to understand what was required by Parliament. It would also give the company director protection and guidance on how to balance his duties to shareholders and the company’s duty to pay tax. Freedman’s paper suggests that the GANTIP could be a statutory provision entitling the courts to go beyond the ordinary rules of statutory construction and potentially negate artificial avoidance schemes which abused the wording of the legislation. In effect this could create the overlying principle guiding taxpayer behaviour that Lord Hoffman noted was beyond the constitutional authority of the courts. Once the statutory provision had been enacted, it would provide a legitimate framework in which the courts could operate to work out what Parliament would have intended. This would allow HMR&C to concentrate on the extreme cases of avoidance, while the majority complied voluntarily with the principles. The GANTIP could give rise to a debate around the meaning of avoidance which could be held between the taxpaying community and the revenue authorities in agreeing the guidelines, although some have argued that the development of the GANTIP should be a matter for the courts. Again, there is a lack of certainty for the taxpayer and the tax gatherer, however as discussed further on in the paper, certainty may not assist in the fight against tax avoidance. A legislative solution to the issues at stake might therefore be a useful one, but if too prescriptive it could add further complexity to the legislation. Also as with the tax cases that have come to the courts in the UK to date, the severity and usefulness of a GAAR would depend on test cases that came before the judges and it would take some time before the boundaries of such legislation could be established. A principle, whether created in the legislation (such as the GANTIP) or whether as a code incorporated into corporate governance might be of more assistance in that it could provide guidance to the taxpayer when navigating the complicated tax system. Whilst both provide a clearer statement of intent, both leave areas of uncertainty; perhaps this should be accepted as inevitable - the objective may simply be to reduce the areas of uncertainty. 2.6 The case for a social solution As discussed above, the ambiguities that can be found in the legislation make it difficult for the law to arrive at a solution to the emerging problems. Can considerations of ethics help? The word “ethics” has been much quoted in the press, but what could those who are involved in the academic study of ethics contribute to the debate? In short, who decides what the correct ethical stance to take is? The information contained within this section will no doubt appear rudimentary to a scholar of philosophy, but a brief summary of some of the different perspectives of the differing schools of philosophy, along with the author’s thoughts as to how these might apply to the tax avoidance debate, might be of interest to the non-specialist reader. This is by no means an exhaustive review of all schools of philosophy, but rather a general discussion about some of the more major principles. Fisher and Lovell (2003) and Crane and Matten (2004) provide further insight into the schools discussed here. An article by John Sartoris in the Philosophy for Business online journal (2/11/2003) provides an interesting discussion of the issues to be considered here. The argument has been raised that tax avoidance is unethical because if some people avoid their taxes, then others will have to bear an increased burden. This implies that if avoidance was to cease completely and the tax revenue to the

© 2005 KPMG LLP, the UK member firm of KPMG International, a Swiss cooperative. All rights reserved. KPMG and the KPMG logo are registered trademarks of KPMG International.

KPMG’s Tax Business School is a registered trademark of KPMG in the UK, a member firm of KPMG International.

Page 13: Philosophy of Tax Law

13

government to increase, the government would reduce the tax rates. This appears to be a fair solution, although it may be an unlikely one. It is equally probable that the government would identify something else to spend the money on and it is possible that this additional spending would increase the level of public services, which would also be a beneficial outcome. Ethical theories can be roughly split into two camps – non-consequentialist and consequentialist. The first considers ethics to be a set of principles that apply regardless of the consequences of the actions. The second considers an action to be more ethical if it brings a person closer to a desired ethical state – i.e. that it is the result of the action that is important. Examples of non-consequentialist theories are virtue ethics and deontological ethics, and examples of consequentialist theories are ethical learning and growth, and teleological ethics. Teleological ethics argues that the “rightness” of an action is not inherent in that action, but is judged by its consequences. Utilitarianism theory, a subset of teleological ethics, accepts utility, or the greatest happiness theory as the foundation of morals. As Jeremy Bentham, the 18th century philosopher said: “the greatest happiness of the greatest number is the foundation of morals and legislation” (Bentham 1982). It has been claimed that tax avoidance is unethical on utilitarian grounds because it damages the general economy and therefore does not increase “the greatest happiness of the greatest numbers”. However, economics needs to play its part here and it is far from certain that tax avoidance causes the economy to suffer; in fact there is an school of economic thought that would argue that a lower tax burden encourages innovation. Perhaps if it does not cause the economy to suffer, tax avoidance cannot be said to be reducing the level of happiness. Utilitarianism can perhaps be thought to be a calculating approach to ethics and it assumes that it is possible to measure both the quantity and quality of happiness. However, when assessing considerations of happiness it is necessary to consider whether the happiness that has been achieved has been at the cost of greater pain to other people. When thinking about what actions lead toward the greatest happiness, it is important to consider whether a good is being maximised rather than the good – whether the greatest happiness of some is being obtained rather than the greatest happiness of all. It could be postulated therefore that if tax avoidance ceased completely, the revenues of the government would be maximised. However, this could be at the cost of damage to innovation and the economy, in which case the overall good might not have been maximised. Also, utilitarianism may fail to work as a method of assessment if people are unable to make accurate predictions about the consequences of their actions (as may well be the case for the tax debate), as there is little point in weighing up the greatest happiness from a set of actions if the actual consequences of the actions have been misinterpreted. Another subset of teleological ethics is discourse ethics. This approach deals with the proper process of rational debate. It is a concept of self-reflection that requires those involved in the debate to challenge their own arguments. Contributors to this school of ethics have looked at advice given in popular books on the skill of debate and considered whether some of these could be considered unfair “tricks” of presentation. This leads to some tests that people should consider when assessing their own arguments. The first is called formal validity and considers whether arguments are logically rigorous or not. Has the proponent only used cases that support his point of view and discounted all others? The second is sincerity/truth – are the arguments intentionally misleading, incoherent or incompatible with the truth? Is the proponent misrepresenting the position of his opponent or exaggerating points? The third is content justice. This includes arguments where the opponent is attacked, rather than his arguments criticised. The final one is procedural justice which would counter techniques preventing an opponent from fully participating in the debate – for example the use of unnecessary jargon. It is also an important ethical consideration to determine who should have a voice in the debate. This point has been used to underline the fact that including the opinions of stakeholders in the running of a company can help to include consideration of the impact of a decision on workforces, communities and the government. If only the point of view of the directors were included, only bottom line profit might be considered, as it is the job of this group to maximise shareholder profit. On this basis, a fair debate on tax avoidance would presumably need to include the

© 2005 KPMG LLP, the UK member firm of KPMG International, a Swiss cooperative. All rights reserved. KPMG and the KPMG logo are registered trademarks of KPMG International.

KPMG’s Tax Business School is a registered trademark of KPMG in the UK, a member firm of KPMG International.

Page 14: Philosophy of Tax Law

14

views of the tax authorities, government, tax practitioners and representatives of all categories of taxpayer. It would be ironic to conclude that the current method and tone of the debate of ethics and tax was itself unethical! Deontological ethics is from the non-consequentialist school. One subset of this is Kantian ethics, which seems to argue that knowing what action to take in a situation will be determined by a set of pre-determined principles that are completely independent of the situation at hand. According to Kant’s principles, this applies to such an extent that if lying is considered to be wrong, then no-one should lie under any circumstances, not even if such a lie could save an innocent human life. The framework that Kant developed was called the categorical imperative and it has three parts (De George 1999):

• Act only according to that maxim by which you can at the same time will that it should become a universal law.

• Act so that you treat humanity, whether in your own person or another, always as an end and never as a means only.

• Act only so that the will through its maxims could regard itself at the same time as universally lawgiving.

If an action is to be viewed as morally right, it must “pass” all three tests. The first maxim checks for consistency – an action can only be right if everyone could follow the same underlying principle. The second maxim focuses on the idea of human dignity – that no-one should ever treat another person solely as a means to achieve what he wants and forget about that individual’s needs in life. The third maxim tries to overcome the subjectivity that is inherent in a person’s analysis of his own behaviour as it stipulates that a person should consider whether other rational actors would endorse his judgement of a certain situation. This can be compared with the Texas Instruments ethics test discussed below – how would you feel if your actions were published in the papers? If the answer to this question is not positive, it is likely that from a Kantian standpoint your actions cannot be considered ethical. It would be interesting for a philosopher to apply Kant’s theories to the tax avoidance debate. This third maxim was expanded on by Rawls (Rawls 1971), who theorised that in order to arrive at a blueprint for a just society it must be discussed by people who are in ignorance of where they might fit into that society. For example from a tax perspective, perhaps a group of people could discuss an ideal tax policy without knowing whether, when put into this society, they would be an unemployed person relying on state benefits, someone reliant on lifesaving drugs from the NHS, an extremely rich person, a chancellor seeking to maximise revenue, or one of the millions of “ordinary” people who fall somewhere in between these extremes. Rawls argues that in adopting this approach a person will take a risk-averse approach and analyse all the worst case scenarios she can think of before selecting the one that is “least worse”. In theory, this leads to the policy that is beneficial to the most people. The Libertarian school of philosophy (another subset of deontological ethics) can also be applied to the tax debate. The Libertarian school holds that differences in personal wealth, talent, intelligence are seen as being natural in that their ownership owes nothing to political or social institutions. Differences to the opportunities in life of individuals owing to the possession or otherwise of these characteristics do not justify the intervention of the government to redistribute some of the associated benefits. The school therefore holds the view that individuals have a fundamental right to own and keep their property, including the wages they earn. It accepts that tax should be paid, but holds that taxpayers must give voluntary consent to the state taking away what belongs to them. This school rejects that the state has a general right to tax or a moral right to a fair share of the wealth or the income of the nation, and opines that any prior consent given applies only to the circumstances set out in the legislation specifically consented to. This would imply that if the circumstances of the taxpayer change or the taxation environment changes, the consent previously given is withdrawn and tax is no longer due as prior consent has not been given to taxation in the new circumstances. Robert Nozick was a leading advocate of the libertarian position on justice and rights. He arrived at the term

© 2005 KPMG LLP, the UK member firm of KPMG International, a Swiss cooperative. All rights reserved. KPMG and the KPMG logo are registered trademarks of KPMG International.

KPMG’s Tax Business School is a registered trademark of KPMG in the UK, a member firm of KPMG International.

Page 15: Philosophy of Tax Law

15

“entitlement theory” to demonstrate his opinion that what has been acquired legally and fairly cannot be taken away within the libertarian notion of justice (Nozick 1974). An alternative perspective that branches off the main libertarian philosophy is liberalism, which appears to take the freedom advocated in libertarianism, and add a more socialist element. This school of thought believes that the state can be used to achieve social justices and therefore a liberal view of tax might be that part of the wealth or the income of the population belongs to the state and even without consent it is possible for it to redistribute wealth and income as it sees fit. This is on the grounds that wealth would not be able to be earned were it not for the state. Virtue ethics takes the point of view that virtues are not ends but means, and these characteristics provide the basis for individuals to lead a good and noble life. For Aristotle, one of the original proponents of virtue ethics, the notion of a good life meant a complete life and assumes that happiness comes from behaving well in addition to faring well. Virtue ethics can be defined as the belief that there is a set of personal characteristics that if practised will ensure that an individual is likely to make the right choices. Therefore when confronted with a dilemma, one should ask – what would a virtuous person do in this situation? However, one important thing to note about this ethical school is that the notion of the individual is seen as an individual as part of a wider society. Therefore it is the perception of others that determines where on the scale of values one fits. The scale of values starts with the virtue itself (e.g courage) and goes on to describe the vice of deficiency (cowardice) or the vice of excess (recklessness). This balance can be shown in the Aristotelian perspective of justice “to do injustice is to have more than one ought and to suffer it is to have less than one ought and justice is the mean between doing injustice and suffering it.” Over the years philosophers have added to Aristotle’s concepts and developed the idea that sometimes wisdom is needed to temper justice. This leads to the idea of “care” as a virtue – this has formed a school that is sometimes called feminist ethics. This is an approach that seeks to find a way forward that not only provides some form of equitable resolution to a conflict, but also holds out the possibility for maintaining a working relationship between the parties so that future co-operation might be possible. One can imagine that this could be put to good use in the debate between the taxpayer and the tax authorities. Philosophers within the school based on Aristotle’s teaching have also debated whether a good outcome is a virtuous one even if the deed was set about with bad motives, or if the achievement of socially desirable ends can justify less than acceptable means. A further school of thought, ethical learning, develops the idea that policy ends should be the yardsticks against which the morality of actions should be judged and they can only be achieved indirectly. This means that the end has to be approached indirectly by encouraging processes of learning that enable people to decide for themselves to act ethically. This is one element of philosophy that has definitely been used in our modern world and the concepts of individual growth and organisational learning are frequently used in business. The reasoning behind this is that individual learning is necessary for the growth of an organisation and it is only organisations that learn and grow that will be successful. Learning is considered to be an ethical end in itself. Therefore in trying to learn or develop knowledge about a particular issue, a person is achieving an ethical goal. Ethical egoism, a school of consequentialist ethics, states that an individual should pursue his own interests by applying his own reason to the task of identifying and achieving his own best interests – a person’s actions would be morally right if he freely decided to pursue either his short term desires or long term interests. The ethical position of these theories, one of which is objectivism proposed by Ayn Rand, is that each independent individual should seek his own happiness through a productive independent life in which his own rational judgement is his only guide. Rand said “my philosophy, in essence, is the concept of man as a heroic being, with his own happiness as the moral purpose of his life, with productive achievement as his noblest activity, and reason as his only absolute” (Rand, 1964). Ethical egoism school encourages a robust belief in self-help and concludes that people who will not take responsibility for themselves will have to bear the consequences and cannot expect society to help them out. However, egoism appears to be different from selfishness. An egoist might

© 2005 KPMG LLP, the UK member firm of KPMG International, a Swiss cooperative. All rights reserved. KPMG and the KPMG logo are registered trademarks of KPMG International.

KPMG’s Tax Business School is a registered trademark of KPMG in the UK, a member firm of KPMG International.

Page 16: Philosophy of Tax Law

16

be moved to help others by seeking to remove his own distress at their plight, whereas a selfish person would be entirely indifferent to the plight of others. It appears straightforward to apply this theory to tax behaviour – as long as the law is adhered to a person should just use their own reason to determine whether or not they should adopt tax minimisation strategies that can lower their liabilities. While ethics can provide some guidance and a basis for discussion of modern day problems, obviously it is probably not capable of providing “answers” to the problems currently facing tax authorities, tax practitioners and taxpayers. However, it would be of great interest for a philosopher to apply their work to tax issues in the current environment and for philosophy’s contribution to the debate to be heard. 2.7 Adapting an existing framework – the case for CSR The idea of ethical tax governance has also come to the forefront as part of the debate on corporate social responsibility (CSR). Should companies try to make sure they pay the absolute minimum in tax? Should companies recognise a responsibility to the community that they operate in and ensure that they make a fair contribution? Has less tax being payable encouraged innovation and growth, thus leading to benefits such as increased employment? Do companies ever truly bear the burden of tax? Or do they pass the cost on to their customers as they would any other cost of doing business? As Holman W Jenkins Jr stated: “A business is nothing more than a conduit for passing along costs to its customers. Taxes are a cost, so tax avoidance is part and parcel of competition to bring consumers better stuff at lower cost”. Perhaps it is worth mentioning here Milton Friedman’s objections to the idea of a corporation as an entity with responsibilities (Friedman 1970). The first objection is an economic criticism that states that the engagement of companies in philanthropic activities distorts allocative efficiency. He opined that a corporation’s only responsibility was to use shareholder’s funds in a profitable way. He only accepted that spending on socially responsible activities could be a company’s goal if it improved the company’s profits more than other ways of spending that money. His second point was: “How can it be ethical that a corporation should act first as an unpaid tax collector and then as an unaccountable benefactor?” In his opinion, it was up to publicly elected representatives to provide finance for public services and up to individuals to donate to charity. Finally he stated that companies cannot possess responsibilities – only individuals can do so. Companies are social constructs set up by the law and as such are unable to have responsibilities – a subject that has been the focus of much philosophical debate. There are significant obstacles facing companies that wish to undertake socially responsible activities. For example, if they incur costs that their competitors do not, they put themselves at risk of erosion of their competitive position. Also, drawing on regulatory themes, if they invite government attention, they may be hampered by regulations that impose costs without generating meaningful societal benefits in return (such as environmental taxes criticised by the CBI for imposing burdens on businesses without providing much benefit to the environment). Could academic study apply the principles facing companies in the broader field of socially responsible behaviour to the specific issues of the ethics surrounding tax planning? The legal structures of corporations owned by shareholders impose certain priorities on their leaders. If leaders fail to maximise shareholder value, they risk removal by equity holders and they put the company at risk of being acquired by a stronger company. This would seem to imply that self preservation would dictate that no rational executive would engage in any activities which do not have as their primary purpose the increase of shareholder value. The fact that the directors of a company have a fiduciary duty to protect the investment of the shareholders is of key importance. In some states in the USA, shareholders are able to sue a company if they believe that actions are being taken that are not in their best interests. A situation can be conceived whereby a company could be sued for being overly philanthropic with money that the shareholders believe should be put to work to improve their investments. Tax can be a very large number in the profit and loss account of a company’s

© 2005 KPMG LLP, the UK member firm of KPMG International, a Swiss cooperative. All rights reserved. KPMG and the KPMG logo are registered trademarks of KPMG International.

KPMG’s Tax Business School is a registered trademark of KPMG in the UK, a member firm of KPMG International.

Page 17: Philosophy of Tax Law

17

financial statements and if a company were to make no attempt to arrange its tax affairs to mitigate these liabilities it is logical that this will be to the detriment of the business and potentially all the stakeholders, not just the shareholders. However, it is true to say that corporations do not exist in a world that is made up solely of shareholders. They are also subject to pressures from other stakeholders and it is important to note that stakeholders are not mutually exclusive of each other. A person could be a shareholder and a consumer for example. As discussed further on in this paper, pressure from certain sections of society can drive improvements in one company or industry that can become normal practice through the expectations of society in general, which can then be introduced into legislation or regulation to ensure a minimum standard of behaviour for all firms. In this way, there can be a continual cycle of improvement of corporate behaviour. The large amount of tax that corporations pay, together with their broader contribution to the economy, makes them key stakeholders in the nation and arguably should give them a greater influence than they currently have on the setting of fiscal policies. This would also mean that companies could use their business skills and financial expertise in a socially responsible way in order to help the government to develop fiscal policy that is beneficial to all. There are many examples in practice of where the most effective type of socially responsible behaviour is using a company’s particular capabilities to address a problem faced by groups in society. For example, Procter and Gamble used their own expertise in order to develop a technology that allows people in the developing world to disinfect water in their own homes at very low cost (Martin 2002). Another point that has been made by supporters of the CSR debate is that surely an aim of corporate social responsibility is to give a company an ethical approach to doing business. Is it possible to be ethical in one area of the business and not in others and yet still be socially responsible? If one assumes the point of view that aggressive tax planning is not ethical, then one can imagine a situation where a company makes a contribution of, say, £100,000 to a children’s ward of a hospital for vital equipment, but undertakes a tax planning scheme that allows them not to pay £1,000,000 of tax, which potentially would go to the NHS. There must be many examples of this in practice. Does this show a disconnection in the values of the company? If one accepts that a company should try to be socially responsible it would appear that its tax policy should be in line with its other CSR policies. 2.8 Tools to consider

A tool has been developed by Texas Instruments in order to help people consider the relevant issues when making ethical decisions (http://www.ti.com/corp/docs/company/citizen/ethics/quicktest.shtml). The Texas Instruments ethics test uses a series of questions to help a person to decide whether something is ethical or not, although it is worth noting again that the answers will be subjective and wide-ranging from individual to individual. These are:

Is it legal? Does it comply with our values? If you do it, will you feel bad? How will it look in the newspapers?

This looks at ethics from a point of view of social responsibility rather than a pure philosophical outlook, but these questions are very interesting when applied to tax from a perspective of corporate social responsibility and linked to a company’s own CSR agenda. Arguably most companies would only undertake legal tax planning activities, but how do tax directors feel about the arrangements they implement? Would companies want the intricate details of their tax planning published on the front pages of the Financial Times? If a specific consequence of the non-payment of tax could be identified, might their responses be different? Do companies consider tax when designing their CSR policies?

© 2005 KPMG LLP, the UK member firm of KPMG International, a Swiss cooperative. All rights reserved. KPMG and the KPMG logo are registered trademarks of KPMG International.

KPMG’s Tax Business School is a registered trademark of KPMG in the UK, a member firm of KPMG International.

Page 18: Philosophy of Tax Law

18

The Australian Tax Office has also developed a tool designed to be used by the boards of companies in assessing their tax strategy. In the form of a letter sent out to board members of Australian companies, they asked a number of questions to try and ensure that board members are thinking about their company’s tax policy (http://www.ato.gov.au/large/). Two examples of questions asked are:

If your group is consistently reporting losses, are these real economic losses and can they be satisfactorily explained in terms of the group’s overall performance?

If the structure for your group’s business or a major transaction is complicated, is this

because the business issues are complicated? Or are there additional steps designed to reduce the taxes that would ordinarily be payable?

The ATO intend these questions to help board members determine whether there are any governance issues associated with the group’s tax responsibilities and whether there are any tax issues within the group that might attract ATO attention. Even if the company still fully intends to undertake tax mitigation, it can only be helpful that the board is fully informed and involved in these decisions and the above questions allow those at the company to evaluate the ATO’s likely response to their actions. This way any consequences of tax planning and policy can be anticipated and tax risks managed. Here in the UK, now that several non-financial considerations have been assigned to tax, such as reputational risk, reporting decisions and governance issues, it is important that decisions regarding tax also reach non-financial directors, in order that the tax function is managed to the best advantage of the company. On a more fundamental level, Roger L Martin, in an article in the Harvard Business Review, introduces us to a concept called the Virtue Matrix, which he designed in order to assist executives to think about the issues of corporate responsibility. He split the types of activity that a company can undertake into four sections of a matrix, each governed by their effect on shareholder behaviour. His theory discussed four sections of a matrix with the structural frontier at the top right; the strategic frontier at the top left; the choice section of the civil foundation at the bottom left and the compliance section of the civil foundation at the bottom right. These terms are explained below: Frontier – structural This part of the matrix again represents a course of action that is undertaken because it is the right thing to do, but that is clearly contrary to the interests of shareholders. These activities are unlikely to become the norm in the corporate field. The example that Roger Martin gives to illustrate this is that of Aaron Feuerstein’s decisions at Malden Mills (see below). Frontier – strategic This part of the matrix represents a course of action that is undertaken because it is the right thing to do. This is a risk, but it may add to shareholder value by generating positive reactions from customers, employees or authorities. A real life example of this is the introduction by Prudential Insurance of viatical settlements that allowed people suffering from AIDS to use the death benefits of their life insurance policies to pay for medical expenses. This was groundbreaking at the time, but swiftly became commonplace due to the goodwill it created. This is also a good example of how socially responsible corporate practices can move from the strategic frontier as other companies adopt the practice until it becomes the norm. Civil foundation – choice This part of the matrix represents activities that a company chooses to undertake that have the dual aim of enhancing shareholder value and meeting the social requirements of the broader community. For example a company might provide kit, equipment and improved facilities for a

© 2005 KPMG LLP, the UK member firm of KPMG International, a Swiss cooperative. All rights reserved. KPMG and the KPMG logo are registered trademarks of KPMG International.

KPMG’s Tax Business School is a registered trademark of KPMG in the UK, a member firm of KPMG International.

Page 19: Philosophy of Tax Law

19

disadvantaged children’s sports team because they believe that the cost of providing such facilities is far less than the value of the goodwill it creates among the customers of the company. Civil foundation – compliance This part of the matrix represents activities that explicitly serve the purpose of enhancing shareholder value, but this time it creates shareholder wealth by ensuring that a business stays on the right side of the law. For example, a company ensuring that it does not exceed its limits on carbon emission. This safeguards shareholders by ensuring a company does not attract legal sanctions or reputation-damaging publicity.

The Malden Mills example mentioned above is an interesting one. On December 11, 1995 a fire burnt most of Malden Mills to the ground and put 3,000 people out of work. Rather than taking the compensation money and moving the factory to a less economically depressed part of the US, Aaron Feuerstein continued to pay all the staff who had worked in the factory on full benefits while the factory was being rebuilt. He said: “I have an equal responsibility to the community. It would have been unconscionable to put 3,000 people on the streets and deliver a death blow to the cities of Lawrence and Methuen. Maybe on paper our company is worth less to Wall Street, but I can tell you it is worth more.” Despite the fact that his actions were not beneficial to the shareholders (most of whom were admittedly members of his family) he went ahead and paid the workers and rebuilt in the same location as he thought that was the ethical thing to do. Unfortunately, the company eventually went into liquidation. How would these definitions affect the current debate on ethical tax behaviour? What are the benefits or disadvantages to shareholders of the company ceasing to use tax planning arrangements? If the company pays out more tax, this will decrease the returns made to the shareholder, thus diminishing the value of his investment. If the company was the only one in its field to cease tax planning, the extra costs that it incurred might reduce its ability to be competitive in the market place. It might also give the company cash flow problems. None of these effects are beneficial to the shareholder. However, it is possible that the effect of being seen to be a socially responsible company paying its fair share of tax might be to enhance the reputation of the company and therefore its shareholder value. Arguably these considerations put a conservative tax policy on the strategic frontier, although arguments could be made for its presence on the structural frontier. In any case, it would seem that any policy on what constitutes acceptable tax planning would need to be made on behalf of corporate groups as a whole, as the risk for one company acting alone would outweigh the benefits. This situation can be compared with the emission of greenhouse gases. Were one company to undertake to drastically reduce its emissions, it would be at considerable risk to its own market position, and without much overall reduction in the emission of gases by society as a whole. On the other hand, if emitting companies were to act together to agree a suitable policy for reducing emissions and stick to it, this would significantly cut both gas emissions and the risks posed to each firm individually. Equally, for example, were one company to resolve not to use tax havens and to pay tax in the location where its profits were earned, it would not increase the tax take of that locale significantly, but the company would put itself at a distinct disadvantage in the market place. If all firms operating in that location were to make the same agreement, the tax revenue would rise substantially, again with reduced risks to each individual company. However, the advantage of this to the shareholders of the companies is unclear. An article in the Harvard Business Review by Simon Zadek (December 2004) documents the power of stakeholders in businesses to achieve socially beneficial outcomes, taking the reader through the stages of learning that companies such as Nike (the focus of the article) go through when developing socially responsible behaviour. It is interesting to see if these stages can be applied to tax responsibility.

© 2005 KPMG LLP, the UK member firm of KPMG International, a Swiss cooperative. All rights reserved. KPMG and the KPMG logo are registered trademarks of KPMG International.

KPMG’s Tax Business School is a registered trademark of KPMG in the UK, a member firm of KPMG International.

Page 20: Philosophy of Tax Law

20

The first stage is the defensive stage. This would arise after a company had come under criticism regarding its tax activities. The likely response would be implemented by PR and legal teams and would be along the lines of “we have only taken the steps allowed by the law in order to minimise our tax liability”. The second stage is the compliance stage. At this stage it is clear that a corporate policy is required and that it can be demonstrated to the company’s critics that it is working. Companies can understand compliance – it protects the company’s reputation and reduces the risk of litigation. The third stage is the managerial stage. This is where the company realises that it is facing a problem that is not short term and will not go away and that someone in the company needs to take responsibility for solving the problem. Arguably this is the stage that tax directors of large companies are currently at in respect to tax ethics. Some companies are learning the importance of taking tax into the boardroom and thinking about developing internal tax policies that will impose accountability on the tax department and require board approval (or otherwise) of tax planning arrangements. The fourth stage is the strategic stage. This is where the company learns how developing responsible business practices can give it a competitive edge and help contribute to the organisation’s success. This could be the application of the internal tax policies mentioned above, although more research is required as to the effect that tax reputation issues actually have on share price. One study based in Israel (Harony and Aviva 2003) showed that there was no statistically significant effect on the share price of a company for the period of time during which its CEO was being prosecuted for tax evasion. However, this does not mean that if there are no reputational effects, companies should be able to behave as they wish. The campaign against Nike, which was so well documented in the media did not appear to produce any real damage to its share price and this could have been due to the fact that Nike was willing to address its problems and take innovative steps to change the ethos of the way that it managed its supply chains. This process may have been kick-started by the negative publicity, but it also appeared that Nike wished to address the issues discussed in Zadek’s article because of a genuine desire to improve its way of doing business. The final stage is the civil stage. In this stage, companies promote collective action to address society’s concerns. This might be the encouragement of all companies to adopt acceptable tax practices and agreement with HMR&C that certain standards will be adhered to. Perceptions of tax and of the tax authorities

3.1 Introduction

Much research has been undertaken in respect of the economic psychology of how individuals decide whether to comply with tax regulations or whether to attempt to reduce their tax liability. This approach has been developed into methods that tax authorities can use in order to encourage compliance amongst taxpayers and seek to ensure that the relationship between taxpayers and tax authorities encourages maximum voluntary compliance possible. Tax evasion is of course illegal and therefore not acceptable under any circumstances but perhaps the lessons learned from studies of evaders (the literature on which is more prevalent) can be helpful in assessing the attitude of people and corporations toward tax avoidance. It is also possible that in the field of psychology, the distinction between avoidance and evasion is not as critical as it is to the legal profession as both start with the premise of trying to reduce one’s tax bill – this would be an interesting preliminary question that psychologists might need to research before undertaking more detailed work into tax avoidance behaviour.

There appears to be a lack of academic research undertaken to date about people’s attitudes to various different taxes and the extent to which people think that it is appropriate to attempt to avoid these taxes. Also, the research that has been done is mainly concentrated on individuals rather than corporations, so further studies about the decision making process behind a corporation’s tax planning

© 2005 KPMG LLP, the UK member firm of KPMG International, a Swiss cooperative. All rights reserved. KPMG and the KPMG logo are registered trademarks of KPMG International.

KPMG’s Tax Business School is a registered trademark of KPMG in the UK, a member firm of KPMG International.

Page 21: Philosophy of Tax Law

21

would be of great interest. Further empirical research done in these areas could do much to add to the debate on tax behaviour and tax policy. Due to an apparent lack of relevant tax research undertaken in the UK, many of the papers discussed here are from the United States or Australia. This section is by no means intended to be an exhaustive review of the literature published on the topics of taxation and psychology. Rather, the intention here is to highlight thought provoking pieces of research which pose interesting questions for additional research activities.

A vast amount of research has been done on the subject of tax policy and the drivers behind it and it is not proposed to attempt to summarise all of this research in this paper. Section 3.6 of the paper discusses how the concepts of incentivisation could be applied to the tax avoidance debate. Tax policy is of also interest due to the fact that the drivers of tax policy can be influenced by how these policies are perceived by taxpayers and therefore if tax policy could be designed with taxpayer behaviour in mind, it may help to reduce problems associated with avoidance and evasion. It would be very interesting for academics who study taxpayer behaviour to look at UK tax policy in this light.

3.2 Taxpayer behaviour

Academic research has studied the decision making processes that individuals undergo when deciding what amount of tax to pay. The starting point of these theories is the consideration that the taxpayer has solely self interest in mind and therefore considers the probability of being caught and the fine he will need to pay if he is caught, and then compares this with the amount that he will save if he does not pay his taxes and does not get caught (the so-called rational actor theory). This approach implies that high penalties and high probabilities of audit are needed to ensure maximum compliance. However, this approach cannot explain the generally high levels of compliance that have been observed, where the majority of taxpayers complete their tax returns in agreement with the law. For example, in the US, in 1990 only 0.8 percent of individual tax returns were audited and in 1995 only 4.1 percent of taxpayers who were audited and who were reassessed as a result of the audit had any penalty at all (Wintrobe 2001). Yet the IRS estimates that, for example in 1992, 91.7 percent of income that should have been reported was reported. As discussed earlier in this paper, it is clear that for some people paying tax is a moral obligation, but there are also other psychological factors explaining the departure from pure self-interest that have been studied in the literature and that need to be taken into account.

Some studies of individual taxpayer compliance look at the “public choice” approach to the issue. This hypothesises that citizens of democratic political jurisdictions perceive a connection between the taxes they pay and the government services they receive and implies that taxpayers are aware that taxes are the price they pay for public services. This therefore forms part of an implicit contract with other taxpayers and the government. A paper by Ronald Wintrobe (2001) discusses this concept in terms of the relationship of exchange between the government and the taxpayer. The results of his research led him to make some suggestions that could be used to reduce tax evasion and these may also be useful when considering what taxpayers may think about when intending to avoid taxes. The first is that as long as taxpayers (individuals and corporations) do not think that the government is responsive to their wishes, they may attempt to evade their taxes. This implies that it is important for the government to know what taxpayers are happy for their money to be spent on and to be motivated to do this. Secondly, if taxpayers do not trust the government they are unlikely to comply voluntarily with the tax laws. The example shown here is that of Russia, which in the past had strong authoritarian governments that were not trusted by taxpayers and which attempted to uphold the law with a punitive regime. This can go part way to explaining Russia’s past problems with large scale tax evasion. Thirdly, and possibly most importantly when trying to explain tax avoidance behaviour, people are more willing to pay their taxes where they believe the tax code is fair. It would appear not to take much motivation for a taxpayer to use legal tax mitigation where he think the tax law is unfair and he should not be subject to those taxes/that amount of tax he seeks to avoid. Finally, the point is made that as long as people believe that others are evading tax, they will seek to do the same. Again this psychology can be applied to those looking to avoid their taxes – if everyone else is doing it, and it is legal, why shouldn’t they? Also, for corporations, if others are able to avoid paying tax and they

© 2005 KPMG LLP, the UK member firm of KPMG International, a Swiss cooperative. All rights reserved. KPMG and the KPMG logo are registered trademarks of KPMG International.

KPMG’s Tax Business School is a registered trademark of KPMG in the UK, a member firm of KPMG International.

Page 22: Philosophy of Tax Law

22

cannot or do not; then economically they are placing themselves at a competitive disadvantage. However, if reputational effects are important, and the public would prefer to purchase goods from a company that did not use tax reduction strategies, the company may not be disadvantaged.

A paper by H Elffers and DJ Hessing (1997) uses knowledge of psychology to suggest methods of preventing tax evasion in the United States. They postulate a theory that states that if a person is expecting to gain from a situation, they adopt risk avoiding behaviour, whereas if the taxpayer is expecting to lose out in a situation, they will adopt more risky behaviour. For example, if a taxpayer fills in his tax return and discovers that the IRS will be paying him back some tax, he will simply file his return. Whereas if the taxpayer fills in his return and discovers that he owes some tax to the IRS, he is more likely to re-examine his form to see where he can rectify this situation – potentially a more risky approach if his examinations and subsequent amendments take him the wrong side of the law. This approach appears to be supported by a study by Cox and Plumley (1988) which shows that the percentage of tax returns needing correction increases consistently and considerably as a function of the amount of supplementary payments that the taxpayers need to pay.

Their second suggestion involves taxpayers choosing whether to forgo the claim for tax deductible items on their tax return in exchange for the right to a standard deduction. This approach highlights problems in theories proposing that human behaviour is governed by rational choices, which would assume that taxpayers would calculate their tax liabilities under both methods and then pick the one which is lower. The paper postulates that in actual fact the taxpayer may instead make a rough estimate of what his deductions are and compare this with the situation under the standard deduction and then decide whether or not to make the effort and do a full calculation. The paper also argues that there is also a psychological advantage to the standard deduction in that the taxpayer can be certain of the tax liability on his return. He does not need to worry about whether he has interpreted the tax legislation correctly and claimed only the permissible deductions or whether he has made errors which will be challenged or rejected by the Inspectors. These psychological advantages may improve compliance, but clearly these considerations could only work in a system where the majority of taxpayers complete a tax return annually. Lars P Feld and Bruno S Frey (2002) looked at how the constitutional differences of Swiss cantons affected the likelihood of evasion. Previous studies (such as Pommerehne and Frey (1992)) have concluded that the more directly democratic the political decision making procedures of a canton are, the lower the incidence of tax evasion. In the cantons of Switzerland, the taxpayer can change tax laws in the political process (via referenda) and the tax authorities are aware of this; therefore citizens have much better ways of expressing their discontent with tax policy than by breach of the psychological contract with the tax authorities. Even if groups of voters do not win in a referendum, they are aware that the political process is fair and therefore will comply with tax laws. This paper seems to imply that were taxpayers to be more involved in setting the tax rules, they would be more likely to abide by them and not seek creative ways in which to reduce their tax bills. If taxpayers could participate in the creation of a code of agreed conduct, they might well be more likely to perceive the system as fair and to co-operate with the agreed practices. Is it possible that all the theories about why a taxpayer, whether individual or corporate, might attempt to evade his taxes could also be applied to why a taxpayer might use tax mitigating arrangements to avoid paying taxes? It may be possible that due to the obvious distinction that the risk is lessened as avoidance is legal, the motivation to use mitigating arrangements may be higher than any motivation to evade taxes. Most of the literature on avoidance or evasion is concentrated on individuals rather than corporations, but it could be argued that the opportunities and rewards for a company to minimise its tax liability are higher and the risks are lower. There can be a subtle distinction between ways of looking at tax minimisation. For example, sale and leaseback is both a means of raising finance for a company and a technique for obtaining a favourable tax treatment for leasing. Whether the primary reason for implementing the scheme is to raise finance or to obtain tax relief, the results are the same and both are achieved. Is a corporation’s propensity to implement such schemes likely to

© 2005 KPMG LLP, the UK member firm of KPMG International, a Swiss cooperative. All rights reserved. KPMG and the KPMG logo are registered trademarks of KPMG International.

KPMG’s Tax Business School is a registered trademark of KPMG in the UK, a member firm of KPMG International.

Page 23: Philosophy of Tax Law

23

be higher when its tax function can justify it by a business purpose as well as by reference to the tax relief?

3.3 Using behavioural models to change behaviour

3.3.1 The Compliance Pyramid

In 1998 the Australian Tax Office (ATO) introduced a new regulatory model in order to improve their long-term compliance enforcement strategies (see Taxing Democracy, Ashgate Publishing International for a full description). This model was introduced because of regular media reports about poor ATO practices, bullying tactics and unfair use of their powers. This model proposes that as taxation is continuous and fundamental to the long-term health of the community, the goal of the tax authorities should not be to punish, but rather to secure long term voluntary compliance. When punishment, rather than co-operation, is the premise of a regulatory encounter it is basic to human psychology that people will feel humiliated and their response may well be weakened respect for compliance with the law. Also, individuals and firms are more likely to regard enforcement action as fair if persuasion has been attempted first.

A study was undertaken so that the regulators could understand why a person has a certain attitude towards paying tax. An article by Kristina Murphy in the British Tax Review discussed the five terms that were adopted to describe the attitudes of taxpayers to compliance. These are commitment, capture, resistance, disengagement and game-playing. The idea behind the compliance model was that by tailoring the ATO’s approach, it could select the correct response to the attitude presented by the taxpayer and then attempt to encourage taxpayers toward the more desirable attitudes. Perhaps it is the category of taxpayers who are game-players that are of the most interest in light of the subject matter of this paper. They enjoy the challenge of unearthing grey areas of tax law and the test of minimising their tax liabilities and generally believe that they are fulfilling their obligations under the law. Murphy mentions that it would be interesting for more research to be undertaken regarding the behaviour of this type of taxpayer, as they are those who would adopt and use tax avoidance schemes.

The approach adopted by the ATO was designed to be a balance between deterrence and persuasion as there are significant disadvantages to adopting one approach absolutely over the other. The problem of a punishment-based policy is that it can inadvertently cause resistance to regulation reducing the likelihood of compliance amongst individuals who always intend to do the right thing. For example, if a taxpayer makes an inadvertent error due to the complexities and ambiguities of the tax system, she is likely to believe that any punishment she receives is unfair and unreasonable. Also, deterrence can be expensive and time-consuming. However, a solely persuasive approach could be viewed as naïve. The regulatory approach adopted at the ATO therefore considers when to punish taxpayers and when to persuade them. The model used is called the Compliance Pyramid and it starts with a persuasive approach and graduates through warning letters and civil then criminal penalties to the most severe sanctions that the ATO is allowed to impose. The idea is that in starting with a gentler and more persuasive response, the taxpayer is given every opportunity to correct his behaviour and assistance can be given if the errors made have come from a lack of tax or business knowledge. This means that relationships can be built up, the taxpayer can be educated about the tax system and the message that it is the taxpayer’s responsibility to comply with the rules can be reinforced. The level of punishment then increases if taxpayers continue to resist the authority’s attempts to encourage compliance, but all the while at the discretion of the tax authorities, in order that they can attempt to select the correct response to the taxpayer’s attitude.

This is interesting to apply to the Inland Revenue, who promote the use of a model similar to that of the ATO. There are many approaches that the Inland Revenue have put in place in order to improve their relationship with taxpayers and it will be interesting to see how they continue to do this as part of HMR&C. However, in practice, it would appear that in some cases the authorities are formalising their approach to certain taxpayers. It has come to the attention of the accounting firms that Large Business Office inspectors have been instructed rigorously to apply paragraph 27 Sch18 FA1998, one

© 2005 KPMG LLP, the UK member firm of KPMG International, a Swiss cooperative. All rights reserved. KPMG and the KPMG logo are registered trademarks of KPMG International.

KPMG’s Tax Business School is a registered trademark of KPMG in the UK, a member firm of KPMG International.

Page 24: Philosophy of Tax Law

24

of their main investigatory powers, from 1 May 2005. The impact that inspection style can have on regulation is discussed further on in the paper in section 3.4, where a paper by May (2004) regarding compliance with building codes in the USA concluded that inspector behaviour can affect the dispositions of regulatees to comply with regulations and that inspectors can play an important role in shaping a sense of obligation to comply that is fundamental to the regulatory social contract. The paper also suggests that once an inspector “gets tough”, any later attempts at facilitation will backfire – there is no going back and they will be seen more as a “cop than a consultant”!

As a small aside, it may be worth noting that the population of Switzerland is around 7.4 million and the population of Australia is approximately 20 million, whereas the population of the UK is roughly 60 million. Therefore, where this paper discusses approaches that have been used in these two countries to improve their tax system, it could be argued that it is easier for these smaller countries to adopt a more personal approach from the tax authorities that it would be in the UK. Also any changes to the tax system or approaches to the taxpayer in these countries would be easier and cheaper to implement.

3.3.2 Applications of the principles of the ATO compliance model

A further paper by John Braithwaite (2003) describes how the risk management by the ATO of risk management systems of corporations (“meta risk management”) can be a cost-effective and responsive regulatory strategy. He makes the point that while globalisation and the creation of purpose-built financial products makes the risk faced by tax authorities more complex, new information technologies also make possible more sophisticated monitoring of these risks. Once example of this is the meta-risk management system the ATO have in place for transfer pricing. In this way they show business that if corporations manage their risks of breaching the arm’s length principle in ways the ATO specifies or approves, then they will not be subject to time-consuming and costly reviews. Here, the ATO selected 190 large companies for the Transfer Pricing Record Review (TPRR) and Improvement Project. ATO staff visited the companies to conduct a review of their transfer pricing procedures and then sent each company a letter advising them of a quality assessment between high and low given to their transfer pricing policies and documentation and different strategies adopted accordingly. The companies on the top three tiers of the risk assessment were given the option of changing their transfer pricing policies to those of an Advance Pricing Arrangement (APA). This approach is interesting to compare with the theory noted above of standard deductions for individual taxpayers. The APA is an arrangement negotiated between the company and ATO on the transfer pricing policies that will be used. If the company sticks to this, it has certainty over its tax returns and far less involvement from the ATO. For the ATO, the company is effectively doing the ATO’s risk management for it. The amount of tax paid in the year of the review increased by 26 percent despite the fact that the income of the companies fell by 5 percent. This increase in tax revenue (almost 18 million Australian dollars) cost the ATO less than half a million Australian dollars in tax office resources. There were increased tax revenues in the years following the survey also. This approach is also interesting in that the TPRR was a collaborative exercise with major accounting firms and corporate clients and the project was designed to build trust. As well as being an area where tax avoidance can be used, transfer pricing is a very difficult thing to get right and therefore in starting with an approach to help corporations improve their transfer pricing, trust began to be built.

It would be interesting for further independent research to be carried out to determine how well the theoretical approaches of the ATO discussed in this paper are actually working in practice. Research could also be performed in the same manner around HMR&C in the UK. This would allow policies to be more widely publicised and increased trust to be built up between the taxpayer, the tax practitioner and the tax authorities.

3.3.3 The compliance model and creative compliance.

© 2005 KPMG LLP, the UK member firm of KPMG International, a Swiss cooperative. All rights reserved. KPMG and the KPMG logo are registered trademarks of KPMG International.

KPMG’s Tax Business School is a registered trademark of KPMG in the UK, a member firm of KPMG International.

Page 25: Philosophy of Tax Law

25

A further paper produced in Australia discusses the issue of creative compliance (McBarnet (2002)). This paper defines “creative compliance” as finding ways to accomplish compliance with the letter of the law, while undermining the policy behind the words. The paper mentions that one factor that contributes to creative compliance is the nature of the law itself, in that it is open to different interpretations and that drafting of the law is not infallible. Some aspects of regulation theory are discussed below, but it would be interesting to study other fields where arrangements can be used to avoid the full weight of legislation and the reasons why firms and individuals might seek to do this. This might also help by removing some of the emotion that is evident in the debate surrounding tax avoidance. McBarnet believes that another factor influencing tax avoidance is a particular attitude toward the law – the attitude that sees the law as “a material to be worked on, to be tailored, regardless of the policy behind it, to one’s own interests”.

Her main argument is that regulators are often concerned about uncertainties in the law being exploited, whereas in fact creative compliance can operate particularly effectively in rule-bound systems. The paper also points out that as case law is built up around avoidance (or on the GAAR in Australia) potential new opportunities for avoidance are produced because the system determines specific responses to specific situations rather than just relying on a principle of good behaviour. Any power based on legal proceedings, such as the GAAR, that involves the courts can only be as powerful as those who are interpreting it will allow. The paper concludes by suggesting that changes in law, however wide ranging, are unlikely to eliminate creative compliance and it is attitudes that need to be changed. Perhaps this is the aim of the authorities when pushing an “ethical dimension” for tax onto centre stage. Might this mean adapting the tax law from a body of legislation that taxpayers are happy to comply with creatively but are not committed to, to include a code of principles behind the legislation with the spirit of which taxpayers were happy to comply?

3.4 Regulation, self-regulation and the role of a code of conduct

The previous section shows how the approach of the authorities to regulation can influence the behaviour of those that they seek to regulate but, looking outside the area of taxation, to what extent is regulation important in shaping corporate behaviour? A paper by Kagan, Thornton and Gunningham (2003) notes that some regulatory strategies, in focusing on compliance, fail to facilitate or encourage “beyond compliance” behaviour. They may even inadvertently discourage it. However, others argue that government-mandated self-regulation is the key to progress. Kagan’s paper looks at how firms in America and Canada have responded in the area of environmental regulation by studying the environmental performance of fourteen pulp and paper mills in various countries. They found that over the last three decades the increase in regulatory requirements and political pressures have caused an improvement in the environmental performance of the mills and that many of them have gone beyond compliance in many ways. However, regulation does not account for the differences in environmental performance that remain. Rather, pressure from their local communities and environmental activists encourages some firms toward better environmental compliance than others. Also, the style of the management of the firms has a large part to play. On the other hand, economic considerations impose limits on the extent to which the companies can take their environmental performance further no matter how committed they are to doing so. The paper concludes that regulation is important in producing large improvements in environmental performance, but not as a system of rigidly enforced rules, rather as a “co-ordinate mechanism, routinely interacting with market pressures, local and national environmental activists and the culture of corporate management in generating environmental improvement while narrowing the spread between corporate leaders and laggards.”

If regulation is less important than these other pressures in ensuring that firms continuously seek to improve their environmental performance, an efficient regulatory system will nevertheless encourage progress by reassuring the leaders that their less committed competitors will also be compelled to spend money to achieve the same levels of environmental performance as the leaders have shown is possible. This means that pressures on one firm (the leader) and its environmental style of

© 2005 KPMG LLP, the UK member firm of KPMG International, a Swiss cooperative. All rights reserved. KPMG and the KPMG logo are registered trademarks of KPMG International.

KPMG’s Tax Business School is a registered trademark of KPMG in the UK, a member firm of KPMG International.

Page 26: Philosophy of Tax Law

26

management can be used in order to develop the regulatory system and improve performance across the population.

It would appear that there are important parallels that can be drawn between environmental regulation and performance and the tax avoidance issue. Firstly, the improvement of environmental performance and of tax policies are both generally accepted to give desirable social consequences. Secondly, both issues cause firms to face adverse publicity from those who are unhappy with their behaviour. Thirdly, if a company has a desire to go beyond compliance, it has to temper this with responsibilities to its shareholders, employees and customers. Finally in both of these cases, companies take as their basic starting point compliance with the law. It is then up to them whether they wish to just stick to the law, or go beyond this in developing their own “code” of environmental standards or tax standards. How can the regulatory environment encourage these desirable outcomes? Interestingly, in comparison with the managerial style that was noted as important to environmental performance in the paper discussed above, tax research in the United States has shown that small companies that are non-compliant in their corporate income taxes are three times more likely to be managed by executives who have understated personal taxes (Joulfaian 2000). This suggest that at least for small companies managerial styles play an important role in determining the level of tax compliance (Slemrod 2004). Intuitively it would appear likely that the attitude of corporate tax staff toward tax risk would affect the type of tax planning undertaken by that company, therefore this might be an interesting area for further research.

Sometimes, it is possible for strategic self-regulation to pre-empt political action. Also, self-regulation may increase consumer demand by reducing uncertainty about quality of products or ensuring the inter-operability of the products of different firms. It may enhance employee retention by improving workplace safety. It can also serve a more strategic purpose by softening competition or pre-empting stricter government regulation. If self-regulation is more cost effective than government regulation, it is more sensible for companies to self regulate even if they do not face a greater level of restraint from the government. Reports by Rice (Rice 1992) using the US Taxpayer Compliance Measurement Program also concluded that compliance (i.e. the absence of evasion) among US companies was highest amongst publicly traded companies and those in highly regulated areas such as banking and insurance. This suggests that factors encouraging transparency and disclosure also foster compliance. However, it would be interesting to know whether a relationship can be drawn between a firm’s propensity to engage in tax planning activities and its regulatory environment.

PJ May (May, 2004) undertook a study of the regulation of the homebuilding sector in the United States. This sector seems to provide an ideal case study for responsive regulation practices as the primary mechanism for ensuring compliance with building code are safety inspections by local building inspectors and inspections occur multiple times at different stages of the building project. As inspection is certain, compliance is ensured through detection and correction of violations. However, as the homebuilders have more at stake than just the avoidance of penalties (namely the maintenance of reputation and the fact that build quality will be a key factor in the sale of their properties) the inspection is not the sole reason why they comply. According to May’s research, two reasons why people might comply with regulations are because they fear detection and punishment (a negative base) and because they feel a duty to comply (an affirmative base). He argues that in order for regulation to be treated as a social contract, there must be affirmative reasons for adhering to the contract. If it is presumed that regulatees will not comply with regulations voluntarily, and must be compelled to do so, greater compliance will be obtained by reinforcing the fears that create the negative set of compliance motivations. For example, if people are motivated to pay tax by a fear of getting caught, then reinforcing these fears with increased audit probabilities and strict penalties will increase compliance. However, if this presumption is incorrect, it may be that affirmative motivations are undermined. This balance between affirmative and negative motivations can be compared with the ATO compliance pyramids balance between persuasive and deterrent regulation.

© 2005 KPMG LLP, the UK member firm of KPMG International, a Swiss cooperative. All rights reserved. KPMG and the KPMG logo are registered trademarks of KPMG International.

KPMG’s Tax Business School is a registered trademark of KPMG in the UK, a member firm of KPMG International.

Page 27: Philosophy of Tax Law

27

The paper studied the enforcement style of building inspectors and expected it to be a greater factor in influencing affirmative motivations than just the actions of the inspector. The paper looked at the facilitation style of the building inspectors, ranging from helpful and friendly to un-cooperative and threatening and also the formalism of the inspectors ranging from flexible to rigid and easy-going to fastidious. Taking one of these as an example, increased facilitation was thought to foster affirmative motivations while detracting from negative motivations, because it leads to greater understanding of the basis of the regulations and of the means of complying with them. However, by demystifying the means of compliance and the basis for applying sanctions, facilitation undermines the fear that is the basis of negative motivations. It may be that if cost of compliance is high and the benefit to those regulated is low, deterrent actions are more important, whereas if the cost of compliance is low and the benefit to those regulated is higher, then affirmative motivations are more important. Lowering the cost of tax compliance and increasing the benefits to regulatees might yield long term affirmative results.

Codes of practice are the most common form of self-regulation. The advantage of these voluntary codes is that they can be implemented quickly and inexpensively as they do not require time-consuming parliamentary processes. Also, the industry designs, implements and enforces the code. This has two advantages, the first being that it is likely to be set up in a way that does not place too high an administrative burden on its members and secondly; it does not involve the additional costs to society that arise when a code is set up and policed within the public sector. However, a voluntary code may be less effective than classic regulation depending on which firms/industries it covers, and may be subject to undue influence by larger companies. The use of both industry-generated codes of conduct and externally imposed codes has grown over recent years. Regulatory codes imposed additional burdens on businesses and this means that careful consideration needs to be given to this when new codes are created. However, the fact that industries can be seen to react to the possibility of government intervention by designing their own regulation suggests that business can see the advantage in this type of regulation over a more strictly imposed classic style of regulation. Sometimes voluntary codes of practice are subject to significant government intervention before they reach their final form and statutory backing can give voluntary codes added credibility.

Companies often also adopt internal codes of conduct, covering issues such as equal opportunities and good working practices. A study (Doig and Wilson 1998) of the content of company codes of conduct found that the more discrete the issue or the more the issue had legal implications, the more likely it was to be included in the code. Codes of corporate governance are used to ensure that listed companies govern themselves in an appropriate manner and some of these codes consist of recommendations rather than rigid rules, requiring companies to state whether they have adopted them and, if not, why they have not done so. Perhaps one step in the direction of improving the current situation between corporate taxpayers and the tax authorities would be such a code. This code could be determined by collaboration between these parties and companies that wished to sign up to the code could do so. There are many forms that this code could take. It could be a statement of principle; for example, not to undertake tax planning activities that are designed solely for the purpose of avoiding tax, or not to undertake activities that give a tax advantage without the company undergoing the other economic consequences that were intended by the relevant legislation. Alternatively, it could be a more structured set of rules that states that the company has agreed not to undertake certain specified activities. This code could be made part of corporate governance, by requiring that companies declare in their financial statements whether or not they had adopted it. The important thing would be that for this code to be effective it would have to be arrived at as a partnership between those who are bound by it.

In many countries efforts have been made to align tax regulation with corporate governance legislation and guidance, however, an agenda set solely by the tax authorities runs the risk of being too prescriptive and lacking the flexibility required by businesses. There are also issues in general with requiring additional disclosure by companies. For example, for many years Nike resisted the publication of details of its supply chains. This was bemoaned by CSR advocates, who wanted to monitor the supply chains in order to ensure that Nike was actually making the improvements to

© 2005 KPMG LLP, the UK member firm of KPMG International, a Swiss cooperative. All rights reserved. KPMG and the KPMG logo are registered trademarks of KPMG International.

KPMG’s Tax Business School is a registered trademark of KPMG in the UK, a member firm of KPMG International.

Page 28: Philosophy of Tax Law

28

working conditions that it had publicised (Crane and Matten; Chapter 2). However, Nike argued that details surrounding its supply chain were of a sensitive nature and if they were to publish these details, they would be losing their competitive advantage. Also, additional governance regulations raise costs for a company. If disclosure of tax payments, tax planning arrangements or tax policies were to become a requirement in financial statements of the future, this would allow investors and the general public to be aware of how a company runs its tax function. On one hand, this would increase burdens for businesses and might require a company to disclose sensitive information about its tax payments. However, on the other hand it might help the transition of tax policy decisions from the tax function to the boardroom, ensuring that the company has a clear decision-making process laid out and that all planning undertaken has the unequivocal support of the company’s leaders. However, arguably it is crucial that businesses and tax and accounting bodies are involved in the development of any such regulation in order to ensure a fair and workable system that is not too burdensome to businesses.

3.5 How certain taxes are perceived

This section looks at some of the research concerning how taxpayers perceive taxes. Again, this is not an exhaustive study of all relevant literature, but a discussion of a few pieces of work that pave the way for further research in this area. A survey done by Kirchler, Maciejovsky and Schneider (2003) for the Johannes Kepler University of Linz concerning people’s perceptions of tax avoidance, tax evasion and what the author calls tax flight (relocation of business in order to achieve a favourable tax treatment) makes interesting reading. The author asked those he surveyed to “free associate” words that they thought described each of these three concepts. With respect to tax evasion, people chose illegal; fraud; risk, punishable and tax saving. Tax flight was associated with the intention to save taxes and the impression that taxes are lower abroad. However, when tax avoidance was discussed, people thought that it was legal; cost saving; clever and a good idea. The author also used techniques to measure where on a scale of legality and morality each of the three tax behaviours fitted. This gave the following results:

Tax evasion Tax avoidance Tax flight

Illegal Legal Legal

Immoral Moral Immoral

It would be interesting to repeat such a study in the UK, as the popular press seems to suggest that tax avoidance is not seen as fair by the general public.

Literature also suggests that perceptions of payment may be important. In a study done by Adams and Webley (2001), people who thought of VAT payments as depleting their business funds were more likely to seek to reduce their payments than those who saw the VAT payments as belonging to C&E in the first place. Also it would seem intuitive that people object more to the paying of taxes that appear to reduce profits that they have made, for example capital gains tax or income tax on business profits, where they see their potential additional cash being reduced by the amount of tax they have to pay at a later date. This can be contrasted with the deductions at source via PAYE and NIC, where an individual is likely only to note her net income, rather than the gross amount and the tax payment. This appears to encourage the notion that this amount of tax always belonged to the government. Therefore, as well as the opportunity factor that is important in governing what taxes people seek to avoid, the method of payment may also be important.

Research by Prof Norman Gemmell, Prof Oliver Morrissey and Dr Abuzer Pinar (2004) drew some conclusions from the British Social Attitudes Survey (BSAS), which looked at how accurately people

© 2005 KPMG LLP, the UK member firm of KPMG International, a Swiss cooperative. All rights reserved. KPMG and the KPMG logo are registered trademarks of KPMG International.

KPMG’s Tax Business School is a registered trademark of KPMG in the UK, a member firm of KPMG International.

Page 29: Philosophy of Tax Law

29

assess the effect on them of increases in tax rates and whether this affects their preferences as to which taxes the Chancellor raised. They found that people are more likely to overestimate how much an increase in tax will cost them than they are to underestimate the cost. For example, more than 40 percent of people are able to estimate accurately how much an increase in income tax might cost them. Again, however, 40 percent overestimate the cost and only 15 percent underestimate the cost. Also the survey showed that given the choice between a 1 percent rise in VAT, 1p on the basic rate of income tax or 5p on the top rate of income tax, 59 percent chose the last option, with 10 percent choosing the VAT increase and 30 percent choosing the basic rate increase. The survey indicates that in general, people prefer increases in those taxes they do not pay or in those taxes that are less costly to them. Does this indicate that people are so worried about the prospects of further tax rises, that they inflate the amount they think it will cost them in their minds?

A research review by MORI using data from its own polls and again from BSAS, concluded that the public’s tolerance on taxation is very dependent on their recognising the need for it and whether they believe that the money raised will be properly and efficiently used. People also seem to distinguish between different types of taxation, with 73 percent of people thinking that the government could afford to cut excise duty on petrol and still retain adequate funding for schools and hospitals, yet simultaneously supporting the raising of national insurance to fund the NHS. More generally this survey showed that people appeared to be tolerant of the burden of tax placed on them at present, as long as this manifested itself in improved public services. A study carried out in the USA (Barron and McCaffrey) makes the point that taxes might be more acceptable to the general public if it could link them more directly to the benefits it receives. For example, social security and medicare taxes in the USA are the largest taxes for most Americans but these taxes are seldom cut. Also, people’s approaches to taxes are governed by self interest. This would appear to link back to Rawls justice theory discussed in section 2.6, which discussed how the development of an ideal society requires personal considerations to be set aside.

Moving on to the perceptions of the business community, a survey carried out in November 2002 by the CBI undertook 256 interviews with senior executives from CBI member companies various questions to assess whether they thought the UK was a good place to do business. 13 percent of those questioned thought that the UK was not an attractive place to do business due to its high corporation tax rate. 50 percent of those questioned thought that business taxation levels were very influential in their choice of country to invest in. Even more significantly, 76 percent thought that the total amount of tax paid by their company as a percentage of turnover had increased over the last five years. 17 percent thought that taxation had a very negative impact on the competitiveness of their business and 55 percent thought that it had had a fairly negative impact. Of those who thought that tax was the reason that they were non-competitive, difficulty with taxation and tax credits, the level of national insurance contributions and rising cost were listed as the reasons. A list of tax changes introduced by the government was read to the executives and they were required to state the extent to which they had affected their business. The full survey makes interesting reading - for example, 54 percent of businesses surveyed thought that the R&D tax credits have had no impact on their business. This may be because they do not apply to these companies, but it may also be that the scheme is not widely enough publicised or understood. Also National Insurance contributions appeared to concern the majority of companies surveyed. Perhaps more study of how business feels that it is affected by certain taxes might help the government develop more efficient tax policy. Incentives can only be useful if companies are aware of them and equally, unintentionally damaging provisions could be removed from legislation.

The public’s perception of inheritance tax has also been well publicised in recent years, because of the failure of the nil rate band to keep up with inflation and also because of the huge growth in house prices has brought many people into its ambit. A recent survey on the Daily Telegraph website revealed strong opinions on the subject, with almost every person whose opinions were displayed speaking out in favour of reform or removal of this tax. The two most common themes were the disincentive to save for old age, as anything that remained on death would be subject to tax, and the point that wealth accumulated during life had already been taxed during life and therefore it was

© 2005 KPMG LLP, the UK member firm of KPMG International, a Swiss cooperative. All rights reserved. KPMG and the KPMG logo are registered trademarks of KPMG International.

KPMG’s Tax Business School is a registered trademark of KPMG in the UK, a member firm of KPMG International.

Page 30: Philosophy of Tax Law

30

unjust to tax it again on death. Also mentioned was the fact that children who still live in the family home left to them by their parents will have to sell up to pay the inheritance tax on the property. This was seen as unfair by the public. Also, the tax has to be calculated and paid at a time of distress for a grieving family, which adds to its unpopularity. Even given this, however, only a small percentage of estates (estimated to be around 6 per cent in the recent Budget speech) actually pay inheritance tax and its emotional unpopularity and the perception of its inequity may be outweighing this fact in the minds of the public.

3.6 Providing incentives and disincentives

One of the functions of the tax system is to encourage desirable investments by providing tax incentives and to discourage undesirable behaviour by providing tax disincentives. Examples of the former would be the research and development tax reliefs, 100 percent capital allowances for energy- saving equipment and tax relief on pension contributions. Examples of the latter are the duties on petrol, alcohol and tobacco. Tax can be an effective form of regulation as it keeps choice regarding individual or corporate behaviour in the hands of the individual or company, whilst ensuring that, through tax, they literally pay for undertaking actions that the government has decided are bad. However, it is acknowledged that this incentivisation can be very difficult to achieve. For example, while duties on alcohol and tobacco raise revenue for the government which can help pay for the harmful effects of overuse of these drugs, they do not seem to have a large effect on people’s consumption. Also, they help to increase illegal smuggling. However, in certain circumstances they can be effective as additional taxes do hit those who are more price-constrained, such as young people. Taxes on petrol do not in general reduce people’s propensity to use their cars and can be seen to be unfair to those in rural areas where there is little public transport. In 1999, motorists contributed £36bn to the Treasury, so even if the tax does not succeed in changing people’s driving habits, it certainly raises tax revenue.

When financial directors are deciding on how to approach their tax planning, there are several things to be taken into account. The disincentives to undertake tax planning seem fairly clear. Even those tax planning arrangements that are not contested by the authorities cost money to implement and involve additional work for the tax and accounting staff at the company. With arrangements that are open to challenge, there is the cost and additional work of responding to HMR&C enquiries, and the risks of court proceedings. If the taxpayer loses the court case, she will have to pay the tax, interest on that tax and potentially penalties also. The new disclosure legislation adds a further level of administrative burden to the company (through their advisors) when undertaking tax planning. There may be reputational damage to any company that is not aware of these risks. Yet the benefits to the company of reducing its tax bill can be large enough that these risks are worthwhile. At present, there appear to be no incentives for a company to adopt a strategy toward its tax planning that is more in line with what the government intends.

One possible avenue that the government could explore in order to encourage the behaviour that they would like companies to adopt in relation to tax mitigation activities is the introduction of incentives for companies not to adopt arrangements that the government deems unacceptable. In light of the research summarised above about the attitudes of tax authorities and taxpayers that encourage voluntary compliance, further research could determine whether incentives such as tax credits for companies who adhere to a code of conduct for a set number of tax accounting periods might reduce unacceptable avoidance in a way that is initially beneficial to both parties. Tax avoidance arrangements that are legal, even if unacceptable to the government, can always succeed in saving tax for companies before the law is changed. If companies could be encouraged not to adopt the “worst” avoidance schemes, rather than penalised for adopting them, a system of co-operation could be fostered. There would be appear to be a psychological difference between, on one hand companies receiving a benefit for choosing not to do something that, while they are entitled to do so by the law, the government would prefer that they did not, and on the other hand, to the government attempting to penalise them with “reputational shaming” for something that they are entitled to do by law.

© 2005 KPMG LLP, the UK member firm of KPMG International, a Swiss cooperative. All rights reserved. KPMG and the KPMG logo are registered trademarks of KPMG International.

KPMG’s Tax Business School is a registered trademark of KPMG in the UK, a member firm of KPMG International.

Page 31: Philosophy of Tax Law

31

One example of an incentive to comply with the tax system that has been used in countries such as Ireland, Italy and in certain states within the USA is tax amnesties. These take many different forms, but basically involve a declaration by the tax authorities that if a taxpayer approaches them with the intention of bringing their tax affairs up to date, they will not face penalties for their past non-compliance. It would be interesting to see if the lessons learned from studies of tax amnesties might contribute to resolving the issue of long-term tax avoidance.

4 Conclusions and further research for academia

In conclusion, it can be seen that the tax system can lead to complex dilemmas for all those involved in it and this paper has tried to outline what some of these dilemmas are. Taxpayers and tax authorities alike desire certainty in the tax system in order that they can manage their tax payments or revenue streams. However if the views of society as to what is acceptable behaviour in this field are changing, taxpayers, and corporate taxpayers in particular, may need to consider their actions more carefully in order to avoid the risk to their reputations and the risk of increased tax authority focus. The tax authorities also may need to consider their actions and policies more carefully in light of the impact these can have on voluntary compliance. It would be very interesting for scholars to take forward some of the themes of this paper and undertake their own independent research in this area, as it appears that further study could add much to the debate.

© 2005 KPMG LLP, the UK member firm of KPMG International, a Swiss cooperative. All rights reserved. KPMG and the KPMG logo are registered trademarks of KPMG International.

KPMG’s Tax Business School is a registered trademark of KPMG in the UK, a member firm of KPMG International.

Page 32: Philosophy of Tax Law

32

Bibliography

Adam Smith Institute Idea 49: One Law for All www.adamsmith.org/80ideas/idea/49.htm Association of British Insurers Risk returns and responsibility Association of British Insurers Australian Tax Office Large Business and Tax Compliance http://www.ato.gov.au/corporate/content.

asp?doc=/content/mr2003054.htm Avery-Jones Tax Law: Rules or Principles British Tax Review 1996 p580 Baker Taxation and the Human Rights Act. British Tax Review 2005 no 1 Barlow, I and Williams DF Tax at the Crossroads Tax Advisor, October 2004 Barron, J and McCaffrey E Starving the beast - The psychology

of budget deficits

Baxendale Walker, P Avoiding the Issue Tax Journal 6/10/1997 Beer, M and Eisenstat, R How to have an honest conversation

about your business strategy Harvard Business Review February 2004

Bentham, J An Introduction to the Principles of Morals and Legislation

(1982) Eds Burns and Hart; London Methuen. Original edition (1781)

Better Regulation Task Force Imaginative Thinking for Better Regulation

Better Regulation Task Force

Bloom, N; Griffith, R and Van Reenen, J

Do R&D tax credits work? Evidence from a panel of countries 1979-1997

Journal of Public Economics 85(2002) 1-31

Bond, S; Hawkins, M; Klemm, A

Stamp Duty on Shares and its effect on share prices

IFS Working Paper 04/11

Boyns, N; Cox, M and Spires R (PACEC) and Hughes, A

Research into the Enterprise Investment Scheme and Venture Capital Trusts

www.inlandrevenue.gov.uk

Bracewell-Milnes, B Free Wills: Inheritance without Taxation

Adam Smith Institute

Braithwaite, J Meta Risk Management and

Responsive Regulation Law & Policy 25 (1), 1-16. 2003

Braithwaite, J; Pittelkow Y and Williams R

Tax compliance by the very wealthy: Red Flags of Risk

Taxing Democracy

Braithwaite, V Perceptions of who is not paying

their fair share Taxing Democracy

Braithwaite, V (ed) Taxing Democracy - Understanding

Avoidance and Evasion Ashgate Publishing International

© 2005 KPMG LLP, the UK member firm of KPMG International, a Swiss cooperative. All rights reserved. KPMG and the KPMG logo are registered trademarks of KPMG International.

KPMG’s Tax Business School is a registered trademark of KPMG in the UK, a member firm of KPMG International.

Page 33: Philosophy of Tax Law

33

Brown, M Customs Take Stock Tax Journal 22/12/1997 Calderwood, G and Webley P Who responds to changes in

taxation? The relationship between taxation and the incentive to work

Journal of Economic Psychology 13 (1992) 735-748

CBI Is the UK a good place to do business?

November 02

CBI Green Taxes: Rhetoric and Reality April 2002 Christensen and Murphy The Social Irresponsibility of

Corporate Tax Avoidance Society for International Development Journal Volume 47 no.3 September 2004

Clark, GL and Hebb, T Why do they care? The market for corporate global responsibility and the role of institutional investors

Why Care? 29/06/2004

Cone, C; Feldman, M; DaSilva, A

Causes and effects Harvard Business Review July 2003

Cook, PJ and Moore, MJ This Tax is for you - the case for

higher alcohol taxes National Tax Journal September 1994, 47, 3 pg 559

Copnell T Taxing Times Audit Committee Institute Cowe, R Corporate social responsibility and

tax Ethical Corporation December 2004

Cowell FA Tax Evasion and Inequity Journal of Economic Psychology 13

(1992) 521-543 Cowell, F Sticks and Carrots Prepared for Conference on Crisis in Tax

Administration

Crane and Matten Business Ethics - A European Perspective

Oxford University Press 2004

Cribbon, J A Sterile Activity Tax Journal 22/09/1997 CSR Europe Communicating Corporate Social

Responsibility CSR Europe

Cullis, JG and Lewis, A Why people pay taxes: From a

conventional economic model to a model of social convention

Journal of Economic Psychology 18 (1997) 305-321

Dalsgaard, T The Tax System in New Zealand: An Appraisal and Options for change

OECD economic survey of New Zealand

© 2005 KPMG LLP, the UK member firm of KPMG International, a Swiss cooperative. All rights reserved. KPMG and the KPMG logo are registered trademarks of KPMG International.

KPMG’s Tax Business School is a registered trademark of KPMG in the UK, a member firm of KPMG International.

Page 34: Philosophy of Tax Law

34

De George , RT Business Ethics 5th Edition NJ: Prentice Hall Devereux, M; Lockwood, B Redoano, M

Is there a race to the bottom in corporate taxes?

Doig, A and Wilson, J The Effectiveness of Codes of

Conduct Business Ethics Vol 7 No.3 July 1998

Dwyer, T Information Exchange and Global

Economic Regulation - For Whose Benefit?

Talk at International Trade and Investment Organisation

Ellfers, H., & Hessing, D.J. Influencing the prospects of tax evasion.

Journal of Economic Psychology, 18, 289-304 (P150.5 J20M)

Erard, B and Ho, C Searching for Ghosts - Who are the non filers and what do they owe?

Journal of Public Economics 81 (2001) 25-50

Feld, LP and Frey BS Deterrence and Tax Morale: How Tax Administrations and Taxpayers Interact

University of Marburg 2002

Feld, LP and Frey BS Trust breeds Trust: How taxpayers are treated

Institute for Empirical Research in Economics University of Zurich Working Paper Series ISSN 1424-0459

Fisher and Lovell Business Ethics and Values Prentice Hall 2003 Chapter 3 Foster, M and Jones AM The role of tobacco taxes in starting

and quitting smoking: duration analysis of British data

Journal of the Royal Statistical Society (2001) 164 part 3, 517-547

Freedman, J Tax and Corporate Responsibility Tax Journal 02/06/2003 Freedman, J Defining Taxpayer Responsibility British Tax Review 2004 Vol 4 Friedman, M The Social Responsibility of

Business is to increase its profits NY Times Magazine 13/09/1970 33 122-26

Gemmell, N, Morrissey, O and Pinar, A

Tax perceptions and preferences over tax structure in the UK

The Economic Journal 114 (F117-138) 2004

Goldberg, D (QC) The Approach of the Courts to Tax

Planning Taxbar.com

Grecu, A Flat Tax - The British Case Adam Smith Institute 2004 Griffith, R and Klemm, A What has been the tax competition of IFS and UCL

© 2005 KPMG LLP, the UK member firm of KPMG International, a Swiss cooperative. All rights reserved. KPMG and the KPMG logo are registered trademarks of KPMG International.

KPMG’s Tax Business School is a registered trademark of KPMG in the UK, a member firm of KPMG International.

Page 35: Philosophy of Tax Law

35

the last 20 years? Gurtner, B Tax Evasion: Hidden Billions for

Development Social Watch

Harding, D Quaker tax protesters challenge law Accountancy Age 10/03/2005 Harony, JA and Aviva, G Moral Implications of Law in

Business: A Case of Tax Loopholes Business Ethics Vol 12 p 378-393 Oct 2003

Holt, DB; Quelch, JA; Taylor, EL

How Global Brands Compete Harvard Business Review September 2004

IFS Making Tax Law IFS Tax Law Review Committee

Discussion Paper No.3

IFS Tax Policy and Companies Green Budget Jan 2002 Inland Revenue Inland Revenue Tax receipts www.inlandrevenue.gov.uk Irvine, I and Sims, WA The Welfare Effects of Alcohol

Taxation Journal of Public Economics 52 (1993) 83-100

Ittner, CD; Larcker, DF; Randall, T

Performance Implications of Strategic Performance Measurement in financial services firms

Accounting, Organisations and Society 28 (2003) 715-741

James, S; Hasseldine, J; Hite P; Toumi, M

Tax compliance policy: An International comparison and new evidence on normative appeals and auditing

Draft Manuscript

Jenkins, R Self regulation in a global economy UNRISD Kagan, RA; Thornton, D and Gunningham, N

Explaining Corporate Environmental Performance: How does regulation matter?

Law & Society Review, Volume 37, No.1 (2003)

Karanta, M; Malmer, H; Munck, I and Olson, G

A Citizens Perspective on Public Sector Performance and Service Delivery

King, S and Sheffrin, S Tax Evasion and Equity Theory: An Investigative Approach

International Tax and Public Finance 9 505-521 2002

KPMG in the UK Tax in the Boardroom KPMG internal communication Leicester, A and Windmeijer, F The Fat Tax: Economic Incentives to

reduce obesity IFS Briefing Note No. 49

© 2005 KPMG LLP, the UK member firm of KPMG International, a Swiss cooperative. All rights reserved. KPMG and the KPMG logo are registered trademarks of KPMG International.

KPMG’s Tax Business School is a registered trademark of KPMG in the UK, a member firm of KPMG International.

Page 36: Philosophy of Tax Law

36

Mainprice, H Why Martin Brown is Wrong Tax Journal 26/01/1998 Margolis, JD and Walsh, JP Does Misery love Companies? How

Social Performace pays off Harvard Business School Working Knowledge

Martin, RL The Virtue Matrix - Calculating the return on corporate responsibility

Harvard Business Review March 2002

Maxwell, JW; Lyon, TP and Hackett, SC

Self regulation and social welfare: The polical economy of corporate environmentalism

Journal of Law and Economics vol XLIII (October 2000)

May, PJ Compliance Motivations: Affirmative and Negative bases

Law & Society Review, Volume 38, No.1 (2004)

McBarnet, D When compliance is not the solution

but the problem Taxing Democracy; Ashgate Publishing International 2002

McCafferty, EJ and Baron, J Framing and Taxation: Evaluation of tax policies involving household compositions

Journal of Economic Psychology 25 (2004) 679-705

McKerchar, M Understanding and predicting taxpayer behavioural responses to actions by tax administrations

Morgan, J How reality ate itself: Orthodoxy, Economy and Trust

Post Neo-Liberal Review April 2003

Murphy, K Aggressive tax planning:

Differentiating those playing the game from those who don’t

Journal of Economic Psychology 25 (2004) 307-329

Murphy, K Moving towards a more effective model of regulatory enforcement at the ATO

Manuscript Submitted to the British Tax Review Sept 2004; at http://ctsi.anu.edu.au/publications/taxlist.author.html

Murphy, R The Campaiging Accountant Tax Journal 05/07/2004 Nathan, A Fairness of the Means Tax Journal 6/10/1997 Nozick, R Anarchy, State and Utopia NY Basic Books, 1974 O'Donnell, G Financing Britain's Future HM Treasury March 2004 OECD 2004 Economic Survey of the United

Kingdom OECD

© 2005 KPMG LLP, the UK member firm of KPMG International, a Swiss cooperative. All rights reserved. KPMG and the KPMG logo are registered trademarks of KPMG International.

KPMG’s Tax Business School is a registered trademark of KPMG in the UK, a member firm of KPMG International.

Page 37: Philosophy of Tax Law

37

OECD Chapter Four: Forces shaping tax policy

OECD 17/06/1998

Oxfam Tax Havens: Releasing the hidden

billions for poverty eradication Oxfam website

Parry Wingfield, M Advancing the Debate Tax Journal 19/01/1998 PETRAS Environmental tax reform - what

does Europe think? PETRAS 2002

Plant, M and Harrison, L Prevention and Harm Minimisation

in the UK Alcohol Concern

PricewaterhouseCoopers Total Tax Contribution discussion

paper http://www.pwc.com/Extweb/insights.nsf/docid/75D58AF8B3774A3C80256F8800586AC6

Primarolo, D Playing with Fire Tax Journal 22/09/1997 Quinlan, M More Reform, Less Deterrent Tax Journal 27/10/1997 Rae, D FD's targeted as war on tax

avoidance gets personal Accountancy Age 24/02/2005

Rand, A The Virtue of Selfishness Signet Books 1964 Rawls, J A Theory of Justice Cambridge Mass: Harvard University

Press 1971 Sartoris, J The Ethics of Tax Avoidance Philosophy for Business Vol 1 2/11/2003 Schneider, F; Kirchler, E; Maciejovsky

Social Representations on Tax avoidance, tax evasion and tax flight

Johannes Kepler University of Linz

Sharnock, M Can we GAAR-D against Tax Avoidance?

Tax Journal 15/09/1997

Sharnock, M A Nine Days Wonder Tax Journal 6/10/1997 Sikka, P Chasing the tax cheats Public Finance 02/04/04 Simon's Direct Tax Services Tax avoidance: Transactions in

Securities

Simon's Direct Tax Services Transactions in Land and Leased

Assets

Slemrod, J; Blumenthal, M; Christian, C

Taxpayer response to an increased probability of audit: evidence from a controlled experiment in Minnesota

Journal of Public Economics 79(2001) 455-483

Stainer, A; Stainer, L and Segal, A

The Ethics of Tax Planning A European Review, Vol6 No4 Oct 1997

© 2005 KPMG LLP, the UK member firm of KPMG International, a Swiss cooperative. All rights reserved.

KPMG and the KPMG logo are registered trademarks of KPMG International. KPMG’s Tax Business School is a registered trademark of KPMG in the UK, a member firm of KPMG International.

Page 38: Philosophy of Tax Law

38

Tax Law Review Committee Tax avoidance (IFS, London 1997) para 1.24 Texas Instruments The Texas Instruments Ethics Test www.ti.com/corp/docs/company/citizen/

ethics/quicktest.shtml Thornhill, A Opening the debate Tax Journal 29/09/1997 Torgler, B Speaking to theorists and searching

for facts: Tax morale and tax compliance in experiments

Journal of Economic Surveys Vol 16, No.5

Ward, G ICAEW Corporate Governance - Why should companies care?

ICAEW Centre for Business Performance

Wenzel, M An analysis of norm processes in tax

compliance Journal of Economic Psychology 25 (2004) 213-228

Wintrobe, R Tax Evasion and Trust University of Western Ontario Department of Economics Working Papers Number 200111.

Wyman, P Upholding the Law Tax Journal 10/11/1997 Zadek, S The Path to Corporate Responsibility Harvard Business Review December

2004 Cases IRC v Duke of Westminster AC1 New Angel Court v Adam [2004] STC 779 Reed v Nova Securities [1985] STC 124 Ramsay v IRC [1981] STC 174 Furniss v Dawson [1984] STC 153 MacNiven v Westmoreland [2001] STC 237 Barclays Mercantile Business Finance Limited v Mawson [2005] STC 1 Scottish Provident Institution v IRC [2005] STC15

© 2005 KPMG LLP, the UK member firm of KPMG International, a Swiss cooperative. All rights reserved. KPMG and the KPMG logo are registered trademarks of KPMG International.

KPMG’s Tax Business School is a registered trademark of KPMG in the UK, a member firm of KPMG International.