optimizing venture capital investments in a jump diffusion model

22
Math Meth Oper Res (2008) 67:21–42 DOI 10.1007/s00186-007-0181-x ORIGINAL ARTICLE Optimizing venture capital investments in a jump diffusion model Erhan Bayraktar · Masahiko Egami Received: 1 June 2007 / Revised: 24 August 2007 / Published online: 25 September 2007 © Springer-Verlag 2007 Abstract We study two practical optimization problems in relation to venture capital investments and/or Research and Development (R&D) investments. In the first problem, given the amount of the initial investment and the cash flow structure at the initial public offering (IPO), the venture capitalist wants to maximize overall discounted cash flows after subtracting subsequent investments, which keep the in- vested company solvent. We describe this problem as a mixture of singular stochastic control and optimal stopping problems. The second problem is concerned with optimal dividend policy. Rather than selling the company at an IPO, the investor may want to harvest technological achievements in the form of dividend when it is appropriate. The optimal control policy in this problem is a mixture of singular and impulse controls. Keywords Venture capital investments · R&D · IPO · Stochastic control · Optimal stopping · Singular control · Impulse control · Jump diffusions Mathematics Subject Classification (2000) Primary 49N25 · Secondary 60G40 1 Introduction In accordance with the recent theoretical and practical development in the area of real options, modeling venture capital investment and R&D has become an important E. Bayraktar was supported in part by the National Science Foundation, under grant DMS-0604491. E. Bayraktar (B ) · M. Egami Department of Mathematics, University of Michigan, Ann Arbor, MI 48109-1043, USA e-mail: [email protected] M. Egami e-mail: [email protected] 123

Upload: erhan-bayraktar

Post on 11-Jul-2016

217 views

Category:

Documents


3 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Optimizing venture capital investments in a jump diffusion model

Math Meth Oper Res (2008) 67:21–42DOI 10.1007/s00186-007-0181-x

ORIGINAL ARTICLE

Optimizing venture capital investments in a jumpdiffusion model

Erhan Bayraktar · Masahiko Egami

Received: 1 June 2007 / Revised: 24 August 2007 / Published online: 25 September 2007© Springer-Verlag 2007

Abstract We study two practical optimization problems in relation to venturecapital investments and/or Research and Development (R&D) investments. In thefirst problem, given the amount of the initial investment and the cash flow structureat the initial public offering (IPO), the venture capitalist wants to maximize overalldiscounted cash flows after subtracting subsequent investments, which keep the in-vested company solvent. We describe this problem as a mixture of singular stochasticcontrol and optimal stopping problems. The second problem is concerned with optimaldividend policy. Rather than selling the company at an IPO, the investor may want toharvest technological achievements in the form of dividend when it is appropriate. Theoptimal control policy in this problem is a mixture of singular and impulse controls.

Keywords Venture capital investments · R&D · IPO · Stochastic control · Optimalstopping · Singular control · Impulse control · Jump diffusions

Mathematics Subject Classification (2000) Primary 49N25 · Secondary 60G40

1 Introduction

In accordance with the recent theoretical and practical development in the area ofreal options, modeling venture capital investment and R&D has become an important

E. Bayraktar was supported in part by the National Science Foundation, under grant DMS-0604491.

E. Bayraktar (B) · M. EgamiDepartment of Mathematics, University of Michigan, Ann Arbor, MI 48109-1043, USAe-mail: [email protected]

M. Egamie-mail: [email protected]

123

Page 2: Optimizing venture capital investments in a jump diffusion model

22 E. Bayraktar, M. Egami

topic, see Davis et al. (2004) for a review of this literature. One of the most importantissues is modeling the dynamics of the value process of start-up companies and/orR&D projects. Among many approaches, one approach is to use jump models withPoisson arrivals. For example, Willner (1995) uses a deterministic drift componentand stochastic jumps whose size follows a gamma distribution. A similar model ispresented by Pennings and Lint (1997), who also model with a deterministic driftand a jump part whose size follows a Weibull distribution with scale parameter two.In the spirit of these papers, we will model the value of the process with a jumpdiffusion.

It is customary to model the value of a company by an arithmetic Brownianmotion. See e.g., Shiu and Gerber (2004), Grandits et al. (2007) and Jeanblanc andShiryeav (1995). In our model, in addition to the arithmetic Brownian motion com-ponent, we will include a jump component into our model to take into account thetechnological breakthroughs or discovery of innovative methods and their effectson the value of the start-up company. Let {�,F , P} be a probability space hos-ting a Poisson random measure N (dt, dy) on [0,∞) × R and Brownian motionW = (Wt )t≥0, adapted to some filtration F = {Ft }t≥0 satisfying the usual condi-tions. The mean measure of N is ν(dt, dy) � λdt F(dy), where λ > 0 is constant,and F(dy) is the common distribution of the jump sizes, which we assume to bepositive. The (uncontrolled) value process X0 of the invested company is describedas follows:

d X0t = µ(X0

t )dt + σ(X0t )dWt +

∞∫

0

yN (dt, dy), t ≤ τ (0), in which

τ (0) � inf{t ≥ 0; X0t < 0}. (1.1)

We assume that µ and σ are Lipschitz continuous functions and that they satisfylinear growth conditions. These conditions guarantee that (1.1) has a unique strongsolution (see e.g., Pham 1998). In this set up the jumps of X0 come from a com-pound Poisson process whose jump size distribution is F . To obtain explicitresults we will take this distribution to be exponential. Let us mention someadvantages of using a jump diffusion model rather than a piecewise deterministicMarkov model as in other works cited above. At an early stage, the company’s growthmostly depends on the timing and magnitude of jump part in (1.1), since its growthrelies on technological breakthroughs. At a later stage it is often the case that theyhave generated some cash flows from their operation while jumps of great magni-tude are not necessarily expected. At this stage, the diffusion part of (1.1) is beco-ming increasingly influential. The diffusion model takes into account the uncertaintyin the cash-flow generation. Hence the jump diffusion model can represent start-up companies of various stages by appropriately modifying the parameters of themodel.

The final objective of these venture capital investments is, in many cases, to makethe company public through initial public offerings (IPO’s) or to sell to a third party ata premium. However, in due course, there are times when the start-up company faces

123

Page 3: Optimizing venture capital investments in a jump diffusion model

Optimizing venture capital investments in a jump diffusion model 23

the necessities to solicit new (additional) capital. In turn, the venture capitalist has tomake decisions on whether to make additional investments. We refer to this type ofproblem as the “IPO problem”. To address the issue of subsequent investments in theIPO problem, we first solve an optimal stopping problem of a reflected jump diffusion.In this problem, the venture capitalist does not allow the company’s value to go belowa fixed level, say a, with a minimal possible effort and attempts to find an optimaltime to IPO (Sect. 2.1). A similar optimal stopping problem for a reflected continuousdiffusion process was solved by Shreve et. al. (1984). Next, we solve the problemin which the venture capitalist chooses the level a optimally (Sect. 2.2) subject to abudget constraint. In the process of solving this problem we also solve the min-maxversion of it. In mathematical terms, this problem is a mixture of local-time control(plus an impulse applied at time 0 depending on whether the start-up company’s valueis initially below a) and optimal stopping. The local time control is how the venturecapitalist exercises controls or interventions in terms of additional capital infusions.The optimal stopping is, given a certain reward function at the IPO market, to find anoptimal timing of making the company public. In summary, while making decisionswith respect to additional investments, the venture capitalist seeks to find an optimalstopping rule in order to maximize her return, after subtracting the present value ofher intermediate investments or capital infusion.

Another problem of interest is the following: Rather than selling outright theinterest in the start-up company or R&D investments, the investor may want to extractvalues out of the company or project in the form of dividend until the time when thevalue becomes zero. This situation may be more suitable in considering R&D invest-ments because one wants to harvest technological achievements when appropriate,while one keeps the project running. We refer to this type of problem as the “har-vesting problem” (Sect. 3) or dividend payment problem. We prove the optimalityof a threshold policy. Optimal dividend problem for Lévy processes with negativejumps was analyzed by Avram et al. (2007). Here the Lévy process we consider haspositive jumps, due to this nature of the jumps one applies a mixture of impulse andsingular stochastic control: When the controlled process jumps over the optimal thre-shold, the controller applies impulse control, when the controlled process approachesthe threshold continuously, the controller reflects the controlled process, i.e., sheapplies singular control. Our model is for the value of the company is related to thedual model in risk theory. The problem of finding the optimal dividend barrier in thedual model without the Brownian component is dealt with in Avanzi et al. (2007).A general reference for solving optimal control problems for jump diffusions isØksendal and Sulem (2005). Another methodologically relevant work is by Buckleyand Korn (1998).

The rest of the paper is structured as follows: In Sect. 2, we solve the “IPO problem”,first by setting the lower threshold level a fixed and later by allowing this level to vary.In Sect. 3, we solve the “harvesting problem”. Next, we construct a candidate solutionand verify the optimality of this candidate by showing that the conditions prescribed inthe verification lemma are all satisfied. We also provide some static sensitivity analysisto the model parameters. In Sect. 4, we give our concluding remarks and compare thevalues of IPO and harvesting problems.

123

Page 4: Optimizing venture capital investments in a jump diffusion model

24 E. Bayraktar, M. Egami

2 The IPO problem

2.1 Optimal stopping of a reflected diffusion

The dynamics of the value of the start-up company is described as (1.1). After makingthe initial investment in the amount of x , the venture capitalist can make interventionsin the form of additional investments. Hence the controlled process X is written asfollows:

d Xt = µ(Xt )dt + σ(Xt )dWt +∞∫

0

yN (dt, dy) + d Zat , X0 = x, (2.1)

in which for a given a ≥ 0,

Zat = (a − x)1{x<a} + Lt , t ≥ 0 (2.2)

where Lt is the solution of

Lt =t∫

0

1{Xs=a}d Ls, t ≥ 0. (2.3)

Note that Za = (Zat )t≥0 is a continuous, non-decreasing (except at t = 0) Ft -adapted

process. In this set up, through cash infusion or additional investments, the venturecapitalist aims to keep the value of the start-up above a with a minimal possible effort.

The venture capitalist’s purpose is to find the best F-stopping time to make thecompany public through an IPO to maximize the present value of the discountedfuture cash-flow. We will denote the set of all F stopping times by S. The discountedfuture cash-flow of the venture capitalist if he applies the control Z , and makes aninitial public offering at time τ is

J τ,a(x) � Ex

⎡⎣e−ατ h(Xτ ) −

τ∫

0

e−αsd Zas

⎤⎦ , τ ∈ S. (2.4)

We use the following notation:

t∫

0

e−αt d Zat = Za

0 +∫

(0,t)

e−αt d Zat . (2.5)

We will assume that h : R+ → R+ is given by h(x) = r x , with r > 1. The reason fortaking r > 1 is justified by by the literature about initial stock returns on IPO markets.For example, Johnston and Madura (2002) examined the initial (i.e., first day trading)returns of IPOs (both Internet firms and non-Internet firms) during January 1, 1996 to

123

Page 5: Optimizing venture capital investments in a jump diffusion model

Optimizing venture capital investments in a jump diffusion model 25

December 31, 2000 and found that the average initial returns of Internet firms IPOswas 78.50%. The purpose of the venture capitalist is to determine τ ∗ ∈ S such that

V (x; a) � supτ∈S

J τ,a(x) = J τ∗,a(x), x ≥ 0. if such a τ ∗ exists. (2.6)

2.1.1 Verification Lemma

Lemma 2.1 If a non-negative function v ∈ C1(R+) is also twice continuously dif-ferentiable except at countably many points, and satisfies (i) (A − α)v(x) ≤ 0,x ∈ (a,∞), (ii) v(x) ≥ h(x), x ∈ (a,∞), (iii) v(x) = x − a + v(a), x ∈ [0, a], andv′(a+) = 1, in which the integro-differential operator A is defined by

A f (x) = µ(x) f ′(x) + 1

2σ 2(x) f ′′(x) + λ

∞∫

0

( f (x + y) − f (y))F(dy), (2.7)

thenv(x) ≥ J τ,Za

(x), τ ∈ S. (2.8)

Moreover, if there exists a point b(a) such that(iv) (A − α)v(x) = 0 and for all x ∈ [a, b(a)), v(x) > h(x) for all x ∈ (a, b(a)),(v) (A − α)v(x) < 0 for all x ∈ (b(a),∞), v(x) = h(x) for all x ∈ [b(a),∞),then v(x) = V (x; a), x ∈ R+, and τb(a) � inf{t ≥ 0; Xt ≥ b(a)} is optimal.

Proof Let us define τ(n) � inf{t ≥ 0; Xt ≥ n}. Let τ ∈ S. When we apply Itô’sformula to the semimartingale X (see e.g., Jacod and Shiryaev 1987), we obtain

e−α(τ∧τ(n)∧τ0)v(Xτ∧τ(n)∧τ0) = v(x)

+τ∧τ(n)∧τ0∫

0

(e−αs(A − α)v(Xs)ds + e−αsv′(Xs)d Ls

)

+ 1{x<a}(a − x) +τ∧τ(n)∧τ0∫

0

e−αsσ(Xs)v′(Xs)dWs

+τ∧τ(n)∧τ0∫

0

∞∫

0

(v(Xs− + y) − v(Xs−))

× (N (ds, dy) − ν(ds, dy)). (2.9)

123

Page 6: Optimizing venture capital investments in a jump diffusion model

26 E. Bayraktar, M. Egami

Rearranging this equation and after taking expectations we get

v(x) = (x − a)1{x<a} + Ex

⎡⎣e−α(τ∧τ(n)∧τ0)v(Xτ∧τ(n)∧τ0) −

τ∧τ(n)∧τ0∫

0

e−αsd Ls

⎤⎦

+Ex

⎡⎣

τ∧τ(n)∧τ0∫

0

e−αs(1 − v′(Xs))d Ls −τ∧τ(n)∧τ0∫

0

e−αs(A − α)v(Xs)ds

⎤⎦

−Ex

⎡⎣

τ0∧τ(n)∧τ0∫

0

e−αs(v(Xs− + y) − v(Xs−))(N (ds, dy) − ν(ds, dy))

−e−αsσ(Xs)v′(Xs)dWs

⎤⎦ . (2.10)

Since the functions σ(·), v(·) and v′(·) are bounded on the interval [0, n], the expectedvalue stochastic integral terms vanish (since the integral with respect to the Wienerprocess and compensated Poisson random measure are martingales), and since v′(a) =1 the expected value of the integral with respect to L also vanishes. On the other hand,the expected value of the integral with respect to the Lebesgue measure is greater thanzero by Assumption (i). Therefore,

v(x) ≥ (x − a)1{x<a} + Ex

⎡⎣e−α(τ∧τ(n)∧τ0)v(Xτ∧τ(n)∧τ0) −

τ∧τ(n)∧τ0∫

0

e−αsd Ls

⎤⎦ .

Equation (2.8) follows from Fatou’s lemma and the bounded convergence theoremand assumption (ii). On the other hand, if we substitute τ and τ(n) with τb(a) in theabove equations and use assumptions (iv) and (v) we get that v(·) = J τb(a),a(·), whichproves that v(·) = V (·) and that τb(a) is optimal, i.e., J τb(a),a(·) ≥ J τ,a(·) for anyτ ∈ S.

2.1.2 Construction of a candidate solution

We will assume that the mean measure of the Poisson random measure N is given byν(dt, dy) = λdtηe−ηydy. In other words, we consider the case in which the jumpscome from a compound Poisson process with exponentially distributes jump sizes.We also assume that µ(x) = µ where µ ∈ R and σ(x) = σ > 0. We will also assumethat µ + λ/η > 0. This assumption simply says that the overall trend of the companyis positive which motivates the venture capitalist to keep the start-up alive.

123

Page 7: Optimizing venture capital investments in a jump diffusion model

Optimizing venture capital investments in a jump diffusion model 27

The action of the infinitesimal generator of X0 on a test function f is given by

A f (x) = µ f ′(x) + 1

2σ 2 f ′′(x) + λ

∞∫

0

( f (x + y) − f (x))ηe−ηydy. (2.11)

Let us define

G(γ ) � 1

2σ 2γ 2 + µγ + λη

η − γ− λ. (2.12)

Note that Ex[eγ X0

t

]= exp (G(γ )t).

Lemma 2.2 The equation G(γ ) = α has two positive roots γ1, γ2 and one negativeroot −γ3 satisfying

0 < γ1 < η < γ2, and γ3 > 0. (2.13)

Proof Let us denote

A(γ ) � 1

2σ 2γ 2 + µγ − (λ + α), B(γ ) � λη

γ − η. (2.14)

It follows that

limγ↓η

B(γ ) = ∞, limγ↑η

B(γ ) = −∞, limγ→−∞ B(γ ) = 0, (2.15)

limγ→−∞ A(γ ) = lim

γ→∞ A(γ ) = ∞, (2.16)

and thatA(0) = −(λ + α) < B(0) = −λ. (2.17)

Moreover, A(·) is strictly decreasing on (−∞,−µ/σ 2) and strictly increasing on(−µ/σ 2,∞); B(·) is strictly decreasing both on (−∞, η) and on (η,∞) with differentasymptotic behavior on different sides of γ = η. The claim is a direct consequence ofthese observations.

Let us definev0(x; a) � A1eγ1x + A2eγ2x + A3e−γ3x , (2.18)

for some A1, A2, A3 ∈ R and b > a, which are to be determined. We set the candidatevalue function as

v(x; a) �

⎧⎪⎨⎪⎩

x − a + v0(a; a), x ∈ [0, a],v0(x; a), x ∈ [a, b],r x, x ∈ [b,∞),

(2.19)

123

Page 8: Optimizing venture capital investments in a jump diffusion model

28 E. Bayraktar, M. Egami

Our aim is to determine these constants so that v(·; a) satisfies the conditions of theverification lemma. We will choose A1, A2, A3 ∈ R and b > a to satisfy

A1eγ1b + A2eγ2b + A3e−γ3b = rb, (2.20a)

A1η

γ1 − ηeγ1b + A2η

γ2 − ηeγ2b + A3η

−γ3 − ηe−γ3b + r

(b + 1

η

)= 0, (2.20b)

γ1 A1eγ1a + γ2 A2eγ2a − γ3 A3e−γ3a = 1, (2.20c)

γ1 A1eγ1b + γ2 A2eγ2b − γ3 A3e−γ3b = r . (2.20d)

For the function v in (2.19) to be well-defined, we need to verify that this set ofequations has a unique solution. But before let us point out how we came up withthese equations. The expressions (2.20a), (2.20c) and (2.20d) come from continuouspasting at b, first-order smooth pasting at a and first order smooth pasting at b,respectively. Equation (2.20b) on the other hand comes from evaluating

(A − α)v(x; a) = µv′0(x) + 1

2σ 2v′′

0 (x)

⎛⎝

b−x∫

0

v0(x + y)ηe−ηydy +∞∫

b−x

r(x + y)ηe−ηydy

⎞⎠

−(λ + α)v0(x) = 0. (2.21)

Lemma 2.3 For any given a, there is a unique (A1, A2, A3, b) ∈ R3 × (a,∞) that

solves the system of Eqs. (2.20a)–(2.20d). Moreover, b > max{a, b∗}, in which

b∗ � 1

α

(µ + λ

η

)(2.22)

and A1 > 0, A2 > 0.

Proof Using (2.20a), (2.20b) and (2.20d) we can determine A1, A2 and A3 as functionsof b:

A1(b) = r

η2

(η − γ1)[γ2γ3(ηb + 1) + η(γ2 − γ3)](γ3 + γ1)(γ2 − γ1)

e−γ1b =: D1(b)e−γ1b,

A2(b) = r

η2

(γ2 − η)[γ1γ3(ηb + 1) + η(γ1 − γ3)](γ3 + γ2)(γ2 − γ1)

e−γ2b =: D2(b)e−γ2b,

A3(b) = r

η2

(η + γ3)[γ2γ1(ηb + 1) − η(γ2 + γ1)](γ3 + γ1)(γ2 + γ3)

eγ3b =: D3(b)eγ3b.

(2.23)

Let us define

R(b) � γ1 A1(b)eγ1a + γ2 A2(b)eγ2a − γ3 A3(b)e−γ3a . (2.24)

123

Page 9: Optimizing venture capital investments in a jump diffusion model

Optimizing venture capital investments in a jump diffusion model 29

To verify our claim we only need to show that there is one and only one root of theequation R(b) = 1. Observe that

R(a) = γ1 A1(a)eγ1a + γ2 A2(a)eγ2a − γ3 A3(a)e−γ3a

= γ1 D1(a) + γ2 D2(a) − γ3 D3(a)

= r > 1, (2.25)

and that limb→∞ R(b) = −∞. The derivative of b → R(b) is

R′(b) = γ1 A′1(b)eγ1a + γ2 A′

2(b)eγ2a − γ3 A′3(b)e−γ3a

=[γ1C1e−γ1(b−a) + γ2C2e−γ2(b−a) + γ3C3eγ3(b−a)

](−ηγ1γ2γ3b + Y ),

(2.26)

in which

C1 � r

η2

η − γ1

(γ3 + γ1)(γ2 − γ1)> 0, C2 � r

η2

γ2 − η

(γ3 + γ2)(γ2 − γ1)> 0, and

C3 � r

η2

η + γ3

(γ3 + γ1)(γ3 + γ2)> 0, (2.27)

andY � −γ1γ2γ3 + η(−γ1γ2 + γ2γ3 + γ1γ3). (2.28)

Observe that Yηγ1γ2γ3

= b∗. From (2.26) it follows that on (−∞, b∗] the functionb → R(b) is increasing, and on [b∗,∞) it is decreasing. If b∗ ≤ a, then it followsdirectly from R(a) = r > 1 and limb→∞ R(b) = −∞ that there exists a unique b > asuch that R(b) = 1. On the other hand, if b∗ > a, then R(x) > 1 on x ∈ [a, b∗].Again, since limb→∞ R(b) = −∞, there exists a unique b > b∗ such that R(b) = 1.

Let us show that A1(b) > 0 for the unique root of R(b) = 1. Observe that A′1(b

∗) =0 and A1(b∗) > 0. Moreover, b∗ is the only local extremum of the function b → A1(b),and limb→∞ A1(b) = 0. Since this function is decreasing on [b∗,∞), A1(b) > 0.Similarly, A2(b) > 0. Remark 2.1 It follows from (2.20a), (2.20c) and (2.20d) that

v(b; a) = rb, v′(a; a) = 1 < v′(b(a); a) = r. (2.29)

Lemma 2.4 Let A1, A2, A3, and b be as in Lemma 2.3 and v0(·; a) be as in (2.18).Then if A3 ≥ 0, then v0(·; a) is convex for all a ≥ 0. Otherwise, there exists a uniquepoint x < b such that, v0(·; a) is concave on [0, x) and convex on (x,∞).

Proof The first and the second derivative of v0(·; a) [defined in (2.19)] are

v′0(x; a) = A1γ1eγ1x + A2γ2eγ2x − γ3 A3e−γ3x ,

v′′0 (x; a) = A1γ

21 eγ1x + A2γ

22 eγ2x + γ 2

3 A3e−γ3x . (2.30)

123

Page 10: Optimizing venture capital investments in a jump diffusion model

30 E. Bayraktar, M. Egami

From Lemma 2.3 we have that A1 > 0 and A2 > 0. If A3 ≥ 0, then (2.30) and(2.29) imply that v′′(x; a) > 0, x ∈ [a, b(a)], i.e., v(·; a) is convex on [a, b(a)].

Let us analyze the case when A3 < 0. In this case the functions x → A1γ21 eγ1x +

A2γ22 eγ2x and x → −γ 2

3 A3e−γ3x intersect at a unique point x > 0. The functionv′

0(·; a) [defined in (2.19)] decreases on [0, x) and increases on [x,∞). Now from(2.29) it follows that x < b(a).

2.1.3 Verification of optimality

Proposition 2.1 Let us denote the unique b in Lemma 2.3 by b(a) to emphasize itsdependence on a. Then v(·; a) defined in (2.19) is equal to V (·; a) of (2.6).

Proof The function v in (2.19) already satisfies

(A−α)v(x; a)=0, x ∈ (a, b(a)), v(x; a) = r x, x ∈ [b(a),∞), v′(a; a)=1.

(2.31)Therefore, we only need to show that

(A − α)v(x; a) < 0, x ∈ (b(a),∞), and that v(x; a) > r x, x ∈ (a, b(a)),

(2.32)Let us prove the first inequality.

(A − α)v(x; a) = µr + λr

η− αr x, x > b(a). (2.33)

So, (A − α)v(x; a) < 0, for x > b(a) if and only if

b(a) >1

α

(µ + λ

η

)= b∗. (2.34)

However, we already know from Lemma 2.3 that (2.34) holds.Let us prove the second inequality in (2.32). If A3 ≥ 0, then Lemma 2.4 imply

that v′′(x; a) > 0, x ∈ [a, b(a)], i.e., v(·; a) is convex on [a, b(a)]. Therefore v′(·; a)

is increasing on [a, b(a)] and v′(x; a) ∈ [1, r) on [a, b(a)). Since x → v(x; a)

intersects the function x → r x at b(a), v(x; a) > r x , x ∈ [a, b(a)). Otherwise therewould exist a point x∗ ∈ [a, b(a)) such that v′(x∗; a) > r .

If A3 < 0, then the function v′0(·; a) [defined in (2.19)] decreases on [0, x) and

increases on [x,∞), in which x < b(a), by Lemma 2.4. If x ≥ a, then v′(x; a) < rfor x ∈ [a, b(a)) since v′(a; a) = 1, v′(x; a) < 1 for x ∈ (a, x] and v′(x; a) < r forx ∈ (x, b(a)). On the other hand if x < a, then v′(x; a) ∈ [1, r) for x ∈ [a, b(a)) sincev′(·; a) is increasing on this interval and v′(b(a); a) = r . So in any case v′(x; a) < ron [a, b(a)). Since v(b(a); a) = rb(a), then v(x) > r x , x ∈ [a, b(a)). Otherwisethere would exist a point x∗ ∈ [a, b(a)) such that v′(x∗; a) > r .

Figure 1 shows the value function and its derivatives. As expected the value functionv(·; 1) is concave at first and becomes convex before it coincides with the line h(·). Itcan be seen that v(·; a) satisfies the conditions of the verification lemma.

123

Page 11: Optimizing venture capital investments in a jump diffusion model

Optimizing venture capital investments in a jump diffusion model 31

1 2 3 4 5 6x

3

4

5

6

7

v x

1 2 3 4 5 6x

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1

1.2

v’ x

(a) (b)

Fig. 1 The IPO problem with parameters (µ, λ, η, σ, α, r) = (−0.05, 0.75, 1.5, 0.25, 0.1, 1.25) anda = 1: a The value function v(x) with b(a) = 4.7641. b v′(x) is also continuous in x ∈ R+

2.2 Maximizing over the cash-infusion level a

In this section, the goal of the venture capitalist is to find an a∗ ∈ [0, B] and τ ∗ ∈ Ssuch that

U (x) � supa∈[0,B]

supτ∈S

J τ,a(x) = supa∈[0,B]

V (x; a) = J τ∗,a∗(x), x ≥ 0, (2.35)

if (a∗, τ ∗) ∈ [0, B] × S exists. In this optimization problem, the constraint a ≤ B,reflects the fact that the venture capitalist has a finite initial budget to pump-up thevalue of the start-up company: the first term in (2.2) can not be greater than B. Themain result of this section is Proposition 2.2. We will show that V (x; a), for all x ≥ 0,is maximized at either a = 0 or a = B. In the mean time we will also find a solutionto the min-max problem

U (x) � infa∈[0,B] sup

τ∈SJ τ,a(x). (2.36)

We will start with analyzing the local extremums of the function a → v0(x; a),x ≥ 0. We will derive the second order smooth fit condition at a, from a first orderderivative condition.

Lemma 2.5 Recall the definition of the function v0(·; a) from (2.19). If a ≥ 0 is alocal extremum of the function a → v0(x; a), for any x ≥ 0, then v′′

0 (a; a) = 0.

Proof Let us denote

A1(a) � A1(b(a)), A2(a) � A2(b(a)), and A3(a) � A3(b(a)), (2.37)

in which the functions A1(·), A2(·) and A3(·) are given by (2.23). The derivative

dv0

da(x; a) = A′

1(a)eγ1x + A′2(a)eγ2x + A′

3(a)e−γ3x = 0 (2.38)

for all x ≥ 0 if and only if

A′1(a) = A′

2(a) = A′3(a) = 0, (2.39)

123

Page 12: Optimizing venture capital investments in a jump diffusion model

32 E. Bayraktar, M. Egami

since the functions x → eγ1x , x → eγ2x and x → e−γ2x , x ≥ 0, are linearlyindependent.

It follows from (2.20c) that for any a ≥ 0

γ1 A1(a)eγ1a + γ2 A2(a)eγ2a − γ3 A3(a)e−γ3a = 1. (2.40)

Taking the derivative with respect to a we get

(γ 21 A1(a) + γ1 A′

1(a))eγ1a + (γ 22 A2(a)+ A′

2(a))eγ2a +(γ 23 A3(a)−γ3 A′

3(a))e−γ3a = 0.

(2.41)

Evaluating this last expression at a = a we obtain

γ 21 A1(a)eγ1a + γ 2

2 A2(a)eγ2a + γ 23 A3(a)e−γ3a = v′′

0 (a; a) = 0, (2.42)

where we used (2.39). Lemma 2.6 Let a be as in Lemma 2.5 and a → b(a), a ≥ 0, be as in Proposition 2.1.Then b′(a) = 0. The point a is a unique local extremum of a → v0(x; a), for allx ≥ 0, if and only if a is the unique local extremum of a → b(a). If a is the uniquelocal extremum of b(·), then b′′(a) > 0. Moreover, a = argmina≥0(b(a)).

Proof Let A1(·) be as in (2.37). Since

A′1(a) = d

dbA1(b(a))b′(a) = 0, (2.43)

and for any a, b(a) > b∗, in which b∗ is the unique local extremum of the functionb → A1(b), it follows that b′(a) = 0.

Assume that a is the unique local extremum of b(·). Then

A′1(a) = A′

2(a) = A′3(a) = 0, (2.44)

if and only if a = a. Using (2.38), it is readily seen that a → v0(x; a) has a uniquelocal extremum and that this local extremum is equal to a.

On the other hand we know from Lemma 2.3 that b(a) > a for all a. Therefore, ifb(·) has a unique local extremum at a, it can not be a local maximum. On the otherhand, if there were an a = a such that b(a) ≤ b(a), then there would be a localmaximum in (min{a, a}, max{a, a}), which yields a contradiction. Lemma 2.7 Recall the definition of v(·; a), a ≥ 0, from (2.19). For any a1, a2 ≥ 0,if b(a1) > b(a2), then v(x; a1) > v(x; a2), x ≥ 0.

Proof We will first show that

v0(x; a1) = A1(a1)eγ1x + A2(a1)e

γ2x + A3(a1)e−γ3x ≥ v0(x; a2)

= A1(a2)eγ1x + A2(a2)e

γ2x + A3(a2)e−γ3x , (2.45)

123

Page 13: Optimizing venture capital investments in a jump diffusion model

Optimizing venture capital investments in a jump diffusion model 33

for x ∈ [0, b(a2)], in which A1, A2, A3 are defined in (2.37). Since b(a2) ≤ b(a1),

A1(b(a1)) < A1(b(a2)), A2(b(a1)) < A2(b(a2)), A3(b(a1)) > A3(b(a2)).

(2.46)

This follows from the fact that the functions A1(·), A2(·) are increasing and A3(·) isdecreasing on [b∗,∞) and that b(a) > b∗, for any a ≥ 0. See (2.23) and Lemma 2.3.

Let us defineW (x) � v0(x; a1) − v0(x; a2), x ∈ R. (2.47)

The derivativeW ′(x) < 0, x ∈ R, (2.48)

andlim

x→−∞ W (x) = ∞, limx→∞ W (x) = −∞. (2.49)

Therefore, W (·) has a unique root. We will show that this root, which we will denoteby k, satisfies b(a2) < k < b(a1).

It follows from Lemma 2.4 that v0(·; a) is convex on [b(a),∞), for any a. Moreover,for any a ≥ 0,v0(·; a) smoothly touches the function h(·) [see (2.20a) and (2.20d)], andstays above h(·) since v0(·; a) is convex. Now, since b(a2) < b(a1), for the functionW (·) to have a unique root, that unique root has to satisfy b(a2) < k < b(a1). Thisproves (2.45).

From (2.45) it follows that v(x; a1) ≥ v(x; a2), for any x ∈ [min{a1, a2}, b(a2)].But v(x; a2) = r x for x ≥ b(a2) and v(x; a) = v0(x; a1) > r x , x ∈ [b(a2), b(a1)]and v(x; a) = r x , x ≥ b(a1). Therefore, we have

v(x; a1) ≥ v(x; a2), x ≥ min{a1, a2}. (2.50)

In what follows we will show that the inequality in (2.50) also holds on x ≤min{a1, a2}.

Let us assume that a1 < a2. It follows from (2.48) and v′0(a2; a2) = 1 [see (2.20c)]

thatv′

0(a2; a1) < 1. (2.51)

Therefore, v0(·; a1) does not intersect x → x−a2+v0(a2, a2) x ∈ [a1, a2]. Otherwise,at the point of intersection, say x , v′

0(x, a1) > 1, which together with (2.51) contradictsLemma 2.4. This implies that v(x; a1) > v(x; a2), x ∈ [a1, a2].

Let us assume that a1 > a2 and that b(a2) ≥ a1. Then, v0(x; a2) < x − a1 +v0(a1; a1). Otherwise, v0(·; a2) intersects x → x − a1 + v0(a1; a1) at x0 ∈ (a2, a1).Then v′

0(x0; a2) > 1. Since v′0(a; a) = 1 for any a ≥ 0, using Lemma 2.4, it follows

that v0(a1; a2) > v0(a1; a1). This yields a contradiction since v0(·; a2) and v0(·; a1) donot intersect for any x < k, in which k > b(a2) ≥ a1. Therefore, v(x; a1) > v(x; a2),x ≥ [a2, a1].

Finally, let us assume that a1 > a2 and that b(a2) < a1. Since v(x; a2) = r x andv0(x; a1) > r x for x ≥ [b(a2), a1] it follows that v(x; a1) > v(x; a2), x ≥ [a2, a1].Now, the proof is complete.

123

Page 14: Optimizing venture capital investments in a jump diffusion model

34 E. Bayraktar, M. Egami

Corollary 2.1 Recall the definition of v(·; a) from (2.19). Let a be the unique localextremum of a → b(a), a ≥ 0. Then v(x; a) ≤ v(x; a), x ≥ 0, for all a ≥ 0.

Proof The proof follows from Lemmas 2.6 and 2.7. Corollary 2.2 Let a be the unique local extremum of a → b(a), a ≥ 0. Then functionv(·; a) is convex. Moreover, v′(x; a) > 1, x > a.

Proof Let A3(a) be as in (2.37). If A3(a) ≥ 0 then v0(·; a) is convex by Lemma 2.4.If A3(a) < 0, then the function

v′′′0 (x; a) = A1(a)γ 3

1 eγ1x + A2(a)γ 32 eγ2x − γ 3

3 A3(a)e−γ3x > 0. (2.52)

Since v′′0 (a, a) = 0, then (2.52) implies that v′′

0 (x; a) > 0 for x > a. The convexity ofv(·; a) follows, since it is equal to v0(·; a) on [a, b(a)] and is linear everywhere else.

Since v′(a; a) = 1 (see Remark 2.1), it follows from the convexity of v(·; a) thatv′(x; a) > 1 for x > a.

Note that the second order smooth fit condition v′′(a; a) = 0 yields a solution thatminimizes V (x; a), x ≥ 0, a ≥ 0, as a result of Corollary 2.1. In the next propositionwe find the maximizer.

Proposition 2.2 Assume that a → b(a), a ≥ 0 has a unique local extremum at a.Then

U (x) = maxa∈{0,B} v(x; a), and U (x) = v(x; a), (2.53)

in which U and U are given by (2.35) and (2.36), respectively.

Proof It follows from Lemma 2.6 that a → b(a), has a unique local extremum, and infact this local extremum is a minimum. Therefore, a → b(a), a ∈ [0, B] is maximizedat either of the boundaries. The result follows from Lemma 2.7.

Using the same parameters as in Fig. 1, we solve (2.20a)–(2.20d) and

v′′0 (a; a) = γ 2

1 A1(a)eγ1a + γ 22 A2(a)eγ2a + γ 2

3 A3(a)e−γ3a = 0. (2.54)

numerically and find a and confirm its uniqueness. We observe in Fig. 2 that (a) a isthe minimizer of b(a), and (b) v(x; 0) ≥ v(x; a) for x ∈ R+.

Before ending this section, we provide a sensitivity analysis of the optimal stoppingbarrier to the parameters of the problem. We use the parameter sets (µ, λ, η, σ, α) =(−0.05, 0.75, 1.5, 0.25, 0.1) with r = 1.25 and a = 0 and vary one parameter with theothers fixed at the base case. Figure 3 shows the results. In fact, all the graphs showmonotone relationship between b(a) and the parameters, which is intuitive. Largerη (that means smaller 1/η) leads to a smaller threshold value since the mean jumpsize is small (Graph a). Similarly, larger λ leads to a larger threshold value since thefrequency of jumps is greater and the investor can expects higher revenue (Graph b).

123

Page 15: Optimizing venture capital investments in a jump diffusion model

Optimizing venture capital investments in a jump diffusion model 35

2 4 6 8a

3.5

4.5

5

5.5

6

6.5

7b a

1 2 3 4 5 6x

2

4

6

8

v x;a

1 2 3 4x

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1

v x;0 v x;a tilde

(a) (b) (c)

Fig. 2 Using the parameters (µ, λ, η, σ, α) = (−0.05, 0.75, 1.5, 0.25, 0.1): a a = 3.884 minimizes thefunction b(a) with b(a) = 4.741. b The corresponding value function v(x; a) (solid line) is below v(x; 0)

(dashed line). c v(x; 0) − v(x; a)

0.5 1 1.5 2 2.5

2.5

5

7.5

10

12.5

15

17.5

b

0.5 1 1.5 2

2

4

6

8

10

12

b

-0.6 -0.5 -0.4 -0.3 -0.2 -0.1

1

2

3

4

5

b

0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1

4.6

4.8

5.2

5.4

5.6

b

η λ

σ

µ

(a) (b)

(c) (d)

Fig. 3 Sensitivity of the optimal stopping barrier to the parameters. The basis parameters are (µ, λ,

η, σ, α) = (−0.05, 0.75, 1.5, 0.25, 0.1): a jump size parameter η, b arrival rate λ, c drift µ(x) = −µ,d volatility σ

In the same token, if the absolute value of µ is greater (when the drift is negative), theprocess inclines to return to zero more frequently. Hence the investor cannot expecthigh revenue due to the time value of money (Graph c). A larger volatility expandsthe continuation region since the process X has a greater probability to reach furtherout within a fixed amount of time. Hence the investor can expect the process to reacha higher return level (Graph d).

123

Page 16: Optimizing venture capital investments in a jump diffusion model

36 E. Bayraktar, M. Egami

3 The harvesting problem

3.1 Problem description

In this section, the investor wants to extract the value out of the company intermittently(i.e., receives dividends from the company) when there are opportunities to do so. Thisproblem might fit better the case of R&D investments rather than the venture capitalinvestments. Namely, the company or R&D project has a large technology platform,based on which applications are made and products are materialized from time totime. Each time it occurs, the investor tries to sell these products or applications andin turn receives dividends. There are many papers about dividend payout problemsthat consider continuous diffusion processes. See, for example, Bayraktar and Egami(2006) and the references therein. The first systematic treatment of the optimal dividendproblem for a compound Poisson model can be found in Gerber (1968), see alsoSchmidli (2007) for a systematic overview of the field. When the value of a companyis modeled as a piece-wise deterministic Lévy process (Avram et al. 2007; Dassios andEmbrechts 1989) solve the dividend payment problem when there are only downwardjumps, whereas Gerber (2007) solve the problem for upward jumps. In what follows,the dividend payments are triggered by sporadic upward jumps of the process as wellas the diffusion part. Whenever the value of the company exceed a certain value, whichmay occur continuously or via jumps, dividends are paid out. So the investor appliesa mixture of singular and impulse controls.

In this section our model for the value of the company is given by (2.1) afterreplacing d Za

t by d Zt , in which Z = (Zt )t≥0 is a continuous non-decreasing (expectat t = 0) F-adapted process, i.e., Z ∈ V , is the dividend payment policy. The investorwants to maximize the discounted expected value of the payments she receives, whichis given by

J Z (x) � Ex

⎡⎣

τ0∫

0

e−αt d Zt

⎤⎦ (3.1)

in which τ0 � inf{t ≥ 0; Xt = 0}. The investor wants to determine the optimaldividend policy Z∗ that satisfies

V (x) � supZ∈V

J Z (x) = J Z∗(x), if such a Z∗ ∈ V exists. (3.2)

3.2 A mixed singular and impulse control problem

3.2.1 Verification Lemma

Lemma 3.1 If a non-negative function v ∈ C1(R+) is also twice continuously diffe-

rentiable except at countably many points and satisfies (i) (A − α)v(x) ≤ 0, x ≥ 0,(ii) v′(x) ≥ 1, x ≥ 0, (iii) v′′(x) ≤ 0 (i.e., v is concave), then v(x) ≥ V (x), x ≥ 0.

Moreover, if there exists point b ∈ R+ such that v ∈ C1(R+)∩C2(R+\{b}) and if valso satisfies (iv) (A−α)v(x) = 0 , v′(x) > 1, for all x ∈ [0, b), (v) (A−α)v(x) < 0,

123

Page 17: Optimizing venture capital investments in a jump diffusion model

Optimizing venture capital investments in a jump diffusion model 37

v(x) = x − b + v(b), x > b, in which the integro-differential operator A is definedby (2.7), then v(x) = V (x), x ∈ R+, and the constant barrier strategy

Zt = (Xt − b)1{Xt >b} + Lbt , t ≥ 0, in which

Lt =t∫

0

1{Xs=b}d Lbs , t ≥ 0, is optimal. (3.3)

Proof Let τ(n) be as in the proof of Lemma 2.1. Using Itô’s formula for semimartin-gales (see e.g., Jacod and Shiryaev 1987)

e−α(τ(n)∧τ0)v(Xτ(n)∧τ0) = v(x) +τ(n)∧τ0∫

0

e−αs(A − α)v(Xs)ds −τ(n)∧τ0∫

0

e−αsd Zs

+τ(n)∧τ0∫

0

e−αs(1 − v′(Xs))d Zs +τ(n)∧τ0∫

0

∞∫

0

e−αs(v(Xs− + y)

− v(Xs−))(N (ds, dy) − ν(ds, dy))

+∑

0≤θk≤τ(n)∧τ0

e−αθk(v(Xθk ) − v(Xθk−)

+(Xθk − Xθk−)v′(Xθk−)) +

τ(n)∧τ0∫

0

e−αsσ(Xs)dWs

+τ(n)∧τ0∫

0

∞∫

0

e−αs (v(Xs)−v(Xs− + y)

+ (Xs −Xs− − y)v′(Xs− + y))

N (ds, dy) (3.4)

in which {θk}k∈N is an increasing sequence of F stopping times that are the times theprocess X jump due to jumps in Z that do not occur at the time of Poisson arrivals.The controller is allowed to choose the jump times of Z to coincide with the jumptimes of N . This is taken into account in the last expression of (3.4) (the integral withrespect to the Poisson random measure). Observe that this expression is zero if thejump times of Z never coincide with those of the Poisson random measure.

After taking expectations stochastic integral terms, with respect to Wiener measureand the compensated Poisson random measure, vanish. Also, the concavity of v impliesthat

v(x) − v(y) + v′(y)(x − y) ≤ 0, for any y ≥ x . (3.5)

The rest of the proof is similar to that of Lemma 2.1.

123

Page 18: Optimizing venture capital investments in a jump diffusion model

38 E. Bayraktar, M. Egami

3.2.2 Construction of a candidate solution

As in Sect. 2.1.2 we will assume that the mean measure of the Poisson random measureN is given by ν(dt, dy) = λdtηe−ηydy, µ(x) = µ where µ > 0 and σ(x) = σ . Letus define

v0(x) � B1eγ1x + B2eγ2x + B3e−γ3x , x ≥ 0, (3.6)

for B1, B2, B3 ∈ R that are to be determined. We set our candidate function to be

v(x) �{

v0(x) x ∈ [0, b),

x − b + v0(b), x ∈ [b,∞).(3.7)

We will choose B1, B2, B3 and b to satisfy

B1η

γ1 − ηeγ1b+ B2η

γ2 − ηe−γ2b− B3η

γ3+ηe−γ3b+B1eγ1b + B2e−γ2b + B3e−γ3b+ 1

η= 0,

(3.8)

γ1 B1eγ1b+γ2 B2eγ2b−γ3 B3e−γ3b = 1, γ 21 B1eγ1b+γ 2

2 B2eγ2b+γ 23 B3e−γ3b = 0,

(3.9)

B1+B2+B3 = 0. (3.10)

Equation (3.8) is obtained by explicitly evaluating

(A − α)v(x) = µv′(x) + 1

2σ 2v′′(x)

⎛⎝

b−x∫

0

v(x + y)F(dy) +∞∫

b−x

(v(b) + (x + y − b))F(y)dy

⎞⎠

−(λ + α)v(x)

and setting it to zero. Equations in (3.9) are there to enforce first and second ordersmooth fit at point b. The last equation imposes the function v to be equal to zeroat point zero. The vale function V satisfies this condition since whenever the valueprocess X hits level zero bankruptcy is declared.

Lemma 3.2 There exists a unique solution B1, B2, B3 and b to the system ofEqs. (3.8)–(3.10) if and only if the quantity µ + λ/η > 0. Moreover, B1 > 0, B2 > 0and B3 < 0.

123

Page 19: Optimizing venture capital investments in a jump diffusion model

Optimizing venture capital investments in a jump diffusion model 39

Proof Using (3.8) and (3.9), we can express B1, B2 and B3 as functions of b: For allb > 0, we have

B1(b)= e−γ1b

η

γ2γ3(η − γ1)

γ1(γ2 − γ1)(γ1 + γ3)>0, B2(b)= e−γ2b

η

γ3γ1(γ2 − η)

γ2(γ2 + γ3)(γ2 − γ1)>0,

B3(b)=−eγ3b

η

γ1γ2(η + γ3)

γ3(γ1 + γ3)(γ2 + γ3)<0. (3.11)

Let us define Q(b) � B1(b) + B2(b) + B3(b), b ≥ 0. Our claim follows once weshow that the function b → Q(b), b ≥ 0 has a unique root. The derivative of Q(·)satisfies Q′(b) = B ′

1(b)+ B ′2(b)+ B ′

3(b) < 0, therefore Q(·) is decreasing. Explicitlycomputing Q(0) in (3.11), we obtain

Q(0) > 0 if and only if1

ηγ1γ2γ3

(− γ1γ2γ3 + η(−γ1γ2 + γ2γ3 + γ3γ1)

)

= µ + λ/η

α> 0.

Since limb→∞ Q(b) = −∞ the claim follows.

3.2.3 Verification of optimality

Lemma 3.3 Let B1, B2, B3 and b be as in Lemma 3.2. Then v defined in (3.7) satisfies(i) (A − α)v(x) < 0 for x ∈ (b,∞), (ii) v′(x) > 1 on x ∈ [0, b), (iii) v′′(x) < 0

on x ∈ [0, b).

Proof (i): On x ∈ (b,∞), v(x) = (x − b) + v0(b), we compute

(A − α)v(x) = µ + λ/η − α(x − b) − αv0(b∗) < µ + λ/η − αv0(b)

= limx↓b

(A − α)v(x) = limx↑b

(A − α)v(x) = 0.

Here we used the continuity of v(x), v′(x) and v′′(x) at x = b.(ii) and (iii): Since B1, B2 > 0 and B3 < 0,

v′′′0 (x) = B1γ

31 eγ1x + B2γ

32 eγ2x − B3γ

33 e−γ3x > 0, (3.12)

i.e., v′′0 (·) is monotonically increasing in x . It follows from (3.9) that v′′

0 (b) = 0,therefore v′′

0 (x) < 0 on x ∈ [0, b). This proves (iii).Since v′′

0 (x) < 0, x ∈ R+, v′0(·) is decreasing on R+. It follows from (3.9) that

v′0(b) = 1. Therefore, v′

0(x) > 1 on x ∈ [0, b). This proves (ii).

Proposition 3.1 Suppose that µ + λη

> 0. Let B1, B2, B3 and b be as in Lemma 3.2.

123

Page 20: Optimizing venture capital investments in a jump diffusion model

40 E. Bayraktar, M. Egami

0.5 1 1.5 2 2.5 3x

123456

v x

0.5 1 1.5 2 2.5 3x

2468101214v’ x

0.5 1 1.5 2 2.5 3x

-50

-40

-30

-20

-10

v’’x

(a) (b) (c)

Fig. 4 The harvesting (dividend payout) problem with parameters (µ, λ, η, σ, α) = (−0.05, 0.75,

1.5, 0.25, 0.1): a The value function v(x) with b = 1.276. b v′(x) and v′′(x) to show that the optima-lity conditions are satisfied

Then the function v(·) defined in (3.7) satisfies

v(x) = V (x) = supZ∈V

J Z (x). (3.13)

and Z defined in (3.3) is optimal.

Proof Note that (A − α)v(x) = 0, x ∈ [0, b) as a result of (3.8). The function v(·)is linear on [b,∞). It follows from Lemma 3.3 that the function v(·) satisfies all theconditions in the verification lemma.

Figure 4 shows the value function and its derivatives. As expected the value functionis concave and is twice continuously differentiable. Finally, we perform some sensi-tivity analysis of the optimal barrier b with respect to the parameters of the problem,see Fig. 5. Graph a: The first graph shows that as the expected value of jump size1/η decreases, so does the threshold level b, as expected. Graph b: It is interesting toobserve that b increases first and starts decreasing as λ reaches a certain level, say λmax.A possible interpretation is as follows: in the range of (0, λmax), i.e., for small λ, onewants to extract a large amount of cash whenever jumps occur since the opportunitiesare limited. As λ gets larger, one starts to be willing to let the process live longer byextracting smaller amounts each time. On the other hand, for λ ≥ λmax, one becomescomfortable with receiving more dividends, causing the declining trend of b. Graphc: The smaller |µ| is the more X takes to hit zero. Accordingly, it is safe to extracta large amount of dividend when |µ| is small. However, when µ decreases up to acertain level, say µ∗, it becomes risky to extract and hence b increases. It is observedthat when µ is smaller than µ∗, one becomes desperate and takes a large dividendat one time in the fear of imminent insolvency due to a very negative drift. Graph d:As the volatility goes up, then the process tends to spend more time away from zero.Accordingly, the threshold level increases.

4 Concluding remarks

Before concluding, we compare two value functions, one for the IPO problem and theother for the harvesting problem. We fix the values of µ, σ, λ, η, and α and vary r

123

Page 21: Optimizing venture capital investments in a jump diffusion model

Optimizing venture capital investments in a jump diffusion model 41

2 4 6 8 10

0.5

1

1.5

b

1 2 3 4 5 6 7

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1

1.2

b

-0.4 -0.3 -0.2 -0.10.9

1.1

1.2

1.3

1.4

1.5

b

0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1

0.5

1

1.5

2

2.5

3

b

η λ

σ

µ

(a) (b)

(c) (d)

Fig. 5 Sensitivity of the harvesting problem to the parameters. The basis parameters are (µ, λ, η, σ, α) =(−0.05, 0.75, 1.5, 0.25, 0.1): a jump size parameter η, b arrival rate λ, c drift µ, d volatility σ

1 2 3 4 5 6x

2

4

6

8

V x , V x;0

1 2 3 4 5 6x

2

4

6

8

V x , V x;0

1 2 3 4 5 6x

24681012V x , V x;0

(a) (b) (c)

Fig. 6 The comparison of two value functions with (µ, λ, η, σ, α) = (−0.05, 0.75, 1.5, 0.25, 0.1):a r = 1.25. b r = 1.5 and c r = 2 where the value function for the IPO problem with a = 0 isshown in solid line and the value function for the harvesting problem is shown in dashed line

(recall that r − 1 is the expected rate of return at the IPO market). Figure 6 exhibitsthe two value functions: v(x; 0) (solid line) for the IPO problem and v(x) (dashedline) for the harvesting problem. It can be observed that as r increases, the valuefunction for the IPO problem shifts upward for all the points of x ∈ R+. This tells uswhich strategy (IPO or harvesting) is more advantageous given the initial investmentamount x .

Acknowledgements We thank Savas Dayanik for valuable comments and are most grateful to Anthea AuYeung, Ikumi Koseki, Toru Masuda, and Akihiko Yasuda for insight and good memories through helpfuland enjoyable conversations.

123

Page 22: Optimizing venture capital investments in a jump diffusion model

42 E. Bayraktar, M. Egami

References

Avram F, Palmowski Z, Pistorius M (2007) On the optimal dividend problem for a spectrally negative Lévyprocesses. Ann Appl Probab 17(1):156–180

Bayraktar E, Egami M (2006) A unified treatment of dividend payment problems under fixed cost andimplementation delay (Submitted), http://arxiv.org/abs/math.OC/0703825

Buckley IRC, Korn R (1998) Optimal index tracking under transaction costs and impulse control. Int JTheor Appl Finance 1(3):315–330

Dassios A, Embrechts P (1989) Martingales and insurance risk. Comm Stat Stoch Models 5:181–217Davis M, Schachermayer W, Tompkins R (2004) The evaluation of venture capital as an instalment option.

Zeitschrift für Betriebswirtschaft 3:77–96Gerber HU (1968) Entscheidungskriterien fuer den zusammengesetzten poisson-prozess. Schweiz Aktuar-

ver Mitt 1:185–227Gerber HU, Shiu ESW (2004) Optimal dividends: analysis with Brownian motion. North Am Actuar J

8(1):1–20Gerber HU, Avanzi B, Shiu ESW (2007) Optimal dividends in the dual model. Insur Math Econ 41(1):111–

123Grandits P, Hubalek F, Schachermayer W, Zigo M (2007) Optimal expected exponential utility of dividend

payments in brownian risk model. Scand Actuar J (in press), http://www.fam.tuwien.ac.at/~wschach/pubs

Jacod J, Shiryaev A (1987) Limit theorem for stochastic processes. Springer, BerlinJeanblanc-Picqué M, Shiryaev AN (1995) Optimization of the flow of dividends. Russ Math Surv 50(2):

257–277Johnston J, Madura J (2002) The performance of internet firms following their initial public offering. Financ

Rev 37:525–550Øksendal B, Sulem A (2005) Applied stochastic controll of jump diffusions. Springer, New YorkPennings E, Lint O (1997) The option value of advanced R&D. Eur J Oper Res 103:83–94Pham H (1998) Optimal stopping of controlled jump diffusion process: a viscosity solution approach.

J Math Syst Estim Control 8(1):1–27Schmidli H (2007) Optimal control in insurance. Springer, New YorkShreve SE, Lehoczky JP, Gaver DP (1984) Optimal consumption for general diffusions with absorbing and

reflecting barriers. SIAM J Control Optim 22(1):55–75Willner R (1995) Valuing start-up venture growth options in real options in capital investments. MIT,

Cambridge

123